A utility function can generate Giffen behavior

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A utility function can generate Giffen behavior"

Transcription

1 A utility function can generate Giffen behavior Junko Doi Department of Economics, Kansai University Kazumichi Iwasa GSE, Kobe University December, 006 Koji Shimomura RIEB, Kobe University Abstract We present a specific utility function which generates Giffen behavior. The derived demand function of each good is not only continuous in its price and income but also partly increasing in its price and decreasing in income. Moreover, we show that Giffen behavior is compatible with any level of utility and an arbitrarily low share of income spent on the inferior good; thus the standard margarine-butter paradigm may not adequately explain Giffen s paradox. Acknowledgement Comments from Murray C. Kemp, Binh Tran- Nam, Masao Oda, Ngo Van Long, and Chiaki Hara have greatly improved the paper. We have also benefitted from the discussion with Koichi Hamada, Satya Das, Takashi Kamihigashi, Tomoyuki Kamo, Takeshi Nakatani, Kazuo Nishimura, Ken-Ichi Shimomura, and Stephen J. Turnovsky. Introduction Giffen s paradox is usually construed as a possible economic behavior acted by households with low real wealth levels. For a recent example, a standard textbook of microeconomic theory gives an intuitive explanation of Giffen behavior as follows: Low-quality goods may well be Giffen goods for consumers with low wealth levels. For example, imagine that a poor consumer initially is fulfilling much of his dietary requirements with potatoes because they are a low-cost way to avoid hunger. If the price of potatoes falls, he can then afford to buy other, more desirable foods Corresponding author:rieb, Kobe University, - Rokkodai-cho, Nada-ku, Kobe, , Japan:Tel: :Fax: ; simomura@rieb.kobe-u.ac.jp

2 that also keep him from being hungry. His consumption of potatoes may well fall as a result. Note that the mechanism that leads to potatoes being a Giffen good in this story involves a wealth consideration: When the price of potatoes falls, the consumer is effectively wealthier (he can afford to purchase more generally), and so he buys fewer potatoes...(mas-colell, Whinston, and Green, 995, p.6). The purpose of this paper is to give a theoretical example which clearly shows the existence of Giffen behavior to be distinguished from the standard interpretation. Specifically, we show that there exists a continuous, non-decreasing, quasi-concave utility function u = u(x, x ) which maps the two-dimensional positive orthant R++ onto the set of real numbers R such that it has the following properties. Property I For any given positive income I and prices of good and good, p ( p) and p ( ), the textbook utility maximization problem has a unique, positive and interior optimal consumption bundle; continuous demand functions, say x (p, I) and x (p, I), exist for any positive pair (p, I). That is, those functions map the set of price-income pairs which is equal to R ++ into the set of positive real numbers, R ++. Property II The set of price-income pairs, R ++, is decomposed into three mutually exclusive subsets, g, i, and n, i.e., R ++ = g i n and s t =, s, t = g, i, n, s t, as follows. (i) Good is a Giffen good [x (p, I) is increasing in p and decreasing in I over the interior of g ]; (ii) Good is an inferior good with negatively sloped demand curve [x (p, I) is decreasing in both p and I over the interior of i ]; (iii) Good is a normal good [x (p, I) is decreasing in p and increasing in I over the interior of n ]. Property III Define a set of positive pair (p, I) Ω(u) {(p, I) : u = u(x (p, I), x (p, I))} For any utility level u there are three nonempty subsets Ω g (u), Ω i (u), and Ω n (u) such that (i) x (p, I) is increasing in p and decreasing in I over the interior of Ω g (u); good is a Giffen good; (ii) x (p, I) is decreasing in both p and I over the interior of Ω i (u); good is an inferior good with negatively sloped demand curve; (iii) x (p, I) is decreasing in p and increasing in I over the interior of Ω n (u); good is a normal good. Property IV Denote a share of income spent on good by θ, that is, θ px (p, I)/I. There exist two upper bounds θ g and θ i such that (i) good is a Giffen good if and only if θ < θ g ; (ii) good is an inferior good if and only if θ < θ i ; (iii) θ g and θ i are independent of (p, I) and satisfy 0 < θ g < θ i. We emphasize that Property III means that Giffen behavior is possible, irrespective of the standard of living, and Property IV means that Giffen behavior is compatible with an arbitrarily low share of income spent on the inferior good,

3 not compatible with high share. So Giffen behavior under this utility function cannot be comprehended through the standard interpretation, and reveals the theoretical possibility such that it is inappropriate to presume Giffen s paradox merely an exceptional phenomenon under extreme circumstances. Let us briefly review the theoretical literature on Giffen s paradox. According to Weber (997), Wold and Jureen (953) are the first to present a specific utility function that generates Giffen behavior. Vandermeulen (97) and Spiegel (994) presented other specific utility functions that generate Giffen behavior. On the other hand, Moffatt (00) shows that for an arbitrarily given ( x, x ) there exists a strictly quasi-concave utility function which generates a backward sloping price offer curve around ( x, x ). However, all of those specific functions lack either some standard properties as a utility function or analytical tractability due to smooth demand functions. And none of preceding researchers fully characterizes the domain of the demand functions to the extent of Property II and Property III above. As we shall show in the subsequent sections, subsets χ, Ω χ (u), χ = g, i, n and the upper bounds θ g and θ i are explicitly derived. Based on Property II, for an arbitrarily given point on the two-dimensional positive commodity space, we can draw the income expansion path and the price offer curve (see Figure 3B in this paper) both of which intersect with each other at the point. Moreover, find that on each income expansion path, Giffen behavior is accompanied by an arbitrarily high level of utility and low expenditure share on the inferior good. Thus, we can examine an asymptotic behavior of the demand for a Giffen good, which is impossible without specifying utility functions as we propose. This paper is organized as follows. Section presents the specific utility function. Section 3 derives the demand functions of good and good from the utility function and proves Property I. Section 4 characterizes the demand functions and proves Property II, Property III, and Property IV. Section 5 concludes. The utility function. The definition and the main assumption Let Ϝ(x, x ) α ln x + β ln x γx x The utility function we consider is defined as { Ϝ(x, x ) for (x, x ) R+ Λ 0, u(x, x ) ln(α/γ) α x β α () α for (x, x ) Λ 0, Vandermeulen (97) also shows that expenditure shares are irrelevant to Giffen behavior, because it depends solely on the properties of the indifference map, that is, the slope of indifference curves along vertical lines. Indeed, none of preceding researchers does, because their specific functions lack global quasi-concavity or generate Giffen behavior only at a finite part of the commodity space. 3

4 where Λ 0 {(x, x ) > (0, 0) : x x α/γ}. Parameters, α, β, and γ, satisfy the following assumption. ASSUMPTION: β > α > β > 0 and γ > 0.. The properties () has all the standard properties as a utility function. First, both u(x, x ) and its partial derivatives with respect to x and x are continuous in (x, x ) over the domain, as stated in the following lemma. Lemma : For any ( x, x ) R ++, lim u(x, x ) = u( x, x ), () (x,x ) ( x, x ) lim u i(x, x ) = u i ( x, x ), (3) (x,x ) ( x, x ) where u i (x, x ) is the partial derivative of u(x, x ) with respect to x i, i =,. Proof. See Appendix. (QED) Second, we prove the following lemma, and then draw some indifference curves of the utility function (see Figure ). Note that the slope of any indifference curve is zero in Λ 0. Lemma : u(x, x ) is non-decreasing and quasi-concave in x and x over the domain R ++. Proof. In fact, the function () is concave in x and x : For any (x, x ) R + Λ 0, u (x, x ) = α x γx > 0, u (x, x ) = β x γx > 0, u (x, x ) x u(x, x ) = α x < 0, u (x, x ) x u(x, x ) = β x < 0, u (x, x ) u(x, x ) = γ < 0, x x 4

