NOTES D ÉTUDES ET DE RECHERCHE

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "NOTES D ÉTUDES ET DE RECHERCHE"

Transcription

1 NOTES D ÉTUDES ET DE RECHERCHE A TIME-VARYING NATURAL RATE OF INTEREST FOR THE EURO AREA Jean-Stéphane Mésonnier and Jean-Paul Renne September 2004 NER # 115 DIRECTION GÉNÉRALE DES ÉTUDES ET DES RELATIONS INTERNATIONALES

2 DIRECTION GÉNÉRALE DES ÉTUDES ET DES RELATIONS INTERNATIONALES DIRECTION DES ÉTUDES ÉCONOMIQUES ET DE LA RECHERCHE A TIME-VARYING NATURAL RATE OF INTEREST FOR THE EURO AREA Jean-Stéphane Mésonnier and Jean-Paul Renne September 2004 NER # 115 Les Notes d'études et de Recherche reflètent les idées personnelles de leurs auteurs et n'expriment pas nécessairement la position de la Banque de France. Ce document est disponible sur le site internet de la Banque de France « The Working Paper Series reflect the opinions of the authors and do not necessarily express the views of the Banque de France. This document is available on the Banque de France Website France.fr.

3 A Time-Varying Natural Rate of Interest for the Euro Area 1 J.-S. Mésonnier 2 Banque de France Monetary Policy Research Unit J.-P. Renne Banque de France Monetary Policy Research Unit September 15, We are grateful to Gilbert Cette, Laurent Clerc, Patrick Fève, Nicola Giammarioli, Enisse Kharroubi, Hervé Le Bihan, Julien Matheron, Adrien Verdelhan and participants in the Banque de France workshop on Small Monetary Macromodels (Paris, September 2004) and in the MMF Annual Conference 2004 (London, September 2004) for useful comments and suggestions. All errors remain our own. Opinions expressed re ect the authors view only and not necessarily the position of the Banque de France. 2 Banque de France, Monetary Policy Research Unit, SEPMF, Paris cedex 01. Corresponding author: J.S. Mésonnier, jean-stephane.mesonnier@banque-france.fr.

4 Résumé : Dans cet article, nous estimons, pour une zone euro synthétique sur la période 1979T1-2002T4, un taux d intérêt naturel variable dans le temps à partir d un petit modèle macroéconomique backward-looking. La méthodologie est proche de celle développée par Laubach et Williams (2003) pour les Etats-Unis. Le ltre de Kalman permet d estimer simultanément deux variables inobservables: l écart de production et le taux d intérêt naturel. Le modèle espace-état sous-jacent comprend une équation de demande agrégée et une courbe de Phillips. Nos hypothèses d identi cation utilisent une relation étroite entre les variations du taux d intérêt naturel et les uctuations de basse fréquence de la croissance potentielle. L écart de taux d intérêt, c est à dire la di érence entre le taux d intérêt réel et l estimation de son niveau naturel, constitue un outil intéressant pour l évaluation de la politique monétaire sur les deux dernières décennies. Alors que notre taux d intérêt naturel estimé semble assez robuste aux modi cations des spéci cations du modèle, la relative importance de l incertitude entourant les séries estimées entrave son intégration directe dans le processus d élaboration de la politique monétaire. Mots-clés : Taux d intérêt naturel, écart de taux d intérêt, politique monétaire, ltre de Kalman, écart de production. Abstract: In this article we estimate a time-varying natural rate of interest (TVNRI) for a synthetic euro area over the period 1979Q1-2002Q4 using a small backward-looking macroeconomic model, broadly following a methodology developed by Laubach and Williams (2003) for the United States. The Kalman lter simultaneously estimates two unobservable variables: the output gap and the natural rate of interest. The underlying state-space model incorporates an aggregate demand equation and a Phillips curve. Consistent with the theoretical intuition, our identifying assumptions include a close relationship between the TVNRI and the low-frequency uctuations of potential output growth. The resulting interest rate gap, that is, the di erence between the real rate of interest and its estimated natural level, provides us with a valuable tool for assessing the monetary policy stance in EU12 over the last two decades. While our TVNRI estimate seems quite robust to changes in model speci cations, the relatively high uncertainty surrounding the estimate hampers its direct integration into the policy-making process. Keywords: Natural rate of interest, interest rate gap, monetary policy, Kalman lter, output gap. JEL Classi cation: C32, E32, E43, E52. 2

5 Résumé non technique : Le concept de taux d intérêt naturel et son utilisation normative pour la politique monétaire sont généralement associés à l économiste suédois pré-keynésien Knut Wicksell (1898, 1906, 1907) selon lequel, there is a certain rate of interest on loans which is neutral in respect to commodity prices and tends neither to raise nor to lower them (1936, p. 102). D après Wicksell, stabiliser les prix consiste donc à aligner le taux d intérêt (réel) du crédit supposé égal au taux d escompte contrôlé par la banque centrale sur le taux d intérêt naturel qui varie en réponse aux chocs a ectant ses déterminants (réels), principalement la productivité du capital. Le regain d intérêt actuel pour le concept s inscrit dans le cadre néo-wicksellien d analyse de la politique monétaire défendu par Woodford (2003), dans lequel le taux d intérêt naturel prévalant dans la règle de Taylor varie continûment en réponse à divers chocs réels. L écart de taux d intérêt réel, c est à dire la di érence entre le taux d intérêt réel de court terme caractérisant la politique monétaire et son niveau d équilibre ou naturel, semble être un candidat intéressant pour l évaluation de la politique monétaire. Nous reprenons la méthodologie que Laubach et Williams (2003) ont développée pour les Etats-Unis et l appliquons à une zone euro synthétique sur la période 1979T1-2002T4. Trois points principaux distinguent notre approche de la leur. Premièrement, nous supposons que le processus inobservable décrivant les uctuations de basses fréquences communes au taux d intérêt naturel et à la croissance potentielle est stationnaire auto-regressif, fortement persistant mais non intégré d ordre un. Ceci nous permet d éviter la di cile réconciliation d un taux d intérêt d équilibre et d une croissance potentielle non-stationnaires avec la théorie économique. Deuxièmement, nous optons pour une dynamique du taux d intérêt naturel présentant un degré de sophistication intermédiaire entre celui de Laubach et Williams (2003) d une part et celui d Orphanides et Williams (2002) qui ne prennent pas en compte de possibles co-mouvements entre le taux d intérêt naturel et la croissance potentielle d autre part. En n, notre taux d intérêt réel est le taux d intérêt réel ex ante utilisant les anticipations d in ations issues du modèle lui-même et non celles issues d une modélisation externe et univariée de l in ation. L estimation du taux d intérêt naturel et l écart de taux qui en dérive constituent des outils intéressants pour l évaluation de la politique monétaire sur les deux dernières décennies. En particulier, la supériorité de telles estimations sur des ltres univariés classiques est illustrée. Cependant, l intervalle de con ance mesurant l incertitude inhérente au ltrage de Kalman est relativement importante. En outre, les erreurs de mesure en temps réel peuvent également être substantielles. 3

6 Non-technical summary: The concept of a natural real rate of interest and its prescriptive use for monetary policy is generally associated with the Swedish pre-keynesian economist Knut Wicksell (1898, 1906, 1907). According to this early contribution, there is a certain rate of interest on loans which is neutral in respect to commodity prices and tends neither to raise nor to lower them (1936, p. 102). In Wicksell s view, price stability thus depends on keeping the (real) interest rate of credit understood to be equal to the discount rate controlled by the central bank in line with the neutral rate of interest, which varies according to shocks a ecting its (real) determinants, mainly the productivity of capital. The recent revival of the concept owes to the Neo-wicksellian framework for monetary policy analysis advocated by Woodford (2003), where the neutral rate embedded in the Taylor rule varies continuously in response to various real disturbances. The interest rate gap, then de ned as the di erence between the real short term interest rate representative of monetary policy and its equilibrium or natural counterpart, seems to be an interesting candidate for assessing the current monetary policy stance. We apply the methodology rst developed by Laubach and Williams (2003) to a synthetic euro area over the period 1979Q1-2002Q4. However, our model speci cations depart from theirs in three signi cant ways. Firstly, we assume that the unobservable process that drives the low frequency common uctuations of both the NRI and potential output growth remains stationary autoregressive instead of nonstationary, although we expect it to be persistent. This allows us to avoid the di cult reconciliation of a nonstationary output growth and a nonstationary equilibrium real interest rate with both economic theory and intuition. Secondly, we opt for a speci cation of the NRI whose degree of sophistication can be viewed as a compromise between those of Laubach and Williams (2003) and Orphanides and Williams (2002), who do not assume any co-movements between the NRI and potential ouput growth. Lastly, we compute the real interest rate as a model-consistent ex ante real rate of interest, using the in ation expectations provided by the model instead of deriving them from univariate autoregressive models of in ation. The estimated NRI and the derived interest rate gap constitute valuable tools for assessing the monetary policy stance over the last two decades. In particular, the superiority of such estimates in comparison with classical univariate lters is illustrated. However, the con dence interval, integrating the uncertainty associated with Kalman ltering, remains relatively broad. Besides, the real-time misperception of the natural rate of interest can also be substantial. 4

