Inference on Trending Panel Data

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Inference on Trending Panel Data"

Transcription

1 Inference on rending Panel Data Peter M Robinson and Carlos Velasco London School of Economics and Universidad Carlos III de Madrid November 3, 15 Abstract Semiparametric panel data modelling and statistical inference with fractional stochastic trends, nonparametrically time-trending individual effects, and general cross-sectional correlation and heteroscedasticity in innovations is developed. he fractional stochastic trends allow for a wide range of nonstationarity, indexed by a memory parameter, nesting the familiar I1 case and allowing for parametric short-memory. he individual effects can nonparametrically vary simultaneously across time and across units. he cross-sectional covariance matrix is also nonparametric. he main focus is on estimation of the time series parameters. wo methods are considered, both of which entail an only approximate differencing out of the individual effects, leaving an error which has to be taken account of in our theory. In both cases we obtain standard asymptotics, with a central limit theorem, over a wide range of possible parameter values, and unlike the nonstandard asymptotics for autoregressive parameter estimates at a unit root. For statistical inference, consistent estimation of the limiting covariance matrix of the parameter estimates requires consistent estimation of a functional of the cross-sectional covariance matrix. We examine effi ciency loss due to cross-sectional correlation in a spatial model example. A Monte Carlo study of finite-sample performance is included. Keywords: Semiparametric panel data modelling, Nonparametrically timetrending individual effects, Nonparametric cross-sectional correlation and heteroscedasticity, Spatial model, Parametric fractional dependence, Consistency, Asymptotic normality. JEL classifications: C1, C13, C3... Corresponding author. el fax address: p.m.robinson@lse.ac.uk 1

2 1. Introduction A considerable literature has developed around the theme of nonstationary panel data with individual and temporal effects. he nonstationarity can have both stochastic and deterministic origins. Unit roots in an autoregressive setting have been the main representation of stochastic trends, while individual and temporal effects are often modelled in a separable, additive way, so that temporal effects are common over the cross-section and individual ones stay constant over time, and explanatory variables, including linear and other deterministic trends, can also feature. Autoregressive models are also commonly adopted in the nonstationary time series and cointegration literature. However, the latter has also developed fractional time series modelling, which can nest I1 behaviour in a continuum of nonstationary possibilities, with the degree of nonstationarity characterized by a memory parameter, which can be estimated from the data. his approach has the advantages of flexibility and of yielding standard asymptotics, and possible local effi ciency of inference, unlike the nonstandard theory which usually emerges from an autoregressive setting. Likewise, the fixed-design nonparametric regression literature suggests a modelling of deterministic trends which is less prone to specification error than parametric functions. Robinson and Velasco 15 employed fractional models with individual effects in a panel data setting, but with no provision for other time-trending features such as deterministic trends. Another aspect of their work was the assumption of crosssectional independence and homoscedasticity, conditional on individual effects, which is increasingly seen as restrictive, and sometimes replaced by factor modelling, or spatial modelling. he present paper considers semiparametric modelling of panel data, such that dynamic parametric fractional stochastic trends are complemented by stochastic or deterministic nonparametrically time trending individual effects and allowance for cross-sectional correlation and heteroscedasticity of a nonparametric form, entailing greater generality than factor or spatial models. he number of time series observations,, is large, and the number of cross-sectional ones, N, can be large increasing with or small. he latter setting is also considered by Robinson and Velasco 15, but our introduction of nonparametric temporal variation of individual effects and relaxation of cross-sectional independence and homoscedasticity strengthens the need for an asymptotic theory based on increasing. Large- panel data are increasingly available, for example very long time series of prices of several stocks, monthly or quarterly macroeconometric series for several countries, and repeated micro-economic surveys. We consider an observable array {y it }, i = 1,..., N, t =, 1,...,. he vectors of

3 N cross-sectional observations y t = y 1t,..., y Nt, the prime denoting transposition, are assumed to be generated by the semiparametric model λ t L; θ y t α t = ε t, t =, 1,...,. 1 he parametric aspect of 1 is due to the p parameter vector θ, which is known only to lie in a given compact subset Θ of R p+1. In 1 L is the lag operator, and for any θ Θ and each t, λ t L; θ is a scalar function given by λ t L; θ = t λ j θ L j, j= where the λ j θ are given functions to be defined subsequently. he unobservable vectors ε t have elements with zero mean and are uncorrelated and homoscedastic across t. hus, 1 is an autoregressive representation for the y t α t with initial condition at t =, where the number of terms in keeps increasing with t. he assumptions on λ t L; θ that we will impose are aimed at covering fractionally integrated autoregressive moving average FARIMA sequences y t α t, with unknown memory parameter that can lie in either the stationary or nonstationary regions. Other aspects of 1 are nonparametric. We do not require uncorrelatedness or homoscedasticity across the elements of ε t, allowing it to have covariance matrix that is unrestricted apart from remaining positive definite with increasing N, thereby to reflect possible crosssectional correlation and heteroscedasticity of a nonparametric nature, though it can also be assumed to be diagonal, to reflect a lack of cross-sectional correlation but the possibility of nonparametric heteroscedasticity. he vectors α t consist of stochastic or deterministic unobservable individual effects that can time-trend in a nonparametric way, and in a manner that can vary across elements of the vector, where with N increasing the familiar incidental parameters problem arises. Our allowance for temporally varying individual effects and cross-sectional correlation and heteroscedasticity of innovations, and our relaxation of temporal independence of innovations to martingale difference structure, extend the scope of the model of Robinson and Velasco 15 to a practically significant degree, but as a consequence reduces the range of memory parameter values covered and limits the degree to which N can increase relative to. he main goal of the paper is to justify statistical inference on the unknown parameter vector θ. Detailed regularity conditions, later employed in establishing the properties of consistency and asymptotic normality, are described in the following section. In Section 3 an estimate of θ, based on initial first-differencing of 1, is shown to be consistent and asymptotically normal, and feasible statistical inference is justified. In Section 4 a more refined estimate, with some advantages, is similarly 3

4 analysed. Section 5 employs a spatial model to illustrate relative effi ciency. A Monte Carlo study of finite-sample performance is reported in Section 6. Section 7 contains some final comments. he proofs of theorems are included in an appendix.. heoretical setting he present section presents detailed regularity conditions on the model introduced in the previous section, which will be assumed to hold in our theoretical results. he function λ t L; θ defined in is regarded as truncating the expansion λ L; θ = λ j θ L j, j= which has the structure λ L; θ = δ ψ L; ξ, where δ is a scalar, ξ is a p 1 vector, θ = δ, ξ and the functions δ and ψ L; ξ are described as follows. Defining the difference operator = 1 L, δ has the expansion δ = π j δ L j Γj δ, π j δ = Γ δγj + 1, j= for non-integer δ >, while for integer δ =, 1,..., π j δ = 1j =, 1,..., δ 1 j δ δ 1 δ j + 1 /j!, taking / = 1 and 1. to be the indicator function; ψ L; ξ is a known function of its arguments such that for complex-valued x, ψ x; ξ =, x 1 and is continuously differentiable in ξ, and in the expansion ψ L; ξ = ψ j ξ L j, j= the coeffi cients ψ j ξ satisfy ψ ξ = 1, ψj ξ + ψj ξ = O exp c ξ j, 3 where ψ j ξ = / ξ ψ ξ and c ξ is a positive-valued function of ψ. Note that λ j θ = j π j k δ ψ k ξ, j. 4 k= In general it is assumed that 3 holds for all ξ Ξ with c ψ satisfying inf Ξ c ξ = c >. 5 4

5 We impose the identifiability condition that, for all ξ ξ, ψ x; ξ ψ x; ξ on a subset of {x : x = 1} of positive Lebesgue measure. Define φ L; ξ = ψ 1 L; ξ = φ j ξ L j j= and χ L; ξ = θ log λ L; θ = log, / ξ log ψ L; ξ = χ j ξ L j, j= where the prime denotes transposition and χ j ξ = χ 1j ξ, χ j ξ, χ1j ξ = j 1, χ j ξ = j φ k ξ ψ j k ξ, k=1 with the φ k ξ given by k= φ k ξ L j = ψ L; ξ 1. hen define the p + 1 p + 1 matrix [ B ξ = χ j ξ χ π /6 ] j=1 j ξ = χ j ξ /j j=1 χ j ξ /j j=1 χ, j ξ χ j ξ j=1 and assume B ξ is non-singular. he conditions on ψ L; ξ are satisfied by the coeffi cients in stationary and invertible autoregressive moving average sequences, and the conditions on λ L; θ are satisfied by the coeffi cients in FARIMA sequences. he above setting is identical to that of Robinson and Velasco 15, but we extend their model in the following three respects. First, we relax their assumption of independence and identity of distribution of the unobservable elements ε it of the vectors ε t = ε 1t,..., ε Nt across t to martingale difference structure for levels and squares/products, in particular, almost surely, E ε it ε j,t s, s 1, j 1 =, i 1, t, 6 E ε it ε ij σ ij ε k,t s, ε l,t s, s 1, k, l 1 =, i, j 1, t, 7 where 6 implies E ε it =. We impose also the moment condition and the fourth cumulant condition sup t N i,j,k,l=1 supeε 4 it < 8 i,t cum ε it, ε jt, ε kt, ε lt = O N, 9 both of which are automatically satisfied if ε it is Gaussian. 5

