Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis"

Transcription

1 Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis 1 Convex sets Both convex sets and functions have general importance in economic theory, not only in optimization. Given two points x; y 2 R n and 2 [0; 1]; the weighted average x + (1 )y is called the convex combination of x and y. (As a simpli cation, in this lecture we use normal fonts instead of bold to denote vectors.) De nition 1.1. A subset S R n is convex if for any 0 1 and x; x 0 2 S, x + (1 )x 0 2 S. It s straightforward to see that if S is convex, then any nite convex combination 1 x k x k of points in S such that P k l=1 l = 1 also belongs to S, and the intersection of any number of convex sets is convex. De nition 1.2. The convex hull of a set S R n ; denoted by Conv(S); is the smallest convex set containing S. Geometrically, Conv(S) consists of all points that can be written as nite convex combinations of points in S. That is, it is the convex span of S. De nition 1.3. For a set S; x 2 S is an extreme point of S if x cannot be written as the convex combination of other points in S. Theorem 1.1 (Krein-Milman). A compact and convex set S is the convex hull of its extreme points. The example below is useful in giving you a more general sense of the concepts de ned above. Example 1. The Minkowski sum of two sets A; B S is de ned as A + B = fx + y : x 2 A; y 2 Bg: Be careful that although A + f0g = A; unless A is a singleton, A A 6= 1

2 f0g. The Hausdor distance (metric) between two sets A and B is de ned as d H (A; B) = maxfd(a; B); d(b; A)g, where d(a; B) = supfd(x; B); x 2 Ag and d(x; B) = inffd(x; y); y 2 Bg. Let S = f(x 1 ; x 2 ; x 3 ) 2 R 3 : x 1 + x 2 + x 3 = 1g: Consider the set of all closed convex subsets of S; and with a little abuse of noation, denoted it as 2 S. From the above, for any A; B 2 2 S ; their convex combination A + (1 )B S is well-de ned and is also convex. The set 2 S is a large set and its structure is not so transparent. Nevertheless, since it is convex and compact (under the Hausdor metric), due to the Krein-Milman theorem, we can picture 2 S as the convex hull of its extreme points. Therefore, the work reduces to nd out which subsets of S are extreme points of 2 S ; that is, which subsets of S cannot be written as convex combinations of other subsets of S. 2 Hyperplane separation theorem De nition 2.1. Let p 2 R n and p 6= 0; and let a 2 R: The set H(p; a) = fx 2 R n : p x = ag is called a hyperplane in R n. The sets fx 2 R n : p x ag and fx 2 R n : p x ag are called the half-space above and below the hyperplane H(p; a); respectively. Recall that p x = jjpjj jjxjj cos, where is the angle between the vectors p and x. The vector p is the normal of the hyperplane H(p; a) and is thus orthogonal (perpendicular) to it, and a half-space is above H(p; a) if it is by the side of the hyperplane as the direction of p points to. Each hyperplane in R n is a subset of R n with dimension n 1. A hyperplane in R 2 is a straight line and a hyperplane in R 3 is just a two-dimensional plane. Example 2. If p = (p 1 ; p 2 ) 2 R 2 and I 2 R; then the hyperplane H(p; I) = f(x 1 ; x 2 ) 2 R 2 : p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 = Ig can be understood as the budget line, given income I and prices p 1 ; p 2. De nition 2.2. Let X; Y be subsets of R n. We say that the hyperplance H(p; a) separates X from Y if p x < a; 8x 2 X and p y > a; 8y 2 Y: 2

3 Theorem 2.1 (Hyperplane separation). Let C be a closed and convex subset of R n, and x 2 R n nc. Then there exists p 2 R n ; p 6= 0; and a 2 R such that the hyperplance H(p; a) separates C and x. Proof. Let y be the point in C that the distance between x and y; jjx yjj; obtains its minimum. (Such y exists due to the Weierstrass theorem). If we let p = x y and a 0 = p y, then p(x y) > 0; hence px > a 0. Also, for any z 2 C, denote the angle between the vectors z y and p by, then cannot be an acute angle, hence p (z y) = jjpjjjjz yjj cos 0: That is, p z p y = a 0 ; 8z 2 C. Now we can see that there must be " > 0; " small enough such that p z < a 0 + "; 8z 2 C and p x > a 0 + ". Let a = a 0 + "; then H(p; a) separates C and x. There are many other versions of hyperplane separation theorems on how hyperplanes separate points or (open or closed) convex subsets from (open or closed) convex subsets; these theorems all share the same geometric intuition as that of the theorem above. When one of the two sets is not closed, the separation theorem may ensure only weak separation. Example 3. Let u 1 (x) and u 2 (x) be utility functions of two agents de ned on a convex set X. Suppose fv 2 R 2 : (v 1 ; v 2 ) (u 1 (x); u 2 (x)) for some x 2 Xg is convex (e.g., this holds true when u 1 ; u 2 are concave functions, which we will formally de ne very soon). The following result is on the Pareto frontier of allocations between two agents; it can be generalized to more agents. Claim 2.2. Every Pareto e cient allocation x 2 X maximizes u 1 (x) + (1 some 2 [0; 1]. )u 2 (x) for We now sketch the proof of this claim using a version of the Hyperplane separation theorem. Suppose x is Pareto e cient. Then the sets A = fv : v u(x) for some x 2 Xg and B = fv : v > u(x )g are disjoint. Since A is convex by assumption and B is also convex, there exist a vector p 2 R 2 and a scalar a such that H(p; a) separates the two sets: that is, p v a for all v 2 A and p v a for all v 2 B (since B is not closed, we don t get strict separation). Since the half-space above H(p; a) contains B, it must be that p 0. Geometrically, since u(x ) 2 A and is on the boundary of B; we have u(x ) 2 H(p; a): That is, p u(x ) = 3