5 u u u u = αβ = x x γ [ ][ ] αβ αβ + γ γ x x x x > 0, ( α < αβ, due to ASSUMPTION) and for any (x, x ) Λ 0, u = u = u = 0, u = β α > 0, u = β α x x < 0 It follows that the utility function is quasi-concave over the commodity space R+ and strictly concave on the subset R+ Λ 0. (QED) Third, the utility level on its border, α = γx x, is ( ) ( ) α α α u, x = ln x β α α γx γ Due to ASSUMPTION (β > α), it is monotonically increasing in x along the hyperbola. Since lim u( ) α x 0 γx, x = and lim u( ) α x γx, x =, for any real number u there is (x, x ) in R++ such that u = u(x, x ). In a word, u(x, x ) is a mapping from R++ onto the set of real numbers R. Finally, considering that u(0, x ) = u(x, 0) =, we see that any indifference curve cuts neither horizontal nor vertical axis of coordinates; both goods are indispensable. 3 The derivation of the demand function 3. The utility maximization problem Let us show that for any positive price-income pair (p, I) the utility maximization problem, max u(x, I px ) (4) 0 x I/p has a unique, interior and positive optimal consumption pair (x (p, I), x (p, I)) in R ++ Λ 0. First of all, note that, depending on the values of p and I, we have two types of budget constraints. Let G(x ) α γx (I px ). Type budget constraints such that G(x ) > 0 for any x (0, I/p). An example is BEC in Figure. 5

6 Type budget constraints which are not of type ; that is, each type- budget contstraint satisfies the condition as follows An example is B E C in Figure. x (0, I/p) such that G(x ) 0 Let us derive the optimal consumption pair for each type. 3. Type- budget constraint Taking into account the definition of the utility function, we have Since u(x, I px ) = α ln x + β ln(i px ) γx (I px ) lim u(x, I px ) = lim u(x, I px ) =, x 0 x I/p there is an interior optimal solution to (4) which satisfies the first-order condition 3 d dx u(x, I px ) = α x βp = γ(i px ) I px ] [ p [ α x γ(i px ) β I px γx = 0 (5) To show the uniqueness of the optimal solution, let us prove the following lemma. Lemma 3: For any x (0, I/p) satisfying G( x ) > 0, the second derivative of u(x, I px ) with respect to x is negative, i.e., d u(x, I px ) < 0 (6) x= x dx ] Proof. See Appendix. (QED) 3 d Note that u(.) denotes the total derivative of u(.) with respect to x dx. Letting x = I px, we have the frollowing identity. d dx u(x, x ) = = u(x, x ) + u(x, x ) dx x x dx u(x, I px ) p u(x, I px ) x x 6

7 Lemma 3 implies that the second-order condition holds, and that the optimal solution to the maximization problem (4) is uniquely determined by the firstorder condition for any given positive pair (p, I) which generates a type- budget constraint. Note that the first-order condition (5) can be rewritten to the standard (price) = (the marginal rate of substitution) condition, p = (I px )[α γx (I px )] x [β γx (I px )] (7) Point E in Figure is the unique optimal solution corresponding to a type- budget constraint BEC. The point satisfies (7). 3.3 Type- budget constraint We find from the definition of G(x ) that G(0) = G(I/p) = α, G (0) = γi < 0, and G (I/p) = γi > 0. Thus, there exist x and ˆx such that and 0 < x < ˆx < I/p G(x ) > 0 for x (0, x ) (ˆx, I/p), G(x ) < 0 for x ( x, ˆx ), G(x ) = 0 for x = x, ˆx Based on this sign pattern of G(x ) and Lemma which implies that not only u(x, I px ) but also the first derivative d dx u(x, I px ) are continuous in x (0, I/p), we are now at the position to prove the unique existence of the optimal solution to the maximization problem (4) for any given type- budget constraint. First, it follows from (5) that there exists ε > 0 such that the first derivative, d dx u(x, I px ), is positive for any x (0, ε ). Second, it is also clear from (5) that the first derivative is negative at x and ˆx. In fact, we can find that the first derivative is always negative in the interval ( x, ˆx ). Third, Lemma 3 d ensures us that dx u(x, I px ) is negative for any x > ˆx as well. Since Lemma 3 also holds for the interval (0, x ), we can conclude that the graph of u(x, I px ) is bell-shaped with the single peak between 0 and x, where the first-order condition d u(x, I px ) = 0 dx is established. Point E in Figure is an example of the optimal solution. 7

8 3.4 The first main proposition Based on the foregoing argument, we can assert that, whether the budget constraint is of type or type, the optimal solution is uniquely determined and continuous in p and I. We now derive the first result of this paper. PROPOSITION (Property I): For any given positive income I and prices of good and good, p ( p) and p ( ), the textbook utility maximization problem has a unique, positive, and interior optimal consumption bundle. That is, the demand functions x (p, I) > 0 and x (p, I) I px (p, I) > 0 are defined for any positive pair (p, I). Moreover the demand functions are continuous in p and I. 4 Properties of the demand functions To characterize the demand functions, x (p, I) and x (p, I), we focus on the budget constraint and the equality between the price and the marginal rate of substitution (7). I = px + x, (8) 0 = (β z)px (α z)x, (9) where z γx x. 4 Solving this system of equations for x and x, we obtain x = x = (α z)i p(α + β z), (0) (β z)i α + β z () Combining (0) and (), we have p (α z)(β z) = Ψ(z) () γi z(α + β z) Figure depicts the graph of Ψ(z). As is clear from lim Ψ(z) =, Ψ(α) = 0, (3) z 0+ and Ψ (z)z Ψ(z) [ z(α β) ] = + < for any z (0, α), (4) (α z)(β z)(α + β z) 4 As shown in the preceding section, for any (p, I) the optimal consumption pair (x, x ) exists in R ++ Λ 0, therefore, z (0, α). 8

9 z is uniquely determined for any positive m p/γi. Let us denote the inverse function of Ψ by z(m). It follows from (3) and (4) that lim z(m) = 0, z(0) = α, m and z (m)m z(m) = [ z(m)(α β) ] + (α z(m))(β z(m))(α + β z(m)) (, 0) for any m > 0 (5) Making use of (0), () and the inverse function, we can express the demand functions as I ( α z ( )) p γi x (p, I) = p ( α + β z ( p )), (6) γi I ( β z ( )) p γi x (p, I) = α + β z ( ) p (7) γi In what follows, we shall use these expressions Comparative statics Now that we obtain the demand functions, we shall check how the demand for x (p, I) and x (p, I) may depend on p and I. 4.. Price effects First, the demand for good has a distinctive feature such that the sign of x (p, I)/ depends solely on the value of z(m), as proved in the following lemma. Lemma 4.: For any given price-income pair, (i) x (p, I)/ is negative if z(p/γi ) ( 0, β β(β α)/ ) ; (ii) x (p, I)/ is positive if z(p/γi ) ( β β(β α)/, α ). Proof. The logarithmic differentiation of x (p, I) with respect to p yields p x (p, I) x (p, I) z(m)(α β) = + (α z(m))(α + β z(m)) z (m)m z(m) 5 Needless to say, from the definition of z(.) the equality z(p/γi ) = γx (p, I)x (p, I) holds. 9