7 1 Introduction In this paper, we estimate a time-varying natural rate of interest (TVNRI) for the euro area within the framework of a small backward-looking macroeconomic model and using the Kalman lter along the lines of Laubach and Williams (2003). The concept of a natural real rate of interest and its prescriptive use for monetary policy is generally associated with the Swedish pre-keynesian economist Knut Wicksell (1898, 1906, 1907). According to this early contribution, there is a certain rate of interest on loans which is neutral in respect to commodity prices and tends neither to raise nor to lower them (1936, p. 102). In Wicksell s view, price stability hence depends on keeping the (real) interest rate of credit understood to be equal to the discount rate controlled by the central bank in line with the neutral rate of interest, which varies according to shocks a ecting its (real) determinants, mainly the productivity of capital. Although one may consider that a natural rate of interest (NRI) appears implicitly as the intercept in popular interest rate rules of the kind rst proposed by Taylor (1993) roughly a decade ago, the recent revival of the concept owes much to the Neo-wicksellian framework for monetary policy analysis advocated by Woodford (2003), where the neutral rate embedded in the Taylor rule varies continuously in response to various real disturbances. The interest rate gap (IRG), then de ned as the di erence between the real short term interest rate representative of monetary policy and its equilibrium or natural counterpart, seems to be an interesting candidate for assessing the current monetary policy stance, notably as an alternative to measures that employ monetary aggregates or exchange rates. Hence, central banks and central bank economists have recently devoted much attention to these theoretical developments and the resulting empirical estimation strategies (see, e.g., ECB, 2004, Christensen, 2002, Williams, 2003, Crespo-Cuaresma et al., 2003, Basdevant et al., 2004). A more careful reading of this expanding literature however reveals two main approaches, depending on whether the focus is on short term or medium to long run implications of a non-zero gap and, simultaneously, on the degree of structure put into the models that yield the estimates. A rst strand of this new natural rate literature broadly follows the lines of Blinder (1998), Woodford (2003) or Neiss and Nelson (2001) and derives the natural rate of interest within the framework of detailed structural New Keynesian models (see, e.g., Giammarioli and Valla, 2003, Smets and Wouters, 2003, for applications to the euro area). From this perspective, the natural rate of interest equals the equilibrium real rate of return in an economy where prices are fully exible, or in other words, it is the real short term rate of interest that equates aggregate demand with potential output at all times. The emphasis is thus put on short term developments. Neiss and Nelson (2001) for instance develop a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model with sticky prices that they calibrate to the UK economy: they then compute what Laubach and Williams (2003) term the higher frequency component of the natural rate 5

8 of interest and track the period-by-period movements in the real rate of interest that are required to keep in ation constant. As Larsen and McKeown (2004) state it, such a DSGE approach is a priori desirable, because it obviously enables a structural interpretation of the interest rate gap and its variations, which pure statistical approaches (such as a band pass or a HP lter) do not allow. However, as far as its prescriptive use for policy purposes is concerned, the advantage of such an approach over more statistical ones is not clear-cut, at least given that the calibration exercise of the derived models usually implies a signi cant amount of arbitrary assumptions. Besides, the natural rate of interest generated by a DSGE model appears in some cases to be substantially more volatile than the actual real rate, which makes policy use quite di cult (see, e.g., results in Smets and Wouters, 2003). Be that as it may, Neiss and Nelson (2001) for the UK as well as Giammarioli and Valla (2003) for the euro area provide promising results suggesting that their interest rate gap estimates have an informational content for in ation that could be used for policy purpose. Another strand of the literature follows Laubach and Williams (2003) and mixes the reference to simple macroeconomic models usually found in the monetary policy literature with the use of semi-structural methods such as the Kalman lter in order to estimate the natural rate of interest, the potential level of output and/or the natural rate of unemployment as unobserved variables (recent examples include Orphanides and Williams, 2002, Crespo-Cuaresma et al., 2003, Basdevant et al., 2004). In this view, the natural rate of interest is the real short term rate of interest consistent with output at its potential and in ation stable in the medium run, i.e. once the e ects of demand shocks on the output gap and supply shocks on in ation have completely vanished. Though it is less precise than the former, this latter de nition seems to be more tractable in practice and hence more widely accepted. In a very stimulating contribution, Orphanides and Williams (2002) warn against the adverse and often undervalued consequences of misperceptions in the true NRI and of its companion concepts of natural rate of unemployment and potential output in terms of the stabilisation properties of monetary policy rules that include such unobserved variables. They compute various statistical estimates of the natural rate including the output of simple state-space models of the kind introduced by Laubach and Williams and compare the properties of policies optimised so as to provide a good stabilisation performance of in ation and output, but which possibly underestimate the magnitude of mismeasurements in the natural rate of interest. They conclude that the costs associated with underestimating natural rate mismeasurement are signi cantly higher than those of overestimating it. It follows that, given the uncertainty, central bankers need to be extremely cautious regarding the policy implications of the interest rate gaps they compute. This lesson converges with the conclusion of Laubach and Williams, who point out the high uncertainty surrounding estimates of natural rates in general. Along with Larsen and McKeown (2004) however, we argue that there is a case for the use of natural rate estimates obtained via semi-structural techniques such as those employed by Laubach and Williams, 6

9 which strike a convenient compromise between the DSGE approach and purely statistical estimates such as the commonly used HP lter. When not used as a basis for real-time prescription nor as a rm anchor for monetary policy (as advocated e.g. by Christensen, 2002), such estimates of the natural rate and of the interest rate gap provide a useful tool for an ex post assessment of the policy stance. Moreover, and, by essence, since they allow for large changes in structural variables like the level of potential output and the NRI, they can deal with and reasonably account for the large shocks and many structural changes that have a ected European economies over the last two to three decades. Low-frequency movements of such variables remain a priori out of reach of a more structural approach like DSGE models, where aggregate relationships are expressed as log-linear approximations around a non stochastic steady state. We apply the methodology rst developed by Laubach and Williams (2003) to a synthetic euro area over the period 1979Q1-2002Q4. However, our model speci cations depart from theirs in three signi cant ways. Firstly, we assume that the unobservable process that drives, as in Laubach and Williams, the low frequency common uctuations of both the NRI and potential output growth remains stationary autoregressive instead of nonstationary, although we expect it to be persistent 1. This allows us to avoid the di cult reconciliation of a nonstationary output growth and a nonstationary equilibrium real interest rate with both economic theory and intuition. Secondly, as we express some doubt regarding the feasability of estimating our already unobservable NRI as the sum of two equally unobservable components, we opt for a speci cation of the NRI whose degree of sophistication can be viewed as a compromise between those of Laubach and Williams and Orphanides and Williams, who do not assume any co-movements between the NRI and potential ouput growth. Lastly, we compute the real interest rate as a model-consistent ex ante real rate of interest, using the in ation expectations provided by the model instead of deriving them from univariate autoregressive models of in ation as Laubach and Williams and others do. The maximum likelihood estimation involves the calibration of two ratios, and the choice of the calibrated ratios relies on several statistical criteria. Our TVNRI nevertheless appears to be robust to changes in both ratios. The estimated NRI and the derived interest rate gap the di erence between the real short term interest rate and the natural rate constitute valuable tools for assessing the monetary policy stance in EU12 over the last two decades. In particular, the superiority of such estimates in comparison with classical univariate lters is illustrated. However, the con dence interval, integrating the uncertainty associated with Kalman ltering, remains relatively broad. Besides, the real-time misperception of the 1 The speci cation of a nonstationary process for the natural rate of interest and/or the rate of growth of potential output is relatively common in the literature : see e.g. Laubach and Williams (2003), Orphanides and Williams (2002), Larsen and McKeown (2002), Fabiani and Mestre (2001) or Crespo Cuaresma and Gnan (2003). The random walk assumption for the natural rate of interest has the technical advantage of combining persistent changes in the unobservable component with a smooth accomodation of plausible but unspeci ed structural breaks in the e ective interest rate series over a period of estimation that generally covers the last two to three decades. Nevertheless, using a unobservable components setting for the euro area, Gerlach and Smets (1999) assume that potential output is I(1). 7

