Robust Mean-Variance Hedging via G-Expectation

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Robust Mean-Variance Hedging via G-Expectation"

Transcription

1 Robust Mean-Variance Hedging via G-Expectation Francesca Biagini, Jacopo Mancin Thilo Meyer Brandis January 3, 18 Abstract In this paper we study mean-variance hedging under the G-expectation framework. Our analysis is carried out by exploiting the G-martingale representation theorem and the related probabilistic tools, in a continuous financial market with two assets, where the discounted risky one is modeled as a symmetric G- martingale. By tackling progressively larger classes of contingent claims, we are able to explicitly compute the optimal strategy under general assumptions on the form of the contingent claim. 1 Introduction Mean-variance hedging is a classical method in Mathematical Finance for pricing and hedging of square-integrable contingent claims in incomplete markets. In this paper we consider the mean-variance hedging problem in the G-expectation framework in continuous time. Our analysis deeply relies on the quasi probabilistic tools provided by the G-calculus and thus distinguishes itself from other works on model uncertainty such as the BSDEs approach see 5 as a reference), the parameter uncertainty setting see for example 19) or the one period model examined in 1. The G-expectation space, which represents a generalization of the usual probability space, was introduced in 6 by Peng 1 for modeling volatility uncertainty and then progressively developed to include most of the classical results of probability theory and stochastic calculus see 4, 7, 1, 11, 14 and 17 to cite some of them). As a result the G-expectation theory has become a very useful framework to cope with volatility ambiguity in finance and many authors have studied some classical problems of stochastic finance, such as no arbitrage conditions, super-replication and optimal control problems in this new setting see for example 8 and ). In this context we assume that the discounted risky asset X t ) t,t is a symmetric G-martingale see Definition.1). This means that we consider a financial market that is intrinsically incomplete because of the uncertainty affecting the volatility of X. Since perfect replication of a claim H by means of self-financing portfolios will Department of Mathematics, Workgroup Financial and Insurance Mathematics, University of Munich LMU), Theresienstraße 39, 8333 Munich, Germany. s: francesca.biagini@math.lmu.de, jacopo.mancin@math.lmu.de, meyer-brandis@math.lmu.de Secondary affiliation: Department of Mathematics, University of Oslo, Box 153, Blindern, 316, Oslo, Norway 1

2 not always be possible, we look for the self-financing strategy which is as close as possible in a quadratic sense to H in a robust way. More precisely we aim at solving the optimal problem inf J V, φ) = inf V,φ) R + Φ V,φ) R + Φ H V T V, φ)), 1.1) where Φ is a space of suitable strategies defined in Definition 3.1 and V T V, φ) stands for the terminal value of the admissible portfolio V, φ). The objective functional can be interpreted as a stochastic game between the agent and the market, the latter displaying the worst case volatility scenario and the former choosing the best possible strategy. In the classical setting see 16 for an overview), if the underlying discounted asset is a local martingale, this is equivalent to retrieve the Galtchouk-Kunita-Watanabe decomposition of the square-integrable claim H, i.e. to find the projection of H onto the closed space of square integrable stochastic integrals of X. In the G-expectation framework such result cannot be used. However the structure of G-martingales has been clarified in several works such as 14, 17 and 18. We base our analysis on these results to solve the robust mean-variance hedging problem. From a technical point of view tackling 1.1) is very different from solving the classical mean-variance problem in a standard probability setting. In fact the nonlinearity of the model prevents the orthogonality of B and B, namely the G-Brownian motion and its quadratic variation see 6). This in turn limits the possibility to compute explicitly expressions of the type θ s db s ξ s d B s, for suitable processes θ and ξ, which is a desirable condition when adopting a quadratic criterion. Our main contribution is the explicit computation of the optimal mean-variance hedging portfolio for a wide class of sufficiently integrable) contingent claims 1 H. We focus on claims with martingale decomposition H = H + θ s db s + η s d B s Gη s )ds. 1.) where the finite variation part is explicitely characterized. We first assume η to be a continuous process, deterministic or depending only on B. The class of claims admitting this particular decomposition is already wide enough and includes the quadratic polynomials of B and the Lipschitz functions of B. This last result is particularly interesting from a practical perspective, as it includes a wide class of volatility derivatives, such as volatility swaps. For this kind of claims we are able to provide a full description of the optimal portfolio. In the general case obtaining the characterization of the optimal meanvariance strategy is much more involved. We consider the situation in which η is a 1 More explicitly, we consider H L +ɛ G FT ), where L+ɛ G FT ) is introduced in Definition.. This can be done without loss of generality, since this class of claims is dense in L +ɛ G FT ). Theorem 3.5 shows that the optimal value function for H L +ɛ G FT ) can be obtained as limit of the optimal value functions for any approximating sequence for H of the form 1.).

3 piecewise constant process η s = n 1 i= η t i I ti,t i+1 s) and outline a stepwise procedure that we solve explicitly for n =. In addition we provide a lower and upper bound for the terminal risk. This limitation is not completely unexpected since it analogously arises also in the classical context of one single prior, where the discounted asset price X t ) t,t is modeled as a semimartingale. In this case the solution to the mean variance hedging problem is implicitly described in a feedback form see 15) as no orthogonal projection of the claim on the space of the square integrable integrals with respect to X is possible. The paper is organized as follows. In Section we introduce some fundamental preliminaries on the G-expectation theory and also present some new results on stochastic calculus in the G-setting. In Section 3 we describe the market model and formulate the mean-variance hedging problem. In Section 4 we provide the explicit solution for the optimal mean-variance portfolio for some classes of contingent claims. In Section 5 we provide a lower and upper bound for the optimal terminal risk. G-Setting We outline here an introduction to the theory of sublinear expectations, G-Brownian motion and the related stochastic calculus. The results from this section can be found in 4, 11 and 18. Moreover we present some new insights concerning the G-martingale decomposition and G-convex functions, see Lemma.13 and.16. We first introduce the construction of G-expectation and the corresponding G- Brownian motion. We fix a time horizon T > and set Ω T := C, T, R), the space of all R-valued continuous paths ω t ) t,t with ω =. Let F = BΩ T ) be the Borel σ-algebra and consider the probability space Ω T, F, P ). Let W = W t ) t,t be a classical Brownian motion on this space. The filtration generated by W is denoted by F = F t ) t,t, where F t := σ{w s s t} N, and N denotes the collection of P -null subsets. Let Θ be a bounded closed subset Θ := σ, σ and Gy) = 1 σ y + 1 σ y, y R. We denote by A Θ t,t the collection of all the Θ-valued F-adapted processes on t, T. Let P σ be the law of the integral process t σ udw u, t, T. Define P 1 := {P σ σ A Θ,T },.1) and P := P 1, as the closure of P 1 under the topology of weak convergence. We denote by C l,lip R n ) the space of real continuous functions defined on R n such that ϕx) ϕy) C1 + x k + y k ) x y, x, y R n, where k and C depend only on ϕ. Definition.1. For any ϕ C l,lip R n ), n N, t 1 t n T, we define 3

4 ϕb t1,..., B tn B tn 1 )) := sup E P σ ϕb t1,..., B tn B tn 1 )) σ A Θ,T = sup E P σ ϕb t1,..., B tn B tn 1 )). P σ P 1 By 4 we obtain that defines a sublinear operator called G-expectation on Ω T, L ip F T )), where L ip F T ) := {ϕb t1,, B tn ) n N, t 1,..., t n, T, ϕ C l,lip R n )}. Definition.. For any p 1, is a continuous mapping on L ip F T ) with norm ξ p := ξ p )) 1 p and can be extended to the completion of L ip F T ) under p, which we call L p G F T ). Let B = B t ) t,t be the canonical process on Ω T defined as B t ω) := ω t, t, T. Then it is a G-Brownian motion as in the definition of 1. The following property is quite useful. Proposition.3 Proposition of 1). Let Y L 1 G F T ) be such that Y ) = Y ). Then we have X + Y ) = X) + Y ), X L 1 GF T ). Denote, for t, T and P P, Pt, P ) := {P P : P = P on F t }. For any X L 1 G F T ), we then introduce the G-conditional expectation X F t := ess sup E Q X F t ), P a.s.,.) Q Pt,P ) for s T, P P, see 17 for more details. Remark.4. This choice of the measurable space will allow us to use the results on stochastic calculus with respect to the G-Brownian motion and in particular the G-martingale representation Theorem.1. This assumption can be done without loss of generality as, for any probability measure P on Ω T, F) denoting with F P := { F P t, t, T } the P -augmented filtration, we have the following lemma see 17 for the proof). Lemma.5. For any F P t -measurable random variable ξ, there exists a unique Pa.s.) F t -measurable random variable ξ such that ξ = ξ, P-a.s.. Similarly, for every F P t -progressively measurable process X, there exists a unique F t -progressively measurable process X such that X = X, dt dp -a.e.. Moreover, if X is P -almost surely continuous, then one can choose X to be P -almost surely continuous. Finally, given the set of probability measures P, we introduce here a notation that will be useful later on. Definition.6. A set A is said polar if P A) = P P. A property is said to hold quasi surely q.s.) if it holds outside a polar set. In the rest of the paper we work in the setting outlined above. 4

5 .1 Stochastic Calculus of Itô type with G-Brownian Motion We now introduce the stochastic integral with respect to a G-Brownian motion. To this purpose we summarize some results of 11, if not mentioned otherwise, that are useful in the sequel. For p 1 fixed, we consider the following type of simple processes: for a given partition {t,..., t N } of, T, N N, we set η t ω) = N 1 j= ξ j ω)i tj,t j+1 )t),.3) where ξ i L p G F t i ), i,..., N 1. The collection of this type of processes is denoted by M p, p, G, T ). For each η MG, T ) let η M p := G η s p ds) 1 p and denote by M p p, G, T ) the completion of MG, T ) under the norm M p. G Definition.7. For η M, G, T ) with the representation in.3) we define the integral mapping I : M, G, T ) L G F T ) by Iη) = ηs)db s := N 1 j= η j B tj+1 B tj ). Lemma.8 Lemma 3 of 1). The mapping I : M, G, T ) L G F T ) is a linear continuous mapping and thus can be continuously extended to I : MG, T ) L G F T ). It is then possible to show that the integral has similar properties as in the classical Itô case. Definition.9. The quadratic variation of the G-Brownian motion is defined as B t = B t t B s db s, t T, and it is a continuous increasing process which is absolutely continuous with respect to the Lebesgue measure dt see Definition. in 18). Here B t, t, T, perfectly characterizes the part of uncertainty, or ambiguity, of B. For s, t, we have that B s+t B s is independent 3 of F s and B s+t B s, B t are identically distributed 4. We have that for all ϕ C l,lip R), ϕ B t )) = sup ϕvt),.4) σ v σ i.e., the quadratic variation of the G-Brownian motion is maximally distributed. The integral with respect to the quadratic variation of G-Brownian motion t η sd B s is introduced analogously. Firstly for all η M 1, G, T ), and then, again by continuity, for all η MG 1, T ). 3 We say that Y, X L ipf T ) are independent under if for any test function ψ C l,lip R ) we have ψx, Y )) = ψx, Y )) X=x). 4 We call X 1, X L ipf T ) identically distributed if ψx 1)) = ψx )), ψ C l,lip R). 5

