LECTURE 11 A MODEL OF LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "LECTURE 11 A MODEL OF LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE"

Transcription

1 LECTURE 11 A MODEL OF LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE JACOB T. SCHWARTZ EDITED BY KENNETH R. DRIESSEL Abstract. We construct a model of production and exchange within which a decision to expand or to reduce inventories can be studied as an optimization problem. We find that optimum adjustment to the conditions of the constructed model may lead to decisions to reduce inventory in the manner assumed in the preceding lectures. 1. Establishing the Model A key element in the cycle-theory presented in Lectures 5 10 was the decision to reduce inventories which we built into our models, basing ourselves on reasonable empirical grounds, but which we left largely unanalyzed. When manufacturers reduce inventories they free resources for other uses: how does this affect the conclusions developed in the preceding lectures? In the present lecture and in the one which follows, we shall attempt to illuminate this question. Our method will be to construct a model of production and exchange within which a decision to expand or to reduce inventories can be studied as a problem of the optimization type familiar from efficiency economics. We will find that optimum adjustment to the conditions of the model to be constructed may lead to decisions to reduce inventory in the manner assumed in the preceding lectures. In this way, we will confirm our earlier conclusions and establish them upon a more ample basis. Our model is as follows: we take, as usual, an economy involving n material commodities C 1,, C n, and L + 1 labor commodities 2010 Mathematics Subject Classification. Primary 91B55; Secondary 91B08. Key words and phrases. Liquidity Preference, Business Cycle Theory. 1

2 2 JACOB T. SCHWARTZ C 0,, C L. Again, as usual, we take the input-output matrix to be π i,j, where 1 i n and L j n. In addition, we introduce a money commodity C n+1 which cannot be produced; this money commodity is taken to consist of a collection of identical, infinitely divisible, legal-tender bonds issued by a central authority and bearing interest, at a rate 100s per cent per day or planning period, payable in additional bonds. Thus, the possessor of x bonds will at the end of one day s uninterrupted possession be awarded sx additional bonds. We shall assume that s 0. Let the (instantaneous) price of one unit of commodity C k be p k ; we assume that all prices are positive. Revising our otherwise arbitrary physical units of each commodity, we may suppose that p j = 1 for all j; these price units will be used throughout the present lecture unless the contrary is explicitly indicated. With this normalization, the essential features of the present model may be described as follows. Each individual entrepreneur is assumed to be in possession, at the start of a typical day, of holdings of the commodities C 1,, C n+1 in certain amounts b 1,, b n+1. This being his situation, the entrepreneur is assumed to have the option of dividing his holding of bonds into n + 1 parts, using the jth part, 1 j n, for the purchase of the inputs to the production of C j in appropriate proportions and then immediately using these inputs completely, thereby producing a certain well determined number of units of C j. The (n + 1)st part into which the entrepreneur s holding of bonds is divided is assumed to be retained in order to earn interest at the given rate s. Moreover, the entrepreneur is assumed to have the additional option of dividing his holding of each sort of commodity into two parts, one of which is retained in storage, the other of which is offered for sale. We assume that conditions in the C j -market are such that of each unit of C j offered for sale, σ j units of C j will be sold, and 1 σ j units will remain unsold; thus σ j is a parameter between 0 and 1 which measures the instantaneous state of the market for the commodity C j, as reflected in the rate of stock turnover which an optional sales policy is capable of achieving. In order to take account within our model of style

3 11. A MODEL OF LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE 3 obsolescence and technical obsolescence, spoilage, and fixed overhead costs, we assume that each unit of C j which is either retained or unsold decays after one day to a certain number τ j of units; here 0 τ j < 1. The coefficient τ j then is a general spoilage and carrying charge loss parameter. Let the number of units of commodity C j which can be produced by expending one bond on the necessary inputs in correct proportion and using them to produce C j be η j ; η j is of course determined not merely by the input-output matrix but also by the prices; we have 0 < η j. Then, starting with holdings of C 1,, C n+1 equal to the components of the vector b = [b 1,, b n+1 ], and dividing it in accordance with the above-described options into a sum of nonnegative terms (11.1) b = [b 11 + b 12, b 21 + b 22,, b n1 + b n2, b n+1,1 + + b n+1,n+1 ], the entrepreneur will upon exercise of these options find himself at the end of the day in possession of inventories of C 1,, C n+1 equal to the components of the following vector c: (11.2) c = [τ 1 b 11 + τ 1 (1 σ 1 )b 12 + η 1 b n+1,1, τ 2 b 21 + τ 2 (1 σ 2 )b 22 + η 2 b n+1,2,, τ n b n1 + τ n (1 σ n )b n2 + η n b n+1,n, σ 1 b 12 + σ 2 b σ n b n2 + (1 + s)b n+1,n+1 ]. Let φ(b) denote the set of all vectors c which can be derived from a given vector b after the fashion of (11.1) (11.2); then φ is a (one-tomany, i.e., many-valued) transformation defined in the positive orthant. Of course, φ depends upon the constants σ j reflecting the instantaneous state of the market for C j and upon the instantaneous prices p j ; were we at the present moment aiming at the direct integration of the transformation φ into a dynamic model of prices and production, we would have to deal at once with this dependence. Our idea, however, is somewhat different. We wish to analyze an entrepreneur s projection of his future operations, assuming, as in the cycle-theory of Lectures 5, 6, and 7, that these projections are based upon the simplest of

4 4 JACOB T. SCHWARTZ all hypotheses, the hypothesis that market conditions will remain unchanged. In a more complete model the specific action taken by an entrepreneur on any particular day would still be determined by this projection, but the projection would be revised each day as the actual motion of the economy changes the data upon which the entrepreneur bases his projections. We may consider, however, that the phenomena of cyclic expansion and contraction of production which would occur in such a dynamic model have been portrayed with at least qualitative fidelity in Lectures 7 and 10. Thus, in the present lecture, we forego the dynamic problem in order to develop a detailed still photograph of instantaneous market conditions and of the instantaneous optimal adjustment to the conditions which may correspond either to a decision to increase or to reduce inventories. The parameters σ, τ, s of (11.2) should then be taken as descriptive of a given state of business which entrepreneurs expect to persist for a period of time sufficiently long so as to compel them to make at least a temporary adjustment. What we wish to find is this adjustment. For the present, then, it is appropriate for us to take the constants σ j and η j as fixed, and hence to study the iterates of the fixed multivalued transformation φ. We will show in what follows that this study leads in a natural manner to a systematic ranking of inventory positions as more or less favorable. It is then heuristically plausible to suppose that a manufacturer always strives to attain the most favorable position in the sense of this ranking; this assumption enables us to discover his optimal action in the given situation. The analysis leads by a technically complicated path to very simple conclusions; the reader may prefer to read the main statements and preliminary definitions which are to follow immediately, and to ignore the technical mathematics of their proof. 2. Basic Lemmas and Definitions, Statement of Main Results Let b = [b 1,, b n+1 ] be a vector (necessarily of dimension n + 1) describing the inventory holdings of an entrepreneur. It is plain that

5 11. A MODEL OF LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE 5 if b 1 b, the holdings b 1 are definitely preferable to the holdings b. This ordering of vectors is, however, only a partial ordering, in the sense that there exist noncomparable pairs of vectors, i.e., pairs of vectors b 1, b 2 for which both assertions b 1 b 2 and b 2 b 1 are false. We will show in what follows how a linear ordering may be derived from the ordering and the mapping φ, i.e., we will show how to derive a transitive relationship b 1 b 2 such that one of the two alternatives b 1 b 2 or b 2 b 1 necessarily holds for each pair of vectors b 1, b 2. In order to be able to describe this construction, we must first give some preliminary definitions and lemmas. We begin by extending the ordering of vectors to sets of vectors. Definition Let E and F be two sets of vectors. Then we will write E F if for each b 1 F, there exists a b 2 E such that b 2 b 1. The statement E F has then the following heuristic significance: the set of options E is preferable to the set of options F. Next we give a more convenient form to the definition (11.1) (11.2) of the mapping φ. It is evident, in the first place, that the set of vectors c in (11.2) is identical with the set of vectors d such that (11.3) d = [τ 1 (1 σ 1 )b 11 + τ 1 (b 12 + b b 1,n+1 ) + η 1 b n+1,1, τ 2 (1 σ 2 )b 22 + τ 2 (b 21 + b b 2,n+1 ) + η 2 b n+1,2,, τ n (1 σ n )b nn + τ n (b n1 + + b n,n 1 + b n,n+1 ) + η n b n+1,n, σ 1 b 11 + σ 2 b σ n b nn + (1 + s)b n+1,n+1 ] where (11.4) b = [b 11 + b b 1,n+1,b 21 + b b 2,n+1,, b n+1,1 + b n+1,2 + + b n+1,n+1 ],

