Institutions as a Source of Comparative Advantage

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Institutions as a Source of Comparative Advantage"

Transcription

1 Institutions as a Source of Comparative Avantage Tomohiro Ara Fukushima University This Version: February 2013 Abstract Why oes the fraction of firms that eport vary with countries comparative avantage? To aress this question, I evelop a general-equilibrium Ricarian moel of orth-south trae in which both institutional quality an firm heterogeneity play a key role in etermining international trae flows. Because of contractual frictions that vary across countries an sectors, orth with better institutions prouces relatively more in a sector where prouction is more institutionally epenent. In aition, institution-inuce comparative avantage makes it relatively easier for orthern heterogeneous firms to incur eport costs in a more contract-epenent sector, thereby leaing to a higher eporters percentage. Keywors: Contracting institutions, firm heterogeneity, comparative avantage JEL Classification umbers: D23, F12, F14, L33, O43 I am eeply grateful to Arghya Ghosh an Hoaka Morita for invaluable guiance an encouragement, an to Richar Balwin, Anrew Bernar, Arpita Chatterjee, Qingyuan Du, Taiji Furusawa, Jota Ishikawa, Keith Maskus, Phillip McCalman, Devashish Mitra, icolas Schmitt, an seminar an conference participants at various institutions for helpful comments an suggestions. I have also benefite from financial support from USW an Hitotsubashi University. eeless to say, all remaining errors are my own responsibility. Faculty of Economics an Business Aministration, Fukushima University, Fukushima, , Japan. aress: tomohiro@econ.fukushima-u.ac.jp.

2 1 Introuction A growing boy of empirical evience using firm-level ata has etensively reveale that the etent to which firms participate in eporting varies systematically across countries an sectors. These works have foun that, in evelope countries, the percentage of firms that eport tens to be substantially higher in sectors where prouction technology is more comple an customize (such as chemical proucts), an the share of eporters steaily eclines as sectors prouction requires simpler an more generic technology (such as tetile proucts). In eveloping countries, on the other han, the opposite patterns are typically observe: the ratio of eporting firms to overall firms tens to be notably higher (resp. lower) in simpler (resp. more comple) sectors. At the same time, these stuies have also ocumente that eporting occurs in every major manufacturing sector of both evelope an eveloping countries: even in a strong comparative isavantage sector, a small fraction of firms o eport. 1 Why oes the fraction of firms that eport vary with countries comparative avantage? To answer this question, combining the recent empirical fining quantifie by Levchenko (2007) an unn (2007) with firm heterogeneity of Melitz (2003), I evelop a general-equilibrium Ricarian moel of orth-south trae in which both institutional quality an firm heterogeneity play a key role in etermining international trae flows. Following Levchenko s an unn s fining, the moel assumes that each country is ifferent in terms of contracting institutions, an each sector is ifferent in terms of contract intensity. Furthermore, each firm is ifferent in terms of its prouctivity à la Melitz. These three-imensional ifferences in country, sector, an firm characteristics enogenously pin own the pattern of specialization an trae in equilibrium. To investigate the role of country an sector characteristics, I buil on the concept of partial contractibility, originally evelope by Acemoglu, Antràs, an Helpman (2007). I consier an environment in which orth has better institutions for partially e-ante contractible activities than South, whereas customize sectors make use of relationship-specific investments intensively more than generic sectors. Because of these contractual frictions that vary across countries an sectors, aggregate output ifferences emerge. In contrast to Acemoglu et al., I o not eplicitly eamine the interaction between contractual incompleteness an technological complementarity by simply assuming that prouction in customize (generic) sectors is more (less) epenent on institutions. Instea, I eten their framework by allowing countries institutional quality an sectors institutional epenency to obey the Ricarian law of comparative avantage. This elaboration makes it possible to capture the aggregate relationship between country an sector characteristics neatly in a way such that orth with better institutions prouces relatively more in a sector where prouction is more institutionally epenent. 1 See Bernar, Eaton, Jensen, an Kortum (2003) an Bernar, Jensen, Reing, an Schott (2007) for the Unite States, Tomiura (2007) for Japan, an Lu (2011) for China, respectively. For eample, Bernar et al. (2007, Table 2) report that, as of 2002, 36 percent (8 percent) of U.S. firms eport in a chemical manufacturing sector (an apparel manufacturing sector), whereby a more customize sector tens to ehibit a higher percentage of eporters among 21 sectors. Conversely, Lu (2011, Figure 1) shows that, as of 2005, aroun 60 percent (less than 20 percent) of Chinese firms eport in cloth an fur manufacturing sectors (a chemical manufacturing sector), inicating that there eists a clear negative relationship between eport participation an the capital-labor ratio among 29 sectors. Finally, Bernar et al. (2003, 2007), Tomiura (2007), an Lu (2011) all ocument that there eist some eporting firms in every manufacturing sector. 1

