Trade, Neoclassical Growth and Heterogeneous Firms

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Trade, Neoclassical Growth and Heterogeneous Firms"

Transcription

1 Trade, Neoclassical Growth and eterogeneous Firms Julian Emami Namini Department of Economics, University of Duisburg Essen, Campus Essen, Germany essen.de 10th March 2006 Abstract This paper extends the heterogeneous firms model by Melitz 2003, as it combines a two factor/two country neoclassical Ramsey growth model with Melitz intra industry trade model. eterogeneity across firms refers here to the capital intensity in production at given relative factor prices. This paper demonstrates that the key result of Melitz 2003 with respect to the gains from trade does not hold when the countries capital endowments are endogenized. Most importantly, depending on the magnitude of variable and fixed export costs, exposure to international trade may change the average firm s capital intensity in either direction. The subsequent increase decrease in the country s total capital endowment increases decreases the country s steady state welfare. owever, by including the adjustment path to the new steady state a negative positive overall welfare effect of exposure to trade may result. Consequently, exposure to trade may reduce welfare due to heterogeneity across firms. In contrast to Melitz 2003, this model is therefore able to provide a rationale for an import tariff. JEL classification: F12, L11 Keywords: Intra industry trade, firm heterogeneity, firm dynamics, neoclassical growth model The working paper version is downloadable at essen.de/dt/int/emami. I would like to thank Volker Clausen, Eckhard Janeba, James Markusen and arald Uhlig for helpful comments. All errors are mine. 1

2 Non technical summary International trade theory has recently been extended by the new new trade theory cf. Baldwin/Forslid 2004 for this labeling. The new new trade theory allows for heterogeneity across firms and is formalized by, among others, Melitz 2003, Baldwin/Forslid 2004, Bernard et al and Falvey et al The results of these new new models share one central feature: opening up a country to international trade leads to an overall welfare gain due to a factor reallocation towards the more productive firms. Previous trade models without firm heterogeneity therefore underestimated the potential gains from trade. owever, these new new models are static in the sense that they neglect the special features which arise from an endogenous factor accumulation in a neoclassical growth model. Therefore, this paper extends the Melitz 2003 intra industry trade model to a two country Ramsey growth model with capital and labor as factors of production. eterogeneity across firms refers here to the capital intensity in production at given relative factor prices. As in Melitz 2003, countries are symmetric. This paper starts by making four propositions. First, in this dynamic model the total capital endowment of a country always adjusts to the capital intensity of the average firm. Second, the relative price of labor is larger than unity for a sufficiently low time discount and capital depreciation rate, i. e., for a capital rich country. Since fixed production costs exist, firms therefore only start to produce if the capital intensity, which is a random variable, exceeds a threshold value. If, in addition, fixed export costs exist, a firm exports only if its capital intensity exceeds a second and higher threshold value. Third, total production of the potential exporters remains constant in the short run: if a country opens up to trade, the exporters produce more, but their number falls proportionately. The country s average capital intensity therefore does not change with exposure to trade per se. Fourth, an increase decrease in the average capital intensity increases decreases steady state welfare of a country. The main part of this paper analyzes the steady state consequences of exposure to international trade. The capital intensity of the average firm in any country is determined by its free entry and exit condition: the present value of expected variable profits minus expected fixed costs in future periods has to equal the one time market entry costs. Exposure to trade influences this free entry and exit condition via two channels: first, additional demand from abroad raises the expected variable profits in future periods; second, serving the foreign market increases the expected fixed costs 1

3 in future periods. The relative magnitude of both channels depends on the size of the variable and/or fixed export costs. igher variable export costs reduce the additional variable profits from exporting and higher fixed export costs increase the entire fixed costs in future periods. Given that the variable and/or fixed export costs are large, so that the second channel dominates the first, exposure to trade reduces the present value of the expected total profits of the average firm. The probability of a successful market entry therefore must increase, so that the present value of the expected total profits of the market entry exactly equal the one time market entry costs again. This result is equivalent to a decrease in the average capital intensity. Both countries lose in steady state welfare. This outcome is in sharp contrast to previous models. In Melitz 2003 with only one factor of production, firms do not differ with respect to the factor intensity, but with respect to the factor productivity. Consequently, exposure to trade increases the total amount the more productive exporters produce, while the least productive firms are forced to exit the market due to scarce resources. Therefore, exposure to trade always increases the expected total profits of the average firm, irrespective of the magnitude of the fixed export costs. The probability of a successful market entry therefore always has to decrease in Melitz This result is analogous to an increase in the average labor productivity, which benefits all countries. owever, if the variable and/or fixed export costs are small in the present model, exposure to trade increases the present value of the expected total profits of the average firm. The previously mentioned line of argument simply revolves and both countries gain in steady state welfare due to an increase in the average capital intensity. This result is in line with Melitz The comparative steady state analysis is augmented by a numerical simulation which takes into account the adjustment path to the new steady state as well. Under the chosen parameterization, the inclusion of the adjustment path leads to a negative positive overall welfare effect of exposure to trade, although the new steady state is more less favorable than the old steady state. Nevertheless, this paper shows that a positive optimum tariff may exist due to heterogeneity across firms. 2

4 1 Introduction Standard new trade theory excludes heterogeneity across firms. Consequently, the welfare effects of international trade are unambiguous: removing trade barriers increases a country s welfare due either to economies of scale or a love of variety effect. Very recently, however, new new trade models were developed. 1 These models assume that countries are endowed only with labor. They extend the new trade models by including heterogeneity with respect to the labor productivity across firms into Krugman s 1980 intra industry trade model. Two further assumptions are central to these new new models: first, firms do not come to know their productivity until they enter the market and pay a fixed market entry cost. Second, it is presumed that additional fixed production and export costs exist. These two assumptions trigger an endogenous firm selection mechanism when a country opens up to international trade. As exporting is costly, only the more productive firms will export. The less productive firms produce only for the home market. Therefore, exposure to trade leads to an increasing demand for resources. Real factor rewards rise and force the least productive firms to exit the market. Trade liberalization accordingly increases a country s average productivity. This increase in productivity provides an alternative source for gains from trade. Moreover, these new new trade models are able to explain certain empirical regularities. Recent econometric studies have shown that firms producing identical or similar goods exhibit substantial heterogeneity with respect to the technologies they use. In this context, exporters are generally shown to use more advanced technologies. More advanced technologies is interpreted as producing with a higher labor productivity. 2 This paper, in contrast, assumes two factors of production, capital and labor. A more advanced technology now denotes a higher capital intensity at given relative factor prices. If the analyzed countries are capital rich in the sense that the relative price of labor exceeds unity, it is still true that only firms with more advanced technologies self select into the export market. Furthermore, this paper assumes endogenous capital accumulation: while the countries capital endowments are fixed in the short run, they may change in the long run. More specifically, the steady state of a neoclassical growth model with heterogeneous firms and intra industry trade between two identical countries will be analyzed. All other central components of the model are adopted from Melitz 2003, Baldwin/Forslid 2004 and Falvey et al Most importantly, firms face uncertainty 1 See, e. g., Melitz 2003, Baldwin/Forslid 2004, Bernard et al and Falvey et al See Bernard/Jensen 1999, Aw et al and Girma et al

5 about their capital intensity before market entry. Market entry leads to one time fixed costs, serving the home market and exporting, respectively, to per period fixed costs. This paper shows that the key result of Melitz 2003 with respect to the gains from trade does not hold in the present setup. If firms differ with respect to the factor intensity in this two factor model instead of the labor productivity in the previous single factor models, exposure to trade does not change the total amount the technologically more advanced exporters produce: each single exporting firm produces more, but their mass decreases proportionately with exposure to trade due to fixed resources in the short run. Depending on the magnitude of fixed and variable export costs, exposure to trade therefore may increase or decrease the average firm s total profit over the entire model horizon. Since fixed market entry costs exist, the probability of a successful market entry has to adjust such that the average firm s free entry and exit condition holds again. This probability of a successful market entry is directly linked to the average capital intensity. owever, as the average capital intensity affects welfare, a country may lose from exposure to trade due to heterogeneity across firms. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the setup of the model. Section 3 derives the equilibrium for the closed economy. Section 4 deals with the open economy. Subsection 4.1 describes the first selection process with exposure to trade, which analyzes the consequences of exposure to trade for the established firms. Subsection 4.1 also emphasizes the crucial difference from the corresponding first selection process in Melitz Subsection 4.2 describes the equilibrium in the open economy. Subsection 4.3 describes the second selection process with exposure to trade, which finally allows potential entrants to enter the market. Subsection 4.4 analyzes the consequences of exposure to trade for steady state welfare. Section 5 provides a numerical analysis, which includes the adjustment path to the new steady state. Section 6 concludes. 2 Basic model The steady states of two countries, the home country and the foreign country F, are analyzed. Both countries are endowed with two factors of production, labor L and capital K, which are used to produce one differentiated good. The labor endowment is assumed to be constant over time. As countries and F are completely identical, the country index is initially omitted. Furthermore, since only the steady state is analyzed, the time index is also dropped for the time being. The market for the differentiated good is characterized by Dixit Stiglitz monopolistic competition. 4

