Persistence Heterogeneity Testing in Panels with Interactive Fixed Effects. Yunus Emre Ergemen and Carlos Velasco. CREATES Research Paper

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Persistence Heterogeneity Testing in Panels with Interactive Fixed Effects. Yunus Emre Ergemen and Carlos Velasco. CREATES Research Paper"

Transcription

1 Persistence Heterogeneity esting in Panels with Interactive Fixed Effects Yunus Emre Ergemen and Carlos Velasco CREAES Research Paper 8- Department of Economics and Business Economics Aarhus University Fuglesangs Allé 4 DK-8 Aarhus V Denmark oekonomi@au.dk el:

2 Persistence Heterogeneity esting in Panels with Interactive Fixed Effects Yunus Emre Ergemen Carlos Velasco March 9, 8 Abstract We consider large, panel data models with fixed effects, a common factor allowing for cross-section dependence, and persistent data and shocks, which are assumed fractionally integrated. In a basic setup, the main interest is on the fractional parameter of the idiosyncratic component, which is estimated in first differences after factor removal by projection on the cross-section average. he pooled conditional-sum-ofsquares estimate is consistent but the normal asymptotic distribution might not be centered, requiring the time series dimension to grow faster than the cross-section size for correction. We develop tests of homogeneity of dynamics, including the degree of integration, that have no trivial power under local departures from the null hypothesis of a non-negligible fraction of cross-section units. A simulation study shows that our estimates and test have good performance even in moderately small panels. Mathematics Subject Classification: 6G, 6F5, 6F, 6F, 6H5, 6M JEL Classification: C, C3 Keywords: Fractional integration, panel data, factor models, long memory, homogeneity test. CREAES and Department of Economics and Business Economics, Aarhus University. Fuglesangs Allé 4, Building 68, 8 Aarhus V, DEMARK. ergemen@econ.au.dk. Financial support from CREAES, Center for Research in Econometric Analysis of ime Series DRF78, funded by the Danish ational Research Foundation, is gratefully acknowledged. Corresponding Author. Department of Economics, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid, Calle Madrid, 6, 893 Getafe Madrid, SPAI. Carlos.Velasco@uc3m.es. Financial support from the Spanish Ministerio de Economía y Competitividad grants ECO and ECO7-869-P, ECO4-577p and MDM 4-43, and Comunidad de Madrid, MadEco-CM S5/HUM-3444 is gratefully acknowledged.

3 . Introduction he classical approach in the panel data literature for modeling persistence uses autoregressive AR models under different panel specifications. For example, Arellano and Bond 99 and Alvarez and Arellano 3 develop asymptotics for their estimators based on AR models characterized by homogeneous slope parameters under large and fixed or increasing. Pesaran 7 uses a dynamic panel setup to test for panel unit roots allowing for slope heterogeneity when and are both large. Han and Phillips obtain inference in an AR panel based on generalized method of moments GMM estimation with strong instruments when the homogeneous AR parameter is near unity. here is a recent literature on large, panel data models with long-range dependence constituting an alternative to AR specifications, see e.g. Robinson and Velasco 5, Ergemen and Velasco 7 and Ergemen 7. Like models with AR dynamics, these models nest I behaviour, but smoothly and thus the estimates of long-range dependence parameters are asymptotically normal unlike the nonstandard asymptotics under nonstationary AR specifications. his leads to chi-squared test statistics for memory parameter estimates and, for instance, panel unit-root testing can be readily performed based on the memory estimates. Although classical AR panel literature uses both homogeneous and heterogeneous AR parameter specifications in modeling persistence, little or no justification is provided for these choices. In fractional panel data literature, Ergemen and Velasco 7 and Ergemen 7 allow memory parameters under their setups to vary across cross-section units, providing valid arguments that this allows for a greater flexibility in suiting the presentation of data as well as describing the dynamics of different units more accurately rather than restricting all units to have the same dynamics. However, a formal testing procedure for persistence homogeneity has not yet been provided in the fractional panel data literature either. Developing such a test is important because when there is no statistically significant discrepancy between the integration orders of different cross-section units, it is preferable to employ pooled memory estimates that enjoy faster convergence rates and avoid the curse of dimensionality as increases. o fill in this gap, this paper develops a testing framework for persistence homogeneity when interactive fixed effects are also present. In doing so, we first present a rigorous treatment for a panel data model that allows for fractionally integrated long-range dependence in both idiosyncratic shocks and a common-factor structure that accounts for cross-section dependence. In the model, persistence is described by a memory or fractional integration parameter, constituting an alternative to dynamic autoregressive AR panel data models. he setup we consider requires that both the number of cross section units,, and the length of the time series,, grow in the asymptotics, departing from the case of multivariate time series with fixed or short panels with fixed. Our setup differs from Hassler et al. and Robinson and Velasco 5 in that we model cross-section dependence employing an unobservable common factor structure that can be serially correlated and display long-range dependence, which makes the model more general by introducing cross-section

4 dependence without further structural impositions on the idiosyncratic shocks. Using a type-ii fractionally integrated panel data model with fixed effects and crosssection dependence modeled through a common factor dependence, we allow for long-range persistence through this factor and the integrated idiosyncratic shock. he model assumes a common set of parameters for the dynamics of the idiosyncratic component of all crosssectional units. We deal with the fixed effects and the unobservable common factor through first differencing and projection on the cross-section average of the differenced data as a proxy for the common factor, respectively. hen, estimation of the memory parameter is based on a pooled conditional sum of squares CSS criterion function of the projection residuals which produces estimates asymptotically equivalent to Gaussian ML estimates. We require to impose conditions on the rate of growth of and to control for the projection error and for an initial condition bias induced by first differencing of the type-ii fractionally integrated error terms, so that our pooled estimate can achieve the convergence rate. We nevertheless discuss bias correction methods that relax the restriction that should grow substantially faster than in the joint asymptotics, which would not affect the estimation of the heterogeneous model. We also propose a heterogenous model whose estimates, adapting the same CSS criterion to have heterogeneous dynamics, are shown to be asymptotically normal for each cross section unit as gets larger. We then develop LM tests for dynamics homogeneity that are similar to the slope homogeneity tests of Su and Chen 3 in panel data models with interactive fixed effects and that allow for scale heterogeneity. In particular, these tests include the null of homogenous degree of integration and have no trivial power under local departures from the null hypothesis of a non-negligible fraction of cross-section units. We explore the performance of our estimates and tests via Monte Carlo experiments, which indicate that our inference methods have good small-sample properties in a variety of scenarios. ext section details the model and necessary assumptions. Section 3 explains the estimation strategy for both homogeneous and heterogeneous parameters, and discusses the asymptotic behaviour of the estimates. Section 4 shows the details of persistence homogeneity testing along with the asymptotics. Section 5 presents Monte Carlo simulations. Finally, Section 6 concludes the paper. hroughout the paper, we use the notation, j to denote joint cross-section and timeseries asymptotics, p to denote convergence in probability and d to denote convergence in distribution. All mathematical proofs and technical lemmas are collected in the appendix.. he Model In this section, we detail a type-ii fractionally integrated panel data model with fixed effects and cross-section dependence and list our assumptions. We consider that the observable y it 3

5 satisfy λ t L; θ y it α i γ i f t = ε it, for t =,,...,, i =,...,, where ε it iid, σ are idiosyncratic shocks; θ Θ R p+ is a p + parameter vector; L is the lag operator and for any θ Θ and for each t, t λ t L; θ = λ j θ L j truncates λ L; θ = λ L; θ. We assume that λ L; θ has this particular structure, λ L; θ = δ ψ L; ξ, where δ is a scalar, ξ is a p vector, θ = δ, ξ. filter δ has the expansion Here = L, so that the fractional δ = π j δl j, π j δ = Γj δ Γj + Γ δ, and denote the truncated version as δ t = t π jδl j, with Γ δ = δ for δ =,,..., Γ /Γ = ; ψ L; ξ is a known function such that for complex-valued x, ψ x; ξ, x and in the expansion ψ L; ξ = ψ j ξ L j, the coefficients ψ j ξ satisfy ψ ξ =, ψ j ξ = O exp c ξ j, 3 where c ξ is a positive-valued function of ξ. ote that λ j θ = j π j k δ ψ k ξ, j, 4 k= behaves asymptotically as π j δ, see Robinson and Velasco 5, where λ j θ = ψ ; ξ π j δ + O j δ, as j, π j δ = Γ δ j δ + Oj as j, so the value of δ determines the asymptotic stationarity δ < / or nonstationarity δ / of y it α i γ i f t and ψl; ξ describes short memory dynamics. 4

6 he α i are unobservable fixed effects, γ i unobservable factor loadings and f t is the unobservable common factor that is assumed to be an Iϱ process, where we treat ϱ as a nuisance parameter. his way the model incorporates heterogeneity through α i as well as γ i and also introduces account cross-section dependence by means of the factor structure, γ i f t, which was not considered in Robinson and Velasco 5. When we write as y it = α i + γ i f t + λ t L; θ ε it = α i + γ i f t + λ L; θ {ε it t }, where is the indicator function, the memory of the observed y it is max {δ, ϱ}, where f t could be the major source of persistence in data. he model could be complemented with the presence of incidental trends and other exogenous or endogenous observable regressor series, see Ergemen and Velasco 7 and Ergemen 7. he model can be reorganized in terms of the variable δ t y it for i =,...,, and t =,..., and when ψ L; ξ = ξ L corresponds to a finite AR polynomial as δ t y it = ξ δ t α i + ξ δ t y it + γ i ξ L δ t f t + ε it, which is then easily comparable to a standard dynamic AR panel data model with crosssection dependence, e.g. that of Han and Phillips, y it = ρα i + ρy it + γ i f t + ε it. In both models, error terms are iid, and there are fixed effects so long as δ, ξ and ρ. However, autoregressive panel data models can only cover a limited range of persistence levels, just I or I series depending on whether ρ < or ρ =. On the other hand, the fractional model covers a wide range of persistence levels depending on the values of δ and ϱ, including the unit root case and beyond. In addition, accounts for persistence in cross-section dependence depending on the degree of integration of δ t f t. We are interested in conducting inference on θ, in particular on δ. For the analysis in this paper we require that both and increase simultaneously due to presence of the unobserved common factor and the initial condition term in the fractional difference operator, unlike in Robinson and Velasco 5, who only require to grow in the asymptotics, while could be constant or diverging simultaneously with. In the first part of the paper we assume a common vector parameter, including a common integration parameter δ, for all cross-section units i =,...,. While the fractional integration parameter may as well be allowed to be heterogeneous, our approach is geared towards getting a pooled estimate for the entire panel exploiting potential efficiency gains. Further, this pooling has to control for potential distortions due to common factor elimination, that, as well as fixed effects removal, lead to some bias in the asymptotic distribution of parameter estimates, cf. Robinson and Velasco 5. We use the following assumptions throughout the paper: Assumption A. 5

7 A.. he idiosyncratic shocks, ε it, i =,,...,, t =,,,..., are independently and identically distributed both across i and t with zero mean and variance σ, and have a finite fourth-order moment, and δ, 3/. A.. he Iϱ common factor is f t = ϱ t z f t, ϱ < 3/, where z f t = ϕ f L v f t k with ϕf s = k= ϕf k sk, k= k ϕf k <, ϕf s for s, and v f t iid, σf, E vf t 4 <. A.3. ε it and f t are independent of the factor loadings γ i, and are independent of each other for all i and t. A.4. Factor loadings γ i are independently and identically distributed across i, sup i E γ i <, and γ = γ i. A.5. For ξ Ξ, ψ x; ξ is differentiable in ξ and, for all ξ ξ, ψ x; ξ ψ x; ξ on a subset of {x : x = } of positive Lebesgue measure, and 3 holds for all ξ Ξ with c ξ satisfying inf c ξ = Ξ c >. 5 Assumption A. implies that the idiosyncratic errors λ L; θ ε it, are fractionally integrated with asymptotically stationary increments, δ < 3/, which will be exploited by our projection technique. he homoskedasticity assumption on idiosyncratic shocks, ε it, is not restrictive since y it are still heteroskedastic as α i and γ i vary in each cross section. By Assumption A., the common factor f t is a zero mean fractionally integrated Iϱ linear process, with the I increments possibly displaying short-range serial dependence but with positive and smooth spectral density at all frequencies. he zero mean assumption is not restrictive since we are allowing for fixed effects α i which are not restricted in any way. Restrictions similar to Assumption A. have been used under different setups in e.g. Hualde and Robinson and ielsen 4. Under Assumption A., the range of persistence for the common factor covers unit root and beyond, making the model a powerful tool for several practical problems. Although we treat ϱ as a nuisance parameter, in empirical applications this parameter could be estimated based on the cross-section average of the observed series using semiparametric estimates, e.g. with a local Whittle approach. Assumption A.3 and A.4 are standard identifying conditions in one-factor models as also used in e.g. Pesaran 6 and Bai 9. In particular, the condition on γ is related to Assumption 5b of Pesaran 6 and used to guarantee that our projection to remove factors works in finite samples. Assumption A.5 ensures that ψ L; ξ is smooth for ξ Ξ, and the weights ψ j lead to shortmemory dynamics as is also assumed by Robinson and Velasco 5, where the parameter space Ξ can depend on stationarity and invertibility restrictions on ψ L; ξ. 3. Parameter Estimation Bai 9 and Pesaran 6, among many others, study the estimation of panel data 6

8 models with cross-section dependence. Bai 9 estimates the slope parameter in an interactive fixed effects model where the regressors and the common factor are stationary and idiosyncratic shocks exhibit no long-range dependence. Likewise, Pesaran 6 estimates the slope parameter in a multifactor panel data model where covariates are I. In this section we focus on the estimation of the parameter vector θ that describes the idiosyncratic dynamics of data, including the degree of integration. In our estimation strategy, we first project out the unobserved common structure using sample averages of first-differenced data as proxies, where the fixed effects are readily removed by differencing. We then use a pooled conditional-sum-of-squares CSS estimation on first differences based on the remaining errors after projection. First-differencing to remove α i, we get y it = γ i f t + λ t L; θ ε it, i =,...,, t =,,...,, where we denote by θ the true parameter vector, and then y it is projected on the crosssection average ȳ t = y it as non-scaled proxies for f t with the projection coefficient ˆφ i given by ˆφ i = ȳ t y it ȳ t, which we assume can be computed for every i with ȳ t >. hen we compute the residuals ε it θ = λ t L; θ y it ˆφ i ȳ t, i =,...,, t =,...,. where θ = δ, ξ adapts to the previous differencing initial step. hen we denote by ˆθ the estimate of the unknown true parameter vector θ, ˆθ = arg min θ Θ L, θ, where we assume Θ is compact and L, is the CSS of the projection residuals after fractional differencing L, θ = ε it θ, which is the relevant part of the concentrated out of σ Gaussian likelihood for ε it θ. ote that after the first-differencing transformation to remove α i, there is a mismatch between the sample available t =,,..., and the length of the filter λ t L; θ that can be applied to it, with the filter λ t L; θ that generates the data, since for instance λ t L; θ λ t L; θ ε it = λ t L; θ λ t L; θ ε it λ t θ ε i, because λ t L; θ = λ t L; θ, t =,,.... Even when θ = θ, all residuals involve ε i, i.e. the initial condition, which is reflected in a bias term of ˆθ as in Robinson and Velasco 5. 7

