Equivalence of several methods for decomposing time series into permananent and transitory components

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Equivalence of several methods for decomposing time series into permananent and transitory components"

Transcription

1 Equivalence of several methods for decomposing time series into permananent and transitory components Don Harding Department of Economics and Finance LaTrobe University, Bundoora Victoria 3086 and Centre for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis (CAMA) September 24, 2008

2 Abstract I show that several popular methods including the Hodrick Prescott lter, band pass lter, Butterworth lter, unobserved components model and the Beveridge Nelson decomposition all yield equivalent decompositions of time series into permanent and transitory components provided that the underlying model of the economy is held constant. Thus when practitioners obtain di erent permanent-transitory decompositions using these methods it is because they are varying the assumed model of the economy. JEL codes: C12; C13; C32; E32 Keywords: Permanent; transitory; unobserved components; Beveridge Nelson decomposition; Kalman lter; Butterworth Filter; Low Pass Filter; Band Pass Filter.

3 1 Introduction Macroeconomists separate time series into permanent and transitory components using one of the following methods, unobserved components (UC) models; Beveridge-Nelson (BN) decomposition; or Hodrick-Prescott (HP), Butterworth, Low Pass (LP) and Band-Pass (BP) lters. These methods all associate the permanent component with low frequency uctuations so it is of interest to ask how closely related are these methods. Previous work by Harvey and Jaeger (1993), Gomez (1999, 2001) and Harvey and Trimbur (2003) show that the HP, LP, BP and Butterworth lters all have UC representations so it su ces to focus attention on the relationship between the UC and BN permanent and transitory decompositions. Morely, Nelson and Zivot (2003) and Oh, Zivot and Creal (2007) show the equivalence of the BN and UC de nitions of permanent and transitory components in certain models. In this paper I extend these results in two ways. First, I extend the BN de nition of permanent component to I(2) processes. Second, I show that for a broad class of I(1) and I(2) processes the BN and UC permanenttransitory decompositions are equivalent in the sense that for a given reduced form model of the economy the BN permanent component is identical to the permanent component in the UC model. In addition to these extensions this paper contributes to the literature by virtue of the simplicity of the proofs and ease of access to practitioners. The paper also contributes to the literature by exploring two implications of the result just cited. The rst of these is that where practitioners obtain di erent permanent-transitory components using UC, BN, HP, BP or Butterworth methods, those di erence must be attributable to over identifying assumptions being imposed when particular methods are applied. Many of the methods for extracting permanent components are "black boxes" and this makes it di cult for practitioners to understand the identifying and over identifying restrictions that are imposed, implicitly, by the particular method that they have chosen use. To aid in understanding of this issue I set out the over identifying restrictions that are imposed in certain popular UC models. In future versions of the paper I propose to develop and implement tests of these restrictions. 2

4 The second implication that will be more fully explored in the future is that for a wide range of UC models it is possible to use the BN decomposition to write the model using a single source of error (SSOE) representation which simpli es the estimation and testing of these models without any loss of generality. The paper is structured as follows. In section 2 I generalize the de nitions of permanent and transitory components given by Beveridge and Nelson (1981) to I(2) processes. In section 3 I set out a general UC framework. That framework is used in section 4 to show that the Beveridge-Nelson and unobserved components approaches are equivalent for a wide range of processes. Over identifying restrictions imposed by popular UC models are explained in section 5. An application to US GDP is discussed in section 6. Conclusions are presented in section 7. 2 Generalization of the Beveridge Nelson de- nition of permanent and transitory components Macroeconomists spend much of their time studying how shocks move through the economic system. A useful question to ask about a variable in such a system is this, given the dynamics of the system, what value would that variable be expected to take after all of the shocks known at time t have moved through the economic system. This concept is formalized in the following de nition. De nition 1: Generalized Beveridge Nelson. Given a series y t, that is integrated of order two or less, the permanent component P t ; expected growth rate of the permanent component d t and transitory component T t are jointly de ned as follows P t = y t T t (1) T t = E t d t = E t 1 P t (2) 1 X j=1 (y t+j d t+j ) (3) Since P t is de ned as y t plus the sum of all the future changes in y t that are attributable to shocks known at time t: It is natural to name this concept as the permanent component of y as it is an estimate of the value that y will take at the in nite horizon conditional on what shocks we know 3

5 today. Similarly, it is natural to de ne as transitory that part of y t which is not permanent. If y t is I(1) with a deterministic trend then we have the standard Beveridge Nelson decomposition. But the extended de nition can handle the I(2) case where P t = t 1 + t And t = t 1 + t In this case d t = E t 1 ( t 1 + t ) = t 1 : The de nition also encompasses the case where y t is stationary about a deterministic trend. In this case g (t) is a deterministic function of time, d t = g (t) g (t 1), P t = g (t) and T t = (y t g (t)) : Thus a desirable feature of the generalized Beveridge-Nelson de nition is that it encompasses I(0), I(1) and I(2) cases in one setup. 3 A general unobserved components framework Consider a general UC representation of the DGP for y t in which y t is comprised of three unobservable components viz t ; z t and " t via the measurement equation (4). y t = t + z t + " " t 0 " < 1 (4) The component t evolves as follows Where t follows a random walk. t = t 1 + t 1 + t 0 < 1 (5) t = t 1 + t 0 < 1 (6) And s t = " t ; t ; t 0 is a 3 1 vector of mean zero shocks with unit variance that are mutually uncorrelated and are serially uncorrelated. Technically, Es t = 0; Es 2 t = I 3 and Es t s = 08t 6= : (7) The component z t is assumed to be an ergodic covariance stationary process that converges in mean to zero. The latter condition implies that lim E tz t+j = 0 (8) j!1 No restriction is placed on the covariation between z t and s t. 4

6 3.1 In what sense is this UC representation general? The system (4) to (8) is a reduced form model and thus the BN permanent and transitory components are reduced form concepts. A natural question is whether the dynamics of the model (4) to (8) are restricted in any way other than that which is necessary to ensure that the model is just identi ed. To address this question consider the process y t = t + z t + " " t 0 " < 1 (9) t = t 1 + t 1 + w t + t 0 < 1 (10) Where t evolves according to (6), zt and wt are ergodic covariance stationary processes. Many authors suggest that (9) and (10) represents a more general UC model than (4) and (5) because in the former t contains a cyclical component whereas t does not. For example, Quah (1992, p 110) writes By contrast, Shapiro and Watson (1998) and Blanchard and Quah (1989) have considered models where permanent components have richer dynamics than those in a random walk. But since it is covariance stationary w t can be represented as w t = (1 L) u t where u t has strictly positive but nite spectral density at the zero frequency. Thus we can replace w t in (10) and rewrite it as t u t = t 1 u t 1 + t 1 + t (11) De ning t = t u t and z t = z t + u t we can rewrite (9) and (10) as y t = t + z t + " " t (12) t = t 1 + t 1 + t (13) con rming that the representation (9) and (10) and the representation (4) and (5) are equivalent. It is worth observing here that this is the sense in which the UC representation (4) to (8) is general. In the representation (9) and (10) t u t is the BN permanent component and zt + u t is the BN transitory component. While in the representation (4) and (5) t is the BN permanent component and z t is the transitory component. Since t = t u t and z t = zt + u t the two representations yield identical BN decompositions. 5