6 2.1 Production A single firm i produces a unique variety of the differentiated good with the following modified CES production function q i 1/α, φ α i L α i + 1 φ i α Ki α 1 where L i and K i denote the labor and capital inputs for firm i. This modified CES production function yields the calibrated share form of the per unit cost function if all absolute prices are equal to unity. This calibrated share form of the cost function is taken from applied general equilibrium theory and simplifies further calculations considerably since only the firms cost functions will be used. The parameter φ i denotes different technologies across firms. Firm i accordingly has the per unit cost function c i φ i w φ i r 1 1/1, 2 with w and r denoting the wage rate and the capital rental rate. The parameter represents the elasticity of substitution in production, which is given by 1/1 α. Furthermore, serving the domestic market leads to fixed costs f, which are produced with the same technology as the good itself. The magnitude of these fixed costs is identical across all firms. Given Dixit Stiglitz preferences for the representative household, the profit maximizing price of firm i is given by p i 1 1/ c i φ i, where stands for the elasticity of substitution in the representative household s utility function. For simplicity, the firms production function and the household s utility function share an identical value for. Furthermore, the number of firms is assumed to reach infinity. 2.2 Demand Intratemporal preferences of the representative household are described by a CES love of variety utility function over the varieties of the differentiated good. function leads to the following revenue function for a single firm i: R i φ i P Q This utility p i φ i /P 1, 3 where P p i iφ i 1 dφ i + p j jφ j τ 1 dφ j 1/1 denotes the aggregate price index and Q q i iφ i α dφ i + q j jφ j /τ α dφ j 1/α the aggregated consumption good. The index j stands for the foreign varieties supplied to the home market and τ, τ 1, denotes iceberg transport costs. 5

7 2.3 Aggregation In each country, a continuum of heterogeneous firms in the differentiated goods sector exists. In order to keep the model still tractable, the mass of heterogeneous firms is aggregated to a mass of average firms. Aggregation proceeds in two steps. First, the production side is analyzed. It can be shown that the following two versions of the model lead to identical absolute factor prices and total factor income: 3 Version 1 the disaggregated model A mass N of heterogeneous firms produces according to the following per unit cost function: cφ i φ i w φ i r 1 1/1, with φi [0, 1], while the demand for each single variety is given by q D i P Q P 1 pφ i ; Version 2 the aggregated model A mass function: c φ Ñ of average firms produces according to the following per unit cost φ w φ 1/1, 1 r 1 with φ gφdφ φ, where gφ is the distribution function for φ, which is assumed to be uniformly distributed over the interval [0, 1]. Each average firm s demand is given by q D M C /Ñ c φ / 1. M C denotes total factor income which is available for consumption and equals P Q in the disaggregated model. The share parameters φ and 1 φ will be labelled in the following as average labor intensity and average capital intensity, respectively. Second, if both versions of the model lead to identical general equilibrium factor prices and total factor income, the aggregated model has to be extended by a Dixit Stiglitz demand side. The equilibrium mass of average firms Ñ is determined by a free entry and exit condition of the average firm, which is given by f 1 q D. 4 costs f are identical across firms. 0 The fixed 3 See Appendix A for a detailed description of the aggregation procedure. 4 Even if the free entry and exit condition is always fulfilled for the average firm in the aggregated model, the free entry and exit condition need not be fulfilled for each type of firm in the disaggregated model. As the production technologies differ across firms in the disaggregated model, the free entry and exit condition can be violated for certain firms if w r. For example, if f 1 < p i P 1 P Q for firms of type i, these firms produce too much and their number is too small for the free entry and exit condition of firms of type i to be fulfilled. 6

8 2.4 Dynamic structure This paper endogenizes each country s long run capital endowment by means of the Ramsey growth model. In the short run, however, each country s capital endowment is fixed. Both countries labor endowment is fixed in the short and in the long run. Let the parameter t denote any single time period. Each household has an infinite time horizon. The representative household in each country maximizes its lifetime utility 1 U 1 + ρ uq t, 4 t t0 subject to the production technologies and the factor endowments in each period. The parameter ρ denotes the time discount rate and u the intratemporal utility function. Each country s total capital endowment in period t, K t, depends on the capital stock in period t 1, K t 1, investment in t 1, I t 1, and the per period depreciation rate δ: K t 1 δ K t 1 + I t 1. Furthermore, the average firm s good is used for investment. When the dual to this restricted maximization problem is formulated, the dynamic general equilibrium for the economy is defined by several zero profit and market clearing conditions. Most importantly, the zero profit condition for investment, the zero profit condition for the average good and the zero profit condition for the capital rental activity by households, which is the Euler equation, already determine relative factor prices in the steady state. Furthermore, in order to simplify further calculations without changing the general results, the following assumption is made: A1: The elasticity of substitution is set equal to 2. The relative wage rate and the capital rental rate in the steady state then simplify to 5 w t r t φ ρ + δ 1 + φ and r t w t ρ + δ 1 + φ. φ In order to guarantee that the relative price of labor is positive and, at the same time, larger than unity, two further assumptions are made: A2: ρ + δ > 1 φ and A3: 1 > ρ + δ. A3 implies that per unit production costs decline if the capital intensity increases. 6 As only steady states will be analyzed and the labor endowment is assumed to be 5 See Appendix B for the derivation of w t /r t in the steady state. The result that w t /r t in the steady state is independent of the factor market equilibrium conditions is originally due to Baxter 1992, pp Concentrating on the steady state therefore simplifies the analysis considerably. 6 A3 is critical for the model results in the sense that they would just reverse if the relative price of labor were smaller than unity. The impact of A3 will become clear in subsection 2.5, which describes the dynamic entry and exit process of firms. 7

9 constant over time, the index t can henceforth be dropped. It can be shown that all aggregate variables of the model now depend only on ρ and δ, the average labor intensity φ, the wage rate w and the country s labor endowment L: price of the average good: p φ w ρ + δ 1 + φ φ ρ + δ country s capital endowment: K 1 φ r 1 L φ φ w ρ + δ 1 + φ L 2 factor income: M ρ + δ w L + r K w L ρ + δ 1 + φ aggregate production: φα L α + 1 φ α K α 1/α L φ ρ + δ 2 ρ + δ 1 + φ 2 aggregate investment: I δ K δ 1 φ φ ρ + δ 1 + φ 2 L disposable factor income: M C w L + r K I w L ρ + δ δ 1 φ ρ + δ 1 + φ, where also contains the production of fixed costs. Labor is chosen as the numéraire and w is set equal to unity for both countries, as countries are symmetric Firm entry and exit The monopolistically competitive sector is populated by an unbounded mass of potential entrants into the market. Entering the market in t instantaneously requires an irreversible investment of f, which is included in the model as a fixed one time market entry cost. Each firm produces f with an identical technology as the respective good itself. After the firm entered the market, it has to draw in t its labor intensity φ from a common exogenous cumulative distribution for φ, which is given by G. After a firm gets to know its labor intensity φ, it either starts producing in t + 1 or it exits the market. The firm starts producing if φ is sufficiently small, i. e., if the capital intensity 1 φ is sufficiently large. Due to a relative wage rate larger than unity, total per period profits are positive only for a sufficiently large capital intensity. owever, if the capital intensity is small, the firm immediately exits the market. In every period, each firm may be hit by a negative technology shock with probability θ, 0 < θ < 1. If 7 In fact, labor can be chosen as numéraire for one period only. Accordingly, the wage rate can be set equal to unity for one period only as well. The present value of both factor prices in the steady state then declines with the discount factor 1/1 + ρ. owever, as only the model s steady state is analyzed in chapters 3 and 4, this simplification does not affect the model s quantity variables. 8