10 Making use of (5), we derive p x (p, I) x (p, I) [ { }] { }] (z(m) α) z(m) β [z(m) β(β α) β + β(β α) = z(m)(α β), + (α z(m))(β z(m))(α + β z(m)) (8) where the denominator is positive, due to β > α > z(m). Let us denote the numerator as [ { { }] Ξ(z(m)) (z(m) α) z(m) β }][z(m) β(β α) β + β(β α) It is clear that Ξ(0) = αβ(α + β) < 0. Further, we see that the inequality α > β β(β α) holds, due to ASSUMPTION. 6 Considering that Ξ(0) < 0, we derive ( Ξ(z(m)) < 0 for z(m) 0, β ( Ξ(z(m)) > 0 for z(m) β ), β(β α) ), β(β α), α and (8) implies [ ] x (p, I) sign [ ( ( p ))] = sign Ξ z γi Therefore, Lemma 4. is established. (QED) Second, let us partially differentiate x (p, I) with respect to p. We obtain, from the partial differentiation of (7), x (p, I) = (β α)z (m) γi(α + β z(m)) < 0 6 (β α) p β(β α)/ < 0 holds for» q» q (β α) β(β α) (β α) + β(β α) = (β α) β(β α) «β = (β α) α, which is negative due to ASSUMPTION. 0

11 Finally, since z(.) is the inverse function of Ψ(.), from Lemma 4. we obtain the following result. PROPOSITION. (Property II): (i) If a pair (p, I) satisfies Ψ Ψ ( β β(β α)/ ) < p/γi, then x (p, I)/ is negative at the pair; (ii) If they satisfy Ψ > p/γi > 0, then x (p, I)/ is positive at the pair; good is a Giffen good at the price and income levels; (iii) x (p, I)/ is always negative. 4.. Income effects Next, let us check income effects on the demand for good and good. Similarly to the case of price effects, we first derive the following lemma. Lemma 4.: For any given price-income pair, (i) x (p, I)/ I is positive if z(p/γi ) ( 0, β β(β α) ) ; (ii) x (p, I)/ I is negative if z(p/γi ) ( β β(β α), α ). Proof. See Appendix. (QED) Second, let us partially differentiate x (p, I) with respect to I. We obtain, from the partial differentiation of (7), x (p, I) I = β z(m) α + β z(m) p(β α)z (m) γi (α + β z(m)) > 0 From Lemma 4. we have the following result. PROPOSITION. (Property II): (i) If a pair (p, I) satisfies Ψ Ψ ( β β(β α) ) < p/γi, then x (p, I)/ I is positive at the pair; good is a normal good at the pair; (ii) If they satisfy Ψ > p/γi > 0, then x (p, I)/ I is negative at the pair; good is an inferior good at the pair; (iii) x (p, I)/ I is always positive The diagrammatic explanation of the comparative static analysis Let us diagrammatically explain PROPOSITIONS. and., and then depict the income expansion path and the price offer curve. See Figure 3A, where the horizontal and vertical axes of coordinates measure p and I, respectively; curve OGC and OAH are two quadratic curves Ψ = p/γi and Ψ = p/γi. The propositions above mean that (i) good is a Giffen good at (p, I) in Region I, (ii) good is an inferior good with negatively sloped demand curve at (p, I) in Region II, and good is a normal good at (p, I) in Region III. The signs of x (p, I)/ and x (p, I)/ I depends on whether the value z = γx (p, I)x (p, I), which is uniquely determined by p/γi, is greater or smaller than β β(β α)/ and β β(β α) (Lemma 4. and 4.). Thus,

12 as is shown in Figure 3B, the commodity space (x, x ) > (0, 0) is divided by three hyperbolas; γx x = α, γx x = β β(β α), γx x = β β(β α) Regions I, II, and III in Figure 3B correspond to Region I, II, and III in Figure 3A, respectively. Take any positive point in the commodity space, say (x e, x e ). There is an indifference curve and its tangent line at point e; the latter line is expressed as u (x e, x e ) u (x e, xe )x + x = u (x e, x e ) u (x e, xe )xe + x e (x e, x e ) is the solution to the maximization problem (4) if the price is p E u (x e,xe ) u (x e,xe ) and the income is IE u (x e,xe ) u (x e,xe )xe + x e ; we have x e = x (p E, I E ) and x e = x (p E, I E ). For example, suppose that point e is in Region II in Figure 3B. Then p E /γ(i E ) is in between Ψ and Ψ ; point (p E, I E ) has to be in Region II in Figure 3A, in which case good is an inferior good with negatively sloped demand curve at (p E, I E ), i.e., both x (p E, I E )/ and x (p E, I E )/ I are negative. By this correspondence, points in Figures 3A and 3B have an one-toone relationship Income expansion path and price offer curve 7 Based on the foregoing argument, we can draw the income expansion path and the price offer curve both of which commonly cross a point, say E, in Figure 3A. Point E in Figure 3A corresponds to point e in Figure 3B, and so does the vertical line BAECD in Figure 3A to the income expansion path baecd in Figure 3B and the horizontal line JHEGF in Figure 3A to the price offer curve jhegf in Figure 3B. The income expansion path and the price offer curve bend when they cross the hyperbolas β β(β α) = γx x and β β(β α)/ = γx x, respectively. One can also verify that the Engel curve of good is bell-shaped. Moving up along the vertical line BAECD in Figure 3A, the ratio p/γi monotonically declines, which means that z(p/γi ) (= γx (p, I)x (p, I)) monotonically rises. The path goes up between the hyperbola α = γx x and the vertical axis of coordinates. On the other hand, moving to the right direction along the horizontal line F GEHJ in Figure 3A, the ratio p/γi monotonically rise, which means that z(p/γi ) (= γx (p, I)x (p, I)) monotonically decreases. The price offer curve converges a point on the vertical axis of coordinates, say j in Figure 3B. Note that, because of (7), lim x = Iβ/(α + β). z(p/γi ) 0 7 The definitions of income expansion path and price offer curve are given in standard textbooks of micro eocnomic theory. For example, see Varian (99, pp.6-8).

13 4..5 The independency of Giffen behavior from living standard For an arbitrarily chosen hyperbola ζ = γx x (0 < ζ α), the utility level on it is given by ( ) ( ) α ζ ζ u, x = ln x β α ζ, (9) γx γ which is monotonously increase from to +, as x increase from 0 to +. Therefore, any indifference curve crosses the hyperbola ζ = γx x, which obviously means it has to cross the two border curves β β(β α) = γx x and β β(β α)/ = γx x. Based on this fact, we derive the following result. PROPOSITION 3 (Property III): Define a set of positive pair (p, I) Ω(u) {(p, I) : u = u(x (p, I), x (p, I))} For any utility level u there are three nonempty subsets Ω g (u), Ω i (u), and Ω n (u) such that (i) for any (p, I) Ω g (u) x (p, I) > 0 and x (p, I) I < 0; (0) good is a Giffen good at (p, I) Ω g (u); (ii) for any (p, I) Ω i (u) x (p, I) < 0 and x (p, I) I < 0; () good is an inferior good with negatively sloped demand curve at (p, I) Ω i (u); (iii) for any (p, I) Ω n (u) x (p, I) < 0 and good is a normal good at (p, I) Ω n (u). x (p, I) I > 0; () Proof: See Figure 4A, where a awns is an arbitrarily chosen indifference curve. As we proved just before the statement of PROPOSITION 3, the curve has to cross the two border hyperbolas at w and n. Corresponding to the indifference curve awns in Figure 4A, we can derive the curve AW NS in Figure 4B; points w and n in Figure 4A correspond to points W and N in Figure 4B, respectively. As is clear from what we have showed so far, good is a Giffen good when (x (p, I), x (p, I)) is on aw, an inferior good with negatively sloped demand curve when it is on wn, and a normal good when it is on ns. Therefore, we can define Ω g (u), Ω i (u), and Ω n (u) as follows. Ω g (u) = {(p, I) : (p, I) is on AW in Figure 4B} Ω i (u) = {(p, I) : (p, I) is on W N in Figure 4B} Ω n (u) = {(p, I) : (p, I) is on NS in Figure 4B} (QED) 3