4 a p v; 8v 2 A. Hence p u(x ) p u(x); 8x 2 X: Let = p 1 =(p 1 + p 2 ); then we have a proof. The hyperplane separation theorems are also applied in proving for example, the second theorem of welfare economics, and in game theory, in showing that a mixed strategy is never a best-response if and only if it is strictly dominated. In general, the theorem is potentially useful when we need to show the existence of a vector of weights. De nition 2.3. The support function h X : R n! R of a closed and convex subset X R n is de ned as h X (p) = supfp x : x 2 Xg; where h ; (p) 1 and h X (p) +1 if the sup is in nite. Example 4. Consider X R 2. If X = fxg; then h X (p) = p x, and if X = f(x 1 ; x 2 ) : x x 2 2 = 1g; then h X (p) = jjpjj: The support function h X () is uniquely determined by X, and by de nition, X fx 2 R n : p x h X (p)g: That is, X is included in the half-space below the hyperplane H(p; h X (p)). Furthermore, due to the notation sup in the de nition, h X (p) is chosen to be the smallest number a such that the half-space below H(p; a) includes X. Claim 2.3. h X (p) = inffa 2 R : p x a; 8x 2 Xg: Geometrically, for any closed and convex set X and a vector p; h X (p) is chosen in a way that the hyperplane H(p; h X (p)) is tangent to X and X is included in the half-space below the hyperplane. That is, in direction p; H(p; h X (p)) supports X from the above. Theorem 2.4 (Support-function theorem). For a closed and convex subset X R n ; X = \ p2r nfx 2 R n : p x h X (p)g: Since this result is geometrically straightforward, we don t give its proof. Intuitively, it says that if we know that h X : R n! R is the support function of some closed and convex subset X of R n ; then we can uniquely recover X by taking intersection of the half-spaces below the respective hyperplane H(p; h X (p)); p 2 R n. And in practice, we don t need to consider all p 2 R n when taking the intersection: it is su cient to consider all directions p in the unit ball fx 2 R n : jjxjj = 1g: 4

5 3 Concave functions De nition 3.1. Let f : S! R; where S R n is convex. The function f is (a) concave if f(x + (1 )x 0 ) f(x) + (1 )f(x 0 ), for any x; x 0 2 S and 2 (0; 1), and is (b) convex if f(x + (1 )x 0 ) f(x) + (1 )f(x 0 ), for any x; x 0 2 S and 2 (0; 1) That is, a function is concave if its value at the average of two points is always great than or equal to the average of its values at the two points. When the inequality is strict for all x; x 0 ;, then f is said to be strictly concave (or respectively, strictly convex). The functions which are both concave and convex are of the form f(x) = a x + b and are called a ne functions. Example 5. The function f : R +! R de ned as f(x) = x a is strictly concave if 0 < a < 1 and is strictly convex if a > 1. The function f : R 2 +! R de ned as f(x 1 ; x 2 ) = x a 1x b 2 is called the Cobb-Douglas function; it is concave if a + b 1 and is neither concave nor convex if a + b > 1. Example 6. The pro t function (p) = max x2x p x (similarly, the support function h X (p) in the previous section) is convex. For any concave function f; f is convex and vice versa. Hence it is without loss of generality to concentrate on concave functions. The result below can be viewed as an alternative way of de ning concave functions. Theorem 3.1. Let A f(x; y) : x 2 S; f(x) yg be the set of points "on and below" the graph of f. Then f is concave if and only if A is a convex set. Proof. ()) Suppose f is concave. Let (x 1 ; y 1 ); (x 2 ; y 2 ) be two points in A. Then by de nition, f(x 1 ) y 1 and f(x 2 ) y 2. Since f is concave, for any 2 [0; 1]; f(x 1 + (1 )x 2 ) f(x 1 ) + (1 )f(x 2 ) y 1 + (1 )y 2 : 5

6 This means that (x 1 + (1 )x 2 ; y 1 + (1 )y 2 ); which is (x 1 ; y 1 ) + (1 )(x 2 ; y 2 ); also belongs to A. Hence A is a convex set. (() Suppose A is a convex set. Let x 1 ; x 2 be two points in S. Since f(x 1 ) f(x 1 ) and f(x 2 ) f(x 2 ); we have (x 1 ; f(x 1 )); (x 2 ; f(x 2 )) 2 A: As A is convex, for any 2 [0; 1]; (x 1 ; f(x 1 )) + (1 )(x 2 ; f(x 2 )) 2 A: That is, (x 1 + (1 )x 2 ; f(x 1 ) + (1 )f(x 2 )) 2 A. By the de nition of A; f(x 1 + (1 )x 2 ) f(x 1 ) + (1 )f(x 2 ): Hence f is concave. Theorem 3.2. Let f : S! R be a concave function. Then, if S is open, f is continuous on S. Proof. Pick x 2 S. Since S is open, there exists r > 0 such that N r (x) S and its boundary A = fy : jjx yjj = rg S. Pick any fx n g S such that x n! x. Then there exists N such that for all n N; jjx n xjj < r: Then for all n N; there exist n 2 (0; 1) and z n 2 A such that x n = n x + (1 n )z n : Since f is concave, f(x n ) n f(x) + (1 n )f(z n ): Taking limits on both sides, lim inf n f(x n) f(x): Similarly, for all n N; there exist n 2 (0; 1) and w n 2 A such that x = n x n + (1 n )w n : Since f is concave, f(x) n f(x n ) + (1 n )f(w n ): 6

7 Taking limits on both sides, f(x) lim sup f(x n ): n That is, f(x n ) converges and lim n f(x n ) = f(x). Since fx n g is picked arbitrarily, we know that f(x) is continuous on S. Nevertheless, a function f is concave does not imply that it is always di erentiable on the interior of its domain. The positive result on this is that if f : (a; b)! R is concave, then it is di erentiable at all but countably many points in (a; b). That is, it is di erentiable almost everywhere (cf. Rockafeller, Convex Analysis, 1970). Theorem 3.3. If f : (a; b)! R is twice continuously di erentiable, then f is concave if and only if f 00 (x) 0 for all x 2 (a; b). Proof. (() Suppose f 0 (x) 0; 8x 2 (a; b). Then f 0 (x) is non-increasing. For x; y such that a < x < y < b, pick 2 (0; 1) and let z = x + (1 )y. Then z x = (1 )(y x); y z = (y x): Note that since f 0 (x) is non-increasing, f(z) f(x) = f(y) f(z) = Z z x Z y z f 0 (t)dt f 0 (t)dt Z z x Z y z f 0 (z)dt = f 0 (z)(z f 0 (z)dt = f 0 (z)(y x); z): Hence f(z) f(x) + f 0 (z)(1 )(z x); f(z) f(y) f 0 (z)(y x): 7