10 a firm is hit by such a shock, it immediately exits the market. 8 This type of market entry and exit decision establishes the threshold value for the labor intensity and, therefore, the probability of a successful market entry. All firms with a labor intensity exceeding the threshold value exit the market immediately and never start producing, as variable per period profits do not cover fixed per period costs. All firms with a lower labor intensity are at least able to cover the fixed per period costs and start producing. The threshold value of the labor intensity is denoted by φ. Due to the uniform distribution of φ, the probability of a successful market entry is likewise given by φ, and the labor intensity of the average active firm is given by φ φ /2. 3 Equilibrium in the closed economy The steady state equilibrium of the closed economy is identical to the one in a standard one sector Ramsey growth model with given technologies. The present model therefore is extended by further equations which determine the average labor intensity φ. First, the per period zero profit condition Z.P.C. defines the threshold labor intensity φ : Rφ q D φ cφ Rφ f cφ, 5 where q D φ denotes demand for the variety, which is produced with the labor intensity φ. This Z.P.C. states that the variable per period profits of a firm with the threshold labor intensity, Rφ /, have to equal the per period fixed costs of this firm, f cφ. owever, Rφ/ < f cφ results if a firm draws a labor intensity exceeding φ. Total per period profits would accordingly be negative and could not cover the one time fixed market entry costs f cφ. The firm producing with φ is called marginal firm. All firms with a labor intensity smaller than φ are characterized by Rφ/ > f cφ. Second, if market entry and exit are unrestricted, the average firm s present value of expected total profits over the entire model horizon has to equal the one time fixed market entry costs. This free entry and exit F.E.C. condition can be written as Gφ R φ f M + Gφ f c φ, 6 where f M denotes the per period equivalent of the one time fixed market entry costs and is implicitly defined by f f M /ρ + µ + ρ µ, µ θ/1 θ, as the firm has 8 The negative shock guarantees that in every period a constant amount of fixed market entry costs arises in the steady state. This sequence of the market entry and exit decision is adopted from openhayn 1992 and Melitz

11 an infinite lifetime as well. 9 G denotes the distribution function for φ. Gφ therefore equals the probability that φ falls below the threshold value φ and that the firm starts producing, i. e., that both variable profits and per period fixed costs occur. Finally, the relationship between the equilibrium mass of firms, Ñ, and the amount produced by the average firm q φ is given by the aggregate production function φ ρ + δ 2 Ñ q φ L 1 1/, 7 ρ + δ 1 + φ 2 where the fraction 1/ of aggregate production is used to produce fixed costs. Equations 5 7 determine the equilibrium values for q φ, Ñ and φ in autarky. Both the zero profit condition 5 and the free entry and exit condition 6 can be further simplified. Profit maximizing behavior of firms implies that marginal costs equal marginal revenue, i. e., p 1 1/ cφ. The relationship between the amount produced by the marginal firm, qφ, and the average firm, q φ, is given by qφ q φ pφ P 1 M C p φ P pφ 1 M C p φ 2 p φ, 8 pφ where the last equality follows from A1. Inserting the respective equilibrium prices gives: 10 qφ q φ w ρ + δ 1 + φ/ φ ρ + δ w ρ + δ 1 + φ/2 φ ρ + δ φ ρ + δ 1. 9 ρ + δ This equation shows that q φ > qφ, as ρ + δ > 2 ρ + δ 1 is fulfilled due to 1 > ρ + δ by A3. Substituting Rφ pφ qφ / 1 cφ qφ into equation 5 and considering that qφ q φ 2 ρ + δ 1/ρ + δ 2 from equation 9 and 2 from A1 gives the following simplified per period Z.P.C. for the marginal firm: 2 2 ρ + δ 1 q φ f. 10 ρ + δ 9 The parameter θ denotes the probability of a negative shock in each period. The negative shock forces the firm to exit the market immediately. Accordingly, the firm reaches period T with probability 1 θ T 1. The discounted value of the periodic equivalent of the fixed market entry costs in period t, 1/1 + ρ t f M, therefore only occurs with probability 1 θ t. Defining 1/1 + µ 1 θ, which is equivalent to µ θ/1 θ, gives f f M /ρ + µ + ρ µ from the formula of an infinite geometric series. f M obviously increases with the probability of a negative shock. 10 The price of the average good p φ is defined in subsection 2.4. The price of the marginal good pφ results from substituting r t, which is derived in subsection 2.4, into the cost function 2. 10

12 Furthermore, inserting Gφ φ, R φ p φ q φ / 1 c φ q φ and 2 into equation 6 results in the following F.E.C. of the average firm: q φ f M + f φ Therefore, the equilibrium in autarky is described by the following system of equations: 2 ρ + δ Z.P.C.: q φ f 12 2 ρ + δ 1 F.E.C.: q φ f M + f 13 2 φ φ ρ + δ 2 aggregate production: Ñ q φ L 1 1/. 14 ρ + δ 1 + φ 2 The zero profit condition shows that the amount produced by the average firm only depends on the model parameters. An increase in the labor endowment therefore only increases the mass of average firms. 4 Equilibrium in the open economy As both countries are symmetric, only the home country will be analyzed in detail. Country now opens up to international markets and can trade the differentiated good with the foreign country F. Exporting leads to two types of extra costs. First, iceberg transport costs τ, τ 1, may exist. Second, a firm has to pay additional fixed per period costs f Ex for serving the foreign market. The dynamic entry and exit process of firms remains unchanged. Firms which enter the market have to pay one time sunk costs of f. Afterwards, firms draw their labor intensity φ and decide whether to exit the market or to start producing. owever, given that τ is sufficiently large and/or the fixed per period costs for exporting exceed the fixed per period costs for serving the home market, not all firms find it profitable to export. Therefore, a second and lower threshold value for φ exists. This second value determines whether a firm which already serves the domestic market exports as well. Again, in every period, each firm may be hit by a negative technology shock with probability θ, 0 < θ < 1. This shock forces the firm to exit the market. The firm selection process with exposure to trade must be split up into two steps. The first selection process analyzes how exposure to trade influences the established firms. After the first selection process is completed, all potential entrants observe how 11

13 exposure to trade influenced the established firms. The second firm selection process is triggered by the subsequent entry decision of potential entrants: if exposure to trade benefits harms the average established firm, the mass of new entrants will be larger smaller than the mass of shock induced firm exits. It is assumed that both the first and the second firm selection process with exposure to trade are completed within a single time period. The first selection process is described in subsection 4.1, the second selection process is described in subsection First selection process with exposure to trade The first selection process in the present two factor model differs crucially from the first selection process in the single factor models by Melitz 2003 and Falvey et al Moreover, it is the specific first selection process which drives the difference between the present model s results and those of Melitz 2003 and Falvey et al With respect to the production side, opening the country up to international trade is equivalent to an increase in the fixed costs of the exporting firms. These exporting firms also face an additional demand from abroad. owever, firms start exporting only if R F φ/ f Ex cφ, i. e., if additional variable profits from serving the foreign market R F φ/ at least cover the additional fixed export costs. The average exporting firm therefore always gains with exposure to trade. owever, if each exporting firm produces a larger amount than in autarky, some firms must exit the market since resources are fixed in the short run. But which firms will exit the market, the more capital intensive exporting firms or the less capital intensive non exporting firms? If the production of each single exporting firm rises with exposure to trade, both the absolute factor prices and the relative price of capital increase. If p φ denotes the price of the average more capital intensive exporting firm and p φ N the price of the average less capital intensive non exporting firm, p φ /p φ N increases accordingly with exposure to trade. The marginal exporting firms are therefore forced to exit the market due to the existence of fixed per period costs. Moreover, it can be shown that the general equilibrium can be re established only if the mass of exporting firms decreases such that their aggregate production remains constant. 11 Since the aggregate 11 Due to symmetry across countries, total demand of the average exporting firm rises from q φ M C P 1 p φ to q φ M C P 1 Q p φ 1 + τ 1 with exposure to trade. The price index P therefore rises from P ÑN p φ N 1 + Ñ p φ 1 1/1 to P ÑN p φ N 1 + Ñ 1 + τ 1 p φ 1 1/1 with exposure to trade, 12