14 REMARK: Formally, the curve AW NS in Figure 4B is expressed as follows. Let x = ς(x ; u) be an indifference curve with the utility level u. Then, the corresponding p and I is expressed as p(x ) I(x ) ( ς(v; u) v ς(v; u) v v=x v=x ) x + ς(x ; u) Any point on the curve AW NS in Figure 4B is expressed as (p(x ), I(x )). For example, point A is (p(x a ), I(x a )) where p(x a ) = 0. Similarly, point W and point N are (p(x w ), I(x w )) and (p(x n ), I(x n )), respectively The expenditure share on a Giffen good Suppose that the consumption pair (x, x ) is optimally chosen for a given (p, I), then from (8) and (9), the share of income spent on good is px I = = (α z)x (β z)x x (α z)x (β z)x x + x α z α + β z α z Let ϑ(z) α+β z, then ϑ(z) ( ) α 0, α + β and ϑ (z) = Based on the above, we obtain the following result. α β < 0 for z (0, α) (3) (α + β z) PROPOSITION 4 (Property IV): Denote a share of income spent on good by θ, that is, θ px (p, I)/I. There exist the following relations between the property of demand for good and θ. (i) Good is a Giffen good if θ (0, θ g ); (ii) Good is an inferior good with negatively sloped demand curve if θ (θ g, θ i ); (iii) Good is a normal good if θ ( ) α θ i, α+β, where θg and θ i are defined as follows. θ g α β + β(β α) α β + β(β α), θ i α β + β(β α) α β + β(β α) 4

15 Proof: Considering the fact that for any (p, I) the expenditure share on good is given by ϑ(z(p/γi )), from (3), Lemma 4., and 4., we can conclude x (p, I) x (p, I) x (p, I) > 0 and < 0 and < 0 and x (p, I) < 0 I ( ( if θ ϑ(α), ϑ β x (p, I) < 0 I ( ( if θ ϑ β β(β α) )), β(β α) ), ϑ ( β β(β α) )), x (p, I) > 0 I ( if θ ϑ ( β β(β α) ) ), ϑ(0), where ϑ(α) = 0, ϑ ( β β(β α)/ ) = θ g, ϑ ( β β(β α) ) = θ i, and ϑ(0) = α/(α + β). (QED) Let us consider the change along an income expansion path. As households income I goes up, which means z(p/γi ) monotonously rises, the expenditure share on good monotonously declines, but at the same time good becomes a Giffen good. However low the expenditure share on good becomes, it remains to be a Giffen good. 5 Concluding remarks In this paper we have proposed a specific but standard utility function under which one good can be an inferior good or even a Giffen good. We show that Giffen behavior generated from the utility function is compatible with an arbitrarily high level of utility and low share of income spent on the inferior good. Thus, this behavior is clearly to be discriminated from the textbook margarine-butter paradigm, so the theoretical possibility emerges such that it is inappropriate to presume Giffen s paradox merely an exceptional phenomenon under extreme circumstances. Finally let us make a couple of technical remarks on the utility function we proposed in this paper. First, we can slightly modify the utility function in such a way that it becomes increasing and strictly quasi-concave in good and good. See Figure 5. The curve ABCD is an arbitrarily chosen indifference curve of the utility function. Choose a small positive number ε that satisfies α [ β β(β α)/ ] > ε. We can draw a curve BF G such that (i) it is tangent to the original indifference curve at B, (ii) it is a convex curve, and (iii) it asymptotically converge to the horizontal part of the original indifference curve ABCD. Define ABF G as a modified indifference curve. Making such 5

16 modification to each indifference curve, we can derive a modified utility function which is increasing and strictly quasi-concave in good and good. Second, one may wonder whether there is a family of utility functions that has the same properties as (). The answer is affirmative. The following utility function does. u(x, x ) α σ (x σ ) + βσ σ [ ( ) ] σ β γ α γ σ σ (x ) γx x for x σ x α/γ, σ σ x σ σ + α βσ σ for x σ x > α/γ, where we assume that all parameters, α, β, γ, and σ, are positive and satisfy ( ) /σ β γ < α γ < β γ. We can check that, as σ, this function converges to (). Appendix Proof of Lemma. Trivial from the definition if α γ x x. Let us focus on any point of the hyperbola α = γ x x. It suffices to prove. lim Ϝ(x β α, x ) = ln(α/γ) α x α { = u( x, x ) } (x,x ) ( x, x ). lim (x,x ) ( x, x ) Ϝ (x, x ) = 0 3. lim (x,x ) ( x, x ) Ϝ (x, x ) = β α x { [ = x ln(α/γ) α x β α α ] } (x,x )=( x, x ) { [ = x ln(α/γ) α x β α α ] } (x,x )=( x, x ) where Ϝ i (x, x ) is the partial derivative of Ϝ(x, x ) with respect to x i, i =,. Let us prove here. The others can be proved in a similar way. Since Ϝ(x, x ) [ β α ln(α/γ) α x α ] = α ln x + β ln x γx x = α ln γx x α [ α ln + β ln x x (γx x α), α ] + β ln x α γ x it is apparent from the continuity of γx x that for any δ > 0 there is some ɛ > 0 such that max { x x, x x } < ɛ Ϝ(x, x ) [ β α ln(α/γ) α x α ] < δ Therefore, is established. (QED) 6

17 Proof of Lemma 3. Considering (5), the differentiation of the first derivative at x yields d u(x, I px ) dx x= x [ βp = (I p x ) γp + α x ] [ p = β (I p x ) γ ] β (I p x ) (I p x ) [ ] βα β x (I p x ) γ Here the term [ βα γ ] is positive if G( x x ) = α γ x (I p x ) > 0 and (I p x) x (0, I/p). For, [ βα βα x (I p x ) γ x = + γ(i p x ) ][ βα x γ(i p x ) ] (I p x ) > > 0, [ βα x + γ(i p x ) ][ α x γ(i p x ) ] (I p x ) where the first inequality comes from α < βα ( ASSUMPTION) and the second inequality is due to G( x ) > 0. Therefore, (6) is established for any x (0, I/p) if G( x ) > 0. (QED) Proof of Lemma 4. The logarithmic differentiation of x (p, I) with respect to I yields Let I x (p, I) x (p, I) I z(m)(β α) = + (α z(m))(α + β z(m)) z (m)m z(m) z(m)(β α)(β z(m)) = z(m)(α β) + (α z(m))(β z(m))(α + β z(m)) [ ] αβ βz(m) + z(m) (α + β z(m)) = [ z(m)(α β) + (α z(m))(β z(m))(α + β z(m)) ] Φ(z(m)) αβ βz(m) + z(m) The sign of x (p, I)/ I is equal to the one of Φ(z(m)). Since Φ(0) = αβ > 0 and Φ(α) = α(β α) < 0, we derive [ ] [ x (p, I) ( ( p ))] sign = sign Φ z I γi > 0 ( p ) if z γi is in the interval ( 0, β β(β α) ) 7