7 4 Equivalence of Beveridge Nelson and Unobserved Components decompositions Consider a variable y t generated by a DGP the reduced form of which can be represented as the UC model (4) to (8) Then, proposition 1 states that the Beveridge Nelson and UC de nitions of permanent and transitory components are equivalent for that variable. Proposition 1 Equivalence of Beveridge Nelson and Unobserved Components decompositions of y t. The unobserved component model (4) to (6) satisfying restrictions (7) and (8) has the property that it produces an permanent-transitory decomposition identical to that of the Beveridge-Nelson decomposition (1), (2) and (3). Speci cally, t P t and T t z t " " t : Proof. Using the BN de nition of P t P t = y t + E t 1 X j=1 (y t+j d t+j ) Substituting in for y t from (4) and using the facts that d t = t 1 yields So, (y t+j d t+j ) = tt+j + t+j 1 + z t+j + " " t+j t+j 1 = tt+j + z t+j + " " t+j P t = t + z t + " " t + E t 1 X j=1 t+j + z t+j + " " t+j = t + z t + " " t + lim j!1 E t z t+j z t " " t But lim j!1 E t z t+j = 0 by the ergodic stationarity of z t : The remaining terms cancel leaving P t = t The result that T t z t " " t is obtained immediately by subtracting P t from y t. Proposition 1 shows when the same DGP is used the BN and UC permanent and transitory components are equivalent. The implication is that where practitioners obtain permanent and transitory components with UC models that di er from those obtained via a BN decomposition then the di erence must arise because in one of the cases the practitioner implicitly imposed over identifying restrictions on the model. 6

8 4.1 Interpreting the BN permanent and transitory components It is commonplace for practitioners to associate the BN transitory component with demand or to associate the variance in of the transitory component with a measure of the maximum contribution that demand uctuations make to the variation in y t : Both of these interpretations are false as is explained by Quah (1992, p110) who states that... permanent components turn out to have variances that can no longer be identi ed from just the second moments of the original sequence. To fully understand this issue it is useful to use the representation (4) to (8) and associate t with the permanent component from the supply side of the economy. Then, the BN transitory component is comprised of two parts viz z t and the measurement error " t : Here the variance of y t is Suppose to simplify the discussion = 0 so we are dealing with a I(1) process. The we can decompose the variance of y t as follows. V ar (y t ) = V ar ( t ) + V ar (z t ) + var (" t ) + 2Cov ( t ; z t ) +2Cov (" t ; z t ) + 2Cov (" t ; t ) But we saw in section 3.1 that z t is comprised of two parts zt that we can think of as the demand component and u t that we can view as the transitory part of the supply component. In many instances it is convenient to assume that demand and supply components are uncorrelated ie zt and u t ; and zt and t are uncorrelated so that V ar (z t ) = V ar (zt ) + V ar (u t ) and Cov ( t ; z t ) = 0: the measurement error " t is uncorrelated with (z t ; u t ; t ) With these assumptions we can express the variance of y t as, V ar (y t ) = 2 + V ar (z t ) + V ar (u t ) + 2 " + 2Cov ( t ; u t ) The term Cov ( t ; u t ) is the covariance between the innovation into the permanent part of the supply component and the change in the transitory part of the supply component. This covariance can have either a positive or negative sign and so we cannot use our estimates of 2 ; 2 " and V ar (y t ) 7

9 to place an upper bound on V ar (z t ) : Thus, even with the assumptions made earlier it is not possible to place an upper bound on the contribution made by demand to the variance of y t : Further, restrictions from economic theory are required to identify the respective contributions of demand and supply shocks. 1 5 Over identifying restrictions imposed in popular UC model Clarke (1987), Harvey (1985) and Harvey Trimbur and Van Dijk (2007) all use UC models to obtain permanent-transitory decompositions that di er substantially from that obtained when the BN decomposition is applied using an unrestricted ARIMA model as the reduced form. The implication of proposition 1 is that this nding must arise because the UC models are estimated imposing over identifying restrictions that are not supported by the data. In this section I investigate those over identifying restrictions. A maintained assumption here is that, using the notation of section 3, the shocks s t = 0 t t " t are mean zero iid and mutually uncorrelated. Speci cally 2 Es t = 0; Es t s 0 t = " 3 5 (14) The remaining identi cation assumptions relate to the nature of the process z t : I look at three cases in the literature. The rst studied in section 5.1 allows z t to follow a stationary ARMA (p; q) process. The second speci cation studied in section 5.2 is favoured by Andrew Harvey and his coauthors imposes some additional over identifying restrictions on z t : The third speci cation studied in section is of interest because it provides a UC motivation for BP lters. 5.1 ARMA (p; q) speci cation of z t Here we assume that z t follows the ARMA(p,q) process z t = (L) (L) $ t (15) 1 The UC model (4) to (6) is some time referred to as being a structural time series model but this name is very misleading as the shocks do not necessarily have an economic interpretation and thus do not have meaning derived from economic theory. 8

10 where (L) = L + + q L q and (L) = 1 1 L p L p are lag polynomials and (L) has all its roots inside the unit circle. The shocks $ t are Gaussian with mean zero variance 2 $ and cov(; $) = $ :The covariances with all other shocks are zero ARIMA representation and identi cation Given the assumptions above 2 y t can be written as 2 y t = t 1 + t t 1 + (L) ($ t 2$ t 1 + $ t 2 ) (L) + " t 2" t 1 + " t 2 (16) Multiplying both sides of (16) by (L) yields an AR(p) in 2 y t on the left hand side. The rst term of the right hand side is (L) t 1 a p order moving average, the second terms is (L) (1 L) t a p + 1 order moving average, the third term is (L) (1 L) 2 $ t a (2 + q) order moving average and the nal term is (L) (1 L) 2 " t a p + 2 order moving average. Thus letting q = max (q; p) + 2 and appealing to Grangers theorem, 2 y t has an ARIMA(p; 2; q) representation. The ARIMA representation yields p q parameters. The state space representation has 5 + p + q parameters. A necessary condition for identi cation is that the number of parameters in the ARIMA model equals the number of parameters in the UC model, That is, There are two cases to consider. p q = 5 + p + q (17) ) q q = 4 Case 1: q = 2 + q This is the case where there are more MA parameters than AR parameters (q > p) Making use of (17) we see that identi cation requires that 2 = 4 which is impossible so the parameters of the UC model are unidenti ed unless further restrictions are placed on the parameters. Case 2: q = p + 2 This is the case where there are at lease as many AR parameters as MA parameters. Again making use of (17) we see that the UC model is just identi ed if there are two more AR parameters in the cycle than there are MA parameters (p q = 2) : The UC model is over identi ed if (p q > 2) It is useful to explore the issue of identi cation in the context of the models made popular by Clarke (1989) and Harvey (1985). In this model 9