6 6 JACOB T. SCHWARTZ each of the terms b ij being nonnegative. Thus, if we define (n + 1) (n + 1) matrices M 1,, M n and M n+1 by the equations (11.5) (M k ) i,j = τ j δ ij if 1 i, j n and i, j k; (M k ) i,j = 0 in every other case 1 i, j n + 1 unless (i, j) = (k, n + 1), (n + 1, k), or (k, k); (M k ) k,n+1 = η k ; (M k ) k,k = τ k (1 σ k ); (M k ) n+1,k = σ k ; and (11.6) (M n+1 ) i,j = τ j δ ij, j = 1,, n, i = 1,, n + 1; (M n+1 ) i,n+1 = (1 + s)δ i,n+1, i = 1,, n + 1; we may describe the set φ(b) as follows: (11.7) φ(b) = {d d = M 1 r M n+1 r n+1, r r n+1 = b, r j 0, j = 1,, n + 1}. We will also make use of certain standard set-theoretical notions and notations. If E and F are sets of vectors, we write E F or F E if E is included in F ; we write a E if a is a member of the set E, write φ(e) for the set (11.8) φ(e) = {φ(b) b E}, and write E + F and te for the sets (11.9) E + F = {b 1 + b 2 b 1 E, b 2 F } and (11.10) te = {tb b E}, respectively. The union of E and F will be denoted by E F ; more generally, if {E α } is an arbitrary collection of sets, indexed by an index α, then the union of all the sets E α, i.e., the collection of all elements which lie in at least one of the sets E α, will be written α E α. The following rather trivial lemmas will be quite useful. Lemma Let E F. Then φ(e) φ(f ).

7 11. A MODEL OF LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE 7 Proof: Let c φ(f ), so that there exist r 1,, r n+1 0 such that (11.11) r r n+1 F, M 1 r M n+1 r n+1 = c. Then, since E F, there exists, by Definition 1, a vector b E such that b r r n+1. Put q n+1 = b r 1 r n. Then plainly q n+1 0, r r n + q n+1 = b E, and d = M 1 r M n r n + M n+1 q n+1 c. Since d φ(e), our lemma is proved. Q.E.D. Lemma Let t 0 be a number. Then φ(te) = tφ(e). Proof: Obvious. Q.E.D. We may now make our fundamental definition. Definition Let b and c be two nonnegative vectors. Then we write b c (or c b) if for each ɛ > 0 there exists an n = n(ɛ) such that (1 + ɛ)φ n (b) φ n (c). If both b c and c b are true, we write b c. If b c but b c is false, we write b c. Note that, by Lemmas 2 and 3, the inequality (1 + ɛ)φ n (b) φ n (c) implies that (1 + ɛ)φ m (b) φ m (c) for all m n. In particular, b c implies b c. The relationship b c has the following heuristic significance. The set φ(b) is the collection of all inventory-positions attainable after the lapse of one day by an entrepreneur whose initial holdings are b; similarly, φ n (b) is the collection of all inventory-positions attainable after the lapse of n days by an entrepreneur whose initial holdings are b. Thus b c signifies that the inventory-position b is preferable to the inventory-position c in the sense that after the lapse of a certain number of days any position which could have been attained starting with c could have been bettered by a position attainable with the start b (at any rate, if c is diminished by any arbitrarily small percentage ɛ). Thus, any long-term inventory target attainable from c can be bettered if one s start is b. Hence, b c means that b is preferable to c in the long run. It is heuristically plain that the relationship b c is transitive. The following lemma states this simple fact formally.

8 8 JACOB T. SCHWARTZ Lemma If b c and c d, then b d. Proof: By hypothesis, and by Definition 4 and the remark which follows it, there exists a finite number n(ɛ) such that n n(ɛ) implies that (1 + ɛ)φ n (b) φ n (c) and (1 + ɛ)φ n (c) φ n (d). Thus (1 + ɛ) 2 φ n (b) φ n (d) for n n(ɛ). Q.E.D. Corollary. The relationship b c is reflexive, transitive, and symmetric. If b c, then b d and c d are equivalent. Lemma 5 shows that the relationship b c establishes an ordering between vectors; the central fact which we now wish to establish is that this ordering is a linear ordering, i.e., that it enables us to compare any two nonnegative vectors with the result that exactly one of b c, b c, c b holds in every case. Heuristically, this means that of two inventory positions b and c, either one is distinctly better (in the heuristic sense explained above) or both are equally good. This fact and somewhat more are stated in the following main theorem. Theorem There exists a positive vector v 0 such that the statement b c is equivalent to the statement v 0 b v 0 c. Thus, for any pair b and c of nonnegative vectors, exactly one of the statements b c, b c, c b is true. The proof of Theorem 6 will be given in what is to follow. Theorem 6 may be taken as establishing the existence of an exhaustive ranking of inventory positions as more or less favorable. Making the heuristically plausible assumption that an entrepreneur always strives to attain the most favorable position open to him, we arrive at a description of his optimal plan. Formal statements and results are contained in the following definition and in Theorem 9 below. Definition A sequence of vectors b 1, b 2, is an optimal path beginning at b if and only if b 1 = b; b n+1 φ n (b), n 1, and b n φ n (b) for arbitrarily large integers n. Our second main result will characterize the set of all optimal paths beginning at b. In order to do this, we need a number of preliminary

9 11. A MODEL OF LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE 9 definitions. The following definition extends the definition of dom(a) to arbitrary matrices. Definition 11.8a. Let A be a matrix. Then dom(a) is the maximum of the absolute value of all the (real or complex) eigenvalues of A. Definition 11.8b. Let M 1 M n+1 be the matrices of (11.5) (11.6). Then the optimal matrices are those M j for which the quantity dom(m j ) attains the value K = max 1 i n+1 dom(m i ). We may now state the second main result. Theorem The sequence of vectors b 1, b 2, is an optimal path beginning at b if and only if b 1 = b and b k+1 has the form (11.12) b k+1 = M 1 r M n+1 r n+1 where (11.13) r j 0, j = 1,, n + 1; r r n+1 = b k and where in addition we require that all components of r j but the jth and (n + 1)st vanish if M j is optimal, all components of r j but the jth vanish if M j is nonoptimal, and r n+1 = 0 if M n+1 is nonoptimal. Corollary. Any finite sequence b 1,, b m satisfying the conditions of the previous theorem for k + 1 m may be extended to an optimal sequence. If we examine the definition of the matrices M j as given by formulae (11.5) (11.6) in the light of Theorem 9, making use of the fact that b c means that b is bound to be preferable to c in the long run, we recognize the heuristic significance of Theorem 9 to be as follows: the only sound procedure for an entrepreneur whose holdings are b is to (1 ) offer the whole of each of his commodity stocks for sale; (2 ) use the whole of his cash holdings for the expansion of those stocks whose sale yields the greatest rate of profit; here, the money commodity C n+1 is to be considered as yielding the rate of profit s.

10 10 JACOB T. SCHWARTZ Theorem 9 then merely states a principle of investment practice so familiar as to be cliché. What is somewhat new is the derivation of this principle from the rather general definition of preference given by Definitions 1 and 4. We should emphasize that in (2 ) of the preceding paragraph, the rate of profit yielded by sale of a commodity C j is to be defined as the dominant of the 2 2 matrix [ ] 0 η j (11.14). σ j τ j (1 σ j ) The dominant is the unique positive root of the equation (11.15) λ 2 j λ j τ j (1 σ j ) σ j η j = 0; from this it is plain that λ increases with η and τ. Moreover, if η 1, then since η 2 ητ(1 σ) ση η(1 τ(1 σ) σ) > 0, we have λ < η: similarly λ > τ(1 σ) and hence (11.16) λ/ σ = (η λτ)/(2λ τ(1 σ)) > 0. Thus if η 1, λ increases with σ also. If σ = 0 then λ = τ; hence, as σ 0, λ τ. Consequently, Theorem 9 tells us that if (heuristically speaking) the stocks in every line of industry are sufficiently large so that each parameter σ j is distinctly reduced from 1, and if in addition the rate τ 1 j of obsolescence in each line of industry is sufficiently large so that the eigenvalues λ j of (11.15) are all less than (1 + s), the only prudent action may be to sell off stocks and hold the bond-money commodity C n+1 ; this can be the case even if the rate s of interest is zero, provided that the rates τ 1 j of obsolescence are sufficiently high. Theorem 9 thus gives a basis in efficiency economics to the decision to reduce stocks which played an important but unanalyzed role in the theory of Lectures We now intend to give the proof of Theorems 6 and 9; unfortunately, the proof involves a surprising mass of technical detail. We shall begin