6 Definition.1. A process M = M t ) t,t, such that M t L 1 G F t) for any t, T, is called G-martingale if M t F s ) = M s for all s t T. If M and M are both G-martingales, M is called a symmetric G-martingale. Note that by.) we have that a G-martingale M can be seen as a multiple prior martingale which is a supermartingale under each P P. We next give a characterization of G-martingales via the following representation theorem. Theorem.11 Theorem. of 13). Let H L ip F T ), then for every t T we have t t H F t = H + θ s db s + η s d B s Gη s )ds,.5) where θ t ) t,t MG, T ) and η t) t,t MG 1, T ). In particular, the nonsymmetric part K t := t η s d B s t Gη s )ds,.6) t, T, is a G-martingale that is continuous and non-increasing with quadratic variation equal to zero. A similar decomposition can be obtained for all G-martingales in L β G F T ), with β > 1. Theorem.1 Theorem 4.5 of 18). Let β > 1 and H L β G F T ). Then the G-martingale M with M t := H F t ), t, T, has the following representation M t = X + t θ s db s K t, where K is a continuous, increasing process with K =, K T L α G F T ), θ t ) t,t MG α, T ), α 1, β), and K is a G-martingale. It then easily follows as a corollary that a G-martingale is symmetric if and only if the process K is equal to zero, thus every symmetric G-martingale can be represented as a stochastic integral in the G-Brownian motion. Finally we provide some insights on how the representation of the G-martingale H F t )) t,t is linked to the one of H F t )) t,t. We focus on the particular class of random variables for which the process η appearing in.6) is stepwise constant. To ease the notation we explicitly prove the case in which η s = I t,t s) η, where < t < T, s, T and η L ip F t ), but the generalization to n steps is straightforward. Lemma.13. Let H = H + θ s db s + η B T B t ) G η)t t), 6

7 where θ s ) s,t M G, T ), and η L ipf t ) is such that η = η + t µ s db s + t ξ s d B s t Gξ s )ds, for some processes µ s ) s,t MG, t) and ξ s) s,t MG 1, t). Then the decomposition of H is given by where and H = H + µ s = ξ s = µ s db s + ξ s d B s G ξ s )ds, { µ s σ σ )T t) θ s, if s, t, θ s, if s t, T, { ξ s σ σ )T t), if s, t, η, if s t, T. Proof. For s < t we have by the properties of B and of the conditional G- expectation that H F s = H = H = H s s θ u db u η B T B t ) + G η)t t) F s θ u db u + η B T B t ) + G η)t t) F s θ u db u + + η B T B t ) + G η)t t) F t F s = H s θ u db u + σ σ )T t) η F s = H + σ σ )T t) η + + σ σ )T t) = H + s + σ σ )T t) s ξ u d B u s s µu σ σ )T t) θ u ) dbu + s ξ u d B u s where in the last equality we used the fact that µu σ σ )T t) θ u ) dbu Gξ u σ σ )T t))du Gξ u σ σ )T t))du, H + H = K T = η B T B t ) + G η)t t). On the other hand, when s > t η B T B t ) + G η)t t) F s =G η)t t) + η B t + η B T F s 7

8 =G η)t t) + η B t + η + B T + σ T F s σ T ) + + η B T σ T Fs + σ T ) =G η)t t) + η B t + η + B s + σ s σ T ) + η B s σ s + σ T ) =G η)t t) + η B t η B s + G η)t s) =G η)t t) η B s B t ) + G η)t t) G η)s t) = η σ σ )T t) η B s B t ) G η)s t), where we used the fact that This completes the proof.. G-Jensen s Inequality Gx) + G x) = x σ σ ) x R. Denote now with Sd) the space of symmetric matrices of dimension d. In the framework of G-expectation, the usual Jensen s inequality in general does not hold. Nevertheless an analogue to this result can be proved also in this setting, introducing the notion of G-convexity. Definition.14. A C -function h : R R is called G-convex if the following condition holds for each y, z, A) R 3 : Gh y)a + h y)zz ) h y)ga), where h and h denote the first and the second derivatives of h, respectively. Using this definition, Proposition of 11 shows the following result. Proposition.15. The following two conditions are equivalent: The function h is G-convex. The following Jensen inequality holds: hx) F t h X F t ), t, T, for each X L 1 G F T ) such that hx) L 1 G F T ). As a particular case we show that the Jensen s inequality holds in the G-framework for hx) = x, proving that this function is G-convex. Lemma.16. In the one dimensional case, the function x x is G-convex. Proof. According to the definition we have to check if, for each y, z, A) R 3, GyA + z ) yga), which is ya + z ) + σ ya + z ) σ ya + σ A σ )..7) 8

9 This can be done by cases. When both A and y are greater than zero the condition is obvious. If A is positive but y is negative the only situation to study is when ya + z <. In this case Condition.7) becomes ya + z )σ yaσ yaσ σ ) + z σ, which is always satisfied since yaσ σ ) >. The case in which A is negative is analogue. It is easy to verify that the function x x 4 is convex, but not G-convex. In the framework of g-expectation, this issue is studied in 1, where the authors show that, even for a linear function, Jensen s inequality for g-expectation does not always hold. 3 Robust Mean-Variance Hedging In the same setting outlined in Section, we consider the discounted risky asset X = X t ) t,t with dynamics dx t = X t db t, X >, and set the discounted risk-free asset equal to 1. In analogy to what is done in 16, we take into consideration the space of strategies of the following type. Definition 3.1. A trading strategy ϕ = φ t, ψ t ) t,t is called admissible if φ t ) t,t Φ, where { ) } Φ := φ predictable φ t X t db t <, ψ is adapted, and it is self-financing, i.e. the associated portfolio value V t ϕ) := ψ t + φ t X t = V + t φ s dx s, t, T. 3.1) The value of such strategies ϕ Φ at any time t, T is then completely determined by V, φ), so that we can write V t ϕ) = V t V, φ) for all t, T. We consider the problem of hedging a contingent claim H L +ɛ G F T ), for an ɛ >, using admissible trading strategies. This integrability condition on H is required in order to be able to use the G-martingale representation theorem. As a claim H can be perfectly replicated with such a strategy only if it is symmetric, for a general derivative H the idea of robust mean-variance hedging is to minimize the residual terminal risk defined as J V, φ) := H V T V, φ)) = sup E P H V T V, φ)) 3.) P P by the choice of V, φ). That is we wish to solve inf J V, φ) = inf V,φ) R + Φ V,φ) R + Φ H V T V, φ)), 3.3) as it is done in 16 in the classical case in which a unique prior exists. In particular we have the following result. 9

10 Proposition 3.. There exists a unique solution for the optimal problem 3.3), i.e. inf H V T V, φ)) = H V T V, φ )), 3.4) V,φ) R + Φ for V, φ ) R + Φ. Proof. The existence and uniqueness of the minimizer V, φ ) R + Φ for the optimal problem 3.3) follows by Theorem 5.5 of 3, since the space R + Φ is convex and closed by Theorem 4.5 of 18. We call φ optimal mean-variance strategy with optimal mean-variance portfolio V t = V + t φ sdx s, t, T. The functional in 3.3) can be interpreted as a stochastic game between the agent and the market, the latter displaying the worst case volatility scenario and the former choosing the best possible strategy. When we have P = {P } this problem is solved thanks to the Galtchouk-Kunita-Watanabe decomposition, by projecting H onto the linear space {I = x + φ sdx s x R and φ Φ} for more on this in the classical case we refer again to 16). Here the situation is more cumbersome for several reasons. Firstly, there exists no orthogonal decomposition of the space of -integrable G-martingales. Moreover a symmetric criterion does not distinguish between a buyer or a seller, so the best hedging strategy should be optimal both for H and H. This prevents us from using straightforwardly the G-martingale representation theorem as the coefficients in the decomposition of H are a priori di fferent from those coming from the decomposition of H, see Lemma.13. Nevertheless we can get some insights from its direct application. L +ɛ G Lemma 3.3. The initial wealth V the interval H, H. of the optimal mean-variance portfolio lies in Proof. Let H = H + H = H + θ s db s K T, 3.5) θ s db s K T, be the G-martingale decomposition of H and H for suitable processes θ t ) t,t, θ t ) t,t, K t ) t,t and K t ) t,t, as given in Theorem.1, respectively. Let us assume there exist P, P P such that P K T > ) > and P K T > ) >, 5 Note that the proof of Theorem.5 of of 3 holds also for Banach spaces. 1

11 otherwise the claim is trivial. It then follows that ) H V φ s X s db s = H V + θ s φ s X s )db s K T ) ) = H V ) + θ s φ s X s ) db s K T + K T H V ), 3.6) and similarly ) H + V + φ s X s db s = H + V + θ s + φ s X s )db s K T ) ) = H + V ) ) + θs + φ s X s dbs K T + K T H + V ), by the properties of the stochastic integrals with respect to the G-Brownian motion and Proposition.3. From the expressions above we see that, as K T and K T are nonnegative random variables, which are not identically zero for at least one probability in P, the optimal initial wealth V is in the interval H, H. This agrees with the results on no-arbitrage pricing and superreplication presented in, thanks to which we can argue that V should indeed be in H, H), as long as H < H. When the claim is symmetric, i.e. H = H, it is also perfectly replicable and we would then have V = H and φ t ) t,t = θ t /X t ) t,t, as in the classical case. As for the initial value, it is possible to show that also the optimal trading strategy must belong to some bounded set in the MG norm. Lemma 3.4. Let be given a contingent claim H L +ɛ G F T ) with H = H + θ s db s K T, for some θ t ) t,t MG, T ) and K T L G F T ). Then there exists a R R + such that inf J V, φ) = inf J V, φ). V,φ) R + Φ V,φ) R + Φ θs φsxs)dbs R 11

12 Proof. We start by noticing that the optimal mean variance portfolio V, φ ) clearly satisfies JV, φ ) H 3.7) and put A := H V K T, D := θ s φ s X s )db s. We can derive the following chain of inequalities JV, φ) = A + D) = A + D + AD D D AD D A A 1 D 1. This shows that for great values of D, i.e. when the L G distance of φ sx s db s from θ sdb s is too big, for any V H, H) the terminal risk JV, φ) cannot be smaller than the upper bound in 3.7). This completes the proof. Theorem 3.5. Let be given a claim H L +ɛ G F T ) and a sequence of random variables H n ) n N such that H H n +ɛ as n. Then as n we have where, for every n N, and J n := J := J n J, inf H n V T V, φ)) V,φ) R + Φ inf H V T V, φ)). V,φ) R + Φ Proof. As first step of the proof we study the convergence of the terminal risk H n V T V, φ)) H V T V, φ)), 3.8) for some strategy V, φ). We assume without loss of generality that H has a representation as in 3.5). Similarly, for every n N, we claim that H n = H n + θs n db s KT n, for a θt n ) t,t MG, T ) and Kn T L G F T ). We begin by proving that we can restrict ourselves to study the convergence in 3.8) for a bounded class of trading strategies. It follows from Theorem 4.5 in 18 that the L G convergence of Hn ) n N to H implies also θs n θ s ) db s 1