11 p = 2 and q 1: There are two ways to ensure that this model is just identi ed. The rst is to set q = 0 so that there are no MA terms in the cycle. This identi cation was pursued by Clarke (1987). The second is to set q > 0 but write the model so that the MA parameters are completely determined as functions of the AR parameters. This later identifying assumption is made in the local linear trend plus cycle models and the cyclical trend models that have been made popular by Harvey et al(1993). 5.2 Periodic cycle speci cation of z t In this model z t is generated by, zt cos sin zt = 1 + sin cos z t z t 1 t t (18) where, 0 1 to impose stationarity, is frequency in radians, t and t are mutually independent i:i:d N (0; 2 ) and i:i:d N (0; 2 ) respectively. To establish the nature of these restrictions write the moving average representation of (18) as, zt z t = 1 cos L sin L sin L 1 cos L 1 t t (19) Now applying a standard formula for matrix inversion 1 cos L sin L sin L 1 cos L 1 = 1 cos L sin L sin L 1 cos L (20) 1 2 cos L + 2 cos 2 L 2 Thus z t has a representation as, 1 2 cos L + 2 cos 2 L 2 z t = (1 cos L ) t + sin L t (21) The right hand side in (21) is the sum of a MA(1) process and Gaussian white noise. Thus by Granger s theorem the right hand side is an MA(1). The left hand side of (21) is an AR(2) with coe cients 1 = 2 cos and 10

12 2 = 2 : Thus z t is an ARMA(2; 1): Focusing on the AR(2) part we can see that the roots are cos p cos 2 1 and since 0 cos 2 < 1 they are complex so z t must have a periodic cycle in this speci cation. One can obtain an equivalent restriction on (15) that involves restricting the AR parameters to the region de ned by the intersection of the regions ; and 1 2 0:. The last two regions coming from the de nitions of 1 and 2 together with the restrictions on and : Thus, the identifying assumption used by Harvey imposes a periodic cycle by placing restrictions on the AR parameters. In addition it also imposes a restriction that MA coe cient is completely determined by the AR parameters. It is this identifying assumption that allows the model to be estimated. To obtain the restriction on the MA parameters let w t = (1 cos L ) t + sin L t then E (wt 2 ) = (1 + 2 ) 2, E (w t ; w t 1 ) = cos 2 : Thus, w t has a representation as w t = (1 + L) u t where u t ~N (0; 2 u) and in this representation E (wt 2 ) = u and E (w t ; w t 1 ) = 2 u. Thus equating the expectations we have u = E w 2 t = (22) 2 u = E (w t ; w t 1 ) = cos 2 (23) Dividing (23) by (22) yields Rearranging gives cos = = cos cos 2 (24) Solving the quadratic for yields = q (1 + 2 ) cos 2 2 cos And, the invertibility condition that jj < 1 selects (25) 11

13 = q (1 + 2 ) cos 2 2 cos (26) Now letting 1 = 2 cos and 2 = terms of the AR parameters viz, 2 we can rewrite completely in = 1 2 q (1 2 ) (27) Which demonstrates the earlier claim that the periodicity restriction completely determine 1 in terms of the AR parameters: 5.3 n th order cycles, Butterworth and low pass lters The low pass Butterworth lter is B lp m (L) = As m! 1 B lp m (L)! q 1 j1 Lj 2m ; q = 2 sin 2 2m ; 0 < Harvey and Trimbur (2003) and Harvey Trimbur and Van Dijk (2007) consider an extension of the a periodic cycle model (18). Speci cally, they de ne z 1t and z1t as follows. z1t cos sin z1t = 1 t + (28) sin cos 0 z 1t z 1t 1 where, 0 1 to impose stationarity, is frequency in radians, t and t are mutually independent i:i:d N (0; 2 ) and i:i:d N (0; 2 ) respectively. The components z it and zit are de ned recursively as, zit z it cos sin = sin cos zit 1 z it 1 + zi 1;t 1 0 i = 2; 3; ::: (29) Here there are two di erences between (28) and (29) and the periodic model discussed earlier. First, in (28) the innovation t is set to zero. Second in (29) z i 1;t 1 is set to zero. 12

14 Following Harvey and Trimbur (2003) we can write where c (L) = z nt = [c (L)] n t 1 cos L 1 2 cos L + 2 L 2 Harvey and Trimbur (2003) de ne a m th order stochastic trend as follows. De nition 2 An unobserved component 1 is an m;t t= 1 mth order stochastic trend, for positive integers m, if 1;t = 1;t 1 + t i;t = i;t 1 + i 1;t ; i = 2; : : : ; m where the disturbance term t is serially uncorrelated with mean zero and constant variance 2 ; denoted hereafter by writing t~w N 0; 2 Harvey and Trimbur (2003) write the measurement equation associated with the UC model that has a m th order stochastic trend and a n th order cycle and measurement error " t as y t = m;t + z nt + " t ; " t ~W N 0; 2 " The low pass Wiener-Kolmogorov lter associated with this model is q GBm;n lp j1 Lj L; ; ; q ; q = 2m q + q j1 Lj 2m + 1 ; q = jc(l)j 2n 2 2 " ; and q = 2 2 " (30) Harvey and Timbur state that as m and n go to in nity GBm;n lp L; ; ; q ; q tends to an ideal low pass lter. The important point to make here is that the equivalence between certain UC models and low pass or band pass ltering arises because potentially testable assumptions are being imposed on the UC models. Testing those assumptions directly may prove to be di cult. Proposition 1 provides us with a simpler way to proceed. That is, estimate a parsimonious reduced form model that is not rejected by the data. Use that model to obtain the Beveridge-Nelson permanent-transitory decomposition. If that BN decomposition di ers substantially from the permanent transitory decomposition from the UC model or the band pass lter then we can conclude that the UC model implied by the band pass lter imposes over identifying restrictions that are not supported by the data. 13

15 6 Application The important implication for practitioners is that one does not need to use an UC model to implement a valid permanent transitory decomposition. All that one needs to do is nd an ARIMA model that is an adequate approximation to the DGP for y t and then apply (1), (2) and (3) to obtain the permanent-transitory decomposition. For example a reasonable approximation to the DGP of y t = ln(usgdp t ) is 2 y t = + y t 1 + " t So the permanent component is given by (31) X 1 P t = y t + E t j y t 1 j=1 And the transitory component is given by = y t + 1 y t (31) T t = 1 y t (32) The permanent and transitory components of US GDP are shown in Figure 1 where it is evident that almost all of the movement in that series is attributable to the permanent component. The transitory component of US GDP is shown in Figure 2. The facts that an AR (1) in growth rates ts US GDP well and that it implies the decomposition above is well known. But there are a variety of other approaches that yield very di erent permanent transitory decompositions and the question that has been asked is why should the decomposition shown in Figures 1 and 2 be chosen over the other decompositions? This paper gives the following answer to that question First, the AR (1) model is selected by standard signi cance testing so it is the most parsimonious model that is consistent with the data. Second we know from proposition 1 that all of the methods yield equivalent decompositions if the underlying model is held constant. Thus, the permanent transitory decompositions that di er from that obtained from (31) and (32) must be based on models that have a reduced form which is very di erent from an AR(1). This can only happen if those other methods involve the imposition of assumptions that are not supported by the data. 2 The estimated parameters are = 0: and = 0:3259: 14