11 11. A MODEL OF LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE 11 the proof in the present lecture, but shall only be able to conclude it in the following lecture. 3. Proof of Theorem 6. Initial Part In proving Theorem 6, we shall have use for some results from the theory of convex sets, which we shall now state, referring the reader to the monograph of Bonessen-Fenchel, Konvexe Körper, for proofs. The condition that a set E be convex may be written as te + (1 t)e E, 0 t 1. Let us recall that the closure of a set E of vectors is the set of all vectors b such that b is the limit of a sequence of vectors b n in E. The closure of an arbitrary set is easily seen to be a closed set. Lemma Let E and F be convex sets. Then (a) te is convex for each t 0 (b) E + F is convex (c) the closure of E is convex (d) if {E n } is a sequence of convex sets, and E n E n+1 for all n, then n E n is a convex set. Proof: For (a) and (b), see Bonessen-Fenchel, pp. 29 and 30; for (c) note that if b and c are in the closure of E, then b = lim n b n and c = lim n c n, where b n and c n belong to E. Thus, if 0 t 1, we have tb + (1 t)c = lim n (tb n + (1 t)c n ). Since E is convex, tb n + (1 t)c n lies in E, and hence tb + (1 t)c lies in the closure of E. This proves (c). To prove (d), note that if b n E n and c n E n, then, since E n E n+1 there exists an integer m such that b E m and c E m. Thus, if 0 t 1, tb + (1 t)c E m n E n. Q.E.D. sets. The following is a useful definition of convergence for closed convex

12 12 JACOB T. SCHWARTZ Definition Let K n, n 1, and K be closed convex sets. Then we write lim n K n = K or K n K, and say that the sequence K n approaches K, if for each ɛ > 0 there exists an n(ɛ) such that for all n n(ɛ) we have (11.17) K n K + S ɛ and K n + S ɛ K, S ɛ denoting the sphere of radius ɛ. Lemma Let K n, K, E n, E (n 1) be bounded closed convex sets. Then if K n K and E n E, it follows that tk n tk for all real t 0, and that K n + E n K + E. For a proof, see Bonessen-Fenchel, p. 35. Lemma Let E n, n 1, be a sequence of bounded closed convex sets such that E n E n+1. Then, if n E n is bounded, and if E denotes the closure of n E n, we have E n E. Proof: Note first that it follows from Lemma 10 that the set E is convex (and, of course, closed and bounded). Since E n E for all n, we have only to prove that for each ɛ there exists an n sufficiently large so that E E n +S ɛ. If this is false, then for each n there exists a vector p n E whose minimum distance from the set E n exceeds ɛ. Since E is bounded, we may find a subsequence p ni of p n which converges to a vector p; plainly, the minimum distance from p to E ni exceeds ɛ/2 for all sufficiently large i. Since E n+1 E n, it follows that E, which is the closure of n E n, is also the closure of i j E ni for each j no matter how large; thus the minimum distance from p to E is at least ɛ/2. But, since p is the limit of a sequence of vectors in E, this is impossible. Q.E.D. After these necessary generalities, we begin to build up the statements more directly required for the proof of Theorem 6, in a series of lemmas. Lemma The relationship defined in Definition 4 depends upon the matrices M 1,, M n+1, but remains invariant if M 1,, M n+1 are all multiplied by a common positive factor.

13 Proof: 11. A MODEL OF LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE 13 The first part of the statement is obvious from Definition 4 and the definition (11.7) of the map φ. Formula (11.7) also makes it plain that if M 1,, M n+1 are all multiplied by a common factor t, then the map φ is changed into tφ, and thus the set φ n (b) is changed into the set t n φ n (b). Definition 4. Q.E.D. The present lemma then follows at once from Lemma 14 shows that in proving Theorem 6 we may assume without loss of generality that max j dom(m j ) = 1. This will be assumed throughout the remainder of the present section. A certain subset of the matrices M j will have the distinguishing property dom(m j ) = 1; these are the matrices which are optimal in the sense of Definition 8. By renumbering the commodities C 1,, C n, we may suppose without loss of generality that set of optimal matrices is either the set M m,, M n or the set M m,, M n+1. By examining the form (11.5) of the matrices M j, remembering that the matrices M j initially introduced are first to be multiplied by a common positive factor t (1+s) 1, we see at once that if M j, j n, is an optimal matrix we have 1 = tτ j (1 σ j )+t 2 σ j η j ; if M j is not optimal, we have 1 > tτ j (1 σ j ) + t 2 σ j η j. Similarly, the matrix M n+1 is optimal if and only if (M n+1 ) n+1,n+1 = 1. The form (11.5) of the matrices M j also makes evident the following lemma. Lemma Each optimal matrix M j has a unique fixed vector u j. All components of this vector except the jth and (n + 1)st vanish. Next we use the form (11.5) of the matrices M j to prove Lemma (a) There exists a positive vector ω such that ω M j ω, j = 1,, n + 1. (b) For any vector b 0, the set φ n (b) remains bounded. Proof: Note first that (b) follows from (a). Indeed, if c φ(b), then, by the definition (11.7) of φ(b) and by (a), we have ω c ω b. By induction, this same inequality must hold for each α φ n (b), proving (b). To prove (a), we let ω n+1 = 1, and then define ω j for each j between 1 and n by requiring that (1, ω j ) be a dominant eigenvector of the transpose of the transformation [a, b] [tσ j b, tη j a + tτ j (1 σ j )b].

14 14 JACOB T. SCHWARTZ Since the constants τ k are all less than 1, it follows from the form (11.5) of the matrices M j that if [ω 1,, ω n, 1] = ω, we have ω M j ω. Q.E.D. Corollary. We have ω M j u < ω u for a nonnegative vector u unless M j is an optimal matrix and all components of u but the jth and (n + 1)st vanish. Proof: It is plain from our construction that if M j is nonoptimal ω M j < ω and that even if M j is optimal (ω M j ) k < (ω ) k unless k = j or n + 1. Q.E.D. Next we give a useful algebraic property of the mapping φ. Lemma Let E 1 and E 2 be two sets of nonnegative vectors. Then φ(e 1 ) + φ(e 2 ) = φ(e 1 + E 2 ). Proof: First suppose that r 1 φ(e 1 ), r 2 φ(e 2 ). Then, by the definition (11.7) of the map φ, we may find nonnegative vectors q 1,, q n+1 and q 1,, q n+1 such that (11.18) r 1 = M 1 q M n+1 q n+1 ; r 2 = M 1 q M n+1 q n+1, while q q n+1 E 1, q q n+1 E 2. Hence (q 1 + q 1) + + (q n+1 + q n+1) E 1 + E 2, while r 1 + r 2 = M 1 (q 1 + q 1) + + M n+1 (q n+1 + q n+1). This shows that φ(e 1 ) + φ(e 2 ) φ(e 1 + E 2 ). Conversely, let r φ(e 1 +E 2 ). Then there exist nonnegative vectors s 1,, s n+1 such that s s n+1 = e 1 + e 2, where e 1 E 1 and e 2 E 2, and such that r = M 1 s M n+1 s n+1. Define vectors q k

15 inductively by putting 11. A MODEL OF LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE 15 (11.19) (q q k ) j = min((s s k ) j, (e 1 ) j ), j = 1,, n + 1, k = 1,, n + 1. Then clearly q k 0, 1 k n + 1, and q q n+1 = e 1. It is also clear from (11.19) that, for k 2, (q k ) j = 0 unless (s s k ) j > (s s k 1 ) j, and that (s k ) j (q k ) j. Since by (11.19) this last inequality also holds for k = 1, we have (11.20) s k q k, k = 1,, n + 1. Let vectors q k be defined by q k = s k q k ; then it is clear from (11.20) that q k 0. We have (11.21) Thus and n+1 n+1 n+1 q k = s k q k = e 1 + e 2 e 1 = e 2. k=1 k=1 k=1 r 1 = M 1 q M n+1 q n+1 φ(e 1 ) r 2 = M 1 q M n+1 q n+1 φ(e 2 ). Since it is plain that r = r 1 + r 2, we have φ(e 1 + E 2 ) φ(e 1 ) + φ(e 2 ). Q.E.D. Lemma If E is convex, then φ(e) is convex. Proof: By the preceding lemma we have tφ(e) + (1 t)φ(e) = φ(te + (1 t)e) φ(e) for 0 t 1 since E is convex; thus φ(e) is convex. Q.E.D. We may now argue as follows. By Lemma 15, each optimal matrix M j has a unique fixed vector u j. The definition (11.7) of φ makes it plain that φ(u j ) M j u j = u j. Thus, inductively, φ n (u j ) φ n 1 (u j ). By the preceding lemma, all the sets φ n (u j ) are convex. By Lemmas 13 and 16(b), the sequence of sets φ n (u j ) converges to a bounded closed convex set K j ; K j is the closure of n φ n (u j ). The next lemma contributes