10 natural rate of interest (that can be approximated by the di erence between the two-sided estimates using the whole sample information and the one-sided estimates using only information up to time t) can also be substantial 2. The rest of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2 presents the data set. Section 3 introduces the model. Section 4 develops estimation issues. Lastly, Section 5 analyses the results and examines our estimated TVNRI. 2 Data The euro area time series are taken from ECB s AWM database and cover the period 1979Q1 2002Q4 with quarterly frequency (see Fagan et al., 2000). The rst year corresponds to the EMS entering into force. Whereas the real GDP gures provided by the AWM database are already seasonally adjusted, the HICP series is not and we hence adjust it using the Tramo/Seats procedure. We denote by y t the log real GDP. In ation is de ned as the annualised quarterly growth rate of the HICP series (in logs) and is denoted by t. The ex ante real short term rate of interest r t is obtained by deducting from the current level of the 3-month nominal rate of interest i t the one-quarter-ahead expectation of (quarterly annualised) in ation as derived from the entire model estimation (denoted with t+1jt below). A novelty of our approach is hence to compute an ex ante real rate of interest using modelconsistent in ation expectations instead of proxies for expectations as derived from univariate models of price dynamics or other external modelisation of in ation. Appendix 2 provides with an assessment of the quality of our model-consistent in ation expectations and compares them with alternative in ation expectations derived from both continuously updated univariate autoregressive models of in ation and the univariate time-varying coe cients procedure described by Stock and Watson (1996). Figure 1 plots our model-consistent in ation expectations together with the one-quarter-lead of quarterly annualised in ation. To end with, two variables are unobservable and constitute the state variables in the state-space model described in the following section, namely the output gap z t and the natural rate of interest rt. 3 Speci cations Our speci cations are close to these of Laubach and Williams (2003), themselves partly following the lines of Rudebusch and Svensson (1998). The model relies on six backward-looking linear equations. 2 Note that this measure of misperception is potentially optimistic since even in the one-sided case, the whole sample information has been used to estimate the model parameters and is consequently not exactly a real-time estimate of the NRI. 8

11 Figure 1: In ation, model-consistent in ation expectations and current annual increase in consumer prices. This backward-looking nature of the model makes it subject to the Lucas critique, according to which reduced-form relations in traditional macroeconomic models depend implicitly on the agents expectations of the policy process and are hence unlikely to remain stable as policymakers changed their rules. However, empirical backward-looking models without explicit expectations are still widely used for monetary policy analysis, as in Rudebusch and Svensson (1998, 2002), Onatski and Stock (2002), Smets (1998), Dennis (2001), Laubach and Williams (2003), Fagan, Henry and Mestre (2001) and Fabiani and Mestre (2004). Moreover, several articles suggest that such models appear to be fairly robust empirically, notably Rudebusch and Svensson (1998), Bernanke and Mihov (1998), Estrella and Fuhrer (1999), Dennis (2001) and Leeper and Zha (2002). The model consists of the following equations: 9

12 t+1 = A(L) t + B(L)z t + " t+1 (1) z t+1 = (L)z t + (L)(i t t+1jt rt ) + " z t+1 (2) rt = r + r a t (3) yt = y + y a t + " y t (4) a t+1 = a t + " a t+1 (5) y t = yt + z t (6) where L denotes the lag operator. We assume that the four shocks are independently normally distributed, their variance covariance matrix " is given by: 2 " = z y 0 0 : : : 0 2 a 3 ; 2 a = 1 (7) 7 5 The rst equation can be interpreted as an aggregate supply equation, or Phillips curve. It relates consumer price in ation to its own lags and to the lagged output gap. The second one is a reduced form of an aggregate demand equation, or IS curve, relating the output gap to its own lags and to the interest rate gap i.e. the di erence between the short term real rate and the natural rate of interest. Policymakers then control the in ation rate with a lag of two periods. The natural rate of interest is identi ed through the interest rate gap. More precisely, the output gap is assumed to converge to zero in the absence of demand shocks and if the real rate gap closes. In this model, stable in ation is consistent with both null output and interest rate gaps. Hence, our NRI could also be conveniently labelled as a nonaccelerating-in ation rate of interest (NAIRI). An important feature of the model is the fact that monetary policy only a ects the rate of in ation indirectly, via the output gap. Lastly, we take the nominal short rate of interest as exogenous, or, put di erently, the reaction function of the central bank remains implicit. Departing from common speci cations in the literature 3, we assume that the natural rate of interest rt follows an autoregressive process instead of a random walk, as speci ed by (3) and (5). The complete estimation of the model con rms that this process is in fact highly persistent (see the estimator of in Table 1), which ts our purpose of capturing large and low frequency uctuations in the level of the equilibrium real rate, as would the hypothesis of a nonstationary NRI also do. 3 See e.g. Laubach and Williams (2003), Orphanides and Williams (2002), or Larsen and McKeown (2004). 10

13 Nevertheless, assuming that the NRI follows a nonstationary process hinders the economic interpretation of the model, in particular if we assume, as suggested by economic theory, that potential growth yt shares common uctuations with rt 4. Indeed, the economic intuition underlying our speci cation choice in equations (3) to (5) refers to a basic optimal growth set-up (the textbook Ramsey model), where intertemporal utility maximisation by the representative household yields the following log-linear relationship between the real interest rate r and the (usually constant) rate of labor-augmenting technological change g, which is also the rate of growth of per capita output along a balanced-growth path 5 : r = g + (8) Assuming then that this trend growth rate g is in fact subject to low frequency uctuations, we get the intuition underlying our speci cation choice, where g is equivalent to our y a t. The (highly) autoregressive process denoted by a t aims hence at capturing low-frequency variations in potential output growth, under the assumption that these variations are common with those of the NRI. In addition to this persistent but stationary process, potential output growth consists in our model of another stationary component, which may account for other sources of discrepancies with the natural rate of interest e.g. due to shocks to preferences or changes in scal policies. Estimations show that a simple white noise is su cient to model this stationary component 6. These speci cations assume that potential GDP is an I(1) process, as is usual for the euro area 7. Our speci cations attempt to model the links between potential output growth and the natural rate of interest. In this respect, our approach lies between these of Laubach and Williams (2003) and of Orphanides and Williams (2002). In the former, rt is the sum of the trend growth rate, which also drives the low-frequency uctuations of potential output growth, and of a second speci c (possibly nonstationary) component. In the latter study, the natural rate of interest and potential output growth are completely 4 A nonstationary speci cation for the NRI and then potential output growth through the assumption of a randomwalk for a t would indeed imply that potential output is integrated of order two, which would be at odds with available evidence for the euro area. Besides, when translated into the set-up of a standard optimal growth model, this would mean a nonstationary path for the ratio of output to the stock of capital. 5 This relationship relies notably on the assumption of a standard utility function of the representative household u(c t) = Ct 1 =(1 ) with constant relative risk aversion (which corresponds to the inverse of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution) and where stands for the rate of time preference of consumers. 6 AR speci cations systematically lead to non-signi cant autoregressive coe cients. 7 See for example Gerlach and Smets (1998). Besides, both the ADF and Phillips-Perron tests clearly reject the null hypothesis of an I(2) log real GDP. 11

14 uncorrelated. This last assumption appears at odds with theoretical intuition and may potentially results in non-optimal exploitation of the data. Laubach and Williams approach features a higher level of complexity and therefore appears more attractive. However, this complexity raises numerous estimation problems, notably because it means extracting two unobservable components out of an already unobservable variable (rt ) which in turn is identi ed through the dynamics of an other unobservable variable (z t ) 8. Since we aim precisely at estimating a TVNRI in a way as transparent and robust as possible, we prefer to consider a single-process-driven NRI, yet presenting common uctuations with potential output growth. 4 Estimation The previous equations can be written in the state-space form, and the parameters can be estimated by maximisation of the likelihood function provided by the Kalman lter (see Annex D for the statespace representation of the present model). This lter is a recursive algorithm for sequentially updating a linear projection for a dynamic system. Given a set of measurement and transition equations, the Kalman lter provides the best linear unbiased estimator of the state variables ( ltered or smoothed 9 ) and a particularly attractive feature of this approach is its ability to quantify uncertainty around the estimated state variables 10. Estimation by the Kalman recursive equations requires the setting of initial values for the state vector, which comprises two blocks relative to a t (and its rst lag) on the one hand and to the output gap z t (and its rst lag) on the other. Natural candidates for the initial conditions are the unconditional mean and autocovariances of the unobservable variables in each block. Since we have not speci ed any equation for the dynamics of the nominal interest rate (in other words the reaction function of the central bank 8 In particular, some estimates of key-parameters when several components enter the dynamics of the NRI are very sensitive to the initial state values and variances. More precisely, if the NRI is assumed to follow a two-component process (rt = rat + t ) and if the variance re ecting the con dence on the initial value 0 is not large enough, the parameter r might be bounded to estimate the initial level of the NRI instead of assessing the extent to which the NRI and potential output growth uctuate together. 9 A ltered estimate is one-sided that is, it uses information only up to time t. A smoothed estimate is two-sided and uses information from the whole sample, up to time T. In this respect, the HP lter is a smoother, since it can be thought of as a two-sided moving average. 10 As pointed out by Hamilton (1986), two forms of uncertainties are associated with the estimated state vector of a statespace model. The rst one, the lter uncertainty, re ects the fact that the estimated state vector represents conditional expectations of true unobserved values. This rst uncertainty is due to Kalman lter estimation and would be present even if the true value of the model parameter were known. The second one, the parameter uncertainty re ects the uncertainty around the estimated parameters. 12