6 Secondly, we relax their assumption of homoscedasticity and lack of correlation across elements of the vectors ε t, in allowing Eε t ε t = Σ N, t =, 1,...,, for an N N matrix Σ N = σ ij which is assumed to stay positive definite and have bounded elements with increasing N but is otherwise unknown, to reflect possible cross-sectional correlation and heteroscedasticity, or else is restricted to be diagonal, to reflect an assumed lack of cross-sectional correlation, but the possibility of heteroscedasticity. Since N is allowed to increase, Σ N can in either case be regarded as nonparametric. Specifically, we assume that where. denotes spectral norm, and existence of lim Σ N + Σ 1 N <, 1 N σ = lim N 1 N tr Σ N, 11 and of 1 κ = lim N N tr Σ N, 1 Of course N 1 tr Σ N Σ N while also, from the inequality tr ABB A A tr BB see e.g. Horn and Johnson 1988, p. 313, N 1 tr Σ N Σ N N 1 tr Σ N, so the first component of 1 implies σ + κ <, while the second implies σ >. Condition 1 effectively upper- and lowerbounds variances and mildly limits the extent of cross-sectional dependence. Under cross-sectional uncorrelatedness assumption 1 reduces to sup σii + σii 1 <. i Our final extension allows the α t = α 1t,..., α Nt in 1 to vary with t, being vectors of unobserved nonparametric possibly stochastic, and cross-sectionally dependent trending individual effects, such that α it = α i t/, for functions α i u which satisfy a possibly stochastic Lipschitz condition sup α i t α i t + u u as u. 13 i,t Here there is no exogeneity requirement on α i t, with no restriction on possible dependence with the ε it. However we find that if a strong exogeneity condition is imposed, and a related condition to 13 is added, we can slightly increase the range of values of δ covered and relax the restrictions on increase of N with. In particular: {α i t α i t + u, t, t + u, 1], i 1} is independent of {ε it, i 1, t } 14 6

7 and sup E α i t α i t + u = O u as u. 15 i,t Note that neither 13 nor 15 implies the other, though they are closely related. o illustrate these various conditions, suppose α i t has the formal separable infinite series representation α i t = β i + β ij g ij t, i 1, 16 j=1 where β i is completely unrestricted as it can be fully differenced out, the functions g ij t are nonstochastic, and the β ij can be random variables. hen since α i t α i t + u a suffi cient condition for 13 is sup i j=1 while the latter and sup E β ij <, i j=1 i β ij j=1 j=1 1/ g ij t g ij t + u β ij 1, sup g ij t g ij t + u = O u, j=1 { βij, i, j 1 } is independent of {ε it, i 1, t } are collectively suffi cient for 14 and 15. An example of 16 are polynomials in t, with degree and possibly-stochastic coeffi cients allowed to vary with i. In any case the trending individual effects are nonparametric, as in fixed-design nonparametric regression see eg Cai 7, though here they can be stochastic, and also the fact that there are N of them, where N like will be regarded as increasing in our asymptotic theory, lends a further nonparametric aspect. We can compare our approach with the familiar one see e.g. Hsiao 14 in which our α it is replaced by the addition of a separable individual effect and time effect, namely β i + γ t. hen first differencing, which is employed in the current paper, eliminates the individual effect β i completely, but not the time effect γ t. If, however we take γ t = γt/, for a Lipschitz continuous function γu, we obtain γ t γ t 1 1, which becomes small as diverges. We obtain the same error bound by differencing our α it given condition 13, but clearly they afford more generality than the additive β i + γt/, since our time trends can vary over individuals. It is thus possible that differenced estimation of θ that ignores the α it is more or less robust to their presence, and the extent of this will be examined below. he more specialised structure β i + γt/ was also employed by Robinson 1, but there the focus was on estimating the nonparametric function γu. Note that the dependence on of the α t in 1 implies that the y t form a triangular array but our notation suppresses reference to this fact. 7

8 3. First difference estimates We consider in the current section one of the estimates of θ proposed by Robinson and Velasco 15 in their more specialised model, with our goal being to achieve the same property of consistency as if α t were absent from 1 or constant over t and the elements of ε t were cross-sectionally uncorrelated and homoscedastic, and asymptotic normality with the same convergence rate as before but with a different asymptotic variance matrix, and also to justify feasible large sample inference. From 1 and 13 or 15 it follows that y t = v t + α it 17 = v t + O p 1, as, 18 where the final term on the right of 18 in fact represents a vector with elements that are O p 1 uniformly in i and t, and v t = λ 1 t L; θ α it, t =,...,. 19 For any θ Θ, we attempt to fully whiten the data by forming the N matrix Z θ = z 1 θ..., z θ, where z t θ = λ t L; θ 1 y t, t = 1,...,, with θ 1 = δ 1, ξ. From 7 of Robinson and Velasco 15 and 17 z t θ = λ t L; θ v t τ t θ ε + λ t L; θ 1 α it 1 where τ t θ = λ t 1; θ. We have λ t L; θ v t = ε t but our estimates will be based on as if the two error terms in 1 were absent, though our theoretical justification will take account of them. Define the set Θ = D Ξ, where Ξ is a compact subset of R p and D = [δ, δ], where δ > max, δ 1, δ <, and we assume that δ D. he feasibly bias-corrected difference estimate of Robinson and Velasco 15 is θd = arg min θ Θ LD θ 1 b D arg min θ Θ LD θ, where L D θ = 1 N tr Z θ Z θ, b D θ = B 1 ξ S τ τ θ S τχ θ, 8

9 S τ τ θ = τ t θ τ t θ, S τχ θ = where π t δ = / δ π t δ and τ t θ χ t ξ, τ t θ = θ τ t θ = [ t k= π k δ t k j= ψ j ξ t k= π k δ t k j= ψ j ξ ], 3 he basic objective function is of conditional sum of squares type, but corrupted by the second and third components on the right hand side of 1, whose presence will be accounted for in the theoretical development. Finally define heorem 3.1 As µ = κ /σ 4. θd p θ. 4 If also 14 and 15 are not imposed but 1 < δ 1 and N 1 δ log or δ > 1 and N 1, or if 14 and 15 are imposed with 1 < δ 4 1 and N 1 4δ log 4, as, N 1 θd θ d N, µ B 1 ξ. 5 he consistency 4 requires no further restriction on δ, beyond δ D, and no restriction on the rate of increase of N with. However, comparing with Robinson and Velasco s 15 heorem 5. for their much more special model, we restrict δ and N in order to achieve asymptotic normality 5, in particular requiring δ to take nonstationary values when the α t are not exogenous; this is due to bias produced by temporal variation in individual effects. In order to base statistical inference on heorem 3.1 we estimate B ξ by B ξd, with ξ D denoting the final p elements of θ D, and estimate µ by µ D = Ntr Σ N θd /tr ΣN θd, 6 where Σ N θ = 1 Z θ Z θ. 7 An analogous unrestricted estimate of the cross-sectional covariance matrix was considered by Robinson 1 in the context of a panel model with no autocorrelation. If instead we maintain cross-sectional uncorrelatedness we take Σ N θ = 1 diag Z θ Z θ. 8 9

10 heorem 3. Under the conditions of heorem 3.1, as, B ξd p B ξ, 9 µ D p µ, 3 with µ D given by 6 where Σ N θd is defined either by 7 or, if σ ij = for all i j, 8, N 1 1/ B ξd / µ D θd θ converges in distribution to a vector of independent standard normal random variables. 4. Pseudo maximum likelihood estimate based on first differences Our next estimate is the difference pseudo maximum likelihood estimate PMLE of Robinson and Velasco 15. Define the matrix, Ω θ = ω st θ, ω st θ = 1 s = t+τ s θ τ t θ, so that Ω θ is proportional to the exact covariance matrix of the vector ε i1 τ t θ ε i,..., ε i τ θ ε i, cf 1. Unlike in the difference estimate of the previous section we thus allow for the initial value effect in our estimation, though as there we attempt to incorporate cross-sectional correlation or heteroscedasticity only in studentization, not in the point estimation of θ, and we have to contend in the theory with the O p 1 error of differencing the α it in 1. We estimate θ by θp = arg min θ Θ LP θ, where Θ is as defined in the previous section and L P θ = Ω θ 1 σ θ, 31 in which. σ θ = 1 N tr Z θ Ω 1 θ Z θ. heorem 4.1 As, θp p θ. 3 If also 14 and 15 are not imposed but 1<δ 1 and N 1 δ log or δ > 1 and N 1, or if 14 and 15 hold with 3 8 < δ 1 and N 3 8δ log 4 + N 1 log, as, N 1 θp θ d N, µ B 1 ξ. 33 1

11 he cost of allowing temporal variation in individual effects is greater than with the difference estimates, especially as the corresponding result heorem 4.4 of Robinson and Velasco 15 imposed no restrictions on δ and N. Now define µ P = Ntr Σ N θp /tr ΣN θp 34 and denote by ξ P the final p elements of θ P. heorem 4. Under the conditions of heorem 4.1, as, B ξp p B ξ, µ P p µ, with µ D given by 34 where Σ N θp is defined either using 7 or, if σ ij = for all i j, 8, N 1 1/ B ξp / µ P θp θ converges in distribution to a vector of independent standard normal random variables. 5. Ineffi ciency of estimation In the limiting covariance matrix µ B 1 ξ in heorems 3.1 and 4.1, the factor µ = 1 when the ε it are homoscedastic and uncorrelated across i, but in general µ 1 so heteroscedasticity and/or cross-sectional correlation inflates the variance matrix in the limiting distribution by a scalar factor, relative to the outcome of Robinson and Velasco 15. Note also that µ D 1 whether it is based on either of the estimates 7 or 8 of Σ N. he potential ineffi ciency of our estimates, or equivalently the degree of invalidity of the inference rules which assume homoscedasticity and lack of correlation across i, can be examined by considering a specific model for ε t. he spatial moving average model is defined by ε t = I N + ρw η t, 35 where I N is the N N identity matrix, W is an N N user-chosen spatial weight matrix with zero diagonal elements, taken here to be symmetric and normalised such that W = 1, and correspondingly the scalar ρ satisfies ρ < 1, while the elements of η t are mutually uncorrelated with common variance ς. hus tr Σ N = ς tr I + ρw = ς N + ρ tr W, tr Σ N = ς 4 tr I + ρw 4 = ς 4 N + 6ρ tr W + 4ρ 3 tr W 3 + ρ 4 tr W 4, 11