16 16 JACOB T. SCHWARTZ an essential bit of information by showing that all the sets K j substantially the same. are Lemma (a) If ω is the vector of Lemma 16, and the fixed vectors u j of the optimal matrices M j are normalized by the condition ω u j = 1, then all of the sets K j are identical. (b) φ(k j ) = K j. (c) The set K j contains the vector 0; thus tk j K j for 0 t 1. Proof: We first put the definition (11.7) of the mapping φ into a more convenient form. Let µ denote an arbitrary nonnegative (n+1) (n + 1) matrix whose entries µ ij satisfy the condition (11.22) n+1 µ ij = 1, i = 1,, n + 1. j=1 Let Σ j (µ), j = 1,, n + 1, be the mapping which takes a vector b into the vector Σ j (µ)b whose components are (11.23) [µ 1,j b 1,, µ n+1,j b n+1 ]. Then plainly n+1 j=1 Σ j(µ)b = b, and (11.7) shows that φ(b) may be written in the form (11.24) φ(b) = { n+1 } M j Σ j (µ)b. µ Thus, if we let j=1 n+1 (11.25) M(µ) = M j Σ j (µ), we have j=1 (11.26) φ(b) = µ M(µ)b. Since the mappings M(µ) are continuous, it follows from this last formula that M(µ)K j = M(µ) lim n φ n (u j ) lim n M(µ)φ n (u j ) lim n φ n+1 (u j ) K j ;

17 11. A MODEL OF LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE 17 thus M(µ)K j K j, and hence by (11.26) we have (11.27) φ(k j ) K j. Since u j φ(u j ) φ 2 (u j ) K j, it follows that u j K j, and thus φ(u j ) φ(k j ) and u j φ(k j ). Inductively from (11.27) we have φ n (K j ) K j ; thus φ n (u j ) φ n+1 (K j ) φ(k j ). Letting n in this last inclusion, it follows that K j φ(k j ). Combining this with (11.27), statement (b) of the present lemma follows. It is plain from the form (11.5) of the matrices M j that φ(u j ) includes a vector of the form [c 1,, c n, 0]. Thus φ n+1 (u j ) includes [τ n 1 c 1,, τ n n c n, 0]. Since τ j < 1, it follows on letting n that 0 K j, proving (c) of the present lemma. To prove (a) of the present lemma, we shall show that if M j and M k are optimal matrices and u j and u k the corresponding fixed vectors, then u j K k. Using (b) it will then follow that φ n (u j ) K k, and, letting n, that K j K k. Statement (a) will then follow at once by symmetry. If we renumber the commodities C m,, C n, we may suppose without loss of generality that k = n and j = n + 1 or j = n 1. We shall treat only the case j = n 1, leaving it to the reader to elaborate the very similar and somewhat simpler details of the case j = n + 1. Let ω be the vector of Lemma 16(a). If we examine the construction of the vector ω as described in the first paragraph of the proof of Lemma 16, and note the structure (11.5) of the matrices M j, we find that ω 0 = [0,, ω n, 1] is a fixed vector of M n, i.e., that ω 0M n = ω 0. Similarly, ω 00 = [0, 0,, ω n 1, 0, 1] is a fixed vector of M n 1. Thus, if u is a vector all of whose components except the nth and (n + 1)st vanish, we have ω M n u = ω 0M n u = ω 0 u = ω u. Similarly, if u is a vector all of whose components except the (n 1)st and (n + 1)st vanish, ω M n 1 u = ω u. Let M = M n 1 P 1 + M n P 2

18 18 JACOB T. SCHWARTZ where P 1 and P 2 are the projection operators defined by (11.28) P 1 [u 1,, u n+1 ] = [u 1,, u n 1, 0, 0] P 2 [u 1,, u n+1 ] = [0,, 0, u n, u n+1 ]. It is then clear from (11.7) that Mu φ(u) for each nonnegative vector u. Moreover, from what has been proved just above, ω Mu = ω u if all the components of u except the (n 1)st, nth, and (n + 1)st vanish. It follows from this, from (11.28) and from (11.5), and from the property of the vector u n 1 given by Lemma 15 that ω M m u n 1 = 1 for each m. According to (11.28) and the form (11.5) of the matrices M j, the (n 1)st component of M m u n 1 converges to zero, while the components 1 through n 2 are identically zero. A subsequence of this bounded sequence of vectors necessarily converges to some vector v; this vector v has all components but its nth and (n + 1)st equal to zero, while ω v = 1 and v lies in the closed convex set K n 1. Equation (11.15) for the eigenvalues of the 2 2 matrix (11.14) has clearly two distinct roots, one positive and one negative, the positive having the larger absolute value unless the square of the matrix is a constant. Since we have normalized our matrices M j in such a way that dom(m j ) = 1 if M j is an optimal matrix, it follows that (if M j is an optimal matrix) the corresponding matrix (11.14) has either the twoby-two identity matrix as its square, or has two eigenvalues of which one is +1 and the other is less than 1 in modulus. If x and y are the two eigenvectors of this 2 2 matrix, which we shall call N, x being the fixed vector, it follows in consequence that n 1 (11.29) lim n n 1 N k (αx + βy) = αx. k=0 Thus, inspecting the form (11.5) of the matrix M n, it follows that m 1 (11.30) lim n m 1 (M n ) k v exists, and is a fixed vector u of the matrix M n. Moreover, since we have as above that ω (M n ) k v = 1 for all k, it follows that ω u = 1. k=0

19 11. A MODEL OF LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE 19 Thus, since the fixed vector u n of M n is unique by Lemma 15 except for normalization, it follows that u = u n. Since we have shown above that v K n 1 and since φ(k n 1 ) = K n 1 by (b) while M n c φ(c) by (11.7), it follows from (11.30) that u n K n 1. As we have remarked above, this fact implies (a). Q.E.D. We pause at this point. The proof of Theorems 6 and 9 will be completed in the next lecture.

LECTURE 12 A MODEL OF LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE (CONCLUDED)

LECTURE 12 A MODEL OF LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE (CONCLUDED) LECTURE 12 A MODEL OF LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE (CONCLUDED) JACOB T. SCHWARTZ EDITED BY KENNETH R. DRIESSEL Abstract. We prove Theorem 11.6 and Theorem 11.9 of the previous lecture. 1. Proof of Theorem 11.6

More information

LECTURE 10 ADDITIONAL DISCUSSION OF CYCLE THEORY

LECTURE 10 ADDITIONAL DISCUSSION OF CYCLE THEORY LECTURE 10 ADDITIONAL DISCUSSION OF CYCLE THEORY In the present lecture, we shall present three theoretical fragments, two of which are intended to round out our study of the unstable cycletheory model

More information

LECTURE 15 PROOF OF THE EXISTENCE OF WALRASIAN EQUILIBRIUM

LECTURE 15 PROOF OF THE EXISTENCE OF WALRASIAN EQUILIBRIUM LECTURE 15 PROOF OF THE EXISTENCE OF WALRASIAN EQUILIBRIUM JACOB T. SCHWARTZ EDITED BY KENNETH R. DRIESSEL Abstract. We prove the existence of Walrasian equilibrium in a case of single labor sector and

More information

MATH 117 LECTURE NOTES

MATH 117 LECTURE NOTES MATH 117 LECTURE NOTES XIN ZHOU Abstract. This is the set of lecture notes for Math 117 during Fall quarter of 2017 at UC Santa Barbara. The lectures follow closely the textbook [1]. Contents 1. The set

More information

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM Discussion Papers in Economics Discussion Paper No. 0/06 CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY by Indraneel Dasgupta July 00 DP 0/06 ISSN 1360-438 UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM

More information

AN ELEMENTARY PROOF OF THE SPECTRAL RADIUS FORMULA FOR MATRICES

AN ELEMENTARY PROOF OF THE SPECTRAL RADIUS FORMULA FOR MATRICES AN ELEMENTARY PROOF OF THE SPECTRAL RADIUS FORMULA FOR MATRICES JOEL A. TROPP Abstract. We present an elementary proof that the spectral radius of a matrix A may be obtained using the formula ρ(a) lim

More information

CONSTRUCTION OF THE REAL NUMBERS.