18 and [ ] [ x (p, I) ( ( p ))] sign = sign Φ z I γi < 0 ( p ) if z γi is in the interval ( β β(β α), α ) Therefore, Lemma 4. is established. (QED) References [] Doi, J., K. Iwasa, and K. Shimomura, 006, A note on Giffen goods, Kobe University. [] Mas-Collel, A., M. D. Whinston, and J. R. Green, 995, Microeconomic Theory, Oxford: Oxford University Press. [3] Moffatt, P. G., 00, Is Giffen behavior compatible with the axioms of consumer theory?, Journal of Mathematical Economics 37, [4] Spiegel, U., 994, The case of a Giffen good, Journal of Economic Education 5, [5] Vandermeulen, D. C., 97, Upward sloping demand curve without the Giffen paradox, American Economic Review 7, [6] Varian, H., 99, Microeconomic Analysis, 3rd edition, New York: W.W. Norton & Company. [7] Weber, C. E., 997, The case of a Giffen good: comment, Journal of Economic Education 8, [8] Wold, H. and L. Jureen, 953, Demand Analysis, New York: John Wiley. 8

The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics

The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics Topics Volume 9, Issue 1 2009 Article 43 Simple Economies with Multiple Equilibria Theodore C. Bergstrom Ken-Ichi Shimomura Takehiko Yamato University of California,

More information

Chapter 1 - Preference and choice

Chapter 1 - Preference and choice http://selod.ensae.net/m1 Paris School of Economics (selod@ens.fr) September 27, 2007 Notations Consider an individual (agent) facing a choice set X. Definition (Choice set, "Consumption set") X is a set

More information

Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais

Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais Microeconomics Fall 2016 Primitive notions There are four building blocks in any model of consumer choice. They are the consumption set, the feasible set, the preference relation, and the behavioural assumption.

More information

Preferences and Utility

Preferences and Utility Preferences and Utility How can we formally describe an individual s preference for different amounts of a good? How can we represent his preference for a particular list of goods (a bundle) over another?

More information

Week 6: Consumer Theory Part 1 (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 1)

Week 6: Consumer Theory Part 1 (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 1) Week 6: Consumer Theory Part 1 (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 1) Tsun-Feng Chiang* *School of Economics, Henan University, Kaifeng, China November 2, 2014 1 / 28 Primitive Notions 1.1 Primitive Notions Consumer

More information

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction Microeconomic Theory -- Introduction. Introduction. Profit maximizing firm with monopoly power 6 3. General results on maximizing with two variables 8 4. Model of a private ownership economy 5. Consumer

More information

Microeconomics II Lecture 4. Marshallian and Hicksian demands for goods with an endowment (Labour supply)

Microeconomics II Lecture 4. Marshallian and Hicksian demands for goods with an endowment (Labour supply) Leonardo Felli 30 October, 2002 Microeconomics II Lecture 4 Marshallian and Hicksian demands for goods with an endowment (Labour supply) Define M = m + p ω to be the endowment of the consumer. The Marshallian

More information

Midterm #1 EconS 527 Wednesday, February 21st, 2018

Midterm #1 EconS 527 Wednesday, February 21st, 2018 NAME: Midterm #1 EconS 527 Wednesday, February 21st, 2018 Instructions. Show all your work clearly and make sure you justify all your answers. 1. Question 1 [10 Points]. Discuss and provide examples of

More information

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

September Math Course: First Order Derivative September Math Course: First Order Derivative Arina Nikandrova Functions Function y = f (x), where x is either be a scalar or a vector of several variables (x,..., x n ), can be thought of as a rule which

More information

GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 1 September Q1. Are the preferences described below transitive? Strictly monotonic? Convex?

GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 1 September Q1. Are the preferences described below transitive? Strictly monotonic? Convex? GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 1 September 2011 Q1. Are the preferences described below transitive? Strictly monotonic? Convex? Explain briefly. The person consumes 2 goods, food and clothing.

More information

On the (Non-)Differentiability of the Optimal Value Function When the Optimal Solution Is Unique

On the (Non-)Differentiability of the Optimal Value Function When the Optimal Solution Is Unique On the (Non-)Differentiability of the Optimal Value Function When the Optimal Solution Is Unique Daisuke Oyama Faculty of Economics, University of Tokyo Hongo, Bunkyo-ku, Tokyo 113-0033, Japan oyama@e.u-tokyo.ac.jp

More information

Monotone Function. Function f is called monotonically increasing, if. x 1 x 2 f (x 1 ) f (x 2 ) x 1 < x 2 f (x 1 ) < f (x 2 ) x 1 x 2

Monotone Function. Function f is called monotonically increasing, if. x 1 x 2 f (x 1 ) f (x 2 ) x 1 < x 2 f (x 1 ) < f (x 2 ) x 1 x 2 Monotone Function Function f is called monotonically increasing, if Chapter 3 x x 2 f (x ) f (x 2 ) It is called strictly monotonically increasing, if f (x 2) f (x ) Convex and Concave x < x 2 f (x )

More information

Recitation #2 (August 31st, 2018)

Recitation #2 (August 31st, 2018) Recitation #2 (August 1st, 2018) 1. [Checking properties of the Cobb-Douglas utility function.] Consider the utility function u(x) = n i=1 xα i i, where x denotes a vector of n different goods x R n +,

More information

Notes on Consumer Theory

Notes on Consumer Theory Notes on Consumer Theory Alejandro Saporiti Alejandro Saporiti (Copyright) Consumer Theory 1 / 65 Consumer theory Reference: Jehle and Reny, Advanced Microeconomic Theory, 3rd ed., Pearson 2011: Ch. 1.

More information

Chapter 13. Convex and Concave. Josef Leydold Mathematical Methods WS 2018/19 13 Convex and Concave 1 / 44

Chapter 13. Convex and Concave. Josef Leydold Mathematical Methods WS 2018/19 13 Convex and Concave 1 / 44 Chapter 13 Convex and Concave Josef Leydold Mathematical Methods WS 2018/19 13 Convex and Concave 1 / 44 Monotone Function Function f is called monotonically increasing, if x 1 x 2 f (x 1 ) f (x 2 ) It

More information

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7 Mathematical Foundations -- Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization An intuitive approach First Order Conditions (FOC) 7 Constraint qualifications 9 Formal statement of the FOC for a maximum

More information

Applications I: consumer theory

Applications I: consumer theory Applications I: consumer theory Lecture note 8 Outline 1. Preferences to utility 2. Utility to demand 3. Fully worked example 1 From preferences to utility The preference ordering We start by assuming

More information

The Law of Demand versus Diminishing Marginal Utility

The Law of Demand versus Diminishing Marginal Utility Review of Agricultural Economics Volume 28, Number 2 Pages 263 271 DOI:10.1111/j.1467-9353.2006.00286.x The Law of Demand versus Diminishing Marginal Utility Bruce R. Beattie and Jeffrey T. LaFrance Diminishing

More information

Utility Maximization Problem. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 2

Utility Maximization Problem. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 2 Demand Theory Utility Maximization Problem Advanced Microeconomic Theory 2 Utility Maximization Problem Consumer maximizes his utility level by selecting a bundle x (where x can be a vector) subject to

More information

Week 9: Topics in Consumer Theory (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 2)

