Energy transition with variable and intermittent renewable electricity generation

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Energy transition with variable and intermittent renewable electricity generation"

Transcription

1 Energy transition with variable and intermittent renewable electricity generation Aude Pommeret City University of Hong Kong Katheline Schubert Paris School of Economics, University Paris and CESifo November 6, 207 Very preliminary; do not quote. Introduction In the short/medium term, renewables cannot be deployed at a large scale to replace coal and other fossil fuels in electricity generation, on the one hand because they are on average still more costly than fossil fuels, and on the other hand because they are both variable, which is predictable (night and day, seasons), and intermittent, which is not (cloud cover, etc.). But in the future the production of electricity has to be decarbonized, and producing energy by renewable means seems to be the only possibility to do so, before nuclear fusion becomes eventually available. The literature considering the penetration of renewables in the energy mix consists so far in two rather separate trends. On the one hand, macro-dynamic models à la Hotelling consider renewable energy as an abundant and steady flow available with certainty, possibly after an investment in capacity has been made, at a higher unit cost than fossil energy 2. The issue is the cost otherwise clean renewable energy would replace polluting fossil fuels immediately. Thus standard models of energy transition ignore variability and intermittency and focus on the cost issue. However, the expansion of renewables will probably not be limited by the direct costs of electricity generation in the (near) future. Costs have already been widely reduced, due to technical progress and learning effects in production and installation, and the decrease is expected to continue, until a limit lower bound of the cost is reached. For instance, Carbon Capture and Storage (CCS) is another option, but it is still expensive and can only offer a partial solution as the potential carbon sinks are of limited capacity. Moreover, CCS has already been extensively studied. See for instance Lafforgue, Magne and Moreaux (2008). 2 See, for early path-breaking papers, Hoel and Kverndokk (996), and Tahvonen (997).

2 according to the International Energy Agency (20), solar PV costs have been reduced by 20% for each doubling of the cumulative installed capacity. The Energy Information Administration reports that the US average levelized cost of electricity in 202 is $/MWh 95.6 for conventional coal, 66.3 for natural gas-fired combined cycle, 80.3 for terrestrial wind, 204. for offshore wind, 30 for solar PV, 243 for solar thermal and 84.5 for hydro. Terrestrial wind and hydro (that we do not consider here because the expansion possibilities are very limited in developed countries) are already competitive, and solar PV is rapidly catching up in the US. In sunny and dry countries it is even more so: solar PV has already obtained grid parity 3 in sunny islands, and is expected to reach grid parity very soon for instance in Italy or California. Hence the real obstacle to a non-marginal expansion of renewables is not their cost but their variability, their intermittency, and maybe also their footprint in terms of land use especially for wind energy. Another strand of literature is composed of static models not directly interested in energy transition, but in the design of the electric mix (fossil fuels and renewables) when intermittency is taken into account, with or without storage devices. Ambec and Crampes (202, 205) are representative of this literature. They study the optimal electricity mix with intermittent renewable sources, and contrast it to the mix chosen by agents in a decentralized economy where the retailing price of electricity does not vary with its availability. They examine the properties of different public policies and their impacts on renewable penetration in the electric mix: carbon tax, feed-in tariffs, renewable portfolio standards, demand-side management policies. A recent survey on the economics of solar electricity (Baker et al., 203) emphasizes the lack of economic analysis of a decentralized clean energy provision through renewable sources. We intend to contribute to fill this lack by putting together the two strands of the literature mentioned above, in order to make macro-dynamic models more relevant for the study of the energy transition. Indeed we believe that energy transition is by essence a dynamic problem, which cannot be fully understood through static models. On the other hand, dynamic models are so far unable to take into account properly some crucial features of renewables. We plan to extend to a dynamic setting the static models cited above, taking into account variability and intermittency, in order to study to what extent they actually constitute a serious obstacle to energy transition. In a first step we tackle the variability issue alone. We build a stylized deterministic dynamic model of the optimal choice of the electricity mix (fossil and renewable), where the fossil energy, coal, is abundant but CO 2 -emitting, and the renewable energy, solar, is variable but clean. The originality of the model is that electricity produced when the renewable source of energy (solar) is available, and electricity produced when it is not, are considered two different goods (say day-electricity and night-electricity). At each period of time, consumers 3 Grid-parity is reached when the cost of electricity generation with the renewable source is roughly equal to the retailing electricity price. 2

3 derive utility from the consumption of the two goods. Considering that there are two different goods allows taking into account intra-day variability. Day-electricity can be produced with coal and/or solar. Night-electricity can be produced with coal, or by the release of day-electricity that has been stored to that effect. Storing energy is costly due to the loss of energy during the restoration process. We consider that coal and solar are available at zero variable costs, in order to focus on the variability and intermittency issues. We also make the assumption that at the beginning of the planning horizon coal-fired power plants already exist so that there is no capacity constraint on the production of electricity by the fossil source, but that the existing solar capacity is small so that investments are to be made in order to build up a sizable capacity. We solve the centralized program under the constraint of a carbon budget that cannot be exceeded and derive an optimal succession of regimes. We show that with a low initial solar capacity it is optimal to first use fossil fuels during night and day, then use fossil fuels during night only and finally go for no fossil fuels at all. The optimal dynamics for the capacity of solar power plants is derived, as well as the optimal amount of electricity stored in time. Simulations allow us to analyze the consequences of improvements in the storage and solar power generation technologies and of a more stringent environmental policy on the optimal investment decisions and energy mix. In a second step, we introduce intermittency 4. in the model and study the design of the power system enabling to accommodate it. With intermittency, day-electricity generation by solar power plants becomes uncertain. We consider that there is only partial generation if solar radiations are too weak due for instance to the cloud system, which occurs with a given probability. The succession of regimes is now more complex. It depends on the relative values of the efficiency of the storage technology, the weather pattern and whether there is sun at peak or off-peak periods. We perform simulations to compare the variability-only and the variability and intermittency solutions, and show that intermittency does not matter so much, rejoining there the empirical result of Gowrisankaran et al. (206). Simulations also allow us to do a number of comparative dynamics exercises. We show that a lenient climate policy delays both storage and the switch to clean energy, as does a higher probability of bad weather. Off-peak sun, rather than peak sun, increases storage and hinders consumption. Finally, we go back to the standard literature that ignores variability and intermittency. Joskow (20) underlines the mistakes that are made when doing so, particularly in the computation of the levelized cost of electricity. Ignoring variability and intermittency and reasoning on average values gives an undue advantage to renewable sources and leads to taking wrong decisions. We compare here the optimal solution and the solution of the model when variability and intermittency are taken into account only on average. Solar panel accumulation is not very sensitive to variability neither, thanks to storage that smoothes electricity provision. Indeed, we show that less solar panels are accumulated without storage. 4 This means that clean energy is not only variable but intermittent as well 3

4 The structure of the paper is the following. Section 2 sets up the framework, solves the model and studies the sensitivity of the solution to the main parameters in the case where variability only is taken into account. Section 3 introduces intermittency. In Section 4 we compare the previous results with the solution in the case where variability and intermittency are not fully taken into account. Section 5 concludes. 2 Variability in renewable electricity generation One of the novelties of the paper is that day and night electricity are modeled as two different goods that the representative household wants to consume at each point in time. Energy requirements may be satisfied by fossil sources, let s say coal, at day and night. Coal is abundant and carbon-emitting: the issue with coal extraction and consumption is not scarcity but climate change. There are no extraction costs. Climate policy takes the form of a carbon budget that society decides not to exceed, to have a good chance to maintain the temperature increase at an acceptable level -typically 2 C. This carbon budget is consumed when coal is burned. It is also possible to use a renewable source of energy, abundant but clean, provided that a production capacity is built. This energy is variable i.e. changes in a predictable way. We consider for the purpose of illustration that it is solar energy, that can be harnessed at day but not at night. Costly investment allows to increase solar capacity. There exists a storage technology that allows to store imperfectly electricity from day to night at no monetary cost but with a physical loss. 2. The optimal solution The social planner seeks to maximize the discounted sum of the net surplus of the economy. Instantaneous net surplus is the difference between the utility of consuming day and nightelectricity and the cost of the investment in solar capacity. 5 Day-electricity can be produced by coal-fired power plants and/or solar plants. A fraction of solar electricity can be stored to be released at night. 6 In addition to fossil electricity, night-electricity can be produced by the release of solar electricity stored during the day, with a loss. 7 5 For simplicity and to focus on the variability issue, we ignore the extraction cost of coal and the variable cost of using solar panels. We suppose that a large fossil capacity exists at the beginning of the planning horizon but that the initial solar capacity is low. 6 It does not make sense to store coal electricity since coal-fired power plants can be operated at night as well and there is no capacity constraint. 7 For instance, according to Yang (206), the efficiency of pumped hydroelectric storage (defined as the electricity generated divided by the electricity used to pump water) is lower than 60% for old systems, but over 80% for state-of-the-art ones. 4