16 Figure 1: Beveridge-Nelson permanent and transitory components of US GDP, 1947Q1 to 2008Q Ln(US GDP) ln(us GDP) Permanent component (BN) 7 Apr 47 Apr 52 Apr 57 Apr 62 Apr 67 Apr 72 Apr 77 Apr 82 Apr 87 Apr 92 Apr 97 Apr 02 Apr 07 Figure 2: Transitory component of US GDP, 1947Q1 to 2008Q BN Transitory component in ln(us GDP) Transitory component (BN) 0.02 Apr 47 Apr 52 Apr 57 Apr 62 Apr 67 Apr 72 Apr 77 Apr 82 Apr 87 Apr 92 Apr 97 Apr 02 Apr 07 15

17 7 Conclusion I have shown that permanent-transitory decompositions obtained from a wide range of methods are all equivalent if the underlying reduced form model is held constant. The implication from this is that practitioners can obtain valid permanent-transitory decompositions through the following steps. 1) Find a parsimonious reduced form model that is not rejected by the data. 2) Use that model to obtain the Beveridge-Nelson decomposition. 3) Justify the use of this as the permanent - transitory decomposition by arguing that any method which provides a markedly di erent permanent-transitory decomposition must involve restrictions on the reduced form model that are not supported by the data. 4) Observe that using a model that is more profligate with parameters will incur ine ciency but should not yield a markedly di erent permanent - transitory decomposition.. References Baxter, M. and R. King (1999), Measuring Business Cycles: Approximate Band-Pass Filters for Economic Time Series, Review of Economics and Statistics, 81, pp Beveridge, S. and C.R. Nelson (1981), "A new approach to the decomposition of economic time series into permanent and transitory components with particular attention to measurement of the business cycle", Journal of Monetary Economics, 7, Blanchard, O.J. and S. Fischer (1989), Lectures on Macroeconomics, M.I.T. Press Cambridge, MA, Canova, F. (1998), Detrending and business cycle facts, Journal of Monetary Economics, Volume 41, Issue 3, 20 May, Hamilton, J.D., (1989), A New Approach to the Economic Analysis of Non-Stationary Times Series and the Business Cycle, Econometrica, 57, pp Harvey, A.C., (1985), "Trends and cycles in macroeconomic time series", Journal of Business and Economic Statistics,3, Harvey, A.C., and A. Jaeger (1993). Detrending, Stylized Facts and the Business Cycle, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 8,. pp King, R.G. and S.T. Rebelo (1993), Low Frequency Filtering and Real Business Cycles, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 17, Kaiser, R and A. Maravall (2001), "Measuring Business Cycles in Economic Time Series", Lecture Notes in Statistics 154, New York, Springer- Verlag 16

18 Morley, J.C. (2002), "A state-space approach to calculating the Beveridge- Nelson decomposition", Economics Letters 75, Morley, J.C., C.R. Nelson, and Zivot, E. (2003), "Why are the Beveridge_Nelson and Unobserved Components Decompositions of GDP so Different", The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol LXXV, May, No 2, pp Pierce, D.A. (1979), Signal extraction error in nonstationary time series. Annals of Statistics, 7, pp Sargent, T.J. (1979), Macroeconomic Theory (Academic Press) 17

Time Series Models and Inference. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley

Time Series Models and Inference. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Time Series Models and Inference James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Overview In contrast to the classical linear regression model, in which the components of the

More information

Notes on Time Series Modeling

Notes on Time Series Modeling Notes on Time Series Modeling Garey Ramey University of California, San Diego January 17 1 Stationary processes De nition A stochastic process is any set of random variables y t indexed by t T : fy t g

More information

CENTRE FOR APPLIED MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS

CENTRE FOR APPLIED MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS CENTRE FOR APPLIED MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS The Australian National University CAMA Working Paper Series May, 2005 SINGLE SOURCE OF ERROR STATE SPACE APPROACH TO THE BEVERIDGE NELSON DECOMPOSITION Heather

More information

The MIT Press Journals

The MIT Press Journals The MIT Press Journals http://mitpress.mit.edu/journals This article is provided courtesy of The MIT Press. To join an e-mail alert list and receive the latest news on our publications, please visit: http://mitpress.mit.edu/e-mail

More information

Trend-Cycle Decompositions

Trend-Cycle Decompositions Trend-Cycle Decompositions Eric Zivot April 22, 2005 1 Introduction A convenient way of representing an economic time series y t is through the so-called trend-cycle decomposition y t = TD t + Z t (1)

More information

On the Correlations of Trend-Cycle Errors

On the Correlations of Trend-Cycle Errors On the Correlations of Trend-Cycle Errors Tatsuma Wada Wayne State University This version: December 19, 11 Abstract This note provides explanations for an unexpected result, namely, the estimated parameter

More information

Class: Trend-Cycle Decomposition

Class: Trend-Cycle Decomposition Class: Trend-Cycle Decomposition Macroeconometrics - Spring 2011 Jacek Suda, BdF and PSE June 1, 2011 Outline Outline: 1 Unobserved Component Approach 2 Beveridge-Nelson Decomposition 3 Spectral Analysis

More information

Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts

Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts Contents 1 Motivating Examples 1 1.1 Instrumental variable estimator....................... 1 1.2 Estimating parameters in monetary policy rules.............. 2 1.3 Estimating

More information

Univariate Nonstationary Time Series 1

Univariate Nonstationary Time Series 1 Univariate Nonstationary Time Series 1 Sebastian Fossati University of Alberta 1 These slides are based on Eric Zivot s time series notes available at: http://faculty.washington.edu/ezivot Introduction

More information

On Econometric Analysis of Structural Systems with Permanent and Transitory Shocks and Exogenous Variables

On Econometric Analysis of Structural Systems with Permanent and Transitory Shocks and Exogenous Variables On Econometric Analysis of Structural Systems with Permanent and Transitory Shocks and Exogenous Variables Adrian Pagan School of Economics and Finance, Queensland University of Technology M. Hashem Pesaran

More information

Estimating Output Gap, Core Inflation, and the NAIRU for Peru

Estimating Output Gap, Core Inflation, and the NAIRU for Peru BANCO CENTRAL DE RESERVA DEL PERÚ Estimating Output Gap, Core Inflation, and the NAIRU for Peru Gabriel Rodríguez* * Central Reserve Bank of Peru and Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú DT. N 2009-011

More information

ARIMA Models. Richard G. Pierse

ARIMA Models. Richard G. Pierse ARIMA Models Richard G. Pierse 1 Introduction Time Series Analysis looks at the properties of time series from a purely statistical point of view. No attempt is made to relate variables using a priori

More information

Lecture 19 - Decomposing a Time Series into its Trend and Cyclical Components

Lecture 19 - Decomposing a Time Series into its Trend and Cyclical Components Lecture 19 - Decomposing a Time Series into its Trend and Cyclical Components It is often assumed that many macroeconomic time series are subject to two sorts of forces: those that influence the long-run

More information

Econ 424 Time Series Concepts

Econ 424 Time Series Concepts Econ 424 Time Series Concepts Eric Zivot January 20 2015 Time Series Processes Stochastic (Random) Process { 1 2 +1 } = { } = sequence of random variables indexed by time Observed time series of length

More information

The Predictive Space or If x predicts y; what does y tell us about x?