12 and so Ntr Σ N tr Σ N = N N + 6ρ tr W + 4ρ 3 tr W 3 + ρ 4 tr W 4 N + ρ tr W = 1 + 4ρ Ntr W + 4ρ 3 Ntr W 3 + ρ 4 Ntr W 4 tr W N + ρ tr W 1 + 4ρ N tr W + ρtr W 3 N + ρ tr W. 36 his lower bound is 1 when there is no spatial correlation, ρ =, but in general 36 exceeds 1, noting that tr W + ρtr W 3 > even when 1 < ρ < since W 1 implies tr W 3 tr W, and 36 increases in ρ. A simple W, proposed by Case 1991, is W = I r B s, B s = s s 1 s I s, 37 where rs = N and 1 s is the s 1 vector of 1 s, representing r districts each containing s farms, so farms are neighbours if and only if they lie in the same district and neighbours are equally weighted. Since we have B s = s 1 s 1 s 1 s + I s, B 3 s = s 1 3 s 3s s 1 s I s, tr W = r s 1 s s + s = N s 1 1, tr W 3 = r s 1 3 s s 3s + 3 s = N s s 1, and the lower bound 36 becomes 1 + 4ρ s ρ s s ρ s 1 1 = 1 + 4ρ s 1 + ρ s s 1 + ρ 38 A lower bound for µ is obtained by letting N, and if s this tends to 1, but if s stays fixed the bound exceeds 1, and again increases with ρ. 6. Monte Carlo simulations In this section we report the results of a simulation study of the properties of our estimates in finite samples in the presence of cross-sectional dependence and trends. We extend a similar set-up of Robinson and Velasco 15, where only constant fixed effects and independent and identically distributed ε it, across both i and t, were employed. 1

13 We generate the ε t as the spatial moving average 35, where η t is N, I N and ρ =.5 or.9, while W is generated as in 37, setting r = 4 when N = 8 or r = 5 N > 8. We consider both a pure fractional model, so p = 1, θ = δ and ψ L; ξ 1, and a model with FARIMA1,δ, dynamics, so p = and θ = δ, ξ with ψ L; ξ = 1 ξl. We consider different choices of N, and θ. In particular we employ three basic values of N, namely 1,, 4 with two combinations of N and for each, to account for relatively short = 1, and moderate time series = 1, 5, 5, and also N = 96 for = 1. he range of values of N thus varies from 8 through from the smallest to the largest sample size. he values of δ include a stationary one δ =.3, which our theorems predict will be the most problematic from the point of view of bias, a moderately non-stationary one δ =.6, a value close to the unit root δ =.9, and a more nonstationary one δ = 1.. For FARIMA models we consider two autoregressive parameter values, ξ =.5,.8. Optimizations were carried out using the Matlab function fmincon with D = [.1, 1.5] and Ξ = [.95,.95], and the results are based on 1, independent replications. For all combinations of sample sizes and parameter values we report scaled empirical bias of both the feasibly bias-corrected difference estimate θ D and the PMLE θp, root-mean square error MSE and empirical size of the corresponding t or Wald test based on estimates of µ and B for the asymptotic variance as studied in heorems 3. and 4. "corrected" tests to account for cross sectional dependence, while we also report the empirical size for tests based on a pooled estimate of the variance of innovations, which would be only valid in case of uncorrelated homoscedastic innovations "uncorrected" tests. he results in ables 1-8 concern the pure fractional case, θ = δ. We first consider the case without trends, where constant fixed effects are exactly removed by first differencing. able 1 provides a bias comparison of the estimates of δ. In general bias is not affected by cross-sectional correlation compared with the results in Robinson and Velasco 15, who did not allow for such, and typically reduces with increase of δ and as expected. Bias of the difference estimate δ D for δ =.3 can be of an order of magnitude larger than in the other cases for the smallest for a given N, despite bias-correction having a large beneficial effect results without bias correction are not reported here. he PMLE δ P does much better in this diffi cult setup, but the difference for larger δ is much smaller. MSE results in able confirm the consistency of estimates, no clear superiority of any of the two estimates apart from the bias effect, and increase in the variance of estimates with cross-sectional correlation that is, with increasing ρ. he empirical size of the properly studentized t-test is sensitive to the 13

14 parameter and sample size values, though they converge with increasing N to the nominal value. In general, performance tends to deteriorate with the larger ρ and smaller δ, and PMLE-based tests do better than difference ones. ests not using consistent estimates of µ under cross-sectional correlation are systematically very oversized in all cases, cf. able 4. We repeat the experiment in ables 5-8 for ρ =.8 but with a linear trend specified as α i u = β i u cf 16, where the β i are generated independently from the N, γ distribution with γ = 1, 3 and our estimates are of course invariant to fixing a temporally constant component of the individual effects at zero. he larger value of γ can generate relatively large trends that can dominate the behaviour of the time series as shown by the bias and MSE results in ables 5 and 6, respectively. However, for the smaller γ, first differencing seems to account properly for the heterogenous deterministic component, though bias is substantially increased, as is MSE, for the small values of N and. In this case PMLE-based t-tests perform in a similar way as in the absence of trend for not too small and N and δ.6. In ables 9-14 we consider the results for the FARIMA model, again considering for only the value of ρ,.9. he estimation of δ is substantially affected by the autoregressive short run dynamic component, and the bias in able 9 can change sign with the value of δ and of, for ξ =.5, the results improving in most cases with increasing δ, while bias is always positive for the largest ξ,.8, so persistence is incorporated in the estimation of δ in finite samples. In general, the PMLE dominates bias-corrected difference estimates again. here is an overall increase in variability in able 1 compared to able, since both parameter estimates are highly correlated. Estimation results for ξ in ables 11-1 are parallel to the ones for δ : large bias for small N and δ, negative bias in all cases for ξ =.8, but no clear pattern for ξ =.5, and MSE decreasing with N, and δ. he feasible asymptotic inference results reported in ables 1 and 14 confirm previous ideas on the need for consistent estimation of µ to account for cross-sectional correlation, though now oversizing is more severe for the larger values of across the whole range of values of δ and ξ. 7. Final Comments In a semiparametric panel data model with fractional dynamics we have established desirable and useful asymptotic properties of estimates of time series parameters that are robust to nonparametric, time-varying individual effects and to cross-sectional correlation and heteroscedasticity, at the cost of restrictions on the range of possible 14

15 values of the memory parameter and the rate of increase of N with. Some further issues that might be considered are as follows. 1. As an alternative to our nonparametric estimation of the factor µ that inflates the limiting covariance matrix we could invest in a parametric model for the covariance matrix of ε t, such as a factor model see eg Ergemen and Velasco 14 or a spatial model cf. the discussion in Section 5. With a correct specification improved finitesample properties are likely to result, though a misspecified parameterization would lead to inconsistent estimation of µ and thus invalidate inferences based on heorems 3. and 4... Point estimates of θ that use either our nonparametric estimates of Σ N, or parametric ones such as just described, to correct for cross-sectional correlation/heteroscedasticity to the extent of being asymptotically effi cient in a Gaussian context, can be constructed. heir investigation would be worthwhile but likely entail a considerable amount of further work and possibly some further restrictions on δ and. 3. Whereas we impose the same dynamics over the cross-section, Hassler, Demetrescu and arcolea 11 developed tests in a panel with a fractional structure which is allowed to vary across units, and with allowance for cross-sectional dependence, but without allowing for individual effects and keeping N fixed as. In our context where N can increase it would be possible to keep the number of time series parameters fixed by assuming they are constant within finitely-many known cross-sectional subsets, over which the parameters can vary. 4. hough the nonstochastic conditional covariance matrix of innovations assumed in 7 is common in the time series literature, the implications of allowing for conditional heteroscedasticity could be explored. 5. Observable explanatory variables might be allowed to enter, in either a parametric or nonparametric way. In the former case, if they are linearly involved our differencing will leave only their first differences and initial value, but with nonlinear or nonparametric modelling we will get a difference of the functions, which structure, in the nonparametric case, needs to be exploited via additive nonparametric regression methodology in order to minimize a curse of dimensionality. Appendix Proof of heorem

16 o prove 4 we first prove consistency of arg min θ Θ L D θ. he proof of this extends that of heorem 3.3 of Robinson and Velasco 15 hereafter RV which uses their Lemma, which clearly still holds in our setting, and their Proposition 1, which needs extending because we have relaxed their iid assumption on ε it. First consider RV s A θ, and their U θ, which is defined as there but with σ defined in 11. A θ A θ U θ is 1 N N j ν jθ ε it σ ii + N j=1 t= N tr Σ N σ σ N j + 1ν jθ j=1 j 1 ν jθ σ j=1 j= +1 j 1 t ν j θν k θε i,t j ε i,t k j=1 k= ν jθ 39 there is a typo in the last term on p.449 of RV. As in RV j N sup ν Θ jθ ε N j it σ ii sup ν Θ jθ ε it σ ii, j=1 t= which is uniformly o p N much as in RV using also the proof of heorem 1 of Hualde and Robinson 11 6 and 8. he second term in 39 is uniformly o p 1 in much the same way, and the remaining terms are uniformly o1 from 11 and 5 of RV. Since from 1 L D θ = λ t L; θ v t τ t θ ε + λ t 1 L; θ 1 α t it remains to show that the term in α t contributes negligibly. First, sup λ t 1 L; θ 1 t 1 α t sup α t sup λ j θ 1 Θ t Θ j= N t 1 δ + 1 j=1 t= N 1 δ + 1 = o p N 4 as for δ >. Next using the Cauchy inequality, sup λ Θ t 1 L; θ 1 α t λt L; θ v t 1/ sup λ t L; θ v t sup λ t 1 L; θ 1 Θ Θ 1/ α t N 1/ o p N 1/ = o p N, 41 16

17 since the first term converges uniformly to a bounded function after standardization by N 1, while proceeding in a similar way, sup λ Θ t 1 L; θ 1 α t τ t θ ε 1/ 1/ sup τ t θ ε i sup λ t 1 L; θ 1 α t Θ Θ = o p N 1/ o p N 1/ = o p N. 4 hus consistency of arg min θ Θ L D θ is established, and thence straightforwardly 4, using smoothness properties of b D. he latter are also used, along with 4, in proving 5, as in RV s heorem 5., which incidentally required weaker conditions on δ and N than ours, so we do not repeat the details. But we have to extend RV s heorem 4.3 on arg min θ Θ L D θ bd θ to our setting, and this requires first extending the CL for scores in Proposition of RV. We can write their w as w = 1 N 1 N θ A i θ = 1 N 1 t 1 χ t j θ ε jε t. j= hus Ew w = 1 N = 1 N t 1 j= s 1 χ t j θ ε jε t ε sε k χ s k θ s=1 k= t 1 s 1 χ t j θ ε jσ N ε k χ t k θ = tr Σ N N j= k= t 1 χ t j θ χ t j θ. j= hen given 1 and much as in RV, w d N, κ B ξ. Apart from the extra terms discussed below the score and Hessian are handled much as in RV, where the latter has probability limit σ B ξ, with σ is as in 11. We consider first the extra terms in the score when 14 and 15 are not imposed. We have N 1 θ LD θ = N 1 ft ε τ εt t + λ t 1 L α t τ t ε + αt λ t 1 L, 17