8 We have f(z) = f(z) + (1 )f(z) [f(x) + f 0 (z)(1 )(z x)] + (1 )[f(y) f 0 (z)(y x)] = f(x) + (1 )f(y): ()) Suppose f is concave and instead there exists x 0 2 (a; b) such that f 00 (x 0 ) > 0. Since f 00 (x) is continuous, there exists " > 0 such that f 00 (x) > 0 for all x 2 (x 0 "; x 0 +") (a; b). Reverse the proof in the (() part, we can nd x; y 2 (x 0 "; x 0 + ") and 2 (0; 1) such that f(ax + (1 )y) < f(x) + (1 )f(y); of f. which means f is strictly convex on (x 0 "; x 0 + "); this contradicts with the concavity De nition 3.2. An n n matrix A = (a ij ) i;jn is symmetric if a ij = a ji ; 8i; j n. A symmetric A is negative semi-de nite if for all vectors z 2 R n ; z T Az 0. It is negative de nite if for all z 6= 0; z T Az < 0. Theorem 3.4. If C is an open convex subset of R n and f : C! R is twice continuously di erentiable, then f is concave if and only if D 2 f(x) is negative semi-de nite for all x 2 C. Proof. Part I. Pick arbitrary y; z 2 R n such that f : y + z 2 Cg is nonempty. Let g y;z () = f(y + z). We will show that f is concave i each g y;z () is concave in. First, Suppose f is concave. Pick ; 0 such that x := y + z 2 C; x 0 := y + 0 z 2 C. Then f(x) = g y;z () and f(x 0 ) = g y;z ( 0 ). Furthermore, f(x + (1 )x 0 ) = f(y + ( + (1 ) 0 )z) = g y;z ( + (1 ) 0 ): We see straightforwardly that the concavity of f implies that of each g y;z (). Second, suppose g y;z () is concave for each y; z. Pick x; y 2 C and let z = x y: Then y + z = y + (x y) = x + (1 )y: 8

9 Therefore, for each 2 (0; 1); f(x + (1 )y) = g y;x y () = g y;x y ( 1 + (1 ) 0) g y;x y (1) + (1 )g y;x y (0) = f(y + (x y)) + (1 )f(y + 0 z) = f(x) + (1 )f(y): Part II. Now we know that f is concave i each g y;z () is concave, that is, i [g y;z ()] 00 0 for each pair of y; z 2 R n. Let x 0 = y + z, then g 00 y;z() f(y + 2 = z T D 2 f(x 0 )z: Hence g 00 y;z() 0 for each pair y; z is equivalent to D 2 f(x 0 ) being negative semi-de nite for all x 0 2 C. 4 Quasi-concave functions De nition 4.1. Let f : S! R; where S R n is convex. The function f is (a) quasiconcave if f(x + (1 )x 0 ) minff(x); f(x 0 )g; for any x; x 0 2 S and 2 (0; 1); and is (b) quasiconvex if f(x + (1 )x 0 ) maxff(x); f(x 0 )g; for any x; x 0 2 S and 2 (0; 1): The function f is strictly quasiconcave, or quasiconvex, respectively, if the inequality holds strict for all x; x 0 ;. If f is quasiconcave, then its value at the average of two points is greater than or equal to the minimum of its values at the two points. Quasiconcave functions are strictly more general than concave functions. If a function is monotonic, then it is both quasiconcave and quasiconvex. Example 7. f(x) = e x is quasiconcave, although it is strictly convex. The Cobb-Douglas function f(x 1 ; x 2 ) = x a 1x b 2 is quasiconcave if a; b > 0. 9

10 The main reason that we care about quasiconcave functions in economics is because of the following result, which intuitively states that a utility function is quasiconcave if and only if its indi erence curves are boundaries of some convex set, and this captures diminishing marginal rate of substitution. Theorem 4.1. Let U(c) = fx 2 S : f(x) cg be the upper contour set of f for level c. Then f is quasiconcave i U(c) is a convex set for all c 2 R. Proof. ()) Suppose f is quasiconcave. If x; x 0 2 U(c); then f(x) c and f(x 0 ) c. Thus for all 2 (0; 1); f(ax + (1 )x 0 ) minff(x); f(x 0 )g c; which implies x + (1 )x 0 2 U(c): (() Suppose U(c) is a convex set for each c 2 R. For any x; x 0 2 S; obviously, f(x); f(x 0 ) minff(x); f(x 0 )g. Therefore, x; x 0 2 U(minff(x); f(x 0 )g): Since U(minff(x); f(x 0 )g) is a convex set, 8 2 [0; 1]; x+(1 )x 0 2 U(minff(x); f(x 0 )g). That is, 8 2 [0; 1]; f(x+ (1 )x 0 ) minff(x); f(x 0 )g. Example 8. Let u : R 2 +! R denote a consumer s utility function. Then the boundary of the upper contour set, u(x; y) = c; is exactly the indi erence curve of the consumer at utility level c. Thus u(x; y) is quasiconcave guarantees that the indi erence curve is of convex shape. That is, the function y(x) that solves u(x; y) = c is convex in x. This implies diminishing marginal rate of substitution, that is, it guarantees that MRS xy = dy dx = u x(x; y) u y (x; y) is decreasing in x. Intuition: the more of good x that you are consuming right now, the less of good y is needed to compensate you for your loss of 1 unit of good x. 5 A digression on ordinal and cardinal utility De nition 5.1. For any nondecreasing function g on R and u : R n! R; the composition g u that maps x 2 R n to g(u(x)) is called a monotonic (nondecreasing) transformation of u. 10

11 Example 9. The utility functions 3x 1 x 2 + 2; (x 1 x 2 ) 2 ; (x 1 x 2 ) 3 + x 1 x 2 ; e x 1x 2 and ln x 1 x 2 are all monotonic transformations of u(x 1 ; x 1 ) = x 1 x 2 : Intuitively, a preference relation is ordinal if it de nes the relative order of the objects (e.g., prefer bundle (x 1 ; x 2 ) over bundle (y 1 ; y 2 )), and it is cardinal if it also de nes the intensity of comparison (e.g., bundle (x 1 ; x 2 ) generates 5 units more utility than bundle (y 1 ; y 2 )). Formally, De nition 5.2. A property of functions is called ordinal if whenever a function u has this property, for any monotonic transformation g, g u also has this property. Otherwise, it is called cardinal. Claim 5.1. Concavity is a cardinal property. This can easily be seen from the following example. Example 10. u(x) = p x is concave on [0; 1); but the monotonic transformation of it, g(u(x)) = ( p x) 4 = x 2, is strictly convex. Claim 5.2. Quasiconcavity is an ordinal property. Proof. This is immediate. Since g is nondecreasing and f is quasiconcave, 8 2 (0; 1) and x; y 2 S; g(f(x + (1 )y)) g(minff(x; f(y))g) = minfg(f(x)); g(f(y)): 11

Nonlinear Programming (NLP)

Nonlinear Programming (NLP) Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 6: Nonlinear Programming - Unconstrained Optimization Note 6 is based on de la Fuente (2000, Ch. 7), Madden (1986, Ch. 3 and 5) and Simon and Blume

