Nonparametric Trending Regression with Cross-Sectional Dependence

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Nonparametric Trending Regression with Cross-Sectional Dependence"

Transcription

1 Nonparametric Trending Regression with Cross-Sectional Dependence Peter M. Robinson London School of Economics January 5, 00 Abstract Panel data, whose series length T is large but whose cross-section size N need not be, are assumed to have a common time trend. The time trend is of unknown form, the model includes additive, unknown, individual-speci c components, and we allow for spatial or other cross-sectional dependence and/or heteroscedasticity. A simple smoothed nonparametric trend estimate is shown to be dominated by an estimate which exploits the availability of cross-sectional data. Asymptotically optimal choices of bandwidth are justi ed for both estimates. Feasible optimal bandwidths, and feasible optimal trend estimates, are asymptotically justi ed, the nite sample performance of the latter being examined in a Monte Carlo study. A number of potential extensions are discussed. JEL Classi cations: C3; C4; C3 Keywords: Panel data; nonparametric time trend; cross-sectional dependence; generalized least squares; optimal bandwidth Tel ; fax: address: p.m.robinson@lse.ac.uk

2 . INTRODUCTION Much econometric modelling of nonstationary time series employs deterministic trending functions that are polynomial, indeed frequently linear. However the penalties of mis-specifying parametric functions are well appreciated, and nonparametric modelling is increasingly widely accepted, at least in samples of reasonable size. The inability of polynomials to satisfactorily globally approximate general functions of time deters study of polynomial functions whose order increases slowly with sample size, and rather leads one to consider the possibility of a smooth trend mapped into the unit interval and approximated by a smoothed kernel regression. For example, Starica and Granger (005) employed this approach in modelling series of stock prices. There is a huge literature on such xed-design nonparametric regression, principally in the setting of a single time series. Here we are concerned with panel data, where N series of length ave a common, nonparametric, time trend but also additive, xed, individual e ects, for which we have to correct before being able to form a trend estimate. We assume an asymptotic framework in which T is large; but not necessarily N; so that the cross-sectional mean at a given time point is not necessarily consistent for the trend, hence the recourse to smoothed nonparametric regression. A major feature of the paper is concern for possible cross-sectional correlation and/or heteroscedasticity. These in uence the asymptotic variance of our trend estimate, and thence also the mean squared error and consequent optimal rules for bandwidth choice. The availability of crosssectional data enables us to propose a trend estimate, based on the generalized least squares principle, that reduces the asymptotic variance. This estimate, along with its asymptotic variance (and that of the original trend estimate), depends on the cross-sectional covariance matrix. In general this is not wholly known, and possibly not known at all. Using residuals from the tted trend, we consistently estimate

3 its elements, so as to obtain a feasible improved trend estimate, and a consistent estimate of its variance, as well as feasible optimal bandwidths that are asymptotically equivalent to the infeasible versions. These results are valid with N remaining xed as T increases, and they continue to hold if N is also allowed to increase, in which case there is a faster rate of convergence, and in this latter situation our results hold irrespective of whether or not the covariance matrix is nitely parameterized. Section describes the basic model. In Section 3 we present a simple trend estimate and its mean squared error properties. Improved estimation is discussed in Section 4. In Section 5 optimal bandwidths are reported. Section 6 suggests estimates of the cross-sectional covariance matrix, with asymptotic justi ication for their insertion in the optimal bandwidths and improved trend estimates. Section 7 suggests some directions for further research. Proof details may be found in two appendices.. PANEL DATA NONPARAMETRIC MODEL We observe y it, i = ; :::; N, t = ; :::; T, generated by y it = i + t + x it ; (.) where the i and t are unknown constants, and the x it are unobservable zero-mean random variables, uncorrelated and homoscedastic across time, but possibly correlated and heteroscedastic over the cross section. Thus we impose Assumption For all i; t, E(x it ) = 0; (.) for all i; j; t there exist nite constants! ij such that E (x it x jt ) =! ij ; (.3) and for all i; j; t; u, E (x it x ju ) = 0; t 6= u: (.4) 3

4 Our focus is on estimating the time trend. Super cially this is represented in (.) by t, but the i and t are identi ed only up to location shift. To resolve this problem we initially impose the (arbitrary) restriction NX i = 0: (.5) i= An immediate consequence of (.5) is the relationship y At = t + x At ; (.6) de ning the cross-sectional means x At = N N X X N x it ; y At = N y it : (.7) i= i= We use the A subscript to denote averaging, in (.7) with respect to i and subsequently also with respect to t. In view of (.) an obvious estimate of t is thus t = y At : (.8) This can be a good estimate if N is large. For any xed t, it is trivially seen that t is mean-square consistent for t if lim N!N NX NX! ij = 0: (.9) i= j= Condition (.9) is trivially satis ed if the x it are uncorrelated over i, but more generally if cross-sectional dependence is limited by the condition lim N! N NX NX! ij < : (.0) i= j= We mention (.0) because it is analogous to a common weak dependence condition for time series, indeed it would correspond to an extension of the latter condition to stationary spatial lattice processes. Also (.0) is slightly weaker than Condition C.3 4

5 of Bai and Ng (00), in a di erent panel data context. The more general condition (.9) permits a type of cross-sectional long range dependence. While it can also cover certain models including additive factors, (.9) does not, however, hold for factor models in which the x it, for all i, are in uenced by the same factor or factors. For this reason, and because we do not wish to model the t in terms of nitely many parameters (as would be the case for a polynomial trend, say), we use nonparametric smoothing across time which requires T to be large, but not necessarily N. In order to achieve consistent estimates we assume the existence of a function (), 0, that is suitably smooth, such that t = (t=t ); t = ; :::; T: (.) The T -dependent argument in (.) enables information to be borrowed so as to permit consistent estimation of () for any xed as T!. Thus t, and hence in turn y it, should be regarded as triangular arrays, i.e. t = tt, y it = y itt, but for ease of notation we suppress reference to the T -subscript. Also, though our work is relevant in part to the case of a xed N (as T! ), we also allow N! (slowly, as T! ). In the latter circumstances, the i should also be regarded as triangular arrays, i = in, in view of the restriction (.5), and this would imply dependence of the y it on N also, though again we suppress reference to an N subscript. In terms of practical applications, on the other hand, one envisages data for which T is much larger than N, one example being many frequent time series observations on a relatively modest number of stock prices. Smoothed nonparametric estimation has been considered previously in a panel data setting. For example, Ruckstuhl, Welsh and Carroll (000) considered a model in which t is replaced by a nonparametric function of a stochastic explanatory variable, which can vary across both i and t, the i are stochastic, and independent and homoscedastic across i; t, and N is xed. Thus there is an explicit factor structure 5

6 built in, with no other source of cross-sectional dependence (and no heteroscedasticity). We discuss a factor structure for x it but as a special case only, and here as elsewhere we consider the possibility that N, like T; diverges. Also, Hart and Wehrly (986) considered the special case of (.) with no individual-speci c e ects, i.e. i 0, and with no cross-sectional correlation or heteroscedasticity. A deterministic nonparametric trend also features in the panel data partly linear semiparametric regression models considered by Severini and Stanisvalis (994), Moyeed and Diggle (994), for example. 3. SIMPLE TREND ESTIMATION We introduce a kernel function k(u), < u <, satisfying Z k(u)du = ; (3.) and a positive scalar bandwidth h = h T. Then with the abbreviation T t k t = k ; (3.) de ne the estimate ~() = k t y At = t= k t ; (0; ): (3.3) t= Important measures of goodness of nonparametric estimates, which lead to optimal choices of bandwidth h, are mean squared error, i.e. and mean integrated squared error, i.e. n o n o MSE ~() = E ~() () ; (3.4) n o MISE ~ = Z 0 E n ~(u) (u) o du: (3.5) 6

7 To approximate these we require conditions on ; k and h. Assumption () is twice continuously di erentiable, 0. Assumption 3 k(u) satis es (3.) and is even, non-negative, and twice boundedly di erentiable at all but possibly nitely many points, k(u) and its derivative k 0 (u) = (d=du)k(u) satisfying k(u) = O ( + u 4 ), k 0 (u) = O ( + juj c ) ; some c > : (3.6) Assumption 4 As T! h + ()! 0: (3.7) The smoothness condition on in Assumption could be relaxed at cost of inferior optimal rates of convergence, or on the other hand strengthened, which would lead to better rates if Assumption 3 were modi ed to permit higher order kernels; in any case the non-negativity condition on k is imposed only to simplify proofs. Assumption 4 is as usual a minimal condition for consistent estimation. De ne the N N cross-sectional disturbance covariance matrix ; having (i; j) th element! ij (see Assumption ), de ne by ` the N vector of s, and also de ne = Z k (u)du; = Z u k(u)du; (3.8) () = 00 (), = Z 00 (u) du; (3.9) where 00 (u) = (d =du ) (u): 0 Assumption 5 () > 0, > 0: 7