9 he estimates are only implicitly defined and entail optimization over Θ = D Ξ, where Ξ is a compact subset of R p and D= [δ, δ], with < δ < δ < 3/. We aim to cover a wide range of values of δ D with our asymptotics, c.f. ielsen 4 and Hualde and Robinson, but there are interactions with other model parameters that might require to restrict the set D reflecting some a priori knowledge on the true value of δ or to introduce further assumptions on and. In particular, and departing from Robinson and Velasco 5, it is essential to consider the interplay of ϱ and δ, i.e. the memories of the unobservable common factor and of the idiosyncratic shocks, respectively, since projection on cross-section averages of first differenced data is assuming that f t is asymptotically stationary, but possibly with more persistence than the idiosyncratic components. hen, for the asymptotic analysis of the estimate of θ, we further introduce the following assumptions. Assumption B. he lower bound δ of the set D satisfies max {ϱ, δ } / < δ δ. 6 Assumption B indicates that if the set D is quite informative on the lower possible value of δ and this is not far from ϱ, the CSS estimate is consistent irrespective of the relationship between and, as we show in our first result. heorem. Under Assumptions A and B, θ Θ, and as, j, ˆθ p θ. Although the sufficient condition in Assumption B may seem restrictive, the lower bound could be adapted accordingly to meet the distance requirement from ϱ and δ using information on the whereabouts of these parameters. his assumption may be relaxed at the cost of restricting the relative rates of growth of and in the asymptotics. In the technical appendix, we provide more general conditions that are implied by Assumption B to prove this result. A similar result of consistency for CSS estimates is provided by Hualde and Robinson and ielsen 4 for fractional time series models and in Robinson and Velasco 5 for fractional panels without common factors. ote that the theorem only imposes that both and grow jointly, but there is no restriction on their rate of growth when 6 holds. his contrasts with the results in Robinson and Velasco 5, where only was required to grow and could be fixed or increasing in the asymptotics. An increasing therein is required to control for the initial condition contribution due to first differencing for fixed effects elimination, as is needed here, but projection on cross-section averages for factor removal further requires that both and grow. ext, we establish the asymptotic distribution of the parameter estimates, for which we assume that ψ L; ξ is twice continuously differentiable for all ξ Ξ with ψ t L; ξ = 8

10 d/dξψ t L; ξ where it is assumed that ψ t L; ξ = O exp cξj. In establishing the asymptotic behaviour, the most delicate part is formulating the asymptotic bias. he initial condition IC bias of ˆθ / θ is proportional to θ, where θ = τ t θ { τ t θ χ t ξ } where τ t θ = λ t θ = λ t L; θ = t λ j θ, τ t θ = / θτ t θ and χ t is defined by χ L; ξ = θ log λ L; θ = log, / ξ log ψ L; ξ = χ j ξ L j. he term θ, depending only on the unknown θ and, also found in Robinson and Velasco 5, appears because of the data-index mismatch that arises due to time truncation for negative values and first differencing. j= Introduce the p + p + matrix [ B ξ = χ j ξ χ π /6 j ξ = j= χ j ξ /j j= j= χ j ξ /j j= χ j ξ χ j ξ ], and assume B ξ is non-singular. For the asymptotic distribution analysis we further require the following conditions. Assumption C. C.. As, j, log + 3. C.. max {/4, ϱ /} < δ min {5/4, 5/ ϱ}. he next result shows that the fractional integration parameter estimate is asymptotically normal and efficient at the convergence rate. heorem. Under Assumptions A, B and C, θ IntΘ, as, j, ˆθ / θ B ξ θ d, B ξ, where θ = O δ log {δ < } + log {δ = } + {δ > }. Corollary. Under Assumptions of heorem, / ˆθ θ d, B ξ for δ >, and this also holds when δ 3, if additionally, as, j, 4δ log, and when δ = if log 4. 9

11 hese results parallel heorem 5.3 in Robinson and Velasco 5 additionally using Assumption C to control for the projection errors and requiring to grow with to remove the cross-sectionally averaged error terms, while the range of allowed values of δ is limited in the same way. Assumption C. basically requires that grows faster than, but slower than 3, so that different projection errors are not dominating to achieve the rate of convergence. his last restriction is milder than the related conditions that impose for slope estimation, e.g. Pesaran 6, but we also need to grow faster than to control the initial condition bias. Condition C. is only a sufficient condition basically requiring that the overall memory, ϱ + δ, be not too large so that common factor projection with first-differenced data works well, especially if grows relatively fast with respect to, and that ϱ is not much larger than δ, so the common factor distortion can be controlled for. We relax these sufficient conditions in the technical appendix to prove our results. he asymptotic centered normality of the uncorrected estimates further requires that δ > in view of Assumption C., so it is interesting for statistical inference purposes to 3 explore a bias correction. Let θ be the fractional integration parameter estimate with IC bias correction constructed by plugging in the uncorrected estimate ˆθ, θ = ˆθ B ˆξ ˆθ. he next result shows that the bias-corrected estimate is asymptotically centered and efficient at the convergence rate. Corollary. Under Assumptions of heorem, / θ θ d, B ξ. Bias correction cannot relax the lower bound restriction on the true fractional integration parameter δ, but eliminates some further restrictions on and though still requires Assumption C. which implies the restrictions of heorem 5. of Robinson and Velasco 5 for a similar result in the absence of factors. 3. Estimation of a Heterogeneous Model Although a panel data approach allows for efficient inference under a homogeneous setup, it may be restrictive from an empirical perspective. Most of the time, the applied econometrician is interested in understanding how each cross-section unit behaves while accounting for dependence between these units. We therefore consider the heterogeneous version of with the same prescribed properties as λ t L; θ i y it α i γ i f t = ε it, 7 where θ i may change for each cross-section unit. his type of heterogeneous modelling is well motivated in country-specific analyses of economic unions and asset-specific analyses

12 of portfolios where cross-section correlations are permitted and generally the interest is in obtaining inference for a certain unit rather than for the panel. Under the heterogeneous setup, just like in the homogeneous case, the common factor structure is asymptotically replaced by the cross-section averages of the first-differenced data under the sufficient conditions given in Assumption C. he asymptotic behaviour of the heterogeneous estimates can be easily derived from the results obtained in heorems and taking = as follows. ow, denote ˆθ i = arg min θ Θ i L i, θ, with Θ i defined as before, D i = [ δ i, δ i ], 3/, and L i, θ = ε iθε i θ, where ε i = ε i,..., ε i, and ε it θ i = λ t L; θ y it ˆφ i ȳ t. i We have the following results replacing δ, δ and δ in Assumptions A., A.5, B and C. with δ i, δ i and δ i, respectively. We denote these conditions as A i, B i and C i, and assume them to hold for all i. heorem 3. Under Assumptions A i and B i, θ i Θ i, and as, j, ˆθ i p θ i, and under Assumptions A i, B i and C i, θ i IntΘ i, as, j, / ˆθi θ i d, B ξ i. An increasing is still needed here, as in the homogeneous setting, since the projection errors arising due to factor removal require that. However the asymptotic theory is made easier due to the convergence rate being just now, with which the initial-condition IC bias asymptotically vanishes for all values of δ i D, without any restriction on the relative rate of growth of and. 4. Homogeneity est In both AR and fractional panel data literature, the use of homogeneous versus heterogeneous dynamic parameters is a rather arbitrary choice in theoretical modeling of persistence. While it can be argued that allowing for heterogeneity in dynamics is a more flexible way

13 of modeling persistence in applied research, this can cause efficiency losses when the true dynamics are homogeneous. For example, Ergemen 7 analyzes debt and GDP series for OECD countries under heterogeneity of dynamics, however both series are estimated to be I series, in which case considering homogeneous dynamics appear to be a more efficient approach. Bearing in my mind such possibilities and the lack of formal justifications for the heterogeneity of dynamics in the literature, we develop a formal testing procedure in this section. We propose a test of the model against its heterogeneous version 7 similar to the LM test developed in Su and Chen 3 for slope homogeneity in panel data models with interactive fixed effects. In order to set up the testing framework, we use the following auxiliary heterogeneous model λ t L; θ + ϑ i y it α i γ i f t = ε it, where ϑ i denote the deviations from a common value θ and the null hypothesis of homogeneity corresponds to H : ϑ = = ϑ =. o estimate the deviations we use the CSS loss function L, ϑ,..., ϑ = ε it ϑ i where ε it ϑ i = λ t L; ˆθ + ϑ i y it ˆφ i ȳ t, i =,...,, t =,...,, with ˆθ defined in Section 3 and to test the null hypothesis H against H : at least one ϑ j, we consider LM tests, evaluating under H the derivatives of L,, L, ϑ,..., ϑ = ε it ϑ i ε it ϑ i ϑ i ϑ i i.e. hen we can check that ϑ i ϑ i = ϑ i L,,..., = L,,..., = + { ε it ϑ i λ t L; ϑ ˆθ } + ϑ i λ t L; ˆθ ε it ˆθ, i ε it ˆθχ t L; ˆθ ε it ˆθ. { ε it ˆθ λ ϑ i ϑ t L; ˆθ } y it ˆφ i ȳ t i χ t L; ˆθ ε it ˆθχ t L; ˆθ ε it ˆθ,

14 and that the cross derivatives with respect to ϑ i and ϑ j, i j, are identically zero, so we can set up the following LM type statistic LM = ε it ˆθ ε itˆθ Bˆθ ε it ˆθ ε itˆθ = ε it ˆθε is ˆθ ε itˆθbˆθ ε is ˆθ, s= where ε it ˆθ = χ t L; ˆθ ε it ˆθ and we replace the second derivative of the CSS function by Bˆθ as an approximation to the limit of ε itˆθ ε itˆθ for each i, ignoring the contributions from second derivatives of λ t L; θ. If a common parameter estimate ˆθ describes properly the dynamics of all cross-sections, then we expect, for all i, ε it ˆθ to be approximately uncorrelated with ε it ˆθ, which only depends on past observations of ε it ˆθ. However, as the number of restrictions increases with, we consider instead a properly centred and scaled statistics in the joint asymptotics, as in Su and Chen 3 where J = / LM B / V B = V = / ε itˆθ ε it ˆθBˆθ ε itˆθ ˆσ 4 i [ ε itˆθbˆθ ε is ˆθ s= ] with individual estimates ˆσ i = ε itˆθ to account for possible heterogeneity in the variances across cross-section units, where V can be replaced by V = p + ˆσ i 8, or, under cross-section unconditional homoskedasticity, by V = ˆσ4 [ s= ε itˆθbˆθ ε is ˆθ ] or just V = p + ˆσ8 with ˆσ = ε itˆθ. We introduce a variant of Assumption A for our asymptotic analysis. Assumption A*. All other conditions in Assumption A hold and Assumption A. is replaced by 3

15 A.*. he idiosyncratic shocks, ε it, i =,,...,, t =,,,..., are independently and identically distributed across t and are independent across i, with zero mean and variance σi, and have a finite th-order moment uniformly in i, with σ 8 = lim σi 8 <, 8 and δ, 3/. Assumption A* removes the identical distribution condition across i, in particular allowing for heterogeneity across i in the variance, and it can be shown that under Assumption A* and the rest of conditions of Corollary, / ˆθ θ = O p and is still asymptotically normal but with a different asymptotic variance, increased by the factor σ 4 / σ > compared to the homoskedastic case, with σ 4 and σ defined as described in 8. It also requires an increased number of moments to account for the structure of LM. heorem 4. Under the assumptions of Corollary and Assumption A*, as, j, under H, J d,. hen the null hypothesis is rejected when J is large compared to the corresponding critical value from the standard normal distribution. In practice we would expect that V and V perform better than V or V under the null in finite samples, since they resemble more closely the actual variability in LM, as the asymptotic approximations on which V and V are based might need moderate values of and to be accurate. Similar tests can be developed to test homogeneity in some subset of θ while maintaining homogeneity in the remaining dimensions. For that we just need to replace ε it ˆθ in the definition LM, B and V by the corresponding coordinates of the p + vector χ t L; ˆθ ε it ˆθ to be tested, and then, possibly, replace p + in the definitions of V or V by the number of homogeneity restrictions tested. o investigate the power properties of our LM test we consider the following sequence of local alternatives H, : ϑ i = ζ /4 / for i I for some p + -vector ζ and some index set I satisfying for n =, 4, σ n = lim i I σ n i,, which indicates that a non-negligible proportion of cross-section units display dynamics local to those defined by the common value θ. he next theorem shows that our homogeneity test has no trivial power under these local alternatives, which converge as in Su and Chen 3 to the null almost at an optimal rate defined by the rate of convergence of the pooled estimate ˆθ. 4

16 heorem 5. Under the assumptions of heorem 4, as, j, under H,, σ 4 ζ B ζ J d +,. p + σ 8 / he positive drift depends naturally on the value of ζ, on the parameters that are not constant across i through B, and on the relative variability of the cross-section units whose dynamics depart from H through the ratio σ 4 / σ 8 /. In case of homoskedasticity, we find trivially that this drift is just υζ B ζ/ p + / where υ = lim i I,, and for a pure fractional model the drift amounts to υζ δ π / Monte Carlo Simulations In this section we carry out a Monte Carlo experiment to study the small-sample performance of the memory estimates and the homogeneity test in the simplest case in which there are no idiosyncratic short memory dynamics, ξ =, no heteroskedasticity and persistence depends only on the value of δ. We draw the idiosyncratic shocks ε i,t as standard normal and the factor loadings γ i from U.5, not to restrict the sign. We then generate serially correlated common factors f t =.5f t + ϱ t z f t, based on the iid shocks z f t drawn as standard normals and then fractionally integrated to the order ϱ. he individual effects α i are left unspecified since they are removed via first differencing in the estimation, and projections are based on the first-differenced data. We focus on different cross-section and time-series sizes, and, as well as different values of δ and ϱ, and different ζ values leading to departures from the null to determine the power in the testing case. Simulations are based on, replications. 5.. Memory Estimation We investigate the finite-sample properties of our estimate of δ. In this case, we set =, and = 5, for values of δ =.3,.6,.9,,.,.4 thus covering a heavily biased stationary case, a slightly nonstationary case, near-unit-root cases and finally a quite nonstationary case, respectively. We report total biases containing initial-condition and projection biases as well as carry out bias correction based on estimated memory values to obtain projection biases for ϱ =.4,. As is clear in able, when the factors are less persistent ϱ =.4, the estimate is heavily biased for the stationary case of δ =.3 while the bias gets considerably smaller around the unit-root case. oticeably, the bias becomes negative when δ.6 for several, combinations. Better results in terms of bias are obtained with increasing. Expectedly, when the factors have a unit root, the estimate of δ contains a larger bias in the stationary δ =.3 and in the moderately nonstationary δ =.6 cases because the 5

17 idiosyncratic shocks are dominated by a more persistent common factor. Biases for other memory values are also exacerbated due to factor persistence increase except for the very high persistent case δ =.4. Bias correction works reasonably well when ϱ =.4 although benefits are limited for ϱ =. While there is a monotonically decreasing pattern for increasing δ in terms of bias both for the total bias and bias-corrected cases, magnitudes of biases increase when δ leaves the neighbourhood of unity. able also reports the root mean square errors RMSE, which indicate that performance increases with increasing δ, and. Standard errors are dominated by bias in terms of contribution to RMSE. able shows the empirical coverage of 95% confidence intervals of δ based on the asymptotics of our estimate. For ϱ =.4,, the true fractional parameter is poorly covered when δ.6. Bias correction in these cases improves the results reasonably. For near-unit-root cases, the estimate achieves the most accurate coverage, especially by comparison with intervals based on estimates of δ =.4 and δ Homogeneity est o determine the size and power properties of our test, we consider = 5, to study a factor-augmented multivariate time-series setup and a small panel setup, respectively, and = 5, to show the usefulness of our test in empirical studies that use moderately small time series. We also consider the pure fractional case in which both the common factor and the idiosyncratic errors are pure fractional processes as well as the case in which the common factor, generated as in the previous subsection, is serially correlated. In terms of size, the test performs well for δ < while it may be oversized when δ, as able 3 shows. An increasing drives down the size of the test while an increasing does not affect the size much. When δ, an increasing ϱ exacerbates the oversize problem of the test, which is quite pronounced when the factor is serially correlated. o check the power properties of the test, we consider ζ =. /4 /,.5 /4 /, corresponding to local departure values of. and.5 under H,, and for ease of exposition, we analyze the case in which ϑ i exhibit departures from the null for all i. able 4 shows that when the departures from the null are by., the test has low power for δ.6 although for other δ values, the power is reasonably high attaining the maximum when δ = in most cases. Increasing, help in terms of power improvement. When ζ =.5 /4 / in able 5, power of the test is quite high in all cases except when δ =.3. hese results also reflect the findings from the previous setting and even more so, demonstrate that the test is consistent even for relatively small panels. 6. Final Comments We have considered large, panel data models with fixed effects and cross-section dependence where the idiosyncratic shocks and common factors are allowed to exhibit long-range 6