Week 9: Topics in Consumer Theory (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 2) Week 9: Topics in Consumer Theory (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 2) Tsun-Feng Chiang *School of Economics, Henan University, Kaifeng, China November 15, 2015 Microeconomic Theory Week 9: Topics in Consumer Theory

More information

Final Exam - Math Camp August 27, 2014

Final Exam - Math Camp August 27, 2014 Final Exam - Math Camp August 27, 2014 You will have three hours to complete this exam. Please write your solution to question one in blue book 1 and your solutions to the subsequent questions in blue

More information

Technical Results on Regular Preferences and Demand

Technical Results on Regular Preferences and Demand Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Technical Results on Regular Preferences and Demand KC Border Revised Fall 2011; Winter 2017 Preferences For the purposes of this note, a preference relation

More information

Last Revised: :19: (Fri, 12 Jan 2007)(Revision:

Last Revised: :19: (Fri, 12 Jan 2007)(Revision: 0-0 1 Demand Lecture Last Revised: 2007-01-12 16:19:03-0800 (Fri, 12 Jan 2007)(Revision: 67) a demand correspondence is a special kind of choice correspondence where the set of alternatives is X = { x

More information

Problem Set 1 Welfare Economics

Problem Set 1 Welfare Economics Problem Set 1 Welfare Economics Solutions 1. Consider a pure exchange economy with two goods, h = 1,, and two consumers, i =1,, with utility functions u 1 and u respectively, and total endowment, e = (e

More information

Single Peakedness and Giffen Demand

Single Peakedness and Giffen Demand Single Peakedness and Giffen Demand Massimiliano Landi January 2012 Paper No. 02-2012 ANY OPINIONS EXPRESSED ARE THOSE OF THE AUTHOR(S) AND NOT NECESSARILY THOSE OF THE SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS, SMU Single

More information

Utility Maximization Problem

Utility Maximization Problem Demand Theory Utility Maximization Problem Consumer maximizes his utility level by selecting a bundle x (where x can be a vector) subject to his budget constraint: max x 0 u(x) s. t. p x w Weierstrass

More information

Unlinked Allocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One Bad

Unlinked Allocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One Bad Unlinked llocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One ad Chiaki Hara Faculty of Economics and Politics, University of Cambridge Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University pril 16,

More information

Risk Aversion over Incomes and Risk Aversion over Commodities. By Juan E. Martinez-Legaz and John K.-H. Quah 1

Risk Aversion over Incomes and Risk Aversion over Commodities. By Juan E. Martinez-Legaz and John K.-H. Quah 1 Risk Aversion over Incomes and Risk Aversion over Commodities By Juan E. Martinez-Legaz and John K.-H. Quah 1 Abstract: This note determines the precise connection between an agent s attitude towards income

More information

Microeconomics II. MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3

Microeconomics II. MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3 Microeconomics II MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3 Problem 1 Consider an economy 1 1, with one firm (or technology and one consumer (firm owner, as in the textbook (MWG section 15.C. The set of

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 2: Demand Theory

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 2: Demand Theory Advanced Microeconomic Theory Chapter 2: Demand Theory Outline Utility maximization problem (UMP) Walrasian demand and indirect utility function WARP and Walrasian demand Income and substitution effects

More information

x 1 1 and p 1 1 Two points if you just talk about monotonicity (u (c) > 0).

x 1 1 and p 1 1 Two points if you just talk about monotonicity (u (c) > 0). . (a) (8 points) What does it mean for observations x and p... x T and p T to be rationalized by a monotone utility function? Notice that this is a one good economy. For all t, p t x t function. p t x

More information

CONSUMER DEMAND. Consumer Demand

CONSUMER DEMAND. Consumer Demand CONSUMER DEMAND KENNETH R. DRIESSEL Consumer Demand The most basic unit in microeconomics is the consumer. In this section we discuss the consumer optimization problem: The consumer has limited wealth

More information

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions.

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions. Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 3: Optimization - interior optima 1 Session: 11-12 Aug 2015 (Thu/Fri) 10:00am 1:00pm I. Optimization: introduction Decision-makers (e.g. consumers,

More information

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 4, September 7 Outline 1 Structural Properties of Utility Functions 1 Local Non Satiation 2 Convexity 3 Quasi-linearity

More information

i) This is simply an application of Berge s Maximum Theorem, but it is actually not too difficult to prove the result directly.

i) This is simply an application of Berge s Maximum Theorem, but it is actually not too difficult to prove the result directly. Bocconi University PhD in Economics - Microeconomics I Prof. M. Messner Problem Set 3 - Solution Problem 1: i) This is simply an application of Berge s Maximum Theorem, but it is actually not too difficult

More information

UC Berkeley CUDARE Working Papers

UC Berkeley CUDARE Working Papers UC Berkeley CUDARE Working Papers Title The Law of Demand Versus Diminishing Marginal Utility Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/ks565h0 Authors Beattie, Bruce R. LaFrance, Jeffrey T. Publication

More information

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Chiaki Hara April 5, 2004 Abstract We give a theorem on the existence of an equilibrium price vector for an excess

More information

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 6, September 14 Outline 1 Applications of Envelope Theorem 2 Hicksian Demand 3 Duality 4 Connections between

More information

ANSWER KEY. University of California, Davis Date: June 22, 2015

ANSWER KEY. University of California, Davis Date: June 22, 2015 ANSWER KEY University of California, Davis Date: June, 05 Department of Economics Time: 5 hours Microeconomic Theory Reading Time: 0 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Please answer four

More information

Chapter 1 Consumer Theory Part II

Chapter 1 Consumer Theory Part II Chapter 1 Consumer Theory Part II Economics 5113 Microeconomic Theory Kam Yu Winter 2018 Outline 1 Introduction to Duality Theory Indirect Utility and Expenditure Functions Ordinary and Compensated Demand

More information

Consumer theory Topics in consumer theory. Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais

Consumer theory Topics in consumer theory. Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais Microeconomics Fall 2016 Indirect utility and expenditure Properties of consumer demand The indirect utility function The relationship among prices, incomes, and the maximised value of utility can be summarised

More information

CHAPTER 3: OPTIMIZATION

CHAPTER 3: OPTIMIZATION John Riley 8 February 7 CHAPTER 3: OPTIMIZATION 3. TWO VARIABLES 8 Second Order Conditions Implicit Function Theorem 3. UNCONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION 4 Necessary and Sufficient Conditions 3.3 CONSTRAINED

More information

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Midterm Suggested Solutions 2/8/ (a) The equation of the indifference curve is given by,

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Midterm Suggested Solutions 2/8/ (a) The equation of the indifference curve is given by, Dirk Bergemann Department of Economics Yale University Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Midterm Suggested Solutions 2/8/12 1. (a) The equation of the indifference curve is given by, (x 1 + 2)

More information

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers The Ohio State University Department of Economics Econ. 805 Winter 00 Prof. James Peck Homework Set Questions and Answers. Consider the following pure exchange economy with two consumers and two goods.