More information

Lecture 3 - Axioms of Consumer Preference and the Theory of Choice

Lecture 3 - Axioms of Consumer Preference and the Theory of Choice Lecture 3 - Axioms of Consumer Preference and the Theory of Choice David Autor 14.03 Fall 2004 Agenda: 1. Consumer preference theory (a) Notion of utility function (b) Axioms of consumer preference (c)

More information

Advanced Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomics Advanced Microeconomics Ordinal preference theory Harald Wiese University of Leipzig Harald Wiese (University of Leipzig) Advanced Microeconomics 1 / 68 Part A. Basic decision and preference theory 1 Decisions

More information

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics ECON2285: Mathematical Economics Yulei Luo Economics, HKU September 17, 2018 Luo, Y. (Economics, HKU) ME September 17, 2018 1 / 46 Static Optimization and Extreme Values In this topic, we will study goal

More information

Set, functions and Euclidean space. Seungjin Han

Set, functions and Euclidean space. Seungjin Han Set, functions and Euclidean space Seungjin Han September, 2018 1 Some Basics LOGIC A is necessary for B : If B holds, then A holds. B A A B is the contraposition of B A. A is sufficient for B: If A holds,

More information

CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES. Likewise, we may define the higher order derivatives. f(x, y, z) = xy 2 + e zx. y = 2xy.

CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES. Likewise, we may define the higher order derivatives. f(x, y, z) = xy 2 + e zx. y = 2xy. April 15, 2009 CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES In this chapter D denotes an open subset of R n. 1. Introduction Definition 1.1. Given a function f : D R we define the second partial derivatives as

More information

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1 Microeconomics, Block I Part 1 Piero Gottardi EUI Sept. 26, 2016 Piero Gottardi (EUI) Microeconomics, Block I Part 1 Sept. 26, 2016 1 / 53 Choice Theory Set of alternatives: X, with generic elements x,

More information

Static Problem Set 2 Solutions

Static Problem Set 2 Solutions Static Problem Set Solutions Jonathan Kreamer July, 0 Question (i) Let g, h be two concave functions. Is f = g + h a concave function? Prove it. Yes. Proof: Consider any two points x, x and α [0, ]. Let

More information

Topics in Mathematical Economics. Atsushi Kajii Kyoto University

Topics in Mathematical Economics. Atsushi Kajii Kyoto University Topics in Mathematical Economics Atsushi Kajii Kyoto University 25 November 2018 2 Contents 1 Preliminary Mathematics 5 1.1 Topology.................................. 5 1.2 Linear Algebra..............................

More information

EC9A0: Pre-sessional Advanced Mathematics Course. Lecture Notes: Unconstrained Optimisation By Pablo F. Beker 1

EC9A0: Pre-sessional Advanced Mathematics Course. Lecture Notes: Unconstrained Optimisation By Pablo F. Beker 1 EC9A0: Pre-sessional Advanced Mathematics Course Lecture Notes: Unconstrained Optimisation By Pablo F. Beker 1 1 Infimum and Supremum Definition 1. Fix a set Y R. A number α R is an upper bound of Y if

More information

Lecture 6: Contraction mapping, inverse and implicit function theorems

Lecture 6: Contraction mapping, inverse and implicit function theorems Lecture 6: Contraction mapping, inverse and implicit function theorems 1 The contraction mapping theorem De nition 11 Let X be a metric space, with metric d If f : X! X and if there is a number 2 (0; 1)

More information

Microeconomics II. MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3

Microeconomics II. MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3 Microeconomics II MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3 Problem 1 Consider an economy 1 1, with one firm (or technology and one consumer (firm owner, as in the textbook (MWG section 15.C. The set of

More information

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy Andrew McLennan October 28, 2014 Economics 7250 Advanced Mathematical Techniques for Economics Second Semester 2014 Lecture 15 The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy I. Introduction A. The material discussed

More information

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Lecture Notes. Course Outline

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Lecture Notes. Course Outline LONDON SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS Professor Leonardo Felli Department of Economics S.478; x7525 EC400 20010/11 Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Lecture Notes Course Outline Lecture 1: Tools for

More information

Preferences and Utility

Preferences and Utility Preferences and Utility How can we formally describe an individual s preference for different amounts of a good? How can we represent his preference for a particular list of goods (a bundle) over another?

More information

Microeconomic Theory-I Washington State University Midterm Exam #1 - Answer key. Fall 2016

Microeconomic Theory-I Washington State University Midterm Exam #1 - Answer key. Fall 2016 Microeconomic Theory-I Washington State University Midterm Exam # - Answer key Fall 06. [Checking properties of preference relations]. Consider the following preference relation de ned in the positive

More information

Topics in Mathematical Economics. Atsushi Kajii Kyoto University

Topics in Mathematical Economics. Atsushi Kajii Kyoto University Topics in Mathematical Economics Atsushi Kajii Kyoto University 26 June 2018 2 Contents 1 Preliminary Mathematics 5 1.1 Topology.................................. 5 1.2 Linear Algebra..............................

More information

Generalized Convexity in Economics

Generalized Convexity in Economics Generalized Convexity in Economics J.E. Martínez-Legaz Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, Spain 2nd Summer School: Generalized Convexity Analysis Introduction to Theory and Applications JULY 19, 2008 KAOHSIUNG

More information

The Kuhn-Tucker Problem

The Kuhn-Tucker Problem Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 8: Nonlinear Programming - The Kuhn-Tucker Problem Note 8 is based on de la Fuente (2000, Ch. 7) and Simon and Blume (1994, Ch. 18 and 19). The Kuhn-Tucker

More information

1 Topology Definition of a topology Basis (Base) of a topology The subspace topology & the product topology on X Y 3

1 Topology Definition of a topology Basis (Base) of a topology The subspace topology & the product topology on X Y 3 Index Page 1 Topology 2 1.1 Definition of a topology 2 1.2 Basis (Base) of a topology 2 1.3 The subspace topology & the product topology on X Y 3 1.4 Basic topology concepts: limit points, closed sets,

More information

CHAPTER 2: CONVEX SETS AND CONCAVE FUNCTIONS. W. Erwin Diewert January 31, 2008.

CHAPTER 2: CONVEX SETS AND CONCAVE FUNCTIONS. W. Erwin Diewert January 31, 2008. 1 ECONOMICS 594: LECTURE NOTES CHAPTER 2: CONVEX SETS AND CONCAVE FUNCTIONS W. Erwin Diewert January 31, 2008. 1. Introduction Many economic problems have the following structure: (i) a linear function

More information

Second Welfare Theorem

Second Welfare Theorem Second Welfare Theorem Econ 2100 Fall 2015 Lecture 18, November 2 Outline 1 Second Welfare Theorem From Last Class We want to state a prove a theorem that says that any Pareto optimal allocation is (part

More information

ARE211, Fall 2005 CONTENTS. 5. Characteristics of Functions Surjective, Injective and Bijective functions. 5.2.