8 Theorem Let Assumptions -5 hold. Then as T! n o MSE ~() n o MISE ~ `0` N + () h 4 ; 4 (3.0) `0` N + h 4 : 4 (3.) Theorem contains nothing new in itself, for xed N; `0`=N being just the variance of the dependent variable y At in the nonparametric regression. Versions of this result were given long ago, e.g. by Benedetti (977), though conditions employed in Theorem are essentially taken from Robinson (997), and no proof is required. Hart and Wehrly (986) also considered nonparametric regression of cross-sectional means in a panel data setting, but without allowing for individual-speci c e ects. However, the availability of cross-sectional data o ers the possibility of improved estimation, in terms of variance-reduction, as explored in the following section. 4. IMPROVED TREND ESTIMATION Improved estimation of the trend requires it to be identi ed in a di erent way from that in Section, in particular to shift its location. Consider the representation y it = (w) i + (w) t + x it ; (4.) where the bracketed superscript w represents a vector w = (w ; :::; w n ) 0 of weights, such that w 0` = ; (4.) w 0 (w) = 0; (4.3) where ` is a N vector of s. This represents a generalisation of (.), (.5), in which w = (=N; :::; =N) 0. It is convenient to write (4.), for i = ; :::; N, in 8

9 N-dimensional column vector form as where (w) = 6 4 (w). (w) N y t = (w) + (w) t ` + x t ; (4.4) ; x t = 6 4 x t. x Nt ; y t = 6 4 For given w consider a smooth function (w) () such that (w) t two weight vectors w a ; w b we have y t. y Nt : (4.5) = (w) (t=t ). For any (wa) + (wa) ()` = (w b) + () (w b)`: (4.6) Thus (w b) () = (wa) () + w 0 b (wa) ; (4.7) (w b) = (wa) + (wa) () (wb) () ` where I N is the N N identity matrix. The location shift in (w b) t = (I N `w 0 b) (wa) ; (4.8) relative to (wa) t is thus +w 0 b (wa) (and that in (w b) i relative to (wa) i is w 0 b (wa), for each i). However, the time trend is scale- and shape-invariant to choice of w. Moreover, de ning the estimate e (w) () = k t w 0 y :t = t= we have, with as de ned in Section, n o E ~ (w) () (w) () = = t= k t ; (4.9) t= n (w) (t=t ) o (w) () k t = f(t=t ) ()g k t = t= 9 t= k t k t (4.0) t=

10 for any w, so bias is invariant to w. Thus, n o n MSE ~ (w) () = E ~ (w) () ()o (w) (4.) and MISE n ~ (w) o = Z E n ~ (w) (u) (w) (u)o du (4.) 0 are a ected by w only through the variance. This is approximated by the leading term on the right sides of (4.3) and (4.4) in Theorem below, which requires the additional Assumption 6 is non-singular. Theorem Let Assumptions -6 hold. Then as T!, n o MSE ~ (w) () (w0 w) n o MISE ~ (w) (w0 w) + h4 (); (4.3) 4 + h4 : (4.4) 4 Again no proof is needed. The bias contributions in Theorems and are identical as discussed above, or alternatively due to and having identical second derivatives. The right hand sides of (4.3) and (4.4) are minimized, subject to (4.), by w = w, where w = `0 `; (4.5) For notational ease denote () = (w) () = () + (`0 )=(`0 `); ~() = ~ (w ) (). Disregarding the vertical shift, ~() can be said to be at least as good an estimate as ~ (). We have w 0 w = `0 ` : (4.6) 0

11 Thus the asymptotic variance, and MSE and MISE, of ~ () equal those of ~() when `0` N = `0 `: (4.7) This is true if has an eigenvector `. One such situation of interest arises when the cross-sectional dependence in x it is described by a spatial autoregressive model with row- and column-normalized weight matrix: in particular, x t = W x :t + " :t ; (4.8) where " :t is an N vector of zero-mean uncorrelated, homoscedastic random variables (with variance constant also across T ); the scalar ( ; ); and W is an N N matrix with zero diagonal elements and satisfying W ` = W 0` = `. In practice elements of W are a measure of inverse economic distance between the corresponding elements of x :t. Thus W is often, though not always, symmetric, in which case if one of the latter equalities holds, so do both. This is the case in the familiar "farmers-districts" setting in which W is block-diagonal with symmetric blocks, including spatial correlation across farmers within a district, but not across districts. However, if W is non-symmetric, and only row-normalized, ~() is better than ~ (). As another example, suppose x it has factor structure such that = ai N + bb 0 (4.9) where the scalar a > 0 and b is an N non-null vector. Then `0` = a (`0b) N N + N ; (4.0) (`0 `) (`0b) = a N ; (4.) a + b 0 b and (4.7) holds if and only if b is proportional to `, i.e. if all factor weights are identical. Another simple example in which (4.7) holds is when there is no crosssectional dependence in x it but not all variances! ii are identical.

12 In terms of the impact on (4.3) and (4.4) of N increasing in the asymptotic theory, note that `0 ` N= kk ; denoting by kak the square root of the greatest eigenvalue of A 0 A. Thus if kk increases more slowly than N (it cannot increase faster) the variance components of (4.3) and (4.4) decrease faster than if N were xed, indeed if kk remains bounded the variance rate is (N) ; and the latter property holds even in the factor case (4.9), where kk increases at rate N but, as (4.) indicates, (`0 `) = O(N ) if lim N! (`0b) = fn(a + b 0 b)g < ; (4.) where the expression whose upper limit is taken is clearly less than for all xed N (by the Cauchy inequality), but converges to as N! if, say, b is proportional to `; essentially the requirement for (6.7) to hold for this factor model is one of su cient variability in the factor weights. 5. OPTIMAL BANDWIDTH CHOICE A key question in implementing either ~ or ~ is the choice of bandwidth h. Choices that are optimal in the sense of minimizing asymptotic MSE or MISE are conventional. The following theorem di ers only from well known results in indicating the dependence of the optimal choices on and N; and so again no proof is given. Theorem 3 Let Assumptions -5 hold. MISE of ~ are respectively h ;MSE () = h ;MISE = The h minimizing asymptotic MSE and `0` =5 T N = () ; (5.) =5 : (5.) `0` T N =

13 Let Assumption 6 also hold. The h minimizing asymptotic MSE and MISE of ~ are respectively ( =5 (`0 `) h ;MSE () = = ()) ; (5.3) T ( =5 (`0 `) h ;MISE = = ) : (5.4) T For xed N, these optimal h all have the conventional T =5 rate. If N is regarded as increasing also then unless (.9) does not hold the rates of (5.) and (5.), and thus (5.3) and (5.4) (in view of (4.5)), are of smaller order. In any case (4.5) implies generally smaller optimal bandwidths for ~ than. ~ 6. FEASIBLE OPTIMAL BANDWIDTH CHOICE AND TREND ESTIMATION In practice the optimal bandwidths of the previous section cannot be computed. The constants and are trivially calculated, but () and are unknown. Discussion of their estimation can be found in the nonparametric smoothing literature, see e.g. Gasser, Kneip and Kohler (99), and there is nothing about our setting to require additional treatment here, apart from the improved estimation possible by averaging over the cross section. More notable is the need to approximate the partly or wholly unknown. This arises also if, instead of employing a plug-in proxy to the optimal bandwidths of the previous section, some automatic method such as crossvalidation is employed. Estimation of is also required in order to form a feasible version of the optimal trend estimate ~() In the simplest realistic situation, of no cross-sectional heteroscedasticity or dependence, =!I N, with! unknown, in which case ~() (). ~ More generally we have a parametric structure permitting dependence and/or heteroscedasticity, such as in 3

14 the examples of the previous section. Of course if N remains xed as T increases, is by de nition parametric, so there is no theoretical loss in regarding as an unrestricted positive de nite N N matrix. If then N is allowed to increase this corresponds to a nonparametric treatment of. In all cases is estimated by means of residuals. It is natural to base the residuals on the originally parameterized model (.), but there is a choice of residuals depending on whether or not N is regarded as increasing with T, and, if it does, on the properties of the sequence as N increases. De ne the temporal means x ia = T and the overall means x AA = N x it ; y ia = T y it ; (6.) t= N X x ia ; y AA = N t= N X i= i= y ia : (6.) Then we have, using (.5), y it y ia + y AA = t + x it x ia + x AA : (6.3) Employing also (.6) gives y it y ia y At + y AA = x it x ia x At + x AA : (6.4) This suggests the residual ~x it = y it y ia y At + y AA : (6.5) Clearly x ia = O p (T ) uniformly in i and x AA = O p (T ), helping to justify (6.5). However, it is necessary also that x At = o p () and this requires N!, and, as discussed previously, will not hold even then in models such as (4.9) due to the strength of the cross-sectional dependence. Moreover, a satisfactory convergence rate 4