5 The social planner s programme reads: max 0 e ρt [u (e d (t), e n (t)) C(I(t))] dt e d (t) = x d (t) + ( a(t))y (t) e n (t) = x n (t) + ka(t)y (t) Ẋ(t) = x d (t) + x n (t) ( λ(t)) Ẏ (t) = I(t) (µ(t)) 0 a(t) (ω a (t), ω a (t)) X(t) X (ω X (t)) x d (t) 0, x n (t) 0 (ω d (t), ω n (t)) X 0 0, Y 0 0 given where u is the instantaneous utility function, supposed to have the standard properties, e d and e n are respectively day and night-electricity consumption, x d and x n are fossil-generated electricity consumed respectively at day and night, X is the stock of carbon accumulated into the atmosphere due to fossil fuel combustion, X is the carbon budget i.e. the ceiling on the atmospheric carbon concentration, Y is solar capacity, I is the investment in solar capacity, C(I) is the investment cost function, a is the share of solar electricity produced at day that is stored to be released at night. The efficiency of the storage technology is represented by the parameter k [0, ] ( k is the leakage rate of this technology). ρ is the discount rate. We make the following assumptions on the utility and investment cost functions: utility is logarithmic and investment cost is quadratic (because of adjustment costs): u (e d, e n ) = ln e d + ( ) ln e n, 0 < < C(I) = c I + c 2 2 I2, c, c 2 > 0 With these assumptions we are able to solve the problem analytically. following results. We obtain the Proposition In the case where only variability of renewable energy is taken into account and the initial solar capacity is low, the optimal solution consists in 4 phases: () production of day and night-electricity with fossil fuel-fired power plants complemented at day by solar plants, no storage, investment in solar panels to increase solar capacity (from 0 to T ); (2) production of day-electricity with solar plants only, use of fossil fuel-fired power plants at night while proceeding with the building up of solar capacity, no storage (from T to T i ); 5

6 (3) production of day-electricity with solar plants only, use of fossil fuel-fired power plants at night while proceeding with the building up of solar capacity, progressive increase of storage from 0 to its maximal value, which depends on preferences for day and night-electricity (from T i to T ); (4) production of day and night-electricity with solar plants only, storage at its maximum value at day to produce night-electricity, and investment in solar panels to increase capacity, up to a steady state (from T to ). This last phase begins when the carbon budget is exhausted. Proof. See Appendix A. Proposition shows that it is always optimal to begin installing solar panels immediately and to use them to complement fossil energy at daytime. However, it is never optimal to begin storing immediately. Storage would allow saving fossil energy at night, but at the expense of more fossil at day to compensate for the solar electricity stored; it would also cause a physical loss of electricity. Even if the storage technology is available, as it is the case in the model, storage must only begin after fossil has been abandoned at day because the installed solar capacity has become high enough. Full storage coincides with the final abandonment of fossil. We show analytically in Appendix A that the 4 phases identified in Proposition are characterized by the following equations. Evolution of the shadow value λ of the atmospheric carbon stock (the carbon value) before the carbon budget is exhausted: λ(t) = λ(0)e ρt () Evolution of solar capacity over the whole horizon: Ẏ (t) = c 2 (µ(t) c ) (2) Evolution of the value of solar capacity in each phase: Phase () µ(t) = ρµ(t) λ(t) Phase (2) µ(t) = ρµ(t) Y (t) Phase (3) µ(t) = ρµ(t) kλ(t) (3) Phase (4) µ(t) = ρµ(t) Y (t) 6

7 Fossil fuel use, storage and total electricity consumption in each phase: Phase () x d (t) = λ(t) Y (t) e d (t) = λ(t) x n(t) = λ(t) e n (t) = λ(t) Phase (2) x d (t) = 0 x n (t) = λ(t) e d (t) = Y (t) e n (t) = λ(t) a(t) = 0 a(t) = 0 (4) Phase (3) x d (t) = 0 x n (t) = λ(t) ky (t) a(t) = e d (t) = kλ(t) e n (t) = λ(t) Phase (4) x d (t) = 0 x n (t) = 0 a = e d (t) = Y (t) e n (t) = ( )Y (t) The carbon value follows the Hotelling rule (Eq.()). kλ(t)y (t) The joint paths of solar capacity Y and its shadow value µ are determined by the four dynamic systems composed of Eq.(2) and each of the equations in system (4). They are represented on the phase diagram on Figure, constructed for a given λ(0) (that reflects the stringency of the climate constraint). The last phase is a saddle path leading to a steady state µ = c, Y = /(ρc ). Moving backward from the steady state along the stable branch, date T is reached. The relevant path then corresponds to phase (3) where the dynamics of Y and µ are independent, until date T i is reached. From T i on, the saddle path of phase (2), corresponding to the steady state µ = c, Y = /(ρc ) is followed until date T (the steady state is never reached). 8 After T the path followed corresponds to phase () where Y and µ are independent, until date 0. The initial shadow value of solar panels, µ(0) then obtained (as a function of λ(0)) matches the initial condition Y (0) = Y 0. For a given value of λ(0), the joint evolutions of λ and Y trigger the phase switchings, i.e. gives dates T, T i and T (see Figure 2 and Eqs. () and (2)). The climate constraint then pins down λ(0). In phase (), e d (t) = /λ(t) and e n (t) = ( )/λ(t): electricity consumptions are only driven by the carbon value, i.e. by climate policy. In phase (2) (when there is no storage), it is still the case for night electricity consumption, but during daytime, electricity only depends on installed solar capacity. 9 In phase (3) storage occurs and no fossil is used 8 Phase (2) does not exist if there is no loss in the storage technology (k = ). 9 It implies that there is overcapacity of fossil generation during daytime. 7

8 during daytime; but due to storage (driven by the climate constraint), it is again only the climate constraint that determines electricity consumption at each period. In phase (4), when electricity production is totally carbon-free, electricity consumption night and day only depends on installed solar capacity. The amount of electricity stored at day to be consumed at night only depends on the preference for night-electricity: a =. If > /2, consumers prefer consuming at day, when there is sun. This means that peak time consumption coincides with the availability of solar electricity. It is obviously the most favorable case. If on the contrary < /2, sun is shining at off-peak time. This would correspond to the Californian duck documented by CAISO 0 and recently analyzed by Fowlie and Wolfram 2 Y (t) Ẏ (t) = 0 Y Y (4) Y (T ) Y (T i ) Y (T ) Y 0 µ 6 (3) 6 µ(t) = 0 in phase (2) 6 (2) () µ(t) = 0 in phase (4) µ(0) µ(t) Figure : Phase diagram 0 What the duck curve tells us about managing a green grid, FastFacts.pdf See The duck has landed, the Energy Institute Blog, 2 See What s the Point of an Electricity Storage Mandate? 8

9 kλ(0) Y Y (t) kλ(0) Y λ(0) kλ(t) Y 0 kλ(t) λ(t) T T i T Figure 2: Solar capacity and carbon value before the ceiling t 2.2 Numerical illustrations We now perform some comparative dynamics exercises, to assess the impact of the stringency of climate policy and of the value of the parameters on the level and the time profile of electricity consumption, storage and solar capacity. The parameters of the reference simulation are given in Table. They are chosen for illustrative purposes only, without any pretension of realism. ρ k c c 2 Y 0 X 0 X Table : Parameters in the reference simulation, variability only In the reference simulation, day-electricity consumption is W-shaped (V-shaped if k = ). It is first decreasing because of the rise of the carbon value (phase ()); it is then increasing as fossil fuel is abandoned at day and more solar panels are installed (phase (2)); next, storage begins and increases, at the expense of day-electricity consumption, which decreases (phase (3)); finally, the increasing use of solar panels joint with a constant share of day-electricity stored generates a rise in day-electricity consumption (phase (4)). Nightelectricity consumption is V-shaped: it is driven by the carbon value i.e. climate policy while fossil energy is used at night, hence decreasing (phases ()-(3)); then, when fossil fuel 9