CONSTRUCTION OF THE REAL NUMBERS. CONSTRUCTION OF THE REAL NUMBERS. IAN KIMING 1. Motivation. It will not come as a big surprise to anyone when I say that we need the real numbers in mathematics. More to the point, we need to be able to

More information

Notes on the Matrix-Tree theorem and Cayley s tree enumerator

Notes on the Matrix-Tree theorem and Cayley s tree enumerator Notes on the Matrix-Tree theorem and Cayley s tree enumerator 1 Cayley s tree enumerator Recall that the degree of a vertex in a tree (or in any graph) is the number of edges emanating from it We will

More information

3 Integration and Expectation

3 Integration and Expectation 3 Integration and Expectation 3.1 Construction of the Lebesgue Integral Let (, F, µ) be a measure space (not necessarily a probability space). Our objective will be to define the Lebesgue integral R fdµ

More information

Standard forms for writing numbers

Standard forms for writing numbers Standard forms for writing numbers In order to relate the abstract mathematical descriptions of familiar number systems to the everyday descriptions of numbers by decimal expansions and similar means,

More information

Introduction and Preliminaries

Introduction and Preliminaries Chapter 1 Introduction and Preliminaries This chapter serves two purposes. The first purpose is to prepare the readers for the more systematic development in later chapters of methods of real analysis

More information

µ (X) := inf l(i k ) where X k=1 I k, I k an open interval Notice that is a map from subsets of R to non-negative number together with infinity

µ (X) := inf l(i k ) where X k=1 I k, I k an open interval Notice that is a map from subsets of R to non-negative number together with infinity A crash course in Lebesgue measure theory, Math 317, Intro to Analysis II These lecture notes are inspired by the third edition of Royden s Real analysis. The Jordan content is an attempt to extend the

More information

THE CANTOR GAME: WINNING STRATEGIES AND DETERMINACY. by arxiv: v1 [math.ca] 29 Jan 2017 MAGNUS D. LADUE

THE CANTOR GAME: WINNING STRATEGIES AND DETERMINACY. by arxiv: v1 [math.ca] 29 Jan 2017 MAGNUS D. LADUE THE CANTOR GAME: WINNING STRATEGIES AND DETERMINACY by arxiv:170109087v1 [mathca] 9 Jan 017 MAGNUS D LADUE 0 Abstract In [1] Grossman Turett define the Cantor game In [] Matt Baker proves several results

More information

DS-GA 1002 Lecture notes 0 Fall Linear Algebra. These notes provide a review of basic concepts in linear algebra.

DS-GA 1002 Lecture notes 0 Fall Linear Algebra. These notes provide a review of basic concepts in linear algebra. DS-GA 1002 Lecture notes 0 Fall 2016 Linear Algebra These notes provide a review of basic concepts in linear algebra. 1 Vector spaces You are no doubt familiar with vectors in R 2 or R 3, i.e. [ ] 1.1

More information

CHAPTER 2: CONVEX SETS AND CONCAVE FUNCTIONS. W. Erwin Diewert January 31, 2008.

CHAPTER 2: CONVEX SETS AND CONCAVE FUNCTIONS. W. Erwin Diewert January 31, 2008. 1 ECONOMICS 594: LECTURE NOTES CHAPTER 2: CONVEX SETS AND CONCAVE FUNCTIONS W. Erwin Diewert January 31, 2008. 1. Introduction Many economic problems have the following structure: (i) a linear function

More information

Some Notes on Linear Algebra

Some Notes on Linear Algebra Some Notes on Linear Algebra prepared for a first course in differential equations Thomas L Scofield Department of Mathematics and Statistics Calvin College 1998 1 The purpose of these notes is to present

More information

M17 MAT25-21 HOMEWORK 6

M17 MAT25-21 HOMEWORK 6 M17 MAT25-21 HOMEWORK 6 DUE 10:00AM WEDNESDAY SEPTEMBER 13TH 1. To Hand In Double Series. The exercises in this section will guide you to complete the proof of the following theorem: Theorem 1: Absolute

More information

ELEMENTARY LINEAR ALGEBRA

ELEMENTARY LINEAR ALGEBRA ELEMENTARY LINEAR ALGEBRA K. R. MATTHEWS DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS UNIVERSITY OF QUEENSLAND Second Online Version, December 1998 Comments to the author at krm@maths.uq.edu.au Contents 1 LINEAR EQUATIONS

More information

Introduction to Real Analysis Alternative Chapter 1

Introduction to Real Analysis Alternative Chapter 1 Christopher Heil Introduction to Real Analysis Alternative Chapter 1 A Primer on Norms and Banach Spaces Last Updated: March 10, 2018 c 2018 by Christopher Heil Chapter 1 A Primer on Norms and Banach Spaces

More information

LECTURE 10: REVIEW OF POWER SERIES. 1. Motivation

LECTURE 10: REVIEW OF POWER SERIES. 1. Motivation LECTURE 10: REVIEW OF POWER SERIES By definition, a power series centered at x 0 is a series of the form where a 0, a 1,... and x 0 are constants. For convenience, we shall mostly be concerned with the

More information

ELEMENTARY LINEAR ALGEBRA

ELEMENTARY LINEAR ALGEBRA ELEMENTARY LINEAR ALGEBRA K R MATTHEWS DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS UNIVERSITY OF QUEENSLAND First Printing, 99 Chapter LINEAR EQUATIONS Introduction to linear equations A linear equation in n unknowns x,

More information

NORMS ON SPACE OF MATRICES

NORMS ON SPACE OF MATRICES NORMS ON SPACE OF MATRICES. Operator Norms on Space of linear maps Let A be an n n real matrix and x 0 be a vector in R n. We would like to use the Picard iteration method to solve for the following system

More information

Chapter Four Gelfond s Solution of Hilbert s Seventh Problem (Revised January 2, 2011)

Chapter Four Gelfond s Solution of Hilbert s Seventh Problem (Revised January 2, 2011) Chapter Four Gelfond s Solution of Hilbert s Seventh Problem (Revised January 2, 2011) Before we consider Gelfond s, and then Schneider s, complete solutions to Hilbert s seventh problem let s look back

More information

DR.RUPNATHJI( DR.RUPAK NATH )

DR.RUPNATHJI( DR.RUPAK NATH ) Contents 1 Sets 1 2 The Real Numbers 9 3 Sequences 29 4 Series 59 5 Functions 81 6 Power Series 105 7 The elementary functions 111 Chapter 1 Sets It is very convenient to introduce some notation and terminology

More information

a 11 x 1 + a 12 x a 1n x n = b 1 a 21 x 1 + a 22 x a 2n x n = b 2.

a 11 x 1 + a 12 x a 1n x n = b 1 a 21 x 1 + a 22 x a 2n x n = b 2. Chapter 1 LINEAR EQUATIONS 11 Introduction to linear equations A linear equation in n unknowns x 1, x,, x n is an equation of the form a 1 x 1 + a x + + a n x n = b, where a 1, a,, a n, b are given real

More information

Theorem 5.3. Let E/F, E = F (u), be a simple field extension. Then u is algebraic if and only if E/F is finite. In this case, [E : F ] = deg f u.

Theorem 5.3. Let E/F, E = F (u), be a simple field extension. Then u is algebraic if and only if E/F is finite. In this case, [E : F ] = deg f u. 5. Fields 5.1. Field extensions. Let F E be a subfield of the field E. We also describe this situation by saying that E is an extension field of F, and we write E/F to express this fact. If E/F is a field

More information

1 Simplex and Matrices

1 Simplex and Matrices 1 Simplex and Matrices We will begin with a review of matrix multiplication. A matrix is simply an array of numbers. If a given array has m rows and n columns, then it is called an m n (or m-by-n) matrix.

More information

2 Lecture 2: Logical statements and proof by contradiction Lecture 10: More on Permutations, Group Homomorphisms 31

2 Lecture 2: Logical statements and proof by contradiction Lecture 10: More on Permutations, Group Homomorphisms 31 Contents 1 Lecture 1: Introduction 2 2 Lecture 2: Logical statements and proof by contradiction 7 3 Lecture 3: Induction and Well-Ordering Principle 11 4 Lecture 4: Definition of a Group and examples 15

More information

Putzer s Algorithm. Norman Lebovitz. September 8, 2016

Putzer s Algorithm. Norman Lebovitz. September 8, 2016 Putzer s Algorithm Norman Lebovitz September 8, 2016 1 Putzer s algorithm The differential equation dx = Ax, (1) dt where A is an n n matrix of constants, possesses the fundamental matrix solution exp(at),

More information

Jónsson posets and unary Jónsson algebras

Jónsson posets and unary Jónsson algebras Jónsson posets and unary Jónsson algebras Keith A. Kearnes and Greg Oman Abstract. We show that if P is an infinite poset whose proper order ideals have cardinality strictly less than P, and κ is a cardinal

More information

MA103 Introduction to Abstract Mathematics Second part, Analysis and Algebra

MA103 Introduction to Abstract Mathematics Second part, Analysis and Algebra 206/7 MA03 Introduction to Abstract Mathematics Second part, Analysis and Algebra Amol Sasane Revised by Jozef Skokan, Konrad Swanepoel, and Graham Brightwell Copyright c London School of Economics 206

More information

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs Lecture Notes by Walter Schachermayer Nachdiplom-Vorlesung, ETH Zürich, WS 15/16 1 Models on Finite Probability Spaces In this section we consider a stock price

More information

8.5 Taylor Polynomials and Taylor Series

8.5 Taylor Polynomials and Taylor Series 8.5. TAYLOR POLYNOMIALS AND TAYLOR SERIES 50 8.5 Taylor Polynomials and Taylor Series Motivating Questions In this section, we strive to understand the ideas generated by the following important questions:

More information

Operations On Networks Of Discrete And Generalized Conductors

Operations On Networks Of Discrete And Generalized Conductors Operations On Networks Of Discrete And Generalized Conductors Kevin Rosema e-mail: bigyouth@hardy.u.washington.edu 8/18/92 1 Introduction The most basic unit of transaction will be the discrete conductor.