The Predictive Space or If x predicts y; what does y tell us about x? The Predictive Space or If x predicts y; what does y tell us about x? Donald Robertson and Stephen Wright y October 28, 202 Abstract A predictive regression for y t and a time series representation of

More information

TREND ESTIMATION AND THE HODRICK-PRESCOTT FILTER

TREND ESTIMATION AND THE HODRICK-PRESCOTT FILTER J. Japan Statist. Soc. Vol. 38 No. 1 2008 41 49 TREND ESTIMATION AND THE HODRICK-PRESCOTT FILTER Andrew Harvey* and Thomas Trimbur** The article analyses the relationship between unobserved component trend-cycle

More information

GMM-based inference in the AR(1) panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails

GMM-based inference in the AR(1) panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails GMM-based inference in the AR() panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails Edith Madsen entre for Applied Microeconometrics (AM) Department of Economics, University of openhagen,

More information

1 Regression with Time Series Variables

1 Regression with Time Series Variables 1 Regression with Time Series Variables With time series regression, Y might not only depend on X, but also lags of Y and lags of X Autoregressive Distributed lag (or ADL(p; q)) model has these features:

More information

Some Time-Series Models

Some Time-Series Models Some Time-Series Models Outline 1. Stochastic processes and their properties 2. Stationary processes 3. Some properties of the autocorrelation function 4. Some useful models Purely random processes, random

More information

Macroeconomics Theory II

Macroeconomics Theory II Macroeconomics Theory II Francesco Franco FEUNL February 2016 Francesco Franco Macroeconomics Theory II 1/23 Housekeeping. Class organization. Website with notes and papers as no "Mas-Collel" in macro

More information

Stochastic Trends & Economic Fluctuations

Stochastic Trends & Economic Fluctuations Stochastic Trends & Economic Fluctuations King, Plosser, Stock & Watson (AER, 1991) Cesar E. Tamayo Econ508 - Economics - Rutgers November 14, 2011 Cesar E. Tamayo Stochastic Trends & Economic Fluctuations

More information

Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence

Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence Peter M. Robinson London School of Economics Based on joint work with Javier Hualde: Javier Hualde and Peter M. Robinson: Gaussian Pseudo-Maximum Likelihood Estimation

More information

Markov-Switching Models with Endogenous Explanatory Variables. Chang-Jin Kim 1

Markov-Switching Models with Endogenous Explanatory Variables. Chang-Jin Kim 1 Markov-Switching Models with Endogenous Explanatory Variables by Chang-Jin Kim 1 Dept. of Economics, Korea University and Dept. of Economics, University of Washington First draft: August, 2002 This version:

More information

Structural VAR based estimates of the euro area output gap: Theoretical considerations and empirical evidences

Structural VAR based estimates of the euro area output gap: Theoretical considerations and empirical evidences Structural VAR based estimates of the euro area output gap: Theoretical considerations and empirical evidences James Mitchell, Gian Luigi Mazzi y, Filippo Moauro z June 17, 2008 Abstract Users look with

More information

The Clark Model with Correlated Components

The Clark Model with Correlated Components The Clark Model with Correlated Components Kum Hwa Oh and Eric Zivot January 16, 2006 Abstract This paper is an extension of Why are the Beveridge-Nelson and Unobserved- Components Decompositions of GDP

More information

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models Fall 22 Contents Introduction 2. An illustrative example........................... 2.2 Discussion...................................

More information

Cointegration Tests Using Instrumental Variables Estimation and the Demand for Money in England

Cointegration Tests Using Instrumental Variables Estimation and the Demand for Money in England Cointegration Tests Using Instrumental Variables Estimation and the Demand for Money in England Kyung So Im Junsoo Lee Walter Enders June 12, 2005 Abstract In this paper, we propose new cointegration tests

More information

7. Forecasting with ARIMA models

7. Forecasting with ARIMA models 7. Forecasting with ARIMA models 309 Outline: Introduction The prediction equation of an ARIMA model Interpreting the predictions Variance of the predictions Forecast updating Measuring predictability

More information

Structural Macroeconometrics. Chapter 4. Summarizing Time Series Behavior

Structural Macroeconometrics. Chapter 4. Summarizing Time Series Behavior Structural Macroeconometrics Chapter 4. Summarizing Time Series Behavior David N. DeJong Chetan Dave The sign of a truly educated man is to be deeply moved by statistics. George Bernard Shaw This chapter

More information

Empirical Macroeconomics

Empirical Macroeconomics Empirical Macroeconomics Francesco Franco Nova SBE April 5, 2016 Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 1/39 Growth and Fluctuations Supply and Demand Figure : US dynamics Francesco Franco Empirical

More information

What are the Differences in Trend Cycle Decompositions by Beveridge and Nelson and by Unobserved Component Models?

What are the Differences in Trend Cycle Decompositions by Beveridge and Nelson and by Unobserved Component Models? What are the Differences in Trend Cycle Decompositions by Beveridge and Nelson and by Unobserved Component Models? April 30, 2012 Abstract When a certain procedure is applied to extract two component processes

More information

Economics 620, Lecture 13: Time Series I

Economics 620, Lecture 13: Time Series I Economics 620, Lecture 13: Time Series I Nicholas M. Kiefer Cornell University Professor N. M. Kiefer (Cornell University) Lecture 13: Time Series I 1 / 19 AUTOCORRELATION Consider y = X + u where y is

More information

11. Further Issues in Using OLS with TS Data

11. Further Issues in Using OLS with TS Data 11. Further Issues in Using OLS with TS Data With TS, including lags of the dependent variable often allow us to fit much better the variation in y Exact distribution theory is rarely available in TS applications,

More information

Time Series Analysis for Macroeconomics and Finance

Time Series Analysis for Macroeconomics and Finance Time Series Analysis for Macroeconomics and Finance Bernd Süssmuth IEW Institute for Empirical Research in Economics University of Leipzig December 12, 2011 Bernd Süssmuth (University of Leipzig) Time