13 and KT n K T as n. These facts, together with Lemma 3.3 and Lemma 3.4, allow us to fix a R R + such that Jn = inf H n V T V, φ)) V,φ) R + Φ V + θs φsxs)dbs R J = inf H V T V, φ)). V,φ) R + Φ V + θs φsxs)dbs R This in turns implies the convergence H n ) H ) on the set of strategies V, φ) R + Φ such that V + θ s φ s X s )db s R. In fact, denoting x := V + φ sx s db s any of such strategies, for any δ > we can find n N such that for all n > n H n x) H x) EG H n x) H x) H n x) H x) = H n H) H n + H x) H n H) 1 H n + H x) 1 H n H) 1 H n + H) 1 + x) 1 ) < δ. 3.9) This is clear since the second factor in 3.9) is bounded. The previous chain of inequalities holds true also upon considering the supremum of x over the set x R, which in turns implies uniform convergence. We can now prove the main statement. For any δ >, from the definition of J, there exists V, φ) R + Φ such that V + θ s φ s X s )db s R and ) J + δ H V φ s X s db s. 3.1) Moreover, the uniform convergence from 3.9), allows us to consider n big enough so that ) ) H V φ s X s db s H n V φ s X s db s < δ. 3.11) From 3.1) and 3.11) we can conclude that Analogously it is possible to find Ṽ, φ) such that J + δ J n. 3.1) Jn + δ H n Ṽ 13 φ s X s db s )

14 and H Ṽ from which we can argue ) φ s X s db s H n Ṽ φ s X s db s ) < δ, J n J δ. 3.13) The inequalities 3.1) and 3.13) conclude the proof as together they imply and δ was chosen arbitrarily. J δ J n J + δ Remark 3.6. Theorem 3.5 shows that we can begin our study of the mean-variance optimization by considering claims in the space L ip F T ). Any random variable in L +ɛ G F T ) is in fact by definition the limit in the L +ɛ G -norm of elements in L ipf T ). Moreover, as stated in Theorem.11, this class of random variables has the great advantage that the term K T in their representation has a further decomposition as K T = for some process η t ) t,t MG 1, T ). η s d B s Gη s )ds, 3.14) From now on we consider H L +ɛ G F T ) with decomposition H = H + θ s db s K T η) = H + θ s db s + η s d B s Gη s )ds. 3.15) Given the complexity of the problem, we proceed stepwise as follows. We first enforce some conditions on the process η, namely being deterministic or depending only on B t ) t,t, then we assume η to be a piecewise constant process having some particular characteristics that we will clarify at each time. In these cases we are able to solve the mean-variance hedging problem explicitly. Finally we address the general case by providing estimates of the minimal terminal risk. 4 Explicit Solutions We first present the computation of the optimal mean-variance portfolio for random variables H L +ɛ G F T ) with decomposition 3.15), where η is assumed to be deterministic or depending only on the realization of B t ) t,t. On the contrary the integrand θ in 3.15) is completely general and must only belong to MG, T ). In this way, as η does not exhibit volatility uncertainty through a direct dependence on the G-Brownian motion, uncertainty can be hedged by means of the initial wealth V without using the strategy φ. In these cases we are able to provide explicitly the optimal solutions in Theorem 4.1 and Theorem

15 4.1 Deterministic Case We first consider the case where η in the representation 3.15) is deterministic, and provide the optimal investment strategy and initial wealth. Theorem 4.1. Consider a claim H L +ɛ G F T ) of the following form H = H + θ s db s + η s d B s Gη s )ds, 4.1) where θ MG, T ) and η M G 1, T ) is a deterministic process. mean-variance portfolio is given by for every t, T and φ t X t = θ t V = H H. Proof. We start by computing the span of the process H + t η s d B s Gη s )ds. The optimal This lies quasi surely in the interval H σ σ ) η s ds, H. We begin with the upper bound, noticing that under the volatility scenario given by { σ if η t, σ t = σ if η t <, for each t, T, the negative random variable η sd B s Gη s)ds is P σ - a.s. equal to zero. As a consequence we have that E P σ H = H. For the lower bound we consider { σ t σ if η t, = σ if η t >, for each t, T. This is the scenario where η sd B s Gη s)ds reaches its minimum. It follows that E P σ H = H. In fact, from 4.1), H = H = H = H + θ s db s θ s db s η s d B s + η s d B s + + G η s )ds θ s )db s + + σ σ ) η s )d B s η s ds, Gη s )ds Gη s )ds G η s )ds G η s )ds 4.) 15

16 since Gη s ) + G η s ))ds = σ σ ) η s ds. We note that the expression 4.), as η is deterministic, provides the G-martingale decomposition of H. Hence we can conclude that H + σ σ ) η s ds = H. 4.3) Then, using Proposition.15 together with Lemma.16 we get inf V,φ) inf V,φ) H V + Gη s )ds) H V + Gη s )ds EG H + V η s d B s + = inf H V + V H + V = inf V ) Gη s )ds θ s φ s X s )db s + η s d B s + θ s φ s X s )db s + η s d B s + θ s φ s X s )db s + η s d B s Gη s )ds 4.4) ) T Gη s )ds η s d B s + H V + η s d B s Gη s )ds 4.5) ) T η s )d B s G η s )ds, H + V + where we have used Proposition.3 in 4.4) and the relation 4.3) in 4.5). This is equal to inf H V H + V ), 4.6) V as a + ξ s d B s =a + ξ s d B s Gξ s )ds = Gξ s )ds = a, 16

17 for a R and ξ MG 1, T ). The minimum of 4.6) is attained for V ). and is equal to If we show that EG H+ H ) H V + η s d B s Gη s )ds ) EG H + H = the proof is completed. Since H + η s d B s Gη s )ds = H H lies between H σ σ ) η s ds = H and H, it is clear that the maximum of H V + η s d B s Gη s )ds under the constraint V H, H is given by H+ H. This completes the proof. Remark 4.. Note that the optimal investment strategy φ = θ X is well defined as X, being a geometric G-Brownian motion, is q.s. strictly greater than. Moreover notice that, as η s d B s Gη s )ds = K T, it holds H V = K T, since K T = H + θ s db s H = H + H. Remark 4.3. The result of Theorem 4.1 becomes quite intuitive when considering the claim H = B T. In this case, since the G-martingale decomposition of B T is simply B T = σ T + B T σ T = B T + B T σ T, the solution V, φ ) to the mean-variance problem is given by V = σ +σ and φ. This means that the investor s optimal behavior is to place her initial wealth at the middle point between the two extreme realizations of the claim. The set of contingent claims which admit the decomposition 4.1) for η deterministic is non trivial. For any given integrable deterministic process η t ) t,t, any constant c R and any process θ t ) t,t MG, T ), we can construct the claim t H := c + θ s db s + η s d B s Gη s )ds, 17

18 for which the result of Theorem 4.1 holds. The intersection of such a set of random variables with L ip F T ) includes the second degree polynomials in B t, B t1 B t,..., B tn B tn 1 ), where {t i } n i= is a partition of, T. To have an intuition on this fact consider for simplicity random variables depending only on one increment of the G-Brownian motion. The coefficients of the decomposition of H = ϕb T B ) are given by η t ω) = xut, ω) and θ t ω) = x ut, ω), where u is the solution to { t u + G xu) =, ut, x) = ϕx), for t, x), T R see 11). If η is deterministic, we can write xut, ω) as a function of t, i.e. at) := xut, ω). Therefore, by integration w.r.t. x, we see that ut, x) must be of the form so that ut, x) = at) x + bt)x + ct), H = at ) B T + bt )B T + ct ). Remark 4.4. Another class of claims that can be optimally hedged by means of Theorem 4.1 is obtained thanks to Theorem 4.1 in. If we consider the situation in which H = ΦX T ), for some real valued Lipschitz function Φ, then it holds see for the details) ΦX T ) = ΦX T ) x ut, X t )X t db t xut, X t )X t d B t where u solves { t u + Gx xu) =, ut, x) = Φx). G xut, X t ))X t dt, It is then easy to see that xut, X t )Xt is deterministic for every t, T if and only if H = ΦX T ) = ut, X T ) = at ) log X T + bt )X T + ct ), for some real functions a, b and c. Through a slight modification to the previous argument we can prove that if on the market there exists another asset X, which is not possible to trade and solves the SDE dx t = αx t)db t, X >, 18

19 for some Lipschitz function 6 α, then it is possible to use again Theorem 4.1 to hedge every claim ΦX T ), where Φ is a Lipschitz function such that { t u + Gα x) xu) =, 4.7) ut, x) = Φx), provided that xut, x) = 1 α x) for every t, x), T R+. With easy calculations we can see that in this case ut, x) must be of the form ut, x) = x y 1 α z) dzdy + cx 1 σ t + d, t, x), T R +, 4.8) for suitable constants c, d R, if the double integrable in 4.8) is finite for all x R +, and α and Φ satisfy the relation Φx) = x y 1 α z) dzdy + cx 1 σ T + d, x R +. In particular, one could consider αx) = x 1 4 or αx) = x + ɛ) 1, ɛ >. 4. Mean Uncertainty Case We now consider the case in which η only shows mean uncertainty, being a function of the quadratic variation of the G-Brownian motion. Also in this case we are able to retrieve a complete description of the optimal mean-variance portfolio. Theorem 4.5. Let H L +ɛ G F T ) be of the form H = H + θ s db s + ψ B s )d B s Gψ B s ))ds, 4.9) where θ t ) t,t MG, T ) and ψ : R R is such that there exist k R and α R + for which ψx) ψy) α x y k, for all x, y R. The optimal mean-variance portfolio is given by for every t, T and φ t X t = θ t V = H H. Proof. As in Theorem 4.1, we start by applying the G-Jensen s inequality to obtain ) c + ϕ s db s + ψ B s )d B s Gψ B s ))ds c + c ϕ s db s + ϕ s db s ψ B s )d B s ψ B s )d B s + Gψ B s ))ds Gψ B s ))ds = c K T c), 4.1) 6 We have the existence of a unique solution for the SDE under this assumption by

20 where we defined c : = H V, ϕ t : = θ t φ t X t, 4.11) for all t, T. The minimum of 4.1) is attained when c = K T, and it is ). equal to We conclude by showing that this value is attained by choosing EG K T V = H H and φ t X t = θ t. We then compute EG K T T ) + ψ B s )d B s Gψ B s ))ds. 4.1) In order to do so we use a discretization, noting that where t i = T n i. In fact n 1 n 1 ψ n B t ) := ψ B ti )I ti,t i+1 )t) M G,T ) ψ B t ) 4.13) i= ψ B t ) ψ n B t ) n 1 dt = ti+1 i= t i = n k T n i= B t B ti k dt = n ) k+1 n, ti+1 t i t1 ψ B t ) ψ n B t ) dt B k t t1 dt = n t k dt and similarly for the convergence of Gψ n B t )) to Gψ B t )). The expression in 4.1) is then the limit when n tends to infinity of