More information

MTH Linear Algebra. Study Guide. Dr. Tony Yee Department of Mathematics and Information Technology The Hong Kong Institute of Education

MTH Linear Algebra. Study Guide. Dr. Tony Yee Department of Mathematics and Information Technology The Hong Kong Institute of Education MTH 3 Linear Algebra Study Guide Dr. Tony Yee Department of Mathematics and Information Technology The Hong Kong Institute of Education June 3, ii Contents Table of Contents iii Matrix Algebra. Real Life

More information

ON COST MATRICES WITH TWO AND THREE DISTINCT VALUES OF HAMILTONIAN PATHS AND CYCLES

ON COST MATRICES WITH TWO AND THREE DISTINCT VALUES OF HAMILTONIAN PATHS AND CYCLES ON COST MATRICES WITH TWO AND THREE DISTINCT VALUES OF HAMILTONIAN PATHS AND CYCLES SANTOSH N. KABADI AND ABRAHAM P. PUNNEN Abstract. Polynomially testable characterization of cost matrices associated

More information

Boolean Algebras. Chapter 2

Boolean Algebras. Chapter 2 Chapter 2 Boolean Algebras Let X be an arbitrary set and let P(X) be the class of all subsets of X (the power set of X). Three natural set-theoretic operations on P(X) are the binary operations of union

More information

MTH 2032 Semester II

MTH 2032 Semester II MTH 232 Semester II 2-2 Linear Algebra Reference Notes Dr. Tony Yee Department of Mathematics and Information Technology The Hong Kong Institute of Education December 28, 2 ii Contents Table of Contents

More information

At the start of the term, we saw the following formula for computing the sum of the first n integers:

At the start of the term, we saw the following formula for computing the sum of the first n integers: Chapter 11 Induction This chapter covers mathematical induction. 11.1 Introduction to induction At the start of the term, we saw the following formula for computing the sum of the first n integers: Claim

More information

Chapter 1. Measure Spaces. 1.1 Algebras and σ algebras of sets Notation and preliminaries

Chapter 1. Measure Spaces. 1.1 Algebras and σ algebras of sets Notation and preliminaries Chapter 1 Measure Spaces 1.1 Algebras and σ algebras of sets 1.1.1 Notation and preliminaries We shall denote by X a nonempty set, by P(X) the set of all parts (i.e., subsets) of X, and by the empty set.

More information

LECTURE 14 WALRASIAN EQUILIBRIUM IN THE CASE OF A SINGLE LABOR SECTOR

LECTURE 14 WALRASIAN EQUILIBRIUM IN THE CASE OF A SINGLE LABOR SECTOR LECTURE 14 WALRASIAN EQUILIBRIUM IN THE CASE OF A SINGLE LABOR SECTOR JACOB T. SCHWARTZ EDITED BY KENNETH R. DRIESSEL Abstract. We continue to develop the consequences of the definition of a price equilibrium

More information

FINITE ABELIAN GROUPS Amin Witno

FINITE ABELIAN GROUPS Amin Witno WON Series in Discrete Mathematics and Modern Algebra Volume 7 FINITE ABELIAN GROUPS Amin Witno Abstract We detail the proof of the fundamental theorem of finite abelian groups, which states that every

More information

A Multiplicative Operation on Matrices with Entries in an Arbitrary Abelian Group

A Multiplicative Operation on Matrices with Entries in an Arbitrary Abelian Group A Multiplicative Operation on Matrices with Entries in an Arbitrary Abelian Group Cyrus Hettle (cyrus.h@uky.edu) Robert P. Schneider (robert.schneider@uky.edu) University of Kentucky Abstract We define

More information

MATH 102 INTRODUCTION TO MATHEMATICAL ANALYSIS. 1. Some Fundamentals

MATH 102 INTRODUCTION TO MATHEMATICAL ANALYSIS. 1. Some Fundamentals MATH 02 INTRODUCTION TO MATHEMATICAL ANALYSIS Properties of Real Numbers Some Fundamentals The whole course will be based entirely on the study of sequence of numbers and functions defined on the real

More information

Stanford Mathematics Department Math 205A Lecture Supplement #4 Borel Regular & Radon Measures

Stanford Mathematics Department Math 205A Lecture Supplement #4 Borel Regular & Radon Measures 2 1 Borel Regular Measures We now state and prove an important regularity property of Borel regular outer measures: Stanford Mathematics Department Math 205A Lecture Supplement #4 Borel Regular & Radon

More information

Existence and Uniqueness

Existence and Uniqueness Chapter 3 Existence and Uniqueness An intellect which at a certain moment would know all forces that set nature in motion, and all positions of all items of which nature is composed, if this intellect

More information

Lecture Summaries for Linear Algebra M51A

Lecture Summaries for Linear Algebra M51A These lecture summaries may also be viewed online by clicking the L icon at the top right of any lecture screen. Lecture Summaries for Linear Algebra M51A refers to the section in the textbook. Lecture

More information

Constructions with ruler and compass.

Constructions with ruler and compass. Constructions with ruler and compass. Semyon Alesker. 1 Introduction. Let us assume that we have a ruler and a compass. Let us also assume that we have a segment of length one. Using these tools we can

More information

Chapter 2: Matrix Algebra

Chapter 2: Matrix Algebra Chapter 2: Matrix Algebra (Last Updated: October 12, 2016) These notes are derived primarily from Linear Algebra and its applications by David Lay (4ed). Write A = 1. Matrix operations [a 1 a n. Then entry

More information

Convex Optimization Notes

Convex Optimization Notes Convex Optimization Notes Jonathan Siegel January 2017 1 Convex Analysis This section is devoted to the study of convex functions f : B R {+ } and convex sets U B, for B a Banach space. The case of B =

More information

MATRIX ALGEBRA AND SYSTEMS OF EQUATIONS. + + x 1 x 2. x n 8 (4) 3 4 2

MATRIX ALGEBRA AND SYSTEMS OF EQUATIONS. + + x 1 x 2. x n 8 (4) 3 4 2 MATRIX ALGEBRA AND SYSTEMS OF EQUATIONS SYSTEMS OF EQUATIONS AND MATRICES Representation of a linear system The general system of m equations in n unknowns can be written a x + a 2 x 2 + + a n x n b a

More information

Math 121 Homework 5: Notes on Selected Problems

Math 121 Homework 5: Notes on Selected Problems Math 121 Homework 5: Notes on Selected Problems 12.1.2. Let M be a module over the integral domain R. (a) Assume that M has rank n and that x 1,..., x n is any maximal set of linearly independent elements

More information

Elementary Linear Algebra, Second Edition, by Spence, Insel, and Friedberg. ISBN Pearson Education, Inc., Upper Saddle River, NJ.

Elementary Linear Algebra, Second Edition, by Spence, Insel, and Friedberg. ISBN Pearson Education, Inc., Upper Saddle River, NJ. 2008 Pearson Education, Inc., Upper Saddle River, NJ. All rights reserved. APPENDIX: Mathematical Proof There are many mathematical statements whose truth is not obvious. For example, the French mathematician

More information

Measures. 1 Introduction. These preliminary lecture notes are partly based on textbooks by Athreya and Lahiri, Capinski and Kopp, and Folland.