15 may be required in order to show that the optimal bandwidth, and ~(), are suitably closely approximated. Thus, instead of considering (6.5) further, we rely solely on T being large and in view of (6.3) consider instead the residual ^x it = y it y ia t ~ + y AA ; (6.6) where ~ t = ~ (t=t ). Thus estimate! ij by ^! ij = T ^x it^x jt : (6.7) t= We strengthen Assumption 4 to Assumption 7 As T! ; h + T h 3! 0: (6.8) Theorem 4 Let Assumptions -3, 6 and 7 hold. Then as T! E j^! ij! ij j = O h 3 + h3= + ; (6.9) T uniformly in i and j. The proof appears in Appendix A. Now de ne ^ to be the N N matrix with (i; j)-th element ^! ij, and consider the replacement of by ^ in the optimal bandwidths (5.)-(5.4). For completeness we also assume estimates of ^(), ^ of (), respectively. Notice that from Theorem 4 ^ ( X N i= NX j= (^! ij! ij ) ) = O p Nh 3 + Nh3= + N : (6.0) T 5

16 Assumption 8 ^() () = O p kk ^ ; ^ = O p kk ^ : (6.) Assumption 8 is expressed in a somewhat unprimitive way, but the order in (6.0) is actually what is required to ensure that the e ect of estimating bias is negligible, and as the bias issue is of very secondary importance here we do not go into details about the rates attainable by a particular estimate. However the rate would depend inter alia on the rate of decay of a bandwidth (not necessarily h) used in the nonparametric estimation of 00, or more particularly, in view of (6.), on its rate relative to that of h: Note that if N remains xed as T increases the rate in (6.) must be O p h 3 + h 3= T + ; whereas if N increases then the latter rate is still relevant in, for example, the factor case (4.9), but if kk does not increase or increases more slowly than N; then (6.) entails a milder restriction. De ne ^h ;MSE () = ^h ;MISE = ^h ;MSE () = ^h ;MISE = ( ) =5 ^` `0 T =^() ; (6.) ( ) =5 ^` `0 T =^ ; (6.3) ( (`0 ^ `) ) =5 = ^() ; (6.4) T ( (`0 ^ `) ^) =5 = : (6.5) T Assumption 9 If N! as T! then Nh 3 + Nh3= T + N! 0: (6.6) Assumption 0 If N! as T! then N`0 ` + = O(): (6.7) (`0 `) 6

17 Boundedness of the rst term on the left is equivalent to having smallest eigenvalue that is bounded away from zero for su ciently large N, as in Assumption 6. By the Cauchy inequality, the second term on the left of (6.7) is no less than, so it cannot converge to zero. On the other hand, since `0 ` `0 ` max k k ; N kk ; (6.8) it follows that if also the greatest eigenvalue of is bounded, the second term on the left of (6.7) is also bounded. But the greatest eigenvalue of can diverge with N, as in the factor example (4.9), whereas (6.7) may be held even in this case. To see this, note that `0 ` = a fn (4.) it is su cient that (4.) holds. (`0b) (a + b 0 b) =(a + b 0 b) g = O(N); so in view of Theorem 5 Let Assumptions -3 and 5-0 hold. N! also, Then as T!, and possibly ^h ;MSE () h ;MSE () ; ^h;mise h ;MISE ; The proof is in Appendix A. ^h ;MSE () h ;MSE () ; ^h;mise h ;MISE! p : (6.9) We can also use ^ to obtain a feasible version of ~(), namely `0 ^ ^() = `0 ^ ` k t y t = k t : (6.0) t= t= Theorem indicates that ~() () = O e (`0 `) () + h! ; (6.) where O e denotes an exact stochastic order. It is of interest to show that ^() achieves the same asymptotic MSE as ~(), in other words that ~() ~() is of smaller order than (6.). For this purpose we introduce: 7

18 Assumption If N! as T! then Nh + N! 0: (6.) Theorem 6 Let Assumptions -4 and 5- hold. Then as T!, and possibly N! also, (`0 `)! ^() ~() = o p + h : (6.3) () The proof is in Appendix A. 7. MONTE CARLO STUDY OF FINITE SAMPLE PERFORMANCE As always when large sample asymptotic results are presented, the issue of nitesample relevance arises. In the present case, one interesting question is the extent to which ^() matches the e ciency of ~(), and whether it is actually better than (), ~ given the sampling error in estimating. We study this question by Monte Carlo simulations in the case where has the factor structure (4.9). In (.), we thus take x it = b i i + p a" it ; (7.) where the i and " it have mean zero and variance, and there is independence throughout the f i ; i = ; :::; " it ; i; t = ; ; :::g, more particularly we take the i, " it to be normally distributed. We tried various values of a (a = ; ; ) and set the b i factor weights by rst generating b ; :::; b N independently from a normal distribution, but then keeping them xed across replications; in particular we considered the three choices b N (0; I N ), N (0; 5I N ) and N(0; 0I N ). With respect to the deterministic component of (.), we took (u) = ( + u ) throughout and xed the individual e ects i by rst generating ; :::; N independently from the standard normal distribution, then taking N = ::: N in order to satisfy (.5), then keeping 8

19 these i xed across replications. The estimates ~ (), ~() and ^() were computed at points = ; ; 3. For k we used the uniform kernel on [ ; ], and the band- 4 4 width values used were h = 0:; 0:5;. Two (N; T ) combinations employed, (5; 00) and (0; 500). Monte Carlo MSE, "\MSE" in Tables -3, was computed in each case, based on 000 replications. In Table V ar b i =, in Table V ar b i = 5, and in Table 3 V ar b i = 0. (Tables -3 about here) When (N; T ) = (5; 00) it was found that in every case ^ had larger \MSE than ~ but smaller \MSE than ~. However, when (N; T ) = (0; 500) ^ was always worse than ^ when the b i were generated from a distribution with variance, though when the latter variance was increased to 5 ^ was better in nearly half of the cases (3 out of 7), and when this variance was 0 ^ was worse than ~ in only one case. It would appear that these results re ect the fact that the di erence between variances of ~ and ^, namely `0` `0 ` ; (7.) N has to be large enough relative to the variability increase due to estimation of, in order for ^ to beat ~. In some sense the farther away is from an identity matrix the better for ^ s relative performance, explaining why a large variance in generating the b i helps, though for given such variance increasing N hurts ^ relatively (despite the helpful simultaneous increase of T ). The above description of the results is not informative of the extent to which ^ and ~ are close, or to whether ^ beats or is beaten by ~, and Tables -3 reveal these details. As a increases so does the variance of ~, so again the potential for ^ to improve over ~ is reduced, and the tables illustrate this. For (N; T ) = (5; 00), ^ s performance is often very roughly midway between those of ^ and ~. Also for (N; T ) = (5; 00), \MSE is often U-shaped in h in Tables and, and also for ~ and ^ in Table 3, but 9

20 tends to be decreasing in h for ~ in Table 3. The pattern of performance relative to h is less clear when (N; T ) = (0; 500). In these simulations we have not pursued the discussion of optimal bandwidth choice (see Theorem 3) by incorporating feasible optimal bandwidths (as justi ed in Theorem 5). Some discussion of this issue was presented in Section 6, but a more explicit one is included in the following sequence of steps. Given use of a twice di erenciable k, a feasible ^h ;MISE (6.3) can be computed (or approximated, perhaps by cross-validation), and employed in place of h in the estimate () ~ (3.3). Then the residuals (6.6) are calculated, followed by ^, using (6.7). Finally, ^h ;MISE (6.3) is computed and used in the estimate ^() (6.0). 8. FURTHER DIRECTIONS FOR RESEARCH. Our asymptotic variance formulae for ^() and ^() appear also in central limit theorems, under some additional conditions, indeed one could develop joint central limit theorems for both () ~ and ~() at nitely many, r, xed frequencies ; :::; r, with asymptotic independence across the i. When the bias is negligible relative to the standard deviation, the convergence rate will be () when N is xed, and faster if N is allowed to increase with T. We could also develop a central limit theorem for ^( i ), i = ; :::; r, giving the same limit distribution.. The assumption of regular spacing across t is easily relaxed with some regularity conditions on the spacings, since much of the xed-design nonparametric regression estimation literature permits this. 3. Temporal correlation can also be introduced. For example, suppose X x t = A j " t j ; (8.) 0 j=0

21 where the " t are uncorrelated with covariance matrix I N, and the N N matrix A j satis es Then as T!, where X A j z j 6= 0; jzj = ; (8.) j=0 X ka j k < : (8.3) j=0 n o V ar ~() `0f(0)` N f(0) =! X A j j=0 (8.4)! 0 X A j ; (8.5) which is proportional to the value of the spectral density matrix of x t at frequency zero. Likewise as T! j=0 (`0f(0) `) V ar fe()g : (8.6) We can consistently estimate f(0) by procedures of smoothed probability density estimation, and thence extend the results of Section We could proceed further by relaxing (8.3) to permit long memory, or on the other hand relax (8.) to permit antipersistence. Relevant variance formula for univariate xed-design regression with long memory or antipersistent disturbances can be found in Robinson (997), whose results can be extended to our otherwise more general setting, one further issue arising being the possibility of varying memory parameters over the cross-section. 5. Unknown individual-speci c multiplicative e ects can also be incorporated. To extend (.), y t = + t + x t ; (8.7)