14 price index P therefore remains constant, the non exporting firms neither gain nor lose during the first selection process. Opening the country up to international trade therefore triggers a selection process against the more capital intensive exporting firms: exposure to trade c. p. increases the production of each single exporting firm, but the increase in p φ /p φ N reduces their number proportionately. The first selection process looks completely different in Melitz 2003 and Falvey et al with only labor as a factor of production. Since exporting leads to additional fixed costs, only the more productive firms serve both the domestic and the foreign market. Exposure to trade increases each exporting firm s total output and total factor demand rises. owever, the resulting increase in the wage rate most adversely affects the least productive non exporting firms. These least productive firms are driven out of the market. The more productive exporting firms produce only a larger amount. 12 The difference between the present two factor model and the single factor models by Melitz 2003 and Falvey et al with respect to the first selection process is illustrated in figure 1. λ represents the labor productivity in the models by Melitz 2003 and Falvey et al A higher value of λ denotes a higher labor productivity. The left panel a illustrates the first selection process with exposure to trade in the present two factor model. The horizontal axis displays the range of the labor intensity φ, which leads to production and to exports, respectively. The vertical axis displays total production Nφ qφ of firms with labor intensity φ. As a lower φ leads to lower per unit costs, all firms with φ [0, φ ] serve the home market and all firms with φ [0, φ ] export as well. Exposure to trade c. p. increases the production of each exporting firm, but decreases their mass proportionately due to fixed resources in the short run. Aggregate production of these firms therefore does not change during the first selection process. Most importantly, aggregate home supply is now produced with a smaller average capital intensity than in autarky since the more capital intensive firms export part of their production in the open economy. The average established firm accordingly has smaller total per period profits from serving the domestic market in the open economy. It will be analyzed below whether the larger total per period profits of the exporting firms can compensate for the loss in the domestic market. The right panel b illustrates the first selection process with exposure to trade in where the subscripts N and denote the mass of non exporting and exporting firms, respectively. P accordingly does not change if Ñ decreases by the factor 1/ 1 + τ 1 with exposure to trade. Factor market equilibrium conditions hold again and the new unique general equilibrium results. 12 Note that the first selection process in the present model is closer to reality than the first selection process in Melitz 2003 and Falvey et al In reality, exporting firms are larger and smaller in number, compared to non exporting firms; cf. U. S. Census Bureau 2006, pp. 511,

15 the single factor model and heterogeneity with respect to the factor productivity. The horizontal axis displays the range of the labor productivity λ, which leads to production and to exports, respectively. The vertical axis displays total production Nλ qλ of firms with technology parameter λ. As a higher λ leads to lower per unit costs, all firms with λ [λ, serve the home market and all firms with λ [λ, export as well. Aggregate production of the more productive firms therefore increases, while aggregate production of the less productive firms decreases during the first selection process. In the single factor model, the average established firm therefore gains with exposure to trade: home supply is produced with a larger productivity and the exporting firms gain with exposure to trade anyway. Figure 1: First selection process with exposure to trade a two factors of production and heterogeneity with respect to factor intensities b one factor of production and heterogeneity with respect to factor productivity total production of firm type N q closed economy total production of firm type N q closed economy * * 0 0 * * sales of more capital intensive firms at home sales of less capital intensive firms at home open economy sales of less productive firms at home open economy sales of more productive firms at home total production of firm type N q sales of more capital intensive firms abroad total production of firm type N q additional sales of more productive firms abroad 0 * * 0 * * smaller sales of more capital intensive firms at home unchanged sales of less capital intensive firms at home the least productive firms exit the market total production of nonexporters declines constant sales of more productive firms at home According to figure 1, the first selection process leaves the average labor intensity φ in the present two factor model constant: since no love of variety effect exists on the production side, aggregating N heterogeneous firms to Ñ average firms as explained in subsection 2.3 does not depend on the mass of firms of each type. Aggregation only depends on aggregate production of each firm type. It will be shown below that 14

16 this initial independence of φ from exposure to trade crucially influences the second selection mechanism and, therefore, how φ finally changes with exposure to trade. 4.2 Equilibrium As exporting is costly, two types of firms may exist in the equilibrium of the open economy. First, firms that serve only the domestic market and second, firms that serve the domestic market and export as well. Again, the threshold value φ determines whether a firm starts production at all after it has entered the market. The additional threshold value φ determines whether a firm also exports. Since partitioning with respect to export status is empirically observable between firms within sectors, the export costs parameters will be chosen such that φ < φ. The threshold values φ and φ are again defined by the respective zero profit condition Z.P.C.: Z.P.C. for production: Z.P.C. for exports: R φ R F φ f cφ 15 f Ex cφ. 16 The firm producing with φ is called marginal firm for the home market. The firm producing with φ is called marginal firm for exports. R F φ / denotes variable profits of the marginal firm for exports from serving the foreign market. Furthermore, the free entry and exit condition F.E.C. has to be adjusted to account for the additional sales abroad and the additional per period fixed export costs. Since the average labor intensity does not change during the first selection process, the foreign sales and the fixed export costs must be evaluated with the average labor intensity over all established firms, both exporters and non exporters. The adjusted F.E.C. is given by Gφ R φ +Gφ RF φ f M +Gφ f +Gφ f Ex c φ, 17 where Gφ denotes the probability that the firm starts producing at all.13 Similarly, Gφ denotes the probability that φ falls below the threshold value φ and that the firm starts exporting. R F φ / stands for the variable profits of the average home 13 Equation 17 differs from the respective F.E.C. in Melitz 2003 and Falvey et al If there is only labor and firms differ with respect to their labor productivity, exposure to trade solely leads to additional sales of the most productive exporting firms and therefore increases their aggregate production. The least productive firms exit the market due to scarce resources, as explained in subsection 4.1. In the single factor case, export sales and fixed export costs are evaluated accordingly with the average labor intensity over the exporting firms only. Appendix C proves that equation 17 is indeed the only feasible way to formulate the F.E.C. in the present two factor case. 15

17 firm from exporting and φ denotes the average labor intensity of the home country. Finally, the relationship between the equilibrium mass of firms, Ñ, and expected total production by the average firm, q φ + Gφ /Gφ q F φ, is given by the aggregate production function Ñ q φ + Gφ Gφ q F φ L 1 1/ φ ρ + δ 2 ρ + δ 1 + φ 2, 18 where q φ denotes domestic supply of the average home firm and q F φ exports of the average home firm. Dividing both Z.P.C. by each other gives R φ R F φ M C P 1 M CF P 1 which is equal to pφ 1 F τ 1 pφ 1 pφ pφ f cφ 19 f Ex cφ, τ 1 fex f since countries are symmetric and p 1 1/ cφ. The ratio of the prices of both marginal firms, pφ /pφ, can be derived as pφ pφ φ w1 + 1 φ r1 1 1 φ w1 + 1 φ r1 1 1 φ + 1 φ φ φ + 1 φ ρ+δ 1+ φ, φ ρ+δ 1+ φ where the second equality follows from the steady state value of w/r as defined in subsection 2.4 and from 2 by A1. Further simplification results in pφ pφ φ ρ + δ φ + φ φ ρ + δ φ + φ ρ + δ φ /φ ρ + δ , where the second equality uses the fact that φ 0.5 φ. Equation 20 therefore can be written alternatively as: pφ pφ 2 φ /φ ρ + δ ρ + δ τ 2 1 fex f. 23 The ratio for the threshold labor intensities, which equals the probability that the average established firm exports, is thus given by: φ φ ρ + δ 0.5 τ 0.5 f Ex /f ρ + δ 1 Therefore, the Z.P.C. for exports will be dropped and the function φ φ φ will be taken instead. Obviously, both φ and φ 16 are positive only if ρ + δ 0.5