Measures. 1 Introduction. These preliminary lecture notes are partly based on textbooks by Athreya and Lahiri, Capinski and Kopp, and Folland. Measures These preliminary lecture notes are partly based on textbooks by Athreya and Lahiri, Capinski and Kopp, and Folland. 1 Introduction Our motivation for studying measure theory is to lay a foundation

More information

4.6 Bases and Dimension

4.6 Bases and Dimension 46 Bases and Dimension 281 40 (a) Show that {1,x,x 2,x 3 } is linearly independent on every interval (b) If f k (x) = x k for k = 0, 1,,n, show that {f 0,f 1,,f n } is linearly independent on every interval

More information

1 Matrices and Systems of Linear Equations. a 1n a 2n

1 Matrices and Systems of Linear Equations. a 1n a 2n March 31, 2013 16-1 16. Systems of Linear Equations 1 Matrices and Systems of Linear Equations An m n matrix is an array A = (a ij ) of the form a 11 a 21 a m1 a 1n a 2n... a mn where each a ij is a real

More information

Metric Spaces and Topology

Metric Spaces and Topology Chapter 2 Metric Spaces and Topology From an engineering perspective, the most important way to construct a topology on a set is to define the topology in terms of a metric on the set. This approach underlies

More information

Lecture 9 Metric spaces. The contraction fixed point theorem. The implicit function theorem. The existence of solutions to differenti. equations.

Lecture 9 Metric spaces. The contraction fixed point theorem. The implicit function theorem. The existence of solutions to differenti. equations. Lecture 9 Metric spaces. The contraction fixed point theorem. The implicit function theorem. The existence of solutions to differential equations. 1 Metric spaces 2 Completeness and completion. 3 The contraction

More information

In particular, if A is a square matrix and λ is one of its eigenvalues, then we can find a non-zero column vector X with

In particular, if A is a square matrix and λ is one of its eigenvalues, then we can find a non-zero column vector X with Appendix: Matrix Estimates and the Perron-Frobenius Theorem. This Appendix will first present some well known estimates. For any m n matrix A = [a ij ] over the real or complex numbers, it will be convenient

More information

This operation is - associative A + (B + C) = (A + B) + C; - commutative A + B = B + A; - has a neutral element O + A = A, here O is the null matrix

This operation is - associative A + (B + C) = (A + B) + C; - commutative A + B = B + A; - has a neutral element O + A = A, here O is the null matrix 1 Matrix Algebra Reading [SB] 81-85, pp 153-180 11 Matrix Operations 1 Addition a 11 a 12 a 1n a 21 a 22 a 2n a m1 a m2 a mn + b 11 b 12 b 1n b 21 b 22 b 2n b m1 b m2 b mn a 11 + b 11 a 12 + b 12 a 1n

More information

The small ball property in Banach spaces (quantitative results)

The small ball property in Banach spaces (quantitative results) The small ball property in Banach spaces (quantitative results) Ehrhard Behrends Abstract A metric space (M, d) is said to have the small ball property (sbp) if for every ε 0 > 0 there exists a sequence

More information

Connectedness. Proposition 2.2. The following are equivalent for a topological space (X, T ).

Connectedness. Proposition 2.2. The following are equivalent for a topological space (X, T ). Connectedness 1 Motivation Connectedness is the sort of topological property that students love. Its definition is intuitive and easy to understand, and it is a powerful tool in proofs of well-known results.

More information

Lecture 7: More Arithmetic and Fun With Primes

Lecture 7: More Arithmetic and Fun With Primes IAS/PCMI Summer Session 2000 Clay Mathematics Undergraduate Program Advanced Course on Computational Complexity Lecture 7: More Arithmetic and Fun With Primes David Mix Barrington and Alexis Maciel July

More information

Lecture 4: Completion of a Metric Space

Lecture 4: Completion of a Metric Space 15 Lecture 4: Completion of a Metric Space Closure vs. Completeness. Recall the statement of Lemma??(b): A subspace M of a metric space X is closed if and only if every convergent sequence {x n } X satisfying

More information

w d : Y 0 (N) Y 0 (N)

w d : Y 0 (N) Y 0 (N) Upper half-plane formulas We want to explain the derivation of formulas for two types of objects on the upper half plane: the Atkin- Lehner involutions and Heegner points Both of these are treated somewhat

More information

Analysis II: The Implicit and Inverse Function Theorems

Analysis II: The Implicit and Inverse Function Theorems Analysis II: The Implicit and Inverse Function Theorems Jesse Ratzkin November 17, 2009 Let f : R n R m be C 1. When is the zero set Z = {x R n : f(x) = 0} the graph of another function? When is Z nicely

More information

Shih-sen Chang, Yeol Je Cho, and Haiyun Zhou

Shih-sen Chang, Yeol Je Cho, and Haiyun Zhou J. Korean Math. Soc. 38 (2001), No. 6, pp. 1245 1260 DEMI-CLOSED PRINCIPLE AND WEAK CONVERGENCE PROBLEMS FOR ASYMPTOTICALLY NONEXPANSIVE MAPPINGS Shih-sen Chang, Yeol Je Cho, and Haiyun Zhou Abstract.

More information

LECTURE 16 AN EQUILIBRIUM MODEL COMBINING NEOCLASSICAL AND KEYNESIAN FEATURES

LECTURE 16 AN EQUILIBRIUM MODEL COMBINING NEOCLASSICAL AND KEYNESIAN FEATURES LECTURE 16 AN EQUILIBRIUM MODEL COMBINING NEOCLASSICAL AND KEYNESIAN FEATURES JACOB T. SCHWARTZ EDITED BY KENNETH R. DRIESSEL Abstract. We construct a model which is a common generalization of the two

More information

Sequences. Chapter 3. n + 1 3n + 2 sin n n. 3. lim (ln(n + 1) ln n) 1. lim. 2. lim. 4. lim (1 + n)1/n. Answers: 1. 1/3; 2. 0; 3. 0; 4. 1.

Sequences. Chapter 3. n + 1 3n + 2 sin n n. 3. lim (ln(n + 1) ln n) 1. lim. 2. lim. 4. lim (1 + n)1/n. Answers: 1. 1/3; 2. 0; 3. 0; 4. 1. Chapter 3 Sequences Both the main elements of calculus (differentiation and integration) require the notion of a limit. Sequences will play a central role when we work with limits. Definition 3.. A Sequence

More information

CLASSICAL PROBABILITY MODES OF CONVERGENCE AND INEQUALITIES

CLASSICAL PROBABILITY MODES OF CONVERGENCE AND INEQUALITIES CLASSICAL PROBABILITY 2008 2. MODES OF CONVERGENCE AND INEQUALITIES JOHN MORIARTY In many interesting and important situations, the object of interest is influenced by many random factors. If we can construct

More information

What is A + B? What is A B? What is AB? What is BA? What is A 2? and B = QUESTION 2. What is the reduced row echelon matrix of A =

What is A + B? What is A B? What is AB? What is BA? What is A 2? and B = QUESTION 2. What is the reduced row echelon matrix of A = STUDENT S COMPANIONS IN BASIC MATH: THE ELEVENTH Matrix Reloaded by Block Buster Presumably you know the first part of matrix story, including its basic operations (addition and multiplication) and row

More information

Criteria for existence of semigroup homomorphisms and projective rank functions. George M. Bergman

Criteria for existence of semigroup homomorphisms and projective rank functions. George M. Bergman Criteria for existence of semigroup homomorphisms and projective rank functions George M. Bergman Suppose A, S, and T are semigroups, e: A S and f: A T semigroup homomorphisms, and X a generating set for

More information

Linear Algebra: Lecture Notes. Dr Rachel Quinlan School of Mathematics, Statistics and Applied Mathematics NUI Galway

Linear Algebra: Lecture Notes. Dr Rachel Quinlan School of Mathematics, Statistics and Applied Mathematics NUI Galway Linear Algebra: Lecture Notes Dr Rachel Quinlan School of Mathematics, Statistics and Applied Mathematics NUI Galway November 6, 23 Contents Systems of Linear Equations 2 Introduction 2 2 Elementary Row

More information

Page 52. Lecture 3: Inner Product Spaces Dual Spaces, Dirac Notation, and Adjoints Date Revised: 2008/10/03 Date Given: 2008/10/03

Page 52. Lecture 3: Inner Product Spaces Dual Spaces, Dirac Notation, and Adjoints Date Revised: 2008/10/03 Date Given: 2008/10/03 Page 5 Lecture : Inner Product Spaces Dual Spaces, Dirac Notation, and Adjoints Date Revised: 008/10/0 Date Given: 008/10/0 Inner Product Spaces: Definitions Section. Mathematical Preliminaries: Inner

More information

Notes for Math 290 using Introduction to Mathematical Proofs by Charles E. Roberts, Jr.