21 EG n 1 K T n 1 ) + ψ B ti ) B ti+1 Gψ B ti )) t i+1 = EG K T = i= n 1 + EG K T i= i= i ψ B tj B ti+1 + j= n 1 i ) G ψ B tj t i+1 n 1 + i= i= j= i ψ B tj B ti+1 + i= j= n 1 i ) G ψ B tj t i+1 F tn 1 n EG K T i = sup + ψ B tj B ti+1 + σ v n σ i= j= n 1 n 1 i ) + ψ B tj v n t n G ψ B tj t i+1 j= n EG K T i = sup + ψ B tj B ti+1 + σ v n σ i= j= n 1 n 1 i ) + ψ B tj v n t n G ψ B tj t i+1 F tn = j= sup σ vn σ σ v n 1 σ EG K T n 3 + i= i= i= j= j= j= i ψ B tj B ti ) j= n n + ψ B tj v n 1 t n 1 + ψ B tj + v n 1 t n 1 v n t n + j= j= n G ψ B tj + v n 1 t n 1 t n + i= j= n i ) G ψ B tj t i+1, j= where we have used that B is maximally distributed. Proceeding by itera- 1

22 tion, 4.14) is equal to sup σ v i σ i=1,...,n n 1 K T + i= i ψ v j t j v i+1 t i+1 + i= j= ) n 1 i G ψ v j t j t i+1. j= 4.15) The supremum 4.15), being a quadratic function of v i ) i=1,...,n, is attained either when the term depending on v i ) i=1,...,n is equal to its minimum, which is zero, or its maximum, which is equal to n 1 n 1 Gψ B ti )) t i+1 ψ B ti ) B ti+1. i= In both cases, as n tends to infinity the value of 4.15) converges to because of 4.13). i= ) EG K T Remark 4.6. Theorem 4.5 shows that, when K T depends only on the quadratic variation of the G-Brownian motion, the investor adopting the mean-variance criterion dynamically hedges away all the uncertainty coming from the term θ sdb s in 4.9) by the choice of the optimal strategy φ. By doing so, the remaining randomness H K T, 4.16) which is pure volatility uncertainty, is optimally hedged by the choice of V. This initial wealth is the middle point between the two extreme realizations of 4.16), which are H and H. This corresponds to intuition, since at time these two cases are equally likely in the market. As the optimal mean variance portfolio V, φ ) for a claim H provides, via V, φ ), the optimal solution for the hedging of H, the investment strategy φ t ) t,t would not always be equal to the process θ t ) t,t coming from the G-martingale decomposition of H as in Theorem.1. The result of Theorem 4.5 does not contradict this intuition. Remark 4.7. Using Lemma.13 it is not difficult to prove that for contingent claims of the type H = H + n 1 ) θ s db s + ψ B ti ) B ti+1 Gψ B ti )) t i+1, i= where θ t ) t,t MG, T ) and ψ is a real continuous function, the decomposition of H has the expression H = H + for a suitable random variable K T L 1 G F T ). θ s )dbs K T,

23 It is possible to use the same argument of Remark 4.4 to characterize the class of contingent claims whose representation 4.1) exhibits an η given by a function with polynomial growth of B. This set includes the family of Lipschitz function of B. Theorem 4.5 can be used to hedge volatility swaps, i.e. H = B T K with K R +, and other volatility derivatives we refer to for more details on volatility derivatives). In fact, given a Lipschitz function Φ, the claim Φ B T ) can be written as Φ B T ) = Φ B T ) + x us, B s ) B s d B s where ut, x) solves { t u + Gx x u) =, ut, x) = Φx), G x us, B s )) B s ds, as a consequence of the nonlinear Feynman-Kac formula for G-Brownian motion see 13) and the G-Itô formula see 1). 4.3 Piecewise Constant Case We now study the optimal mean-variance portfolio for a broader class of claims, incorporating mean and volatility uncertainty in the process η. In particular, we focus on n 1 η s = η ti I ti,t i+1 s), 4.17) i= for n N, where {t i } n i= is a partition of, T, i.e. = t t 1 t n = T, and η ti L ip F ti ) for all i {,..., n}. We will outline a recursive solution procedure, which we are able to solve for n =. In the case of n > the proof of Theorem 4.16 provides a recursive procedure, which can be used to find numerically the optimal solution, see Remark 4.19 and Section.3.4 in Chapter of 9. Finally we provide bounds for the optimal terminal risk 3.3) in Section 5. Example 4.8. We now provide an example of a claim with a general η. Consider a call option with strike D >, whose payoff at time T is given by C := X T D) +. It follows from Theorem 4.1 in that C can be written as C = C X s x us, X s )db s xus, X s )Xs d B s G xus, X s ))Xs ds, 3

24 where ut, x) = X t,x T D) + F t, X t,x t = x. As the payoff of a call option is a convex function of the underlying, by Corollary 4.3 in we have that C = E P σc and X t,x T D) + F t = E P σ X t,x T D) + F t. 4.18) The value of the linear conditional expectation in 4.18) is well known and is equal to xnd 1 x)) DNd x)) 4.19) where N stands for the cumulative distribution function of a standard normal random variable, while d 1 x) = σ logx/d) + T t) σ T t By easy computations we obtain and d x) = d 1 x) σ T t. C = E P σc + 1 where fy) = 1 π e y. X s Nd 1 X s ))db s fd 1 X s )) σ T s X sd B s 1 σfd 1 X s )) X s ds, T s As a preliminary result we restrict ourselves to the study of claims which can be represented in the following way H = H + θ t1 B t + η t1 B t Gη t1 ) t, 4.) where t 1 < t T, θ t1 L G F t 1 ), B t := B t B t1 and similarly for B t and t. We choose accordingly the class of investment strategies φ of the form where φ t1 L G F t 1 ). If we denote φ t = φ t1 I t1,t, c := H V, ϕ t := θ t φ t X t, the risk functional 3.) becomes H V + θ t1 φ t1 X t1 ) B t + η t1 B t Gη t1 ) t ) = c + ϕ t1 B t + η t1 B t Gη t1 ) t ) = c + η t1 B t Gη t1 ) t ) + ϕ t 1 B t + 4.1) + ϕ t1 B t η t1 B t, where we used Proposition.3 in the last step. 4

25 Theorem 4.9. Consider a claim H L +ɛ G F T ) with decomposition as in 4.). The optimal mean-variance portfolio is given by V, φ ), where and V solves φ X = θ inf V EG H V ) H V σ σ ) t η t1 ). 4.) Proof. We start by computing where c + η t1 B t Gη t1 ) t ) = c + η t1 B t Gη t1 ) t ) Ft1 = fη t1 ), fx) = c + x B t Gx) t ). Using the fact that B is maximally distributed, fx) = sup c + xv t Gx) t ) σ v σ = c + σ x t Gx) t ) c + σ x t Gx) t ) = c c σ σ ) t x ), so that 4.3) becomes equal to c c σ σ ) t η t1 ). 4.3) This means that, in the time interval t 1, t, the worst case scenario sets the volatility constantly equal to σ t when which is equivalent to or to σ t if c c σ σ ) t η t1 ), c σ σ ) t η t1, c σ σ ) t η t1. Hence it follows that, by Proposition.15, for every c, H + H) inf c + ϕ t1 B t + η t1 B t Gη t1 ) t ) ϕ = inf c + ϕ t1 B t + η t1 B t Gη t1 ) t ) Ft1 ϕ inf c + ϕ t1 B t + η t1 B t Gη t1 ) t F t1 4.4) ϕ c ϕ t1 B t η t1 B t + Gη t1 ) t F t1 = c c σ σ ) t η t1 ). 5

26 This allows us to conclude, as the lower bound is attained by choosing ϕ t1 = and is the solution of 4.). V Theorem 4.9 shows that the determination of the optimal initial wealth can be more involved. We now show with a counterexample that the link between K T and stated in Remark 4. does not hold for general η. V Proposition 4.1. Let H be of the form H = H + θ t1 B t + η t1 B t Gη t1 ) t, where θ t1 L G F t 1 ) and η t1 = e Bt 1. The optimal initial wealth of the mean-variance portfolio is different from V = H H. Proof. Let us first compute H+ H. By conditioning and using some results on the expectation of convex functions of the increments of the G-Brownian motion see Proposition 11 in 1), we obtain H + H = Ge B t1 ) t e Bt 1 B t = σ σ ) t e Bt 1 = E P σ σ ) t e Wt 1 σ = σ σ ) t e σ t 1 /, where W t ) t,t is a standard Brownian motion under P. We now focus on the minimization over c of Hc) := c c σ σ ) ) t e Bt 1 =E P c c σ σ ) t e Wt σ) 1 =E P e W t1 σ t σ σ ) c ) c ) + + c =c + E P e Wt 1 σ t σ σ ) e Wt 1 σ t σ σ ) c ) + =c + E P e N t 1 σ t σ σ ) where N N, 1) and we have used that c e Bt 1 t σ σ ) c ) is a convex function of B t1. Let y := σ σ ) t and Ax) : = {x R : e σ t 1 x > c y } ) log c = x R : x > y σ t 1 = {x R : x > gc)}, 6 ) + e N t 1 σ t σ σ ) c,

27 where gc) := log ) c y σ t 1. With these notations Hc) can be written as Hc) =c + E P e σn t 1 y I AN) cye P e σ t 1 N I AN) =c + y e σ t 1 x 1 e x dx cy e σ t 1 x 1 e x dx. π π x>gc) x>gc) We differentiate with respect to c to find the stationary points: H c) = c y e σ t 1 gc) 1 e gc) g c) + cye σ t 1 gc) 1 e gc) g c)+ π π 1 y e σ t 1 x x dx. 4.5) π x>gc) = ye σ t 1 We now substitute c = H+ H point of minimum. We obtain and therefore ye σ H t1 which is different from zero. gc ) = log ye σ t 1 y into 4.5) to see if it is a possible ) σ t 1 = 1 σ t 1, = ye 1 σ t 1 y e σ t 1 1 σ t 1 1 π e gc ) g c )+ + ye 1 σ t 1 y ye σ t 1 1 σ t 1 1 π e gc ) g c )+ x> 1 σ t 1 1 = y e 1 σ t 1 π e 1 x σ t 1 x) dx x> 1 σ t 1 1 π e 1 x σ t 1 x) dx ) = y e 1 σ t 1 e 1 σ t 1 1 e z dz z> 1 σ t 1 π = y e 1 σ t 1 e 1 σ t 1 1 e z dz+ π e 1 σ t 1 = ye 1 σ t 1 1 σ t σ t 1 1 π e z dz ) π e z dz, ) 7

28 We now derive the optimal initial wealth for other particular cases, as we do in the following proposition. This result will constitute the first step of our recursive scheme. We remark that η will now exhibit volatility uncertainty, which was excluded from the results in Sections 4.1 and 4., while the process θ MG, T ) is completely general. Proposition Consider a claim H of the form t H = H + θ s db s + η t1 B t Gη t1 ) t, where = t < t 1 < t = T, θ s ) s,t M G, t ), η t1 L G F t 1 ) and t1 η t1 = η t1 + µ s db s, 4.6) for a certain process µ s ) s,t1 MG, t 1). The optimal mean-variance portfolio is given by X t φ t = θ t µ tσ σ ) ) t I t,t 1 t) + θ t I t1,t t) for t, T and V = H H. Proof. We use the same technique as in Theorem 4.9 to derive a lower bound for the terminal risk. We use the notations introduced in 4.11) and consider H V + t θ s φ s X s )db s + η t1 B t Gη t1 ) t ) t ) Ft1 = c + ϕ s db s + η t1 B t Gη t1 ) t t Ft1 c + ϕ s db s + η t1 B t Gη t1 ) t t Ft1 c ϕ s db s η t1 B t + Gη t1 ) t t1 ) = c + ϕ s db s where we have used that ) t1 c ϕ s db s + σ σ ) t η t1, 4.7) 8