3 To formalize a higher tenency to eport participation in comparative avantage sectors, I incorporate firm-level ifferences in prouctivity. Since eporting requires fie eport costs that less prouctive firms cannot cover, only a small fraction of firms are able to eport. The variation in this fraction is further reinforce by institution-inuce comparative avantage in my setup, because orthern (Southern) firms are relatively better at proucing in a more (less) contract-epenent sector, which in turn softens the relative buren of incurring eport costs. As a result, compare to a comparative isavantage sector in a counterpart country, relatively less prouctive firms can eport in a country s comparative avantage sector. This mechanism eplains why the stronger institutional comparative avantage is, the smaller the prouctivity cutoff for eporting becomes, thereby leaing to a higher eporters percentage. Following the new literature on institutions an trae, I employ contracting institutions more specifically contract enforcement (rather than the classical eterminants of international trae such as capital or (un)skille labor) to rationalize the stylize fact of eport participation. There are at least three reasons for this. First, countries abilities to enforce contracts can have quantitatively larger impacts on comparative avantage than countries resource enowments. For instance, unn (2007) estimates that contract enforcement eplains more of the global pattern of trae than countries enowments of physical capital an skille labor combine. Secon, as rigorously emonstrate by Costinot (2009a), this empirical evience is appropriately capture by (Ricarian) institutional ifferences with log-supermoularity in country an sector characteristics. 2 In this specification, the characteristic of firms in terms of their prouctivity is an inepenent factor of the variation in eport participation as iscusse above. Finally, the Ricarian view of institutional ifferences gives a complementary eplanation for Bernar, Reing, an Schott s (2007) factor-enowment riven comparative avantage theory. Although the main result is strikingly similar, I show that some phenomena (e.g., home-market effects) are well unerstoo through a lens of Ricarian sources of comparative avantage. In this paper, I o not attempt to eplain why orth has better institutions than South, why customize sectors epen heavily on institutions more than generic sectors, or why some firms are more prouctive than others. Taking these country, sector, an firm characteristics as given, I instea set out to eplore how contracting institutions an heterogeneous firms jointly shape an enogenous pattern of trae. In so oing, the moel shows that orth with better institutions gains comparative avantage in contract-epenent sectors an is a net eporter of customize proucts in intra-inustry trae. South with worse contracting institutions, on the other han, is shown to be a net eporter of generic proucts. Moreover, within sectors in bilateral trae flows, the fraction of eporters is monotonically increasing in countries comparative avantage strength. These results, both of which are consistent with empirical evience, hol even if orth has absolute avantage in institutional quality in any sector, an there eists no technological ifference (in terms of firm prouctivity istributions) between the two countries. 2 As far as log-supermoularity in country an sector characteristics is central, the moeling of technological an institutional ifferences is isomorphic (Costinot, 2009a). This is because a country with better institutions faces less severe unerinvestment an thus has bigger cost avantage in prouction, which is a key presumption in empirical stuies by Levchenko (2007) an unn (2007). Although it is questionable whether institutions are more crucial than technologies for trae patterns, evience on these two ifferences is so far unavailable. 2