Notes for Math 290 using Introduction to Mathematical Proofs by Charles E. Roberts, Jr. Notes for Math 290 using Introduction to Mathematical Proofs by Charles E. Roberts, Jr. Chapter : Logic Topics:. Statements, Negation, and Compound Statements.2 Truth Tables and Logical Equivalences.3

More information

EQUIVALENCE OF TOPOLOGIES AND BOREL FIELDS FOR COUNTABLY-HILBERT SPACES

EQUIVALENCE OF TOPOLOGIES AND BOREL FIELDS FOR COUNTABLY-HILBERT SPACES EQUIVALENCE OF TOPOLOGIES AND BOREL FIELDS FOR COUNTABLY-HILBERT SPACES JEREMY J. BECNEL Abstract. We examine the main topologies wea, strong, and inductive placed on the dual of a countably-normed space

More information

In N we can do addition, but in order to do subtraction we need to extend N to the integers

In N we can do addition, but in order to do subtraction we need to extend N to the integers Chapter 1 The Real Numbers 1.1. Some Preliminaries Discussion: The Irrationality of 2. We begin with the natural numbers N = {1, 2, 3, }. In N we can do addition, but in order to do subtraction we need

More information

5 Birkhoff s Ergodic Theorem

5 Birkhoff s Ergodic Theorem 5 Birkhoff s Ergodic Theorem Birkhoff s Ergodic Theorem extends the validity of Kolmogorov s strong law to the class of stationary sequences of random variables. Stationary sequences occur naturally even

More information

Discrete Mathematics. Spring 2017

Discrete Mathematics. Spring 2017 Discrete Mathematics Spring 2017 Previous Lecture Principle of Mathematical Induction Mathematical Induction: rule of inference Mathematical Induction: Conjecturing and Proving Climbing an Infinite Ladder

More information

Banach Spaces V: A Closer Look at the w- and the w -Topologies

Banach Spaces V: A Closer Look at the w- and the w -Topologies BS V c Gabriel Nagy Banach Spaces V: A Closer Look at the w- and the w -Topologies Notes from the Functional Analysis Course (Fall 07 - Spring 08) In this section we discuss two important, but highly non-trivial,

More information

CHAPTER 3. Sequences. 1. Basic Properties

CHAPTER 3. Sequences. 1. Basic Properties CHAPTER 3 Sequences We begin our study of analysis with sequences. There are several reasons for starting here. First, sequences are the simplest way to introduce limits, the central idea of calculus.

More information

Ahlswede Khachatrian Theorems: Weighted, Infinite, and Hamming

Ahlswede Khachatrian Theorems: Weighted, Infinite, and Hamming Ahlswede Khachatrian Theorems: Weighted, Infinite, and Hamming Yuval Filmus April 4, 2017 Abstract The seminal complete intersection theorem of Ahlswede and Khachatrian gives the maximum cardinality of

More information

Linear Algebra. Preliminary Lecture Notes

Linear Algebra. Preliminary Lecture Notes Linear Algebra Preliminary Lecture Notes Adolfo J. Rumbos c Draft date April 29, 23 2 Contents Motivation for the course 5 2 Euclidean n dimensional Space 7 2. Definition of n Dimensional Euclidean Space...........

More information

Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences. Sums of sets, etc.

Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences. Sums of sets, etc. Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Sums of sets, etc. KC Border September 2002 Rev. November 2012 Rev. September 2013 If E and F are subsets of R m, define the sum E + F = {x + y : x E; y F

More information

MATH 583A REVIEW SESSION #1

MATH 583A REVIEW SESSION #1 MATH 583A REVIEW SESSION #1 BOJAN DURICKOVIC 1. Vector Spaces Very quick review of the basic linear algebra concepts (see any linear algebra textbook): (finite dimensional) vector space (or linear space),

More information

A misère-play -operator

A misère-play -operator A misère-play -operator Matthieu Dufour Silvia Heubach Urban Larsson arxiv:1608.06996v1 [math.co] 25 Aug 2016 July 31, 2018 Abstract We study the -operator (Larsson et al, 2011) of impartial vector subtraction

More information

CHAPTER 1. REVIEW: NUMBERS

CHAPTER 1. REVIEW: NUMBERS CHAPTER. REVIEW: NUMBERS Yes, mathematics deals with numbers. But doing math is not number crunching! Rather, it is a very complicated psychological process of learning and inventing. Just like listing

More information

Spectral Theorem for Self-adjoint Linear Operators

Spectral Theorem for Self-adjoint Linear Operators Notes for the undergraduate lecture by David Adams. (These are the notes I would write if I was teaching a course on this topic. I have included more material than I will cover in the 45 minute lecture;

More information

CHAPTER 0 PRELIMINARY MATERIAL. Paul Vojta. University of California, Berkeley. 18 February 1998

CHAPTER 0 PRELIMINARY MATERIAL. Paul Vojta. University of California, Berkeley. 18 February 1998 CHAPTER 0 PRELIMINARY MATERIAL Paul Vojta University of California, Berkeley 18 February 1998 This chapter gives some preliminary material on number theory and algebraic geometry. Section 1 gives basic

More information

ALGEBRA. 1. Some elementary number theory 1.1. Primes and divisibility. We denote the collection of integers

ALGEBRA. 1. Some elementary number theory 1.1. Primes and divisibility. We denote the collection of integers ALGEBRA CHRISTIAN REMLING 1. Some elementary number theory 1.1. Primes and divisibility. We denote the collection of integers by Z = {..., 2, 1, 0, 1,...}. Given a, b Z, we write a b if b = ac for some

More information

ELEMENTARY LINEAR ALGEBRA

ELEMENTARY LINEAR ALGEBRA ELEMENTARY LINEAR ALGEBRA K R MATTHEWS DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS UNIVERSITY OF QUEENSLAND Second Online Version, December 998 Comments to the author at krm@mathsuqeduau All contents copyright c 99 Keith

More information

Introduction to Dynamical Systems

Introduction to Dynamical Systems Introduction to Dynamical Systems France-Kosovo Undergraduate Research School of Mathematics March 2017 This introduction to dynamical systems was a course given at the march 2017 edition of the France

More information

(VI.C) Rational Canonical Form

(VI.C) Rational Canonical Form (VI.C) Rational Canonical Form Let s agree to call a transformation T : F n F n semisimple if there is a basis B = { v,..., v n } such that T v = λ v, T v 2 = λ 2 v 2,..., T v n = λ n for some scalars

More information

Detailed Proof of The PerronFrobenius Theorem

Detailed Proof of The PerronFrobenius Theorem Detailed Proof of The PerronFrobenius Theorem Arseny M Shur Ural Federal University October 30, 2016 1 Introduction This famous theorem has numerous applications, but to apply it you should understand

More information

3 The language of proof

3 The language of proof 3 The language of proof After working through this section, you should be able to: (a) understand what is asserted by various types of mathematical statements, in particular implications and equivalences;

More information

Bare-bones outline of eigenvalue theory and the Jordan canonical form

Bare-bones outline of eigenvalue theory and the Jordan canonical form Bare-bones outline of eigenvalue theory and the Jordan canonical form April 3, 2007 N.B.: You should also consult the text/class notes for worked examples. Let F be a field, let V be a finite-dimensional

More information

UNDERSTANDING THE DIAGONALIZATION PROBLEM. Roy Skjelnes. 1.- Linear Maps 1.1. Linear maps. A map T : R n R m is a linear map if

UNDERSTANDING THE DIAGONALIZATION PROBLEM. Roy Skjelnes. 1.- Linear Maps 1.1. Linear maps. A map T : R n R m is a linear map if UNDERSTANDING THE DIAGONALIZATION PROBLEM Roy Skjelnes Abstract These notes are additional material to the course B107, given fall 200 The style may appear a bit coarse and consequently the student is

More information

IRREDUCIBLE REPRESENTATIONS OF SEMISIMPLE LIE ALGEBRAS. Contents

IRREDUCIBLE REPRESENTATIONS OF SEMISIMPLE LIE ALGEBRAS. Contents IRREDUCIBLE REPRESENTATIONS OF SEMISIMPLE LIE ALGEBRAS NEEL PATEL Abstract. The goal of this paper is to study the irreducible representations of semisimple Lie algebras. We will begin by considering two

More information

A linear algebra proof of the fundamental theorem of algebra

A linear algebra proof of the fundamental theorem of algebra A linear algebra proof of the fundamental theorem of algebra Andrés E. Caicedo May 18, 2010 Abstract We present a recent proof due to Harm Derksen, that any linear operator in a complex finite dimensional

More information

October 25, 2013 INNER PRODUCT SPACES

October 25, 2013 INNER PRODUCT SPACES October 25, 2013 INNER PRODUCT SPACES RODICA D. COSTIN Contents 1. Inner product 2 1.1. Inner product 2 1.2. Inner product spaces 4 2. Orthogonal bases 5 2.1. Existence of an orthogonal basis 7 2.2. Orthogonal

More information