10 is abandoned at night, it increases with the stock of solar panels and the development of storage. The comparative statics exercises results are represented on figures 3 to 5. Less stringent climate policy (figure 3): In the short run energy consumption at day and night are higher than in the reference case, storage occurs later, the switch to clean energy is postponed. In the medium run energy consumption becomes lower than in the reference case, because investment in solar panels has been lower: there is an hysteresis effect. Even in the absence of explicit damages due to climate change, a lenient climate policy has adverse effects in the long run because it delays investment in clean energy. Less efficient storage technology (figure 4): A less efficient storage technology translates in the model in a higher loss rate k. Then, the date at which storage begins is postponed, which allows to consume more at day in phase (2). Of course night-electricity consumption is smaller. Again an hysteresis effect appears: consumption is lower in the long run, because the development of solar panels has been slower. Off-peak sun (figure 5): In the reference simulation, consumers prefer to consume electricity when the sun is shining and solar panels can harness its radiation, i.e. when there is sun at peak time. We make in this simulation the opposite assumption: consumers prefer to consume electricity when there is no sun (it corresponds to the Californian duck case). Clearly, the situation is now less favorable. At each date, total electricity consumption (over day and night) is reduced. The date at which fossil is not used at day anymore is brought forward so that fossil consumption at night may be higher, and storage occurs earlier. The long run level of storage has to be higher, which means more overall electricity loss. ed(t),en(t) 6 % diff. Y(t) a(t) t t t Energy consumption Solar capacity Storage day (plain) and night (dashed) (% diff.) 0

11 Figure 3. Effect of a less stringent climate policy under variability only (X = 50 in blue and X = 00 in red) ed(t),en(t) % diff. Y(t) a(t) t t t Energy consumption Solar capacity Storage day (plain) and night (dashed) (% diff.) Figure 4. Effect of a less efficient storage technology under variability only (k = 0.6 in blue and k = 0.2 in black) ed(t),en(t) 6 % diff. Y(t) a(t) t t t Energy consumption Solar capacity Storage day (plain) and night (dashed) (% diff.) Figure 5. Effect of a smaller preference in day electricity under variability only ( = 0.8 in blue and = 0.2 in green) 3 Intermittency in renewable electricity generation We now account for the fact that renewable electricity generation is not only variable but intermittent as well, i.e. some of its variations are not predictable. For the purpose of illustration, we again consider the example of solar energy. Solar radiations can be fully harnessed during the day if there is sun, but can only be partially harnessed during the day if there are clouds. No harnessing can happen during the night. As only the expected dynamics of pollution is known, the ceiling constraint on the stock of carbon into the atmosphere is now in expectation.

12 3. The optimal solution During the day, the weather is sunny with a probability q and solar panels are then producing electricity at full capacity Y. With a probability ( q) the weather is cloudy and solar panel only produce φy electricity with 0 < φ <. As before, there exists a storage technology that allows to store imperfectly electricity from day to night at no monetary cost but with a physical loss. With intermittency, the amount stored depends on the weather: a u denotes storage when the sun is shining, while storage when there are clouds in noted a l. Accordingly, fossil-generated electricity consumption and total electricity consumption are denoted with superscripts u and l depending on the weather. The social planner s programme becomes: max 0 e ρt [ qu (e u d(t), e u n(t)) + ( q)u ( e l d(t), e l n(t) ) C(I(t)) ] dt e u d(t) = x u d(t) + ( a u (t))y (t), e l d(t) = x l d(t) + ( a l (t))φy (t) e u n(t) = x u n(t) + ka u (t)y (t), e l n(t) = x l n(t) + ka l (t)φy (t) E(Ẋ(t)) = q (xu d(t) + x u n(t)) + ( q) ( x l d(t) + x l n(t) ) Ẏ (t) = I(t) E(X(t)) X (µ(t)) ( λ(t)) 0 a u (t), 0 a l (t) (ω u a(t), ω u a(t)), (ω l a(t), ω l a(t)) (ω X (t)) x u d(t) 0, x u n(t) 0, x l d(t) 0, x l n(t) 0 X 0 0, Y 0 0 given (ω u d(t), ω u n(t), ω l d(t), ω l n(t)) The characteristics of the optimal solution are described in Proposition 2. The proofs are collected in Appendix B. Proposition 2 When the intermittency of renewable energy is taken into account and the initial solar capacity is low, the optimal solution is composed of seven phases (see Figure 6). () Fossil is used night and day whatever the state of nature, complemented by some solar at day. There is no storage. Investment takes place to build-up solar production capacity. (2) Solar capacity is large enough for fossil to be dropped at day in the good state of nature but not in the bad state. There is still no storage. (3) Solar capacity is large enough either to drop fossil at day in the bad state of nature without storing, or to keep fossil at day in the bad state and begin storing in the good state. The first option is chosen when k < φ i.e. the storage technology is rather poor and the cloud problem not so bad. The second option is adopted when φ < k. (4) There is storage in the good state of nature while fossil is still used at night in the two states or at night and day in the bad state only. The first option is chosen when k < φ/ 2

13 i.e. the storage technology is rather poor, the cloud problem not so bad, and the preference for day-electricity rather low. The second option is adopted when φ/ < k. (5) If k < φ/ and φ/ >, fossil is used night and day in the bad state and storage begins in the bad state, whereas if φ/ < k or k < φ/ < fossil is used at night in the bad state only without storing in the bad state. (6) The complement is done, to get storage in both states and fossil at night only in the bad state only. (7) Fossil is completely abandoned, and there is storage in both states. Notice that the date at which this totally clean last phase begins is determined, inter alia, by the product kφ (see Eq. (66) in Appendix B). Remember that k is the leakage rate of the storage technology and φ the loss rate induced by clouds on the solar technology. When the leakage and loss rates are small, the clean phase logically begins early. It is all the more postponed since one of the two rates is high. Moreover, compared to the case where only variability is taken into account, we see that the clean phase is all the more postponed since the loss rate induced by clouds is high, which makes perfect sense. x u n x u d 0 0 x l n x l d x u n x l n 0 x l d 0 0 k < φ k > φ x u n x l n x u n x l n 0 x l d a u 0 k < φ k > φ x u n x l n 0 0 a u 0 0 x l n 0 x l d a u 0 < φ > φ x u n x l n 0 0 a u a l 0 x l n x l a u a l n 0 0 a u a u a l Figure 6: Intermittency: the seven phases, depending on the values of k, φ and 3.2 Numerical illustrations These simulations are for illustrative purpose only. Parameters are given in Table 2. They are chosen to illustrate the 5 possible different cases identified in the resolution (see Figure 6 and Appendix B): 3

14 Case I: k < φ < φ/ <. Case II: k < φ < φ/, φ/ >. Case III: φ < k < φ/, φ/ >. Case IV: φ < k < φ/, φ/ <. Case V: k > φ/. In all cases, we consider that solar is shining at peak time ( = 0.8 > /2) and that q = 0.2. In Cases I and II the inefficiency of the storage technology is worse than the cloud problem (k < φ), whereas it is the contrary in Cases III, IV and V. In Cases I and II and V the preference for day-electricity consumption comes along with a moderate cloud problem (φ < ), whereas it is the contrary in Cases II and III. We arbitrarily choose Case I as our reference case. We check that the results are qualitatively the same if any other case is taken as reference. k φ Case I Case II Case III Case IV Case V Table 2: Parameter values With no surprise, the general result is that intermittency globally makes matters worse (see figure 7). Electricity consumption is always smaller with intermittency than under variability only. The full storage capacity and the no-fossil economy are reached later. Night-electricity consumption begins to increase later. However differences are not so large. This is consistent with the empirical findings in Gowrisankaran and Reynolds (206). For instance, day-electricity consumption follows a path very close to a W shape as exhibited under variability only. 4

15 ed(t),en(t) 6 5 x(t) t t Energy consumption day (plain) and night (dashed) %diff Y(t) a(t) Fossil fuel consumption total day and night t t Solar capacity Storage Figure 7. Dynamics of variables of interest under intermittency in Case I (black) and variability only (green) Figures 8 to 0 present the same comparative dynamics exercices as in the case with variability only. A less stringent climate policy (figure 8) delays storage and the switch to the no-fossil economy; it increases electricity consumption both night and day in the short and medium run but decreases them in the long run. As expected, phases during which fossil is used exhibit the larger differences in consumption. The effects are qualitatively the same as under variability only (figure 3). A less efficient storage technology has very few effect in the short run since storage is not used, and it transfers energy use from night to day in the medium run. In the long run both day and night energy consumption are smaller. Again, the effects are qualitatively the same as under variability only (see figures 9 and 4). In general, when peak consumption occurs when there is sun (therefore solar electricity generation), the whole daytime energy consumption path is moved up, and the reverse happens for the night energy consumption. Again, this is in accordance with what has been obtained without intermittency (see figures 0 and 5). 5