15 remains implicit), the derivation of the unconditional mean and variance of the output gap z t remains however out of reach. We hence resort to a common practice which consists in adopting relatively di use priors and assuming su ciently large values for the unobserved variance matrix (which measures the con dence in the priors). More precisely, we use the HP lter to get a prior estimate of the output gap. The ltered series is then used to get initial values for z t as well as to derive the output gap block of the covariance matrix of the initial state vector. By contrast, it is straightforward from equation (5) to derive the unconditional mean and autocovariances of the AR process a t as a function of the parameters. The maximisation of the log-likelihood computed by the Kalman lter then yields simultaneously the vector of parameters and the initial conditions for a t. Since a direct estimation by maximum likelihood provides unconsistent results, we resort to the calibration of two ratios of parameters, namely y = z (denoted with 1 ) and r = y (denoted with 2 ). As illustrated in Table 1, no consensus on the 1 ratio can be reached among estimation results for similar models of the US and EU economies 11. On the one hand and due to our speci cations this ratio should not be too small because this would amount to impose the strong hypothesis that the natural rate of interest and potential output growth have exactly the same uctuations. Indeed, potential output growth would then reduce to y a t, which turns out to be equal to y = r rt. On the other hand, too large a ratio entails a potential output growth very close to the observed GDP growth. Besides, the larger 1, the more volatile is potential output growth and the less volatile the output gap. To the extent that we prefer the output gap to be more volatile than potential output growth, we should choose a value for 1 below unity. Without constraining the ratio r = y, y is spontaneously estimated to be zero, suggesting that there is no common trend between the natural rate of interest and potential output growth. However, Figure 2 plots the natural rate of interest resulting from such an estimation together with the HP- ltered output growth and shows that the series exhibit marked common uctuations 12. It can consequently be assumed that information contained in the data is not optimally extracted by direct MLE. For this reason, we resort to a calibration of the ratio r = y. Available empirical evidence suggests that the natural rate of interest varies from one-for-one to ve-for-one with changes in the 11 In Table 1, estimates of y= z ranges from approximately 0 to The correlation coe cient of the two series is

16 Table.1 Estimation results from various studies Auth. area period z y P i MR EA 1979:1-2002: :06 2 lags 0.19 FM EA 1970:1-1999: / 0.12 PS GS GS GS GS EU 1975:1-1997: (5) EU 1975:1-1997: (5) EU (5=10) 1975:1-1997: EU 1990:1-1997: (5) EU (10) 1990:1-1997: PS U S 1975:1-1997: RS U S 1961:1-1996: S U S 1962:1-1997: S U S 1980:1-1997: LW U S 1961:1-2000: Table 1: MR : Mésonnier and Renne, this paper / PS : Peersman and Smets (1999) / GS : Gerlach and Smets (1999) / S : Smets (2000) / RS : Rudebusch and Svensson (1998) / LW : Laubach and Williams (2001) / FM : Fabiani and Mestre (2004, model 1) trend growth rate 13. As a result, we consider such an interval for the ratio r = y in the following Estimation results As regards the Phillips curve, the choice of the order of the lag-polynomial A(L) is based on the signi cance of the last lag included. Moreover, the null hypothesis that the coe cients of the in ation lags sum to one is not rejected by the data, leading to an accelerationist form of the Phillips curve. In other words, 13 Intertemporal elasticities of substitution (IES) estimated by Hall (1988) are small and not statistically di erent from zero (corresponding to in nite risk aversion). However, Ogaki and Reinhart (1998) argue that Hall s model is misspeci ed because the intratemporal substitution between nondurable consumption goods and durable consumption goods is ignored and in two contributions (1998a, 1998b), they obtain IES estimates between 0.27 and 0.77 (corresponding to risk aversions between 1.3 and 3.7). Barsky et al. use micro-data and estimate an IES of 0.18, implying a coe cient of risk aversion of Since we use quarterly growth rate of GDP, a relative risk aversion coe cient of 1 corresponds here to a value of 4 for the ratio r= y: That is why the interval considered in the following for this ratio is [4; 20]. 14

17 Figure 2: HP- ltered output growth & estimate of the natural rate of interest when the ratio r = y is not constrained (the HP- ltered output growth series is demeaned and rescaled). in ation depends only on nominal factors in the long run. As regards the IS equation, only the rst lag of the output gap is included 15. In addition, following Laubach and Williams, two lags of the rate gap enter this equation. However, since the estimation of two distinct coe cients for each of these two lags results in some unsatisfying compensation phenomena, we constrain the two coe cients to be equal. The model can then be rewritten: t+1 = 1 t + 2 t t 2 + z t + " t+1 (9) z t+1 = 1 z t + 2 z t 1 + (1 + L)(i t t+1jt rt ) + " z t+1 (10) rt = r + r a t (11) yt = y + y a t + " y t (12) a t+1 = a t + " a t+1 (13) y t = yt + z t (14) The numerical BFGS algorithm provided by GAUSS is applied to get the MLE 16, under xed 1 = 15 Including a second lag yields a small and non-signi cant second autoregressive parameter. 16 As regards the initialization of the optimisation algorithm, many starting values have been tested: our estimates appear 15

18 y = z and 2 = r = y. The choice of these ratios is based on three criteria: - rst, the Lagrange Multiplier test, whose main advantage is that the unrestricted MLE does not need to be known, is applied for many values of the ratios (f 1 ; 2 g 2 [0; 3] [4; 20]) and combinations leading to a p-value lower than 25% are rejected; - the economic relevance of the estimated unobservable components and the signi cativity of the main parameters of our model constitutes a second criterion; - the level of implied uncertainty inherent to the Kalman ltering procedure is the third one. Results according to the rst criterion 17 are presented on Figure 10, and suggest that 1 should be chosen lower than 2 and 2 greater than 8. Table 2 contains the parameter estimates when 1 is equal to 0.5 and 2 to di erent values (12, 16, 20 or 1); and when 2 is equal to 16 and 1 is equal to p 0:1 or 1:5. The computation of the information matrix is based on the expression given by Engle and Watson (1981) (see Annex C). All the parameters have the expected sign. The monetary policy transmission parameters namely, the slope of the Phillips curve and, the IRG semi-elasticity of the output gap are in line with the estimates obtained in close models for the European Union (see Table 1) 18. Furthermore, the signi cativity of both the slope of the Phillips curve and the IRG semi-elasticity of the output gap compares broadly with those of Laubach and Williams 19. As a rule, except for the standard deviations, the parameter estimates are little a ected by the choice of the ratios. Increasing 1 tends to deteriorate the signi cativity of, while only slightly diminishing this of. Turning to the second ratio, an increase in 2 pulls down the signi cativity of r which is key for our estimate of the natural rate of interest. Moreover, the larger is 2, the wider the con dence interval around the natural rate of interest grows but at the same time the greater is the log-likelihood. Finally, Figures 11 and 12 suggest that the estimates of the state variables are faintly sensitive to the ratios 20. For all this, our preferred ratios are the following: to be particularly robust to their choice. 17 For a given level of 1 taken in the range of accepted values according to the LM test, a likelihood-ratio test rejects the null-hypothesis corresponding to a given level of 2 when this last ratio is below a certain threshold. For 1 equal to 0.5, this threshold for 2 is 7 with a probability of error of 10 %. Hence, the likelihood-ratio test does not help to discriminate further between the values of 2 reported in Table The e ect of the interest rate gap on the output gap is indeed twice larger than since we consider two lags of the real rate gap in the IS curve with this same coe cient. 19 The p-values associated with the Student T for our parameters and are 5 % and 13 % respectively. In their baseline model for the United States, Laubach and Williams get p-values of 10 % and 0 % for the same parameters. 20 Larger swings are observable in the case 2 = 1. However, as previously said, this value corresponds to the case where the trend growth rate and the NRI do not have any common stochastic trend, which is unsatisfying from an economic point of view. 16

19 Table.2 Parameter estimates 1 = 0:5 1 = 0:5 1 = 0:5 1 = p 0:1 1 = 1:5 1 = 0:5 2 = 12 2 = 16 2 = 20 2 = 16 2 = 16 2 = 1 LF 200:61 200:34 200:16 200:35 200:23 199:58 avg SE 0:97 1:12 1:24 1:08 1:41 2:81 1 0:47 (4:8) 2 0:27 (2:6) 3 0:26 (2:6) 0:19 (1:8) 0:97 (13:7) 0:79 (4:8) 0:06 ( 1:5) z 0:37 (8:2) 0:89 (9:1) y 0:18 (8:2) y 0:52 (7:6) y 0:07 (1:7) r 3:12 (2:4) r 0:87 (1:7) 0:46 (4:8) 0:27 (2:6) 0:27 (2:7) 0:19 (1:9) 0:97 (13:7) 0:80 (4:9) 0:06 ( 1:5) 0:37 (8:2) 0:90 (9:5) 0:18 (8:2) 0:52 (8:4) 0:06 (1:7) 3:10 (2:2) 0:98 (1:7) 0:46 (4:7) 0:27 (2:6) 0:27 (2:7) 0:19 (2:0) 0:97 (13:7) 0:80 (5:1) 0:06 ( 1:5) 0:37 (8:2) 0:90 (9:7) 0:18 (8:2) 0:52 (9:2) 0:05 (1:6) 3:07 (2:0) 1:07 (1:6) 0:47 (4:8) 0:27 (2:6) 0:26 (2:7) 0:18 (1:9) 0:97 (13:8) 0:80 (5:1) 0:06 ( 1:5) 0:39 (7:9) 0:90 (9:6) 0:12 (7:9) 0:52 (8:6) 0:06 (1:7) 3:09 (2:2) 0:43 (4:4) 0:28 (2:7) 0:29 (2:9) 0:30 (1:8) 0:95 (13:5) 0:76 (4:1) 0:05 ( 1:2) 0:24 (9:9) 0:89 (8:1) 0:36 (9:9) 0:53 (7:3) 0:07 (1:6) 3:14 (2:3) 0:44 (4:5) 0:28 (2:7) 0:28 (2:8) 0:12 (1:7) 0:97 (13:6) 0:85 (4:8) 0:04 ( 1:1) 0:37 (7:8) 0:90 (6:5) 0:18 (7:8) 0:53 (19:7) Table 2: LF: likelihood Function - t-students in parenthesis - avg SE: average of the estimated standard 0:98 (1:7) error around the estimate of the natural rate of interest ( lter uncertainty) 1:13 (1:6) 0 3:40 (1:8) 2:28 (1:0) 17