4 This paper is closely relate to two branches of the recent literature of international trae. The first is an emerging literature on institutions an trae (e.g., Antràs, 2005; Acemoglu et al., 2007; Costinot, 2009b). These papers show that, even in the absence of technological ifference, cross-country institutional ifferences can enogenously generate comparative avantage, which is at the heart of my moel as well. In this stran of the papers, however, all firms are generally treate as ientical an therefore every firm is able to eport everywhere. 3 In the real worl, a large proportion of firms o not eport even in a strong comparative avantage sector. The current paper emonstrates that not only is comparative avantage enogenously inuce by institutions, but also that the fraction of eporters is higher in a stronger comparative avantage sector, as suggeste by the eisting evience. Another branch of the relate literature is the so-calle heterogeneous-firm moel of trae, especially evelope by the seminal work of Melitz (2003). While Melitz s moel is successful in eplaining the eporters behavior among evelope countries (orth-orth trae), recent empirical evience has pointe out that his moel is less suitable for the stuy of bilateral trae flows between ifferent countries (orth-south trae), as eemplifie by Lu (2011) who analyzes Chinese firm-level manufacturing ata. A number of papers, among others, Demiova (2008), Falvey, Greenaway, an Yu (2005), Fan, Lai, an Qi (2011), an Okubo (2009), incorporate the asymmetry of countries in this setting. My approach iffers from these papers, because I focus on the role of wage ifferentials in orth-south trae, 4 an because most results hol without specifying any parameterization of firm prouctivity istributions. More importantly, none of these papers shes new light on the interplay between institutions an comparative avantage. Although I restrict the analysis only to an open economy an abstract from welfare implications for epositional simplicity, it is straightforwar to eten the current setup to see the impact of trae on inter-/intra-sectoral resource allocations an welfare gains from trae. Finally, this paper is also relate to the heterogeneous-firm literature on factor-proportions theory, especially to Bernar et al. (2007) as argue above. Using Helpman-Krugman s (1985) two-factor moel, they provie a rich framework for analyzing istributional consequences from trae, a feature missing in this Ricarian one-factor moel. Their analysis, however, primarily applies to the situation in which two countries are not too ifferent, an numerical simulations are require for outsie factor-price-equalization regions. In contrast, it is possible in the current paper to analytically eamine trae patterns between any two countries of arbitrary country size (with enogenous wage ifferentials) by sacrificing istributional issues via trae liberalization. A further istinction of this paper is in aressing Krugman s (1980) home-market effect. I show that, ue to selection into omestic an eport markets that varies with comparative avantage, the home-market effect works quite ifferently for the number of omestic firms (specialization) an the number of eporters (trae). 3 Acemoglu et al. (2007) introuce firm heterogeneity in the egree of complementarity among inputs, but all proucts are assume to be freely trae an hence all firms eport in their moel. 4 Wage ifferentials are one of the most prominent factors that have triggere large trae flows among issimilar countries in the past two ecaes. For instance, noting that in 2006 for the first time the Unite States i more trae in manufacture goos with eveloping countries than evelope countries, Krugman (2008) asserts that this is largely ue to the wage ifference between the U.S. an eveloping countries: China s an Meico s wages are respectively only 4 percent an 13 percent of the U.S. level. 3

5 2 Setup Consier a worl composing of two large countries, orth an South, i {, S}. For notational simplicity, country superscript i is roppe unless neee in this section. Deman There is a unit measure of ientical consumers in each country. The preferences of a representative consumer are Cobb-Douglas across sectors an Diit-Stiglitz within sectors: where 1 0 U = 1 0 λ z ln X z z, [ ] 1/α λ z z = 1, X z = z (v) α v. v V z λ z enotes the share of epeniture spent on sector z (0, 1). The representative consumer in each country evotes its income uniformly across sectors (i.e., λ i z = λ). X z enotes aggregate consumption in sector z, where z (v) is consumption of variety v from sector z an V z is the mass of available goos, which is enogenously etermine in equilibrium. It is important to note that there is no homogeneous-goo sector with nontrae costs, an thus wage rates cannot be normalize between orth an South. 5 This structure of the preferences is similar to that of Krugman (1980), an more recently to that of Antràs (2005) an Okubo (2009). otice also that, while the elasticity of substitution between any two varieties within a sector ɛ = 1/(1 α) is assume to be greater than one, the elasticity of substitution between any varieties across sectors is unity. The unit elasticity of substitution implies that firm behavior in each sector can be analyze inepenently. where As is well-known, the above preferences generate eman functions in sector z, = Ap 1/(1 α), λe A = n 0 p(v)1 ɛ v. E is total spening in the economy, n is the number (measure) of varieties available in a country, an p(v) is the consumer price of variety v. From the ieal price ine P = [ p(v) 1 ɛ v ] 1/(1 ɛ), this can be written as A = λep ɛ 1. Prouction There is a continuum of firms, each proucing a ifferent variety. Labor is only a factor of prouction an each supplier faces a perfectly elastic supply of labor at each country size L. Let w enote the wage rate. Since labor is completely mobile across sectors but immobile 5 By ecluing a homogeneous-goo sector, I can eplicitly investigate the role of the relative wage or factoral terms of trae (Matsuyama, 2008) in comparative avantage, which is an orthoo practice in Ricarian moels. While introucing a homogeneous prouct à la Helpman an Krugman (1985) woul help to simplify the analysis, empirical evience suggests that the bulk of recent trae flows cannot be capture without a terms-of-trae effect between evelope an eveloping countries as emphasize in Introuction. 4