More information

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework. Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework. Economy: I consumers, i = 1,...I. J firms, j = 1,...J. L goods, l = 1,...L Initial Endowment of good l in the economy: ω l 0, l = 1,...L. Consumer i : preferences

More information

Multiple Interior Steady States in the Ramsey Model with Elastic Labor Supply

Multiple Interior Steady States in the Ramsey Model with Elastic Labor Supply Multiple Interior Steady States in the Ramsey Model with Elastic Labor Supply Takashi Kamihigashi March 18, 2014 Abstract In this paper we show that multiple interior steady states are possible in the

More information

Dynamic Three-Factor Models of International Trade *

Dynamic Three-Factor Models of International Trade * Dynamic Three-Factor Models of International Trade * Yunfang Hu a#, Kazuo Nishimura b, and Koji Shimomura c a Graduate School of Economics, Kobe University b Institute of Economic Research, Kyoto University

More information

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018 EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 018 Show all your work clearly and make sure you justify all your answers. NAME 1. Consider the market for smart pencil in which only one firm (Superapiz) enjoys a

More information

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP Prof. Olivier Bochet Room A.34 Phone 3 63 476 E-mail olivier.bochet@vwi.unibe.ch Webpage http//sta.vwi.unibe.ch/bochet Advanced Microeconomics Fall 2 Lecture Note Choice-Based Approach Price e ects, Wealth

More information

Notes I Classical Demand Theory: Review of Important Concepts

Notes I Classical Demand Theory: Review of Important Concepts Notes I Classical Demand Theory: Review of Important Concepts The notes for our course are based on: Mas-Colell, A., M.D. Whinston and J.R. Green (1995), Microeconomic Theory, New York and Oxford: Oxford

More information

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution)

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution) Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution) 1. Checking properties of the Cobb-Douglas utility function. Consider the utility function u(x) Y n i1 x i i ; where x denotes a vector of n di erent goods x 2 R n +,

More information

Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer November Theory 1, 2015 (Jehle and 1 / Reny, 32

Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer November Theory 1, 2015 (Jehle and 1 / Reny, 32 Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer Theory (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 1) Tsun-Feng Chiang* *School of Economics, Henan University, Kaifeng, China November 1, 2015 Week 7: The Consumer

More information

The Last Word on Giffen Goods?

The Last Word on Giffen Goods? The Last Word on Giffen Goods? John H. Nachbar February, 1996 Abstract Giffen goods have long been a minor embarrassment to courses in microeconomic theory. The standard approach has been to dismiss Giffen

More information

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions. a11 a 12. x 2

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions. a11 a 12. x 2 LONDON SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS Professor Leonardo Felli Department of Economics S.478; x7525 EC400 2010/11 Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions 1. Show that the general

More information

Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces

Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces Bernhard Schmitzer October 19, 2017 1 Convex non-smooth optimization with proximal operators Remark 1.1 (Motivation). Convex optimization: easier to solve,

More information

Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis

Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis 1 Convex sets Both convex sets and functions have general importance in economic theory, not only in optimization. Given two points x; y 2 R n and 2 [0; 1]; the weighted

More information

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA WORKING PAPERS Cycles and chaos in the one-sector growth model with elastic labor supply Gerhard Sorger May 2015 Working Paper No: 1505 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA All our working papers

More information

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1 Microeconomics, Block I Part 1 Piero Gottardi EUI Sept. 26, 2016 Piero Gottardi (EUI) Microeconomics, Block I Part 1 Sept. 26, 2016 1 / 53 Choice Theory Set of alternatives: X, with generic elements x,

More information

Tvestlanka Karagyozova University of Connecticut

Tvestlanka Karagyozova University of Connecticut September, 005 CALCULUS REVIEW Tvestlanka Karagyozova University of Connecticut. FUNCTIONS.. Definition: A function f is a rule that associates each value of one variable with one and only one value of

More information

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion Matthew Gentzkow and Emir Kamenica Stanford University and University of Chicago December 2015 Abstract Rothschild and Stiglitz (1970) represent random

More information

BEEM103 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER. BUSINESS School. January 2009 Mock Exam, Part A. OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions

BEEM103 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER. BUSINESS School. January 2009 Mock Exam, Part A. OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions BEEM03 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER BUSINESS School January 009 Mock Exam, Part A OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions Duration : TWO HOURS The paper has 3 parts. Your marks on the rst part will be

More information

Multiple Interior Steady States in the Ramsey Model with Elastic Labor Supply

Multiple Interior Steady States in the Ramsey Model with Elastic Labor Supply Multiple Interior Steady States in the Ramsey Model with Elastic Labor Supply Takashi Kamihigashi July 31, 2014 Abstract In this paper, we show that multiple interior steady states are possible in the

More information

Lecture 3 - Axioms of Consumer Preference and the Theory of Choice

Lecture 3 - Axioms of Consumer Preference and the Theory of Choice Lecture 3 - Axioms of Consumer Preference and the Theory of Choice David Autor 14.03 Fall 2004 Agenda: 1. Consumer preference theory (a) Notion of utility function (b) Axioms of consumer preference (c)

More information

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Lecture Notes. Course Outline

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Lecture Notes. Course Outline LONDON SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS Professor Leonardo Felli Department of Economics S.478; x7525 EC400 20010/11 Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Lecture Notes Course Outline Lecture 1: Tools for

More information

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice Economics 101 Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice 1 Uncle Léon The canonical model of exchange in economics is sometimes referred to as the Walrasian Model, after the early economist Léon

More information

Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems

Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems Kiminori Matsuyama 1 Philip Ushchev 2 October 2017 1 Department of Economics, Northwestern University, Evanston, USA. Email:

More information

Economics 201b Spring 2010 Solutions to Problem Set 1 John Zhu

Economics 201b Spring 2010 Solutions to Problem Set 1 John Zhu Economics 201b Spring 2010 Solutions to Problem Set 1 John Zhu 1a The following is a Edgeworth box characterization of the Pareto optimal, and the individually rational Pareto optimal, along with some

More information

Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems

Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems Kiminori Matsuyama 1 Philip Ushchev 2 December 19, 2017, Keio University December 20. 2017, University of Tokyo 1 Department

More information

Competitive Consumer Demand 1

Competitive Consumer Demand 1 John Nachbar Washington University May 7, 2017 1 Introduction. Competitive Consumer Demand 1 These notes sketch out the basic elements of competitive demand theory. The main result is the Slutsky Decomposition

More information

Public Goods and Private Goods

Public Goods and Private Goods Chapter 2 Public Goods and Private Goods One Public Good, One Private Good Claude and Dorothy are roommates, also. 1 They are not interested in card games or the temperature of their room. Each of them

More information

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume Duality for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume Headwords: CONVEXITY, DUALITY, LAGRANGE MULTIPLIERS, PARETO EFFICIENCY, QUASI-CONCAVITY 1 Introduction The word duality is

More information

A Simple Proof of the Necessity. of the Transversality Condition

A Simple Proof of the Necessity. of the Transversality Condition comments appreciated A Simple Proof of the Necessity of the Transversality Condition Takashi Kamihigashi RIEB Kobe University Rokkodai, Nada, Kobe 657-8501 Japan Phone/Fax: +81-78-803-7015 E-mail: tkamihig@rieb.kobe-u.ac.jp

More information

Gi en Demand for Several Goods

Gi en Demand for Several Goods Gi en Demand for Several Goods Peter Norman Sørensen January 28, 2011 Abstract The utility maimizing consumer s demand function may simultaneously possess the Gi en property for any number of goods strictly

More information

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion Matthew Gentzkow and Emir Kamenica Stanford University and University of Chicago January 2016 Consider a situation where one person, call him Sender,

More information

The New Palgrave: Separability

The New Palgrave: Separability The New Palgrave: Separability Charles Blackorby Daniel Primont R. Robert Russell 1. Introduction July 29, 2006 Separability, as discussed here, refers to certain restrictions on functional representations