18 where τ t = τ t θ, τ t = τ t θ, τ t θ = τ tθ θ, λ t 1 L = λ t 1 L; θ 1, λ t 1 L = λ t 1 L; θ 1 λ t 1 L; θ 1 = λ t 1 L; θ 1 t 1 θ, f t = ε t χ t j θ. he additional terms contributing to the asymptotic bias of N 1 are not covered in RV are thus N 1 + N 1 j=, θ LD θ that α t λ t 1 L εt τ t ε + ft ε N 1 τ t αt λ t 1 L α t λ t 1 L αt λ t 1 L. 43 Denoting λ j = λ j and thus N 1 θ 1 sup α it i,t, we have λ j = θ λ j θ 1 α t λ t 1 L εt τ t ε N 1 N 1 N 1 N N λ εt j τ t ε t 1 j= t 1 δ + 1 log t δ + log N 1 = O λ log j = O j δ log t, j 1 δ + 1 log which is o p 1 as N 1 δ log + N 1 log, with δ > 1. he second term in 43 can be bounded similarly, given E ft ε τ t = O N 1/. he third is O p N N 1 t 1 δ + 1 log t N δ + log N 1 which is o p 1 since N 1 4δ log + N 1. with δ > δ + 3/ log, Now impose 14 and 15. Let K denote a generic finite constant. From 14 the first term in 43 has zero mean because E [ε it ] = and, using 1, variance 18

19 bounded by K 3 Σ N t 1 δ + log t log t + K Σ N t 1 δ + log t t δ log t 3 = O 3 3 δ + log log + O = O δ + 1 4δ log 3 = o δ + log log since δ > 1, so is negligible, because 4 [ E λ t 1 L α it λ t 1 L α it ] E λ t 1 L α it t 1 = O E α it j δ log j j= = O t 1 δ + 1 log t. he second term in 43 can be bounded similarly, and the last term is N O p N 1 t 1 δ + log t log t N δ + log log N 1 1 δ + 3/ log log, which is o p 1 since N 1 4δ log + N 1 with δ > 1 4 Proof of heorem 3. Given heorem 3.1 and continuity of B ξ it suffi ces to prove 3. We give the proof only for 7 because that for 8 is simpler. From 11, µ D µ differs by o 1 from Ntr Σ N θd /tr ΣN θd Ntr ΣN /tr Σ N, which is Ntr Σ Ntr N Σ N θd Σ N /tr Σ N θd tr ΣN θd tr Σ N / 19 tr ΣN θd tr Σ N

20 so the result follows on showing that tr ΣN θd Σ N tr Σ N θd Σ N noting that 44 implies that tr We have Σ N θd Σ N = Now Σ N θ = 1 = o p N, 44 = o p N, 45 ΣN θd /N has a positive, finite probability limit. ΣN θd Σ N θ + ΣN θ Σ N. ε t + s t ε t + s t = A + R, where A = 1 t ε ε t, R = 1 s t ε t + ε t s t + s t s t, with s t = λ t 1 L; θ 1 α t τ t θ ε. hus tr ΣN θ Σ N = tr A Σ N + R. Since E ε it σ ii ε jt σ jj = σ ij + cum ε it, ε it, ε jt, ε jt, we have 1 Etr A Σ N = E εt tr Σ N = 1 E N N ε it σ ii ε jt σ jj using 1 and 9, since N. Also j=1 = 1 N σ ij + cum ε it, ε it, ε jt, ε jt i,j=1 = tr Σ 1 N N + cum ε it, ε it, ε jt, ε jt i,j=1 N = O = o N 1 tr R = tr s t ε t + ε t s t + s t s t,

21 where 1 s t λ t θ 1 = o p N, as, ε + λ t 1 L; θ 1 α t as in 4-4. Also 1 tr s t ε t 1 s t 1/ 1 1/ ε t = o p N from the above and the fact that the second factor in brackets is O p N. hus we have shown that tr ΣN θ Σ N = o p N. Next, from heorem 3.1 and for θ such that θ θ θd θ, tr ΣN θd Σ N θ = 1 zt θd zt θ = z t θ z t θ θd θ θ 1 z N 3 t θ z t θ 1/ θ.. 46 From 1, z t θ = ε t τ t θ ε + λ t 1 L; θ 1 α t = ε t + O p 1, and thus z t θ N. Next z t θ = λ t L; θ v t + τ t θε + θ θ λ t 1 L; θ 1 α t. As in RV the derivative with respect to δ dominates, and we have λ t L; θ v t θ K t N 1/ log j j δ δ 1 j=1 ε i,t j N 1/ t δ δ + 1 log t, while τ t θ = O log t t δ, λ t 1 L; θ 1 α t N 1/ t log j j δ j=1 N 1/ t. 1

22 hus from heorem 3.1 and with large enough and any ɛ > z t θ θ = O p N 1/ t ɛ + t ɛ δ N 1/ t ɛ, uniformly in t, and so z t θ θ N 1+ɛ. It follows that 46 is N 1+ɛ O p = O N 1/ 3/ p N 1/ ɛ 1/ = o p N, so tr ΣN θd Σ N θ = o p N. he proof of 44 is completed. Next, to establish 45 we have tr Σ N θd Σ tr N = ΣN θd Σ N ΣN θd + Σ N 1/ 1/ tr ΣN θd Σ N tr ΣN θd + Σ N, where tr ΣN θd Σ N = tr ΣN θd Σ N θ + Σ N θ Σ N tr ΣN θd Σ N θ + tr ΣN θ Σ N. Now tr ΣN θ Σ N = tr A Σ N + R tr A Σ N + tr R, where Etr A Σ N 1 = E tr ε t ε t Σ N = 1 E εt 4 tr Σ N + tr 1 E ε t 4 = 1 = O s=1 3tr N Σ N + N, i,j,k,l=1 s,,s t cum ε it, ε jt, ε kt, ε lt εs ε sε t ε t Σ N

23 from 1 and 9. hus tr A Σ N = o p N. From the proof of 44 it is readily seen that tr R = o pn, to complete the proof of 45. Proof of heorem 4.1 he proof of 3 extends that of RV s heorem 4.4, inspection of which indicates that it suffi ces to consider the additional term in L D θ σ θ beyond ones of the type considered in the proof of heorem 3.1, namely τ t θ λ t 1 L; θ 1 α it, 47 S ττ θ which comes from {z i θ τ θ} /S ττ θ. We can bound 47 by sup α it τ t θ t 1 j= λ j θ 1 sup i,t D,Ξ S ττ θ t δ t 1 δ + 1 sup D 1 δ δ + 1 sup D 1 δ δ + 1 so its contribution to L D θ σ θ is O p δ + 1 = o p 1 since δ >. he proof of 3 then follows straightforwardly from those of RV s heorem 3.4 and our heorem 3.1. o prove 33 we consider first the case where 14 and 15 are not imposed. We have first to bound the extra terms in σ θ depending on α it in the normalized score based on L D, namely N 1 S ττ { λ t 1 L α it + εit τ t ε i λ t 1 L α it } N We have N λ t 1 L α it N τ t λ t 1 L α it + τ t εit τ t ε i λ t 1 L α it.48 t 1 δ + 1 N 3 δ + N 1 δ + 1, 3

24 so its contribution to σ θ is O p δ +. Next S ττ N ε it τ t ε i λ t 1 L α it 1 N t 1 δ N δ +, which is O p N 1 δ + 1, so its contribution to σ θ is O p δ + 1. Finally 1 N τ t λ t 1 L α it S 1 ττ N t δ t 1 δ + 1 S 1 ττ N 1 δ + log S 1 ττ N 1 δ + log N 1 δ + N 1 δ + N log, so its contribution to σ θ is O p δ + 1 4δ + 3 log, as is that of S ττ N τ t εit τ t ε i λ t 1 L α it. Overall the contribution of the extra terms in σ θ to N 1/ / θ L P θ is O p N 1/ δ + 1 4δ + 1 N 1 δ + 3 8δ + 1 1/ = o p 1, since N 1 δ + N 1 and δ > 1, and they do not contribute to the asymptotic bias. With the notation [a t ] 1 meaning the 1 column vector with tth element a t, with respect to the contribution of θ j σ θ to / θ L P θ we have to consider the extra terms in z i θ = [z it θ ] 1 depending on λ t 1 L α it, N = N + N N N [ λ t 1 L α it ] [ λ t 1 L α it ] N 1 Ω 1 1 Ω 1 [ λ t 1 L α it ] 1 Ω 1 θ Ω j θ Ω 1 θ z i θ θ Ω j θ Ω 1 θ [ λ t 1 L α it ] 1 and those in ż i θ = [ż it θ ] 1 depending on λ t 1 L α it, N N [ λ t 1 L α it ] 1 Ω 1 θ ż i θ + N 4 θ Ω j θ Ω 1 θ [ ε it τ t ε i ] 1, 49 N [ ] λ t 1 L α it 1 Ω 1 θ z i θ. 5

25 Since Ω 1 θ = I τ τ, Ω j Sττ θ = τ j, τ + τ τ j,,where τ j, = τ j,1,..., τ j, and τ j,k = O k δ log k as k, the first extra term is N +O p N 3 t [ λ t 1 L α it ] 3 S 1 ττ S ττ 1 Ω 1 θ Ω j θ Ω 1 θ [ ] λ t 1 L α it 1 t 1 δ + 1 t δ t 1 δ + 1 t δ log t r t 1 δ + 1 t δ 3 1 δ + log log 1 4δ log + 3 log 3, while using E τ t ε it E τ t ε it t 1/ = [ σ S ττ 1 ] 1/ = O 1 δ + log 1, and similarly E τ t ε it = O 1 δ log + log, E τ t τ t ε i = O Sτ τ = O 1 δ log + log, the second one is N [ λ N t +O p t 1 L α it ] 1 Ω 1 θ Ω j θ Ω 1 θ [ ε it τ t ε i ] 1 t 1 δ + 1 t δ 1 δ log + log S 1 ττ S ττ t 1 δ + 1 t δ 1 δ log + log 1 δ + log 1 δ log + log 1 4δ log + log 3. heir joint contribution to N 1/ / θ L P θ is thus O p N 1/ 1 4δ log + log 3 t N 3 8δ log + 3 log 4 1/, 5