29 t c + ϕ s db s + η t1 B t Gη t1 ) t F t1 t1 t = c + ϕ s db s + ϕ s db s + η t1 B t Gη t1 ) t F t 1 t 1 t1 = c + ϕ s db s thanks to Proposition.3, and similarly t c = c t1 ϕ s db s η t1 B t + Gη t1 ) t F t1 ϕ s db s + σ σ ) t η t1 as in 4.4). This allows us to conclude that the optimal strategy in the interval t 1, t is given by φ t X t = θ t. We now use 4.6) to rewrite 4.7) as t1 ) c + ϕ s db s c σ σ ) t η t1 + ) 4.8) t1 ϕs σ σ ) ) t µ s dbs. Let us introduce the auxiliary notation and to further rewrite 4.8) as σ σ ) t η t1 σ σ ) t η t1 ɛ := c σ σ ) t η t1 4.9) ψ s := ϕ s σ σ ) t µ s, 4.3) t1 σ σ ) ) ) t µ s + ɛ + + ψ s db s t1 + ɛ + σ σ ) ) ) t µ s + ψ s db s 9

30 σ σ ) t η t1 = = { σ σ ) t η t1 ) t1 + ɛ + ψ s db s σ σ ) t η t1 ) + ɛ + ) t1 + ɛ + ψ s db s t1 ψ s db s ) + + σ σ ) t η t1 { σ σ ) ) t η t1 t1 ) + ɛ + ψ s db s + σ σ ) t η t1 σ σ ) t η t1 t1 = + ɛ + ψ s db s ), t1 ) } ɛ + ψ s db s t1 ) } ɛ + ψ s db s where in the first equality we used the representation of η t1 in 4.6). The minimum is obtained by setting ɛ = and ψ t = on, t 1. Definition 4.1. The parameter ɛ in 4.9) is called admissible if the corresponding value of V is such that V H, H). In order to solve the second step of our recursive scheme we first introduce the following auxiliary lemmas. Lemma For any t, T and any X L p G F t), with p 1 there exists a sequence of random variables of the form n 1 X n = I Ai x i, where {A i } i=,...,n 1 is a partition of Ω, A i F t and x i R, such that Proof. Fix N, n N and let i= X X n p, n. X n := n 1 i= N n i I { N n i X < N n i+1)}. 3

31 It follows that n 1 X X n ) p = X p I { X >N} + X N n i)p I { N n i X < N i+1)} n i= X p n 1 I { X >N} + EG X N n i)p I { N i= X p I { X >N} + N n ) p I{ X N}. n i X < N n i+1)} 4.31) Since by Theorem 5 in 4 we have that X p I X >N converges to zero as N tends to infinity, we can conclude by first letting n and then N in 4.31). Lemma For any t T and n N let {A 1,..., A n } be a partition of Ω such that A i F t for every i {1,..., n}. It holds that n t ) n inf E P I Ai x i + ɛ + ψ s db s = E P I Ai x i + ɛ ), ψ MG,t) i=1 i=1 for every ɛ R, P P and {x 1,..., x n } R n +. Proof. We assume without loss of generality that {x 1,..., x n } are all different and increasingly ordered. The result is achieved by induction. If n = 1 the claim trivially holds. To prove the induction step suppose there exists a ψ MG, t) such that n+1 t ) n+1 E P I Ai x i + ɛ + ψ s db s < E P I Ai x i + ɛ ). 4.3) i=1 We show that this, together with the induction hypothesis, leads to a contradiction. To this purpose we replace x j, where j / {1, n + 1}, with a x k with k {1,..., n + 1} \ j, in order to get a sum of only n different elements and proceed as follows. Note that 4.3) is equivalent to n+1 t E P I Ai x i + ɛ + i=1 i=1 ) n+1 ψ s db s < E P + E P E P i=1 I Ai x i + ɛ ) I Aj x + ɛ + I Aj x j + ɛ + + E P I Aj x j + ɛ ) t t ) ψ s db s ) ψ s db s E P I Aj x + ɛ ), 4.33) 31

32 where x R +, and { x 1,..., x n+1 } stands for the new sequence in which x j has been replaced by x. To conclude we consider t ) t ) E P I Aj x + ɛ + ψ s db s E I P Aj x j + ɛ + ψ s db s + + E P I Aj x j + ɛ ) E P I Aj x + ɛ ) t ) =E I P Aj x x j ) x + x j + ɛ + ψ s db s + E P I Aj x x j ) x + x j + ɛ ) t ) =E I P Aj x x j ) ɛ + ψ s db s ɛ. 4.34) If now t ) E P I Aj ɛ + ψ s db s ɛ we choose x = x k for any k 1,..., j 1 and obtain for the partition and {Ã1,..., A n } := {A 1,..., A k 1, A k A j, A k+1,..., A j 1, A j+1,..., A n+1 } 4.35) {y 1,..., y n } := {x 1,..., x k 1, x k, x k+1,..., x j 1, x j+1,..., x n+1 } 4.36) that n t ) n+1 t ) E P IÃi y i + ɛ + ψ s db s = E P I Ai x i + ɛ + ψ s db s i=1 i=1 n+1 n < E P I Ai x i + ɛ ) = E P IÃi y i + ɛ ), 4.37) i=1 i=1 in contradiction with the induction hypothesis. If t ) E P I Aj ɛ + ψ s db s ɛ <, we obtain 4.37) with x = x k for any k j + 1,..., n + 1. Lemma Under the hypothesis of Lemma 4.14 and for any η t that R it holds n i=1 I Ai x i + ɛ + η t B t Gη t ) t ) = = sup σ A Θ,t σ constant = E P σ n i=1 for some σ σ, σ. E P σ n i=1 I Ai x i + ɛ + η t B t Gη t ) t ) = I Ai x i + ɛ + η t B t Gη t ) t ), 3

33 Proof. We denote for simplicity K t := η t B t Gη t ) t, and proceed again by induction, using the same conventions as in Lemma In particular, also here we assume that {x 1,..., x n } are all different and increasingly ordered. The case n = 1 is clear because of.4), as B t is maximally distributed. Assume now there exists a P P, which is not in the set {P σ, σ σ, σ, σ constant}, such that n+1 n+1 E P I Ai x i + ɛ K t ) > E P σ I Ai x i + ɛ K t ). 4.38) i=1 The expression 4.38) implies that there exists a j {1,..., n + 1} such that i=1 E P I Aj x j + ɛ K t ) > E P σ I Aj x j + ɛ K t ), 4.39) which is equivalent to ) P A j ) P σ A j ) x j + x j E P I Aj ɛ K t E P σ I Aj ɛ K t ) + + E P I Aj ɛ K t E P σ I Aj ɛ K t >. 4.4) Note that, in order for 4.39) to hold, we must have P A j ) P σ A j ) >. This implies that 4.4) is a convex function in x j, which tends to infinity as x j tends to infinity. As in Lemma 4.14, we get to a contradiction by reducing 4.38) to a sum of only n different terms, by replacing x j with another suitable value. We note that 4.38) is equivalent to n+1 n+1 E P I Ai x i + ɛ K t ) >E P σ I Ai x i + ɛ K t ) i=1 i=1 + E P σ I Aj x j + ɛ K t ) E P σ I Aj x + ɛ K t ) + E P I Aj x + ɛ K t ) E P I Aj x j + ɛ K t ), 4.41) where x R and { x 1,..., x n+1 } stands for the new sequence in which x j has been replaced by x as in Lemma To conclude, we consider E P σ I Aj x j + ɛ K t ) E P σ I Aj x + ɛ K t ) > which is equivalent to E P I Aj x j + ɛ K t ) E P I Aj x + ɛ K t ), E P σ I Aj x j x) x j + x + ɛ K t ) > E P I Aj x j x) x j + x + ɛ K t ). 4.4) 33

34 If x > x j, 4.4) is satisfied if E P σ I Aj xj + x ) ) + ɛ K t < E P xj + x I Aj + ɛ K t, which in turn is the same as ) xj + x P A j ) P σ A j ) > E P σ I Aj ɛ K t E P I Aj ɛ K t. 4.43) At this point, if there exists a x = x k satisfying 4.43), where k {j + 1,..., n + 1}, the proof is concluded, as we will get n n+1 E P IÃi y i + ɛ K t ) = E P I Ai x i + ɛ K t ) i=1 i=1 n+1 > E P σ I Ai x i + ɛ K t ) i=1 = E P σ n i=1 IÃi y i + ɛ K t ), where {Ãi} i=1,...,n and {y i } i=1,...,n are introduced in 4.35) and 4.36), respectively. If such x k does not exist, which happens if j = n + 1 for example, we first substitute some x i with a x r, where i r and i, r {1,..., n + 1} \ j, as in 4.41), and then we substitute x j with an x sufficiently large to satisfy E P σ I Aj x j + ɛ K t ) E P σ I Aj x + ɛ K t ) + E P I Aj x + ɛ K t ) E P I Aj x j + ɛ K t ) + E P σ I Ai x i + ɛ K t ) E P σ I Ai x r + ɛ K t ) + E P I Ai x r + ɛ K t ) E P I Ai x i + ɛ K t ) >. This is possible because E P σ I Aj x j + ɛ K t ) E P σ I Aj x + ɛ K t ) + E P I Aj x + ɛ K t ) E P I Aj x j + ɛ K t ) > 4.44) is equivalent to 4.43), and its value can be made large enough to ensure 4.44) because of 4.4). We can now state the main result. Theorem Consider a claim H of the form t H = H + θ s db s + η t B t1 Gη t ) t 1 + η t1 B t Gη t1 ) t, 34

35 where = t < t 1 < t = T, θ s ) s,t M G, t ), η t R, η t1 L G F t 1 ) and t1 η t1 = η t1 + µ s db s, 4.45) for a certain process µ s ) s,t1 MG, t 1). The optimal mean-variance portfolio is given by φ t X t = θ t µ tσ σ ) ) t I t,t 1 t) + θ t I t1,t t) for t, T and V = H 1 σ σ ) t η t1 ɛ, where ɛ R solves ηt1 ) inf E G ɛ σ σ ) t + ɛ + η t B t1 Gη t ) t ) Proof. By the same argument as in Proposition 4.11 we conclude that φ sx s = θ s s t 1, t and focus on the following expression ηt1 inf E t1 ) G ɛ,ψ σ σ ) t + ɛ + ψ s db s + η t B t1 Gη t ) t 1, 4.47) where ɛ and ψ are as in 4.9) and 4.3). Let Y n ) n N be a sequence of random variables approximating ηt 1 σ σ ) t in L G F t 1 ) as in Lemma 4.13, with Y n = n 1 i= I A i,n y i,n, n N, where {A i,n } i=,...,n 1 is a partition of Ω, A i,n F t and y i,n R +. Consider now the auxiliary problem inf ɛ,ψ t1 ) Y n + ɛ + ψ s db s + η t B t1 Gη t ) t 1. For every n N and any admissible ɛ we can derive the following inequalities t1 ) Y n + ɛ + ψ s db s + η t B t1 Gη t ) t 1 t1 ) sup E P σ Y n + ɛ + ψ s db s + η t B t1 Gη t ) t 1 σ σ,σ sup E P σ Y n + ɛ + η t B t1 Gη t ) t 1 ) 4.48) σ σ,σ = Y n + ɛ + η t B t1 Gη t ) t 1 ). 4.49) 35