18 dependence. Our methodology for memory estimation consists in conditional-sum-of-squares estimation on the first differences of defactored variables, where projections are carried out on the sample means of differenced data. We then develop tests for homogeneity of dynamics based on deviations from our homogeneous estimates. While Monte Carlo experiments indicate satisfactory results, our methodology can be extended in the following directions: a Different estimation techniques, such as fixed effects and GMM, can be used under our setup as in Robinson and Velasco 5; b he idiosyncratic shocks may be allowed to feature spatial dependence providing further insights in empirical analyses. Design of persistence homogeneity tests in a setting that allows for spatial dependence, though possibly challenging, could make testing procedures more robust. 7. echnical Appendix We prove our results under more general conditions that are implied by Assumptions B and C allowing for some trade off between the choice of δ and the asymptotic relationship between and. he weaker counterpart of Assumption B is as follows. Assumption B. B.. δ < δ/ and ϱ < δ/. B.. If ϱ δ >, as, j, B.3. If δ δ, as, j, ϱ δ δ δ + δ +ϱ 4δ log + ϱ +δ. 7. Proof of heorem he projection parameter from the projection of y it on its cross-section averages, ȳ t, can be written as where η i = ˆφ i = ȳ t y it ȳ t ȳ t λ t L; θ ε it γ i ε γ t ȳ t = γ i γ + η i 9 is the projection error. he conditional sum of squares then can be written as L, θ = λ t L; θ ε it ˆφ i ε t τ t θε i ˆφ i ε η i γλ t L; θ f t 7

19 where λ t L; θ = λ t L; θ λ t L; θ = t λ j θ L j. and in the first term is the corrected usual idiosyncratic component, the second term is the initial condition term, and the third term is the projection error component. j= Following Hualde and Robinson we give the proof for the most general case where possibly δ δ /. Additionally, the common factor in our model is Iϱ by Assumption A.. While δ may take arbitrary values from [δ, δ], 3/, ensuring uniform convergence of L, θ requires the study of cases depending on δ δ, while controlling the distance ϱ δ. We analyze these separately in the following. In analyzing the idiosyncratic component and the initial condition component, we closely follow Hualde and Robinson. For ɛ >, define Q ɛ = {θ : δ δ < ɛ}, Q ɛ = {θ : θ / Q ɛ, δ D}. For small enough ɛ, P rˆθ Q ɛ P r inf S, θ Θ Q ɛ where S, θ = L, θ L, θ. In the rest of the proof, we will show that L, θ, and thus S, θ, converges in probability to a well-behaved function when δ δ < / and diverges when δ δ /. In order to analyze the asymptotic behaviour of S, δ in the neighborhood of δ = δ /, a special treatment is required. For arbitrarily small ζ >, such that ζ < δ / δ, let us define the disjoint sets Θ = {θ : δ δ δ / ζ}, Θ = {θ : δ / ζ < δ < δ /}, Θ 3 = {θ : δ / δ δ / + ζ} and Θ 4 = { θ : δ / + ζ < δ δ }, so Θ = 4 k= Θ k. hen we will show P r inf S, δ θ Q ɛ Θ k as, j, k =,..., 4. We write L, θ in as { λ t L; θ ε it ˆφ i ε t + τ t θε i ˆφ i ε + ηi γ λ t L; θ f t η i γ λ t L; θ f t λ t L; θ ε it ˆφ i ε t + η i γ λ t L; θ f t τ t θε i ˆφ i ε λ t L; θ ε it ˆφ i ε t τ t θε i ˆφ } i ε. he projection error component in the conditional sum of squares, γ ηi λ t L; θ f t = o p, sup θ Θ 8

20 because the left hand side is O p ϱ+δ 6 + log + 4δ 6 + +O p 4ϱ+δ δ 7 + ϱ δ log + ϱ δ+4δ 7 + ϱ δ = o p uniformly in θ Θ by γ p E [γ i ], Lemmas and a and Assumption B. since ϱ + δ δ < 7/, ϱ δ < and ϱ + δ δ < 7/, are implied by Assumption B.. Similarly, sup θ Θ τt θε i ˆφ i ε = sup θ Θ τt θ = O p δ + log ε i ˆφ i ε i ε + ˆφ i ε 3, O p = o p, because δ >, ε i + ˆφ i = O p, ε = O p / and Cauchy-Schwarz inequality, see Lemma, and therefore we find for the cross term corresponding to the sum of squares in and 3 that sup θ Θ η i γλ t L; θ f t τ t θε i ˆφ i ε = o p uniformly in δ by, 3 and Cauchy-Schwarz inequality. he other cross terms involving usual fractional residuals λ t L; θ ε it ˆφ i ε t are also uniformly o p for θ Θ 4 using Cauchy-Schwarz inequality and that the part of the conditional sum of squares in λ t L; θ ε it ˆφ i ε t converges uniformly in this set. Lemmas 3 and 4 show that these cross terms are also uniformly o p for θ Θ Θ Θ 3 under the assumptions of the theorem. hen to show we only need to analyze the terms in λ t L; θ ε it ˆφ i ε t for Θ k, k =,..., 4 as in Hualde and Robinson. Proof for k = 4. We show that [ ] sup λ t L; θ ε it ˆφ i ε t σ λ j θ = o p, 4 θ Θ 4 analyzing the idiosyncratic term, ε it, and the cross-section averaged term, ˆφ i ε t, separately. For the idiosyncratic term, we first show following Hualde and Robinson, λ t L; θ ε it = t λ j θ ε it j p σ λ j θ, uniformly in δ by Assumption as, j since / + ζ < δ δ for some ζ >. Since the limit is uniquely minimized at θ = θ as it is positive for all θ θ, holds for k = 4 if 4 holds and the contribution of cross-section averaged term, ˆφ i ε t, is negligible. 9

21 o check 4 we show sup t t λ j θ ε it j E λ j θ ε it j θ Θ 4 = o p, where the term in absolute value is hen, + λ j θ j ε il σ l= λ j θ λ k θ E sup a Θ 4 j l=k j+ sup λ j θ E Θ 4 ε il ε il k j = a + b. 5 j ε il σ. Uniformly in j, V ar j l= ε il = O, so using / + ζ < δ δ, sup a = O p Θ 4 / / j= By summation by parts, the term b is equal to λ θ λ j θ j k=j+ l=k j+ k=j+ [ λ k+ θ λ k θ ] l= j ζ = O p / /. λ j θ ε il ε il k j k j r=j+ l=r j+ ε il ε il r j = b + b. hen, using that V ar j { } k=j+ l=k j+ εil ε il k j = O uniformly in i and j, j { } / E sup b ζ 3/ j ζ / V ar εil ε il k j / ζ, Θ 4 while E sup b Θ 4 j= j= j ζ / / / j= k=j+ j ζ / k=j+ l=k j+ k ζ 3/ V ar k=j+ k j r=j+ l=r j+ { εil ε il r j } / k ζ 3/ k j / K / ζ,

22 and therefore b = O p / ζ = o p. ext, we deal with the terms carrying ε t in the LHS of 4. We write ˆφ i λ t L; θ ε t = ˆφ i λ t L; θ ε t. 6 he average in i is O p by Lemma, while the sum in t in the lhs 6 satisfies for θ with first component θ = ζ, λ σ t L; θ ε t = Op λ j θ = O p = o p as, uniformly in θ Θ 4 as, and 6 is at most O p = o p uniformly in θ Θ 4. Finally, the cross-term due to the square on the lhs of 4 is asymptotically negligible by Cauchy-Schwarz inequality. So we have proved 4, and therefore we have proved for k = 4. Proof for k = 3,. he uniform convergence for the idiosyncratic component for the proof of follows as in Hualde and Robinson, since the average in i =,..., adds no additional complication as in the case k = 4. he treatment for the cross-section averaged term and the cross-product term follows from the same steps as the idiosyncratic term as well as the results we derived for k = 4 using ˆφ i = O p and that ε t has variance σ /. Proof for k =. oting that L, θ := λ t L; θ ε it φ i ε t we write P r inf L, θ > K P r ζ inf Θ Θ since δ δ / ζ. δ δ+/ λ t L; θ ε it φ i ε t, λ t L; θ ε it j φ i ε t j > K For arbitrarily small ɛ >, we show P r ζ inf λ Θ δ δ+/ t L; θ ε it j φ i ε t j > K P r inf λ Θ δ δ+/ t L; θ ε it j φ i ε t j > ɛ as, j.

23 h Define h i, δ = δ +δ / λ t L; θ ε it j = / δ = δ+δ / λ t L; θ ε t j = / j= in Marinucci and Robinson, for each i =,...,, h i, δ λ ; θ j= λ j θ δ δ ε it j and λ j θ δ δ ε t j. By the weak convergence results s δ δ Γδ δ + δb is as, j, where B i s is a scalar Brownian motion, i =,...,, and by we mean convergence in the space of continuous functions in Θ with uniform metric. ightness and finite dimensional convergence follows from the[ fractional ] invariance property presented in heorem in Hosoya 5 as well as sup i E h i, δ <. Similarly, / h δ is weakly converging to the same functional of B s. hen, as, j, following the discussions for double-index processes in Phillips and Moon 999 and φ i = O p, λ δ δ+/ t L; θ ε it j φ i ε t j p λ ; θ s δ δ Var Γδ δ + δbs uniformly in θ Θ, where inf λ ; θ Var Θ so that P r inf Θ δ δ+/ s δ δ Γδ δ + δbs = = σ λ ; θ δ δ + Γ δ δ +, σ δ δ + Γ δ δ + >, λ t L; θ ε it j φ i ε t j > ɛ as, j and follows for i = as ɛ is arbitrarily small. 7. Other Proofs in Sections 3 and 4 We use the following more general conditions that are implied by Assumption C in our proofs. Assumption C. C.. As, j, C.. As, j, log ϱ+δ log + 8δ log ϱ+δ 3 + δ log log.

24 C.3. As, j, δ. Proof of heorem. We first analyze the first derivative of L, θ evaluated at θ = θ, θ L, θ θ=θ = { η i γλ t L; θ f t τ t θ ε i ˆφ i ε + ε it ˆφ } i ε t { η i γχ t L; ξ λ t L; θ f t τ t θ where χ t L; ξ ε it = χ t L; ξ ε it + χ t ξ ε i. In open form with the / normalization, ε i ˆφ i ε + χ t L; ξ ε it ˆφ } i ε t, θ L, θ θ=θ = ηi γ λ t L; θ f t χ t L; ξ λ t L; θ f t 7 τ t θ τ t θ ε i ˆφ i ε 8 η i γλ t L; θ f t τ t θ ε i ˆφ i ε 9 η i γλ t L; θ f t χ t L; ξ ε it ˆφ i ε t η i γχ t L; ξ λ t L; θ f t τ t θ ε i ˆφ i ε τ t θ ε i ˆφ i ε χ t L; ξ ε it ˆφ i ε t η i γχ t L; ξ λ t L; θ f t ε it ˆφ i ε t 3 τ t θ ε i ˆφ i ε ε it ˆφ i ε t 4 ε it ˆφ i ε t χ t L; ξ ε it ˆφ i ε t. 5 he term 7 is asymptotically negligible, since with Lemmas and and ϱ δ <, we find that γ η i λ t L; θ f t χ t L; ξ λ t L; θ f t = O p / / O p ϱ+δ 6 + 4δ 6 + log + O p, 3

25 which is o p under Assumption C.-. In 8, we can directly take the expectation of the main term to get the bias term stemming from the initial condition, τ t θ τ t θ E [ ε ] i = σ / τ t θ τ t θ, which is O / / + / δ log = O / /, with variance V ar [ ] ε i τ t θ τ t θ = O + 4δ log 4 = o since δ > /4, as, j, while τ t θ τ t θ ˆφ i ε = ε ˆφ i τ t θ τ t θ = O p / + δ log = o p because δ > /4, and by Cauchy-Schwarz inequality the cross term is of order if δ > /4. O p / / + / δ log / Op / + δ log / = O p + δ log + 4δ log / = op We show that 9 is o p considering the contribution of η i λ t L; θ f t τ t θ ε i whose absolute value is bounded, using Lemmas and c, and ϱ δ <, by / ε i ηi λ t L; θ f t τ t θ i = O p / ϱ+δ 3 + log + 4δ 6 + / +O p / ϱ+δ 3 + log + 4δ 6 + / = O p / ϱ+δ 3 + / log + ϱ δ log +O p / ϱ+δ 3 δ / log +O p / ϱ 3δ / log + / ϱ 3δ / / + / δ log + o p { ϱ δ / + δ / / + δ + ϱ 3δ / } log 4

26 which, using ϱ δ <, is which is o p by Assumption C. O p / δ log + δ log + o p For, we consider the contribution of η i λ t L; θ f t χ t L; ξ ε it whose absolute value is bounded by ηi λ t L; θ f t χ t L; ξ ε it = O p ϱ+δ 6 + log + 4δ 6 + / = O p ϱ+δ 6 + log + 4ϱ 6 log + / = op by using Assumptions C.-, because, uniformly in i, using ϱ δ <, E λ t L; θ f t χ t L; ξ ε it = = = O E [λ t L; θ f t χ t L; ξ ε it λ r L; θ f r χ r L; ξ ε ir ] r= E [λ t L; θ f t λ r L; θ f r ] E [χ t L; ξ ε it χ r L; ξ ε ir ] r= t t r ϱ δ + t r ϱ δ log t r= = O log + ϱ δ = O log. hen the term is o p because the factor depending on ˆφ i χ t L; ξ ε t could be dealt with similarly using Cauchy-Schwarz inequality and Lemma. he proof that the term is o p could be dealt with exactly as when bounding 9, while the proof that the term 3 is o p could be dealt with in a similar but easier way than. / he leading term of 4, depending on ε i ε it, τ t θ ε i ˆφ i ε ε it ˆφ i ε t, 5

27 has zero mean and variance proportional to τ t θ = O + δ = o so it is negligible and the same can be concluded for the other terms depending on ˆφ i. he behaviour of the main term in is given in Lemma 5 and that of 5 in Lemma 6 and, combining the plims of 8 and, we obtain the definition of δ. hen collecting the results for all terms 7 to 5 we have found that θ L, θ θ=θ d / {τ t θ τ t θ τ t θ χ t θ } +, 4B ξ. Finally we analyze the second derivative of L,t θ evaluated at θ = θ, / θ θ L, θ θ=θ, which equals + { η i γχ t L; ξ λ t L; θ f t τ t θ ε i ˆφ i ε + χ t L; ξ ε it ˆφ } i ε t { η i γχ t L; ξ λ t L; θ f t τ t θ ε i ˆφ i ε { η i γλ t L; θ f t τ t θ ε i ˆφ i ε + ε it ˆφ } i ε t { η i γb t L λ t L; θ f t τ t θ ε i ˆφ i ε + χ t L; ξ ε it ˆφ } i ε t + b t L ε it ˆφ } i ε t, where b t L = χ t L; ξ + χ t L; ξ χ t L; ξ, χ t L; ξ = / θ χ t L; ξ and τ t θ = / θ θ τ t θ. Using the same techniques as in the proof of heorem, as and get larger, only the term on χ t L; ξ ε it χ t L; ξ ε it in the first element of the rhs contributes to the probability limit, see the proof of heorem 5. in Robinson and Velasco 5. In the second part of the expression, all terms are asymptotically negligible by using the same arguments as in the convergence in distribution of the score, obtaining as and, θ θ L, θ θ=θ p σ B ξ. Lemma 7 shows the convergence of the Hessian L, θ evaluated at ˆθ to that evaluated at θ, and the proof is then complete. Proof of Corollary. he result is a direct consequence of heorem. 6