16 ed(t),en(t) % diff. Y(t) a(t) t t t Energy consumption Solar capacity Storage day (plain) and night (dashed) (% diff.) Figure 8. Effect of a less stringent climate policy in Case I (X = 50 in blue and X = 00 in red) ed(t),en(t) %diff Y(t) a(t) t t t Energy consumption Solar capacity Storage day (plain) and night (dashed) (% diff.) Figure 9. Effect of a less efficient storage technology in Case I (k = 0.6 in black and k = 0.2 in blue) ed(t),en(t) %diff Y(t) a(t) t t t Energy consumption Solar capacity Storage day (plain) and night (dashed) (% diff.) Figure 0. Effect of a smaller preference in day electricity (Case I with = 0.8 in black and Case II with = 0.2 in green) 6

17 Figures and 2 present new exercises: the effect of a larger cloud problem the the effect of a higher probability of sunny weather. A larger cloud problem (figure ) delays storage and the switch to the no-fossil economy and leads to less energy consumption, in particular during the day in the medium and long run. Such a case is relevant for less sunny countries. A higher probability of sunny weather (figure 2) has the opposite effect. ed(t),en(t) %diff Y(t) a(t) t t t Energy consumption Solar capacity Storage day (plain) and night (dashed) (% diff.) Figure. Effect of a larger cloud problem (Case I with φ = 0.7 in black and Case V with φ = 0.4 in red) ed(t),en(t) 4 %diff Y(t) a(t) t t t Energy consumption Solar capacity Storage day (plain) and night (dashed) (% diff.) Figure 2. Effect of a higher probability of sunny weather in Case I (q = 0.2 in black and q = 0.8 in blue) 4 Appraising the effect of variability and storage To appraise whether renewables are profitable, variability and intermittency are most of the time ignored and it is considered that renewables generate electricity in a continuous way, but at less than full capacity. In order to appraise the consequences of this simplification, 7

18 we consider a special case of our general model where there is constant electricity per unit generation, that is, when an installed solar capacity Y generates an amount of electricity κy day and night, where κ is constant. Other assumptions remain the same as in the general model. First, we compare solar panels accumulation, fossil fuel use, and electricity consumption paths under constant per unit generation, with those obtained under variability and intermittency (as derived in the previous sections). As storage is suspected to play a major role in tackling intermittency and variability, we also compare the model under constant electricity generation with the one under variability but without storage. 3 Under constant per unit generation the social planner program reads: max 0 e ρt [u (e d (t), e n (t)) C(I(t))] dt e d (t) = x d (t) + κy (t) e n (t) = x n (t) + κy (t) Ẋ(t) = x d (t) + x n (t) ( λ(t)) Ẏ (t) = I(t) (µ(t)) X(t) X (ω X (t)) x d (t) 0, x n (t) 0 (ω d (t), ω n (t)) X 0 0, Y 0 0 given Only three phases appear. In Phase (), fossil fuels are used night and day. They provide electricity only during day in Phase (2) if > 0.5, which we assume (in case < 0.5, they are used only during night) and finally, electricity is generated with only solar generation in Phase (3). During all these phases, the shadow value λ of the atmospheric carbon stock follows the Hotelling rule as in the general model. The dynamic equation driving solar capacity accumulation over the whole horizon is the same as in the general model as well. The evolution 3 Intermittency could be accounted for as well, but it would complicate the presentation without altering the qualitative results, as it has been shown in the previous section.) We also appraise the importance of storage by comparing the general model with the one without storage possibilities. 8

19 of the shadow value of solar capacity in each phase is: Phase () µ(t) = ρµ(t) 2κλ(t) Phase (2) µ(t) = ρµ(t) κλ(t) Y (t) Phase (3) µ(t) = ρµ(t) Y (t) Fossil fuel use and total electricity consumption in each phase are: Phase () x d (t) = κy (t) λ(t) x n(t) = κy (t) λ(t) e d (t) = e n (t) = λ(t) λ(t) Phase (2) x d (t) = λ(t) κy (t) x n(t) = 0 e d (t) = λ(t) e n (t) = κy (t) Phase (3) x d (t) = 0 x n (t) = 0 e d (t) = κy (t) e n (t) = κy (t) Only Phase (3) is a saddle path. During this phase, electricity generation is completely carbon-free as solar generation provides the whole electricity and consumptions night and day only depend on the installed solar capacity. It leads to a steady state µ = c, Y = /(ρc ). Moving backward from the steady state along the stable branch, a date is reached when Phase (2) starts. In this second phase, the dynamics of Y and µ are independent and fossil fuels are only used during daytime (for > 0.5). It implies overcapacity of fossil generation during night, which strikingly differs from what happens in the general model where such an overcapacity occurs during daytime. Electricity consumption is determined by climate policy during daytime and by solar capacity during nighttime. Eventually, Phase () is reached, during which Y and µ are independent again, until date 0. Electricity consumptions night and day require fossil fuels and are determined by the carbon value. 4 Numerical simulations allows us to go further into the comparison of the general case and the constant generation case. First, we consider that constant electricity generation is equal to the mean of electricity generation under variability and intermittency i.e. 4 As in the general model, the initial shadow value of solar panels µ(0) (as a function of λ(0)) matches the initial condition Y 0. For a given value of λ(0) the joint evolutions of λ and Y trigger the phase switchings and the climate constraint then pins down λ(0). 9

20 κ = 0.5(q + ( q)φ). Comparisons with the paths obtained with the general model are provided in figure 3. As expected, electricity consumptions (that are fictive since solar generation during night cannot happen in reality) are close to an average of those obtained under variability and intermittency. It is striking that solar panel accumulation is nearly insensitive to the account of variability. This comes from the role of storage that provides a way to transfer solar generated electricity from day to night. We also consider an alternative assumption for the constant electricity generation, such that the planner is over-optimistic with respect to κ and, for instance κ = 0.5(q + ( q)φ). In this case, solar panel accumulation is quicker when variability is ignored. It must be kept in mind, however, that the steady state level of the solar panel capacity is the same whether or not variability is accounted for and regardless of the assumption on κ. ed(t),en(t) 4 % diff Y(t) t t Energy consumption day (plain) and night (dashed), -.0 Solar capacity (% diff) Figure 3. Comparison of the general case (intermittency in Case I, in green) and the constant generation case (in blue) As storage seems to play a large role in smoothing the consequences of variability and intermittency, we now compare the constant generation model with a model with variability but no storage. In the latter, the social planner program reads: max 0 e ρt [u (e d (t), e n (t)) C(I(t))] dt e d (t) = x d (t) + Y (t) e n (t) = x n (t) Ẋ(t) = x d (t) + x n (t) ( λ(t)) Ẏ (t) = I(t) (µ(t)) X(t) X (ω X (t)) x d (t) 0, x n (t) 0 (ω d (t), ω n (t)) X 0 0, Y 0 0 given 20

21 Only two phases appear. In Phase (), fossil fuels are used night and day, but they are used only during night in Phase (2). During these two phases, the shadow value λ of the atmospheric carbon stock still follows Hotelling rule. The dynamic equation driving solar capacity accumulation over the whole horizon is the same as in the general model as well. The evolution of the value of solar capacity in each phase is: Phase () µ(t) = ρµ(t) λ(t) Phase (2) µ(t) = ρµ(t) Y (t) Fossil fuels use and total electricity consumption in each phase are: Phase () x d (t) = λ(t) Y (t) e d (t) = λ(t) x n(t) = λ(t) e n (t) = λ(t) Phase (2) x d (t) = 0 x n (t) = λ(t) e d (t) = Y (t) e n (t) = λ(t) Dynamics for fossil fuels use and electricity consumption are shown in figure 4. Phase (2) is a saddle path leading to a steady state µ = c, Y = /(ρc ). Along this path, daytime electricity consumption is determined by solar capacity, but night electricity consumption still uses fossil fuels as there exists no mean to transfer daytime solar generation towards the night. Therefore electricity generation is never carbon-free and night consumption (that is equal to fossil fuels use) asymptotically tends toward zero as it is driven by the climate constraint. It implies overcapacity of fossil generation during day, as in the general model (but opposite to what happens if variability is ignored). Moving backward from the steady state along the stable branch, a date is reached when there is a switch to Phase (). In this phase, the dynamics of Y and µ are independent; electricity consumptions night and day use fossil fuels and are determined by the climate policy. 5 5 As in the previous models, the initial value of solar panels, µ(0) then provided matches the initial condition Y 0. For a given value of λ(0) the joint evolutions of λ and Y trigger the phase switchings and the climate constraint then pins down λ(0). 2