22 where is an N unknown vector. Since the scale, as well as location, of t is not xed we need a normalization restriction on. Imposing `0 = N; (8.8) in addition to (.5), we readily see that () ~ retains the properties described in Theorem. However, improving on () ~ along the lines discussed in Section 4 is more problematic. It was seen in Section 4 that changing w does not change the bias of ~ (w) () as an estimate of (w) (), and changes the asymptotic variance by a factor that depends only on w. But consider any (w) ; (w) ; (w) (), where w 0 (w) = 0; w 0 (w) = (8.9) and We deduce that and thence + () = (w) + (w) (w) (): (8.0) (w) () = w 0 + (w 0 )() (8.) (w) w = I 0 N ; (8.) w 0 (w) = w 0 : (8.3) Then the bias n o E ~ (w) () (w) () = t= o k t n (w) (t=t ) (w) () = = (w 0 )BIAS t= k t n ~ (w) () o ; (8.4) n o where BIAS ~ (w) () is (4.0). Thus, varying w changes the bias by a factor which re ects the unknown multiplicative e ects, so the incorporation of these complicates the study of optimal trend estimation.

23 6. Analogous methods and theory could be developed for corresponding models in which the regressor in the nonparametric function is stochastic (and possibly multivariate), rather than deterministic. Robinson (007) considers static stochastic-design nonparametric regression but without distinguishing between a time and cross-sectional dimension, and without individual e ects, but his conditions on spatial dependence in regressors and disturbances are quite general and could be employed in more general settings, such as that just envisaged. Appendix A: Proofs of Theorems Proof of Theorem 4 We have (^x it^x jt (x it x jt! ij ) : (A.) ^! ij! ij = T x it x jt ) + T t= t= The second term on the right has mean zero and variance bounded by CT, where C throughout denotes a generic constant (so in the present case there is uniformity in i and j). From (6.3) and (6.6) we may write ^x it = x it + d i + e t ; (A.) where d i = x AA x ia ; e t = t ~ t : (A.3) Then ^x it^x jt x it x jt = (^x it x it ) (^x jt x jt ) + x it (^x jt x jt ) + (^x it x it ) x jt = (d i + e t ) (d j + e t ) + x it (d j + e t ) + (d i + e t ) x jt : (A.4) The rst term on the right of (A.4) is bounded in absolute value by d i + d j + e t. From Assumption, E(d i ) CT uniformly in i. Next write e t = f t =k t m t =k t ; (A.5) 3

24 where f t = () k st ( t s ); (A.6) s= m t = () k st x As ; s= k t = () k st : s= (A.7) (A.8) By Lemma 3, jk t j C uniformly in t and T. Next, m t has mean zero and variance bounded by C() kst C() ; applying Lemma. By the mean value theorem s t s t = 0 t + s t 00 T T st; s= (A.9) (A.0) where 0 t = 0 (t=t ) and j 00 stj C: Thus jf t j j 0 s t s tj () k st + () T T s= s= t jk st 00 stj : (A.) The last term is O(h ) by Lemma. The rst factor of the rst term on the right is uniformly bounded and the second factor may be written Z h s t () k st uk(u)du : s= (A.) From Lemma this is bounded by ( Ch + T h + 3 t T + t ) (A.3) for t T. For other t we use the bound Ch from Lemma. It follows 4

25 from Lemma 3 that f t =k t has the same bounds. Thus T t= ft Thus, for large T, k t C + C C h 3 + ( E T C t= T + T 4 h + h 4 T T + T 4 h + h : 4 T h 3 + T + T 4 h 4 d i + d j + e t ) C Next, looking at the second term in (A.4) we have E d j T x it t= ( Ed j T! X (t=) t : (A.4) h 3 + : (A.5) t= ) E x it CT : (A.6) Also E T ( x it f t =k t C T t= C T t= ft k t ) h 3= + T + T h : (A.7) Write Thus m t E x it k t t= x it m t = k(0) x itx At + x it k(0) E t= >< >: E x it x At k t t= k st x As : s= s6=t x it k t 9 > = C k st x As A >; s= s6=t (A.8) : (A.9) 5

26 The rst term on the right is bounded by C=(T h). The second term is C 8 >< >: E t= t= s= x it k t k sv 0 9 > = C k st x As A >; s= s6=t! C=h + E 0 t= v= v6=t ktv x it x Av x iv x At C k t k v A (A.0) by Lemma. It follows that E T x it m t =k t C=( ): t= (A.) Thus, E j^! ij! ij j C h C h 3= + T T + T h C h 3 + h3= + T + C : (A.) The proof is completed. Proof of Theorem 5 It su ces to consider only the MISE-optimal bandwidths, the proofs for the MSE-optimal ones being identical. We have 8 =5 < ^h ;MISE h ;MISE = T N : `0 ^` ^! =5 `0` 9 = ; =5 : (A.3) By the mean value theorem, the last factor is bounded in absolute value by 5 j~r j `0 ^ ` + 5 j~r j ^ ; (A.4) where ~r lies between (`0`) 4=5 =5 and (`0 ^`) 4=5^ =5 and ~r lies between (`0`) =5 6=5 6

27 6=5 and (`0 ^`) =5^. Then straightforwardly we deduce that (A.4) is n o (`0`) 4=5 N ^ + (`0`) ^ = O p N =5 ^ + kk ^ = O p N =5 ^ (A.5) by Assumption 8. Thus (A.3) is =5 `0` N =5 ^! O p T N `0`! =5 `0` = O p ^ = o T N p (h ;MSE ) : (A.6) Next consider ^h ;MSE h ;MSE = T 8 =5 >< `0 ^ ` >: ^=5 =5 (`0 `) =5 =5 9 >= >; : (A.7) The last factor is bounded in absolute value by 5 j~s j `0 ^ ` `0 ` + 5 j~s j ^ ; (A.8) where ~s lies between (`0 `) 4=5 =5 and `0 ^ ` 4=5 =5 ^ and ~s lies between (`0 `) =5 6=5 and `0 ^ ` =5 6=5 ^. Now `0 ^ ` `0 ` `0 ^ ` `0 ^ ` (`0 `) `0 ^ ^ ` = `0 ^ ` (`0 `) (`0 `) = O p ^ (`0 `) 0 ^ = O A : (A.9) N 7

28 Thus (A.8) is O p `0 `4=5 ^ + `0 ` =5 ^ A N = O p (`0 N `) 4=5 ^ + kk ^! : (A.30) It follows from Assumption 8 that! 4=5 (`0 `) ^h ;MISE h ;MISE = O p ^ NT =5 = O p T `0 ` =5 ^ = o p (h ;MISE ) : (A.3) The proof is completed. Proof of Theorem 6 We have ( ^() ~() = = ( `0 ^ `0 ^ ` `0 ^ `0 ^ ` ) `0 `0 ` k t ( + t` + x t ) = t= t= ) `0 `0 ` k t ( + x t ) = k t : t= t= k t (A.3) It clearly su ces to show that the factor in braces has norm o p (`0 `) h + N (). This norm is bounded by `0 ^ `0 ^ ` `0 ` + `0 ` `0(^ ) : (A.33) From the proof of Theorem 5, 0 `0 ^ ` `0 ` ^ = A p ; N (A.34) 8

29 so since `0 ^ N ^ the rst term is Op N `0(^ ) = O p `0 ` ^ ^. Also, (A.35) and thus from Assumption 0 the second term has the same bound. This bound is O p `0 ` ^ O p `0 ` N h 3 + h3= T + : (A.36) Now Nh 3 = o(h ) if Nh! 0 and Nh 3= =T = o(h ) if N = o (). Also, N=( ) = o () if N = o(t ) but this is implied by the last condition. The conclusion follows. Appendix B: Technical Lemmas Lemma C ( + u c ). Then For given d 0 let the function g(u) be such that for c > d, jg(u)j max tt ( s t d ) s t g C: s= Proof. The expression in braces is bounded by C() d X js tju for any positive U. This is bounded by Choosing U gives the result. js tj d + C() c d X js tju (B.) js tj d c ; (B.) C() d U d+ + C() c d U d c+ : (B.3) Lemma Let the function g be twice boundedly di erentiable, and let g(u) = ( + juj c ) (B.4) 9