6 across countries as in conventional Ricarian moels, w is same across sectors within a country but is ifferent across countries. 6 Following Krugman (1980) an Melitz (2003), firm technology is summarize in a linear cost function of output : f + l = f + θ(ϕ,z,µ) = f + τ θ(ϕ,z,µ) = f + ϕµ(z) τ ϕµ(z) if omestic prouction, if eporting, where θ(,, ) is labor prouctivity, f is a fie cost for omestic prouction, f is a fie cost for eporting, an τ( 1) is a iceberg transport cost. These costs are ientical across countries an sectors. A few points are in orer for this specification. First, labor prouctivity θ(,, ) epens on three factors: (i) firm-specific ϕ; (ii) sector-specific z; an (iii) country-specific µ. In Melitz (2003), he consiers symmetric countries, implying that a country-specific factor µ is ignorable. He also focuses on one sector within each country, leaing a sector-specific factor z to be absent from his analysis. Therefore, only a firm-specific factor ϕ is important in Melitz s moel. In the current moel, by contrast, since two countries are asymmetric an there is a continuum of sectors, the three factors jointly affect labor prouctivity. It follows from this cost function that the country-specific factor µ( ) (0, 1) affects firms variable costs only (leaving fie costs ientical) an labor prouctivity is greater if µ( ) is closer to one. I assume that µ( ) is relate to a country s ability to enforce written contracts between firms an suppliers (as will be shown in the net subsection) an is referre to as partial contractibility in this paper. Secon, I aopt a reuce form of labor prouctivity: θ(ϕ, z, µ) = ϕµ(z). While this form is use for simplicity, one can justify this simplification from Costinot s (2009a) log-supermoular argument. He efines Ricarian technological ifferences as labor prouctivity that satisfies θ(ϕ, z, µ) = f(ϕ)/a(z, µ), where a(, )(> 1) is the unit labor requirement (efine as the inverse of labor prouctivity), an shows that Ricarian sources of comparative avantage hol if 1/a(, ) is log-supermoular (i.e., 2 z µ ln 1 a(z,µ) 0 2 z µ ln a(z, µ) 0), or equivalently a(z 2, µ 1 ) a(z 2, µ 2 ) a(z1, µ 1 ) a(z 1, µ 2 ), for z 1 z 2, µ 1 µ 2, a(z 1, µ 2 ) 0 an a(z 2, µ 2 ) 0. My specification is restricte relative to Costinot s in that θ(ϕ, z, µ) = f(ϕ)/a(z, µ) = ϕµ(z). In aition to applying this reuce form, I further assume that orth has partial contractibility strictly superior to South for any sector. oting the inverse relationship between µ( ) an a(, ), log-supermoularity in terms of µ( ) is 6 I recognize that wage inequality eists across sectors as well as within sectors (Helpman, Itskhoki, Muenler, an Reing, 2012), an that this is particularly serious in the presence of incomplete contracting (Levchenko, 2007). My assumption on wage equality raws from Antràs (2005), who stuies incomplete contracts in a generalequilibrium Ricarian moel with a continuum of sectors. 5

7 i z 1 z S z 0 Customize Generic 1 z Figure 1. Log-supermoularity in contractibility given by 1 < µ (z) µ S (z) < µ (z ) µ S (z ) < +, for z > z, µ > µ S, µ S (z) 0, an µ S (z ) 0. This implies not only that µ(z) = 1/a(z, µ) satisfies log-supermoularity (or Ricaro s classic inequality), but also that orth has absolute avantage in partial contractibility in any sector. Figure 1 illustrates µ i (z) that satisfies the above inequalities with the aitional assumptions that µ (1) = µ S (1) = 1 an µ S (0) = 0. As epicte in the figure, log-supermoularity means in this framework that the gap between µ an µ S is graually larger as the sector s prouction is more customize. An economic interpretation of this figure is as follows. In a generic sector, the severe holup problem is less likely irrespective of institutional quality, because the prouction oes not rely heavily on relationship-specific investments. As a result, the gap between µ an µ S is relatively smaller an µ i is closer to one in a more generic sector. In a customize sector, on the contrary, proucers are more likely to suffer from the holup problem an prouction efficiency is relatively more sensitive to institutional quality. Although µ i is significantly less than one for both countries, superior contractibility gives orth relatively bigger cost avantage in a more customize sector. As formally establishe by Costinot (2009a), this relatively more property which lies at the core of neoclassical trae theory an is also the pivotal element in the empirical evience reporte by Levchenko (2007) an unn (2007) is elegantly capture by log-supermoularity. Finally, in this ecomposition θ(ϕ, z, µ) = ϕµ(z), I refer to countries partial contractibility µ(z) as institutions as in Levchenko (2007), whereas the istribution function G(ϕ) of firms prouctivity raw ϕ as technologies as in Melitz (2003). Furthermore, I restrict attention to environments in which all firms have access to the same technologies across countries an sectors, i.e., G i z(ϕ) = G(ϕ) for i {, S} an z (0, 1). 7 Consequently, there eists no technological 7 This means that, if the istribution of firm prouctivity is Pareto, G(ϕ) = 1 (b/ϕ) k, both the shape an scale parameters, k an b, are ientical across countries an sectors. While these parameters are more likely to vary with country an sector characteristics in evience (Tybout, 2000), the moeling of country-variant istributions 6