26 which is o p 1 under N 1 δ log + N 1 and δ > 1. he extra terms due to the new element in ż it θ = f it τ t ε i + λ t 1 L α it, where f it is the ith row of f t, are N N N N Sττ + ż it θ τ t λ t 1 L α it z it θ + ż it θ λ t 1 L α it λ t 1 L α it τ t z it θ τ t λ t 1 L α it τ t. 51 Using similar methods as before, the first term is O p t 1 δ + 1 log t = O p δ + 1 log. Next, since E z it θ τ t = O Sττ = O 1 δ + log, E ż it θ τ t = O Sτ τ = O S ττ log, the other terms are 1 O p t 1 δ + 1 t δ log t S Sττ ττ + Sτ τ t 1 δ + 1 t δ 1 1 δ + log log + 1 δ + log log δ + log log. hus the contribution to the standardized score of these two terms is O p N 1 δ + log log N 1 4δ + 3 log log 1, which is o p 1 since N 1 δ log + N 1 for δ > 1. proof when 14 and 15 are not imposed. his completes the Now imposing 14 and 15, we have first to reanalyze two terms in σ θ depending on α it in the normalized score based on L D, given in 48. Now N ε it τ t ε i λ t 1 L α it 6

27 has zero mean and variance bounded by K N Σ N t 1 δ t 1 δ + 1 t δ = O N 3 δ +, so it is O p N 1/ 1 δ + 1 Next, N S ττ, and its contribution to σ θ is O p N 1/ 1 δ + 3. has zero mean and variance bounded by τ t εit τ t ε i λ t 1 L α it KN t 1 δ + 1 KN + t 1 δ + 1 t δ Sττ S ττ = O N 3 δ log + 1+δ 1 {δ <1/} + log = O N 1 δ log + 1 log, so its contribution to σ θ is O p δ log + 1 log. Overall, the contribution of the extra terms in σ θ to N 1/ / θ L P θ is N 1 4δ O 1/ p + O p δ + 1 N +O p 3 8δ + log + 1 4δ log 4 1/ +O p N 1 4δ log + 1 log 1/, which is o p 1, since N 1 4δ log 4 + N 1 log and δ > 1, and they do 4 not to contribute to the asymptotic bias. Regarding the contribution of θ j σ θ to / θ L P θ, we need to reconsider the term in 49 N N [ λ t 1 L α it ] 1 Ω 1 θ Ω j θ Ω 1 θ [ ε it τ t ε i ] 1, which has zero mean and variance O N 1 4 S ττ t 1 δ + 1 t δ t = O N δ + log 1 δ + log log = O N 1 8δ log + 4δ log log 6, 7

28 so this term is O p N 1 8δ log + 4δ log log 6 1/. hen the joint contribution of all terms depending on the differenced trend to N 1/ / θ L P θ is thus O p N 3 8δ log log 8 1/ +O p 3 8δ log + 1 4δ log log 6 1/, which is o p 1 since N 3 8δ log 4 + N 1 log and δ > 3. 8 the term in 51 under 14 and 15: N fit τ t ε i λ t 1 L α it N Now consider has zero mean and has variance O N 1 4 t 1 δ + 1 log + t 1 δ + 1 t δ log = O N δ + log + δ + log log = O N 1 1 δ + 3 log + δ + log log, and a similar result holds for the term depending on ε it τ t ε i λ t 1 L α it, so the contribution to the standardized score of this first term is N O p 1 4δ + log 1/ +O p δ + log 1/ + O 1 4δ + 3 log log 1/, which is o p 1 since N 1 4δ log 4 + N 1 log for δ > 3, while the second 8 term is shown o p 1 as before. Proof of heorem 4. his straightforwardly extends the proofs of heorem 3. and heorem 4.1, and is thus omitted. 8

29 References Cai, Z., 7. rending time-varying coeffi cient time series models with serially correlated errors. Journal of Econometrics 136, Case, A.C., Spatial patterns in household demand. Econometrica 59, Ergemen, Y.E. and C. Velasco, 14. Estimation of fractionally integrated panels with fixed effects and cross-section dependence. Preprint UC3M. Hassler, U., M. Demetrescu and A.L. arcolea, 11. Asymptotic normal tests for integration in panels with cross-dependent units. Advances in Statistical Analysis 95, Horn, R.A. and C.R. Johnson, Matrix analysis. Cambridge University Press. Hsiao, C., 14. Analysis of panel data, hird Edition. Press. Cambridge University Hualde, J. and P. M. Robinson, 11. Gaussian pseudo-maximum likelihood estimation of fractional time series models. Annals of Statistics 39, Robinson, P. M., 1. Nonparametric trending regression with cross-sectional dependence. Journal of Econometrics 169, Robinson, P. M. and C. Velasco, 15. Effi cient inference on fractionally integrated panel data models with fixed effects. Journal of Econometrics 185,

30 able 1. Empirical bias 1. Iδ ρ =.5 ρ =.9 δd δp δd δp δ : N able. Empirical Root-MSE 1. Iδ ρ =.5 ρ =.9 δd δp δd δp δ : N

31 able 3. Empirical Size % Corrected 5% t-test. Iδ ρ =.5 ρ =.9 δd δp δd δp δ : N able 4. Empirical Size % Uncorrected 5% t-test. Iδ ρ =.5 ρ =.9 δd δp δd δp δ : N

32 able 5. Empirical bias 1. Iδ, ρ =.9, linear trend β i t/, β i IIN, γ. γ = 1 γ = 3 δd δp δd δp δ : N able 6. Empirical Root-MSE 1. Iδ, ρ =.9, linear trend β i t/, β i IIN, γ. γ = 1 γ = 3 δd δp δd δp δ : N

33 able 7. Empirical Size % Corrected 5% t-test. Iδ, ρ =.9, linear trend β i t/, β i IIN, γ. γ = 1 γ = 3 δd δp δd δp δ : N able 8. Empirical Size % Uncorrected 5% t-test. Iδ, ρ =.9, linear trend β i t/, β i IIN, γ. γ = 1 γ = 3 δd δp δd δp δ : N

34 able 9. Empirical bias δ 1. FARIMAξ, δ, ρ =.9. ξ =.5 ξ =.8 δd δp δd δp δ : N able 1. Empirical Root-MSE δ 1. FARIMAξ, δ, ρ =.9. ξ =.5 ξ =.8 δd δp δd δp δ : N

35 able 11. Empirical bias ξ 1. ARFIξ, δ, ρ =.9. ξ =.5 ξ =.8 P ξd ξδ ξd ξp δ : N able 1. Empirical Root-MSE ξ 1. FARIMAξ, δ, ρ =.9. ξ =.5 ξ =.8 ξd ξp ξd ξp δ : N

Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence

Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence Peter M. Robinson London School of Economics Based on joint work with Javier Hualde: Javier Hualde and Peter M. Robinson: Gaussian Pseudo-Maximum Likelihood Estimation

More information

1 Estimation of Persistent Dynamic Panel Data. Motivation

1 Estimation of Persistent Dynamic Panel Data. Motivation 1 Estimation of Persistent Dynamic Panel Data. Motivation Consider the following Dynamic Panel Data (DPD) model y it = y it 1 ρ + x it β + µ i + v it (1.1) with i = {1, 2,..., N} denoting the individual

More information

Nonparametric Trending Regression with Cross-Sectional Dependence

Nonparametric Trending Regression with Cross-Sectional Dependence Nonparametric Trending Regression with Cross-Sectional Dependence Peter M. Robinson London School of Economics January 5, 00 Abstract Panel data, whose series length T is large but whose cross-section

More information

Persistence Heterogeneity Testing in Panels with Interactive Fixed Effects. Yunus Emre Ergemen and Carlos Velasco. CREATES Research Paper

Persistence Heterogeneity Testing in Panels with Interactive Fixed Effects. Yunus Emre Ergemen and Carlos Velasco. CREATES Research Paper Persistence Heterogeneity esting in Panels with Interactive Fixed Effects Yunus Emre Ergemen and Carlos Velasco CREAES Research Paper 8- Department of Economics and Business Economics Aarhus University

More information

Short T Panels - Review

Short T Panels - Review Short T Panels - Review We have looked at methods for estimating parameters on time-varying explanatory variables consistently in panels with many cross-section observation units but a small number of

More information

Repeated observations on the same cross-section of individual units. Important advantages relative to pure cross-section data

Repeated observations on the same cross-section of individual units. Important advantages relative to pure cross-section data Panel data Repeated observations on the same cross-section of individual units. Important advantages relative to pure cross-section data - possible to control for some unobserved heterogeneity - possible

More information

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1 Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1 John C. Chao April 25, 2017 1 These notes are based in large part on Chapter 16 of Stock and Watson (2011). They are for instructional purposes

More information

A Test of Cointegration Rank Based Title Component Analysis.