20 Figure 3: Natural rate of interest ( 1 = 0:5; 2 = 16). 1 = y z = 0:5 and 2 = r y = 16 In order to detect signs of potential parameter nonconstancy over the sample period, we use recursive estimations. The model parameters are updated at each new observation in time, estimation sample being extended from 1979Q1-1994Q1 to 1979Q1-2002Q4. Figure 13 reports recursive estimates of and with their 80% con dence interval: the estimated parameters then appear to be fairly stable. The other model parameters are not largely a ected by these changes in the sample length either. Figure 3 plots our estimated smoothed natural rate of interest, together with the actual real rate of interest and the 90% con dence interval around the estimates of state variables. The estimated real interest rate gap o ers a valuable insight into the monetary policy stance over the last two decades. Indeed, a positive interest rate gap means that monetary policy aims at dampening the current rate of in ation. Conversely, a negative gap means that the level of the central bank s key rate gives leeway to a rise in in ation. For convenience s sake, we describe here both situations in terms of monetary policy being either tight or loose. However, a more precise terminology would refer to a disin ationary versus an in ationary policy stance. The point at stake is that the real interest rate gap is not conceptually equivalent to the di erential between the (policy driven) real interest rate and the short term real rate that a standard Taylor rule would prescribe. While the interest rate prescription of the Taylor rule aims 18

21 Figure 4: Output gap ( 1 = 0:5; 2 = 16). Figure 5: Potential output growth ( 1 = 0:5; 2 = 16). 19

22 at anchoring in ation at a given level (the in ation target of the central bank), equating the current real rate of interest with its natural counterpart only means that one has an objective of in ation stabilisation, but nothing is said about the nominal anchor. This being said, according to our measure of the real interest rate gap and taking into account lter-uncertainty, monetary policy in the euro area appears to have been signi cantly tight over three particular episodes: in the early 1980s in parallel with the Volcker era in the United States, in 1986 and from the EMS crisis of summer 1992 until Conversely, two to three episodes of signi cantly loose monetary policy are identi ed, namely in the late 1970s during the great in ation and before the vigorous tightening of the early 1980s, possibly in 1988 while the output gap of the area was rapidly reverting, and nally in 1999, mainly as a consequence of the 50 bp cut in the ECB s repo rate in April. From 2000 on, the actual real short term rate of interest appears by contrast to be fairly in line with its estimated natural counterpart, which suggests that the monetary policy stance in the euro area has been broadly appropriate since then in terms of in ation stabilisation. Turning to the output gap, Figure 4 highlights periods of excess demand around 1980, 1990 and 2000 and periods of excess supply in the mid-1980s and mid-1990s. Resulting peaks and troughs are in line with available evidence about the business cycle in the main European countries over the last two decades. The a t component satisfyingly tracks the low-frequency uctuations of potential output growth (see Figure 5) and can therefore be interpreted as the trend growth rate speci ed in Laubach and Williams (2001) once multiplied by y. According to our results, potential output growth would have reached a maximum of 3.2 % in 1989 and a minimum of 1.6% in 1982 and This nal low value of the trend growth rate partly accounts for the positive output gap at the end of the sample. Indications of such a recent decrease in the trend growth rate for the euro area are in turn consistent with empirical evidence of a slowdown in trend productivity growth in European countries in the 1990s (Maury and Pluyaud, 2004), together with the postulated end of the catching up process of American productivity levels in the mid-1990s. A proxy for the real-time estimate of the NRI is the ltered value yielded by the Kalman lter, which uses information available up to time t only (instead of T for the smoothed value) 21. Figure 6 shows that the di erences between the ltered and smoothed series of the NRI are relatively small. Both resulting interest rate gaps present roughly the same sign throughout the period. Nevertheless, the gap derived from the ltered series tends to change signs after its smoothed equivalent, which is in any case not surprising considering the information advantage of the smoothed series. Finally, di erent ltering techniques are compared in Figure 7. Two univariate lters have been used: the Hodrick-Prescott (HP) lter (1997) and the Band-Pass (BP) lter (see Baxter and King, 1999). As 21 As previously stated, this estimate is not rigorously available in real-time because it relies on estimated values for the parameters of the state-space model, which are computed on the basis of the whole sample information. 20

23 Figure 6: Filtered (one-sided) and smoothed (two-sided) natural rate of interest. regards the HP lter, two smoothness parameters are considered: 1600 and Following Staiger, Stock and Watson (2002), as well as Laubach and Williams (2003), the BP lter is used to discard the cyclical component from the real rate of interest, i.e. the frequencies corresponding to periods of up to 15 years. Consistently with their two-sided moving average representations ( nite in the case of the Baxter and King BP lter, in nite in the case of the HP lter), the two univariate lters simply track the trend of the real rate of interest, while our estimate also takes into account the actual uctuations in in ation and the level of output. More precisely, as Figure 8 shows, a positive sign of our real rate gap is contemporaneous with periods of marked disin ation while a signi cant negative sign of our real rate gap entails a rise in in ation over the same period. Besides, a persistent slowdown of the trend growth rate results as expected in a decrease in the natural rate of interest. To comment further on the relationship between the interest rate gap and in ation in the euro area, it is convenient to decompose the changes in our estimated real rate gap into three components: 1/ changes in the nominal interest rate, 2/ changes in one-quarter-ahead in ation expectations and 3/ changes in the NRI itself. Figure 9 displays this breakdown together with the corresponding interest rate gap. According 22 This last value smoothes the data slightly more than the commonly-used 1600 value. Bouthevillain et al. (2001) show that this value entails signi cant bene ts in terms of less leakage e ects (which is a ltering error corresponding to the overestimation of the variability of the cyclical component) compared to the costs related to the increase in compression e ects (which is the alternative ltering error ). 21

Perceived productivity and the natural rate of interest

Perceived productivity and the natural rate of interest Perceived productivity and the natural rate of interest Gianni Amisano and Oreste Tristani European Central Bank IRF 28 Frankfurt, 26 June Amisano-Tristani (European Central Bank) Productivity and the

More information

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models Fall 22 Contents Introduction 2. An illustrative example........................... 2.2 Discussion...................................

More information

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP Measuring monetary policy deviations from the Taylor rule

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP Measuring monetary policy deviations from the Taylor rule Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP-1803 Measuring monetary policy deviations from the Taylor rule João Madeira Nuno Palma February 2018 Economics School of Social Sciences The University of Manchester

More information

Looking for the stars

Looking for the stars Looking for the stars Mengheng Li 12 Irma Hindrayanto 1 1 Economic Research and Policy Division, De Nederlandsche Bank 2 Department of Econometrics, Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam April 5, 2018 1 / 35 Outline

More information

NOTES D ÉTUDES ET DE RECHERCHE

NOTES D ÉTUDES ET DE RECHERCHE NOTES D ÉTUDES ET DE RECHERCHE DOES UNCERTAINTY MAKE A TIME-VARYING NATURAL RATE OF INTEREST IRRELEVANT FOR THE CONDUCT OF MONETARY POLICY? Jean-Stéphane Mésonnier and Jean-Paul Renne September 200 NER

More information

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models 4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models Basic Economic Models In Economics, we use theoretical models to explain the economic processes in the real world. These models de ne a relation

More information

RBC Model with Indivisible Labor. Advanced Macroeconomic Theory

RBC Model with Indivisible Labor. Advanced Macroeconomic Theory RBC Model with Indivisible Labor Advanced Macroeconomic Theory 1 Last Class What are business cycles? Using HP- lter to decompose data into trend and cyclical components Business cycle facts Standard RBC

More information

Policy Inertia and Equilibrium Determinacy in a New. Keynesian Model with Investment

Policy Inertia and Equilibrium Determinacy in a New. Keynesian Model with Investment Policy Inertia and Equilibrium Determinacy in a New Keynesian Model with Investment Wei Xiao State University of New York at Binghamton June, 2007 Abstract Carlstrom and Fuerst (2005) demonstrate that

More information

Searching for the Output Gap: Economic Variable or Statistical Illusion? Mark W. Longbrake* J. Huston McCulloch