18 τ f Ex /f < 0, as 1 > ρ + δ by A3. If τ 0.25 f/ρ + δ f Ex, φ is equal to zero and international trade ceases. Furthermore, φ /φ is smaller than unity, i. e., partitioning with respect to the export status takes place if τ > f/f Ex. The system of equations characterizing the equilibrium in the open economy, equations 15, 17, 18 and 24, can be further simplified. First, consider that p 1 1/ cφ follows from profit maximizing behavior of firms. Second, the ratio of exports to domestic supply is given by q F φ /q φ τ 1 countries. 14 due to symmetry across Third, the domestic supply of the marginal firm for the home market is again determined by the domestic supply of the average firm since q φ /q φ 2 ρ + δ 1 2 /ρ + δ 2 holds again as in autarky. Finally, Gφ /Gφ is equal to φ /φ. The free trade equilibrium values for q φ, φ, φ and Ñ are therefore described by equation 24, together with the following three equations: 2 2 ρ + δ 1 Z.P.C. for production: q φ f 25 ρ + δ F.E.C.: q φ 1 + φ τ 1 φ 1 + f Ex f φ 26 φ f M 2 φ + f aggregate production: Ñ q φ 1 + φ τ 1 φ L 1 1/ φ ρ + δ 2 ρ + δ 1 + φ 2.27 Compared to autarky, the zero profit condition for production did not change. Therefore, the expected domestic supply of any potential entrant, which is produced with the average technology, is not influenced by the first selection process with exposure to trade. Obviously, the F.E.C. is the most critical equation, as it determines the equilibrium average labor intensity φ. The impact of international trade on φ evident if the F.E.C. for both situations are compared: autarky: q φ free trade: q φ 1 + φ φ τ 1 f M 2 φ + f 28 f M 2 φ + f 1 + f Ex f φ.29 φ Given that φ is larger than zero, i. e., φ /φ > 0, exposure to trade alters the average labor intensity φ. This change in φ influences the households investment 14 The variable q F φ denotes exports, i. e., q F φ /τ actually arrives abroad. Therefore, 1 foreign demand for a single domestic variety is given by q F φ /τ M CF P F p φ τ. 17 is

19 behavior and therefore changes the steady state capital endowment of the country. 4.3 Trade and steady state welfare Total welfare of the home country is given by W M C / P. Assuming 2 from A1, the price index P for the home country in autarky and with free trade, respectively, is given by and 1 1 P Aut. Aut. Ñ p φ Aut. P 1 F T Ñ F T p φ F T + ÑF F T φ F p φ F T Ñ F T 1 + φ F φ F p φ Aut. Ñ Aut. φ F τ p φ F F T 30 τ 1 1, 31 where the second equality in 31 follows from symmetry across countries. The superscripts Aut. and FT indicate variables in autarky and with free trade, respectively. Welfare for the home country in autarky and with free trade is therefore given by: M C Aut. W Aut. Ñ Aut. p φ Aut. and W F T M C F T Ñ F T p φ F T 1 + φ F /φ F τ 1. The aggregate production functions, equations 14 and 27, already implicitly specify the general equilibrium number of firms in both situations: L 1 1/ ρ + δ2 q φ Aut. 32 Aut. ρ + δ 1 + φ 2 Ñ Aut. Ñ F T φ Aut. L 1 1/ q φ F T 1 + φ /φ τ 1 φ F T ρ + δ2 ρ + δ 1 + φ F T Inserting these expressions for Ñ Aut. and Ñ F T into the equations for welfare results in W Aut. W F T since φ /φ φ F /φ F φ Aut. φ Aut. M C Aut. p φ Aut. L 1 1/ ρ + δ2 q φ Aut. ρ + δ 1 + M C F T p φ F T L 1 1/ φ F T ρ + δ2 q φ F T ρ + δ 1 + φ F T φ Aut , 35 due to symmetry across countries. Equations 34 and 35 show, if φ F T, welfare with free trade were identical to welfare in autarky. The comparative steady state analysis therefore concentrates on the endowment effect of 18

20 exposure to trade, i. e., on the change of φ due to exposure to trade. It can first be shown that disposable factor income M C increases with a rising average capital intensity 1 φ country s capital stock. 15 since an increase in the average capital intensity raises a This positive effect on M C dominates the negative effect which results from an increase in investment with a rising capital stock. Second, the price of the average good p φ decreases with a rising average capital intensity because the relative price of labor exceeds unity. Finally, the number of varieties as defined by 32 and 33 increases with a rising average capital intensity since q φ Aut. q φ F T, as shown by 12 and 25. An increase in the capital stock therefore raises the number of varieties. In summary, steady state welfare unambiguously increases with a rising average capital intensity. owever, section 5 presents a simulation which includes the adjustment from the old to the new steady state in the welfare evaluation of a rising average capital intensity. 4.4 Second selection process with exposure to trade It finally remains to be analyzed whether the average labor intensity in the steady state increases or decreases during the second selection process. Subsection 4.1 explained that, first, the more capital intensive firms always gain with exposure to trade since a firm starts exporting only if R F φ/ f Ex cφ. Second, that total domestic supply is produced with a smaller average labor intensity after the first selection process since aggregate production of the more capital intensive firms does not change with exposure to trade, but part of their production is exported. The first second effect c. p. increases decreases total per period profits of the average established firm. First, take the case in which the average established firm gains with the first selection process. The mass of new entrants will accordingly be larger than the mass of shock induced firm exits. The average labor intensity of the actually active new entrants is c. p. identical to the average labor intensity of the established firms. The relative price of capital therefore does not change. owever, both absolute factor prices increase, which drives the least capital intensive firms out of the market since their variable per period profits are smallest. The average capital intensity therefore increases during the second selection process in this first case. Second, take the case in which the average established firm loses with the first selection process. The mass of new entrants will accordingly be smaller than the mass of shock induced firm exits. Again, the average labor intensity of the actually active 15 Cf. Appendix D for the derivation of this and the following partial derivatives. 19

21 new entrants is c. p. identical to the average labor intensity of the established firms. The relative price of capital therefore does not change. owever, both absolute factor prices decrease, which provides an incentive for firms to start producing even if they produce with φ > φ. The probability for a successful market entry, which is given by φ, increases accordingly. In this second case, the average capital intensity therefore decreases during the second selection process. In order to evaluate whether the average established firm gains or loses with the first selection process, the F.E.C. with free trade is transformed to q φ F T f + φ q φ φ F T τ 1 f Ex }{{} additional term with free trade f M 2 φ F T. 36 Total profits of the average established firm obviously decrease increase with the first selection process with exposure to trade whenever the additional term is negative positive. In this case, the average labor intensity φ F T, which equals half the probability for a successful market entry, has to increase decrease in order to equalize the average total per period profits and the per period equivalent of the one time market entry costs again. 16 Exposure to trade decreases increases the steady state capital endowment of both countries, as an increase decrease in the average labor intensity implies a subsequent decrease increase in both countries total investment. Most importantly, if firms were homogeneous, φ could not change and the countries capital endowments would be unaffected by exposure to trade. Inserting q φ q f ρ + δ 2 /2 ρ + δ 1 2 from the zero profit condition 25 leads to the following assessment of exposure to trade: endowment gain: τ < no endowment change: τ endowment loss: τ > ρ + δ 2 2 ρ + δ 1 2 f f Ex ρ + δ 2 2 ρ + δ 1 2 f f Ex ρ + δ 2 2 ρ + δ 1 2 f. f Ex 16 The situation of a decrease in expected total profits is excluded in the single factor models by Melitz 2003 and Falvey et al In their models the average established firm always gains with the first selection process since the least productive firms are driven out of the market by the first selection process. Therefore, not only the exporting firms gain with exposure to trade, but additionally total domestic supply is produced with a higher average labor productivity. Even if f Ex rises to infinity, the average established firm at least does not lose with the first selection process in Melitz 2003 and Falvey et al The probability that the average firm exports only converges to zero if f Ex goes to infinity. 20