28 Proof of Corollary. Follows from heorem as the proofs of heorems 5. and 5. in Robinson and Velasco 5. Proof of heorem 3. hese are simple consequences of the results from heorems and, taking =, where the rate of convergence is just now so that the asymptotic IC bias is removed for any δ i D. Proof of heorem 4. he key point is to write / LM / B = / t ε it ˆθε is ˆθ ε itˆθbˆθ ε is ˆθ s= and approximate this by z,t, where z,t = / ε it t s= ε is ε itb ε is 6 by Lemma, where B = B ξ, with z,t being a Martingale Difference, so that [ ] Var z,t = Var [z,t ] = E [ ] z,t and fully expanding matrix calculations using ε it = χ t L ε it = t j= χ jε it j, with χ j = χ j,..., χ p+ j, 4 t Var [z,t ] = σ i E ε is ε itb ε is = = = = a,b,c,d= s= t t σi s= r= p+ B a,b B c,d p+ a,b,c,d= p+ a,b,c,d= B a,b B c,d B a,b B c,d E [ ε is ε ir ε itb ε is ε itb ε ir ] σ i σ i σ 8 i t t E [ ] ε is ε ir ε a it ε b is ε c it ε d ir s= r= t E [ εis] E [ ε a it ε c it] E [ ε b is ε is] d + o s= t χ a j χ c j j= t s= k= s χ b kχ d k + o omitting lower order contributions from other pairwise moments and higher order cumulant 7

29 combinations which is 4 = 4t = 4t p+ a,b,c,d= B a,b B c,d σ 8 i t t χ a j χ c j t k χ b kχ d k + o j= k= σ 8 i trace { B B B B } + o σi 8 p + + o since t k= t k χb k χd k = t t k= χb k χd k + o as t, because χb k = O k, so that [ ] 4 p + Var z,t σ 8 i t σ 8 p +, as, j, so that by Lemma 9 hen it remains to show that / LM B d, σ 8 p +. V p p 4 σ 8 i σ 8 p +, σ 4 i σ 4 i [ s= s= r= ε itb ε is ] E [ ε itb ε is ε itb ε ir ] t trace { B B B B } using Lemma, and the theorem follows. Proof of heorem 5. he proof consists of four steps, where we omit most details already in other proofs. Step. ˆθ θ p, which follows by an essentially similar proof as heorem, the ϑ i contribution for i I being negligible. Step. ˆθ θ = O p /4 /, in particular for υ = σ / σ,, ˆθ θ = υζ /4 / + O p / / using the same aylor expansion as in heorem, with stochastic remainder of order O p / /, but additional average drift υζ /4 / obtained by a similar argument as in step 4 below. 8

30 Step 3. Equivalence of analysis of J evaluated under ˆθ and evaluated under θ for all cross-section units with error ˆθ θ = O p /4 /, similar to Lemma where now the contribution of the term 37 which depends directly on ˆθ θ is O p /4 / log 3 = o p, but there is a new drift term, so that the right hand side of ε it ˆθ ε it θ = ˆθ θ χ t L; ˆθ ε it ˆφ i ε t τ t ˆθ ε i ˆφ i ε η i γλ t L; ˆθ f t for ˆθ θ ˆθ θ is still negligible, but for θ = θ + ζ /4 / and for we have that d it, = /4 / ζ χ t L; θ ε it {i I } ε it θ = λ t L; θ λ t L; θ ε it = ε it + d it, plus a remainder for i I of order / depending on a lag polynomial of ε it with coefficients χ t = O t log t as t uniformly in and. Step 4. Evaluation of the drift generated by d it,. We have that now / LM / B can be approximated by z,t where z,t = / t ε it + d it, ε is + d is, ε itb ε is 7 s= and where the term in ε it ε is is the same as z,t leading to the asymptotic normal distribution, while the term in ε it d is, keeps the martingale structure and is negligible, while that in d it, d is,, i I t ζ χ t L; θ ε it ζ χ t L; θ ε is ε itb ε is, s= 9

31 converges to its expectation, = = = = t E [ ζ χ t L; θ ε it ζ χ t L; θ ε is ε itb ] ε is i I s= p+ i I a,b= p+ i I a,b= ζ χ j θ ζ χ j θ χ a j 3 θ χ b j 4 θ B a,b j,...,j 4 t B a,b s= t E [ε it j ε is j ε it j3 ε is j4 ] s= j,...,j 4 ζ χ j θ ζ χ j θ χ a j 3 θ χ b j 4 θ {E [ε it j ε it j3 ] E [ε is j ε is j4 ] + E [ε it j ε is j ] E [ε it j3 ε is j4 ] + E [ε it j ε is j4 ] E [ε is j ε it j3 ] + κ 4 [ε it p+ t t s σi 4 {i I } B a,b ζ χ j θ χ a j θ ζ χ j θ χ b j θ + o i I a,b= j = s= j = p+ t t σi 4 {i I } B a,b ζ χ j θ χ a j θ t k ζ χ k θ χ b k θ + o i I j = a,b= = σ 4 ζ B B B ζ + o = σ 4 ζ B ζ + o taking only into account only the first pair of expectations since the other terms contribute a smaller order, while the term in ε is d it,, k= 3/4 3/ t ζ χ t L; θ ε it ε is ε itb ε is s= converges to zero, because its expectation is 3/4 3/ K /4 3/ t E [ ] ζ χ t L; θ ε it ε is ε itb ε is s= s= t t s + = O /4 / = o, because E [ε is ε is ] =. Finally, using similar arguments, we still obtain V p p + σ 8 as under H, and the theorem follows. 3

32 8. Lemmas Lemma. Under Assumptions A, as, j, ηi = O p ϱ+δ 6 + log + 4δ 6 + ˆφ i = O p. Proof of Lemma. We only prove the first statement, since the second one is an easy consequence of the first one, 9 and γ p E[γ i ] > and E[γi ] <. Write ηi = t = ȳ t ȳ t λ t L; θ ε it γ i ε γ tλ t L; θ ε it γ i ε γ t. ȳ t he denominator converges to a positive constant term because ȳ t = γ f t + λ t L; θ and by Assumptions A.3 and 4, satisfies as, j, ȳ t p Eγ i σ f t, ε t + γ σ f t = lim f t λ t L; θ ε t E [ f t ], since ϱ < /3 and the second term is negligible due to cross section averaging, because it has expectation = σ [ E j= [ t E λ j λ t θ L; θ ] ] ε it λ t L; θ ε jt = O = o and variance 4 j= t = i = j = [ ] [ ] E λ t L; θ ε it λ t L; θ ε i t E λ t L; θ ε jt λ t L; θ ε j t [ ] [ ] +E λ t L; θ ε it λ t L; θ ε j t E λ t L; θ ε jt λ t L; θ ε i t { } = O 4 t t δ + = O 4δ + log = o, j= t = 3

33 and the third is o p because of Cauchy-Schwarz inequality. In the numerator, it suffices to focus on the dominating term ε it of the error term ε it γ i γ ε t, since ε t = O p / and γ p Eγ i by Assumption A.4. hen, = γ + + γ t = t = ȳ t ȳ t f t f t t = t = λ t λ t λ t L; θ f t λ t L; θ L; θ L; θ ε t λ t ε t ε it λ t ε it λ t L; θ ε t λ t L; θ L; θ L; θ ε it 8 ε it λ t L; θ ε it λ t ε it λ t L; θ ε it. L; θ ε it Up to the factor γ, the expectation of the first term in 8, which is positive, is, using the independence of f t and ε it and Assumption A.3, t = E f t f t E λ t L; θ ε it λ t L; θ ε it. he expectations above for all t t are, cf. Lemma 8, E f t f t = O t t ϱ + + t t ϱ + E λ t L; θ ε it λ t L; θ ε it = O t t δ + + t t δ + where a + = max { a, }and bounded for t = t because max{ϱ, δ } < /3, so that f t λ t L; θ ε it are asymptotically stationary. hen, this term is O p t t = t t ϱ+δ t t ϱ+δ 4 + = O p ϱ+δ 6 + log. and he expectation of the second term in 8, which is also positive, is = = t = [ E λ t t = j= k= L; θ [ E ε t λ t L; θ λ t t t L; θ t = j= k= a= b= c= d= ε jt λ t ε t λ t L; θ L; θ ε it λ t ε kt λ t L; θ t t τa τb τc τδ E [ε jt a ε kt bε it c ε it d], L; θ ] ε it ε it λ t L; θ ] ε it 3

34 where τa function { } as = τ a θ = λ a θ and the expectation can be written using the indicator = E [ε jt a ε kt b] E [ε it c ε it d] {t a = t b} {t c = t d} {j = k} +E [ε jt a ε it d] E [ε kt bε it c ] {t a = t d} {t b = t c} {j = i = k} +E [ε jt a ε it c ] E [ε kt bε it d] {t a = t c} {t b = t d} {j = i = k} +κ 4 [ε it ] ϱ {t a = t b = t c = t d} {j = k = i}. his leads to four different types of contributions, the first type being σ 4 = O t t t t τa τa+ t t τ c τc+ t t t = a= c= t t = t t 4δ + + t t δ 4 + proceeding as in Lemma 8. he second type is σ 4 t = a= c= = O log + 4δ, t t t t τa τa+ t t τ c τc+ t t = O log + 4δ and the third one is, using that τ a = π a δ a δ 4 and δ < 3/, κ 4 t = a= σ 4 t = a= b= t t τ a τ b = O. he final fourth type involving fourth order cumulants is t t τ a τa+ t t = O t = t t δ 4 + = O, he third term in 8 can be bounded using Cauchy-Schwarz inequality and the Lemma follows compiling all the contributions. Lemma. Under Assumptions A and B, as, a λ t L; θ f t = O p + ϱ δ b c sup θ Θ λ t L; θ f t χ t L; ξ λ t L; θ f t = O p + ϱ δ log τ t θ λ t L; θ f t = O p + { ϱ δ + δ + δ + ϱ δ δ } / log. 33

35 Proof of Lemma. o prove a note that by the triangle inequality, sup λ t L; θ f t { sup λt L; θ f t E [ λ t L; θ f t ]} 9 θ Θ θ Θ + sup E [ λ t L; θ f t ]. θ Θ Under Assumption, we have λ t L; θ f t = ψ L; ξ δ ϱ t z t = t λ j δ ϱ; ξz t j = c j v t j, where c j = c j δ ϱ, ξ = j k= ϕf k λ j kδ ϱ, ξ cj ϱ δ as j under Assumption A.. sup θ Θ First, notice that uniformly in θ Θ E [ λ t L; θ f t ] = sup θ Θ while the first term on the lhs of 9 is j c j j= l= vl σv + say. hen, with γ v j = E [v v j ], E sup a Θ σ v t k=j+ c j c j c k sup c je Θ sup K θ Θ j l=k j+ + t ϱ δ = O+ ϱ δ, v l v l k j = a + b, j vl γ v j. Uniformly in j, V ar j l= v l = O, so sup a = O p / j ϱ δ = O p / log + ϱ δ 3/. Θ j= l= ext, using summation by parts, we can express b as c + c j c j j k=j+ l=k j+ k=j+ c k+ c k { vl v l k j γ v j k } k j r=j+ l=r j+ { vl v l r j γ v j r } = b + b. 34

36 Uniformly in j, so, V ar j k=j+ l=k j+ v l v l k j = O, E sup Θ b K ϱ δ j {V ϱ δ ar = O ϱ δ + ϱ δ log j k=j+ l=k j+ where K is some arbitrarily large positive constant. Similarly, E sup Θ b K j ϱ δ k=j+ k ϱ δ {V ar = O ϱ δ + ϱ δ log + k j r=j+ l=r j+ v l v l k j } / v l v l r j } / since V ar k j r=j+ l=r j+ v l v l r j Kk j j. he proof of b of the Lemma is similar but simpler than that of a and is omitted. o prove c of the Lemma, note that λ t L; θ f t τ t θ has zero mean and variance τ t θ τ r θ E [λ t L; θ f t λ r L; θ f r ]. 3 r= When ϱ δ, E [λ t L; θ f t λ r L; θ f r ] K t r ϱ δ + and using that τ t θ Kt δ log t, 3 is O = O t r= tr δ log t log r t r ϱ δ + t δ log t { t δ t ϱ δ + log t + t δ + log t t ϱ δ + } = O + O δ { δ ϱ δ + log + δ + ϱ δ + } log = O + O { δ ϱ δ + log + δ + ϱ δ δ + δ } log = O + O { ϱ δ + δ log + δ + δ + ϱ δ + + ϱ δ δ } log = O + O { ϱ δ + δ + δ + ϱ δ δ } log. When ϱ δ <, E [λ t L; θ f t λ r L; θ f r ] K t r ϱ δ +, see Lemma 8, so 3 35

37 is and the result follows. O = O t r= tr δ log t log r t r ϱ δ + t δ log t = O + δ log 3, Lemma 3. Under the assumptions of heorem, as, j, γ sup η i λ t L; θ f t λ t L; θ ε it ˆφ i ε t = o p. θ Θ Θ Θ 3 Proof of Lemma 3. For θ Θ Θ Θ 3, since γ p E [γ i ] = O p as, we only need to consider = where the first term is equal to η i λ t L; θ f t λ t L; θ ε it ˆφ i ε t η i λ t L; θ f t λ t L; θ ε it η i λ t L; θ f t λ t L; θ ˆφ i ε t, = = η i λ t L; θ f t λ t L; θ ε it t ȳt t ȳt ȳ rλ r L; θ ε ir γ i γ εr r= γ f r + λ r L; θ ε r r= λ t L; θ f t λ t L; θ ε it λ r L; θ ε ir γ i γ εr λ t L; θ f t λ t L; θ ε it. ext γ = O p as and t ȳt = O p as, cf. proof of Lemma, while = γ + γ γ r= r= γ f r + λ r f rλ r λ r r= γ i r= γ i r= L; θ L; θ γ f rλ r λ r L; θ ε r λ r L; θ ε ir γ i γ εr ε ir λ t L; θ f tλ t L; θ ε it ε rλ r L; θ ε ir λ t L; θ f tλ t L; θ ε it L; θ L; θ ε rλ t L; θ f tλ t L; θ ε it ε rλ r L; θ ε rλ t L; θ f tλ t L; θ ε it. 36 λ t L; θ f tλ t L; θ ε it 3

38 he first term on the rhs of 3 can be written as γ times t t k= λ j δ ϱ, ξ λ k θ z t j ε it k r= f r λ r L; θ ε ir which using Lemma 8 and a + = max{ a, } has expectation [ E [ f r λ t L; θ f t ] E r= = O r= = o λ r t r ϱ δ + + t r ϱ δ L; θ t r δ δ + + t r δ δ + + t r δ + ε ir λ t L; θ ε it ] + + t r ϱ + uniformly in θ Θ Θ Θ 3, since all exponents in t r + are negative under Assumptions A and B., so that we can write its centered version as = a + b, say, where = + t k= t λ j δ ϱ, ξ λ k θ A i,t j,t k t λ j δ ϱ, ξ λ j θ A i,t j,t j t λ j δ ϱ, ξ λ k θ A i,t j,t k k j A i,t j,t k = z t j ε it k r= ϱ r z r λ r L; θ ε ir [ E z t j ε it k ϱ r z r λ r r= L; θ ε ir ]. hen where with E sup a δ V ar [ j [ V ar sup λj δ ϱ, ξ λ j θ E δ j A i,l,l, ] [ j A i,l,l = j ] V ar A i,l,l l= ] j j A i,l,l = V ar [A i,l,l ] + Cov [A i,l,l, A i,l,l ]. l= l= l= l l l= l= 37