More information

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy Andrew McLennan October 28, 2014 Economics 7250 Advanced Mathematical Techniques for Economics Second Semester 2014 Lecture 15 The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy I. Introduction A. The material discussed

More information

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Dirk Bergemann, Spring 2012 Week of 1/29-2/4 1 Lecture 7: Expenditure Minimization Instead of maximizing utility subject to a given income we can also minimize expenditure

More information

Microeconomic Analysis

Microeconomic Analysis Microeconomic Analysis Seminar 1 Marco Pelliccia (mp63@soas.ac.uk, Room 474) SOAS, 2014 Basics of Preference Relations Assume that our consumer chooses among L commodities and that the commodity space

More information

A Reversal of Rybczynski s Comparative Statics via Anything Goes *

A Reversal of Rybczynski s Comparative Statics via Anything Goes * A Reversal of Rybczynski s Comparative Statics via Anything Goes * Hugo F. Sonnenschein a and Marcus M. Opp b a Department of Economics, University of Chicago, 6 E. 59 th Street, Chicago, IL 60637 h-sonnenschein@uchicago.edu

More information

CHAPTER 1-2: SHADOW PRICES

CHAPTER 1-2: SHADOW PRICES Essential Microeconomics -- CHAPTER -: SHADOW PRICES An intuitive approach: profit maimizing firm with a fied supply of an input Shadow prices 5 Concave maimization problem 7 Constraint qualifications

More information

Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability

Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability Chapter 7 Nathan Smooha Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability 7.1 Introduction Brouwer s Fixed Point Theorem. Let X be a non-empty, compact, and convex subset of R m. If

More information

Properties of Walrasian Demand

Properties of Walrasian Demand Properties of Walrasian Demand Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 5, September 12 Problem Set 2 is due in Kelly s mailbox by 5pm today Outline 1 Properties of Walrasian Demand 2 Indirect Utility Function 3 Envelope

More information

Midterm Exam, Econ 210A, Fall 2008

Midterm Exam, Econ 210A, Fall 2008 Midterm Exam, Econ 0A, Fall 008 ) Elmer Kink s utility function is min{x, x }. Draw a few indifference curves for Elmer. These are L-shaped, with the corners lying on the line x = x. Find each of the following

More information

Waseda Economics Working Paper Series

Waseda Economics Working Paper Series Waseda Economics Working Paper Series Testable implications of the core in market game with transferable utility AGATSUMA, Yasushi Graduate School of Economics Waseda University Graduate School of Economics

More information

GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production

GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 8, September 21 Outline 1 Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preferences 2 Afriat s Theorem 3 Production Sets and Production Functions 4 Profits

More information

Constrained optimization.

Constrained optimization. ams/econ 11b supplementary notes ucsc Constrained optimization. c 2016, Yonatan Katznelson 1. Constraints In many of the optimization problems that arise in economics, there are restrictions on the values

More information

Econ 5150: Applied Econometrics Empirical Demand Analysis. Sung Y. Park CUHK

Econ 5150: Applied Econometrics Empirical Demand Analysis. Sung Y. Park CUHK Econ 5150: Applied Econometrics Empirical Analysis Sung Y. Park CUHK Marshallian demand Under some mild regularity conditions on preferences the preference relation x ર z ( the bundle x us weakly preferred

More information

On the Principle of Optimality for Nonstationary Deterministic Dynamic Programming

On the Principle of Optimality for Nonstationary Deterministic Dynamic Programming On the Principle of Optimality for Nonstationary Deterministic Dynamic Programming Takashi Kamihigashi January 15, 2007 Abstract This note studies a general nonstationary infinite-horizon optimization

More information

ECON501 - Vector Di erentiation Simon Grant

ECON501 - Vector Di erentiation Simon Grant ECON01 - Vector Di erentiation Simon Grant October 00 Abstract Notes on vector di erentiation and some simple economic applications and examples 1 Functions of One Variable g : R! R derivative (slope)

More information

Regularity of competitive equilibria in a production economy with externalities

Regularity of competitive equilibria in a production economy with externalities Regularity of competitive equilibria in a production economy with externalities Elena del Mercato Vincenzo Platino Paris School of Economics - Université Paris 1 Panthéon Sorbonne QED-Jamboree Copenhagen,

More information

Whitney topology and spaces of preference relations. Abstract

Whitney topology and spaces of preference relations. Abstract Whitney topology and spaces of preference relations Oleksandra Hubal Lviv National University Michael Zarichnyi University of Rzeszow, Lviv National University Abstract The strong Whitney topology on the

More information

A Simplified Test for Preference Rationality of Two-Commodity Choice

A Simplified Test for Preference Rationality of Two-Commodity Choice A Simplified Test for Preference Rationality of Two-Commodity Choice Samiran Banerjee and James H. Murphy December 9, 2004 Abstract We provide a simplified test to determine if choice data from a two-commodity

More information

Adv. Micro Theory, ECON

Adv. Micro Theory, ECON Adv. Micro Theor, ECON 6-9 Assignment Answers, Fall Due: Monda, September 7 th Directions: Answer each question as completel as possible. You ma work in a group consisting of up to 3 members for each group

More information

Using Economic Contexts to Advance in Mathematics

Using Economic Contexts to Advance in Mathematics Using Economic Contexts to Advance in Mathematics Erik Balder University of Utrecht, Netherlands DEE 2013 presentation, Exeter Erik Balder (Mathematical Institute, University of Utrecht)using economic

More information

Problem Set 4 - Solution Hints

Problem Set 4 - Solution Hints ETH Zurich D-MTEC Chair of Risk & Insurance Economics (Prof. Mimra) Exercise Class Spring 206 Anastasia Sycheva Contact: asycheva@ethz.ch Office Hour: on appointment Zürichbergstrasse 8 / ZUE, Room F2

More information

General Equilibrium and Welfare

General Equilibrium and Welfare and Welfare Lectures 2 and 3, ECON 4240 Spring 2017 University of Oslo 24.01.2017 and 31.01.2017 1/37 Outline General equilibrium: look at many markets at the same time. Here all prices determined in the

More information

CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES. Likewise, we may define the higher order derivatives. f(x, y, z) = xy 2 + e zx. y = 2xy.

CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES. Likewise, we may define the higher order derivatives. f(x, y, z) = xy 2 + e zx. y = 2xy. April 15, 2009 CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES In this chapter D denotes an open subset of R n. 1. Introduction Definition 1.1. Given a function f : D R we define the second partial derivatives as

More information

Index. Cambridge University Press An Introduction to Mathematics for Economics Akihito Asano. Index.

Index. Cambridge University Press An Introduction to Mathematics for Economics Akihito Asano. Index. , see Q.E.D. ln, see natural logarithmic function e, see Euler s e i, see imaginary number log 10, see common logarithm ceteris paribus, 4 quod erat demonstrandum, see Q.E.D. reductio ad absurdum, see

More information

The general programming problem is the nonlinear programming problem where a given function is maximized subject to a set of inequality constraints.

The general programming problem is the nonlinear programming problem where a given function is maximized subject to a set of inequality constraints. 1 Optimization Mathematical programming refers to the basic mathematical problem of finding a maximum to a function, f, subject to some constraints. 1 In other words, the objective is to find a point,

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis Solutions to Midterm Exam

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis Solutions to Midterm Exam Advanced Microeconomic Analsis Solutions to Midterm Exam Q1. (0 pts) An individual consumes two goods x 1 x and his utilit function is: u(x 1 x ) = [min(x 1 + x x 1 + x )] (a) Draw some indifference curves

More information