22 Obviously, the countries steady state capital endowments increase decrease with exposure to trade if τ and/or f Ex are small large. In this case, additional variable export profits are large small and additional fixed export costs are small large. Steady state welfare increases decreases with exposure to trade whenever the average capital intensity 1 φ increases decreases as a consequence. The steady state welfare consequences of exposure to trade are visualized in figure 2. According to this analysis, restricting trade may increase a country s steady state welfare. The following section completes the analysis with the help of a numerical example which incorporates the adjustment path to the new steady state into the welfare assessment of exposure to trade with firm heterogeneity. Figure 2: Parameter spaces for steady state welfare gains/losses with exposure to trade no firm exports average labor average labor intensity ~ intensity ~ increases, decreases, endowment endowment loss gain no firm exports steady state welfare loss steady state welfare gain 1 excluded due to parameter restrictions 1 excluded due to parameter restrictions f f Ex f f Ex 5 The model at work a numerical example Does the welfare assessment of exposure to trade change when the adjustment path to the new steady state is also considered? This section answers this question with the help of a specific numerical example. The results therefore should not be generalized. According to subsection 4.3, the welfare consequences of exposure to trade can be reduced to the welfare consequences of a change in the average labor intensity. The numerical analysis therefore simplifies considerably. The equilibrium average labor intensities in autarky and with free trade, respectively, will be calculated exogenously with the help of the respective free entry and exit condition of the average firm, equations 13 and 26. Afterwards, it is assumed that a closed economy as characterized 21

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms Andrew Bernard, Tuck and NBER Stephen e Redding, LSE and CEPR Peter Schott, Yale and NBER 1 Introduction How do economies respond when opening to trade? Classical

More information

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory)

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory) 14.581 International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory) 14.581 Week 9 Spring 2013 14.581 (Week 9) Gravity Models (Theory) Spring 2013 1 / 44 Today s Plan 1 The Simplest Gravity Model: Armington

More information

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011 Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano University of Munich July 22, 2011 & 1 / 20 & & 2 / 20 My Bachelor Thesis: Ottaviano et al. (2009) apply the model to study gains from the euro & 3 / 20 Melitz and Ottaviano

More information

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011 Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano University of Munich July 22, 2011 & 1 / 20 & & 2 / 20 My Bachelor Thesis: Ottaviano et al. (2009) apply the model to study gains from the euro & 3 / 20 Melitz and Ottaviano

More information

Import Protection as Export Destruction

Import Protection as Export Destruction Import Protection as Export Destruction Hiroyuki Kasahara Beverly Lapham December 2005 Incomplete Abstract his paper develops a dynamic, stochastic industry model of heterogeneous firms to examine the

More information

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination January 2016 Department of Economics UNC Chapel Hill Instructions: This examination consists of 3 questions. Answer all questions. If you believe a question is ambiguously

More information

Internation1al Trade

Internation1al Trade 4.58 International Trade Class notes on 4/8/203 The Armington Model. Equilibrium Labor endowments L i for i = ; :::n CES utility ) CES price index P = i= (w i ij ) P j n Bilateral trade ows follow gravity

More information

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models Dave Donaldson (MIT) CEMMAP MC July 2018 1 All material based on earlier courses taught

More information

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013) The Ramsey Model (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 213) 1 Introduction The Ramsey model (or neoclassical growth model) is one of the prototype models in dynamic macroeconomics.

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model New Notes on the Solow Growth Model Roberto Chang September 2009 1 The Model The firstingredientofadynamicmodelisthedescriptionofthetimehorizon. In the original Solow model, time is continuous and the

More information

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Endogenous Growth with Human Capital Consider the following endogenous growth model with both physical capital (k (t)) and human capital (h (t)) in continuous time. The representative household solves

More information

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory)

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory) 14.581 MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory) Dave Donaldson Spring 2011 Introduction to Gravity Models Recall that in this course we have so far seen a wide range of trade models:

More information

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Equilibrium in a Production Economy Equilibrium in a Production Economy Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2012 Sims (ND) Equilibrium in a Production Economy Fall 2012 1 / 23 Production Economy Last time: studied equilibrium in

More information

WHY ARE THERE RICH AND POOR COUNTRIES? SYMMETRY BREAKING IN THE WORLD ECONOMY: A Note

WHY ARE THERE RICH AND POOR COUNTRIES? SYMMETRY BREAKING IN THE WORLD ECONOMY: A Note WHY ARE THERE RICH AND POOR COUNTRIES? SYMMETRY BREAKING IN THE WORLD ECONOMY: A Note Yannis M. Ioannides Department of Economics Tufts University Medford, MA 02155, USA (O): 1 617 627 3294 (F): 1 617

More information

Motivation A Figure 1 Figure 2 Table 1 Table 2

Motivation A Figure 1 Figure 2 Table 1 Table 2 Future Work Motivation A Figure 1 Figure 2 Table 1 Table 2 Motivation B Markup Di erences: SOEs vs. POEs Markup Di erences Across Sectors Sectoral Di erences Motivation Key Novelty Model Trade Liberalization,

More information

Web Appendix for Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Not for Publication)

Web Appendix for Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Not for Publication) Web Appendix for Heterogeneous Firms and Trade Not for Publication Marc J. Melitz Harvard University, NBER and CEPR Stephen J. Redding Princeton University, NBER and CEPR December 17, 2012 1 Introduction

More information

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession ONLINE APPENDIX INVESTMENT HANGOVER A1 Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession By MATTHEW ROGNLIE, ANDREI SHLEIFER, AND ALP SIMSEK APPENDIX A: CALIBRATION This appendix describes

More information

1 The Basic RBC Model

1 The Basic RBC Model IHS 2016, Macroeconomics III Michael Reiter Ch. 1: Notes on RBC Model 1 1 The Basic RBC Model 1.1 Description of Model Variables y z k L c I w r output level of technology (exogenous) capital at end of

More information

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton Figure a. Aggregate exchange rate disconnect (levels) 28.5

More information

Trade and Domestic Policy in Models with Monopolistic Competition

Trade and Domestic Policy in Models with Monopolistic Competition Trade and Domestic Policy in Models with Monopolistic Competition Alessia Campolmi Università di Verona Harald Fadinger University of Mannheim and CEPR Chiara Forlati University of Southampton February

More information

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Paul Pichler and Gerhard Sorger This Version: February 2006 Abstract We study the Ramsey (1928) model under the assumption that households act strategically.

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics Advanced Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model Marcin Kolasa Warsaw School of Economics Marcin Kolasa (WSE) Ad. Macro - Ramsey model 1 / 30 Introduction Authors: Frank Ramsey (1928), David Cass (1965) and Tjalling

More information

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy Economics 522 Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Princeton University Spring 2014 ERH (Princeton University ) Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy Spring 2014 1 / 34 Restuccia and Rogerson

More information

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Hiroaki Ino Institute of Intellectual Property and Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo [Preliminary

More information

Knowledge licensing in a Model of R&D-driven Endogenous Growth

Knowledge licensing in a Model of R&D-driven Endogenous Growth Knowledge licensing in a Model of R&D-driven Endogenous Growth Vahagn Jerbashian Universitat de Barcelona June 2016 Early growth theory One of the seminal papers, Solow (1957) discusses how physical capital

More information

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Government Purchases and Endogenous Growth Consider the following endogenous growth model with government purchases (G) in continuous time. Government purchases enhance production, and the production

More information

Problem 1 (30 points)

Problem 1 (30 points) Problem (30 points) Prof. Robert King Consider an economy in which there is one period and there are many, identical households. Each household derives utility from consumption (c), leisure (l) and a public

More information

Endogenous IPR and Economic Growth

Endogenous IPR and Economic Growth Endogenous IPR and Economic Growth Andreas Schäfer University of Leipzig Maik T. Schneider ETH Zurich Preliminary version 8. May 2008 Abstract Why are intellectual property rights in some countries higher

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 17, 2009. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 7 November 17, 2009. 1 / 54 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Measuring the Gains from Trade: They are Large!

Measuring the Gains from Trade: They are Large! Measuring the Gains from Trade: They are Large! Andrés Rodríguez-Clare (UC Berkeley and NBER) May 12, 2012 Ultimate Goal Quantify effects of trade policy changes Instrumental Question How large are GT?

More information

The Harris-Todaro model

The Harris-Todaro model Yves Zenou Research Institute of Industrial Economics July 3, 2006 The Harris-Todaro model In two seminal papers, Todaro (1969) and Harris and Todaro (1970) have developed a canonical model of rural-urban

More information

Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection

Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection Eric Bartelsman, John Haltiwanger & Stefano Scarpetta American Economic Review (2013) Presented by Beatriz González January

More information

Addendum to: New Trade Models, Same Old Gains?