22 xd(t),xn(t) ed(t),en(t) t t Fossil fuels use Energy consumption day (plain) and night (dashed) day (plain) and night (dashed) Figure 4. No storage Comparisons between the model under variability with no storage and the model under constant generation is provided in figure 5. The absence of storage prevents from using solar generated electricity to be used at night. On the contrary, constant generation allows generation during night as well. Therefore the benefits of solar panels are larger in the later case. This explains that the steady state level of the solar capacity is higher when variability and intermittency are ignored (Y = /(ρc )) than without storage (Y = /(ρc )). This result can be observed in figure 5, even if, during the first periods, accumulation is quicker in the absence of storage. The figure also shows that, without storage, daytime fossil fuels consumption stops while nighttime fossil fuels use asymptotically goes to zero, while under constant generation it is nighttime consumption of fossil fuels that stops first, later followed by a complete stop during daytime as well. xd(t),xn(t) 4 ed(t),en(t) 0 8 %diff Y(t) t t t Fossil fuel use energy consumption Solar capacity day (plain) and night (dashed) days (plain) and night (dashed) (% diff) Figure 5. The role of storage (no storage in red and constant generation in green) Another way to appraise the importance of storage is to compare the model without storage and the general model (with variability, intermittency and storage). Thanks to storage, it is possible to transfer electricity generated at day using solar capacity towards the night. Benefits from solar generation are therefore higher with storage, which explains that solar capacity at the steady state is higher with storage (Y = /(ρc ) compared to Y = /(ρc ) without storage). Finally, the value of storage can be appraised by computing the welfares in the two models. 22

23 5 Conclusion In this paper, we build a stylized dynamic model of the optimal choice of the electricity mix, where the fossil energy, coal, is abundant but CO 2 -emitting, and the renewable energy, solar, is variable and intermittent but clean. We solve the centralized program under the constraint of a carbon budget that cannot be exceeded and derive an optimal succession of regimes. The optimal dynamics for the capacity of solar power plants is derived, as well as the optimal amount of electricity stored in time. Simulations allow us to show that a lenient climate policy delays both storage and the switch to clean energy, as does a higher probability of bad weather. Off-peak sun, rather than peak sun, increases storage and hinders consumption. We also obtain that, compared with variability only, intermittency worsens the situation although not so significantly. Solar panel accumulation is not very sensitive to variability neither, thanks to storage that smoothes electricity provision. Indeed, we show that less solar panels are accumulated without storage. This work can be considered as a first step in the study of energy transition under variability and intermittency of the clean sources. Next steps should concern the account of an endogenous capacity for the fossil fuel generation. In addition, a decentralized version of the model would be interesting and challenging as the energy market exhibits several peculiar features, and it would allow designing policy instruments. Finally, R&D investments improving storage technologies, and learning effects allowing a decrease in the cost of solar energy may also be considered., References Ambec S. and C. Crampes (202), Electricity Provision with Intermittent Sources of Energy, Resource and Energy Economics 34: Ambec S. and C. Crampes (205), Decarbonizing Electricity Generation with Intermittent Sources of Energy, TSE Working Paper Baker E., M. Fowlie, D. Lemoine and S. S. Reynolds (203), The Economics of Solar Electricity, Annual Review of Resource Economics, 5: Gowrisankaran G. and S. S. Reynolds (206), Intermittency and the Value of Renewable Energy, Journal of Political Economy, 24(4), Heal G. (206), Notes on the Economics of Energy Storage, NBER Working Paper 22752, October. Hoel M., and S. Kverndokk (996), Depletion of Fossil Fuels and the Impacts of Global Warming, Resource and Energy Economics, 8:

24 International Energy Agency (20), Solar Energy Perspectives. Joskow, P. (20), Comparing the costs of intermittent and dispatchable generating technologies, American Economic Review, 0(3), Lafforgue G., B. Magne and M. Moreaux (2008), Energy substitutions, climate change and carbon sinks, Ecological Economics, 67: Lazkano I., L. Nostbakken and M. Pelli (206), From Fossil Fuels to Renewables: The Role of Electricity Storage, Working Paper. Sinn H. W. (206), Buffering volatility: A study on the limits of Germany s energy revolution, CESifo Working Papers n 5950, June. Tahvonen O. (997), Fossil fuels, stock externalities, and backstop technology, Canadian Journal of Economics, 30: Yang C.-J. (206), Pumped hydroelectric storage, in Storing Energy, T.M. Letcher ed., Elsevier. 24

25 A Variability The current value Hamiltonian associated to the social planner s programme reads: H = u (x d + ( a)y, x n + kay ) C(I) λ (x d + x n ) + µi and the Lagrangian is: ( ) L = H + ω a a + ω a ( a) + ω d x d + ω n x n + ω X X X The first order conditions are: i.e. L x d = u λ + ω d = 0 L x n = u 2 λ + ω n = 0 L a = Y u + ky u 2 + ω a ω a = 0 L I = C (I) + µ = 0 L X = ω X = λ + ρλ L Y = ( a)u kau 2 = µ ρµ u = λ ω d (5) u 2 = λ ω n (6) Y (u ku 2 ) = ω a ω a (7) C (I) = µ (8) ω X = λ ρλ (9) ( a)u kau 2 = µ ρµ (0) 25

26 The complementarity slackness conditions read: ω a a = 0, ω a 0, a 0 ω a ( a) = 0, ω a 0, a 0 ω d x d = 0, ω d 0, x d 0 ω n x n = 0, ω n 0, x n 0 ( ) ω X X X = 0, ωx 0, X X 0 Before the ceiling, X < X and ω X = 0. Then FOC (9) reads λ/λ = ρ, i.e.: λ(t) = λ(0)e ρt () The shadow price of carbon concentration follows a Hotelling rule before the ceiling, as long as fossil fuel is used. A. No fossil This phase is necessarily the last one, and it always exists. Let T 0 be the date at which this last phase begins. T is also the date at which the ceiling is reached. We have x d = 0, x n = 0, ω d > 0, ω n > 0 t T. The FOC then read: ( a)y = λ ω d (2) kay = λ ω n (3) a ( ) = ω a( a) a ω a (4) c + c 2 I = µ (5) λ ρλ = ω X (6) µ ρµ = Y (7) The no storage (a = 0) or complete storage (a = ) cases cannot occur because the marginal utility of consumption at night or day would become infinite. Hence the solution is an interior solution on a. Eq. (4) yields: a = (8) There is a constant rate of storage all along this phase, depending on the weight of nightelectricity in utility. 26

27 Eq. (5) and (7) together with Ẏ = I yield a dynamic system in (µ, Y ): { µ = ρµ Y Ẏ = c 2 (µ c ) Saddle-point. See the phase diagram on Figure. The values of µ and Y at the steady state are: Finally, Eq. (2) and (3) imply: µ = c (9) Y = ρc (20) Y λ and ky λ The second condition is more stringent than the first one. It therefore provides the value of λ at the beginning of this phase: λ(t ) = (2) ky (T ) The solution in this phase is to store a fraction of the electricity produced at day to use it at night, and to invest in solar panels to increase capacity from Y (T ) (to be determined) to Y = /ρc. A.2 Fossil night and day This phase is necessarily the first one, if it exists. We denote by T the date at which it ends. We have x d > 0, x n > 0, ω d = 0, ω n = 0. The FOC read: to which we add (). x d + ( a)y = λ (22) x n + kay = λ (23) ( k)λy = ω a ω a (24) c + c 2 I = µ (25) (( a) + ka) λ = µ ρµ (26) The left-hand side member of (24) is necessarily positive. Hence the case ω a = 0 and ω a > 0, i.e. a = (full storage) is excluded. The interior case ω a = 0 and ω a = 0, i.e. 0 < a <, 27

28 is possible iff Y = 0, which means that no intermittent source of energy is used. But it does not make sense to have a positive capacity of storage absent any intermittent source of energy. This case is also excluded. The only possibility is thus ω a > 0 and ω a = 0, i.e. a = 0 : no storage. With no storage, Eq. (26) simplifies into: µ ρµ = λ (27) Using (), this equation can be integrated, to obtain µ(t) as a function of µ(0), λ(0) and time. It allows us to obtain I(t) and, by integration, Y (t) as functions of the same variables. We suppose that Y 0 is low enough, s.t. I(0) > 0, which requires µ(0) > c. Eq. (22) and (23) now read: Eq. (29) and (28) allow to compute x n and x d : x d + Y = λ (28) = λ x n (29) x n (t) = λ(t) (30) x d (t) = Y (t) λ(t) (3) At the end of this phase, x d (T ) = 0 (x n (T ) = 0 is impossible, since it would require λ(t ) = + ). Hence: λ(t ) = Y (T ) x n (T ) = λ(t ) (32) (33) The solution in this phase is to use fossil fuel-fired power plants night and day but less and less, not to store, and to build up solar capacity, from Y 0 to Y (T ) to be determined. 28