ARE211, Fall 2005 CONTENTS. 5. Characteristics of Functions Surjective, Injective and Bijective functions. 5.2. ARE211, Fall 2005 LECTURE #18: THU, NOV 3, 2005 PRINT DATE: NOVEMBER 22, 2005 (COMPSTAT2) CONTENTS 5. Characteristics of Functions. 1 5.1. Surjective, Injective and Bijective functions 1 5.2. Homotheticity

More information

Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem

Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem 56 Chapter 7 Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem Recall that C(X) is not a normed linear space when X is not compact. On the other hand we could use semi

More information

Economics 205 Exercises

Economics 205 Exercises Economics 05 Eercises Prof. Watson, Fall 006 (Includes eaminations through Fall 003) Part 1: Basic Analysis 1. Using ε and δ, write in formal terms the meaning of lim a f() = c, where f : R R.. Write the

More information

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume Duality for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume Headwords: CONVEXITY, DUALITY, LAGRANGE MULTIPLIERS, PARETO EFFICIENCY, QUASI-CONCAVITY 1 Introduction The word duality is

More information

Arrovian Social Choice with Non -Welfare Attributes

Arrovian Social Choice with Non -Welfare Attributes Arrovian Social Choice with Non -Welfare Attributes Ryo-Ichi Nagahisa y Kansai University Koichi Suga z Waseda University November 14, 2017 Abstract A social state is assumed to be chracterized by welfare

More information

EC 521 MATHEMATICAL METHODS FOR ECONOMICS. Lecture 1: Preliminaries

EC 521 MATHEMATICAL METHODS FOR ECONOMICS. Lecture 1: Preliminaries EC 521 MATHEMATICAL METHODS FOR ECONOMICS Lecture 1: Preliminaries Murat YILMAZ Boğaziçi University In this lecture we provide some basic facts from both Linear Algebra and Real Analysis, which are going

More information

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory Winter 2018

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory Winter 2018 Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Ec 181 KC Border Convex Analysis and Economic Theory Winter 2018 Topic 7: Quasiconvex Functions I 7.1 Level sets of functions For an extended real-valued

More information

Introduction to Convex Analysis Microeconomics II - Tutoring Class

Introduction to Convex Analysis Microeconomics II - Tutoring Class Introduction to Convex Analysis Microeconomics II - Tutoring Class Professor: V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha TA: Cinthia Konichi April 2010 1 Basic Concepts and Results This is a first glance on basic convex

More information

GENERALIZED CONVEXITY AND OPTIMALITY CONDITIONS IN SCALAR AND VECTOR OPTIMIZATION

GENERALIZED CONVEXITY AND OPTIMALITY CONDITIONS IN SCALAR AND VECTOR OPTIMIZATION Chapter 4 GENERALIZED CONVEXITY AND OPTIMALITY CONDITIONS IN SCALAR AND VECTOR OPTIMIZATION Alberto Cambini Department of Statistics and Applied Mathematics University of Pisa, Via Cosmo Ridolfi 10 56124

More information

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY Elementary properties of convex functions

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY Elementary properties of convex functions Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Ec 181 KC Border Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY 2018 2019 Topic 6: Convex functions I 6.1 Elementary properties of convex functions We may occasionally

More information

g 2 (x) (1/3)M 1 = (1/3)(2/3)M.

g 2 (x) (1/3)M 1 = (1/3)(2/3)M. COMPACTNESS If C R n is closed and bounded, then by B-W it is sequentially compact: any sequence of points in C has a subsequence converging to a point in C Conversely, any sequentially compact C R n is

More information

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

September Math Course: First Order Derivative September Math Course: First Order Derivative Arina Nikandrova Functions Function y = f (x), where x is either be a scalar or a vector of several variables (x,..., x n ), can be thought of as a rule which

More information

MAT 570 REAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES. Contents. 1. Sets Functions Countability Axiom of choice Equivalence relations 9

MAT 570 REAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES. Contents. 1. Sets Functions Countability Axiom of choice Equivalence relations 9 MAT 570 REAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES PROFESSOR: JOHN QUIGG SEMESTER: FALL 204 Contents. Sets 2 2. Functions 5 3. Countability 7 4. Axiom of choice 8 5. Equivalence relations 9 6. Real numbers 9 7. Extended

More information

Convex Analysis and Optimization Chapter 2 Solutions

Convex Analysis and Optimization Chapter 2 Solutions Convex Analysis and Optimization Chapter 2 Solutions Dimitri P. Bertsekas with Angelia Nedić and Asuman E. Ozdaglar Massachusetts Institute of Technology Athena Scientific, Belmont, Massachusetts http://www.athenasc.com

More information

Convex Functions and Optimization

Convex Functions and Optimization Chapter 5 Convex Functions and Optimization 5.1 Convex Functions Our next topic is that of convex functions. Again, we will concentrate on the context of a map f : R n R although the situation can be generalized

More information

Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces

Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces Bernhard Schmitzer October 19, 2017 1 Convex non-smooth optimization with proximal operators Remark 1.1 (Motivation). Convex optimization: easier to solve,

More information

Chapter 2 Convex Analysis

Chapter 2 Convex Analysis Chapter 2 Convex Analysis The theory of nonsmooth analysis is based on convex analysis. Thus, we start this chapter by giving basic concepts and results of convexity (for further readings see also [202,

More information

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers The Ohio State University Department of Economics Econ. 805 Winter 00 Prof. James Peck Homework Set Questions and Answers. Consider the following pure exchange economy with two consumers and two goods.

More information

fy (X(g)) Y (f)x(g) gy (X(f)) Y (g)x(f)) = fx(y (g)) + gx(y (f)) fy (X(g)) gy (X(f))

fy (X(g)) Y (f)x(g) gy (X(f)) Y (g)x(f)) = fx(y (g)) + gx(y (f)) fy (X(g)) gy (X(f)) 1. Basic algebra of vector fields Let V be a finite dimensional vector space over R. Recall that V = {L : V R} is defined to be the set of all linear maps to R. V is isomorphic to V, but there is no canonical

More information

Advanced Microeconomics I: Consumers, Firms and Markets Chapters 1+2

Advanced Microeconomics I: Consumers, Firms and Markets Chapters 1+2 Advanced Microeconomics I: Consumers, Firms and Markets Chapters 1+2 Prof. Dr. Oliver Gürtler Winter Term 2012/2013 1 Advanced Microeconomics I: Consumers, Firms and Markets Chapters 1+2 JJ N J 1. Introduction

More information

Monotone Function. Function f is called monotonically increasing, if. x 1 x 2 f (x 1 ) f (x 2 ) x 1 < x 2 f (x 1 ) < f (x 2 ) x 1 x 2

Monotone Function. Function f is called monotonically increasing, if. x 1 x 2 f (x 1 ) f (x 2 ) x 1 < x 2 f (x 1 ) < f (x 2 ) x 1 x 2 Monotone Function Function f is called monotonically increasing, if Chapter 3 x x 2 f (x ) f (x 2 ) It is called strictly monotonically increasing, if f (x 2) f (x ) Convex and Concave x < x 2 f (x )

More information

Connectedness. Proposition 2.2. The following are equivalent for a topological space (X, T ).