8 ifference across countries an institutional ifference solely gives rise to countries comparative avantage. In reality, technological an institutional ifferences coeist an these two effects are not precisely separable. This istinction is not crucial for the analysis below an the following efinition is mae for the sake of convenience. Definition 1. Technologies are the istribution function G(ϕ) of firms prouctivity raw ϕ, which is ientical across countries an sectors. Institutions are countries partial contractibility µ(z) on relationship-specific activities, which varies across countries an sectors. Each firm chooses to maimize π = p wl. Solving this profit-maimizing problem yiels the following first-orer conitions: p = w ϕαµ, ( ϕαµ ) ɛ = A, w ( µ ) ɛ 1 π = B ϕ ɛ 1 wf, w ( µ ) ɛ 1 π = B ϕ ɛ 1 wf, w where B = Aα ɛ 1 (1 α) = λe(αp ) ɛ 1 (1 α). For analytical simplicity, I assume that transport cost is zero (τ = 1) an thus p = p = p. Section 5 iscusses how the following results are moifie if τ > 1. It is also assume that f > f, which is require for the partitioning between eporters an noneporters an, uner this assumption, only a subset of firms eport even in the absence of transport costs. While these conitions are similar to those in stanar heterogeneous-firm moels of trae, there are two ifferent points. First, wage rates cannot be normalize between orth an South, since countries are asymmetric an there is no freely trae homogeneous-prouct sector in this moel. For instance, Melitz (2003) assumes symmetric countries, whereas Helpman, Melitz, an Yeaple (2004) introuce a homogeneous goo sector to equalize wage across countries. Secon, institutional quality µ enters into these conitions. It is immeiate to see that the pricing rule is higher an the output level is lower in a more customize sector ue to the holup problem. Bargaining So far, bargaining issues have not been eplicitly eplore. As originally propose by Grossman an Hart (1986), the holup problem in relationship-specific investments occurs because parties cannot write every unforeseeable contingency into an initial contract e ante, an they have to renegotiate the contract e post. In what follows, builing on the seminal works of Antràs (2003, 2005) an Antràs an Helpman (2004, 2008), I briefly show that institutional quality µ plays a qualitatively similar (but istinct) role with incomplete contracting. Suppose, while letting perfect institutions (µ = 1) prevail in any sector of both countries, prouction of final goos now requires intermeiate inputs which each firm cannot manufacture coul come at the cost of obscuring Ricarian sources of comparative avantage if G i z(ϕ) is log-supermoular in country an firm characteristics (Costinot, 2007, 2009a). 7