Financial Asset Price Bubbles under Model Uncertainty

Financial Asset Price Bubbles under Model Uncertainty Financial Asset Price Bubbles under Model Uncertainty Francesca Biagini, Jacopo Mancin October 24, 27 Abstract We study the concept of financial bubbles in a market model endowed with a set P of probability

More information

Dynamic Risk Measures and Nonlinear Expectations with Markov Chain noise

Dynamic Risk Measures and Nonlinear Expectations with Markov Chain noise Dynamic Risk Measures and Nonlinear Expectations with Markov Chain noise Robert J. Elliott 1 Samuel N. Cohen 2 1 Department of Commerce, University of South Australia 2 Mathematical Insitute, University

More information

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Tim Leung 1, Qingshuo Song 2, and Jie Yang 3 1 Columbia University, New York, USA; leung@ieor.columbia.edu 2 City

More information

Risk-Minimality and Orthogonality of Martingales

Risk-Minimality and Orthogonality of Martingales Risk-Minimality and Orthogonality of Martingales Martin Schweizer Universität Bonn Institut für Angewandte Mathematik Wegelerstraße 6 D 53 Bonn 1 (Stochastics and Stochastics Reports 3 (199, 123 131 2

More information

Random G -Expectations

Random G -Expectations Random G -Expectations Marcel Nutz ETH Zurich New advances in Backward SDEs for nancial engineering applications Tamerza, Tunisia, 28.10.2010 Marcel Nutz (ETH) Random G-Expectations 1 / 17 Outline 1 Random

More information

Nonlinear representation, backward SDEs, and application to the Principal-Agent problem

Nonlinear representation, backward SDEs, and application to the Principal-Agent problem Nonlinear representation, backward SDEs, and application to the Principal-Agent problem Ecole Polytechnique, France April 4, 218 Outline The Principal-Agent problem Formulation 1 The Principal-Agent problem

More information

Solvability of G-SDE with Integral-Lipschitz Coefficients

Solvability of G-SDE with Integral-Lipschitz Coefficients Solvability of G-SDE with Integral-Lipschitz Coefficients Yiqing LIN joint work with Xuepeng Bai IRMAR, Université de Rennes 1, FRANCE http://perso.univ-rennes1.fr/yiqing.lin/ ITN Marie Curie Workshop

More information

HJB equations. Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance January 10, 2011

HJB equations. Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance January 10, 2011 Department of Probability and Mathematical Statistics Faculty of Mathematics and Physics, Charles University in Prague petrasek@karlin.mff.cuni.cz Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance

More information

Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University

Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University TIME CONSISTENT RISK AVERSE DYNAMIC DECISION MODELS: AN ECONOMIC INTERPRETATION Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University brudloff@princeton.edu Alexandre Street

More information

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint that the ON PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION UNDER \DRAWDOWN" CONSTRAINTS JAKSA CVITANIC IOANNIS KARATZAS y March 6, 994 Abstract We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the wealth

More information

A new approach for investment performance measurement. 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009

A new approach for investment performance measurement. 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009 A new approach for investment performance measurement 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009 Thaleia Zariphopoulou University of Oxford, Oxford-Man Institute and The University of Texas at Austin 1 Performance

More information

Optimal Stopping Problems and American Options

Optimal Stopping Problems and American Options Optimal Stopping Problems and American Options Nadia Uys A dissertation submitted to the Faculty of Science, University of the Witwatersrand, in fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Master

More information

Stochastic integration. P.J.C. Spreij

Stochastic integration. P.J.C. Spreij Stochastic integration P.J.C. Spreij this version: April 22, 29 Contents 1 Stochastic processes 1 1.1 General theory............................... 1 1.2 Stopping times...............................

More information

Brownian motion. Samy Tindel. Purdue University. Probability Theory 2 - MA 539

Brownian motion. Samy Tindel. Purdue University. Probability Theory 2 - MA 539 Brownian motion Samy Tindel Purdue University Probability Theory 2 - MA 539 Mostly taken from Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus by I. Karatzas and S. Shreve Samy T. Brownian motion Probability Theory

More information

Optimal stopping for non-linear expectations Part I

Optimal stopping for non-linear expectations Part I Stochastic Processes and their Applications 121 (2011) 185 211 www.elsevier.com/locate/spa Optimal stopping for non-linear expectations Part I Erhan Bayraktar, Song Yao Department of Mathematics, University

More information

Portfolio Optimization in discrete time

Portfolio Optimization in discrete time Portfolio Optimization in discrete time Wolfgang J. Runggaldier Dipartimento di Matematica Pura ed Applicata Universitá di Padova, Padova http://www.math.unipd.it/runggaldier/index.html Abstract he paper

More information

The main purpose of this chapter is to prove the rst and second fundamental theorem of asset pricing in a so called nite market model.

The main purpose of this chapter is to prove the rst and second fundamental theorem of asset pricing in a so called nite market model. 1 2. Option pricing in a nite market model (February 14, 2012) 1 Introduction The main purpose of this chapter is to prove the rst and second fundamental theorem of asset pricing in a so called nite market

More information

Conjugate duality in stochastic optimization

Conjugate duality in stochastic optimization Ari-Pekka Perkkiö, Institute of Mathematics, Aalto University Ph.D. instructor/joint work with Teemu Pennanen, Institute of Mathematics, Aalto University March 15th 2010 1 / 13 We study convex problems.

More information

Continuous Time Finance

Continuous Time Finance Continuous Time Finance Lisbon 2013 Tomas Björk Stockholm School of Economics Tomas Björk, 2013 Contents Stochastic Calculus (Ch 4-5). Black-Scholes (Ch 6-7. Completeness and hedging (Ch 8-9. The martingale

More information

On continuous time contract theory

On continuous time contract theory Ecole Polytechnique, France Journée de rentrée du CMAP, 3 octobre, 218 Outline 1 2 Semimartingale measures on the canonical space Random horizon 2nd order backward SDEs (Static) Principal-Agent Problem

More information

3 (Due ). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure?

3 (Due ). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure? MA 645-4A (Real Analysis), Dr. Chernov Homework assignment 1 (Due ). Show that the open disk x 2 + y 2 < 1 is a countable union of planar elementary sets. Show that the closed disk x 2 + y 2 1 is a countable

More information

An Uncertain Control Model with Application to. Production-Inventory System

An Uncertain Control Model with Application to. Production-Inventory System An Uncertain Control Model with Application to Production-Inventory System Kai Yao 1, Zhongfeng Qin 2 1 Department of Mathematical Sciences, Tsinghua University, Beijing 100084, China 2 School of Economics

More information

Risk Measures in non-dominated Models

Risk Measures in non-dominated Models Purpose: Study Risk Measures taking into account the model uncertainty in mathematical finance. Plan 1 Non-dominated Models Model Uncertainty Fundamental topological Properties 2 Risk Measures on L p (c)

More information

Information and Credit Risk

Information and Credit Risk Information and Credit Risk M. L. Bedini Université de Bretagne Occidentale, Brest - Friedrich Schiller Universität, Jena Jena, March 2011 M. L. Bedini (Université de Bretagne Occidentale, Brest Information

More information

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3 Brownian Motion Contents 1 Definition 2 1.1 Brownian Motion................................. 2 1.2 Wiener measure.................................. 3 2 Construction 4 2.1 Gaussian process.................................

More information

Stochastic Calculus (Lecture #3)

Stochastic Calculus (Lecture #3) Stochastic Calculus (Lecture #3) Siegfried Hörmann Université libre de Bruxelles (ULB) Spring 2014 Outline of the course 1. Stochastic processes in continuous time. 2. Brownian motion. 3. Itô integral:

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 24 Sep 2018

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 24 Sep 2018 A short note on Anticipative portfolio optimization B. D Auria a,b,1,, J.-A. Salmerón a,1 a Dpto. Estadística, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid. Avda. de la Universidad 3, 8911, Leganés (Madrid Spain b

More information

A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations

A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations Michael Röckner Reference: C. Prevot, M. Röckner: Springer LN in Math. 1905, Berlin (2007) And see the references therein for the original

More information

Convergence at first and second order of some approximations of stochastic integrals

Convergence at first and second order of some approximations of stochastic integrals Convergence at first and second order of some approximations of stochastic integrals Bérard Bergery Blandine, Vallois Pierre IECN, Nancy-Université, CNRS, INRIA, Boulevard des Aiguillettes B.P. 239 F-5456

More information

Prof. Erhan Bayraktar (University of Michigan)

Prof. Erhan Bayraktar (University of Michigan) September 17, 2012 KAP 414 2:15 PM- 3:15 PM Prof. (University of Michigan) Abstract: We consider a zero-sum stochastic differential controller-and-stopper game in which the state process is a controlled

More information

Continuous Functions on Metric Spaces

Continuous Functions on Metric Spaces Continuous Functions on Metric Spaces Math 201A, Fall 2016 1 Continuous functions Definition 1. Let (X, d X ) and (Y, d Y ) be metric spaces. A function f : X Y is continuous at a X if for every ɛ > 0

More information

Quasi-sure Stochastic Analysis through Aggregation

Quasi-sure Stochastic Analysis through Aggregation Quasi-sure Stochastic Analysis through Aggregation H. Mete Soner Nizar Touzi Jianfeng Zhang March 7, 21 Abstract This paper is on developing stochastic analysis simultaneously under a general family of

More information

Time-Consistent Mean-Variance Portfolio Selection in Discrete and Continuous Time

Time-Consistent Mean-Variance Portfolio Selection in Discrete and Continuous Time ime-consistent Mean-Variance Portfolio Selection in Discrete and Continuous ime Christoph Czichowsky Department of Mathematics EH Zurich BFS 21 oronto, 26th June 21 Christoph Czichowsky (EH Zurich) Mean-variance

More information

Some Aspects of Universal Portfolio

Some Aspects of Universal Portfolio 1 Some Aspects of Universal Portfolio Tomoyuki Ichiba (UC Santa Barbara) joint work with Marcel Brod (ETH Zurich) Conference on Stochastic Asymptotics & Applications Sixth Western Conference on Mathematical

More information

Mean-Variance Hedging for Continuous Processes: New Proofs and Examples

Mean-Variance Hedging for Continuous Processes: New Proofs and Examples Mean-Variance Hedging for Continuous Processes: New Proofs and Examples Huyên Pham Équipe d Analyse et de Mathématiques Appliquées Université de Marne-la-Vallée 2, rue de la Butte Verte F 9366 Noisy-le-Grand