39 ow V ar [A i,l,l ] is = = r= r = r= r = r= r = [ ] E zl ϱ r z r ϱ r z r ε il λ r L; θ ε ir λ r L; θ ε ir [ ] [ ] E z l ε il ϱ r z rλ r L; θ ε ir E z l ε il ϱ r z r λ r L; θ ε ir E [ zl ϱ z r ϱ ] ] z r E [ε il λ r L; θ ε ir λ r L; θ ε ir [ ] [ ] [ ] [ ] E ε il λ r L; θ ε ir E z l ϱ r z r E ε il λ r L; θ ε ir E z l ϱ r z r [ ] [ E z l E ϱ z r ϱ ] [ z r + E zl ϱ ] [ z r E zl ϱ z r ] E [ ε ] ] [ ] il E [λ r L; θ ε ir λ r L; θ ε ir + E ε il λ r L; θ ε ir E [ ] E ε il λ r L; θ ε ir E [ z l ϱ ] [ z r E ε il λ r L; θ ε ir [ ε il λ r ] E [ z l ϱ z r L; θ ] ε ir ] and j l= V ar [A i,l,l] is, using Lemma 8 omitting the logarithmic terms, O j r r ϱ + + r r ϱ + + r l ϱ r l ϱ r r δ + + r r δ + + r l δ r l δ l= r= r = while using a similar argument = O log + ϱ +δ, Cov [A i,l,l, A i,l,l ] [ ] = E z l z l ϱ r z r ϱ r z r ε il ε il λ r L; θ ε ir λ r L; θ ε ir [ ] [ ] r= r = E z l ε il ϱ r z r λ r L; θ ε ir E z l ε il ϱ r z r λ r L; θ ε ir { = E [z l z l ϱ z r ϱ z r ] E [ ] } ε il ε il δ r+ ε ir δ r+ ε ir [ ] [ ] E ε il λ r= r = r L; θ ε ir E [z l r ϱ z r ] E ε il λ r L; θ ε ir E [ ] z l ϱ r z r E [z l z l ] E [ ϱ z r ϱ z r ] + E [ [z l ϱ z r ] E [z l ϱ z r ] + E [z l ϱ ] z r ] E [z l ϱ z r ] E [ε il ε il ] E λ r L; θ ε ir λ r L; θ = ε ir [ ] [ ] +E ε il λ r L; θ ε ir E ε il λ r L; θ ε ir [ ] [ ] r= r = +E ε il λ r L; θ ε ir E ε il λ r L; θ ε ir [ ] [ ] E ε il λ r L; θ ε ir E [z l ϱ z r ] E ε il λ r L; θ ε ir E [z l ϱ z r ] and using Lemma 8 j l= O j j l= l = r= r = l l Cov [A i,l,l, A i,l,l ] is = O log + ϱ +δ. l l r r ϱ + + r r ϱ + + r l ϱ r l ϱ + r l ϱ r l ϱ l l r r δ + r r δ + + r l δ r l δ + r l δ r l δ 38

40 hen, using λj δ ϱ, ξ λ j θ Cj ϱ+δ δ, = O E sup a δ sup λ j δ ϱ, ξ λ j θ E δ j A i,l,l log + ϱ +δ + sup ϱ +δ 4δ δ = o + O 4ϱ +4δ 4δ / = o since δ < δ/ and ϱ < δ/, using Assumption B.. l= / For b a similar result is obtained using summation by parts as in the proof of the bound for b in Lemma. First, we can express b = b + b with b = λ θ b = λ j δ ϱ, ξ λ j δ ϱ, ξ k=j+ j k=j+ l=k j+ λ k+ θ λ k θ so that we find that that E sup δ b is bounded by K δ δ A i,l,l k j k j r=j+ l=r j+ j ϱ δ / log + ϱ +δ / j= K / δ δ + ϱ δ log + ϱ +δ / A i,l,l r j, K { δ δ + δ +ϱ 4δ log + ϱ +δ } / which is o by using Assumptions B.-3 while E sup δ b is bounded by K / j ϱ δ k=j+ k δ δ log + ϱ +δ / K / j δ+ϱ δ log + ϱ +δ / K / + ϱ+δ δ log + ϱ +δ /, which is o under Assumptions B.-3. he bounds for the other terms on the rhs of 3 follow in a similar form, noting that the presence of cross section averages introduce a further / factor in the probability bounds. 39

41 Lemma 4. Under the assumptions of heorem, as, j, sup λ t L; θ ε it ˆφ i ε t τ t θε i ˆφ i ε = o p. θ Θ Θ Θ 3 Proof of Lemma 4. Opening the double product λ t L; θ ε it ˆφ i ε t ε i ˆφ i ε into four different terms, we study them in turn. First note that the expectation of is σ λ t L; θ ε it τ t θε i 3 τ t θλ t θ = O log + δ δ = o uniformly in δ by Assumption B.3, so we can show that 3 is negligible by showing that t sup λ j θ τ t θ { ε it j ε i σ t = j } = o p. θ Θ Θ Θ 3 he term inside the absolute value is λ t θ τ t θ + { ε i σ } t λ j θ τ t θ ε it j ε i where the first term is O p / + δ δ = o p, uniformly in δ, while the second can be written using summation by parts as hen, E sup δ = τ δ k=j+ λ j θ τ k δ λ j θ = b + b. λ j θ ε ik j ε i k=j+ k=j+ ε ik j ε i b K δ j δ δ / j / {τ k+ δ τ k δ} k r=j+ ε ir j ε i K δ + δ δ / / K / δ / + δ δ / = o, 4

42 K / j /. Simi- [ by Assumption B.3, because Var ] k=j+ ε ik jε i larly, E sup δ b K j δ δ k=j+ K j δ δ δ+/ / k δ / k j / K / + δ δ δ+/ K / δ / + δ δ / = o. he second term is λ t L; θ ˆφ i ε t τ t θε i = λ t L; θ ε t τ t θ ˆφ i ε i = o p because we can show that sup θ Θ Θ Θ 3 λ t L; θ ε t τ t θ = o p using the same method as for bounding 3, while ˆφ i ε i = γ i γ ε i + η i ε i = O p / + O p ϱ+δ δ 6 + / = o p by Lemma and Cauchy-Schwarz inequality. he third term, λ t L; θ ε it τ t θ ˆφ i ε = ε λ γi t L; θ ε it τ t θ γ + η i is negligible because, on the one hand ε sup γ θ Θ Θ Θ 3 λ t L; θ ε it τ t θγ i = o p because ε = O p /, γ = O p and the average can be bounded as 3 since γ i is independent of ε it, which is zero mean, and on the other hand under Assumption B, ε λ t L; θ ε it τ t θη i ε 4 / λ t L; θ ε it τ t θ η i / = o p

43 because we can show that sup θ Θ Θ Θ 3 λ t L; θ ε it τ t θ = O p + δ δ using again the same methods, ε = O p / and η i = O p ϱ+δ δ 6 + by Lemma. Finally, the last term, λ t L; θ ˆφ i ε t τ t θ ε = ε λ t L; θ ε t τ t θ = O p / o p O p = o p, ˆφ i is also negligible, proceeding as before. Lemma 5. Under the conditions of heorem, / τ t θ ε i φ i ε χ t L; ξ ε it φ i ε t = σ τ t θ χ t ξ +o p. Proof of Lemma 5. he main term on the left hand side converges to its expectation, / E [τ t θ ε i χ t L; ξ ε it ] = σ τ t θ χ t ξ, since its variance is τ t θ τ r θ Cov [ε i χ t L; ξ ε it, ε i χ r L; ξ ε ir ] r= [ = t ] τ t θ σ 4 j + t + {κ 4 } j= [ + t t ] τ t θ τ r θ σ 4 j t r + j + t r + κ 4 t {t = r} r= = O + t δ + O rt δ t r + log t + tr = O + δ + O r= t δ t δ log t + t log t = O log 4 + δ log, 4

44 which is o as, while for the other three terms, we can check in turn that τ t θ ε i ˆφi χ t L; ξ ε t = O p ε i ˆφi τ t θ χ t L; ξ ε t = O p / / ε i ˆφi τ t θ χ t L; ξ ε t } = O p / / { / + / δ log / which is O p / + δ log / = o p because { } / τ t θ χ t L; ξ ε t = O p / τ t θ log t } = O p { / + / δ log /, while τ t θ ˆφ i ε χ t L; ξ ε it ε ˆφ i / τ t θ χ t L; ξ ε it = O p / { + / δ log / } = o p, using ˆφ i = O p, ε = O p / and the same argument as for =, and finally τ t θ ε ˆφ i χ t L; ξ ε t = ε and the proof is completed. ˆφ i / τ t θ χ t L; ξ ε t } / { = O p / τ t θ log t } = O p { / / + δ log / = o p, Lemma 6. Under the conditions of heorem, { ε it ˆφ i ε t [χ t L; ξ ε it ˆφ ]} i χ t L; ξ ε t d, 4B ξ. Proof of Lemma 6. he left hand side can be written as {ε it χ t L; ξ ε it ε it ˆφi χ t L; ξ ε t ˆφ i ε t χ t L; ξ ε it + ˆφ } i ε t χ t L; ξ ε t 33 43

45 where Proposition in Robinson and Velasco 5 shows the asymptotic, 4B ξ distribution of the first term as, j, and we now show that the remainder terms are negligible. hen the second term on 33 can be written as j= { } γi ε it γ + η i χ t L; ξ ε jt, where / j= ε itγ i χ t L; ξ ε jt has zero expectation and variance proportional to = = j= j= j= i = j = t = i = j = t = E [ε it γ i χ t L; ξ ε jt ε i t γ i χ t L; ξ ε j t ] E [γ i γ i ] E [ε it χ t L; ξ ε jt ε i t χ t L; ξ ε j t ] E [ ] [ ] [ γi E ε it E {χt L; ξ ε jt } ] = O = o so this term is o p as. hen the other term depending on η i is also negligible because, using Cauchy-Schwarz inequality, j= ε it η i χ t L; ξ ε jt η i j= ε it χ t L; ξ ε jt = O p / ϱ+δ 6 + / / = O p ϱ+δ 6 + / = o p / because E j= ε it χ t L; ξ ε jt = = E [ε it ε it χ t L; ξ ε jt χ t L; ξ ε j t ] j= j = t = E [ [ εit] E {χt L; ξ ε jt } ] = O. j= he third term in 33 is also o p since it can be written as χ t L; ξ ε it ˆφi ε t = { } γi γ + η i χ t L; ξ ε it ε t 44

46 where / γ iχ t L; ξ ε it ε t has zero expectation and variance = j= j= i = j = t = E [γ i γ i ] E [χ t L; ξ ε it ε jt χ t L; ξ ε i t ε j t ] E [ ] [ ] [ γi E ε jt E {χt L; ξ ε it } ] = O while η i χ t L; ξ ε it ε t η i χ t L; ξ ε it ε t = O p / / ϱ+δ 6 + / / = O p ϱ+δ 6 + / = o p / because E χ t L; ξ ε it ε t = = t = j= j = E [χ t L; ξ ε it ε jt χ t L; ξ ε it ε j t ] E [ [ εjt] E {χt L; ξ ε it } ] = O. j= Finally, the fourth term in 33 is also negligible, since ˆφ i ε t χ t L; ξ ε t = ˆφ i a= b= ε at χ t L; ξ ε bt = O p / / = O p / = o p, since ˆφ i = O p and a= b= ε atχ t L; ξ ε bt is O p / because it has zero expectation and variance = a= b= a = b = t = a= b= E [ε at ε a t χ t L; ξ ε bt χ t L; ξ ε b t ] E [ [ εat] E {χt L; ξ ε bt } ] = O. Lemma 7. Under the assumptions of heorem and for θ p θ, L, θ p L, θ. 45

47 Proof of Lemma 7. his follows as heorem of Hualde and Robinson, using the same techniques as in the proof of heorem to bound uniformly the initial condition and projection terms in a neighborhood of θ. Lemma 8. Under Assumptions A and B., for θ Θ, as, E [ f r λ t L; θ f t ] = O t r ϱ δ + log t r + {ϱ=}+{ϱ=δ} + t r ϱ δ + + t r ϱ + [ ] E λ t L; θ ε ir λ t L; θ ε it = O t r δ δ + log t r + {δ =}+{δ =δ} + t r δ δ + + t r δ +, where a + = max{ a, }, { } is the indicator function and E [ ] ϱ z r z t = O t r ϱ + [ ] E λ t L; θ ε ir ε it = O t r δ +. Proof of Lemma 8. We only prove the statement for E [ f r λ t L; θ f t ], since the rest follow similarly. Under Assumption A., if t > r E [ f r λ t L; θ f t ] = E [ ] r ϱ r z r λ t L; δ ϱ, ξ z t = σ v d j ϱ c j+t r δ ϱ, where d j a = j k= ϕf k π j ka cj a and c j a = c j a, ξ = j k= ϕf k λ j ka, ξ cj a as j, d j = ϕ f j and d j a = c j a = if a >, ξ Ξ, so that the absolute value of the last expression is bounded by, ϱ, K r t r d j ϱ j + t r ϱ δ K t r ϱ δ d j ϱ + K r j=t r+ j ϱ δ 3 K t r ϱ δ t r ϱ log t r + {ϱ=} + K t r ϱ δ = O t r ϱ δ log t r + {ϱ=} since ϱ < δ, ϱ < 3/ and ϱ δ < by Assumption B., and d j ϱ cj ϱ, ϱ >, while d j is summable. If ϱ <, then using summation by parts E [ f r λ t L; θ f t ] is equal to r {c j+t r+ δ ϱ c j+t r δ ϱ} σv t r = O t r ϱ δ j ϱ + r j=t r = O t r ϱ δ + t r ϱ δ, j d k ϱ + c t δ ϱ k= j ϱ 3 δ + t ϱ δ r d k ϱ k= 46

48 using that c j+t r+ δ ϱ c j+t r δ ϱ = c j+t r+ δ ϱ + and r k= d k ϱ K. If r > t E [ f r λ t L; θ f t ] = σ v t d j+r t ϱ c j δ ϱ, so that the absolute of the last expression is bounded by, ϱ δ, K t r t j + r t ϱ c j δ ϱ K r t ϱ c j δ ϱ + K t j=r t+ j ϱ δ 3 K r t ϱ r t ϱ δ log t r + {ϱ=δ} + K r t ϱ δ = O r t ϱ δ log t r + {ϱ=δ}. since ϱ < δ and ϱ < 3/ and c j δ ϱ cj ϱ δ, ϱ > δ. If ϱ < δ, then using summation by parts E [ f r λ t L; θ f t ] is equal to t {c j+r t+ ϱ c j+r t ϱ} σv r t = O r t ϱ 3 j ϱ δ + t j=r t = O r t ϱ δ + r t ϱ. j d k δ ϱ + c r ϱ k= j ϱ 3 δ + r ϱ t d k δ ϱ k= Similarly, if r = t E [ f t λ t L; θ f t ] = σ v t c j ϱ d j δ ϱ = O, as the absolute value of the last expression is bounded by r jϱ δ K, since ϱ δ < by Assumption B.. Lemma 9. Under the Assumptions of heorem 4, z,t d, σ 8 p +. where z,t and σ are defined in 6 and 8 respectively. Proof of Lemma 9. Since z,t is a martingale difference sequence given the independence of ε it, we have [ ] Var z,t = Var [z,t ] = E [ ] z,t 47

49 where, fully expanding matrix calculations using ε it = χ t L ε it = t j= χ jε it j, with χ j = χ j,..., χ p+ j, Var [z,t ] = = = = = σi E a,b,c,d= t ε is ε itb s= t t σi s= r= p+ B a,b B c,d p+ a,b,c,d= p+ a,b,c,d= B a,b B c,d B a,b B c,d ε is E [ ε is ε ir ε itb ε is ε itb ε ir ] σ i σ i σ 8 i t t E [ ] ε is ε ir ε a it ε b is ε c it ε d ir s= r= t E [ εis] E [ ε a it ε c it] E [ ε b is ε is] d + o s= t χ a j χ c j j= t s= k= s χ b kχ d k + o, omitting lower order contributions from other pairwise moments and higher order cumulant combinations which is 4 = 4t = 4t p+ a,b,c,d= B a,b B c,d σ 8 i t t χ a j χ c j t k χ b kχ d k + o j= k= σ 8 i trace { B B B B } + o σi 8 p + + o since t k= t k χb k χd k = t t k= χb k χd k + o as t, because χb k = O k. herefore, [ ] 4 p + Var z,t σ 8 i t σ 8 p +, as, j, and to apply a standard CL, e.g. Brown 97 it remains to show that E [ [ ] ] z,t I,t p Var z,t = E [ z,t], 34 where I,t = σ ε it, ε it,... ; i =,..., and that the Lindeberg condition holds. For the first condition, note that E [ ] z,t 4 I,t = σ i t s= ε is ε itb ε is 48