Searching for the Output Gap: Economic Variable or Statistical Illusion? Mark W. Longbrake* J. Huston McCulloch Draft Draft Searching for the Output Gap: Economic Variable or Statistical Illusion? Mark W. Longbrake* The Ohio State University J. Huston McCulloch The Ohio State University August, 2007 Abstract This

More information

Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts

Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts Contents 1 Motivating Examples 1 1.1 Instrumental variable estimator....................... 1 1.2 Estimating parameters in monetary policy rules.............. 2 1.3 Estimating

More information

Lecture 6, January 7 and 15: Sticky Wages and Prices (Galí, Chapter 6)

Lecture 6, January 7 and 15: Sticky Wages and Prices (Galí, Chapter 6) MakØk3, Fall 2012/2013 (Blok 2) Business cycles and monetary stabilization policies Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen Lecture 6, January 7 and 15: Sticky Wages and Prices (Galí,

More information

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3) MakØk3, Fall 2 (blok 2) Business cycles and monetary stabilization policies Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen Lecture 3, November 3: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter

More information

Estimating Output Gap, Core Inflation, and the NAIRU for Peru

Estimating Output Gap, Core Inflation, and the NAIRU for Peru BANCO CENTRAL DE RESERVA DEL PERÚ Estimating Output Gap, Core Inflation, and the NAIRU for Peru Gabriel Rodríguez* * Central Reserve Bank of Peru and Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú DT. N 2009-011

More information

1 Regression with Time Series Variables

1 Regression with Time Series Variables 1 Regression with Time Series Variables With time series regression, Y might not only depend on X, but also lags of Y and lags of X Autoregressive Distributed lag (or ADL(p; q)) model has these features:

More information

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008 The Basic New Keynesian Model by Jordi Galí June 28 Motivation and Outline Evidence on Money, Output, and Prices: Short Run E ects of Monetary Policy Shocks (i) persistent e ects on real variables (ii)

More information

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010 The Basic New Keynesian Model by Jordi Galí November 2 Motivation and Outline Evidence on Money, Output, and Prices: Short Run E ects of Monetary Policy Shocks (i) persistent e ects on real variables (ii)

More information

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA On the Solution of the Growth Model with Investment-Specific Technological Change Jesús Fernández-Villaverde and Juan Francisco Rubio-Ramírez Working Paper 2004-39 December

More information

Markov-Switching Models with Endogenous Explanatory Variables. Chang-Jin Kim 1

Markov-Switching Models with Endogenous Explanatory Variables. Chang-Jin Kim 1 Markov-Switching Models with Endogenous Explanatory Variables by Chang-Jin Kim 1 Dept. of Economics, Korea University and Dept. of Economics, University of Washington First draft: August, 2002 This version:

More information

Central Bank Communication and the Liquidity Trap

Central Bank Communication and the Liquidity Trap Central Bank Communication and the Liquidity Trap Stefano Eusepi y Federal Reserve Bank of New York October 8, 2009 Abstract Central bank communication plays an important role in shaping market participants

More information

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING James Bullard* Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 33rd Annual Economic Policy Conference St. Louis, MO October 17, 2008 Views expressed are

More information

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999) Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999) The question we are asking is: What are the consequences of a monetary policy shock a shock which is purely related to monetary conditions

More information

Equivalence of several methods for decomposing time series into permananent and transitory components

Equivalence of several methods for decomposing time series into permananent and transitory components Equivalence of several methods for decomposing time series into permananent and transitory components Don Harding Department of Economics and Finance LaTrobe University, Bundoora Victoria 3086 and Centre

More information

Discussion of Juillard and Maih Estimating DSGE Models with Observed Real-Time Expectation Data

Discussion of Juillard and Maih Estimating DSGE Models with Observed Real-Time Expectation Data Estimating DSGE Models with Observed Real-Time Expectation Data Jesper Lindé Federal Reserve Board Workshop on Central Bank Forecasting Kansas City Fed October 14-15, 2010 Summary of paper This interesting

More information

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology Daron Acemoglu MIT October 3, 2007 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Advanced Growth Lecture 8 October 3,

More information

Problem Set 2: Sketch of Answers

Problem Set 2: Sketch of Answers Problem Set 2: Sketch of Answers HEC Lausanne, Département d économie politique Business Cycles 2003 Prof. Aude Pommeret Ivan Jaccard April 30, 2004 Part I: Open questions 1. Explain why the consensus

More information

Combining Macroeconomic Models for Prediction

Combining Macroeconomic Models for Prediction Combining Macroeconomic Models for Prediction John Geweke University of Technology Sydney 15th Australasian Macro Workshop April 8, 2010 Outline 1 Optimal prediction pools 2 Models and data 3 Optimal pools

More information

Inflation Dynamics in the Euro Area Jensen, Henrik

Inflation Dynamics in the Euro Area Jensen, Henrik university of copenhagen Inflation Dynamics in the Euro Area Jensen, Henrik Publication date: 2010 Document Version Publisher's PDF, also known as Version of record Citation for published version (APA):

More information

Aggregate Supply. A Nonvertical AS Curve. implications for unemployment, rms pricing behavior, the real wage and the markup

Aggregate Supply. A Nonvertical AS Curve. implications for unemployment, rms pricing behavior, the real wage and the markup A Nonvertical AS Curve nominal wage rigidity nominal price rigidity labor and goods markets implications for unemployment, rms pricing behavior, the real wage and the markup Case 1: Sticky W, Flexible

More information

Problem set 1 - Solutions

Problem set 1 - Solutions EMPIRICAL FINANCE AND FINANCIAL ECONOMETRICS - MODULE (8448) Problem set 1 - Solutions Exercise 1 -Solutions 1. The correct answer is (a). In fact, the process generating daily prices is usually assumed

More information

Adaptive Learning and Survey Expectations of In ation

Adaptive Learning and Survey Expectations of In ation Adaptive Learning and Survey Expectations of In ation Sergey Slobodyan NRU HSE St.Petersburg & CERGE-EI Raf Wouters National Bank of Belgium preliminary draft August 28, 217 Abstract The use of survey

More information

Macroeconomics Theory II

Macroeconomics Theory II Macroeconomics Theory II Francesco Franco FEUNL February 2016 Francesco Franco Macroeconomics Theory II 1/23 Housekeeping. Class organization. Website with notes and papers as no "Mas-Collel" in macro

More information

Indeterminacy and Forecastability *

Indeterminacy and Forecastability * Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper No. 91 http://www.dallasfed.org/assets/documents/institute/wpapers/2011/0091.pdf Indeterminacy and Forecastability

More information

Solutions to Problem Set 4 Macro II (14.452)

Solutions to Problem Set 4 Macro II (14.452) Solutions to Problem Set 4 Macro II (14.452) Francisco A. Gallego 05/11 1 Money as a Factor of Production (Dornbusch and Frenkel, 1973) The shortcut used by Dornbusch and Frenkel to introduce money in

More information

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks Eric R. Sims University of Notre Dame and NBER January 17, 2012 Abstract In a standard New Keynesian model, a Taylor-type interest rate rule moves the equilibrium real

More information

Public Infrastructure and Economic Growth in Mexico

Public Infrastructure and Economic Growth in Mexico Public Infrastructure and Economic Growth in Mexico Antonio Noriega Matias Fontenla Universidad de Guanajuato and CIDE April 15, 2005 Abstract We develop a model where investment in infrastructure complements

More information

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010 Session 4: Jean November 2010 I So far, focused on real economy. Real quantities consumed, produced, invested. No money, no nominal in uences. I Now, introduce nominal dimension in the economy. First and

More information

Granger Causality and Equilibrium Business Cycle Theory

Granger Causality and Equilibrium Business Cycle Theory Granger Causality and Equilibrium Business Cycle Theory Yi Wen Department of Economics Cornell University Abstract Post war US data show that consumption growth causes output and investment growth. This

More information

GCOE Discussion Paper Series

GCOE Discussion Paper Series GCOE Discussion Paper Series Global COE Program Human Behavior and Socioeconomic Dynamics Discussion Paper No.34 Inflation Inertia and Optimal Delegation of Monetary Policy Keiichi Morimoto February 2009

More information

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics DSGE-Models Calibration and Introduction to Dynare Dr. Andrea Beccarini Willi Mutschler, M.Sc. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics willi.mutschler@uni-muenster.de Summer 2012 Willi Mutschler

More information

Warwick Business School Forecasting System. Summary. Ana Galvao, Anthony Garratt and James Mitchell November, 2014

Warwick Business School Forecasting System. Summary. Ana Galvao, Anthony Garratt and James Mitchell November, 2014 Warwick Business School Forecasting System Summary Ana Galvao, Anthony Garratt and James Mitchell November, 21 The main objective of the Warwick Business School Forecasting System is to provide competitive

More information

On Econometric Analysis of Structural Systems with Permanent and Transitory Shocks and Exogenous Variables

On Econometric Analysis of Structural Systems with Permanent and Transitory Shocks and Exogenous Variables On Econometric Analysis of Structural Systems with Permanent and Transitory Shocks and Exogenous Variables Adrian Pagan School of Economics and Finance, Queensland University of Technology M. Hashem Pesaran

More information

x i = 1 yi 2 = 55 with N = 30. Use the above sample information to answer all the following questions. Show explicitly all formulas and calculations.

x i = 1 yi 2 = 55 with N = 30. Use the above sample information to answer all the following questions. Show explicitly all formulas and calculations. Exercises for the course of Econometrics Introduction 1. () A researcher is using data for a sample of 30 observations to investigate the relationship between some dependent variable y i and independent

More information

The Price Puzzle: Mixing the Temporary and Permanent Monetary Policy Shocks.