More information

B y t = γ 0 + Γ 1 y t + ε t B(L) y t = γ 0 + ε t ε t iid (0, D) D is diagonal

B y t = γ 0 + Γ 1 y t + ε t B(L) y t = γ 0 + ε t ε t iid (0, D) D is diagonal Structural VAR Modeling for I(1) Data that is Not Cointegrated Assume y t =(y 1t,y 2t ) 0 be I(1) and not cointegrated. That is, y 1t and y 2t are both I(1) and there is no linear combination of y 1t and

More information

1 Teaching notes on structural VARs.

1 Teaching notes on structural VARs. Bent E. Sørensen November 8, 2016 1 Teaching notes on structural VARs. 1.1 Vector MA models: 1.1.1 Probability theory The simplest to analyze, estimation is a different matter time series models are the

More information

Macroeconomics II Dynamic macroeconomics Class 1: Introduction and rst models

Macroeconomics II Dynamic macroeconomics Class 1: Introduction and rst models Macroeconomics II Dynamic macroeconomics Class 1: Introduction and rst models Prof. George McCandless UCEMA Spring 2008 1 Class 1: introduction and rst models What we will do today 1. Organization of course

More information

LECTURE 13: TIME SERIES I

LECTURE 13: TIME SERIES I 1 LECTURE 13: TIME SERIES I AUTOCORRELATION: Consider y = X + u where y is T 1, X is T K, is K 1 and u is T 1. We are using T and not N for sample size to emphasize that this is a time series. The natural

More information

LECTURE 12 UNIT ROOT, WEAK CONVERGENCE, FUNCTIONAL CLT

LECTURE 12 UNIT ROOT, WEAK CONVERGENCE, FUNCTIONAL CLT MARCH 29, 26 LECTURE 2 UNIT ROOT, WEAK CONVERGENCE, FUNCTIONAL CLT (Davidson (2), Chapter 4; Phillips Lectures on Unit Roots, Cointegration and Nonstationarity; White (999), Chapter 7) Unit root processes

More information

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, SAN DIEGO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, SAN DIEGO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS 2-7 UNIVERSITY OF LIFORNI, SN DIEGO DEPRTMENT OF EONOMIS THE JOHNSEN-GRNGER REPRESENTTION THEOREM: N EXPLIIT EXPRESSION FOR I() PROESSES Y PETER REINHRD HNSEN DISUSSION PPER 2-7 JULY 2 The Johansen-Granger

More information

Estimating the Number of Common Factors in Serially Dependent Approximate Factor Models

Estimating the Number of Common Factors in Serially Dependent Approximate Factor Models Estimating the Number of Common Factors in Serially Dependent Approximate Factor Models Ryan Greenaway-McGrevy y Bureau of Economic Analysis Chirok Han Korea University February 7, 202 Donggyu Sul University

More information

Modeling the Phillips curve with unobserved components

Modeling the Phillips curve with unobserved components Modeling the Phillips curve with unobserved components Andrew Harvey, Faculty of Economics, Cambridge University. ACH34@CAM.AC.UK January 18, 2008 Abstract The relationship between in ation and the output

More information

Chapter 5. Structural Vector Autoregression

Chapter 5. Structural Vector Autoregression Chapter 5. Structural Vector Autoregression Contents 1 Introduction 1 2 The structural moving average model 1 2.1 The impulse response function....................... 2 2.2 Variance decomposition...........................

More information

Department of Econometrics and Business Statistics

Department of Econometrics and Business Statistics ISSN 1440-771X Australia Department of Econometrics and Business Statistics http://www.buseco.monash.edu.au/depts/ebs/pubs/wpapers/ Exponential Smoothing: A Prediction Error Decomposition Principle Ralph

More information

Learning in Real Time: Theory and Empirical Evidence from the Term Structure of Survey Forecasts

Learning in Real Time: Theory and Empirical Evidence from the Term Structure of Survey Forecasts Learning in Real Time: Theory and Empirical Evidence from the Term Structure of Survey Forecasts Andrew Patton and Allan Timmermann Oxford and UC-San Diego November 2007 Motivation Uncertainty about macroeconomic

More information

ECON 616: Lecture 1: Time Series Basics

ECON 616: Lecture 1: Time Series Basics ECON 616: Lecture 1: Time Series Basics ED HERBST August 30, 2017 References Overview: Chapters 1-3 from Hamilton (1994). Technical Details: Chapters 2-3 from Brockwell and Davis (1987). Intuition: Chapters

More information

Estimation and Inference of Linear Trend Slope Ratios

Estimation and Inference of Linear Trend Slope Ratios Estimation and Inference of Linear rend Slope Ratios imothy J. Vogelsang and Nasreen Nawaz Department of Economics, Michigan State University October 4 Abstract We focus on the estimation of the ratio

More information

Chapter 2. GMM: Estimating Rational Expectations Models

Chapter 2. GMM: Estimating Rational Expectations Models Chapter 2. GMM: Estimating Rational Expectations Models Contents 1 Introduction 1 2 Step 1: Solve the model and obtain Euler equations 2 3 Step 2: Formulate moment restrictions 3 4 Step 3: Estimation and

More information

1 Teaching notes on structural VARs.

1 Teaching notes on structural VARs. Bent E. Sørensen February 22, 2007 1 Teaching notes on structural VARs. 1.1 Vector MA models: 1.1.1 Probability theory The simplest (to analyze, estimation is a different matter) time series models are

More information

Topic 4 Unit Roots. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University

Topic 4 Unit Roots. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University Topic 4 Unit Roots Gerald P. Dwyer Clemson University February 2016 Outline 1 Unit Roots Introduction Trend and Difference Stationary Autocorrelations of Series That Have Deterministic or Stochastic Trends

More information

Problem set 1 - Solutions

Problem set 1 - Solutions EMPIRICAL FINANCE AND FINANCIAL ECONOMETRICS - MODULE (8448) Problem set 1 - Solutions Exercise 1 -Solutions 1. The correct answer is (a). In fact, the process generating daily prices is usually assumed

More information

Testing for Regime Switching: A Comment

Testing for Regime Switching: A Comment Testing for Regime Switching: A Comment Andrew V. Carter Department of Statistics University of California, Santa Barbara Douglas G. Steigerwald Department of Economics University of California Santa Barbara

More information

Trending Models in the Data

Trending Models in the Data April 13, 2009 Spurious regression I Before we proceed to test for unit root and trend-stationary models, we will examine the phenomena of spurious regression. The material in this lecture can be found

More information

9) Time series econometrics

9) Time series econometrics 30C00200 Econometrics 9) Time series econometrics Timo Kuosmanen Professor Management Science http://nomepre.net/index.php/timokuosmanen 1 Macroeconomic data: GDP Inflation rate Examples of time series

More information

Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions

Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions William D. Lastrapes Department of Economics Terry College of Business University of Georgia Athens,