50 and therefore, proceeding as in the proof of heorem 4, the expectation of the lhs of 34 is 4 t σ i E ε is ε itb ε is 4 t t = σ i E [ ] ε is ε itb ε is ε ir ε itb ε ir while its variance is = s= σi 4 t = t = Cov t s= t t t t σi 4 t = t = s = s = s 3 = s 4 = minus the contribution of E = 4 σ 8 i s= r= = σ 8 p + + o [ ] = Var z,t + o ε is ε it B ε is, [ t s= ε is ε itb ε is ] E t t trace { B B B B } + o ε is ε it B ε is 35 s= E [ ε is ε it B ε is ε is ε it B ε is ε is3 ε it B ε is3 ε is4 ε it B ε is4 ] [ t ] s = ε is ε it B ε is. he expectation can be expressed as a linear combination of products of second order moments and higher order cumulants of ε it noting that the elements of ε it are linear combinations of ε is j, j =,,..., t, of which the ones providing the contributions with largest order of magnitude are those expressed as the product of six pairwise expectations among { ε it, ε it, ε it, ε it, ε is, ε is,..., ε is4, ε is4 }. All of them would imply at least 4 expectations with bounds of the type s j s k + log and/or t h s j + log, j, k =,..., 4, j k; h =,, because ε it and ε it appear twice each, and can be combined in two pairwise expectations of the form E [ ] ε it h, considering p = wlog, and because the product of expectations term, involving only such bounds, is removed in the covariance calculation. All these combinations of 4 bounds imply that the contribution of at least time summations out of 6 in {t, t, s,..., s 4 } can be bounded by O log 4, while the contribution from the other 4 summations is O 4, so that 35 can be bounded by K 4 σi 4 4 log 4 = O log 4 = o as, j, and 34 holds. o check Lindeberg condition we show the sufficient condition E [ z,t] 4, 36 49

51 as, j. Denoting µ i4 = E [ε 4 it] <, we write E [ ] z,t 4 6 = 4 µ i4 E t 4 j= s j = ε isj ε itb ε isj he expectation involves again second order moments and higher order cumulants of ε it of which the ones providing the largest magnitude contributions are again those expressed as products of six pairwise expectations among { ε it, ε it, ε it, ε it, ε is, ε is,..., ε is4, ε is4 }. All of them would imply at least 4 expectations with bounds of the type s j s k + log and/or t s j + log, j, k =,..., 4, j k because ε it appears 4 times and can be combined in two pairwise expectations E [ ε it] considering p = wlog. hese 4 bounds imply that the contribution of at least time summations out of 5 in {t, s,..., s 4 } can be bounded by O log 4, and the contribution from the other 3 summations is O 3. hen we can bound E [ ] z,t 4 K 3 log 4 = O log 4 = o 4. as, j, so 36 holds and the lemma follows. Lemma. Under the Assumptions of heorem 4, z,t ẑ,t = o p where z,t is defined in 6 and ẑ,t = / t ε it ˆθ ε is ˆθ ε itˆθbˆθ ε is ˆθ. s= Proof of Lemma. ote that ε it ˆθ = λ t L; ˆθ ε it ˆφ i ε t τ t ˆθ ε i ˆφ i ε η i γλ t L; ˆθ so that ε it ˆθ ε it = for ˆθ θ ˆθ θ and ˆθ θ χ t L; ˆθ ε it ˆφ i ε t τ t ˆθ ε i ˆφ i ε η i γλ t L; ˆθ f t ε it ˆθ ε it = χ t L; ˆθ = χ t L; ˆθ ε it ˆθ ε it ε it ˆθ χ t L; θ ε it + χ t L; ˆθ f t χ t L; θ ε it 5

52 with Bˆθ = B + O p ˆθ θ. We analyze one of the terms in which the difference z,t ẑ,t can be decomposed, which is one of the critical ones since its analysis can not exploit the martingale difference structure that can be used to bound the other contributions. Following as in the proof of heorem, we can write that = / / / / t ε it ε it ˆθ ε is ε itb ε is ˆθ θ ε i ˆφ i ε η i s= χ t L; ˆθ ε it ˆφ t i ε t ε is ε itb ε is 37 s= s= t τ t ˆθ ε is ε itb ε is 38 γλ t L; ˆθ t f t ε is ε itb ε is. 39 s= hen / has expectation bounded by t χ t L; θ ε it ε is ε itb ε is s= K / t t s + log t = O / log s= because E [ ε is B ε is ] =, and variance bounded by K t t t = s= s = s s + t s + t s + log3 = O log 5 by independence of cross-sections, so using ˆθ θ = O p /, the term 37 can be showed to be O p / log 3 = o p, since the contribution of the factor ˆφ i ε t can be treated similarly using Cauchy Schwarz inequality and that E[ ε t ] = O. ext, / has expectation bounded by ε i t τ t θ ε is ε itb ε is s= / t t δ s t s + log t = O / log = o, s= 5

53 and variance bounded by K t t tt δ t = s= s = so 38 is o p. t s { t s + s s } + log 3 t +s s { t s + t s + + t t + s s } + log 3 t = O log 5 Finally, 39 is also o p because / t η i λ t L; θ f t ε is ε itb ε is s= / ηi t λ t L; θ f t ε is ε / itb ε is s= / = O p ηi O p / / = O p / ηi = o p using ϱ δ < and Assumption C with the bound of Lemma, because = t E λ t L; θ f t ε is ε itb ε is t K s= t s= t = s = t t s= t = s = = O. E [λ t L; θ f t λ t L; θ f t ] E [ ] ε is ε itb ε is ε is ε it B ε is t t ϱ δ + + t t ϱ δ s t + t s + s s + + / + t t + s s + Lemma. Under the Assumptions of heorem 4, V, V p p + σ 8 and under cross-section homoskedasticity, V, V p p + σ 8 as, j. 5

54 Proof of Lemma. Under conditional heteroskedasticity it follows from uniform convergence of ˆσ i to σ i and from convergence of ˆσ8 i to σ 8. o show those, write ˆσ i σ i = = ε itˆθ σ i ε itˆθ ε it + = v,i, + v,i,, say, ε it σi where sup v,i, i v,i, / v,i, = O p / because E[v,i, ] = and Var[v,i, ] = O uniformly in i, while sup v,i, i v,i, ˆθ θ = O p / / log because ˆθ θ = O p / / and χ t sup ˆσ i σi i χt L; ˆθ χt ε it + L; ˆθ ε it εit L; ˆθ K log t uniformly in ˆθ, so that = op and sup i ˆσ n i σ n i = o p for any finite n, and therefore ˆσ i 8 σ 8 = ˆσ i 8 σi 8 + o sup ˆσ i 8 σi 8 i + o = o p. Under homoskedasticity we have that ˆσ σ = ˆσ i σ sup ˆσ i σi i = op. and therefore ˆσ 8 σ 8 = o p. hen the rest of the proof follows similarly as that of Lemma. References Alvarez, J. and M. Arellano 3: he ime-series and Cross-section Asymptotics of Dynamic Panel Data Estimators, Econometrica, 74,

55 Arellano, M. and S. Bond 99: Some ests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and An Application to Unemployment Equations, Review of Economic Studies, 58, Bai, J. 9: Panel Data Models with Interactive Fixed Effects, Econometrica, 774, Brown, B. 97: Martingale Central Limit heorems, Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 4, Ergemen, Y. E. 7: System Estimation of Panel Data Models under Long-Range Dependence, forthcoming in Journal of Business and Economic Statistics. Ergemen, Y. E. and C. Velasco 7: Estimation of Fractionally Integrated Panels with Fixed-Effects and Cross-Section Dependence, Journal of Econometrics, 96, Han, C. and P. Phillips : GMM Estimation for Dynamic Panels with Fixed Effects and Strong Instruments at Unity, Econometric heory, 6, 9 5. Hassler, U., M. Demetrescu, and A. I. arcolea : Asymptotic ormal ests for Integration in Panels with Cross-Dependent Units, Advances in Statistical Analysis, 95, Hosoya, Y. 5: Fractional Invariance Principle, Journal of ime Series Analysis, 6, Hualde, J. and P. M. Robinson : Gaussian Pseudo-Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Fractional ime Series Models, he Annals of Statistics, 396, Marinucci, D. and P. Robinson : Weak Convergence of Multivariate Fractional Processes, Stochastic Processes and their Applications, 86, 3. ielsen, M. Ø. 4: Asymptotics for the Conditional-Sum-of-Squares Estimator in Multivariate Fractional ime Series Models, Journal of ime Series Analysis, doi:./jtsa.. Pesaran, H. 6: Estimation and Inference in Large Heterogeneous Panels with a Multifactor Error Structure, Econometrica, 744, : A Simple Panel Unit Root est in the Presence of Cross-section Dependence, Journal of Applied Econometrics,, Phillips, P. and H. R. Moon 999: Linear Regression Limit heory For onstationary Panel Data, Econometrica, 67, 57. Robinson, P. M. and C. Velasco 5: Efficient Estimation of Fractionally Integrated Panel Data Models with Fixed Effects, Journal of Econometrics, 85, Su, l. and Q. Chen 3: esting Homogeneity in Panel Data Models with Interactive Fixed Effects, Econometric heory, 9,

56 55 able : Empirical bias and RMSE of ˆδ and δ Uncorrected estimates, ˆδ Bias-corrected estimates, δ = ˆδ ˆδ, :, 5,, 5,, 5,, 5, ϱ =.4 : δ =.3 Bias RMSE δ =.6 Bias RMSE δ =.9 Bias RMSE δ =. Bias RMSE δ =. Bias RMSE δ =.4 Bias RMSE ϱ = : δ =.3 Bias RMSE δ =.6 Bias RMSE δ =.9 Bias RMSE δ =. Bias RMSE δ =. Bias RMSE δ =.4 Bias RMSE

57 able : Empirical coverage of 95% CI based on ˆδ and δ Uncorrected estimates, ˆδ Bias-corrected estimates, δ = ˆδ ˆδ, :, 5,, 5,, 5,, 5, ϱ =.4 : δ = δ = δ = δ = δ = δ = ϱ = : δ = δ = δ = δ = δ = δ =

58 57 able 3: Size of the test based on ˆδ for 5% nominal size in percentages Pure fractional case Serially correlated factor case, : 5, 5 5,, 5, 5, 5 5,, 5, ϱ =.4 : δ = δ = δ = δ = δ = ϱ = : δ = δ = δ = δ = δ =

59 58 able 4: Power of the test with ζ =. /4 / based on ˆδ for 5% nominal size in percentages Pure fractional case Serially correlated factor case, : 5, 5 5,, 5, 5, 5 5,, 5, ϱ =.4 : δ = δ = δ = δ = δ = ϱ = : δ = δ = δ = δ = δ =

60 59 able 5: Power of the test with ζ =.5 /4 / based on ˆδ for 5% nominal size in percentages Pure fractional case Serially correlated factor case, : 5, 5 5,, 5, 5, 5 5,, 5, ϱ =.4 : δ = δ = δ = δ = δ = ϱ = : δ = δ = δ = δ = δ =

61 Research Papers : Isabel Casas, Eva Ferreira and Susan Orbe: ime-varying coefficient estimation in SURE models. Application to portfolio management 7-34: Hossein Asgharian, Charlotte Christiansen, Ai Jun Hou and Weining Wang: Long- and Short-Run Components of Factor Betas: Implications for Equity Pricing 7-35: Juan Carlos Parra-Alvarez, Olaf Posch and Mu-Chun Wang: Identification and estimation of heterogeneous agent models: A likelihood approach 7-36: Andrés González, imo eräsvirta, Dick van Dijk and Yukai Yang: Panel Smooth ransition Regression Models 7-37: Søren Johansen and Morten Ørregaard ielsen: esting the CVAR in the fractional CVAR model 7-38: ektarios Aslanidis and Charlotte Christiansen: Flight to Safety from European Stock Markets 7-39: ommaso Proietti, iels Haldrup and Oskar Knapik: Spikes and memory in ord Pool electricity price spot prices 8-: Emilio Zanetti Chini: Forecaster s utility and forecasts coherence 8-: orben G. Andersen, icola Fusari and Viktor odorov: he Pricing of ail Risk and the Equity Premium: Evidence from International Option Markets 8-3: orben G. Andersen, icola Fusari, Viktor odorov and Rasmus. Varneskov: Unified Inference for onlinear Factor Models from Panels with Fixed and Large ime Span 8-4: orben G. Andersen, icola Fusari, Viktor odorov and Rasmus. Varneskov: Option Panels in Pure-Jump Settings 8-5: orben G. Andersen, Martin hyrsgaard and Viktor odorov: ime-varying Periodicity in Intraday Volatility 8-6: iels Haldrup and Carsten P.. Rosenskjold: A Parametric Factor Model of the erm Structure of Mortality 8-7: orben G. Andersen, icola Fusari and Viktor odorov: he Risk Premia Embedded in Index Options 8-8: orben G. Andersen, icola Fusari and Viktor odorov: Short-erm Market Risks Implied by Weekly Options 8-9: orben G. Andersen and Rasmus. Varneskov: Consistent Inference for Predictive Regressions in Persistent VAR Economies 8-: Isabel Casas, Xiuping Mao and Helena Veiga: Reexamining financial and economic predictability with new estimators of realized variance and variance risk premium 8-: Yunus Emre Ergemen and Carlos Velasco: Persistence Heterogeneity esting in Panels with Interactive Fixed Effects

Fractionally Integrated Panel Data Systems

Fractionally Integrated Panel Data Systems Fractionally Integrated Panel Data Systems Yunus Emre Ergemen Department of Economics, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid September, 1 Abstract We consider large n, T panel data models with fixed effects,

More information

GMM-based inference in the AR(1) panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails

GMM-based inference in the AR(1) panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails GMM-based inference in the AR() panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails Edith Madsen entre for Applied Microeconometrics (AM) Department of Economics, University of openhagen,

More information

Econometrics of Panel Data

Econometrics of Panel Data Econometrics of Panel Data Jakub Mućk Meeting # 6 Jakub Mućk Econometrics of Panel Data Meeting # 6 1 / 36 Outline 1 The First-Difference (FD) estimator 2 Dynamic panel data models 3 The Anderson and Hsiao

More information

Iterative Bias Correction Procedures Revisited: A Small Scale Monte Carlo Study

Iterative Bias Correction Procedures Revisited: A Small Scale Monte Carlo Study Discussion Paper: 2015/02 Iterative Bias Correction Procedures Revisited: A Small Scale Monte Carlo Study Artūras Juodis www.ase.uva.nl/uva-econometrics Amsterdam School of Economics Roetersstraat 11 1018

More information

Inference on Trending Panel Data

Inference on Trending Panel Data Inference on rending Panel Data Peter M Robinson and Carlos Velasco London School of Economics and Universidad Carlos III de Madrid November 3, 15 Abstract Semiparametric panel data modelling and statistical

More information

Econometric Methods for Panel Data

Econometric Methods for Panel Data Based on the books by Baltagi: Econometric Analysis of Panel Data and by Hsiao: Analysis of Panel Data Robert M. Kunst robert.kunst@univie.ac.at University of Vienna and Institute for Advanced Studies

More information

Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence

Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence Peter M. Robinson London School of Economics Based on joint work with Javier Hualde: Javier Hualde and Peter M. Robinson: Gaussian Pseudo-Maximum Likelihood Estimation

More information

1 Procedures robust to weak instruments

1 Procedures robust to weak instruments Comment on Weak instrument robust tests in GMM and the new Keynesian Phillips curve By Anna Mikusheva We are witnessing a growing awareness among applied researchers about the possibility of having weak

More information

Supplemental Material for KERNEL-BASED INFERENCE IN TIME-VARYING COEFFICIENT COINTEGRATING REGRESSION. September 2017

Supplemental Material for KERNEL-BASED INFERENCE IN TIME-VARYING COEFFICIENT COINTEGRATING REGRESSION. September 2017 Supplemental Material for KERNEL-BASED INFERENCE IN TIME-VARYING COEFFICIENT COINTEGRATING REGRESSION By Degui Li, Peter C. B. Phillips, and Jiti Gao September 017 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO.