9 by itself. To prouce a variety, every firm asks a omestic input supplier to provie a specialize input. This input is relationship-specific in that it has a higher value within the parties an a thir party (such as courts) cannot istinguish its true value. Because no enforceable contract will be signe e ante in such a circumstance, the firm an its supplier have to bargain over the surplus after prouction takes place. Let β an 1 β enote respectively the firm s an its supplier s e-post bargaining power. Then, the firm s profit is π F = βp + T, an the supplier s profit is π S = (1 β)p wl T, where T is a transfer from the supplier to the firm. 8 This transfer works to make the supplier break-even an leas to π = π F + π S = p wl in a subgame-perfect ash equilibrium. The supplier chooses to maimize π S, so the optimal pricing rule is p = w ϕα(1 β). Comparison of the pricing rules reveals µ = 1 β in equilibrium. It can thus be interprete that the supplier s e-post bargaining power is lower in a more customize sector because a fraction of e-ante contractible activities is smaller in such a sector (c.f., Acemoglu et al., 2007). The previous literature on organizations an trae typically assumes that the egree of the holup problem in relationship-specific investments is the same across sectors, but varies across organizational forms (i.e., vertical integration an outsourcing). Instea, I allow this egree to vary across sectors, while abstracting from the firm bounaries. The moel is evelope below, keeping in min the similarity between imperfect institutions an incomplete contracting. Firm Behavior This paper analyzes a static version of Melitz s (2003) moel. To enter a sector in country i {, S}, firms bear a fie cost of entry f e, measure in country i s labor units. Upon paying this fie cost, firms raw their prouctivity level ϕ from a known istribution G i z(ϕ) = G(ϕ). After observing this prouctivity level, each firm ecies whether to eit or not. If the firm chooses to prouce, it bears aitional fie costs f for omestic prouction an f for eporting, as escribe before. An entering firm in country i woul then immeiately eit if π i < 0, or woul prouce an serve its omestic market if πi 0. Moreover, among omestic firms, only the most prouctive firms woul earn π i 0 an serve the foreign market in j as eporters because f > f. While this firm behavior is similar across countries an sectors, the prouctivity cutoffs for omestic prouction an eporting woul vary by reflecting countries comparative avantage. Regaring eporting participation, if π i 0 an π j 0 for some firms in i j {, S}, well-known two-way (intra-inustry) trae occurs in this sector: trae arises even in the same sector because proucts are ifferentiate an consumers are strictly better off by importing goos unavailable in the omestic market. If π i 0 for some firms an π j < 0 for any firm, on the contrary, one-way (inter-inustry) trae happens, whereby eporting from country i to country j takes place in this sector. 8 ote that: (i) ue to incomplete contracting, the bargaining occurs over the revenue rather than the profit; an (ii) only the supplier unertakes (one-sie) relationship-specific investments. While this bargaining setup is amittely simplistic, even if both parties engage in relationship-specific activities thereby creating the two-sie holup problem, the key results o not essentially change. See Antràs an Staiger (2011) for etails. 8

10 3 Partial Equilibrium In this section, I eplore a partial equilibrium in which some important variables are eogenously given. The net section embes this analysis in a general-equilibrium setting. To see a traing equilibrium, consier country j s market where competition occurs between omestic firms in j an eporters from i. From the first-orer conitions in the previous section, the profit functions of these firms are respectively given by ( π j µ j ) ɛ 1 = (z) Bj ϕ ɛ 1 w j f, w j π i = B j ( µ i (z) w i ) ɛ 1 ϕ ɛ 1 w i f. otice that, since they compete in j s market, aggregate eman B j is common for both of the profit functions. π j an πi are measure by ifferent wage rates an contractibility levels, however, because eporters from i have to use omestic labor an institutions to prouce own variety. If there eist multinational enterprises that irectly employ local labor an have internal contractibility within the firm bounaries, this argument is no longer true. See Section 5 for the possibility of foreign affiliate prouction in the current setup. To compare these profit functions graphically, they are rawn in (ϕ ɛ 1, π) space with slope B ( µ ) ɛ 1 w an intercept wf. Then, π i is steeper (flatter) than π j if an only if µ i (z) w i µj (z) µ(z) ω if i =, w j µ(z) ω if i = S, where µ(z) = µ (z)/µ S (z) = a(z, µ S )/a(z, µ ) an ω = w /w S respectively enote the relative contractibility (or relative labor requirement) an relative wage in orth. Following stanar Ricarian moels, I say that orth (South) has institutional comparative avantage in sector z if it has a large (small) relative labor prouctivity in contractibility µ(z), an/or a small (large) relative wage ω, i.e., µ(z) > ω (µ(z) < ω). Uner this efinition, country i s institutional comparative avantage is ientifie as the sector where the slope of eporters π i is steeper than that of omestic firms π j. Definition 2. orth (South) has institutional comparative avantage in sector z if µ(z) > ω (µ(z) < ω), or equivalently if the slope of π (π S ) is steeper than that of π S (π ). The left panel of Figure 2 epicts π an πs in orthern market uner the conitions that (i) µ(z) = ω an (ii) w S f > w f ω < f f. From the first conition, the two profit functions are parallel in this sector. From the secon conition, Southern eporters bear the higher fie costs (measure by the local labor wage) than orthern omestic firms. Following the same line of reasoning, the profit functions in Southern market, π S an π, are epicte in the right panel of the figure uner the conitions that (i) µ(z) = ω an (ii) w f > w S f ω > f f. 9