Connectedness. Proposition 2.2. The following are equivalent for a topological space (X, T ). Connectedness 1 Motivation Connectedness is the sort of topological property that students love. Its definition is intuitive and easy to understand, and it is a powerful tool in proofs of well-known results.

More information

ARE211, Fall2015. Contents. 2. Univariate and Multivariate Differentiation (cont) Taylor s Theorem (cont) 2

ARE211, Fall2015. Contents. 2. Univariate and Multivariate Differentiation (cont) Taylor s Theorem (cont) 2 ARE211, Fall2015 CALCULUS4: THU, SEP 17, 2015 PRINTED: SEPTEMBER 22, 2015 (LEC# 7) Contents 2. Univariate and Multivariate Differentiation (cont) 1 2.4. Taylor s Theorem (cont) 2 2.5. Applying Taylor theory:

More information

Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences. Supergradients. KC Border Fall 2001 v ::15.45

Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences. Supergradients. KC Border Fall 2001 v ::15.45 Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Supergradients KC Border Fall 2001 1 The supergradient of a concave function There is a useful way to characterize the concavity of differentiable functions.

More information

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems The Fundamental Welfare Theorems The so-called Fundamental Welfare Theorems of Economics tell us about the relation between market equilibrium and Pareto efficiency. The First Welfare Theorem: Every Walrasian

More information

Winter Lecture 10. Convexity and Concavity

Winter Lecture 10. Convexity and Concavity Andrew McLennan February 9, 1999 Economics 5113 Introduction to Mathematical Economics Winter 1999 Lecture 10 Convexity and Concavity I. Introduction A. We now consider convexity, concavity, and the general

More information

Alvaro Rodrigues-Neto Research School of Economics, Australian National University. ANU Working Papers in Economics and Econometrics # 587

Alvaro Rodrigues-Neto Research School of Economics, Australian National University. ANU Working Papers in Economics and Econometrics # 587 Cycles of length two in monotonic models José Alvaro Rodrigues-Neto Research School of Economics, Australian National University ANU Working Papers in Economics and Econometrics # 587 October 20122 JEL:

More information

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions. a11 a 12. x 2

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions. a11 a 12. x 2 LONDON SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS Professor Leonardo Felli Department of Economics S.478; x7525 EC400 2010/11 Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions 1. Show that the general

More information

Chapter 13. Convex and Concave. Josef Leydold Mathematical Methods WS 2018/19 13 Convex and Concave 1 / 44

Chapter 13. Convex and Concave. Josef Leydold Mathematical Methods WS 2018/19 13 Convex and Concave 1 / 44 Chapter 13 Convex and Concave Josef Leydold Mathematical Methods WS 2018/19 13 Convex and Concave 1 / 44 Monotone Function Function f is called monotonically increasing, if x 1 x 2 f (x 1 ) f (x 2 ) It

More information

Convexity in R n. The following lemma will be needed in a while. Lemma 1 Let x E, u R n. If τ I(x, u), τ 0, define. f(x + τu) f(x). τ.

Convexity in R n. The following lemma will be needed in a while. Lemma 1 Let x E, u R n. If τ I(x, u), τ 0, define. f(x + τu) f(x). τ. Convexity in R n Let E be a convex subset of R n. A function f : E (, ] is convex iff f(tx + (1 t)y) (1 t)f(x) + tf(y) x, y E, t [0, 1]. A similar definition holds in any vector space. A topology is needed

More information

Lecture 1- The constrained optimization problem

Lecture 1- The constrained optimization problem Lecture 1- The constrained optimization problem The role of optimization in economic theory is important because we assume that individuals are rational. Why constrained optimization? the problem of scarcity.

More information

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions 1. For each of the following propositions, state whether the proposition is true or false. If true, provide a proof (or at least indicate how a proof could

More information

Technical Results on Regular Preferences and Demand

Technical Results on Regular Preferences and Demand Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Technical Results on Regular Preferences and Demand KC Border Revised Fall 2011; Winter 2017 Preferences For the purposes of this note, a preference relation

More information

Intro to Economic analysis

Intro to Economic analysis Intro to Economic analysis Alberto Bisin - NYU 1 Rational Choice The central gure of economics theory is the individual decision-maker (DM). The typical example of a DM is the consumer. We shall assume

More information

Mathematical Economics: Lecture 16

Mathematical Economics: Lecture 16 Mathematical Economics: Lecture 16 Yu Ren WISE, Xiamen University November 26, 2012 Outline 1 Chapter 21: Concave and Quasiconcave Functions New Section Chapter 21: Concave and Quasiconcave Functions Concave

More information

BASICS OF CONVEX ANALYSIS

BASICS OF CONVEX ANALYSIS BASICS OF CONVEX ANALYSIS MARKUS GRASMAIR 1. Main Definitions We start with providing the central definitions of convex functions and convex sets. Definition 1. A function f : R n R + } is called convex,

More information

Problem Set 3

Problem Set 3 4.02 Problem Set 3 Due Thursday, October 2, 2004, in class Starred (*) problems will not count for the grade on this problem set; they are based on material from lectures on 0/2 and 0/26, and provide practice

More information

Chapter 1 - Preference and choice

Chapter 1 - Preference and choice http://selod.ensae.net/m1 Paris School of Economics (selod@ens.fr) September 27, 2007 Notations Consider an individual (agent) facing a choice set X. Definition (Choice set, "Consumption set") X is a set

More information

On John type ellipsoids

On John type ellipsoids On John type ellipsoids B. Klartag Tel Aviv University Abstract Given an arbitrary convex symmetric body K R n, we construct a natural and non-trivial continuous map u K which associates ellipsoids to

More information

a = (a 1; :::a i )

a = (a 1; :::a  i ) 1 Pro t maximization Behavioral assumption: an optimal set of actions is characterized by the conditions: max R(a 1 ; a ; :::a n ) C(a 1 ; a ; :::a n ) a = (a 1; :::a n) @R(a ) @a i = @C(a ) @a i The rm