More information

Snell envelope and the pricing of American-style contingent claims

Snell envelope and the pricing of American-style contingent claims Snell envelope and the pricing of -style contingent claims 80-646-08 Stochastic calculus I Geneviève Gauthier HEC Montréal Notation The The riskless security Market model The following text draws heavily

More information

Applications of Ito s Formula

Applications of Ito s Formula CHAPTER 4 Applications of Ito s Formula In this chapter, we discuss several basic theorems in stochastic analysis. Their proofs are good examples of applications of Itô s formula. 1. Lévy s martingale

More information

Filtrations, Markov Processes and Martingales. Lectures on Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus, Braunschweig, Lecture 3: The Lévy-Itô Decomposition

Filtrations, Markov Processes and Martingales. Lectures on Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus, Braunschweig, Lecture 3: The Lévy-Itô Decomposition Filtrations, Markov Processes and Martingales Lectures on Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus, Braunschweig, Lecture 3: The Lévy-Itô Decomposition David pplebaum Probability and Statistics Department,

More information

Generalized Gaussian Bridges of Prediction-Invertible Processes

Generalized Gaussian Bridges of Prediction-Invertible Processes Generalized Gaussian Bridges of Prediction-Invertible Processes Tommi Sottinen 1 and Adil Yazigi University of Vaasa, Finland Modern Stochastics: Theory and Applications III September 1, 212, Kyiv, Ukraine

More information

Nested Uncertain Differential Equations and Its Application to Multi-factor Term Structure Model

Nested Uncertain Differential Equations and Its Application to Multi-factor Term Structure Model Nested Uncertain Differential Equations and Its Application to Multi-factor Term Structure Model Xiaowei Chen International Business School, Nankai University, Tianjin 371, China School of Finance, Nankai

More information

Discretization of SDEs: Euler Methods and Beyond

Discretization of SDEs: Euler Methods and Beyond Discretization of SDEs: Euler Methods and Beyond 09-26-2006 / PRisMa 2006 Workshop Outline Introduction 1 Introduction Motivation Stochastic Differential Equations 2 The Time Discretization of SDEs Monte-Carlo

More information

2. Dual space is essential for the concept of gradient which, in turn, leads to the variational analysis of Lagrange multipliers.

2. Dual space is essential for the concept of gradient which, in turn, leads to the variational analysis of Lagrange multipliers. Chapter 3 Duality in Banach Space Modern optimization theory largely centers around the interplay of a normed vector space and its corresponding dual. The notion of duality is important for the following

More information

On the Multi-Dimensional Controller and Stopper Games

On the Multi-Dimensional Controller and Stopper Games On the Multi-Dimensional Controller and Stopper Games Joint work with Yu-Jui Huang University of Michigan, Ann Arbor June 7, 2012 Outline Introduction 1 Introduction 2 3 4 5 Consider a zero-sum controller-and-stopper

More information

Sample of Ph.D. Advisory Exam For MathFinance

Sample of Ph.D. Advisory Exam For MathFinance Sample of Ph.D. Advisory Exam For MathFinance Students who wish to enter the Ph.D. program of Mathematics of Finance are required to take the advisory exam. This exam consists of three major parts. The

More information

Introduction Optimality and Asset Pricing

Introduction Optimality and Asset Pricing Introduction Optimality and Asset Pricing Andrea Buraschi Imperial College Business School October 2010 The Euler Equation Take an economy where price is given with respect to the numéraire, which is our

More information

4th Preparation Sheet - Solutions

4th Preparation Sheet - Solutions Prof. Dr. Rainer Dahlhaus Probability Theory Summer term 017 4th Preparation Sheet - Solutions Remark: Throughout the exercise sheet we use the two equivalent definitions of separability of a metric space

More information

Thomas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover

Thomas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover Optimal long term investment under model ambiguity Optimal long term investment under model ambiguity homas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover knispel@stochastik.uni-hannover.de AnStAp0 Vienna, July

More information

(B(t i+1 ) B(t i )) 2

(B(t i+1 ) B(t i )) 2 ltcc5.tex Week 5 29 October 213 Ch. V. ITÔ (STOCHASTIC) CALCULUS. WEAK CONVERGENCE. 1. Quadratic Variation. A partition π n of [, t] is a finite set of points t ni such that = t n < t n1

More information

UTILITY OPTIMIZATION IN A FINITE SCENARIO SETTING

UTILITY OPTIMIZATION IN A FINITE SCENARIO SETTING UTILITY OPTIMIZATION IN A FINITE SCENARIO SETTING J. TEICHMANN Abstract. We introduce the main concepts of duality theory for utility optimization in a setting of finitely many economic scenarios. 1. Utility

More information

Dynkin (λ-) and π-systems; monotone classes of sets, and of functions with some examples of application (mainly of a probabilistic flavor)

Dynkin (λ-) and π-systems; monotone classes of sets, and of functions with some examples of application (mainly of a probabilistic flavor) Dynkin (λ-) and π-systems; monotone classes of sets, and of functions with some examples of application (mainly of a probabilistic flavor) Matija Vidmar February 7, 2018 1 Dynkin and π-systems Some basic

More information

The concentration of a drug in blood. Exponential decay. Different realizations. Exponential decay with noise. dc(t) dt.

The concentration of a drug in blood. Exponential decay. Different realizations. Exponential decay with noise. dc(t) dt. The concentration of a drug in blood Exponential decay C12 concentration 2 4 6 8 1 C12 concentration 2 4 6 8 1 dc(t) dt = µc(t) C(t) = C()e µt 2 4 6 8 1 12 time in minutes 2 4 6 8 1 12 time in minutes

More information

STATISTICS 385: STOCHASTIC CALCULUS HOMEWORK ASSIGNMENT 4 DUE NOVEMBER 23, = (2n 1)(2n 3) 3 1.

STATISTICS 385: STOCHASTIC CALCULUS HOMEWORK ASSIGNMENT 4 DUE NOVEMBER 23, = (2n 1)(2n 3) 3 1. STATISTICS 385: STOCHASTIC CALCULUS HOMEWORK ASSIGNMENT 4 DUE NOVEMBER 23, 26 Problem Normal Moments (A) Use the Itô formula and Brownian scaling to check that the even moments of the normal distribution

More information

I forgot to mention last time: in the Ito formula for two standard processes, putting

I forgot to mention last time: in the Ito formula for two standard processes, putting I forgot to mention last time: in the Ito formula for two standard processes, putting dx t = a t dt + b t db t dy t = α t dt + β t db t, and taking f(x, y = xy, one has f x = y, f y = x, and f xx = f yy

More information

Trajectorial Martingales, Null Sets, Convergence and Integration

Trajectorial Martingales, Null Sets, Convergence and Integration Trajectorial Martingales, Null Sets, Convergence and Integration Sebastian Ferrando, Department of Mathematics, Ryerson University, Toronto, Canada Alfredo Gonzalez and Sebastian Ferrando Trajectorial

More information

Lecture 22 Girsanov s Theorem

Lecture 22 Girsanov s Theorem Lecture 22: Girsanov s Theorem of 8 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 25 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 22 Girsanov s Theorem An example Consider a finite Gaussian random walk X n = n

More information

Worst Case Portfolio Optimization and HJB-Systems

Worst Case Portfolio Optimization and HJB-Systems Worst Case Portfolio Optimization and HJB-Systems Ralf Korn and Mogens Steffensen Abstract We formulate a portfolio optimization problem as a game where the investor chooses a portfolio and his opponent,

More information

Bernardo D Auria Stochastic Processes /12. Notes. March 29 th, 2012

Bernardo D Auria Stochastic Processes /12. Notes. March 29 th, 2012 1 Stochastic Calculus Notes March 9 th, 1 In 19, Bachelier proposed for the Paris stock exchange a model for the fluctuations affecting the price X(t) of an asset that was given by the Brownian motion.

More information

The Wiener Itô Chaos Expansion

The Wiener Itô Chaos Expansion 1 The Wiener Itô Chaos Expansion The celebrated Wiener Itô chaos expansion is fundamental in stochastic analysis. In particular, it plays a crucial role in the Malliavin calculus as it is presented in

More information

Point Process Control

Point Process Control Point Process Control The following note is based on Chapters I, II and VII in Brémaud s book Point Processes and Queues (1981). 1 Basic Definitions Consider some probability space (Ω, F, P). A real-valued

More information

2 Sequences, Continuity, and Limits

2 Sequences, Continuity, and Limits 2 Sequences, Continuity, and Limits In this chapter, we introduce the fundamental notions of continuity and limit of a real-valued function of two variables. As in ACICARA, the definitions as well as proofs

More information

IOANNIS KARATZAS Mathematics and Statistics Departments Columbia University

IOANNIS KARATZAS Mathematics and Statistics Departments Columbia University STOCHASTIC PORTFOLIO THEORY IOANNIS KARATZAS Mathematics and Statistics Departments Columbia University ik@math.columbia.edu Joint work with Dr. E. Robert FERNHOLZ, C.I.O. of INTECH Enhanced Investment

More information

Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process

Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process Lecture 17: Brownian motion as a Markov process 1 of 14 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 2015 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process Brownian motion is

More information

Mathematical finance (extended from lectures of Fall 2012 by Martin Schweizer transcribed by Peter Gracar and Thomas Hille) Josef Teichmann

Mathematical finance (extended from lectures of Fall 2012 by Martin Schweizer transcribed by Peter Gracar and Thomas Hille) Josef Teichmann Mathematical finance (extended from lectures of Fall 2012 by Martin Schweizer transcribed by Peter Gracar and Thomas Hille) Josef Teichmann Contents Chapter 1. Arbitrage Theory 5 1. Stochastic Integration

More information

Non Implementability of Arrow Debreu Equilibria by Continuous Trading under Knightian Uncertainty

Non Implementability of Arrow Debreu Equilibria by Continuous Trading under Knightian Uncertainty arxiv:149.694v1 [q-fin.mf] 18 Sep 214 Non Implementability of Arrow Debreu Equilibria by Continuous Trading under Knightian Uncertainty Frank Riedel Patrick Beißner Center for Mathematical Economics Bielefeld

More information

Pathwise volatility in a long-memory pricing model: estimation and asymptotic behavior

Pathwise volatility in a long-memory pricing model: estimation and asymptotic behavior Pathwise volatility in a long-memory pricing model: estimation and asymptotic behavior Ehsan Azmoodeh University of Vaasa Finland 7th General AMaMeF and Swissquote Conference September 7 1, 215 Outline

More information

Differential Games II. Marc Quincampoix Université de Bretagne Occidentale ( Brest-France) SADCO, London, September 2011

Differential Games II. Marc Quincampoix Université de Bretagne Occidentale ( Brest-France) SADCO, London, September 2011 Differential Games II Marc Quincampoix Université de Bretagne Occidentale ( Brest-France) SADCO, London, September 2011 Contents 1. I Introduction: A Pursuit Game and Isaacs Theory 2. II Strategies 3.