30 for c >, and let g(u) and its derivative g 0 (u) be integrable. Then for t, t T, s= s g t Z Proof. The left side is g(u)du C + T h + 3 (s Zt)= s= (s t )= Z g(u)du s t g Z t= g(u)du: c t T + g(u) du t c! : (B.5) (B.6) (B.7) (T t)= The rst integrand is s t s t g 0 u + s t g00 st where jgstj 00 C. Thus (B.6) is bounded in absolute value by s t () g0 + CT () C 3 + C T h ; 3 s= u ; (B.8) using Lemma. On the other hand (B.7) is bounded in absolute value by (B.9) T t C c + C c t : (B.0) Lemma 3 For all su ciently large T min k t =8: tt (B.) Proof. De ne t = Z (T t)=() k(u)du: (B.) t=() 30

31 Then The integrand is k t t = s= Z (T t)=() t=() s t s t k 0 k s t s t u + C t k(u) du: (B.3) u ; (B.4) where max C t < : tt Thus (B.3) is bounded in absolute value by () s t k0 + C t T () 3 C() + CT h 3 s= (B.5) =8; (B.6) say, for large enough T, using Lemma and Assumption 7. Now for large enough T, min t tt Z =(h) 0 k(u)du 4 (B.7) and thus min k t = min t tt tt max jk t t j > =8: (B.8) tt Acknowledgement This research was supported by ESRC Grant RES I am grateful for the helpful comments of a referee and Jungyoon Lee, and to the latter also for carrying out the simulations. 3

32 References Bai, J., S. Ng, 00. Determining the number of factors in approximate factor models. Econometrica 70, 9-. Benedetti, J.K., 977. On the nonparametric estimation of regression functions. Journal of the Royal Statisticl Society Series B39, Gasser, T., A. Kneip, W. Kohler, 99. A exible and fast method for automatic smoothing. Journal of the American Statistical Association 86, Hart, J.D., T.E. Wehrly, 986. Kernel regression estimation using repeated measurements data. Journal of the American Statistical Association 8, Moyeed, K.A., P.J. Diggle, 994. Rates of convergence in semi-parametric modelling of longitudinal data. Australian Journal of Statistics 36, Robinson, P.M., 997. Large-sample inference for nonparametric regression with dependent errors. Annals of Statistics 5, Robinson, P.M., 007. Asymptotic properties of nonparametric regression with spatial data. Preprint. Ruckstuhl, A.F., A.H. Welsh, R.J. Carroll, 000. Nonparametric function estimation of the relationship between two repeatedly measured variables. Statistica Sinica 0, 5-7. Severini, T.A., J.G. Staniswalis, 994. Quasi-likelihood estimation in semiparametric models. Journal of the American Statistical Association 89, Starica, C., C. Granger, 005. Nonstationarities in stock returns. Review of Economics and Statistics 87,

Simple Estimators for Semiparametric Multinomial Choice Models

Simple Estimators for Semiparametric Multinomial Choice Models Simple Estimators for Semiparametric Multinomial Choice Models James L. Powell and Paul A. Ruud University of California, Berkeley March 2008 Preliminary and Incomplete Comments Welcome Abstract This paper

More information

Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence

Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence Peter M. Robinson London School of Economics Based on joint work with Javier Hualde: Javier Hualde and Peter M. Robinson: Gaussian Pseudo-Maximum Likelihood Estimation

More information

Time Series Models and Inference. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley

Time Series Models and Inference. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Time Series Models and Inference James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Overview In contrast to the classical linear regression model, in which the components of the

More information

GMM estimation of spatial panels

GMM estimation of spatial panels MRA Munich ersonal ReEc Archive GMM estimation of spatial panels Francesco Moscone and Elisa Tosetti Brunel University 7. April 009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/637/ MRA aper No. 637, posted

More information

Simple Estimators for Monotone Index Models

Simple Estimators for Monotone Index Models Simple Estimators for Monotone Index Models Hyungtaik Ahn Dongguk University, Hidehiko Ichimura University College London, James L. Powell University of California, Berkeley (powell@econ.berkeley.edu)

More information

GMM-based inference in the AR(1) panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails

GMM-based inference in the AR(1) panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails GMM-based inference in the AR() panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails Edith Madsen entre for Applied Microeconometrics (AM) Department of Economics, University of openhagen,

More information

Estimating the Number of Common Factors in Serially Dependent Approximate Factor Models

Estimating the Number of Common Factors in Serially Dependent Approximate Factor Models Estimating the Number of Common Factors in Serially Dependent Approximate Factor Models Ryan Greenaway-McGrevy y Bureau of Economic Analysis Chirok Han Korea University February 7, 202 Donggyu Sul University

More information

Nonparametric Identi cation and Estimation of Truncated Regression Models with Heteroskedasticity

Nonparametric Identi cation and Estimation of Truncated Regression Models with Heteroskedasticity Nonparametric Identi cation and Estimation of Truncated Regression Models with Heteroskedasticity Songnian Chen a, Xun Lu a, Xianbo Zhou b and Yahong Zhou c a Department of Economics, Hong Kong University

More information

13 Endogeneity and Nonparametric IV

13 Endogeneity and Nonparametric IV 13 Endogeneity and Nonparametric IV 13.1 Nonparametric Endogeneity A nonparametric IV equation is Y i = g (X i ) + e i (1) E (e i j i ) = 0 In this model, some elements of X i are potentially endogenous,

More information

LECTURE 12 UNIT ROOT, WEAK CONVERGENCE, FUNCTIONAL CLT

LECTURE 12 UNIT ROOT, WEAK CONVERGENCE, FUNCTIONAL CLT MARCH 29, 26 LECTURE 2 UNIT ROOT, WEAK CONVERGENCE, FUNCTIONAL CLT (Davidson (2), Chapter 4; Phillips Lectures on Unit Roots, Cointegration and Nonstationarity; White (999), Chapter 7) Unit root processes

More information

SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER. Donald W. K. Andrews. August 2011

SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER. Donald W. K. Andrews. August 2011 SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER By Donald W. K. Andrews August 2011 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1815 COWLES FOUNDATION FOR RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS

More information

Notes on Time Series Modeling

Notes on Time Series Modeling Notes on Time Series Modeling Garey Ramey University of California, San Diego January 17 1 Stationary processes De nition A stochastic process is any set of random variables y t indexed by t T : fy t g

More information

ECONOMETRICS FIELD EXAM Michigan State University May 9, 2008

ECONOMETRICS FIELD EXAM Michigan State University May 9, 2008 ECONOMETRICS FIELD EXAM Michigan State University May 9, 2008 Instructions: Answer all four (4) questions. Point totals for each question are given in parenthesis; there are 00 points possible. Within

More information

Chapter 2. Dynamic panel data models

Chapter 2. Dynamic panel data models Chapter 2. Dynamic panel data models School of Economics and Management - University of Geneva Christophe Hurlin, Université of Orléans University of Orléans April 2018 C. Hurlin (University of Orléans)

More information

Markov-Switching Models with Endogenous Explanatory Variables. Chang-Jin Kim 1

Markov-Switching Models with Endogenous Explanatory Variables. Chang-Jin Kim 1 Markov-Switching Models with Endogenous Explanatory Variables by Chang-Jin Kim 1 Dept. of Economics, Korea University and Dept. of Economics, University of Washington First draft: August, 2002 This version:

More information

1. The Multivariate Classical Linear Regression Model

1. The Multivariate Classical Linear Regression Model Business School, Brunel University MSc. EC550/5509 Modelling Financial Decisions and Markets/Introduction to Quantitative Methods Prof. Menelaos Karanasos (Room SS69, Tel. 08956584) Lecture Notes 5. The

More information

Introduction: structural econometrics. Jean-Marc Robin

Introduction: structural econometrics. Jean-Marc Robin Introduction: structural econometrics Jean-Marc Robin Abstract 1. Descriptive vs structural models 2. Correlation is not causality a. Simultaneity b. Heterogeneity c. Selectivity Descriptive models Consider

More information

(Y jz) t (XjZ) 0 t = S yx S yz S 1. S yx:z = T 1. etc. 2. Next solve the eigenvalue problem. js xx:z S xy:z S 1

(Y jz) t (XjZ) 0 t = S yx S yz S 1. S yx:z = T 1. etc. 2. Next solve the eigenvalue problem. js xx:z S xy:z S 1 Abstract Reduced Rank Regression The reduced rank regression model is a multivariate regression model with a coe cient matrix with reduced rank. The reduced rank regression algorithm is an estimation procedure,

More information

Inference about Clustering and Parametric. Assumptions in Covariance Matrix Estimation

Inference about Clustering and Parametric. Assumptions in Covariance Matrix Estimation Inference about Clustering and Parametric Assumptions in Covariance Matrix Estimation Mikko Packalen y Tony Wirjanto z 26 November 2010 Abstract Selecting an estimator for the variance covariance matrix

More information

Rank Estimation of Partially Linear Index Models

Rank Estimation of Partially Linear Index Models Rank Estimation of Partially Linear Index Models Jason Abrevaya University of Texas at Austin Youngki Shin University of Western Ontario October 2008 Preliminary Do not distribute Abstract We consider

More information

A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED

A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED by W. Robert Reed Department of Economics and Finance University of Canterbury, New Zealand Email: bob.reed@canterbury.ac.nz

More information

7 Semiparametric Methods and Partially Linear Regression

7 Semiparametric Methods and Partially Linear Regression 7 Semiparametric Metods and Partially Linear Regression 7. Overview A model is called semiparametric if it is described by and were is nite-dimensional (e.g. parametric) and is in nite-dimensional (nonparametric).