11 , S, S S S 0 S 1 0 S 1 w f w S f w S f w f orth South Figure 2. Profits from omestic sales an eports otice that, ue to wage ifferentials, omestic firms in j might bear the higher fie costs than foreign eporters from i in j s market. Because it is empirically well-known that f is huge in any manufacturing sector, 9 I hereafter assume that: Assumption 1. f f < ω < f f. Figure 2 shows that orthern (Southern) firms with prouctivity above ϕ ( ϕ S ) eport to South (orth) an hence two-way trae arises in sector of µ(z) = ω. While this figure epicts only a particular sector where the two profit functions are parallel, one can easily imagine from this partial-equilibrium framework that two-way trae woul happen in any sector z (0, 1) if the slopes of π an π S are positive, i.e., B ( µ w ) ɛ 1 > 0. As will be emonstrate in the net section, this observation survives even in a general-equilibrium setting, although the feeback among enogenous variables imposes some restrictions on eogenous variables. et, I erive the conition uner which the two profit functions are parallel, i.e., µ(z) = ω. From Figure 1, the ratio of contractibility µ(z) = µ (z)/µ S (z) has to satisfy µ(z) > 1, µ (z) < 0, µ (z) > 0, lim z 1 µ(z) = 1, an lim z 0 µ(z) = +, where the first conition stems from the absolute avantage assumption an the thir stems from µ i (z) s log-supermoular property. The relative wage in orth ω, on the other han, shoul be the same for all sectors z (0, 1), because labor is completely mobile across sectors in the Ricarian moel. This suggests that, if ω is greater than one, these two curves intersect at a unique threshol z = µ 1 (ω) such that: (i) 0 < z < z µ(z) > ω; (ii) z = z µ(z) = ω; an (iii) z < z < 1 µ(z) < ω. It is then immeiate from Definition 2 that orth (South) has institutional comparative avantage in relatively customize (generic) sectors. 9 Das, Roberts, an Tybout (2007) econometrically estimate the average costs of foreign market entry among three Colombian manufacturing sectors (leather proucts, knitte fabrics, an basic chemicals), an fin that these fie costs are (i) large enough to cause eport hysteresis an (ii) remarkably similar across these sectors: the average eport costs range from $412,000 (in U.S. ollars) for knitte fabrics to $430,000 for leather proucts. 10

12 While this outcome is reminiscent of Dornbusch, Fischer, an Samuelson s (1977) Ricarian moel with a continuum of goos, there are three notable istinctions between the current paper an theirs. First, since they analyze perfect competition with homogeneous proucts, complete specialization (or inter-inustry trae) occurs below/above the cutoff z. In contrast, this paper stuies monopolistic competition with ifferentiate proucts, an incomplete specialization (or intra-inustry trae) can arise in all manufacturing sectors. Seconly, the number an size of omestic firms an eporters are both ineterminate an irrelevant in their neoclassical moel, but it is enogenously etermine in the current framework in which the number of varieties eporte is only a subset of the number of varieties prouce in the home market. Finally, this paper s focus is on orth-south trae where the ifference in economic evelopment plays a founational role in countries comparative avantage. The result that a less evelope country nevertheless eports ifferentiate goos in the customize sectors seems to be consistent with recent trae flows (see, e.g., Krugman, 2008). Proposition 1. (i) Two-way trae can occur in any sector z (0, 1). (ii) If ω > 1, there eists a unique threshol z (0, 1) such that orth (South) has institutional comparative avantage in z (0, z) (z ( z, 1)). It is important to emphasize that this partial-equilibrium analysis cannot clarify the interplay among key variables of the moel. To see this, it is useful to go back to Figure 2. This figure epicts ϕ j < ϕi in this sector, inicating that foreign eporters from i are more prouctive than omestic firms in j. This is not wholly surprising because foreign eporters are assume to incur the higher fie costs uner Assumption 1, an this can be easily formalize by using a partial-equilibrium moel. However, ϕ i an ϕj or ϕi an ϕ j are not comparable. Obviously, ϕ an ϕs ( ϕ an ϕ S ) are etermine at which π = 0 an πs = 0 (π = 0 an π S = 0), but these variables epen on the market eman B i as well as the wage rate w i, both of which are eogenous in partial equilibrium. Also, Proposition 1(ii) requires that ω shoul be greater than one if orth-south trae is to occur, but it is not clear whether this hols or not. In this sense, the above partial-equilibrium setting is restricte, an a general-equilibrium approach is necessary to enogenize these variables. 4 General Equilibrium In this section, the partial-equilibrium moel is embee into a general-equilibrium framework to eamine the interaction among key variables an to see an enogenous pattern of trae. General-Equilibrium Setup This subsection outlines several conitions that play a central role in enogenizing variables in general equilibrium. In the subsequent subsections, I solve this full general-equilibrium moel with some restrictions. 11