29 A.3 Fossil at night only This or these phases are intermediate. We have here x d = 0, x n > 0, ω d > 0, ω n = 0 and the FOC read: to which we add (). ( a)y = λ ω d (34) x n + kay = λ (35) ( )ky a x n + kay = ω a ω a (36) c + c 2 I = µ (37) Y ( )ka x n + kay = µ ρµ (38) In the case of no storage, the FOC become: Y = λ ω d (39) x n = λ (40) λky = ω a (4) c + c 2 I = µ (42) Y = µ ρµ (43) Eq. (42) and (43) together with Ẏ = I yield the following dynamic system in (µ, Y ): { µ = ρµ Y Ẏ = c 2 (µ c ) Saddle-point. See the phase diagram on Figure. The steady state values of µ and Y are: µ = c (44) Y = ρc (45) According to (39) and (4), we must have Y λ. Hence this phase begins at T ky 29

Energy transition with variable and intermittent renewable electricity generation

Energy transition with variable and intermittent renewable electricity generation Energy transition with variable and intermittent renewable electricity generation Aude Pommeret City University of Hong Kong Katheline Schubert Paris School of Economics, University Paris and CESifo May

More information

Optimal control theory with applications to resource and environmental economics

Optimal control theory with applications to resource and environmental economics Optimal control theory with applications to resource and environmental economics Michael Hoel, August 10, 2015 (Preliminary and incomplete) 1 Introduction This note gives a brief, non-rigorous sketch of

More information

Structural change in a multi-sector model of the climate and the economy

Structural change in a multi-sector model of the climate and the economy Structural change in a multi-sector model of the climate and the economy Gustav Engström The Beijer Institute of Environmental Economics Stockholm, December 2012 G. Engström (Beijer) Stockholm, December

More information

Optimal subsidies for renewables and storage capacities

Optimal subsidies for renewables and storage capacities Optimal subsidies for renewables and storage capacities Mathias Mier 1 Carsten Helm 2 1 ifo Institute 2 University of Oldenburg IEW Gothenburg, 19 June 2018 Electricity is dicult... but we solved the problem...

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT November 28, 2017. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 9 November 28, 2017. 1 / 41 First-Generation Models

More information

Optimal management of a renewable energy source under uncertainty

Optimal management of a renewable energy source under uncertainty Optimal management of a renewable energy source under uncertainty Catherine Bobtcheff University of Toulouse I, LERNA, CEA 21 Allée de Brienne, 31000 Toulouse, France catherine.bobtcheff@univ-tlse1.fr

More information

Optimal control theory with applications to resource and environmental economics

Optimal control theory with applications to resource and environmental economics Optimal control theory with applications to resource and environmental economics Michael Hoel University of Oslo July 15, 2016 Abstract This note gives a brief, non-rigorous sketch of basic optimal control

More information

Optimal Dynamic Management of a Renewable Energy Source under Uncertainty

Optimal Dynamic Management of a Renewable Energy Source under Uncertainty Optimal Dynamic Management of a Renewable Energy Source under Uncertainty Catherine Bobtcheff Toulouse School of Economics (CNRS and LERNA) Abstract I consider a risk averse and prudent social planner

More information

Energy Storage and Intermittent Renewable Energy

Energy Storage and Intermittent Renewable Energy Energy Storage and Intermittent Renewable Energy Tunç Durmaz NHH, Norwegian School of Economics February 2014 Preliminary draft. Please do not cite. Abstract One technology considered to alleviate the

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics Advanced Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model Marcin Kolasa Warsaw School of Economics Marcin Kolasa (WSE) Ad. Macro - Ramsey model 1 / 30 Introduction Authors: Frank Ramsey (1928), David Cass (1965) and Tjalling

More information

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 December 14, 2006 Exercise 1 A Households Households maximise their intertemporal utility function by optimally choosing consumption, savings, and the mix of

More information

1. Money in the utility function (start)

1. Money in the utility function (start) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 1/3 2012 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Money in the utility function (start) a. The basic money-in-the-utility function model b. Optimal

More information

Optimal Demand Response

Optimal Demand Response Optimal Demand Response Libin Jiang Steven Low Computing + Math Sciences Electrical Engineering Caltech June 2011 Outline o Motivation o Demand response model o Some results Wind power over land (outside

More information

Should we extract more shale gas? The effect of climate and financial constraints

Should we extract more shale gas? The effect of climate and financial constraints Should we extract more shale gas? The effect of climate and financial constraints Fanny Henriet & Katheline Schubert Paris School of Economics, University Paris 1 January 23, 215 Abstract In the context

More information

Optimal Dynamic Management of a Renewable Energy Source under Uncertainty

Optimal Dynamic Management of a Renewable Energy Source under Uncertainty Optimal Dynamic Management of a Renewable Energy Source under Uncertainty Catherine Bobtcheff Toulouse School of Economics (CNRS and LERNA) Abstract We consider a risk averse planner who has access to

More information

Econ 204A: Section 3

Econ 204A: Section 3 Econ 204A: Section 3 Ryan Sherrard University of California, Santa Barbara 18 October 2016 Sherrard (UCSB) Section 3 18 October 2016 1 / 19 Notes on Problem Set 2 Total Derivative Review sf (k ) = (δ +

More information

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. Ph.D. Core Exam -- Macroeconomics 5 January 2015 -- 8:00 am to 3:00 pm Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. A1 (required): Ending Quantitative Easing Now that the U.S.

More information

Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization

Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization Yulei Luo Economics, HKU November 13, 2017 Luo, Y. (Economics, HKU) ECON0703: ME November 13, 2017 1 / 43 The Nature of Optimal Control In static optimization,

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction Dynamic Optimization An Introduction M. C. Sunny Wong University of San Francisco University of Houston, June 20, 2014 Outline 1 Background What is Optimization? EITM: The Importance of Optimization 2

More information

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Government Purchases and Endogenous Growth Consider the following endogenous growth model with government purchases (G) in continuous time. Government purchases enhance production, and the production

More information

Schumpeterian Growth Models

Schumpeterian Growth Models Schumpeterian Growth Models Yin-Chi Wang The Chinese University of Hong Kong November, 2012 References: Acemoglu (2009) ch14 Introduction Most process innovations either increase the quality of an existing

More information

Endogenous Growth: AK Model

Endogenous Growth: AK Model Endogenous Growth: AK Model Prof. Lutz Hendricks Econ720 October 24, 2017 1 / 35 Endogenous Growth Why do countries grow? A question with large welfare consequences. We need models where growth is endogenous.

More information

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013) The Ramsey Model (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 213) 1 Introduction The Ramsey model (or neoclassical growth model) is one of the prototype models in dynamic macroeconomics.

More information

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form: Practice Questions for Mid-Term I Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form: y f(k) = k α ; α (0, 1) (1) where y and k are output per worker and capital per worker respectively.

More information

Monetary Policy and Equilibrium Indeterminacy in a Cash in Advance Economy with Investment. Abstract

Monetary Policy and Equilibrium Indeterminacy in a Cash in Advance Economy with Investment. Abstract Monetary Policy and Equilibrium Indeterminacy in a Cash in Advance Economy with Investment Chong Kee Yip Department of Economics, The Chinese University of Hong Kong Ka Fai Li Department of Economics,

More information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers September 6, 016 ONLINE APPENDIX In this Appendix we present in full additional results and extensions which are only mentioned in the paper. In the exposition

More information

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ryoji Ohdoi Dept. of Industrial Engineering and Economics, Tokyo Tech This lecture note is mainly based on Ch. 8 of Acemoglu

More information

In the Ramsey model we maximized the utility U = u[c(t)]e nt e t dt. Now

In the Ramsey model we maximized the utility U = u[c(t)]e nt e t dt. Now PERMANENT INCOME AND OPTIMAL CONSUMPTION On the previous notes we saw how permanent income hypothesis can solve the Consumption Puzzle. Now we use this hypothesis, together with assumption of rational

More information

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 41 I Motivation This Lecture introduces the basic

More information

Battery Energy Storage

Battery Energy Storage Battery Energy Storage Implications for Load Shapes and Forecasting April 28, 2017 TOPICS» What is Energy Storage» Storage Market, Costs, Regulatory Background» Behind the Meter (BTM) Battery Storage Where

More information

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t ) 6. Economic growth Let us recall the main facts on growth examined in the first chapter and add some additional ones. (1) Real output (per-worker) roughly grows at a constant rate (i.e. labor productivity

More information

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty 1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty Sofarwehaveassumedawayaggregatefluctuations (i.e., business cycles) in our description of the incomplete-markets economies with uninsurable idiosyncratic risk