The Price Puzzle: Mixing the Temporary and Permanent Monetary Policy Shocks. The Price Puzzle: Mixing the Temporary and Permanent Monetary Policy Shocks. Ida Wolden Bache Norges Bank Kai Leitemo Norwegian School of Management BI September 2, 2008 Abstract We argue that the correct

More information

In Search of a Nominal Anchor: What Drives In ation Expectations?

In Search of a Nominal Anchor: What Drives In ation Expectations? In Search of a Nominal Anchor: What Drives In ation Expectations? Carlos Carvalho y PUC-Rio Stefano Eusepi z Federal Reserve Bank of NY Bruce Preston { The University of Melbourne Emanuel Moench x Deutsche

More information

The Role of Model Uncertainty and Learning in the U.S. Postwar Policy Response to Oil Prices

The Role of Model Uncertainty and Learning in the U.S. Postwar Policy Response to Oil Prices The Role of Model Uncertainty and Learning in the U.S. Postwar Policy Response to Oil Prices Francesca Rondina June 2010 Barcelona Economics Working Paper Series Working Paper nº 478 The role of model

More information

The Superiority of Greenbook Forecasts and the Role of Recessions

The Superiority of Greenbook Forecasts and the Role of Recessions The Superiority of Greenbook Forecasts and the Role of Recessions N. Kundan Kishor University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee Abstract In this paper, we examine the role of recessions on the relative forecasting

More information

Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence

Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence Peter M. Robinson London School of Economics Based on joint work with Javier Hualde: Javier Hualde and Peter M. Robinson: Gaussian Pseudo-Maximum Likelihood Estimation

More information

Macroeconomics II Dynamic macroeconomics Class 1: Introduction and rst models

Macroeconomics II Dynamic macroeconomics Class 1: Introduction and rst models Macroeconomics II Dynamic macroeconomics Class 1: Introduction and rst models Prof. George McCandless UCEMA Spring 2008 1 Class 1: introduction and rst models What we will do today 1. Organization of course

More information

Time Series Models and Inference. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley

Time Series Models and Inference. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Time Series Models and Inference James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Overview In contrast to the classical linear regression model, in which the components of the

More information

Modeling the Phillips curve with unobserved components

Modeling the Phillips curve with unobserved components Modeling the Phillips curve with unobserved components Andrew Harvey, Faculty of Economics, Cambridge University. ACH34@CAM.AC.UK January 18, 2008 Abstract The relationship between in ation and the output

More information

Technical Appendix-3-Regime asymmetric STAR modeling and exchange rate reversion

Technical Appendix-3-Regime asymmetric STAR modeling and exchange rate reversion Technical Appendix-3-Regime asymmetric STAR modeling and exchange rate reversion Mario Cerrato*, Hyunsok Kim* and Ronald MacDonald** 1 University of Glasgow, Department of Economics, Adam Smith building.

More information

Indicator Variables for Optimal Policy

Indicator Variables for Optimal Policy SWIND00.tex Preliminary. Comments welcome. Indicator Variables for Optimal Policy Lars E.O. Svensson y and Michael Woodford z First draft: November 1999 This version: February 000 Abstract The optimal

More information

Notes on Time Series Modeling

Notes on Time Series Modeling Notes on Time Series Modeling Garey Ramey University of California, San Diego January 17 1 Stationary processes De nition A stochastic process is any set of random variables y t indexed by t T : fy t g

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Monetary Models with Nominal Rigidities. Jordi Galí Universitat Pompeu Fabra April 2018

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Monetary Models with Nominal Rigidities. Jordi Galí Universitat Pompeu Fabra April 2018 Advanced Macroeconomics II Monetary Models with Nominal Rigidities Jordi Galí Universitat Pompeu Fabra April 208 Motivation Empirical Evidence Macro evidence on the e ects of monetary policy shocks (i)

More information

Short-run electricity demand forecasts in Maharashtra

Short-run electricity demand forecasts in Maharashtra Applied Economics, 2002, 34, 1055±1059 Short-run electricity demand forecasts in Maharashtra SAJAL GHO SH* and AN JAN A D AS Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai, India This paper, has

More information

Monetary Economics Notes

Monetary Economics Notes Monetary Economics Notes Nicola Viegi 2 University of Pretoria - School of Economics Contents New Keynesian Models. Readings...............................2 Basic New Keynesian Model...................

More information

Volume 29, Issue 4. Stability under learning: the neo-classical growth problem

Volume 29, Issue 4. Stability under learning: the neo-classical growth problem Volume 29, Issue 4 Stability under learning: the neo-classical growth problem Orlando Gomes ISCAL - IPL; Economics Research Center [UNIDE/ISCTE - ERC] Abstract A local stability condition for the standard

More information

Dynamic probabilities of restrictions in state space models: An application to the New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Dynamic probabilities of restrictions in state space models: An application to the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Dynamic probabilities of restrictions in state space models: An application to the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Gary Koop Department of Economics University of Strathclyde Scotland Gary.Koop@strath.ac.uk

More information

Another Look at the Boom and Bust of Financial Bubbles

Another Look at the Boom and Bust of Financial Bubbles ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 16-2, 417 423 (2015) Another Look at the Boom and Bust of Financial Bubbles Andrea Beccarini University of Münster, Department of Economics, Am Stadtgraben 9, 48143, Münster,

More information

Chapter 1. Introduction. 1.1 Background

Chapter 1. Introduction. 1.1 Background Chapter 1 Introduction Science is facts; just as houses are made of stones, so is science made of facts; but a pile of stones is not a house and a collection of facts is not necessarily science. Henri

More information

Daily Welfare Gains from Trade

Daily Welfare Gains from Trade Daily Welfare Gains from Trade Hasan Toprak Hakan Yilmazkuday y INCOMPLETE Abstract Using daily price quantity data on imported locally produced agricultural products, this paper estimates the elasticity

More information

An Extended Macro-Finance Model with Financial Factors: Technical Appendix

An Extended Macro-Finance Model with Financial Factors: Technical Appendix An Extended Macro-Finance Model with Financial Factors: Technical Appendix June 1, 010 Abstract This technical appendix provides some more technical comments concerning the EMF model, used in the paper

More information

Macroeconomics Theory II

Macroeconomics Theory II Macroeconomics Theory II Francesco Franco Nova SBE February 2012 Francesco Franco Macroeconomics Theory II 1/31 Housekeeping Website TA: none No "Mas-Collel" in macro One midterm, one final, problem sets

More information

ECONOMICS 7200 MODERN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Econometric Theory and Applications

ECONOMICS 7200 MODERN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Econometric Theory and Applications ECONOMICS 7200 MODERN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Econometric Theory and Applications Yongmiao Hong Department of Economics & Department of Statistical Sciences Cornell University Spring 2019 Time and uncertainty

More information

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective Jordi Galí CREI, UPF and Barcelona GSE May 218 Jordi Galí (CREI, UPF and Barcelona GSE) Monetary Policy and Unemployment May 218 1 / 18 Introducing

More information

Cost Channel, Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Policy under Zero Lower Bound

Cost Channel, Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Policy under Zero Lower Bound WP-2016-012 Cost Channel, Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Policy under Zero Lower Bound Siddhartha Chattopadhyay & Taniya Ghosh Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai July 2016

More information

1 A Non-technical Introduction to Regression

1 A Non-technical Introduction to Regression 1 A Non-technical Introduction to Regression Chapters 1 and Chapter 2 of the textbook are reviews of material you should know from your previous study (e.g. in your second year course). They cover, in

More information

1 The social planner problem

1 The social planner problem The social planner problem max C t;k t+ U t = E t X t C t () that can be written as: s.t.: Y t = A t K t (2) Y t = C t + I t (3) I t = K t+ (4) A t = A A t (5) et t i:i:d: 0; 2 max C t;k t+ U t = E t "

More information

The updated version of this paper is available at as Working Paper No. 11-3, Estimation of

The updated version of this paper is available at   as Working Paper No. 11-3, Estimation of The updated version of this paper is available at http://www.bostonfed.org/economic/wp/wp2/wp3.htm as Working Paper No. -3, Estimation of Forward-Looking Relationships in Closed Form: An Application to

More information

Euro-indicators Working Group

Euro-indicators Working Group Euro-indicators Working Group Luxembourg, 9 th & 10 th June 2011 Item 9.4 of the Agenda New developments in EuroMIND estimates Rosa Ruggeri Cannata Doc 309/11 What is EuroMIND? EuroMIND is a Monthly INDicator

More information

Estimates of the Sticky-Information Phillips Curve for the USA with the General to Specific Method