More information

1 Estimation of Persistent Dynamic Panel Data. Motivation

1 Estimation of Persistent Dynamic Panel Data. Motivation 1 Estimation of Persistent Dynamic Panel Data. Motivation Consider the following Dynamic Panel Data (DPD) model y it = y it 1 ρ + x it β + µ i + v it (1.1) with i = {1, 2,..., N} denoting the individual

More information

GMM ESTIMATION FOR DYNAMIC PANELS WITH FIXED EFFECTS AND STRONG INSTRUMENTS AT UNITY. Chirok Han and Peter C. B. Phillips.

GMM ESTIMATION FOR DYNAMIC PANELS WITH FIXED EFFECTS AND STRONG INSTRUMENTS AT UNITY. Chirok Han and Peter C. B. Phillips. GMM ESTIMATION FOR DYNAMIC PANELS WITH FIXED EFFECTS AND STRONG INSTRUMENTS AT UNITY By Chirok Han and Peter C. B. Phillips January 2007 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1599 COWLES FOUNDATION FOR

More information

A panel unit root test in the presence of cross-section dependence

A panel unit root test in the presence of cross-section dependence A panel unit root test in the presence of cross-section dependence Mehdi Hosseinkouchack Department of Economics, Goethe University Frankfurt, Grueneburgplatz, (House of Finance, 60323, Frankfurt am Main,

More information

Improving GMM efficiency in dynamic models for panel data with mean stationarity

Improving GMM efficiency in dynamic models for panel data with mean stationarity Working Paper Series Department of Economics University of Verona Improving GMM efficiency in dynamic models for panel data with mean stationarity Giorgio Calzolari, Laura Magazzini WP Number: 12 July

More information

Least Squares Estimation of a Panel Data Model with Multifactor Error Structure and Endogenous Covariates

Least Squares Estimation of a Panel Data Model with Multifactor Error Structure and Endogenous Covariates Least Squares Estimation of a Panel Data Model with Multifactor Error Structure and Endogenous Covariates Matthew Harding and Carlos Lamarche January 12, 2011 Abstract We propose a method for estimating

More information

Prof. Dr. Roland Füss Lecture Series in Applied Econometrics Summer Term Introduction to Time Series Analysis

Prof. Dr. Roland Füss Lecture Series in Applied Econometrics Summer Term Introduction to Time Series Analysis Introduction to Time Series Analysis 1 Contents: I. Basics of Time Series Analysis... 4 I.1 Stationarity... 5 I.2 Autocorrelation Function... 9 I.3 Partial Autocorrelation Function (PACF)... 14 I.4 Transformation

More information

Panel Unit Root Tests in the Presence of Cross-Sectional Dependencies: Comparison and Implications for Modelling

Panel Unit Root Tests in the Presence of Cross-Sectional Dependencies: Comparison and Implications for Modelling Panel Unit Root Tests in the Presence of Cross-Sectional Dependencies: Comparison and Implications for Modelling Christian Gengenbach, Franz C. Palm, Jean-Pierre Urbain Department of Quantitative Economics,

More information

G. S. Maddala Kajal Lahiri. WILEY A John Wiley and Sons, Ltd., Publication

G. S. Maddala Kajal Lahiri. WILEY A John Wiley and Sons, Ltd., Publication G. S. Maddala Kajal Lahiri WILEY A John Wiley and Sons, Ltd., Publication TEMT Foreword Preface to the Fourth Edition xvii xix Part I Introduction and the Linear Regression Model 1 CHAPTER 1 What is Econometrics?

More information

A PANIC Attack on Unit Roots and Cointegration. July 31, Preliminary and Incomplete

A PANIC Attack on Unit Roots and Cointegration. July 31, Preliminary and Incomplete A PANIC Attack on Unit Roots and Cointegration Jushan Bai Serena Ng July 3, 200 Preliminary and Incomplete Abstract his paper presents a toolkit for Panel Analysis of Non-stationarity in Idiosyncratic

More information

Gravity Models, PPML Estimation and the Bias of the Robust Standard Errors

Gravity Models, PPML Estimation and the Bias of the Robust Standard Errors Gravity Models, PPML Estimation and the Bias of the Robust Standard Errors Michael Pfaffermayr August 23, 2018 Abstract In gravity models with exporter and importer dummies the robust standard errors of

More information

Robust Unit Root and Cointegration Rank Tests for Panels and Large Systems *

Robust Unit Root and Cointegration Rank Tests for Panels and Large Systems * February, 2005 Robust Unit Root and Cointegration Rank Tests for Panels and Large Systems * Peter Pedroni Williams College Tim Vogelsang Cornell University -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

More information

11. Further Issues in Using OLS with TS Data

11. Further Issues in Using OLS with TS Data 11. Further Issues in Using OLS with TS Data With TS, including lags of the dependent variable often allow us to fit much better the variation in y Exact distribution theory is rarely available in TS applications,

More information

Darmstadt Discussion Papers in Economics

Darmstadt Discussion Papers in Economics Darmstadt Discussion Papers in Economics The Effect of Linear Time Trends on Cointegration Testing in Single Equations Uwe Hassler Nr. 111 Arbeitspapiere des Instituts für Volkswirtschaftslehre Technische

More information

The Generalized Cochrane-Orcutt Transformation Estimation For Spurious and Fractional Spurious Regressions

The Generalized Cochrane-Orcutt Transformation Estimation For Spurious and Fractional Spurious Regressions The Generalized Cochrane-Orcutt Transformation Estimation For Spurious and Fractional Spurious Regressions Shin-Huei Wang and Cheng Hsiao Jan 31, 2010 Abstract This paper proposes a highly consistent estimation,

More information

Variance Ratio Tests for Panels with Cross. Section Dependence

Variance Ratio Tests for Panels with Cross. Section Dependence Variance Ratio Tests for Panels with Cross Section Dependence Seongman Moon Carlos Velasco February 13, 2015 Abstract This paper develops econometric methods based on variance ratio statistics to investigate

More information

Missing dependent variables in panel data models

Missing dependent variables in panel data models Missing dependent variables in panel data models Jason Abrevaya Abstract This paper considers estimation of a fixed-effects model in which the dependent variable may be missing. For cross-sectional units

More information

Dynamic Panels. Chapter Introduction Autoregressive Model

Dynamic Panels. Chapter Introduction Autoregressive Model Chapter 11 Dynamic Panels This chapter covers the econometrics methods to estimate dynamic panel data models, and presents examples in Stata to illustrate the use of these procedures. The topics in this

More information

Bias-Correction in Vector Autoregressive Models: A Simulation Study

Bias-Correction in Vector Autoregressive Models: A Simulation Study Econometrics 2014, 2, 45-71; doi:10.3390/econometrics2010045 OPEN ACCESS econometrics ISSN 2225-1146 www.mdpi.com/journal/econometrics Article Bias-Correction in Vector Autoregressive Models: A Simulation

More information

LECTURE ON HAC COVARIANCE MATRIX ESTIMATION AND THE KVB APPROACH

LECTURE ON HAC COVARIANCE MATRIX ESTIMATION AND THE KVB APPROACH LECURE ON HAC COVARIANCE MARIX ESIMAION AND HE KVB APPROACH CHUNG-MING KUAN Institute of Economics Academia Sinica October 20, 2006 ckuan@econ.sinica.edu.tw www.sinica.edu.tw/ ckuan Outline C.-M. Kuan,

More information

Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data

Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data Jeffrey M. Wooldridge / The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England Contents Preface Acknowledgments xvii xxiii I INTRODUCTION AND BACKGROUND

More information

Econometrics. Week 4. Fall Institute of Economic Studies Faculty of Social Sciences Charles University in Prague

Econometrics. Week 4. Fall Institute of Economic Studies Faculty of Social Sciences Charles University in Prague Econometrics Week 4 Institute of Economic Studies Faculty of Social Sciences Charles University in Prague Fall 2012 1 / 23 Recommended Reading For the today Serial correlation and heteroskedasticity in

More information

Bootstrap prediction intervals for factor models

Bootstrap prediction intervals for factor models Bootstrap prediction intervals for factor models Sílvia Gonçalves and Benoit Perron Département de sciences économiques, CIREQ and CIRAO, Université de Montréal April, 3 Abstract We propose bootstrap prediction

More information

Advanced Econometrics

Advanced Econometrics Based on the textbook by Verbeek: A Guide to Modern Econometrics Robert M. Kunst robert.kunst@univie.ac.at University of Vienna and Institute for Advanced Studies Vienna May 16, 2013 Outline Univariate

More information

Long memory and changing persistence

Long memory and changing persistence Long memory and changing persistence Robinson Kruse and Philipp Sibbertsen August 010 Abstract We study the empirical behaviour of semi-parametric log-periodogram estimation for long memory models when

More information

Review of Classical Least Squares. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley

Review of Classical Least Squares. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Review of Classical Least Squares James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley The Classical Linear Model The object of least squares regression methods is to model and estimate

More information

When Should We Use Linear Fixed Effects Regression Models for Causal Inference with Longitudinal Data?

When Should We Use Linear Fixed Effects Regression Models for Causal Inference with Longitudinal Data? When Should We Use Linear Fixed Effects Regression Models for Causal Inference with Longitudinal Data? Kosuke Imai Department of Politics Center for Statistics and Machine Learning Princeton University

More information

Central Bank of Chile October 29-31, 2013 Bruce Hansen (University of Wisconsin) Structural Breaks October 29-31, / 91. Bruce E.

Central Bank of Chile October 29-31, 2013 Bruce Hansen (University of Wisconsin) Structural Breaks October 29-31, / 91. Bruce E. Forecasting Lecture 3 Structural Breaks Central Bank of Chile October 29-31, 2013 Bruce Hansen (University of Wisconsin) Structural Breaks October 29-31, 2013 1 / 91 Bruce E. Hansen Organization Detection

More information

Linear dynamic panel data models

Linear dynamic panel data models Linear dynamic panel data models Laura Magazzini University of Verona L. Magazzini (UniVR) Dynamic PD 1 / 67 Linear dynamic panel data models Dynamic panel data models Notation & Assumptions One of the

More information

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1 Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1 John C. Chao April 25, 2017 1 These notes are based in large part on Chapter 16 of Stock and Watson (2011). They are for instructional purposes

More information

Unit Root Testing in Heteroskedastic Panels using the Cauchy Estimator

Unit Root Testing in Heteroskedastic Panels using the Cauchy Estimator Unit Root esting in Heteroskedastic Panels using the Cauchy Estimator Matei Demetrescu Christoph Hanck Preliminary version: June 25, 2010 Abstract he so-called Cauchy estimator uses the sign of the first

More information

Long-Run Covariability

Long-Run Covariability Long-Run Covariability Ulrich K. Müller and Mark W. Watson Princeton University October 2016 Motivation Study the long-run covariability/relationship between economic variables great ratios, long-run Phillips

More information

A nonparametric test for seasonal unit roots

A nonparametric test for seasonal unit roots Robert M. Kunst robert.kunst@univie.ac.at University of Vienna and Institute for Advanced Studies Vienna To be presented in Innsbruck November 7, 2007 Abstract We consider a nonparametric test for the

More information

Current Version: December, 1999 FULLY MODIFIED OLS FOR HETEROGENEOUS COINTEGRATED PANELS * Peter Pedroni. Indiana University

Current Version: December, 1999 FULLY MODIFIED OLS FOR HETEROGENEOUS COINTEGRATED PANELS * Peter Pedroni. Indiana University Current Version: December, 999 FULLY MODIFIED OLS FOR HEEROGENEOUS COINEGRAED PANELS * Peter Pedroni Indiana University mailing address: Economics, Indiana University Bloomington, IN 47405 (82) 855-7925

More information

Short T Panels - Review

Short T Panels - Review Short T Panels - Review We have looked at methods for estimating parameters on time-varying explanatory variables consistently in panels with many cross-section observation units but a small number of

More information

A Course in Applied Econometrics Lecture 7: Cluster Sampling. Jeff Wooldridge IRP Lectures, UW Madison, August 2008

A Course in Applied Econometrics Lecture 7: Cluster Sampling. Jeff Wooldridge IRP Lectures, UW Madison, August 2008 A Course in Applied Econometrics Lecture 7: Cluster Sampling Jeff Wooldridge IRP Lectures, UW Madison, August 2008 1. The Linear Model with Cluster Effects 2. Estimation with a Small Number of roups and

More information

Lecture 2: Univariate Time Series

Lecture 2: Univariate Time Series Lecture 2: Univariate Time Series Analysis: Conditional and Unconditional Densities, Stationarity, ARMA Processes Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20192 Financial Econometrics Spring/Winter 2017 Overview Motivation:

More information

Estimation of Dynamic Panel Data Models with Sample Selection

Estimation of Dynamic Panel Data Models with Sample Selection === Estimation of Dynamic Panel Data Models with Sample Selection Anastasia Semykina* Department of Economics Florida State University Tallahassee, FL 32306-2180 asemykina@fsu.edu Jeffrey M. Wooldridge

More information

Shortfalls of Panel Unit Root Testing. Jack Strauss Saint Louis University. And. Taner Yigit Bilkent University. Abstract

Shortfalls of Panel Unit Root Testing. Jack Strauss Saint Louis University. And. Taner Yigit Bilkent University. Abstract Shortfalls of Panel Unit Root Testing Jack Strauss Saint Louis University And Taner Yigit Bilkent University Abstract This paper shows that (i) magnitude and variation of contemporaneous correlation are

More information

1 Motivation for Instrumental Variable (IV) Regression

1 Motivation for Instrumental Variable (IV) Regression ECON 370: IV & 2SLS 1 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares Econometric Methods, ECON 370 Let s get back to the thiking in terms of cross sectional (or pooled cross sectional) data

More information

Panel Threshold Regression Models with Endogenous Threshold Variables

Panel Threshold Regression Models with Endogenous Threshold Variables Panel Threshold Regression Models with Endogenous Threshold Variables Chien-Ho Wang National Taipei University Eric S. Lin National Tsing Hua University This Version: June 29, 2010 Abstract This paper

More information

EC821: Time Series Econometrics, Spring 2003 Notes Section 9 Panel Unit Root Tests Avariety of procedures for the analysis of unit roots in a panel

EC821: Time Series Econometrics, Spring 2003 Notes Section 9 Panel Unit Root Tests Avariety of procedures for the analysis of unit roots in a panel EC821: Time Series Econometrics, Spring 2003 Notes Section 9 Panel Unit Root Tests Avariety of procedures for the analysis of unit roots in a panel context have been developed. The emphasis in this development

More information

Econometrics of Panel Data

Econometrics of Panel Data Econometrics of Panel Data Jakub Mućk Meeting # 9 Jakub Mućk Econometrics of Panel Data Meeting # 9 1 / 22 Outline 1 Time series analysis Stationarity Unit Root Tests for Nonstationarity 2 Panel Unit Root

More information

DYNAMIC PANEL GMM WITH NEAR UNITY. Peter C. B. Phillips. December 2014 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1962

DYNAMIC PANEL GMM WITH NEAR UNITY. Peter C. B. Phillips. December 2014 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1962 DYNAMIC PANEL GMM WIH NEAR UNIY By Peter C. B. Phillips December 04 COWLES FOUNDAION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 96 COWLES FOUNDAION FOR RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSIY Box 088 New Haven, Connecticut 0650-88

More information

Time Series Analysis. James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY

Time Series Analysis. James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY Time Series Analysis James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY & Contents PREFACE xiii 1 1.1. 1.2. Difference Equations First-Order Difference Equations 1 /?th-order Difference

More information

A Primer on Asymptotics

A Primer on Asymptotics A Primer on Asymptotics Eric Zivot Department of Economics University of Washington September 30, 2003 Revised: October 7, 2009 Introduction The two main concepts in asymptotic theory covered in these

More information

A fixed-t version of Breitung s panel data unit root test and its asymptotic local power

A fixed-t version of Breitung s panel data unit root test and its asymptotic local power A fixed-t version of Breitung s panel data unit root test and its asymptotic local power by Yiannis Karavias and Elias Tzavalis Granger Centre Discussion Paper o. 4/02 A fixed-t Version of Breitung s Panel

More information

This chapter reviews properties of regression estimators and test statistics based on

This chapter reviews properties of regression estimators and test statistics based on Chapter 12 COINTEGRATING AND SPURIOUS REGRESSIONS This chapter reviews properties of regression estimators and test statistics based on the estimators when the regressors and regressant are difference

More information

Estimation of Dynamic Regression Models

Estimation of Dynamic Regression Models University of Pavia 2007 Estimation of Dynamic Regression Models Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia Factorization of the density DGP: D t (x t χ t 1, d t ; Ψ) x t represent all the variables in the economy.