More information

Inference on Trending Panel Data

Inference on Trending Panel Data Inference on rending Panel Data Peter M Robinson and Carlos Velasco London School of Economics and Universidad Carlos III de Madrid November 3, 15 Abstract Semiparametric panel data modelling and statistical

More information

MC3: Econometric Theory and Methods. Course Notes 4

MC3: Econometric Theory and Methods. Course Notes 4 University College London Department of Economics M.Sc. in Economics MC3: Econometric Theory and Methods Course Notes 4 Notes on maximum likelihood methods Andrew Chesher 25/0/2005 Course Notes 4, Andrew

More information

University of Toronto

University of Toronto A Limit Result for the Prior Predictive by Michael Evans Department of Statistics University of Toronto and Gun Ho Jang Department of Statistics University of Toronto Technical Report No. 1004 April 15,

More information

Econometrics II. Nonstandard Standard Error Issues: A Guide for the. Practitioner

Econometrics II. Nonstandard Standard Error Issues: A Guide for the. Practitioner Econometrics II Nonstandard Standard Error Issues: A Guide for the Practitioner Måns Söderbom 10 May 2011 Department of Economics, University of Gothenburg. Email: mans.soderbom@economics.gu.se. Web: www.economics.gu.se/soderbom,

More information

Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts

Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts Contents 1 Motivating Examples 1 1.1 Instrumental variable estimator....................... 1 1.2 Estimating parameters in monetary policy rules.............. 2 1.3 Estimating

More information

Tests for Cointegration, Cobreaking and Cotrending in a System of Trending Variables

Tests for Cointegration, Cobreaking and Cotrending in a System of Trending Variables Tests for Cointegration, Cobreaking and Cotrending in a System of Trending Variables Josep Lluís Carrion-i-Silvestre University of Barcelona Dukpa Kim y Korea University May 4, 28 Abstract We consider

More information

Department of Econometrics and Business Statistics

Department of Econometrics and Business Statistics ISSN 1440-771X Australia Department of Econometrics and Business Statistics http://www.buseco.monash.edu.au/depts/ebs/pubs/wpapers/ Exponential Smoothing: A Prediction Error Decomposition Principle Ralph

More information

Lecture Notes on Measurement Error

Lecture Notes on Measurement Error Steve Pischke Spring 2000 Lecture Notes on Measurement Error These notes summarize a variety of simple results on measurement error which I nd useful. They also provide some references where more complete

More information

Likelihood Ratio Based Test for the Exogeneity and the Relevance of Instrumental Variables

Likelihood Ratio Based Test for the Exogeneity and the Relevance of Instrumental Variables Likelihood Ratio Based est for the Exogeneity and the Relevance of Instrumental Variables Dukpa Kim y Yoonseok Lee z September [under revision] Abstract his paper develops a test for the exogeneity and

More information

Nonparametric Identi cation of a Binary Random Factor in Cross Section Data

Nonparametric Identi cation of a Binary Random Factor in Cross Section Data Nonparametric Identi cation of a Binary Random Factor in Cross Section Data Yingying Dong and Arthur Lewbel California State University Fullerton and Boston College Original January 2009, revised March

More information

Testing for Panel Cointegration Using Common Correlated Effects Estimators

Testing for Panel Cointegration Using Common Correlated Effects Estimators Department of Economics Testing for Panel Cointegration Using Common Correlated Effects Estimators Department of Economics Discussion Paper 5-2 Anindya Banerjee Josep Lluís Carrion-i-Silvestre Testing

More information

SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER. Donald W. K. Andrews. August 2011 Revised March 2012

SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER. Donald W. K. Andrews. August 2011 Revised March 2012 SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER By Donald W. K. Andrews August 2011 Revised March 2012 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1815R COWLES FOUNDATION FOR

More information

A New Approach to Robust Inference in Cointegration

A New Approach to Robust Inference in Cointegration A New Approach to Robust Inference in Cointegration Sainan Jin Guanghua School of Management, Peking University Peter C. B. Phillips Cowles Foundation, Yale University, University of Auckland & University

More information

Developments in the Analysis of Spatial Data

Developments in the Analysis of Spatial Data Developments in the Analysis of Spatial Data P. M. Robinson London School of Economics August 31, 2007 The Suntory Centre Suntory and Toyota International Centres for Economics and Related Disciplines

More information

Testing the null of cointegration with structural breaks

Testing the null of cointegration with structural breaks Testing the null of cointegration with structural breaks Josep Lluís Carrion-i-Silvestre Anàlisi Quantitativa Regional Parc Cientí c de Barcelona Andreu Sansó Departament of Economics Universitat de les

More information

Nonparametric Spectrum Estimation for Spatial Data. P.M. Robinson. London School of Economics

Nonparametric Spectrum Estimation for Spatial Data. P.M. Robinson. London School of Economics Nonparametric Spectrum Estimation for Spatial Data.M. Robinson London School of Economics The Suntory Centre Suntory and Toyota International Centres for Economics and Related Disciplines London School

More information

Testing for Regime Switching: A Comment

Testing for Regime Switching: A Comment Testing for Regime Switching: A Comment Andrew V. Carter Department of Statistics University of California, Santa Barbara Douglas G. Steigerwald Department of Economics University of California Santa Barbara

More information

Panel cointegration rank testing with cross-section dependence

Panel cointegration rank testing with cross-section dependence Panel cointegration rank testing with cross-section dependence Josep Lluís Carrion-i-Silvestre y Laura Surdeanu z September 2007 Abstract In this paper we propose a test statistic to determine the cointegration

More information

Testing for a Trend with Persistent Errors

Testing for a Trend with Persistent Errors Testing for a Trend with Persistent Errors Graham Elliott UCSD August 2017 Abstract We develop new tests for the coe cient on a time trend in a regression of a variable on a constant and time trend where

More information

ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401S) University of Toronto. Department of Economics. Spring 2013 Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria

ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401S) University of Toronto. Department of Economics. Spring 2013 Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401S) University of Toronto. Department of Economics. Spring 2013 Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria SOLUTION TO FINAL EXAM Friday, April 12, 2013. From 9:00-12:00 (3 hours) INSTRUCTIONS:

More information

Cointegration and the joint con rmation hypothesis

Cointegration and the joint con rmation hypothesis Cointegration and the joint con rmation hypothesis VASCO J. GABRIEL Department of Economics, Birkbeck College, UK University of Minho, Portugal October 2001 Abstract Recent papers by Charemza and Syczewska

More information

When is it really justifiable to ignore explanatory variable endogeneity in a regression model?

When is it really justifiable to ignore explanatory variable endogeneity in a regression model? Discussion Paper: 2015/05 When is it really justifiable to ignore explanatory variable endogeneity in a regression model? Jan F. Kiviet www.ase.uva.nl/uva-econometrics Amsterdam School of Economics Roetersstraat

More information

A formal statistical test for the number of factors in. the approximate factor models

A formal statistical test for the number of factors in. the approximate factor models A formal statistical test for the number of factors in the approximate factor models Alexei Onatski Economics Department, Columbia University September 26, 2006 Abstract In this paper we study i.i.d. sequences

More information

Economics 241B Review of Limit Theorems for Sequences of Random Variables

Economics 241B Review of Limit Theorems for Sequences of Random Variables Economics 241B Review of Limit Theorems for Sequences of Random Variables Convergence in Distribution The previous de nitions of convergence focus on the outcome sequences of a random variable. Convergence

More information

Applications of Subsampling, Hybrid, and Size-Correction Methods

Applications of Subsampling, Hybrid, and Size-Correction Methods Applications of Subsampling, Hybrid, and Size-Correction Methods Donald W. K. Andrews Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics Yale University Patrik Guggenberger Department of Economics UCLA November

More information

Bootstrapping Long Memory Tests: Some Monte Carlo Results

Bootstrapping Long Memory Tests: Some Monte Carlo Results Bootstrapping Long Memory Tests: Some Monte Carlo Results Anthony Murphy and Marwan Izzeldin University College Dublin and Cass Business School. July 2004 - Preliminary Abstract We investigate the bootstrapped

More information

Stochastic integral. Introduction. Ito integral. References. Appendices Stochastic Calculus I. Geneviève Gauthier.