A Test of Cointegration Rank Based Title Component Analysis. A Test of Cointegration Rank Based Title Component Analysis Author(s) Chigira, Hiroaki Citation Issue 2006-01 Date Type Technical Report Text Version publisher URL http://hdl.handle.net/10086/13683 Right

More information

Comments on: Panel Data Analysis Advantages and Challenges. Manuel Arellano CEMFI, Madrid November 2006

Comments on: Panel Data Analysis Advantages and Challenges. Manuel Arellano CEMFI, Madrid November 2006 Comments on: Panel Data Analysis Advantages and Challenges Manuel Arellano CEMFI, Madrid November 2006 This paper provides an impressive, yet compact and easily accessible review of the econometric literature

More information

A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED

A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED by W. Robert Reed Department of Economics and Finance University of Canterbury, New Zealand Email: bob.reed@canterbury.ac.nz

More information

Research Statement. Zhongwen Liang

Research Statement. Zhongwen Liang Research Statement Zhongwen Liang My research is concentrated on theoretical and empirical econometrics, with the focus of developing statistical methods and tools to do the quantitative analysis of empirical

More information

Lecture 7: Dynamic panel models 2

Lecture 7: Dynamic panel models 2 Lecture 7: Dynamic panel models 2 Ragnar Nymoen Department of Economics, UiO 25 February 2010 Main issues and references The Arellano and Bond method for GMM estimation of dynamic panel data models A stepwise

More information

Robust Backtesting Tests for Value-at-Risk Models

Robust Backtesting Tests for Value-at-Risk Models Robust Backtesting Tests for Value-at-Risk Models Jose Olmo City University London (joint work with Juan Carlos Escanciano, Indiana University) Far East and South Asia Meeting of the Econometric Society

More information

GMM estimation of spatial panels

GMM estimation of spatial panels MRA Munich ersonal ReEc Archive GMM estimation of spatial panels Francesco Moscone and Elisa Tosetti Brunel University 7. April 009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/637/ MRA aper No. 637, posted

More information

An estimate of the long-run covariance matrix, Ω, is necessary to calculate asymptotic

An estimate of the long-run covariance matrix, Ω, is necessary to calculate asymptotic Chapter 6 ESTIMATION OF THE LONG-RUN COVARIANCE MATRIX An estimate of the long-run covariance matrix, Ω, is necessary to calculate asymptotic standard errors for the OLS and linear IV estimators presented

More information

Applied Microeconometrics (L5): Panel Data-Basics

Applied Microeconometrics (L5): Panel Data-Basics Applied Microeconometrics (L5): Panel Data-Basics Nicholas Giannakopoulos University of Patras Department of Economics ngias@upatras.gr November 10, 2015 Nicholas Giannakopoulos (UPatras) MSc Applied Economics

More information

Panel Threshold Regression Models with Endogenous Threshold Variables

Panel Threshold Regression Models with Endogenous Threshold Variables Panel Threshold Regression Models with Endogenous Threshold Variables Chien-Ho Wang National Taipei University Eric S. Lin National Tsing Hua University This Version: June 29, 2010 Abstract This paper

More information

The properties of L p -GMM estimators

The properties of L p -GMM estimators The properties of L p -GMM estimators Robert de Jong and Chirok Han Michigan State University February 2000 Abstract This paper considers Generalized Method of Moment-type estimators for which a criterion

More information

DYNAMIC PANEL GMM WITH NEAR UNITY. Peter C. B. Phillips. December 2014 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1962

DYNAMIC PANEL GMM WITH NEAR UNITY. Peter C. B. Phillips. December 2014 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1962 DYNAMIC PANEL GMM WIH NEAR UNIY By Peter C. B. Phillips December 04 COWLES FOUNDAION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 96 COWLES FOUNDAION FOR RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSIY Box 088 New Haven, Connecticut 0650-88

More information

Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions

Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions William D. Lastrapes Department of Economics Terry College of Business University of Georgia Athens,

More information

Long-Run Covariability

Long-Run Covariability Long-Run Covariability Ulrich K. Müller and Mark W. Watson Princeton University October 2016 Motivation Study the long-run covariability/relationship between economic variables great ratios, long-run Phillips

More information

A nonparametric test for seasonal unit roots

A nonparametric test for seasonal unit roots Robert M. Kunst robert.kunst@univie.ac.at University of Vienna and Institute for Advanced Studies Vienna To be presented in Innsbruck November 7, 2007 Abstract We consider a nonparametric test for the

More information

Estimation of Dynamic Regression Models

Estimation of Dynamic Regression Models University of Pavia 2007 Estimation of Dynamic Regression Models Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia Factorization of the density DGP: D t (x t χ t 1, d t ; Ψ) x t represent all the variables in the economy.

More information

Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data

Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data Jeffrey M. Wooldridge / The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England Contents Preface Acknowledgments xvii xxiii I INTRODUCTION AND BACKGROUND

More information

Discussion of Bootstrap prediction intervals for linear, nonlinear, and nonparametric autoregressions, by Li Pan and Dimitris Politis

Discussion of Bootstrap prediction intervals for linear, nonlinear, and nonparametric autoregressions, by Li Pan and Dimitris Politis Discussion of Bootstrap prediction intervals for linear, nonlinear, and nonparametric autoregressions, by Li Pan and Dimitris Politis Sílvia Gonçalves and Benoit Perron Département de sciences économiques,

More information

Semiparametric Trending Panel Data Models with Cross-Sectional Dependence

Semiparametric Trending Panel Data Models with Cross-Sectional Dependence he University of Adelaide School of Economics Research Paper No. 200-0 May 200 Semiparametric rending Panel Data Models with Cross-Sectional Dependence Jia Chen, Jiti Gao, and Degui Li Semiparametric rending

More information

Testing Random Effects in Two-Way Spatial Panel Data Models

Testing Random Effects in Two-Way Spatial Panel Data Models Testing Random Effects in Two-Way Spatial Panel Data Models Nicolas Debarsy May 27, 2010 Abstract This paper proposes an alternative testing procedure to the Hausman test statistic to help the applied

More information

GMM, HAC estimators, & Standard Errors for Business Cycle Statistics

GMM, HAC estimators, & Standard Errors for Business Cycle Statistics GMM, HAC estimators, & Standard Errors for Business Cycle Statistics Wouter J. Den Haan London School of Economics c Wouter J. Den Haan Overview Generic GMM problem Estimation Heteroskedastic and Autocorrelation

More information

Gravity Models, PPML Estimation and the Bias of the Robust Standard Errors

Gravity Models, PPML Estimation and the Bias of the Robust Standard Errors Gravity Models, PPML Estimation and the Bias of the Robust Standard Errors Michael Pfaffermayr August 23, 2018 Abstract In gravity models with exporter and importer dummies the robust standard errors of

More information

Comparing Forecast Accuracy of Different Models for Prices of Metal Commodities

Comparing Forecast Accuracy of Different Models for Prices of Metal Commodities Comparing Forecast Accuracy of Different Models for Prices of Metal Commodities João Victor Issler (FGV) and Claudia F. Rodrigues (VALE) August, 2012 J.V. Issler and C.F. Rodrigues () Forecast Models for

More information

Lasso Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Parametric Models with Singular Information Matrices

Lasso Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Parametric Models with Singular Information Matrices Article Lasso Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Parametric Models with Singular Information Matrices Fei Jin 1,2 and Lung-fei Lee 3, * 1 School of Economics, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics,

More information

Supplemental Material for KERNEL-BASED INFERENCE IN TIME-VARYING COEFFICIENT COINTEGRATING REGRESSION. September 2017

Supplemental Material for KERNEL-BASED INFERENCE IN TIME-VARYING COEFFICIENT COINTEGRATING REGRESSION. September 2017 Supplemental Material for KERNEL-BASED INFERENCE IN TIME-VARYING COEFFICIENT COINTEGRATING REGRESSION By Degui Li, Peter C. B. Phillips, and Jiti Gao September 017 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO.

More information

Causal Inference Lecture Notes: Causal Inference with Repeated Measures in Observational Studies

Causal Inference Lecture Notes: Causal Inference with Repeated Measures in Observational Studies Causal Inference Lecture Notes: Causal Inference with Repeated Measures in Observational Studies Kosuke Imai Department of Politics Princeton University November 13, 2013 So far, we have essentially assumed

More information

The Generalized Cochrane-Orcutt Transformation Estimation For Spurious and Fractional Spurious Regressions

The Generalized Cochrane-Orcutt Transformation Estimation For Spurious and Fractional Spurious Regressions The Generalized Cochrane-Orcutt Transformation Estimation For Spurious and Fractional Spurious Regressions Shin-Huei Wang and Cheng Hsiao Jan 31, 2010 Abstract This paper proposes a highly consistent estimation,

More information

Least Squares Estimation of a Panel Data Model with Multifactor Error Structure and Endogenous Covariates

Least Squares Estimation of a Panel Data Model with Multifactor Error Structure and Endogenous Covariates Least Squares Estimation of a Panel Data Model with Multifactor Error Structure and Endogenous Covariates Matthew Harding and Carlos Lamarche January 12, 2011 Abstract We propose a method for estimating

More information

GARCH Models. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. December Rossi GARCH Financial Econometrics / 50

GARCH Models. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. December Rossi GARCH Financial Econometrics / 50 GARCH Models Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia December 013 Rossi GARCH Financial Econometrics - 013 1 / 50 Outline 1 Stylized Facts ARCH model: definition 3 GARCH model 4 EGARCH 5 Asymmetric Models 6

More information

Efficient Estimation of Dynamic Panel Data Models: Alternative Assumptions and Simplified Estimation

Efficient Estimation of Dynamic Panel Data Models: Alternative Assumptions and Simplified Estimation Efficient Estimation of Dynamic Panel Data Models: Alternative Assumptions and Simplified Estimation Seung C. Ahn Arizona State University, Tempe, AZ 85187, USA Peter Schmidt * Michigan State University,

More information

Non-linear panel data modeling

Non-linear panel data modeling Non-linear panel data modeling Laura Magazzini University of Verona laura.magazzini@univr.it http://dse.univr.it/magazzini May 2010 Laura Magazzini (@univr.it) Non-linear panel data modeling May 2010 1

More information

Semiparametric dynamic portfolio choice with multiple conditioning variables

Semiparametric dynamic portfolio choice with multiple conditioning variables Semiparametric dynamic portfolio choice with multiple conditioning variables Jia Chen Degui Li Oliver Linton Zudi Lu he Institute for Fiscal Studies Department of Economics, UCL cemmap working paper CWP07/5

More information

Bootstrap prediction intervals for factor models

Bootstrap prediction intervals for factor models Bootstrap prediction intervals for factor models Sílvia Gonçalves and Benoit Perron Département de sciences économiques, CIREQ and CIRAO, Université de Montréal April, 3 Abstract We propose bootstrap prediction

More information

Prof. Dr. Roland Füss Lecture Series in Applied Econometrics Summer Term Introduction to Time Series Analysis

Prof. Dr. Roland Füss Lecture Series in Applied Econometrics Summer Term Introduction to Time Series Analysis Introduction to Time Series Analysis 1 Contents: I. Basics of Time Series Analysis... 4 I.1 Stationarity... 5 I.2 Autocorrelation Function... 9 I.3 Partial Autocorrelation Function (PACF)... 14 I.4 Transformation