More information

IMA Preprint Series # 2373

IMA Preprint Series # 2373 BATTERY STORAGE CONTROL FOR STEADYING RENEWABLE POWER GENERATION By Shengyuan (Mike) Chen, Emilie Danna, Kory Hedman, Mark Iwen, Wei Kang, John Marriott, Anders Nottrott, George Yin, and Qing Zhang IMA

More information

Optimal Demand Response

Optimal Demand Response Optimal Demand Response Libin Jiang Steven Low Computing + Math Sciences Electrical Engineering Caltech Oct 2011 Outline Caltech smart grid research Optimal demand response Global trends 1 Exploding renewables

More information

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Equilibrium in a Production Economy Equilibrium in a Production Economy Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2012 Sims (ND) Equilibrium in a Production Economy Fall 2012 1 / 23 Production Economy Last time: studied equilibrium in

More information

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen October 15, 2013 Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen () Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations October 15, 2013 1 / 43 Introduction

More information

"0". Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides

0. Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides Monetary Policy, 7/3 2018 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen "0". Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides 1. Money in the utility function (start) a. The basic

More information

Topic 8: Optimal Investment

Topic 8: Optimal Investment Topic 8: Optimal Investment Yulei Luo SEF of HKU November 22, 2013 Luo, Y. SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 1 / 22 Demand for Investment The importance of investment. First, the combination of

More information

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Endogenous Growth with Human Capital Consider the following endogenous growth model with both physical capital (k (t)) and human capital (h (t)) in continuous time. The representative household solves

More information

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010 Session 4: Jean November 2010 I So far, focused on real economy. Real quantities consumed, produced, invested. No money, no nominal in uences. I Now, introduce nominal dimension in the economy. First and

More information

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models Daron Acemoglu MIT September 12, 2007 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Advanced Growth Lecture 3 September 12, 2007 1 / 40 Introduction

More information

Battery Storage Control for Steadying Renewable Power Generation

Battery Storage Control for Steadying Renewable Power Generation Battery Storage Control for Steadying Renewable Power Generation Shengyuan (Mike) Chen, Emilie Danna, Kory Hedman, Mark Iwen, Wei Kang, John Marriott, Anders Nottrott, George Yin, Qing Zhang March 13,

More information

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj Macro II (UC3M, MA/PhD Econ) Professor: Matthias Kredler Problem Set 1 Due: 29 April 216 You are encouraged to work in groups; however, every student has to hand in his/her own version of the solution.

More information

APPENDIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital?

APPENDIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital? APPENIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital? Santanu Chatterjee epartment of Economics Terry College of Business University of eorgia Appendix A The appendix describes the optimization problem

More information

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2015 1 / 36 Production Economy Last time: studied equilibrium in an endowment economy Now: study equilibrium in an economy

More information

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1 Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm February 25, 2007 Problem : Pareto Optimality The planner solves the following problem: u(c ) + u(c 2 ) + v(l ) + v(l 2 ) () {c,c 2,l,l

More information

2007/8. The Problem of Non-Renewable Energy Pesources in the Production of Physical Capital. Agustin PEREZ-BARAHONA

2007/8. The Problem of Non-Renewable Energy Pesources in the Production of Physical Capital. Agustin PEREZ-BARAHONA 2007/8 The Problem of Non-Renewable Energy Pesources in the Production of Physical Capital. Agustin PEREZ-BARAHONA CORE DISCUSSION PAPER 2007/8 The problem of non-renewable energy resources in the production

More information

Should we extract the European shale gas? The effect of climate and financial constraints

Should we extract the European shale gas? The effect of climate and financial constraints Should we extract the European shale gas? The effect of climate and financial constraints Fanny Henriet, Katheline Schubert To cite this version: Fanny Henriet, Katheline Schubert. Should we extract the

More information

Endogenous Information Choice

Endogenous Information Choice Endogenous Information Choice Lecture 7 February 11, 2015 An optimizing trader will process those prices of most importance to his decision problem most frequently and carefully, those of less importance

More information

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4 Solow Growth Model Michael Bar February 28, 208 Contents Introduction 2. Some facts about modern growth........................ 3.2 Questions..................................... 4 2 The Solow Model 5

More information

SGZ Macro Week 3, Lecture 2: Suboptimal Equilibria. SGZ 2008 Macro Week 3, Day 1 Lecture 2

SGZ Macro Week 3, Lecture 2: Suboptimal Equilibria. SGZ 2008 Macro Week 3, Day 1 Lecture 2 SGZ Macro Week 3, : Suboptimal Equilibria 1 Basic Points Effects of shocks can be magnified (damped) in suboptimal economies Multiple equilibria (stationary states, dynamic paths) in suboptimal economies

More information

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution Toulouse School of Economics, 2013-2014 M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier Exam Solution This is a 3 hours exam. Class slides and any handwritten material are allowed. You must write legibly.

More information

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Hiroaki Ino Institute of Intellectual Property and Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo [Preliminary

More information

NATURAL RESOURCE ECONOMICS LECTURE PLAN 16: APRIL 21, 2011 Hunt Allcott

NATURAL RESOURCE ECONOMICS LECTURE PLAN 16: APRIL 21, 2011 Hunt Allcott NATURAL RESOURCE ECONOMICS 14.42 LECTURE PLAN 16: APRIL 21, 2011 Hunt Allcott PASTURE 1: OVERVIEW Taxonomy of resources. Question: What are examples of depletable, renewable, and expendable resources?

More information

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods 5. Externalities and Public Goods 5. Externalities and Public Goods Externalities Welfare properties of Walrasian Equilibria rely on the hidden assumption of private goods: the consumption of the good

More information

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014 Comprehensive Exam Macro Spring 2014 Retake August 22, 2014 You have a total of 180 minutes to complete the exam. If a question seems ambiguous, state why, sharpen it up and answer the sharpened-up question.

More information

Wind Generation Curtailment Reduction based on Uncertain Forecasts

Wind Generation Curtailment Reduction based on Uncertain Forecasts Wind Generation Curtailment Reduction based on Uncertain Forecasts A. Alanazi & A. Khodaei University of Denver USA Authors M. Chamana & D. Kushner ComEd USA Presenter Manohar Chamana Introduction Wind

More information

Online Appendix for Slow Information Diffusion and the Inertial Behavior of Durable Consumption

Online Appendix for Slow Information Diffusion and the Inertial Behavior of Durable Consumption Online Appendix for Slow Information Diffusion and the Inertial Behavior of Durable Consumption Yulei Luo The University of Hong Kong Jun Nie Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Eric R. Young University

More information

The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers

The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers joint work with Frederic Murphy Climate Policy and Long Term Decisions-Investment and R&D, Bocconi University, Milan,

More information

Pure or Hybrid?: Policy Options for Renewable Energy 1

Pure or Hybrid?: Policy Options for Renewable Energy 1 15th IAEE European Conference 2017 Pure or Hybrid?: Policy Options for Renewable Energy 1 Ryuta Takashima a Yuta Kamobayashi a Makoto Tanaka b Yihsu Chen c a Department of Industrial Administration, Tokyo

More information

5. Externalities and Public Goods

5. Externalities and Public Goods 5. Externalities and Public Goods Welfare properties of Walrasian Equilibria rely on the hidden assumption of private goods: the consumption of the good by one person has no effect on other people s utility,

More information

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania A Modern Equilibrium Model Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania 1 Household Problem Preferences: max E X β t t=0 c 1 σ t 1 σ ψ l1+γ t 1+γ Budget constraint: c t + k t+1 = w t l t + r t

More information

Trade, Neoclassical Growth and Heterogeneous Firms

Trade, Neoclassical Growth and Heterogeneous Firms Trade, Neoclassical Growth and eterogeneous Firms Julian Emami Namini Department of Economics, University of Duisburg Essen, Campus Essen, Germany Email: emami@vwl.uni essen.de 10th March 2006 Abstract

More information

On Stollery s Maximin Model of Global Warming

On Stollery s Maximin Model of Global Warming On Stollery s Maximin Model of Global Warming A. D. d Autume, J.M. Hartwick and K. Schubert May, 2008 Abstract We characterize a solution to Stollery s analysis of maximin with an exhaustible resource

More information

USAEE/IAEE. Diagnostic metrics for the adequate development of efficient-market baseload natural gas storage capacity.

USAEE/IAEE. Diagnostic metrics for the adequate development of efficient-market baseload natural gas storage capacity. USAEE/IAEE Diagnostic metrics for the adequate development of efficient-market baseload natural gas storage capacity Colorado School of Mines November 13, 2017 Contact: eguzman.phd@gmail.com 1 / 28 Introduction

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Macroeconomics II 2 The real business cycle model. Introduction This model explains the comovements in the fluctuations of aggregate economic variables around their trend.