Stochastic integral. Introduction. Ito integral. References. Appendices Stochastic Calculus I. Geneviève Gauthier. Ito 8-646-8 Calculus I Geneviève Gauthier HEC Montréal Riemann Ito The Ito The theories of stochastic and stochastic di erential equations have initially been developed by Kiyosi Ito around 194 (one of

More information

Testing Weak Convergence Based on HAR Covariance Matrix Estimators

Testing Weak Convergence Based on HAR Covariance Matrix Estimators Testing Weak Convergence Based on HAR Covariance atrix Estimators Jianning Kong y, Peter C. B. Phillips z, Donggyu Sul x August 4, 207 Abstract The weak convergence tests based on heteroskedasticity autocorrelation

More information

GMM Estimation of SAR Models with. Endogenous Regressors

GMM Estimation of SAR Models with. Endogenous Regressors GMM Estimation of SAR Models with Endogenous Regressors Xiaodong Liu Department of Economics, University of Colorado Boulder E-mail: xiaodongliucoloradoedu Paulo Saraiva Department of Economics, University

More information

Approximately Most Powerful Tests for Moment Inequalities

Approximately Most Powerful Tests for Moment Inequalities Approximately Most Powerful Tests for Moment Inequalities Richard C. Chiburis Department of Economics, Princeton University September 26, 2008 Abstract The existing literature on testing moment inequalities

More information

Bootstrapping the Grainger Causality Test With Integrated Data

Bootstrapping the Grainger Causality Test With Integrated Data Bootstrapping the Grainger Causality Test With Integrated Data Richard Ti n University of Reading July 26, 2006 Abstract A Monte-carlo experiment is conducted to investigate the small sample performance

More information

A Bootstrap Test for Conditional Symmetry

A Bootstrap Test for Conditional Symmetry ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 6, 51 61 005) A Bootstrap Test for Conditional Symmetry Liangjun Su Guanghua School of Management, Peking University E-mail: lsu@gsm.pku.edu.cn and Sainan Jin Guanghua School

More information

Identi cation of Positive Treatment E ects in. Randomized Experiments with Non-Compliance

Identi cation of Positive Treatment E ects in. Randomized Experiments with Non-Compliance Identi cation of Positive Treatment E ects in Randomized Experiments with Non-Compliance Aleksey Tetenov y February 18, 2012 Abstract I derive sharp nonparametric lower bounds on some parameters of the

More information

A Test of Cointegration Rank Based Title Component Analysis.

A Test of Cointegration Rank Based Title Component Analysis. A Test of Cointegration Rank Based Title Component Analysis Author(s) Chigira, Hiroaki Citation Issue 2006-01 Date Type Technical Report Text Version publisher URL http://hdl.handle.net/10086/13683 Right

More information

Cointegration Tests Using Instrumental Variables Estimation and the Demand for Money in England

Cointegration Tests Using Instrumental Variables Estimation and the Demand for Money in England Cointegration Tests Using Instrumental Variables Estimation and the Demand for Money in England Kyung So Im Junsoo Lee Walter Enders June 12, 2005 Abstract In this paper, we propose new cointegration tests

More information

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models Fall 22 Contents Introduction 2. An illustrative example........................... 2.2 Discussion...................................

More information

On GMM Estimation and Inference with Bootstrap Bias-Correction in Linear Panel Data Models

On GMM Estimation and Inference with Bootstrap Bias-Correction in Linear Panel Data Models On GMM Estimation and Inference with Bootstrap Bias-Correction in Linear Panel Data Models Takashi Yamagata y Department of Economics and Related Studies, University of York, Heslington, York, UK January

More information

Discussion Paper Series

Discussion Paper Series INSTITUTO TECNOLÓGICO AUTÓNOMO DE MÉXICO CENTRO DE INVESTIGACIÓN ECONÓMICA Discussion Paper Series Size Corrected Power for Bootstrap Tests Manuel A. Domínguez and Ignacio N. Lobato Instituto Tecnológico

More information

Comparing Nested Predictive Regression Models with Persistent Predictors

Comparing Nested Predictive Regression Models with Persistent Predictors Comparing Nested Predictive Regression Models with Persistent Predictors Yan Ge y and ae-hwy Lee z November 29, 24 Abstract his paper is an extension of Clark and McCracken (CM 2, 25, 29) and Clark and

More information

Panel Data. March 2, () Applied Economoetrics: Topic 6 March 2, / 43

Panel Data. March 2, () Applied Economoetrics: Topic 6 March 2, / 43 Panel Data March 2, 212 () Applied Economoetrics: Topic March 2, 212 1 / 43 Overview Many economic applications involve panel data. Panel data has both cross-sectional and time series aspects. Regression

More information

Multiple Local Whittle Estimation in Stationary Systems

Multiple Local Whittle Estimation in Stationary Systems Multiple Local Whittle Estimation in Stationary Systems P. M. Robinson London School of Economics The Suntory Centre Suntory and Toyota International Centres for Economics and Related Disciplines London

More information

On the optimal weighting matrix for the GMM system estimator in dynamic panel data models

On the optimal weighting matrix for the GMM system estimator in dynamic panel data models Discussion Paper: 007/08 On the optimal weighting matrix for the GMM system estimator in dynamic panel data models Jan F Kiviet wwwfeeuvanl/ke/uva-econometrics Amsterdam School of Economics Department

More information

Time is discrete and indexed by t =0; 1;:::;T,whereT<1. An individual is interested in maximizing an objective function given by. tu(x t ;a t ); (0.

Time is discrete and indexed by t =0; 1;:::;T,whereT<1. An individual is interested in maximizing an objective function given by. tu(x t ;a t ); (0. Chapter 0 Discrete Time Dynamic Programming 0.1 The Finite Horizon Case Time is discrete and indexed by t =0; 1;:::;T,whereT

More information

Economics 241B Estimation with Instruments

Economics 241B Estimation with Instruments Economics 241B Estimation with Instruments Measurement Error Measurement error is de ned as the error resulting from the measurement of a variable. At some level, every variable is measured with error.

More information

Supplemental Material 1 for On Optimal Inference in the Linear IV Model

Supplemental Material 1 for On Optimal Inference in the Linear IV Model Supplemental Material 1 for On Optimal Inference in the Linear IV Model Donald W. K. Andrews Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics Yale University Vadim Marmer Vancouver School of Economics University

More information

Comparing the asymptotic and empirical (un)conditional distributions of OLS and IV in a linear static simultaneous equation

Comparing the asymptotic and empirical (un)conditional distributions of OLS and IV in a linear static simultaneous equation Comparing the asymptotic and empirical (un)conditional distributions of OLS and IV in a linear static simultaneous equation Jan F. Kiviet and Jerzy Niemczyk y January JEL-classi cation: C3, C, C3 Keywords:

More information

Averaging Estimators for Regressions with a Possible Structural Break

Averaging Estimators for Regressions with a Possible Structural Break Averaging Estimators for Regressions with a Possible Structural Break Bruce E. Hansen University of Wisconsin y www.ssc.wisc.edu/~bhansen September 2007 Preliminary Abstract This paper investigates selection

More information

CAE Working Paper # Fixed-b Asymptotic Approximation of the Sampling Behavior of Nonparametric Spectral Density Estimators

CAE Working Paper # Fixed-b Asymptotic Approximation of the Sampling Behavior of Nonparametric Spectral Density Estimators CAE Working Paper #06-04 Fixed-b Asymptotic Approximation of the Sampling Behavior of Nonparametric Spectral Density Estimators by Nigar Hashimzade and Timothy Vogelsang January 2006. Fixed-b Asymptotic

More information

Comparing Forecast Accuracy of Different Models for Prices of Metal Commodities

Comparing Forecast Accuracy of Different Models for Prices of Metal Commodities Comparing Forecast Accuracy of Different Models for Prices of Metal Commodities João Victor Issler (FGV) and Claudia F. Rodrigues (VALE) August, 2012 J.V. Issler and C.F. Rodrigues () Forecast Models for

More information

Quantiles, Expectiles and Splines

Quantiles, Expectiles and Splines Quantiles, Expectiles and Splines Giuliano De Rossi and Andrew Harvey* Faculty of Economics, Cambridge University February 9, 2007 Abstract A time-varying quantile can be tted to a sequence of observations

More information

E cient Regressions via Optimally Combining Quantile Information

E cient Regressions via Optimally Combining Quantile Information E cient Regressions via Optimally Combining Quantile Information Zhibiao Zhao Penn State University Zhijie Xiao Boston College Abstract We develop a generally applicable framework for constructing e cient

More information

When is a copula constant? A test for changing relationships

When is a copula constant? A test for changing relationships When is a copula constant? A test for changing relationships Fabio Busetti and Andrew Harvey Bank of Italy and University of Cambridge November 2007 usetti and Harvey (Bank of Italy and University of Cambridge)

More information

Nonparametric Estimation of Wages and Labor Force Participation

Nonparametric Estimation of Wages and Labor Force Participation Nonparametric Estimation of Wages Labor Force Participation John Pepper University of Virginia Steven Stern University of Virginia May 5, 000 Preliminary Draft - Comments Welcome Abstract. Model Let y

More information

Measuring robustness

Measuring robustness Measuring robustness 1 Introduction While in the classical approach to statistics one aims at estimates which have desirable properties at an exactly speci ed model, the aim of robust methods is loosely

More information

APPENDIX A. Background Mathematics. A.1 Linear Algebra. Vector algebra. Let x denote the n-dimensional column vector with components x 1 x 2.