More information

1. Stochastic Processes and filtrations

1. Stochastic Processes and filtrations 1. Stochastic Processes and 1. Stoch. pr., A stochastic process (X t ) t T is a collection of random variables on (Ω, F) with values in a measurable space (S, S), i.e., for all t, In our case X t : Ω S

More information

PROGRESSIVE ENLARGEMENTS OF FILTRATIONS AND SEMIMARTINGALE DECOMPOSITIONS

PROGRESSIVE ENLARGEMENTS OF FILTRATIONS AND SEMIMARTINGALE DECOMPOSITIONS PROGRESSIVE ENLARGEMENTS OF FILTRATIONS AND SEMIMARTINGALE DECOMPOSITIONS Libo Li and Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney NSW 26, Australia July 1, 211 Abstract We

More information

Question 1. The correct answers are: (a) (2) (b) (1) (c) (2) (d) (3) (e) (2) (f) (1) (g) (2) (h) (1)

Question 1. The correct answers are: (a) (2) (b) (1) (c) (2) (d) (3) (e) (2) (f) (1) (g) (2) (h) (1) Question 1 The correct answers are: a 2 b 1 c 2 d 3 e 2 f 1 g 2 h 1 Question 2 a Any probability measure Q equivalent to P on F 2 can be described by Q[{x 1, x 2 }] := q x1 q x1,x 2, 1 where q x1, q x1,x

More information

Tools of stochastic calculus

Tools of stochastic calculus slides for the course Interest rate theory, University of Ljubljana, 212-13/I, part III József Gáll University of Debrecen Nov. 212 Jan. 213, Ljubljana Itô integral, summary of main facts Notations, basic

More information

1 Lyapunov theory of stability

1 Lyapunov theory of stability M.Kawski, APM 581 Diff Equns Intro to Lyapunov theory. November 15, 29 1 1 Lyapunov theory of stability Introduction. Lyapunov s second (or direct) method provides tools for studying (asymptotic) stability

More information

Deterministic Dynamic Programming

Deterministic Dynamic Programming Deterministic Dynamic Programming 1 Value Function Consider the following optimal control problem in Mayer s form: V (t 0, x 0 ) = inf u U J(t 1, x(t 1 )) (1) subject to ẋ(t) = f(t, x(t), u(t)), x(t 0

More information

Duality and Utility Maximization

Duality and Utility Maximization Duality and Utility Maximization Bachelor Thesis Niklas A. Pfister July 11, 2013 Advisor: Prof. Dr. Halil Mete Soner Department of Mathematics, ETH Zürich Abstract This thesis explores the problem of maximizing

More information

A numerical method for solving uncertain differential equations

A numerical method for solving uncertain differential equations Journal of Intelligent & Fuzzy Systems 25 (213 825 832 DOI:1.3233/IFS-12688 IOS Press 825 A numerical method for solving uncertain differential equations Kai Yao a and Xiaowei Chen b, a Department of Mathematical

More information

Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales

Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales Lecture 21: Representations of Martingales 1 of 11 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 215 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales Right-continuous inverses Let

More information

Exponential martingales: uniform integrability results and applications to point processes

Exponential martingales: uniform integrability results and applications to point processes Exponential martingales: uniform integrability results and applications to point processes Alexander Sokol Department of Mathematical Sciences, University of Copenhagen 26 September, 2012 1 / 39 Agenda

More information

If Y and Y 0 satisfy (1-2), then Y = Y 0 a.s.

If Y and Y 0 satisfy (1-2), then Y = Y 0 a.s. 20 6. CONDITIONAL EXPECTATION Having discussed at length the limit theory for sums of independent random variables we will now move on to deal with dependent random variables. An important tool in this

More information

Elements of Stochastic Analysis with application to Finance (52579) Pavel Chigansky

Elements of Stochastic Analysis with application to Finance (52579) Pavel Chigansky Elements of Stochastic Analysis with application to Finance 52579 Pavel Chigansky Department of Statistics, The Hebrew University, Mount Scopus, Jerusalem 9195, Israel E-mail address: pchiga@mscc.huji.ac.il

More information

of space-time diffusions

of space-time diffusions Optimal investment for all time horizons and Martin boundary of space-time diffusions Sergey Nadtochiy and Michael Tehranchi October 5, 2012 Abstract This paper is concerned with the axiomatic foundation

More information

Uniformly Uniformly-ergodic Markov chains and BSDEs

Uniformly Uniformly-ergodic Markov chains and BSDEs Uniformly Uniformly-ergodic Markov chains and BSDEs Samuel N. Cohen Mathematical Institute, University of Oxford (Based on joint work with Ying Hu, Robert Elliott, Lukas Szpruch) Centre Henri Lebesgue,

More information

Stochastic optimal control with rough paths

Stochastic optimal control with rough paths Stochastic optimal control with rough paths Paul Gassiat TU Berlin Stochastic processes and their statistics in Finance, Okinawa, October 28, 2013 Joint work with Joscha Diehl and Peter Friz Introduction

More information

n E(X t T n = lim X s Tn = X s

n E(X t T n = lim X s Tn = X s Stochastic Calculus Example sheet - Lent 15 Michael Tehranchi Problem 1. Let X be a local martingale. Prove that X is a uniformly integrable martingale if and only X is of class D. Solution 1. If If direction:

More information

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING 218. HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROF. YURI BAKHTIN Instructions. You are allowed to work on solutions in groups, but you are required to write up solutions on your own. Please

More information

Squared Bessel Process with Delay

Squared Bessel Process with Delay Southern Illinois University Carbondale OpenSIUC Articles and Preprints Department of Mathematics 216 Squared Bessel Process with Delay Harry Randolph Hughes Southern Illinois University Carbondale, hrhughes@siu.edu

More information

Linear Quadratic Zero-Sum Two-Person Differential Games Pierre Bernhard June 15, 2013

Linear Quadratic Zero-Sum Two-Person Differential Games Pierre Bernhard June 15, 2013 Linear Quadratic Zero-Sum Two-Person Differential Games Pierre Bernhard June 15, 2013 Abstract As in optimal control theory, linear quadratic (LQ) differential games (DG) can be solved, even in high dimension,

More information

Solution for Problem 7.1. We argue by contradiction. If the limit were not infinite, then since τ M (ω) is nondecreasing we would have

Solution for Problem 7.1. We argue by contradiction. If the limit were not infinite, then since τ M (ω) is nondecreasing we would have 362 Problem Hints and Solutions sup g n (ω, t) g(ω, t) sup g(ω, s) g(ω, t) µ n (ω). t T s,t: s t 1/n By the uniform continuity of t g(ω, t) on [, T], one has for each ω that µ n (ω) as n. Two applications

More information

Weak solutions of mean-field stochastic differential equations

Weak solutions of mean-field stochastic differential equations Weak solutions of mean-field stochastic differential equations Juan Li School of Mathematics and Statistics, Shandong University (Weihai), Weihai 26429, China. Email: juanli@sdu.edu.cn Based on joint works

More information

REAL AND COMPLEX ANALYSIS

REAL AND COMPLEX ANALYSIS REAL AND COMPLE ANALYSIS Third Edition Walter Rudin Professor of Mathematics University of Wisconsin, Madison Version 1.1 No rights reserved. Any part of this work can be reproduced or transmitted in any

More information

Proving the Regularity of the Minimal Probability of Ruin via a Game of Stopping and Control

Proving the Regularity of the Minimal Probability of Ruin via a Game of Stopping and Control Proving the Regularity of the Minimal Probability of Ruin via a Game of Stopping and Control Erhan Bayraktar University of Michigan joint work with Virginia R. Young, University of Michigan K αρλoβασi,

More information

Backward martingale representation and endogenous completeness in finance

Backward martingale representation and endogenous completeness in finance Backward martingale representation and endogenous completeness in finance Dmitry Kramkov (with Silviu Predoiu) Carnegie Mellon University 1 / 19 Bibliography Robert M. Anderson and Roberto C. Raimondo.

More information

Optimal Trade Execution with Instantaneous Price Impact and Stochastic Resilience

Optimal Trade Execution with Instantaneous Price Impact and Stochastic Resilience Optimal Trade Execution with Instantaneous Price Impact and Stochastic Resilience Ulrich Horst 1 Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin Department of Mathematics and School of Business and Economics Vienna, Nov.

More information

1 The Observability Canonical Form

1 The Observability Canonical Form NONLINEAR OBSERVERS AND SEPARATION PRINCIPLE 1 The Observability Canonical Form In this Chapter we discuss the design of observers for nonlinear systems modelled by equations of the form ẋ = f(x, u) (1)

More information

A Simple Computational Approach to the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing

A Simple Computational Approach to the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 6, 2012, no. 72, 3555-3562 A Simple Computational Approach to the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing Cherng-tiao Perng Department of Mathematics Norfolk State University

More information

Stochastic Calculus for Finance II - some Solutions to Chapter VII

Stochastic Calculus for Finance II - some Solutions to Chapter VII Stochastic Calculus for Finance II - some Solutions to Chapter VII Matthias hul Last Update: June 9, 25 Exercise 7 Black-Scholes-Merton Equation for the up-and-out Call) i) We have ii) We first compute

More information

Metric Spaces and Topology

Metric Spaces and Topology Chapter 2 Metric Spaces and Topology From an engineering perspective, the most important way to construct a topology on a set is to define the topology in terms of a metric on the set. This approach underlies

More information

HOPF S DECOMPOSITION AND RECURRENT SEMIGROUPS. Josef Teichmann

HOPF S DECOMPOSITION AND RECURRENT SEMIGROUPS. Josef Teichmann HOPF S DECOMPOSITION AND RECURRENT SEMIGROUPS Josef Teichmann Abstract. Some results of ergodic theory are generalized in the setting of Banach lattices, namely Hopf s maximal ergodic inequality and the

More information

Necessary Conditions for the Existence of Utility Maximizing Strategies under Transaction Costs

Necessary Conditions for the Existence of Utility Maximizing Strategies under Transaction Costs Necessary Conditions for the Existence of Utility Maximizing Strategies under Transaction Costs Paolo Guasoni Boston University and University of Pisa Walter Schachermayer Vienna University of Technology

More information

Lecture 12. F o s, (1.1) F t := s>t

Lecture 12. F o s, (1.1) F t := s>t Lecture 12 1 Brownian motion: the Markov property Let C := C(0, ), R) be the space of continuous functions mapping from 0, ) to R, in which a Brownian motion (B t ) t 0 almost surely takes its value. Let

More information

Stability of Stochastic Differential Equations

Stability of Stochastic Differential Equations Lyapunov stability theory for ODEs s Stability of Stochastic Differential Equations Part 1: Introduction Department of Mathematics and Statistics University of Strathclyde Glasgow, G1 1XH December 2010

More information

EXTENSIONS OF CONVEX FUNCTIONALS ON CONVEX CONES

EXTENSIONS OF CONVEX FUNCTIONALS ON CONVEX CONES APPLICATIONES MATHEMATICAE 25,3 (1998), pp. 381 386 E. IGNACZAK (Szczecin) A. PASZKIEWICZ ( Lódź) EXTENSIONS OF CONVEX FUNCTIONALS ON CONVEX CONES Abstract. We prove that under some topological assumptions

More information