More information

A Summary of Economic Methodology

A Summary of Economic Methodology A Summary of Economic Methodology I. The Methodology of Theoretical Economics All economic analysis begins with theory, based in part on intuitive insights that naturally spring from certain stylized facts,

More information

Hartwick Rule and utilitarianism when population changes

Hartwick Rule and utilitarianism when population changes Hartwick Rule and utilitarianism when population changes Guillaume Commenge Paris School of Economics and University of Paris Pantheon-Sorbonne October 26, 2010 1 Introduction The main point of this paper

More information

Economic Growth of Insiders and Outsiders of a Climate Agreement: A Theoretical Model

Economic Growth of Insiders and Outsiders of a Climate Agreement: A Theoretical Model Economic Growth of Insiders and Outsiders of a Climate Agreement: A Theoretical Model Michael Rauscher Universität Rostock, ifo-institut, München Paris Accord (sealed Dec., 12 th, 2015 in force Nov. 6

More information

Welfare Equivalent NNP and Habit Formation

Welfare Equivalent NNP and Habit Formation Welfare Equivalent NNP and Habit Formation Thomas Aronsson and Karl-Gustaf Löfgren Department of Economics, Umeå University, SE - 901 87 Umeå, Sweden April 2006 Abstract This note concerns the importance

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics Advanced Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model Micha l Brzoza-Brzezina/Marcin Kolasa Warsaw School of Economics Micha l Brzoza-Brzezina/Marcin Kolasa (WSE) Ad. Macro - Ramsey model 1 / 47 Introduction Authors:

More information

Chapter 9. Natural Resources and Economic Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Chapter 9. Natural Resources and Economic Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko Chapter 9. Natural Resources and Economic Growth Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko Motivation We want to understand growth in the presence of the earth s finite supply of arable land and nonrenewable natural

More information

The effect of learning on membership and welfare in an International Environmental Agreement

The effect of learning on membership and welfare in an International Environmental Agreement Climatic Change (202) 0:499 505 DOI 0007/s0584-0-034-5 The effect of learning on membership and welfare in an International Environmental Agreement Larry Karp Received: 7 March 200 / Accepted: 20 April

More information

Moral Hazard: Part 1. April 9, 2018

Moral Hazard: Part 1. April 9, 2018 Moral Hazard: Part 1 April 9, 2018 Introduction In a standard moral hazard problem, the agent A is characterized by only one type. As with adverse selection, the principal P wants to engage in an economic

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics Advanced Macroeconomics Endogenous Growth Marcin Kolasa Warsaw School of Economics Marcin Kolasa (WSE) Ad. Macro - Endogenous growth 1 / 18 Introduction The Solow and Ramsey models are exogenous growth

More information

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 27 October, 207 Pareto Efficient Allocation Recall the following result: Result An allocation x is Pareto-efficient if and only

More information

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm. max

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm. max Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V31.0013 Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm Question 1. Welfare Theorems (a) There are two households that maximize max i,g 1 + g 2 ) {c i,l i} (1) st : c i w(1

More information

Economics 2010c: Lectures 9-10 Bellman Equation in Continuous Time

Economics 2010c: Lectures 9-10 Bellman Equation in Continuous Time Economics 2010c: Lectures 9-10 Bellman Equation in Continuous Time David Laibson 9/30/2014 Outline Lectures 9-10: 9.1 Continuous-time Bellman Equation 9.2 Application: Merton s Problem 9.3 Application:

More information

Eco Spring 2002 Chris Sims OLG EXERCISES

Eco Spring 2002 Chris Sims OLG EXERCISES Eco 504.2 Spring 2002 Chris Sims OLG EXERCISES (1) Suppose in our overlapping generations model the utility function is U ( C 1 (t), ) = log ( C 1 (t) ). Suppose also that instead of being endowed with

More information

Subsidies for Renewable Energies in the Presence of Learning Effects and Market Power

Subsidies for Renewable Energies in the Presence of Learning Effects and Market Power Subsidies for Renewable Energies in the Presence of Learning Effects and Market Power Department of Economics,, Germany Centre for Energy and Environmental Markets, UNSW Public Seminar 28.04.2010 Motivation

More information

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction The New Keynesian Model: Introduction Vivaldo M. Mendes ISCTE Lisbon University Institute 13 November 2017 (Vivaldo M. Mendes) The New Keynesian Model: Introduction 13 November 2013 1 / 39 Summary 1 What

More information

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition Chapter 4: Anticipation effects and economic policy BJ Heijdra Department of Economics, Econometrics & Finance University of Groningen 1 September 2009

More information

Problem 1 (30 points)

Problem 1 (30 points) Problem (30 points) Prof. Robert King Consider an economy in which there is one period and there are many, identical households. Each household derives utility from consumption (c), leisure (l) and a public

More information

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017 Lecture 15 Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017 Universidad de Costa Rica EC3201 - Teoría Macroeconómica 2 Table of contents

More information

Planning a 100 percent renewable electricity system

Planning a 100 percent renewable electricity system Planning a 100 percent renewable electricity system Andy Philpott Electric Power Optimization Centre University of Auckland www.epoc.org.nz (Joint work with Michael Ferris) INI Open for Business Meeting,

More information

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 36 I Motivation This Lecture considers some applications

More information

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology Daron Acemoglu MIT October 3, 2007 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Advanced Growth Lecture 8 October 3,

More information

Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM

Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM This is a 90-minute exam. Answer all three questions, each of which is worth 30 points. You can get partial credit for partial answers. Do not spend disproportionate

More information

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model Virginia Sánchez-Marcos Macroeconomics, MIE-UNICAN Macroeconomics (MIE-UNICAN) A simple macro dynamic model with

More information

+ τ t R t 1B t 1 + M t 1. = R t 1B t 1 + M t 1. = λ t (1 + γ f t + γ f t v t )

+ τ t R t 1B t 1 + M t 1. = R t 1B t 1 + M t 1. = λ t (1 + γ f t + γ f t v t ) Eco504, Part II Spring 2006 C. Sims FTPL WITH MONEY 1. FTPL WITH MONEY This model is that of Sims (1994). Agent: [ ] max E β t log C t {C t,m t,b t } t=0 s.t. C t (1 + γ f (v t )) + M t + B t + τ t R t

More information

«Optimal Regime Switching and Threshold Effects: Theory and Application to a Resource Extraction Problem under Irreversibility»

«Optimal Regime Switching and Threshold Effects: Theory and Application to a Resource Extraction Problem under Irreversibility» «Optimal Regime Switching and Threshold Effects: Theory and Application to a Resource Extraction Problem under Irreversibility» Raouf BOUCEKKINE Aude POMMERET Fabien PRIEUR DR n 2012-14 Optimal regime

More information

On pollution and R&D-based growth in a trade model between countries concerned and unconcerned about climate change

On pollution and R&D-based growth in a trade model between countries concerned and unconcerned about climate change On pollution and R&D-based growth in a trade model between countries concerned and unconcerned about climate change Francisco Cabo 1 Guiomar Martín-Herrán 1 M.Pilar Martínez-García 2 1 IMUVa, Dpt. Economía

More information

Power Engineering II. Fundamental terms and definitions

Power Engineering II. Fundamental terms and definitions Fundamental terms and definitions Power engineering A scientific discipline that focuses on: Generation of electrical energy (EE) Transmission and distribution of EE Consumption of EE Power grid operation

More information

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter 013 Test 1 February 1, 013 Answer ALL Questions Time Allowed: 1 hour 0 min Attention: Please write your answers on the answer book provided Use the right-side pages

More information

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models 4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models Basic Economic Models In Economics, we use theoretical models to explain the economic processes in the real world. These models de ne a relation

More information

Theoretical premises of the Keynesian approach

Theoretical premises of the Keynesian approach origin of Keynesian approach to Growth can be traced back to an article written after the General Theory (1936) Roy Harrod, An Essay in Dynamic Theory, Economic Journal, 1939 Theoretical premises of the

More information

Chapter 10 Skill biased technological change

Chapter 10 Skill biased technological change Chapter 10 Skill biased technological change O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos Computational Economics: a concise introduction O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos Computational Economics 1 / 29 Overview 1 Introduction

More information

Blocking Development

Blocking Development Blocking Development Daron Acemoglu Department of Economics Massachusetts Institute of Technology October 11, 2005 Taking Stock Lecture 1: Institutions matter. Social conflict view, a useful perspective

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano January 5, 2018 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand.

More information