More information

Some Monte Carlo Evidence for Adaptive Estimation of Unit-Time Varying Heteroscedastic Panel Data Models

Some Monte Carlo Evidence for Adaptive Estimation of Unit-Time Varying Heteroscedastic Panel Data Models Some Monte Carlo Evidence for Adaptive Estimation of Unit-Time Varying Heteroscedastic Panel Data Models G. R. Pasha Department of Statistics, Bahauddin Zakariya University Multan, Pakistan E-mail: drpasha@bzu.edu.pk

More information

Proofs for Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators

Proofs for Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators Proofs for Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators Lars Peter Hansen University of Chicago March 8, 2012 1 Introduction Econometrica did not publish many of the proofs in my

More information

Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Time Series Models: A Score-Marked Empirical Process Approach

Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Time Series Models: A Score-Marked Empirical Process Approach Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Time Series Models: A Score-Marked Empirical Process Approach By Shiqing Ling Department of Mathematics Hong Kong University of Science and Technology Let {y t : t = 0, ±1, ±2,

More information

Estimation of the Conditional Variance in Paired Experiments

Estimation of the Conditional Variance in Paired Experiments Estimation of the Conditional Variance in Paired Experiments Alberto Abadie & Guido W. Imbens Harvard University and BER June 008 Abstract In paired randomized experiments units are grouped in pairs, often

More information

Nonparametric Cointegrating Regression with Endogeneity and Long Memory

Nonparametric Cointegrating Regression with Endogeneity and Long Memory Nonparametric Cointegrating Regression with Endogeneity and Long Memory Qiying Wang School of Mathematics and Statistics TheUniversityofSydney Peter C. B. Phillips Yale University, University of Auckland

More information

G. S. Maddala Kajal Lahiri. WILEY A John Wiley and Sons, Ltd., Publication

G. S. Maddala Kajal Lahiri. WILEY A John Wiley and Sons, Ltd., Publication G. S. Maddala Kajal Lahiri WILEY A John Wiley and Sons, Ltd., Publication TEMT Foreword Preface to the Fourth Edition xvii xix Part I Introduction and the Linear Regression Model 1 CHAPTER 1 What is Econometrics?

More information

Conditional Least Squares and Copulae in Claims Reserving for a Single Line of Business

Conditional Least Squares and Copulae in Claims Reserving for a Single Line of Business Conditional Least Squares and Copulae in Claims Reserving for a Single Line of Business Michal Pešta Charles University in Prague Faculty of Mathematics and Physics Ostap Okhrin Dresden University of Technology

More information

Labor-Supply Shifts and Economic Fluctuations. Technical Appendix

Labor-Supply Shifts and Economic Fluctuations. Technical Appendix Labor-Supply Shifts and Economic Fluctuations Technical Appendix Yongsung Chang Department of Economics University of Pennsylvania Frank Schorfheide Department of Economics University of Pennsylvania January

More information

The exact bias of S 2 in linear panel regressions with spatial autocorrelation SFB 823. Discussion Paper. Christoph Hanck, Walter Krämer

The exact bias of S 2 in linear panel regressions with spatial autocorrelation SFB 823. Discussion Paper. Christoph Hanck, Walter Krämer SFB 83 The exact bias of S in linear panel regressions with spatial autocorrelation Discussion Paper Christoph Hanck, Walter Krämer Nr. 8/00 The exact bias of S in linear panel regressions with spatial

More information

A Course in Applied Econometrics Lecture 4: Linear Panel Data Models, II. Jeff Wooldridge IRP Lectures, UW Madison, August 2008

A Course in Applied Econometrics Lecture 4: Linear Panel Data Models, II. Jeff Wooldridge IRP Lectures, UW Madison, August 2008 A Course in Applied Econometrics Lecture 4: Linear Panel Data Models, II Jeff Wooldridge IRP Lectures, UW Madison, August 2008 5. Estimating Production Functions Using Proxy Variables 6. Pseudo Panels

More information

GARCH Models Estimation and Inference. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia

GARCH Models Estimation and Inference. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia GARCH Models Estimation and Inference Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia Likelihood function The procedure most often used in estimating θ 0 in ARCH models involves the maximization of a likelihood function

More information

Asymptotic inference for a nonstationary double ar(1) model

Asymptotic inference for a nonstationary double ar(1) model Asymptotic inference for a nonstationary double ar() model By SHIQING LING and DONG LI Department of Mathematics, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Hong Kong maling@ust.hk malidong@ust.hk

More information

Asymptotic Distributions of Instrumental Variables Statistics with Many Instruments

Asymptotic Distributions of Instrumental Variables Statistics with Many Instruments CHAPTER 6 Asymptotic Distributions of Instrumental Variables Statistics with Many Instruments James H. Stock and Motohiro Yogo ABSTRACT This paper extends Staiger and Stock s (1997) weak instrument asymptotic

More information

GARCH Models Estimation and Inference

GARCH Models Estimation and Inference GARCH Models Estimation and Inference Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia December 013 Rossi GARCH Financial Econometrics - 013 1 / 1 Likelihood function The procedure most often used in estimating θ 0 in

More information

Regression with time series

Regression with time series Regression with time series Class Notes Manuel Arellano February 22, 2018 1 Classical regression model with time series Model and assumptions The basic assumption is E y t x 1,, x T = E y t x t = x tβ

More information

QED. Queen s Economics Department Working Paper No. 1244

QED. Queen s Economics Department Working Paper No. 1244 QED Queen s Economics Department Working Paper No. 1244 A necessary moment condition for the fractional functional central limit theorem Søren Johansen University of Copenhagen and CREATES Morten Ørregaard

More information

Economics Division University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK. Title Overlapping Sub-sampling and invariance to initial conditions

Economics Division University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK. Title Overlapping Sub-sampling and invariance to initial conditions Economics Division University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK Discussion Papers in Economics and Econometrics Title Overlapping Sub-sampling and invariance to initial conditions By Maria Kyriacou

More information

Robust Unit Root and Cointegration Rank Tests for Panels and Large Systems *

Robust Unit Root and Cointegration Rank Tests for Panels and Large Systems * February, 2005 Robust Unit Root and Cointegration Rank Tests for Panels and Large Systems * Peter Pedroni Williams College Tim Vogelsang Cornell University -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

More information

This chapter reviews properties of regression estimators and test statistics based on

This chapter reviews properties of regression estimators and test statistics based on Chapter 12 COINTEGRATING AND SPURIOUS REGRESSIONS This chapter reviews properties of regression estimators and test statistics based on the estimators when the regressors and regressant are difference

More information

Panel Data Models. Chapter 5. Financial Econometrics. Michael Hauser WS17/18 1 / 63

Panel Data Models. Chapter 5. Financial Econometrics. Michael Hauser WS17/18 1 / 63 1 / 63 Panel Data Models Chapter 5 Financial Econometrics Michael Hauser WS17/18 2 / 63 Content Data structures: Times series, cross sectional, panel data, pooled data Static linear panel data models:

More information

CALCULATION METHOD FOR NONLINEAR DYNAMIC LEAST-ABSOLUTE DEVIATIONS ESTIMATOR

CALCULATION METHOD FOR NONLINEAR DYNAMIC LEAST-ABSOLUTE DEVIATIONS ESTIMATOR J. Japan Statist. Soc. Vol. 3 No. 200 39 5 CALCULAION MEHOD FOR NONLINEAR DYNAMIC LEAS-ABSOLUE DEVIAIONS ESIMAOR Kohtaro Hitomi * and Masato Kagihara ** In a nonlinear dynamic model, the consistency and

More information

Identification and Estimation of Partially Linear Censored Regression Models with Unknown Heteroscedasticity

Identification and Estimation of Partially Linear Censored Regression Models with Unknown Heteroscedasticity Identification and Estimation of Partially Linear Censored Regression Models with Unknown Heteroscedasticity Zhengyu Zhang School of Economics Shanghai University of Finance and Economics zy.zhang@mail.shufe.edu.cn

More information

Lecture 5: Unit Roots, Cointegration and Error Correction Models The Spurious Regression Problem

Lecture 5: Unit Roots, Cointegration and Error Correction Models The Spurious Regression Problem Lecture 5: Unit Roots, Cointegration and Error Correction Models The Spurious Regression Problem Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20192 Financial Econometrics Winter/Spring 2018 Overview Stochastic vs. deterministic

More information

A Bootstrap Test for Causality with Endogenous Lag Length Choice. - theory and application in finance

A Bootstrap Test for Causality with Endogenous Lag Length Choice. - theory and application in finance CESIS Electronic Working Paper Series Paper No. 223 A Bootstrap Test for Causality with Endogenous Lag Length Choice - theory and application in finance R. Scott Hacker and Abdulnasser Hatemi-J April 200

More information

Christopher Dougherty London School of Economics and Political Science

Christopher Dougherty London School of Economics and Political Science Introduction to Econometrics FIFTH EDITION Christopher Dougherty London School of Economics and Political Science OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS Contents INTRODU CTION 1 Why study econometrics? 1 Aim of this

More information

IV Quantile Regression for Group-level Treatments, with an Application to the Distributional Effects of Trade

IV Quantile Regression for Group-level Treatments, with an Application to the Distributional Effects of Trade IV Quantile Regression for Group-level Treatments, with an Application to the Distributional Effects of Trade Denis Chetverikov Brad Larsen Christopher Palmer UCLA, Stanford and NBER, UC Berkeley September

More information

Long memory and changing persistence

Long memory and changing persistence Long memory and changing persistence Robinson Kruse and Philipp Sibbertsen August 010 Abstract We study the empirical behaviour of semi-parametric log-periodogram estimation for long memory models when

More information

Generalized Autoregressive Score Models

Generalized Autoregressive Score Models Generalized Autoregressive Score Models by: Drew Creal, Siem Jan Koopman, André Lucas To capture the dynamic behavior of univariate and multivariate time series processes, we can allow parameters to be

More information

Understanding Regressions with Observations Collected at High Frequency over Long Span

Understanding Regressions with Observations Collected at High Frequency over Long Span Understanding Regressions with Observations Collected at High Frequency over Long Span Yoosoon Chang Department of Economics, Indiana University Joon Y. Park Department of Economics, Indiana University

More information

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999) Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999) The question we are asking is: What are the consequences of a monetary policy shock a shock which is purely related to monetary conditions

More information

Single Equation Linear GMM with Serially Correlated Moment Conditions

Single Equation Linear GMM with Serially Correlated Moment Conditions Single Equation Linear GMM with Serially Correlated Moment Conditions Eric Zivot November 2, 2011 Univariate Time Series Let {y t } be an ergodic-stationary time series with E[y t ]=μ and var(y t )

More information

INFERENCE APPROACHES FOR INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLE QUANTILE REGRESSION. 1. Introduction

INFERENCE APPROACHES FOR INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLE QUANTILE REGRESSION. 1. Introduction INFERENCE APPROACHES FOR INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLE QUANTILE REGRESSION VICTOR CHERNOZHUKOV CHRISTIAN HANSEN MICHAEL JANSSON Abstract. We consider asymptotic and finite-sample confidence bounds in instrumental

More information

When Should We Use Linear Fixed Effects Regression Models for Causal Inference with Longitudinal Data?