More information

Optimality Conditions for Nonsmooth Convex Optimization

Optimality Conditions for Nonsmooth Convex Optimization Optimality Conditions for Nonsmooth Convex Optimization Sangkyun Lee Oct 22, 2014 Let us consider a convex function f : R n R, where R is the extended real field, R := R {, + }, which is proper (f never

More information

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP Prof. Olivier Bochet Room A.34 Phone 3 63 476 E-mail olivier.bochet@vwi.unibe.ch Webpage http//sta.vwi.unibe.ch/bochet Advanced Microeconomics Fall 2 Lecture Note Choice-Based Approach Price e ects, Wealth

More information

It is convenient to introduce some notation for this type of problems. I will write this as. max u (x 1 ; x 2 ) subj. to. p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 m ;

It is convenient to introduce some notation for this type of problems. I will write this as. max u (x 1 ; x 2 ) subj. to. p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 m ; 4 Calculus Review 4.1 The Utility Maimization Problem As a motivating eample, consider the problem facing a consumer that needs to allocate a given budget over two commodities sold at (linear) prices p

More information

MATH 51H Section 4. October 16, Recall what it means for a function between metric spaces to be continuous:

MATH 51H Section 4. October 16, Recall what it means for a function between metric spaces to be continuous: MATH 51H Section 4 October 16, 2015 1 Continuity Recall what it means for a function between metric spaces to be continuous: Definition. Let (X, d X ), (Y, d Y ) be metric spaces. A function f : X Y is

More information

Microeconomic Theory: Lecture 2 Choice Theory and Consumer Demand

Microeconomic Theory: Lecture 2 Choice Theory and Consumer Demand Microeconomic Theory: Lecture 2 Choice Theory and Consumer Demand Summer Semester, 2014 De nitions and Axioms Binary Relations I Examples: taller than, friend of, loves, hates, etc. I Abstract formulation:

More information

Last Revised: :19: (Fri, 12 Jan 2007)(Revision:

Last Revised: :19: (Fri, 12 Jan 2007)(Revision: 0-0 1 Demand Lecture Last Revised: 2007-01-12 16:19:03-0800 (Fri, 12 Jan 2007)(Revision: 67) a demand correspondence is a special kind of choice correspondence where the set of alternatives is X = { x

More information

Microeconomic Analysis

Microeconomic Analysis Microeconomic Analysis Seminar 1 Marco Pelliccia (mp63@soas.ac.uk, Room 474) SOAS, 2014 Basics of Preference Relations Assume that our consumer chooses among L commodities and that the commodity space

More information

Econ Spring Review Set 1 - Answers ELEMENTS OF LOGIC. NECESSARY AND SUFFICIENT. SET THE-

Econ Spring Review Set 1 - Answers ELEMENTS OF LOGIC. NECESSARY AND SUFFICIENT. SET THE- Econ 4808 - Spring 2008 Review Set 1 - Answers ORY ELEMENTS OF LOGIC. NECESSARY AND SUFFICIENT. SET THE- 1. De ne a thing or action in words. Refer to this thing or action as A. Then de ne a condition

More information

Chapter 2: Preliminaries and elements of convex analysis

Chapter 2: Preliminaries and elements of convex analysis Chapter 2: Preliminaries and elements of convex analysis Edoardo Amaldi DEIB Politecnico di Milano edoardo.amaldi@polimi.it Website: http://home.deib.polimi.it/amaldi/opt-14-15.shtml Academic year 2014-15

More information

Preliminary draft only: please check for final version

Preliminary draft only: please check for final version ARE211, Fall2012 CALCULUS4: THU, OCT 11, 2012 PRINTED: AUGUST 22, 2012 (LEC# 15) Contents 3. Univariate and Multivariate Differentiation (cont) 1 3.6. Taylor s Theorem (cont) 2 3.7. Applying Taylor theory:

More information

z = f (x; y) f (x ; y ) f (x; y) f (x; y )

z = f (x; y) f (x ; y ) f (x; y) f (x; y ) BEEM0 Optimization Techiniques for Economists Lecture Week 4 Dieter Balkenborg Departments of Economics University of Exeter Since the fabric of the universe is most perfect, and is the work of a most

More information

Preference and Utility

Preference and Utility Preference and Utility Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 3, 5 September Problem Set 1 is due in Kelly s mailbox by 5pm today Outline 1 Existence of Utility Functions 2 Continuous Preferences 3 Debreu s Representation

More information

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 6, September 14 Outline 1 Applications of Envelope Theorem 2 Hicksian Demand 3 Duality 4 Connections between

More information

Lecture Notes on Game Theory

Lecture Notes on Game Theory Lecture Notes on Game Theory Levent Koçkesen Strategic Form Games In this part we will analyze games in which the players choose their actions simultaneously (or without the knowledge of other players

More information

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Supermodular Games

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Supermodular Games 6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Asu Ozdaglar MIT February 25, 2010 1 Introduction Outline Uniqueness of a Pure Nash Equilibrium for Continuous Games Reading: Rosen J.B., Existence

More information

Analysis and Linear Algebra. Lectures 1-3 on the mathematical tools that will be used in C103

Analysis and Linear Algebra. Lectures 1-3 on the mathematical tools that will be used in C103 Analysis and Linear Algebra Lectures 1-3 on the mathematical tools that will be used in C103 Set Notation A, B sets AcB union A1B intersection A\B the set of objects in A that are not in B N. Empty set

More information

Gi en Demand for Several Goods

Gi en Demand for Several Goods Gi en Demand for Several Goods Peter Norman Sørensen January 28, 2011 Abstract The utility maimizing consumer s demand function may simultaneously possess the Gi en property for any number of goods strictly

More information

BEEM103 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER. BUSINESS School. January 2009 Mock Exam, Part A. OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions

BEEM103 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER. BUSINESS School. January 2009 Mock Exam, Part A. OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions BEEM03 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER BUSINESS School January 009 Mock Exam, Part A OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions Duration : TWO HOURS The paper has 3 parts. Your marks on the rst part will be

More information

1 The Well Ordering Principle, Induction, and Equivalence Relations

1 The Well Ordering Principle, Induction, and Equivalence Relations 1 The Well Ordering Principle, Induction, and Equivalence Relations The set of natural numbers is the set N = f1; 2; 3; : : :g. (Some authors also include the number 0 in the natural numbers, but number

More information

Immerse Metric Space Homework

Immerse Metric Space Homework Immerse Metric Space Homework (Exercises -2). In R n, define d(x, y) = x y +... + x n y n. Show that d is a metric that induces the usual topology. Sketch the basis elements when n = 2. Solution: Steps

More information

Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer November Theory 1, 2015 (Jehle and 1 / Reny, 32

Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer November Theory 1, 2015 (Jehle and 1 / Reny, 32 Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer Theory (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 1) Tsun-Feng Chiang* *School of Economics, Henan University, Kaifeng, China November 1, 2015 Week 7: The Consumer

More information

LECTURE 3 LECTURE OUTLINE

LECTURE 3 LECTURE OUTLINE LECTURE 3 LECTURE OUTLINE Differentiable Conve Functions Conve and A ne Hulls Caratheodory s Theorem Reading: Sections 1.1, 1.2 All figures are courtesy of Athena Scientific, and are used with permission.