More information

Cointegration and the joint con rmation hypothesis

Cointegration and the joint con rmation hypothesis Cointegration and the joint con rmation hypothesis VASCO J. GABRIEL Department of Economics, Birkbeck College, UK University of Minho, Portugal October 2001 Abstract Recent papers by Charemza and Syczewska

More information

Permanent vs Transitory Components and Economic Fundamentals

Permanent vs Transitory Components and Economic Fundamentals Permanent vs Transitory Components and Economic Fundamentals Anthony Garratt, University of Leicester Donald Robertson, University of Cambridge Stephen Wright, Birkbeck College November 6, 2003 Abstract

More information

Time Series Analysis. James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY

Time Series Analysis. James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY Time Series Analysis James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY & Contents PREFACE xiii 1 1.1. 1.2. Difference Equations First-Order Difference Equations 1 /?th-order Difference

More information

Trend and Cycles: A New Approach and Explanations of Some Old Puzzles

Trend and Cycles: A New Approach and Explanations of Some Old Puzzles Trend and Cycles: A New Approach and Explanations of Some Old Puzzles Pierre Perron Boston University Tatsuma Wada Boston University This Version: January 2, 2005 Abstract Recent work on trend-cycle decompositions

More information

Introduction: structural econometrics. Jean-Marc Robin

Introduction: structural econometrics. Jean-Marc Robin Introduction: structural econometrics Jean-Marc Robin Abstract 1. Descriptive vs structural models 2. Correlation is not causality a. Simultaneity b. Heterogeneity c. Selectivity Descriptive models Consider

More information

2. Multivariate ARMA

2. Multivariate ARMA 2. Multivariate ARMA JEM 140: Quantitative Multivariate Finance IES, Charles University, Prague Summer 2018 JEM 140 () 2. Multivariate ARMA Summer 2018 1 / 19 Multivariate AR I Let r t = (r 1t,..., r kt

More information

Empirical Macroeconomics

Empirical Macroeconomics Empirical Macroeconomics Francesco Franco Nova SBE April 21, 2015 Francesco Franco Empirical Macroeconomics 1/33 Growth and Fluctuations Supply and Demand Figure : US dynamics Francesco Franco Empirical

More information

ARIMA Modelling and Forecasting

ARIMA Modelling and Forecasting ARIMA Modelling and Forecasting Economic time series often appear nonstationary, because of trends, seasonal patterns, cycles, etc. However, the differences may appear stationary. Δx t x t x t 1 (first

More information

Modeling the Phillips curve with unobserved components

Modeling the Phillips curve with unobserved components Modeling the Phillips curve with unobserved components Andrew Harvey, Faculty of Economics, Cambridge University. ACH34@CAM.AC.UK September 23, 2008 Abstract The relationship between in ation and the output

More information

Lecture 2: Univariate Time Series

Lecture 2: Univariate Time Series Lecture 2: Univariate Time Series Analysis: Conditional and Unconditional Densities, Stationarity, ARMA Processes Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20192 Financial Econometrics Spring/Winter 2017 Overview Motivation:

More information

Simple Estimators for Semiparametric Multinomial Choice Models

Simple Estimators for Semiparametric Multinomial Choice Models Simple Estimators for Semiparametric Multinomial Choice Models James L. Powell and Paul A. Ruud University of California, Berkeley March 2008 Preliminary and Incomplete Comments Welcome Abstract This paper

More information

Intuitive and Reliable Estimates of the Output Gap from a Beveridge-Nelson Filter

Intuitive and Reliable Estimates of the Output Gap from a Beveridge-Nelson Filter Intuitive and Reliable Estimates of the Output Gap from a Beveridge-Nelson Filter Güneş Kamber, James Morley, and Benjamin Wong The Beveridge-Nelson decomposition based on autoregressive models produces

More information

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA On the Solution of the Growth Model with Investment-Specific Technological Change Jesús Fernández-Villaverde and Juan Francisco Rubio-Ramírez Working Paper 2004-39 December

More information

When Do Wold Orderings and Long-Run Recursive Identifying Restrictions Yield Identical Results?

When Do Wold Orderings and Long-Run Recursive Identifying Restrictions Yield Identical Results? Preliminary and incomplete When Do Wold Orderings and Long-Run Recursive Identifying Restrictions Yield Identical Results? John W Keating * University of Kansas Department of Economics 334 Snow Hall Lawrence,

More information

Comment on HAC Corrections for Strongly Autocorrelated Time Series by Ulrich K. Müller

Comment on HAC Corrections for Strongly Autocorrelated Time Series by Ulrich K. Müller Comment on HAC Corrections for Strongly Autocorrelated ime Series by Ulrich K. Müller Yixiao Sun Department of Economics, UC San Diego May 2, 24 On the Nearly-optimal est Müller applies the theory of optimal

More information

1 The Multiple Regression Model: Freeing Up the Classical Assumptions

1 The Multiple Regression Model: Freeing Up the Classical Assumptions 1 The Multiple Regression Model: Freeing Up the Classical Assumptions Some or all of classical assumptions were crucial for many of the derivations of the previous chapters. Derivation of the OLS estimator

More information

ECONOMICS 7200 MODERN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Econometric Theory and Applications

ECONOMICS 7200 MODERN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Econometric Theory and Applications ECONOMICS 7200 MODERN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Econometric Theory and Applications Yongmiao Hong Department of Economics & Department of Statistical Sciences Cornell University Spring 2019 Time and uncertainty

More information

Time Series Analysis. James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY

Time Series Analysis. James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY Time Series Analysis James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY PREFACE xiii 1 Difference Equations 1.1. First-Order Difference Equations 1 1.2. pth-order Difference Equations 7

More information

Prof. Dr. Roland Füss Lecture Series in Applied Econometrics Summer Term Introduction to Time Series Analysis

Prof. Dr. Roland Füss Lecture Series in Applied Econometrics Summer Term Introduction to Time Series Analysis Introduction to Time Series Analysis 1 Contents: I. Basics of Time Series Analysis... 4 I.1 Stationarity... 5 I.2 Autocorrelation Function... 9 I.3 Partial Autocorrelation Function (PACF)... 14 I.4 Transformation

More information

A time series is called strictly stationary if the joint distribution of every collection (Y t

A time series is called strictly stationary if the joint distribution of every collection (Y t 5 Time series A time series is a set of observations recorded over time. You can think for example at the GDP of a country over the years (or quarters) or the hourly measurements of temperature over a

More information

Cointegrated VARIMA models: specification and. simulation

Cointegrated VARIMA models: specification and. simulation Cointegrated VARIMA models: specification and simulation José L. Gallego and Carlos Díaz Universidad de Cantabria. Abstract In this note we show how specify cointegrated vector autoregressive-moving average

More information

Model-based trend-cycle decompositions. with time-varying parameters

Model-based trend-cycle decompositions. with time-varying parameters Model-based trend-cycle decompositions with time-varying parameters Siem Jan Koopman Kai Ming Lee Soon Yip Wong s.j.koopman@ klee@ s.wong@ feweb.vu.nl Department of Econometrics Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam

More information

Chapter 2. Dynamic panel data models

Chapter 2. Dynamic panel data models Chapter 2. Dynamic panel data models School of Economics and Management - University of Geneva Christophe Hurlin, Université of Orléans University of Orléans April 2018 C. Hurlin (University of Orléans)

More information

Detecting and forecasting business cycle turning points

Detecting and forecasting business cycle turning points MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Detecting and forecasting business cycle turning points Don Harding 23. September 2008 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/33583/ MPRA Paper No. 33583, posted 22.