When Should We Use Linear Fixed Effects Regression Models for Causal Inference with Longitudinal Data? When Should We Use Linear Fixed Effects Regression Models for Causal Inference with Longitudinal Data? Kosuke Imai Department of Politics Center for Statistics and Machine Learning Princeton University

More information

Darmstadt Discussion Papers in Economics

Darmstadt Discussion Papers in Economics Darmstadt Discussion Papers in Economics The Effect of Linear Time Trends on Cointegration Testing in Single Equations Uwe Hassler Nr. 111 Arbeitspapiere des Instituts für Volkswirtschaftslehre Technische

More information

Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo

Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo Karoll GOMEZ kgomezp@unal.edu.co http://karollgomez.wordpress.com Segundo semestre 2016 IX. Vector Time Series Models VARMA Models A. 1. Motivation: The vector

More information

Steven Cook University of Wales Swansea. Abstract

Steven Cook University of Wales Swansea. Abstract On the finite sample power of modified Dickey Fuller tests: The role of the initial condition Steven Cook University of Wales Swansea Abstract The relationship between the initial condition of time series

More information

B y t = γ 0 + Γ 1 y t + ε t B(L) y t = γ 0 + ε t ε t iid (0, D) D is diagonal

B y t = γ 0 + Γ 1 y t + ε t B(L) y t = γ 0 + ε t ε t iid (0, D) D is diagonal Structural VAR Modeling for I(1) Data that is Not Cointegrated Assume y t =(y 1t,y 2t ) 0 be I(1) and not cointegrated. That is, y 1t and y 2t are both I(1) and there is no linear combination of y 1t and

More information

ECON 4160, Lecture 11 and 12

ECON 4160, Lecture 11 and 12 ECON 4160, 2016. Lecture 11 and 12 Co-integration Ragnar Nymoen Department of Economics 9 November 2017 1 / 43 Introduction I So far we have considered: Stationary VAR ( no unit roots ) Standard inference

More information

1 Procedures robust to weak instruments

1 Procedures robust to weak instruments Comment on Weak instrument robust tests in GMM and the new Keynesian Phillips curve By Anna Mikusheva We are witnessing a growing awareness among applied researchers about the possibility of having weak

More information

The Functional Central Limit Theorem and Testing for Time Varying Parameters

The Functional Central Limit Theorem and Testing for Time Varying Parameters NBER Summer Institute Minicourse What s New in Econometrics: ime Series Lecture : July 4, 008 he Functional Central Limit heorem and esting for ime Varying Parameters Lecture -, July, 008 Outline. FCL.

More information

Online Appendix. j=1. φ T (ω j ) vec (EI T (ω j ) f θ0 (ω j )). vec (EI T (ω) f θ0 (ω)) = O T β+1/2) = o(1), M 1. M T (s) exp ( isω)

Online Appendix. j=1. φ T (ω j ) vec (EI T (ω j ) f θ0 (ω j )). vec (EI T (ω) f θ0 (ω)) = O T β+1/2) = o(1), M 1. M T (s) exp ( isω) Online Appendix Proof of Lemma A.. he proof uses similar arguments as in Dunsmuir 979), but allowing for weak identification and selecting a subset of frequencies using W ω). It consists of two steps.

More information

When Should We Use Linear Fixed Effects Regression Models for Causal Inference with Longitudinal Data?

When Should We Use Linear Fixed Effects Regression Models for Causal Inference with Longitudinal Data? When Should We Use Linear Fixed Effects Regression Models for Causal Inference with Longitudinal Data? Kosuke Imai Princeton University Asian Political Methodology Conference University of Sydney Joint

More information

Timevarying VARs. Wouter J. Den Haan London School of Economics. c Wouter J. Den Haan

Timevarying VARs. Wouter J. Den Haan London School of Economics. c Wouter J. Den Haan Timevarying VARs Wouter J. Den Haan London School of Economics c Wouter J. Den Haan Time-Varying VARs Gibbs-Sampler general idea probit regression application (Inverted Wishart distribution Drawing from

More information

11. Bootstrap Methods

11. Bootstrap Methods 11. Bootstrap Methods c A. Colin Cameron & Pravin K. Trivedi 2006 These transparencies were prepared in 20043. They can be used as an adjunct to Chapter 11 of our subsequent book Microeconometrics: Methods

More information

Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters

Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters Thomas MaCurdy a and Xiaohong Chen b and Han Hong c Introduction Many empirical studies of program evaluations are complicated by the presence of both

More information

Introduction to Econometrics

Introduction to Econometrics Introduction to Econometrics T H I R D E D I T I O N Global Edition James H. Stock Harvard University Mark W. Watson Princeton University Boston Columbus Indianapolis New York San Francisco Upper Saddle

More information

Testing for Unit Roots with Cointegrated Data

Testing for Unit Roots with Cointegrated Data Discussion Paper No. 2015-57 August 19, 2015 http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers/2015-57 Testing for Unit Roots with Cointegrated Data W. Robert Reed Abstract This paper demonstrates

More information

On Perron s Unit Root Tests in the Presence. of an Innovation Variance Break

On Perron s Unit Root Tests in the Presence. of an Innovation Variance Break Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 3, 2009, no. 27, 1341-1360 On Perron s Unit Root ests in the Presence of an Innovation Variance Break Amit Sen Department of Economics, 3800 Victory Parkway Xavier University,

More information

Testing Restrictions and Comparing Models

Testing Restrictions and Comparing Models Econ. 513, Time Series Econometrics Fall 00 Chris Sims Testing Restrictions and Comparing Models 1. THE PROBLEM We consider here the problem of comparing two parametric models for the data X, defined by

More information

Testing an Autoregressive Structure in Binary Time Series Models

Testing an Autoregressive Structure in Binary Time Series Models ömmföäflsäafaäsflassflassflas ffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffff Discussion Papers Testing an Autoregressive Structure in Binary Time Series Models Henri Nyberg University of Helsinki and HECER Discussion

More information

Time Series Models and Inference. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley

Time Series Models and Inference. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Time Series Models and Inference James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Overview In contrast to the classical linear regression model, in which the components of the

More information

ASYMPTOTIC NORMALITY OF THE QMLE ESTIMATOR OF ARCH IN THE NONSTATIONARY CASE

ASYMPTOTIC NORMALITY OF THE QMLE ESTIMATOR OF ARCH IN THE NONSTATIONARY CASE Econometrica, Vol. 7, No. March, 004), 4 4 ASYMPOIC NORMALIY OF HE QMLE ESIMAOR OF ARCH IN HE NONSAIONARY CASE BY SØREN OLVER JENSEN AND ANDERS RAHBEK We establish consistency and asymptotic normality

More information

Econometrics of Panel Data

Econometrics of Panel Data Econometrics of Panel Data Jakub Mućk Meeting # 6 Jakub Mućk Econometrics of Panel Data Meeting # 6 1 / 36 Outline 1 The First-Difference (FD) estimator 2 Dynamic panel data models 3 The Anderson and Hsiao

More information

The Role of "Leads" in the Dynamic Title of Cointegrating Regression Models. Author(s) Hayakawa, Kazuhiko; Kurozumi, Eiji

The Role of Leads in the Dynamic Title of Cointegrating Regression Models. Author(s) Hayakawa, Kazuhiko; Kurozumi, Eiji he Role of "Leads" in the Dynamic itle of Cointegrating Regression Models Author(s) Hayakawa, Kazuhiko; Kurozumi, Eiji Citation Issue 2006-12 Date ype echnical Report ext Version publisher URL http://hdl.handle.net/10086/13599

More information

Dynamic Discrete Choice Structural Models in Empirical IO

Dynamic Discrete Choice Structural Models in Empirical IO Dynamic Discrete Choice Structural Models in Empirical IO Lecture 4: Euler Equations and Finite Dependence in Dynamic Discrete Choice Models Victor Aguirregabiria (University of Toronto) Carlos III, Madrid

More information

High Dimensional Empirical Likelihood for Generalized Estimating Equations with Dependent Data

High Dimensional Empirical Likelihood for Generalized Estimating Equations with Dependent Data High Dimensional Empirical Likelihood for Generalized Estimating Equations with Dependent Data Song Xi CHEN Guanghua School of Management and Center for Statistical Science, Peking University Department

More information

Econometrics of Panel Data

Econometrics of Panel Data Econometrics of Panel Data Jakub Mućk Meeting # 1 Jakub Mućk Econometrics of Panel Data Meeting # 1 1 / 31 Outline 1 Course outline 2 Panel data Advantages of Panel Data Limitations of Panel Data 3 Pooled

More information

Nonparametric Time-Varying Coefficient Panel Data Models with Fixed Effects

Nonparametric Time-Varying Coefficient Panel Data Models with Fixed Effects The University of Adelaide School of Economics Research Paper No. 2010-08 May 2010 Nonparametric Time-Varying Coefficient Panel Data Models with Fixed Effects Degui Li, Jia Chen, and Jiti Gao Nonparametric

More information

If we want to analyze experimental or simulated data we might encounter the following tasks:

If we want to analyze experimental or simulated data we might encounter the following tasks: Chapter 1 Introduction If we want to analyze experimental or simulated data we might encounter the following tasks: Characterization of the source of the signal and diagnosis Studying dependencies Prediction

More information