Addendum to: New Trade Models, Same Old Gains? Addendum to: New Trade Models, Same Old Gains? Costas Arkolakis Yale and NBER Arnaud Costinot MIT and NBER September 5, 200 Andrés Rodríguez-Clare Penn State and NBER Abstract This addendum provides generalizations

More information

Productivity Improvements and Falling Trade Costs: Boon or Bane?

Productivity Improvements and Falling Trade Costs: Boon or Bane? Productivity Improvements and Falling Trade Costs: Boon or Bane? Svetlana Demidova y The Pennsylvania State University This version: February 24, 2006. Abstract This paper looks at two features of globalization,

More information

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t ) 6. Economic growth Let us recall the main facts on growth examined in the first chapter and add some additional ones. (1) Real output (per-worker) roughly grows at a constant rate (i.e. labor productivity

More information

Technical Appendix. The Steady State

Technical Appendix. The Steady State Technical Appendix A The Steady State We denote constant, steady-state levels of variables by dropping the time subscript and assume = fe, f = f, τ = τ, L = L,andZ = Z =1. Under these assumption, the steady

More information

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ryoji Ohdoi Dept. of Industrial Engineering and Economics, Tokyo Tech This lecture note is mainly based on Ch. 8 of Acemoglu

More information

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam? The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam? Jean Louis Brillet, France For presentation at the LINK 2014 Conference New York, 22nd 24th October, 2014 Advertisement!!! The model uses EViews The

More information

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. Ph.D. Core Exam -- Macroeconomics 5 January 2015 -- 8:00 am to 3:00 pm Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. A1 (required): Ending Quantitative Easing Now that the U.S.

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT November 28, 2017. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 9 November 28, 2017. 1 / 41 First-Generation Models

More information

Firm Dynamics in the Neoclassical Growth Model

Firm Dynamics in the Neoclassical Growth Model Firm Dynamics in the Neoclassical Growth Model Omar Licandro IAE-CSIC and Barcelona GSE (omar.licandro@iae.csic.es) July 2015 Abstract: This paper integrates firm dynamics theory into the Neoclassical

More information

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj Macro II (UC3M, MA/PhD Econ) Professor: Matthias Kredler Problem Set 1 Due: 29 April 216 You are encouraged to work in groups; however, every student has to hand in his/her own version of the solution.

More information

Schumpeterian Growth Models

Schumpeterian Growth Models Schumpeterian Growth Models Yin-Chi Wang The Chinese University of Hong Kong November, 2012 References: Acemoglu (2009) ch14 Introduction Most process innovations either increase the quality of an existing

More information

Topics in Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory: On the Causes and Consequences of Income Growth and Uncertainty

Topics in Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory: On the Causes and Consequences of Income Growth and Uncertainty Topics in Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory: On the Causes and Consequences of Income Growth and Uncertainty Dissertation zur Erlangung des Grades eines Doktors der Wirtschaftswissenschaft eingereicht an der

More information

Topic 8: Optimal Investment

Topic 8: Optimal Investment Topic 8: Optimal Investment Yulei Luo SEF of HKU November 22, 2013 Luo, Y. SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 1 / 22 Demand for Investment The importance of investment. First, the combination of

More information

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

Lecture notes on modern growth theory Lecture notes on modern growth theory Part 2 Mario Tirelli Very preliminary material Not to be circulated without the permission of the author October 25, 2017 Contents 1. Introduction 1 2. Optimal economic

More information

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 December 14, 2006 Exercise 1 A Households Households maximise their intertemporal utility function by optimally choosing consumption, savings, and the mix of

More information

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances Johannes Brumm University of Zurich Georgios Georgiadis European Central Bank Johannes Gräb European Central Bank Fabian Trottner Princeton

More information

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 41 I Motivation This Lecture introduces the basic

More information

Factor-Augmenting Technology Choice and Monopolistic Competition

Factor-Augmenting Technology Choice and Monopolistic Competition Factor-Augmenting Technology Choice and Monopolistic Competition Jakub Growiec April 22, 212 Abstract. We put forward a tractable, interpretable, and easily generalizable framework for modeling endogeneous

More information

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences 1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences In what follows we ll discuss aggregation. What do we mean with this term? We say that an economy admits aggregation if the behavior

More information

Monopolistic Competition Model with Endogeneous Investments: the case of Closed Economy

Monopolistic Competition Model with Endogeneous Investments: the case of Closed Economy Monopolistic Competition Model with Endogeneous Investments: the case of Closed Economy I.Bykadorov (together with E.Zhelobodko, S.Kokovin) November, 29th, 2011 Abstract Model - (Theoretical?): in monop.

More information

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model Virginia Sánchez-Marcos Macroeconomics, MIE-UNICAN Macroeconomics (MIE-UNICAN) A simple macro dynamic model with

More information

Import Protection as Export Destruction

Import Protection as Export Destruction Western University Scholarship@Western Economic Policy Research Institute. EPRI Working Papers Economics Working Papers Archive 2006 2006-2 Import Protection as Export Destruction Hiroyuki Kasahara Beverly

More information

International Prices and Exchange Rates Econ 2530b, Gita Gopinath

International Prices and Exchange Rates Econ 2530b, Gita Gopinath International Prices and Exchange Rates Econ 2530b, Gita Gopinath Model variable mark-ups CES demand: Constant mark-ups: ( ) εin µ in = log ε in 1 Given that markups are constant, Γ in = 0. ( ) θ = log.

More information

Innovation, Firm Dynamics, and International Trade

Innovation, Firm Dynamics, and International Trade Innovation, Firm Dynamics, and International Trade Andrew Atkeson y and Ariel Burstein z February 2009 Abstract We present a general equilibrium model of the decisions of rms to innovate and to engage

More information

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 36 I Motivation This Lecture considers some applications

More information

R&D Investment, Exporting, and Productivity Dynamics

R&D Investment, Exporting, and Productivity Dynamics R&D Investment, Exporting, and Productivity Dynamics Bee Yan Aw, Mark J. Roberts, Daniel Yi Xu NASM 2009 Motivation Does openness to trade promote productivity? Exports and firm productivity are correlated

More information

Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies:

Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies: Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies: Explorations with a Dynamic General Equilibrium Model of Labor Earnings based on Heckman, Lochner and Taber, Review of Economic

More information

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

Trade policy III: Export subsidies The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies - wiiw June 25, 2015 Overview Overview 1 1 Under perfect competition lead to welfare loss 2 Effects depending on market structures 1 Subsidies to

More information

The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by. β t u(c Mt, c Ht ) t=0

The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by. β t u(c Mt, c Ht ) t=0 Review Questions: Two Sector Models Econ720. Fall 207. Prof. Lutz Hendricks A Planning Problem The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by β t uc Mt,

More information

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT November 7, 9 and 14, 2017. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lectures 5-7 November 7, 9 and 14, 2017. 1 / 83 Introduction

More information

International Trade 31E00500

International Trade 31E00500 International Trade 31E00500 Lecture 6: Intra-industry trade and Gravity modelling Saara Tamminen 1 1 VATT Institute of Economic Research, Finland Winter 2016 Tamminen (VATT) Lecture 6 21.1.2016 1 / 53

More information

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti) Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti) Kjetil Storesletten September 5, 2014 Kjetil Storesletten () Lecture 3 September 5, 2014 1 / 56 Growth

More information

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2015 1 / 36 Production Economy Last time: studied equilibrium in an endowment economy Now: study equilibrium in an economy

More information

CFCM. Working Paper 15/17. Omar Licandro. Produced By:

CFCM. Working Paper 15/17. Omar Licandro. Produced By: CFCM CENTRE FOR FINANCE, CREDIT AND MACROECONOMICS Working Paper 15/17 Firm Dynamics in the Neoclassical Growth Model Omar Licandro Produced By: Centre for Finance, Credit and Macroeconomics School of

More information

Skilled Factor Abundance and Traded Goods Prices

Skilled Factor Abundance and Traded Goods Prices Skilled Factor Abundance and Traded Goods Prices Eddy Bekkers University of Bern Joseph Francois University of Bern and CEPR London Miriam Manchin University College London ABSTRACT: We develop a monopolistic

More information

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany October 3, 2018 Contents I 1 Central Planner 2 3 B. Heer c Public Economics: Chapter

More information

News Driven Business Cycles in Heterogenous Agents Economies

News Driven Business Cycles in Heterogenous Agents Economies News Driven Business Cycles in Heterogenous Agents Economies Paul Beaudry and Franck Portier DRAFT February 9 Abstract We present a new propagation mechanism for news shocks in dynamic general equilibrium

More information

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014 Comprehensive Exam Macro Spring 2014 Retake August 22, 2014 You have a total of 180 minutes to complete the exam. If a question seems ambiguous, state why, sharpen it up and answer the sharpened-up question.