More information

CHAPTER 7. Connectedness

CHAPTER 7. Connectedness CHAPTER 7 Connectedness 7.1. Connected topological spaces Definition 7.1. A topological space (X, T X ) is said to be connected if there is no continuous surjection f : X {0, 1} where the two point set

More information

U e = E (U\E) e E e + U\E e. (1.6)

U e = E (U\E) e E e + U\E e. (1.6) 12 1 Lebesgue Measure 1.2 Lebesgue Measure In Section 1.1 we defined the exterior Lebesgue measure of every subset of R d. Unfortunately, a major disadvantage of exterior measure is that it does not satisfy

More information

1 Uncertainty. These notes correspond to chapter 2 of Jehle and Reny.

1 Uncertainty. These notes correspond to chapter 2 of Jehle and Reny. These notes correspond to chapter of Jehle and Reny. Uncertainty Until now we have considered our consumer s making decisions in a world with perfect certainty. However, we can extend the consumer theory

More information

Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 5: Optimization Kuhn-Tucker conditions for problems with inequality constraints 1

Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 5: Optimization Kuhn-Tucker conditions for problems with inequality constraints 1 Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 5: Optimization Kuhn-Tucker conditions for problems with inequality constraints 1 Session: 15 Aug 2015 (Mon), 10:00am 1:00pm I. Optimization with

More information

A LITTLE REAL ANALYSIS AND TOPOLOGY

A LITTLE REAL ANALYSIS AND TOPOLOGY A LITTLE REAL ANALYSIS AND TOPOLOGY 1. NOTATION Before we begin some notational definitions are useful. (1) Z = {, 3, 2, 1, 0, 1, 2, 3, }is the set of integers. (2) Q = { a b : aεz, bεz {0}} is the set

More information

Metric Space Topology (Spring 2016) Selected Homework Solutions. HW1 Q1.2. Suppose that d is a metric on a set X. Prove that the inequality d(x, y)

Metric Space Topology (Spring 2016) Selected Homework Solutions. HW1 Q1.2. Suppose that d is a metric on a set X. Prove that the inequality d(x, y) Metric Space Topology (Spring 2016) Selected Homework Solutions HW1 Q1.2. Suppose that d is a metric on a set X. Prove that the inequality d(x, y) d(z, w) d(x, z) + d(y, w) holds for all w, x, y, z X.

More information

Assignment 3. Section 10.3: 6, 7ab, 8, 9, : 2, 3

Assignment 3. Section 10.3: 6, 7ab, 8, 9, : 2, 3 Andrew van Herick Math 710 Dr. Alex Schuster Sept. 21, 2005 Assignment 3 Section 10.3: 6, 7ab, 8, 9, 10 10.4: 2, 3 10.3.6. Prove (3) : Let E X: Then x =2 E if and only if B r (x) \ E c 6= ; for all all

More information

An Invitation to Convex Functions Theory

An Invitation to Convex Functions Theory An Invitation to Convex Functions Theory Constantin P. Niculescu 1 1 Partially supported by Grant CEX05-D11-36. ii Contents Introduction v 1 Background on Convex Sets 1 1.1 Convex Sets..............................

More information

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution)

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution) Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution) 1. Checking properties of the Cobb-Douglas utility function. Consider the utility function u(x) Y n i1 x i i ; where x denotes a vector of n di erent goods x 2 R n +,

More information

Partial Solutions to Homework 2

Partial Solutions to Homework 2 Partial Solutions to Homework. Carefully depict some of the indi erence curves for the following utility functions. In each case, check whether the preferences are monotonic and whether preferences are

More information

1 Selected Homework Solutions

1 Selected Homework Solutions Selected Homework Solutions Mathematics 4600 A. Bathi Kasturiarachi September 2006. Selected Solutions to HW # HW #: (.) 5, 7, 8, 0; (.2):, 2 ; (.4): ; (.5): 3 (.): #0 For each of the following subsets

More information

Continuity. Matt Rosenzweig

Continuity. Matt Rosenzweig Continuity Matt Rosenzweig Contents 1 Continuity 1 1.1 Rudin Chapter 4 Exercises........................................ 1 1.1.1 Exercise 1............................................. 1 1.1.2 Exercise

More information

Volume 30, Issue 3. Monotone comparative statics with separable objective functions. Christian Ewerhart University of Zurich

Volume 30, Issue 3. Monotone comparative statics with separable objective functions. Christian Ewerhart University of Zurich Volume 30, Issue 3 Monotone comparative statics with separable objective functions Christian Ewerhart University of Zurich Abstract The Milgrom-Shannon single crossing property is essential for monotone

More information

Almost Transferable Utility, Changes in Production Possibilities, and the Nash Bargaining and the Kalai-Smorodinsky Solutions

Almost Transferable Utility, Changes in Production Possibilities, and the Nash Bargaining and the Kalai-Smorodinsky Solutions Department Discussion Paper DDP0702 ISSN 1914-2838 Department of Economics Almost Transferable Utility, Changes in Production Possibilities, and the Nash Bargaining and the Kalai-Smorodinsky Solutions

More information

7) Important properties of functions: homogeneity, homotheticity, convexity and quasi-convexity

7) Important properties of functions: homogeneity, homotheticity, convexity and quasi-convexity 30C00300 Mathematical Methods for Economists (6 cr) 7) Important properties of functions: homogeneity, homotheticity, convexity and quasi-convexity Abolfazl Keshvari Ph.D. Aalto University School of Business

More information

Notes I Classical Demand Theory: Review of Important Concepts

Notes I Classical Demand Theory: Review of Important Concepts Notes I Classical Demand Theory: Review of Important Concepts The notes for our course are based on: Mas-Colell, A., M.D. Whinston and J.R. Green (1995), Microeconomic Theory, New York and Oxford: Oxford

More information