APPENDIX A. Background Mathematics. A.1 Linear Algebra. Vector algebra. Let x denote the n-dimensional column vector with components x 1 x 2. APPENDIX A Background Mathematics A. Linear Algebra A.. Vector algebra Let x denote the n-dimensional column vector with components 0 x x 2 B C @. A x n Definition 6 (scalar product). The scalar product

More information

Bootstrapping Long Memory Tests: Some Monte Carlo Results

Bootstrapping Long Memory Tests: Some Monte Carlo Results Bootstrapping Long Memory Tests: Some Monte Carlo Results Anthony Murphy and Marwan Izzeldin Nu eld College, Oxford and Lancaster University. December 2005 - Preliminary Abstract We investigate the bootstrapped

More information

LECTURE 13: TIME SERIES I

LECTURE 13: TIME SERIES I 1 LECTURE 13: TIME SERIES I AUTOCORRELATION: Consider y = X + u where y is T 1, X is T K, is K 1 and u is T 1. We are using T and not N for sample size to emphasize that this is a time series. The natural

More information

Panel VAR Models with Spatial Dependence

Panel VAR Models with Spatial Dependence Panel VAR Models with Spatial Dependence Jan Mutl Institute of Advanced Studies Stumpergasse 56 A-6 Vienna Austria mutl@ihs.ac.at January 3, 29 Abstract I consider a panel vector autoregressive (panel

More information

Least Squares Estimation of a Panel Data Model with Multifactor Error Structure and Endogenous Covariates

Least Squares Estimation of a Panel Data Model with Multifactor Error Structure and Endogenous Covariates Least Squares Estimation of a Panel Data Model with Multifactor Error Structure and Endogenous Covariates Matthew Harding and Carlos Lamarche January 12, 2011 Abstract We propose a method for estimating

More information

Notes on Asymptotic Theory: Convergence in Probability and Distribution Introduction to Econometric Theory Econ. 770

Notes on Asymptotic Theory: Convergence in Probability and Distribution Introduction to Econometric Theory Econ. 770 Notes on Asymptotic Theory: Convergence in Probability and Distribution Introduction to Econometric Theory Econ. 770 Jonathan B. Hill Dept. of Economics University of North Carolina - Chapel Hill November

More information

1 Continuation of solutions

1 Continuation of solutions Math 175 Honors ODE I Spring 13 Notes 4 1 Continuation of solutions Theorem 1 in the previous notes states that a solution to y = f (t; y) (1) y () = () exists on a closed interval [ h; h] ; under certain

More information

On Econometric Analysis of Structural Systems with Permanent and Transitory Shocks and Exogenous Variables

On Econometric Analysis of Structural Systems with Permanent and Transitory Shocks and Exogenous Variables On Econometric Analysis of Structural Systems with Permanent and Transitory Shocks and Exogenous Variables Adrian Pagan School of Economics and Finance, Queensland University of Technology M. Hashem Pesaran

More information

Defect Detection using Nonparametric Regression

Defect Detection using Nonparametric Regression Defect Detection using Nonparametric Regression Siana Halim Industrial Engineering Department-Petra Christian University Siwalankerto 121-131 Surabaya- Indonesia halim@petra.ac.id Abstract: To compare

More information

Problem set 1 - Solutions

Problem set 1 - Solutions EMPIRICAL FINANCE AND FINANCIAL ECONOMETRICS - MODULE (8448) Problem set 1 - Solutions Exercise 1 -Solutions 1. The correct answer is (a). In fact, the process generating daily prices is usually assumed

More information

Panel VAR Models with Spatial Dependence

Panel VAR Models with Spatial Dependence Panel VAR Models with Spatial Dependence Jan Mutl y Institute of Advanced Studies February 2, 29 Abstract I consider a panel vector-autoregressive model with cross-sectional dependence of the disturbances

More information

Estimation and Inference of Linear Trend Slope Ratios

Estimation and Inference of Linear Trend Slope Ratios Estimation and Inference of Linear rend Slope Ratios imothy J. Vogelsang and Nasreen Nawaz Department of Economics, Michigan State University October 4 Abstract We focus on the estimation of the ratio

More information

Robust Con dence Intervals in Nonlinear Regression under Weak Identi cation

Robust Con dence Intervals in Nonlinear Regression under Weak Identi cation Robust Con dence Intervals in Nonlinear Regression under Weak Identi cation Xu Cheng y Department of Economics Yale University First Draft: August, 27 This Version: December 28 Abstract In this paper,

More information

Granger Causality and Dynamic Structural Systems

Granger Causality and Dynamic Structural Systems Granger Causality and Dynamic Structural Systems Halbert White and Xun Lu Department of Economics University of California, San Diego June 26, 2008 Abstract We analyze the relations between Granger (G)

More information

11. Bootstrap Methods

11. Bootstrap Methods 11. Bootstrap Methods c A. Colin Cameron & Pravin K. Trivedi 2006 These transparencies were prepared in 20043. They can be used as an adjunct to Chapter 11 of our subsequent book Microeconometrics: Methods

More information

TESTING SERIAL CORRELATION IN SEMIPARAMETRIC VARYING COEFFICIENT PARTIALLY LINEAR ERRORS-IN-VARIABLES MODEL

TESTING SERIAL CORRELATION IN SEMIPARAMETRIC VARYING COEFFICIENT PARTIALLY LINEAR ERRORS-IN-VARIABLES MODEL Jrl Syst Sci & Complexity (2009) 22: 483 494 TESTIG SERIAL CORRELATIO I SEMIPARAMETRIC VARYIG COEFFICIET PARTIALLY LIEAR ERRORS-I-VARIABLES MODEL Xuemei HU Feng LIU Zhizhong WAG Received: 19 September

More information

Weak - Convergence: Theory and Applications

Weak - Convergence: Theory and Applications Weak - Convergence: Theory and Applications Jianning Kong y, Peter C. B. Phillips z, Donggyu Sul x October 26, 2018 Abstract The concept of relative convergence, which requires the ratio of two time series

More information

Economics 620, Lecture 19: Introduction to Nonparametric and Semiparametric Estimation

Economics 620, Lecture 19: Introduction to Nonparametric and Semiparametric Estimation Economics 620, Lecture 19: Introduction to Nonparametric and Semiparametric Estimation Nicholas M. Kiefer Cornell University Professor N. M. Kiefer (Cornell University) Lecture 19: Nonparametric Analysis

More information

R = µ + Bf Arbitrage Pricing Model, APM

R = µ + Bf Arbitrage Pricing Model, APM 4.2 Arbitrage Pricing Model, APM Empirical evidence indicates that the CAPM beta does not completely explain the cross section of expected asset returns. This suggests that additional factors may be required.

More information

PANEL DATA RANDOM AND FIXED EFFECTS MODEL. Professor Menelaos Karanasos. December Panel Data (Institute) PANEL DATA December / 1

PANEL DATA RANDOM AND FIXED EFFECTS MODEL. Professor Menelaos Karanasos. December Panel Data (Institute) PANEL DATA December / 1 PANEL DATA RANDOM AND FIXED EFFECTS MODEL Professor Menelaos Karanasos December 2011 PANEL DATA Notation y it is the value of the dependent variable for cross-section unit i at time t where i = 1,...,

More information

On the Power of Tests for Regime Switching

On the Power of Tests for Regime Switching On the Power of Tests for Regime Switching joint work with Drew Carter and Ben Hansen Douglas G. Steigerwald UC Santa Barbara May 2015 D. Steigerwald (UCSB) Regime Switching May 2015 1 / 42 Motivating

More information

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, SAN DIEGO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, SAN DIEGO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS 2-7 UNIVERSITY OF LIFORNI, SN DIEGO DEPRTMENT OF EONOMIS THE JOHNSEN-GRNGER REPRESENTTION THEOREM: N EXPLIIT EXPRESSION FOR I() PROESSES Y PETER REINHRD HNSEN DISUSSION PPER 2-7 JULY 2 The Johansen-Granger

More information

Large Panel Data Models with Cross-Sectional Dependence: A Surevey

Large Panel Data Models with Cross-Sectional Dependence: A Surevey Large Panel Data Models with Cross-Sectional Dependence: A Surevey Hashem Pesaran University of Southern California, CAFE, USA, and Trinity College, Cambridge, UK A Course on Panel Data Models, University

More information

On Parameter-Mixing of Dependence Parameters

On Parameter-Mixing of Dependence Parameters On Parameter-Mixing of Dependence Parameters by Murray D Smith and Xiangyuan Tommy Chen 2 Econometrics and Business Statistics The University of Sydney Incomplete Preliminary Draft May 9, 2006 (NOT FOR

More information