Estimates of the Sticky-Information Phillips Curve for the USA with the General to Specific Method MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Estimates of the Sticky-Information Phillips Curve for the USA with the General to Specific Method Antonio Paradiso and B. Bhaskara Rao and Marco Ventura 12. February

More information

Sophisticated Monetary Policies

Sophisticated Monetary Policies Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Sta Report 419 January 2008 Sophisticated Monetary Policies Andrew Atkeson University of California, Los Angeles, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis,

More information

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 36 I Motivation This Lecture considers some applications

More information

Modeling the Phillips curve with unobserved components

Modeling the Phillips curve with unobserved components Modeling the Phillips curve with unobserved components Andrew Harvey, Faculty of Economics, Cambridge University. ACH34@CAM.AC.UK September 23, 2008 Abstract The relationship between in ation and the output

More information

Lecture 2. Business Cycle Measurement. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD II Semestre 2017 Last updated: August 18, 2017

Lecture 2. Business Cycle Measurement. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD II Semestre 2017 Last updated: August 18, 2017 Lecture 2 Business Cycle Measurement Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD II Semestre 2017 Last updated: August 18, 2017 Universidad de Costa Rica EC3201 - Teoría Macroeconómica 2 Table of contents 1. Introduction

More information

Volume 30, Issue 1. Measuring the Intertemporal Elasticity of Substitution for Consumption: Some Evidence from Japan

Volume 30, Issue 1. Measuring the Intertemporal Elasticity of Substitution for Consumption: Some Evidence from Japan Volume 30, Issue 1 Measuring the Intertemporal Elasticity of Substitution for Consumption: Some Evidence from Japan Akihiko Noda Graduate School of Business and Commerce, Keio University Shunsuke Sugiyama

More information

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Labor Economics, 14.661. Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Daron Acemoglu MIT December 6, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Sequential Search December 6, 2011. 1 / 43 Introduction Introduction

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHERE ARE WE NOW? REAL-TIME ESTIMATES OF THE MACRO ECONOMY. Martin D.D. Evans

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHERE ARE WE NOW? REAL-TIME ESTIMATES OF THE MACRO ECONOMY. Martin D.D. Evans NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHERE ARE WE NOW? REAL-TIME ESTIMATES OF THE MACRO ECONOMY Martin D.D. Evans Working Paper 11064 http://www.nber.org/papers/w11064 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

Cointegration Tests Using Instrumental Variables Estimation and the Demand for Money in England

Cointegration Tests Using Instrumental Variables Estimation and the Demand for Money in England Cointegration Tests Using Instrumental Variables Estimation and the Demand for Money in England Kyung So Im Junsoo Lee Walter Enders June 12, 2005 Abstract In this paper, we propose new cointegration tests

More information

On the Correlations of Trend-Cycle Errors

On the Correlations of Trend-Cycle Errors On the Correlations of Trend-Cycle Errors Tatsuma Wada Wayne State University This version: December 19, 11 Abstract This note provides explanations for an unexpected result, namely, the estimated parameter

More information

Where Are We Now? Real-Time Estimates of the Macro Economy

Where Are We Now? Real-Time Estimates of the Macro Economy Where Are We Now? Real-Time Estimates of the Macro Economy Martin D. D. Evans Georgetown University and the NBER March 2005 Forthcoming in The International Journal of Central Banking Abstract This paper

More information

KRANNERT GRADUATE SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT

KRANNERT GRADUATE SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT KRANNERT GRADUATE SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT Purdue University West Lafayette, Indiana The Nature of Persistence in Euro Area Inflation: A Reconsideration by Mohitosh Kejriwal Paper No. 118 Date: March, 009

More information

Structural VAR Models and Applications

Structural VAR Models and Applications Structural VAR Models and Applications Laurent Ferrara 1 1 University of Paris Nanterre M2 Oct. 2018 SVAR: Objectives Whereas the VAR model is able to capture efficiently the interactions between the different

More information

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1 Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1 John C. Chao April 25, 2017 1 These notes are based in large part on Chapter 16 of Stock and Watson (2011). They are for instructional purposes

More information

Optimal Monetary Policy in a Data-Rich Environment

Optimal Monetary Policy in a Data-Rich Environment Optimal Monetary Policy in a Data-Rich Environment Jean Boivin HEC Montréal, CIRANO, CIRPÉE and NBER Marc Giannoni Columbia University, NBER and CEPR Forecasting Short-term Economic Developments... Bank

More information

Two-sided Learning in New Keynesian Models: Dynamics, (Lack of) Convergence and the Value of Information

Two-sided Learning in New Keynesian Models: Dynamics, (Lack of) Convergence and the Value of Information Dynare Working Papers Series http://www.dynare.org/wp/ Two-sided Learning in New Keynesian Models: Dynamics, (Lack of) Convergence and the Value of Information Christian Matthes Francesca Rondina Working

More information

Finite State Markov-chain Approximations to Highly. Persistent Processes

Finite State Markov-chain Approximations to Highly. Persistent Processes Finite State Markov-chain Approximations to Highly Persistent Processes Karen A. Kopecky y Richard M. H. Suen z This Version: November 2009 Abstract The Rouwenhorst method of approximating stationary AR(1)

More information

CENTRE FOR APPLIED MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS

CENTRE FOR APPLIED MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS CENTRE FOR APPLIED MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS The Australian National University CAMA Working Paper Series May, 2005 SINGLE SOURCE OF ERROR STATE SPACE APPROACH TO THE BEVERIDGE NELSON DECOMPOSITION Heather

More information

Structural VAR based estimates of the euro area output gap: Theoretical considerations and empirical evidences

Structural VAR based estimates of the euro area output gap: Theoretical considerations and empirical evidences Structural VAR based estimates of the euro area output gap: Theoretical considerations and empirical evidences James Mitchell, Gian Luigi Mazzi y, Filippo Moauro z June 17, 2008 Abstract Users look with

More information

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4 Solow Growth Model Michael Bar February 28, 208 Contents Introduction 2. Some facts about modern growth........................ 3.2 Questions..................................... 4 2 The Solow Model 5

More information

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle. June 7, 2018

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle. June 7, 2018 Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle Jesper Lindé Sveriges Riksbank Mathias Trabandt Freie Universität Berlin June 7, 218 Motivation Key observations during the Great Recession: Extraordinary contraction

More information

Inflation Revisited: New Evidence from Modified Unit Root Tests

Inflation Revisited: New Evidence from Modified Unit Root Tests 1 Inflation Revisited: New Evidence from Modified Unit Root Tests Walter Enders and Yu Liu * University of Alabama in Tuscaloosa and University of Texas at El Paso Abstract: We propose a simple modification

More information

In the Ramsey model we maximized the utility U = u[c(t)]e nt e t dt. Now

In the Ramsey model we maximized the utility U = u[c(t)]e nt e t dt. Now PERMANENT INCOME AND OPTIMAL CONSUMPTION On the previous notes we saw how permanent income hypothesis can solve the Consumption Puzzle. Now we use this hypothesis, together with assumption of rational

More information

Problem 1 (30 points)

Problem 1 (30 points) Problem (30 points) Prof. Robert King Consider an economy in which there is one period and there are many, identical households. Each household derives utility from consumption (c), leisure (l) and a public

More information

Introduction to Macroeconomics

Introduction to Macroeconomics Introduction to Macroeconomics Martin Ellison Nuffi eld College Michaelmas Term 2018 Martin Ellison (Nuffi eld) Introduction Michaelmas Term 2018 1 / 39 Macroeconomics is Dynamic Decisions are taken over

More information

Spectral Covariance Instability Test and Macroeconomic. Volatility Dynamics

Spectral Covariance Instability Test and Macroeconomic. Volatility Dynamics Spectral Covariance Instability Test and Macroeconomic Volatility Dynamics Roberto Pancrazi Toulouse School of Economics Toulouse, France roberto.pancrazi@tse-fr.eu First Draft: 29 October 2009 This Draft:

More information

Identifying SVARs with Sign Restrictions and Heteroskedasticity

Identifying SVARs with Sign Restrictions and Heteroskedasticity Identifying SVARs with Sign Restrictions and Heteroskedasticity Srečko Zimic VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE NOT FOR DISTRIBUTION February 13, 217 Abstract This paper introduces a new method to identify

More information

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions Daniel Němec Faculty of Economics and Administrations Masaryk University Brno, Czech Republic nemecd@econ.muni.cz ESF MU (Brno)

More information

Evaluating Structural Vector Autoregression Models in Monetary Economies

Evaluating Structural Vector Autoregression Models in Monetary Economies Evaluating Structural Vector Autoregression Models in Monetary Economies Bin Li Research Department International Monetary Fund March 9 Abstract This paper uses Monte Carlo simulations to evaluate alternative

More information

An Improved Panel Unit Root Test Using GLS-Detrending

An Improved Panel Unit Root Test Using GLS-Detrending An Improved Panel Unit Root Test Using GLS-Detrending Claude Lopez 1 University of Cincinnati August 2004 This paper o ers a panel extension of the unit root test proposed by Elliott, Rothenberg and Stock

More information