More information

Prices and Exchange Rates: A Theory of Disconnect

Prices and Exchange Rates: A Theory of Disconnect Prices and Exchange Rates: A Theory of isconnect Jose Antonio Rodriguez-Lopez September 2010 Appendix B Online) B.1 The Model with CES Preferences The purpose of this section is to show the similarities

More information

Quantifying the Losses from International Trade

Quantifying the Losses from International Trade Quantifying the Losses from International Trade Spencer Lyon NYU Michael E. Waugh NYU and NBER June 23, 2017 0/23 Big Picture: The Backlash Against Trade Hard to deny that the benefits of globalization

More information

On the Dynamic Implications of the Cobb- Douglas Production Function

On the Dynamic Implications of the Cobb- Douglas Production Function From the SelectedWorks of Jürgen Antony 2010 On the Dynamic Implications of the Cobb- Douglas Production Function Jürgen Antony, CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis Available at: https://works.bepress.com/antony/7/

More information

Modeling firms locational choice

Modeling firms locational choice Modeling firms locational choice Giulio Bottazzi DIMETIC School Pécs, 05 July 2010 Agglomeration derive from some form of externality. Drivers of agglomeration can be of two types: pecuniary and non-pecuniary.

More information

The Dynamic Effect of Openness on Income Distribution and Long-Run Equilibrium

The Dynamic Effect of Openness on Income Distribution and Long-Run Equilibrium The Dynamic Effect of Openness on Income Distribution and Long-Run Equilibrium Tatsuya ASAMI Graduate School of Economics, Kobe University (D1) azutotatsu@gmail.com The Japan Society of International Economics

More information

Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-financing Undo Capital Misallocation?

Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-financing Undo Capital Misallocation? Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-financing Undo Capital Misallocation? Benjamin Moll G Online Appendix: The Model in Discrete Time and with iid Shocks This Appendix presents a version

More information

Aggregate Implications of Innovation Policy

Aggregate Implications of Innovation Policy Aggregate Implications of Innovation Policy Andrew Atkeson University of California, Los Angeles, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, and National Bureau of Economic Research Ariel T. Burstein University

More information

Expanding Variety Models

Expanding Variety Models Expanding Variety Models Yin-Chi Wang The Chinese University of Hong Kong November, 2012 References: Acemoglu (2009) ch13 Introduction R&D and technology adoption are purposeful activities The simplest

More information

Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade

Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade Alfonso A. Irarrazabal University of Oslo September 25, 2007 Contents 1 Simple Ricardian Model 3 1.1 Preferences................................. 3 1.2 Technologies.................................

More information

NATIONAL BANK OF POLAND WORKING PAPER No. 129

NATIONAL BANK OF POLAND WORKING PAPER No. 129 NATIONAL BANK OF POLAND WORKING PAPER No. 29 Factor-augmenting technology choice and monopolistic competition Jakub Growiec Warsaw 22 Jakub Growiec National Bank of Poland, Economic Institute; Warsaw School

More information

On the dynamics of the Heckscher-Ohlin theory

On the dynamics of the Heckscher-Ohlin theory On the dynamics of the Heckscher-Ohlin theory Lorenzo Caliendo The University of Chicago 2010 Introduction "...free commodity trade will, under certain speci ed conditions, inevitably lead to complete

More information

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty 1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty Sofarwehaveassumedawayaggregatefluctuations (i.e., business cycles) in our description of the incomplete-markets economies with uninsurable idiosyncratic risk

More information

Internationa1 l Trade

Internationa1 l Trade 14.581 Internationa1 l Trade Class notes on /19/013 1 Overview Assignment Models in the Trade Literature Small but rapidly growing literature using assignment models in an international context: Trade:

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano January 5, 2018 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand.

More information

Endogenous information acquisition

Endogenous information acquisition Endogenous information acquisition ECON 101 Benhabib, Liu, Wang (2008) Endogenous information acquisition Benhabib, Liu, Wang 1 / 55 The Baseline Mode l The economy is populated by a large representative

More information

Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities

Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities Jang-Ting Guo University of California, Riverside Sharon G. Harrison Barnard College, Columbia University July 9, 2008

More information

Endogenous Transport Investment, Geography, and Growth Take-offs

Endogenous Transport Investment, Geography, and Growth Take-offs Endogenous Transport Investment, Geography, and Growth Take-offs International Conference on Infrastructure Economics and Development Stefan Zeugner ECARES, Université Libre de Bruxelles (ULB) Toulouse,

More information

Labor Union and the Wealth-Income Ratio

Labor Union and the Wealth-Income Ratio Labor Union and the Wealth-Income Ratio Angus C. Chu Zonglai Kou Xueyue Liu November 2017 Abstract We explore how labor union affects the wealth-income ratio in an innovation-driven growth model and find

More information

Trade Liberalization and Pollution in Melitz-Ottaviano Model

Trade Liberalization and Pollution in Melitz-Ottaviano Model Trade Liberalization and Pollution in Melitz-Ottaviano Model Zhou Mohan November 30, 20 Abstract I incorporate Copeland-Talor tpe pollution technolog into Melitz and Ottaviano 2008) s work horse model.

More information

A Summary of Economic Methodology

A Summary of Economic Methodology A Summary of Economic Methodology I. The Methodology of Theoretical Economics All economic analysis begins with theory, based in part on intuitive insights that naturally spring from certain stylized facts,

More information

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1 Review Questions: Overlapping Generations Econ720. Fall 2017. Prof. Lutz Hendricks 1 A Savings Function Consider the standard two-period household problem. The household receives a wage w t when young

More information

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change Chapter 7 Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change 225 Economic Growth: Lecture Notes 7.1 Expanding Product Variety: The Romer Model There are three sectors: one for the final good sector, one

More information

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017 Lecture 15 Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017 Universidad de Costa Rica EC3201 - Teoría Macroeconómica 2 Table of contents

More information

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013 HARVARD UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 203 You have FOUR hours. Answer all questions Part A (Prof. Laibson): 48 minutes Part B (Prof. Aghion): 48

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics Advanced Macroeconomics Endogenous Growth Marcin Kolasa Warsaw School of Economics Marcin Kolasa (WSE) Ad. Macro - Endogenous growth 1 / 18 Introduction The Solow and Ramsey models are exogenous growth

More information

Chapter 4. Explanation of the Model. Satoru Kumagai Inter-disciplinary Studies, IDE-JETRO, Japan

Chapter 4. Explanation of the Model. Satoru Kumagai Inter-disciplinary Studies, IDE-JETRO, Japan Chapter 4 Explanation of the Model Satoru Kumagai Inter-disciplinary Studies, IDE-JETRO, Japan Toshitaka Gokan Inter-disciplinary Studies, IDE-JETRO, Japan Ikumo Isono Bangkok Research Center, IDE-JETRO,

More information

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems Craig Burnside Duke University September 2010 Craig Burnside (Duke University) Competitive Equilibrium September 2010 1 / 32 Competitive Equilibrium and

More information

Internation1al Trade

Internation1al Trade 14.581 Internation1al Trade Class notes on 3/4/2013 1 Factor Proportion Theory The law of comparative advantage establishes the relationship between relative autarky prices and trade ows But where do relative

More information

Housing with overlapping generations

Housing with overlapping generations Housing with overlapping generations Chiara Forlati, Michael Hatcher, Alessandro Mennuni University of Southampton Preliminary and Incomplete May 16, 2015 Abstract We study the distributional and efficiency

More information