More information

Vector Time-Series Models

Vector Time-Series Models T. Rothenberg Fall, 2007 1 Introduction Vector Time-Series Models The n-dimensional, mean-zero vector process fz t g is said to be weakly stationary if secondorder moments exist and only depend on time

More information

State-space Model. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. November Rossi State-space Model Fin. Econometrics / 53

State-space Model. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. November Rossi State-space Model Fin. Econometrics / 53 State-space Model Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia November 2014 Rossi State-space Model Fin. Econometrics - 2014 1 / 53 Outline 1 Motivation 2 Introduction 3 The Kalman filter 4 Forecast errors 5 State

More information

Econometric Forecasting

Econometric Forecasting Graham Elliott Econometric Forecasting Course Description We will review the theory of econometric forecasting with a view to understanding current research and methods. By econometric forecasting we mean

More information

Detecting and predicting recessions

Detecting and predicting recessions ISSN 1977-3331 EWP 2011/012 Euroindicators working papers Detecting and predicting recessions Don Harding This paper was presented at the 6th Eurostat Colloquium on Modern Tools for Business Cycle Analysis:

More information

Spectral Covariance Instability Test and Macroeconomic. Volatility Dynamics

Spectral Covariance Instability Test and Macroeconomic. Volatility Dynamics Spectral Covariance Instability Test and Macroeconomic Volatility Dynamics Roberto Pancrazi Toulouse School of Economics Toulouse, France roberto.pancrazi@tse-fr.eu First Draft: 29 October 2009 This Draft:

More information

Short-run electricity demand forecasts in Maharashtra

Short-run electricity demand forecasts in Maharashtra Applied Economics, 2002, 34, 1055±1059 Short-run electricity demand forecasts in Maharashtra SAJAL GHO SH* and AN JAN A D AS Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai, India This paper, has

More information

CENTRE FOR ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS

CENTRE FOR ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS CENTRE FOR ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS CEA@Cass http://www.cass.city.ac.uk/cea/index.html Cass Business School Faculty of Finance 106 Bunhill Row London EC1Y 8TZ A Note on Common Cycles, Common Trends and Convergence

More information

Stochastic process for macro

Stochastic process for macro Stochastic process for macro Tianxiao Zheng SAIF 1. Stochastic process The state of a system {X t } evolves probabilistically in time. The joint probability distribution is given by Pr(X t1, t 1 ; X t2,

More information

Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods

Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods Robert V. Breunig Centre for Economic Policy Research, Research School of Social Sciences and School of

More information

A spectral analysis of New Zealand output gaps using Fourier and wavelet techniques. June Discussion Paper Series

A spectral analysis of New Zealand output gaps using Fourier and wavelet techniques. June Discussion Paper Series DP/ A spectral analysis of New Zealand output gaps using Fourier and wavelet techniques Paul Conway * and David Frame ** June Discussion Paper Series Abstract 1 This paper uses frequency domain techniques

More information

Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo

Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo Karoll GOMEZ kgomezp@unal.edu.co http://karollgomez.wordpress.com Segundo semestre 2016 IX. Vector Time Series Models VARMA Models A. 1. Motivation: The vector

More information

On Enhanced Alternatives for the Hodrick-Prescott Filter

On Enhanced Alternatives for the Hodrick-Prescott Filter On Enhanced Alternatives for the Hodrick-Prescott Filter Marlon Fritz* Thomas Gries Yuanhua Feng Abstract The trend estimation for macroeconomic time series is crucial due to many different model specifications.

More information

1 Linear Difference Equations

1 Linear Difference Equations ARMA Handout Jialin Yu 1 Linear Difference Equations First order systems Let {ε t } t=1 denote an input sequence and {y t} t=1 sequence generated by denote an output y t = φy t 1 + ε t t = 1, 2,... with

More information

GMM Estimation with Noncausal Instruments

GMM Estimation with Noncausal Instruments ömmföäflsäafaäsflassflassflas ffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffff Discussion Papers GMM Estimation with Noncausal Instruments Markku Lanne University of Helsinki, RUESG and HECER and Pentti Saikkonen

More information

Dynamic probabilities of restrictions in state space models: An application to the New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Dynamic probabilities of restrictions in state space models: An application to the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Dynamic probabilities of restrictions in state space models: An application to the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Gary Koop Department of Economics University of Strathclyde Scotland Gary.Koop@strath.ac.uk

More information

Discussion of "Noisy News in Business Cycle" by Forni, Gambetti, Lippi, and Sala

Discussion of Noisy News in Business Cycle by Forni, Gambetti, Lippi, and Sala Judgement Discussion of Cycle" by Università degli Studi Milano - Bicocca IV International Conference in memory of Carlo Giannini Judgement Great contribution in the literature of NEWS and NOISE shocks:

More information

Modeling Expectations with Noncausal Autoregressions

Modeling Expectations with Noncausal Autoregressions Modeling Expectations with Noncausal Autoregressions Markku Lanne * Pentti Saikkonen ** Department of Economics Department of Mathematics and Statistics University of Helsinki University of Helsinki Abstract

More information

Evaluating Structural Vector Autoregression Models in Monetary Economies

Evaluating Structural Vector Autoregression Models in Monetary Economies Evaluating Structural Vector Autoregression Models in Monetary Economies Bin Li Research Department International Monetary Fund March 9 Abstract This paper uses Monte Carlo simulations to evaluate alternative

More information

Monetary Policy Transmission and the Phillips Curve in a Global Context

Monetary Policy Transmission and the Phillips Curve in a Global Context Kieler Arbeitspapiere Kiel Working Papers 1366 Monetary Policy Transmission and the Phillips Curve in a Global Context Ron Smith and M. Hashem Pesaran June 2007 This paper is part of the Kiel Working Paper

More information

at least 50 and preferably 100 observations should be available to build a proper model

at least 50 and preferably 100 observations should be available to build a proper model III Box-Jenkins Methods 1. Pros and Cons of ARIMA Forecasting a) need for data at least 50 and preferably 100 observations should be available to build a proper model used most frequently for hourly or

More information

Multivariate Time Series

Multivariate Time Series Multivariate Time Series Fall 2008 Environmental Econometrics (GR03) TSII Fall 2008 1 / 16 More on AR(1) In AR(1) model (Y t = µ + ρy t 1 + u t ) with ρ = 1, the series is said to have a unit root or a

More information