More information

Chapter 6. Panel Data. Joan Llull. Quantitative Statistical Methods II Barcelona GSE

Chapter 6. Panel Data. Joan Llull. Quantitative Statistical Methods II Barcelona GSE Chapter 6. Panel Data Joan Llull Quantitative Statistical Methods II Barcelona GSE Introduction Chapter 6. Panel Data 2 Panel data The term panel data refers to data sets with repeated observations over

More information

Online Appendix. j=1. φ T (ω j ) vec (EI T (ω j ) f θ0 (ω j )). vec (EI T (ω) f θ0 (ω)) = O T β+1/2) = o(1), M 1. M T (s) exp ( isω)

Online Appendix. j=1. φ T (ω j ) vec (EI T (ω j ) f θ0 (ω j )). vec (EI T (ω) f θ0 (ω)) = O T β+1/2) = o(1), M 1. M T (s) exp ( isω) Online Appendix Proof of Lemma A.. he proof uses similar arguments as in Dunsmuir 979), but allowing for weak identification and selecting a subset of frequencies using W ω). It consists of two steps.

More information

Inference about Clustering and Parametric. Assumptions in Covariance Matrix Estimation

Inference about Clustering and Parametric. Assumptions in Covariance Matrix Estimation Inference about Clustering and Parametric Assumptions in Covariance Matrix Estimation Mikko Packalen y Tony Wirjanto z 26 November 2010 Abstract Selecting an estimator for the variance covariance matrix

More information

Economics Division University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK. Title Overlapping Sub-sampling and invariance to initial conditions

Economics Division University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK. Title Overlapping Sub-sampling and invariance to initial conditions Economics Division University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK Discussion Papers in Economics and Econometrics Title Overlapping Sub-sampling and invariance to initial conditions By Maria Kyriacou

More information

A ROBUST TEST FOR PARAMETER HOMOGENEITY IN PANEL DATA MODELS

A ROBUST TEST FOR PARAMETER HOMOGENEITY IN PANEL DATA MODELS A ROBUST TEST FOR PARAMETER HOMOGEEITY I PAEL DATA MODELS Chang-Ching Lin Institute of Economics Academia Sinica February 26, 2007 Abstract This paper proposes a robust test for parameter homogeneity in

More information

Dynamic Discrete Choice Structural Models in Empirical IO

Dynamic Discrete Choice Structural Models in Empirical IO Dynamic Discrete Choice Structural Models in Empirical IO Lecture 4: Euler Equations and Finite Dependence in Dynamic Discrete Choice Models Victor Aguirregabiria (University of Toronto) Carlos III, Madrid

More information

E 4101/5101 Lecture 9: Non-stationarity

E 4101/5101 Lecture 9: Non-stationarity E 4101/5101 Lecture 9: Non-stationarity Ragnar Nymoen 30 March 2011 Introduction I Main references: Hamilton Ch 15,16 and 17. Davidson and MacKinnon Ch 14.3 and 14.4 Also read Ch 2.4 and Ch 2.5 in Davidson

More information

Econometrics. Week 8. Fall Institute of Economic Studies Faculty of Social Sciences Charles University in Prague

Econometrics. Week 8. Fall Institute of Economic Studies Faculty of Social Sciences Charles University in Prague Econometrics Week 8 Institute of Economic Studies Faculty of Social Sciences Charles University in Prague Fall 2012 1 / 25 Recommended Reading For the today Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage

More information

A Course in Applied Econometrics Lecture 4: Linear Panel Data Models, II. Jeff Wooldridge IRP Lectures, UW Madison, August 2008

A Course in Applied Econometrics Lecture 4: Linear Panel Data Models, II. Jeff Wooldridge IRP Lectures, UW Madison, August 2008 A Course in Applied Econometrics Lecture 4: Linear Panel Data Models, II Jeff Wooldridge IRP Lectures, UW Madison, August 2008 5. Estimating Production Functions Using Proxy Variables 6. Pseudo Panels

More information

Predicting bond returns using the output gap in expansions and recessions

Predicting bond returns using the output gap in expansions and recessions Erasmus university Rotterdam Erasmus school of economics Bachelor Thesis Quantitative finance Predicting bond returns using the output gap in expansions and recessions Author: Martijn Eertman Studentnumber:

More information

ECON3327: Financial Econometrics, Spring 2016

ECON3327: Financial Econometrics, Spring 2016 ECON3327: Financial Econometrics, Spring 2016 Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics (5th ed, 2012) Chapter 11: OLS with time series data Stationary and weakly dependent time series The notion of a stationary

More information

Note: The primary reference for these notes is Enders (2004). An alternative and more technical treatment can be found in Hamilton (1994).

Note: The primary reference for these notes is Enders (2004). An alternative and more technical treatment can be found in Hamilton (1994). Chapter 4 Analysis of a Single Time Series Note: The primary reference for these notes is Enders (4). An alternative and more technical treatment can be found in Hamilton (994). Most data used in financial

More information

Specification Test for Instrumental Variables Regression with Many Instruments

Specification Test for Instrumental Variables Regression with Many Instruments Specification Test for Instrumental Variables Regression with Many Instruments Yoonseok Lee and Ryo Okui April 009 Preliminary; comments are welcome Abstract This paper considers specification testing

More information

Economics 583: Econometric Theory I A Primer on Asymptotics

Economics 583: Econometric Theory I A Primer on Asymptotics Economics 583: Econometric Theory I A Primer on Asymptotics Eric Zivot January 14, 2013 The two main concepts in asymptotic theory that we will use are Consistency Asymptotic Normality Intuition consistency:

More information

A Dynamic Multi-Level Factor Model with Long-Range Dependence. Yunus Emre Ergemen and Carlos Vladimir Rodríguez-Caballero

A Dynamic Multi-Level Factor Model with Long-Range Dependence. Yunus Emre Ergemen and Carlos Vladimir Rodríguez-Caballero A Dynamic Multi-Level Factor Model with Long-Range Dependence Yunus Emre Ergemen and Carlos Vladimir Rodríguez-Caballero CREATES Research Paper 216-23 Department of Economics and Business Economics Aarhus

More information

Econometric Forecasting

Econometric Forecasting Robert M. Kunst robert.kunst@univie.ac.at University of Vienna and Institute for Advanced Studies Vienna October 1, 2014 Outline Introduction Model-free extrapolation Univariate time-series models Trend

More information

On the Power of Tests for Regime Switching

On the Power of Tests for Regime Switching On the Power of Tests for Regime Switching joint work with Drew Carter and Ben Hansen Douglas G. Steigerwald UC Santa Barbara May 2015 D. Steigerwald (UCSB) Regime Switching May 2015 1 / 42 Motivating

More information

Introductory Econometrics

Introductory Econometrics Based on the textbook by Wooldridge: : A Modern Approach Robert M. Kunst robert.kunst@univie.ac.at University of Vienna and Institute for Advanced Studies Vienna November 23, 2013 Outline Introduction

More information

AR, MA and ARMA models

AR, MA and ARMA models AR, MA and AR by Hedibert Lopes P Based on Tsay s Analysis of Financial Time Series (3rd edition) P 1 Stationarity 2 3 4 5 6 7 P 8 9 10 11 Outline P Linear Time Series Analysis and Its Applications For

More information

Supplement to Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions

Supplement to Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions Supplement to Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions Vadim Marmer University of British Columbia Artyom Shneyerov CIRANO, CIREQ, and Concordia University August 30, 2010 Abstract

More information

GMM estimation of spatial panels

GMM estimation of spatial panels MRA Munich ersonal ReEc Archive GMM estimation of spatial panels Francesco Moscone and Elisa Tosetti Brunel University 7. April 009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/637/ MRA aper No. 637, posted

More information

GARCH Models. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. December Rossi GARCH Financial Econometrics / 50

GARCH Models. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. December Rossi GARCH Financial Econometrics / 50 GARCH Models Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia December 013 Rossi GARCH Financial Econometrics - 013 1 / 50 Outline 1 Stylized Facts ARCH model: definition 3 GARCH model 4 EGARCH 5 Asymmetric Models 6

More information

Robust Backtesting Tests for Value-at-Risk Models

Robust Backtesting Tests for Value-at-Risk Models Robust Backtesting Tests for Value-at-Risk Models Jose Olmo City University London (joint work with Juan Carlos Escanciano, Indiana University) Far East and South Asia Meeting of the Econometric Society

More information

Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts

Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts Contents 1 Motivating Examples 1 1.1 Instrumental variable estimator....................... 1 1.2 Estimating parameters in monetary policy rules.............. 2 1.3 Estimating

More information

Understanding Regressions with Observations Collected at High Frequency over Long Span

Understanding Regressions with Observations Collected at High Frequency over Long Span Understanding Regressions with Observations Collected at High Frequency over Long Span Yoosoon Chang Department of Economics, Indiana University Joon Y. Park Department of Economics, Indiana University

More information

The Role of "Leads" in the Dynamic Title of Cointegrating Regression Models. Author(s) Hayakawa, Kazuhiko; Kurozumi, Eiji

The Role of Leads in the Dynamic Title of Cointegrating Regression Models. Author(s) Hayakawa, Kazuhiko; Kurozumi, Eiji he Role of "Leads" in the Dynamic itle of Cointegrating Regression Models Author(s) Hayakawa, Kazuhiko; Kurozumi, Eiji Citation Issue 2006-12 Date ype echnical Report ext Version publisher URL http://hdl.handle.net/10086/13599

More information

Volume 03, Issue 6. Comparison of Panel Cointegration Tests

Volume 03, Issue 6. Comparison of Panel Cointegration Tests Volume 03, Issue 6 Comparison of Panel Cointegration Tests Deniz Dilan Karaman Örsal Humboldt University Berlin Abstract The main aim of this paper is to compare the size and size-adjusted power properties

More information

Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters

Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters Thomas MaCurdy a and Xiaohong Chen b and Han Hong c Introduction Many empirical studies of program evaluations are complicated by the presence of both

More information

CALCULATION METHOD FOR NONLINEAR DYNAMIC LEAST-ABSOLUTE DEVIATIONS ESTIMATOR

CALCULATION METHOD FOR NONLINEAR DYNAMIC LEAST-ABSOLUTE DEVIATIONS ESTIMATOR J. Japan Statist. Soc. Vol. 3 No. 200 39 5 CALCULAION MEHOD FOR NONLINEAR DYNAMIC LEAS-ABSOLUE DEVIAIONS ESIMAOR Kohtaro Hitomi * and Masato Kagihara ** In a nonlinear dynamic model, the consistency and

More information

Econometrics of Panel Data

Econometrics of Panel Data Econometrics of Panel Data Jakub Mućk Meeting # 4 Jakub Mućk Econometrics of Panel Data Meeting # 4 1 / 30 Outline 1 Two-way Error Component Model Fixed effects model Random effects model 2 Non-spherical

More information

The PPP Hypothesis Revisited

The PPP Hypothesis Revisited 1288 Discussion Papers Deutsches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung 2013 The PPP Hypothesis Revisited Evidence Using a Multivariate Long-Memory Model Guglielmo Maria Caporale, Luis A.Gil-Alana and Yuliya

More information

Efficiency Tradeoffs in Estimating the Linear Trend Plus Noise Model. Abstract

Efficiency Tradeoffs in Estimating the Linear Trend Plus Noise Model. Abstract Efficiency radeoffs in Estimating the Linear rend Plus Noise Model Barry Falk Department of Economics, Iowa State University Anindya Roy University of Maryland Baltimore County Abstract his paper presents

More information

Christopher Dougherty London School of Economics and Political Science

Christopher Dougherty London School of Economics and Political Science Introduction to Econometrics FIFTH EDITION Christopher Dougherty London School of Economics and Political Science OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS Contents INTRODU CTION 1 Why study econometrics? 1 Aim of this

More information

The Bootstrap: Theory and Applications. Biing-Shen Kuo National Chengchi University

The Bootstrap: Theory and Applications. Biing-Shen Kuo National Chengchi University The Bootstrap: Theory and Applications Biing-Shen Kuo National Chengchi University Motivation: Poor Asymptotic Approximation Most of statistical inference relies on asymptotic theory. Motivation: Poor

More information

Long-Run Effects in Large Heterogenous Panel Data Models with Cross-Sectionally Correlated Errors *

Long-Run Effects in Large Heterogenous Panel Data Models with Cross-Sectionally Correlated Errors * Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper o. 223 http://www.dallasfed.org/assets/documents/institute/wpapers/2015/0223.pdf Long-Run Effects in Large Heterogenous

More information

Obtaining Critical Values for Test of Markov Regime Switching

Obtaining Critical Values for Test of Markov Regime Switching University of California, Santa Barbara From the SelectedWorks of Douglas G. Steigerwald November 1, 01 Obtaining Critical Values for Test of Markov Regime Switching Douglas G Steigerwald, University of

More information

E 4160 Autumn term Lecture 9: Deterministic trends vs integrated series; Spurious regression; Dickey-Fuller distribution and test

E 4160 Autumn term Lecture 9: Deterministic trends vs integrated series; Spurious regression; Dickey-Fuller distribution and test E 4160 Autumn term 2016. Lecture 9: Deterministic trends vs integrated series; Spurious regression; Dickey-Fuller distribution and test Ragnar Nymoen Department of Economics, University of Oslo 24 October

More information

Introduction to Econometrics

Introduction to Econometrics Introduction to Econometrics T H I R D E D I T I O N Global Edition James H. Stock Harvard University Mark W. Watson Princeton University Boston Columbus Indianapolis New York San Francisco Upper Saddle

More information

The Restricted Likelihood Ratio Test at the Boundary in Autoregressive Series

The Restricted Likelihood Ratio Test at the Boundary in Autoregressive Series The Restricted Likelihood Ratio Test at the Boundary in Autoregressive Series Willa W. Chen Rohit S. Deo July 6, 009 Abstract. The restricted likelihood ratio test, RLRT, for the autoregressive coefficient

More information

Asymptotic distributions of the quadratic GMM estimator in linear dynamic panel data models

Asymptotic distributions of the quadratic GMM estimator in linear dynamic panel data models Asymptotic distributions of the quadratic GMM estimator in linear dynamic panel data models By Tue Gørgens Chirok Han Sen Xue ANU Working Papers in Economics and Econometrics # 635 May 2016 JEL: C230 ISBN:

More information

Common Correlated Effects Estimation of Dynamic Panels with Cross-Sectional Dependence

Common Correlated Effects Estimation of Dynamic Panels with Cross-Sectional Dependence Common Correlated Effects Estimation of Dynamic Panels with Cross-Sectional Dependence om De Groote and Gerdie Everaert SHERPPA, Ghent University Preliminary, February 00 Abstract his paper studies estimation

More information

Time Series Analysis. James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY

Time Series Analysis. James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY Time Series Analysis James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY PREFACE xiii 1 Difference Equations 1.1. First-Order Difference Equations 1 1.2. pth-order Difference Equations 7

More information

Testing Random Effects in Two-Way Spatial Panel Data Models

Testing Random Effects in Two-Way Spatial Panel Data Models Testing Random Effects in Two-Way Spatial Panel Data Models Nicolas Debarsy May 27, 2010 Abstract This paper proposes an alternative testing procedure to the Hausman test statistic to help the applied

More information