13 First of all, a zero profit conition must be satisfie for the cutoff firm in equilibrium, which is achieve by setting ϕ i = inf{ϕ : πi (ϕ) > 0} an ϕi = inf{ϕ : π i (ϕ) > 0} in this static moel. Following Melitz (2003), I refer to this conition as a zero cutoff profit (ZCP) conition: ( ) µ π i i ɛ 1 ( ϕi ) = 0 Bi w i ( ϕ i )ɛ 1 = w i f, (ZCP i) ( ) µ π( i ϕ i ) = 0 B j i ɛ 1 ( ϕ i ) ɛ 1 = w i f, (ZCP) i for i j {, S}. In this conition, aggregate eman of eporters B j is ifferent from that of omestic firms B i since eporters from i compete in the foreign market in j. w i Seconly, a free entry (FE) conition must hol. Since potential entrants are e ante ientical in the moel, this conition is efine as ϕ i π i (ϕ)g(ϕ) + π(ϕ)g(ϕ) i = w i f e, (F E i ) ϕ i where the first an secon terms in the left-han sie respectively enote the epecte operating profits from omestic prouction an eporting earne by potential entrants. The sum of these epecte profits shoul be equal to the fie entry cost w i f e in equilibrium. Finally, a labor market clearing (LMC) conition must be taken into account: 1 0 ϕ i l i (z, ϕ)g(ϕ)z ϕ i l i (z, ϕ)g(ϕ)z = L i. 10 (LMC i ) The first an secon terms in the left-han sie respectively represent the sum of epecte labor emans use for omestic prouction an eporting by potential entrants, where l i (z, ϕ) an l(z, i ϕ) are etermine by the first-orer conitions of profit maimization in Section 2. ote that l i (z, ϕ) is summe up over the whole sectors in the economy because two-way trae can occur in any sector z (0, 1) as seen in Proposition 1. The sum of these epecte labor emans has to be equal to the fie labor supply L i in equilibrium. ow, it is possible to enogenize the important variables in general equilibrium. Since there are the eight equations (the ZCP, FE, an LMC conitions that must hol in orth an South), these conitions provie implicit solutions for the following eight unknowns: ϕ, ϕs, ϕ, ϕ S, B, B S, w, w S, where either LMC conition can be omitte by Walras law, thereby normalizing w i = 1 as a numéraire To be more precise, this is the LMC conition for prouction an the LMC conition for investment in f e shoul be inclue in this conition. As shown in Supplementary ote, the following result oes not change even if the LMC conition for investment is taken into account. 11 As shown by Krugman (1980), another way to enogenize ω = w /w S in general equilibrium is to look at the balance-of-payments (BOP) conition, an the LMC an BOP conitions are equivalent for this etermination. Okubo (2009) uses the BOP conition in the asymmetric-country version of Melitz (2003). 12

14 Relative ZCP an FE Conitions This subsection sets forth the characterization of the eight unknowns from the eight conitions. It is challenging, however, to solve the full general equilibrium moel with asymmetric countries. In particular, without specifying the functional form of the firm size istribution G(ϕ), eplicit solutions of these unknowns cannot be obtaine. In the following, instea of obtaining the eact values of each of them, the main focus is evote to the characterization of the relative terms of these unknowns. Recall from Proposition 1 that orth-south trae arises only if the relative wage in orth is greater than one. Although this ratio is enogenously etermine in equilibrium, for epositional purposes, suppose first ω > 1 hols in the moel. In other wors, the LMC conitions are left out as if the moel were partial-equilibrium. As will be clear, this inequality must be true in general equilibrium, because I assume that orth has absolute avantage in partial contractibility µ. This means that the marginal prouct of labor is higher (on average across heterogeneous firms) in orth, an thus wages have to be greater in orth than South if trae is to occur between the countries. This intuition will be confirme later by integrating the LMC conitions. Uner the circumstance, the relative ZCP conitions are efine by iviing orthern ZCP conition by Southern ZCP conition: ( ω ) 1/(ɛ 1) ω ϕ = B µ, (RZCP ) ϕ = (Bω) 1/(ɛ 1) ω µ, (RZCP ) where all variables are represente by the relative terms in orth (e.g., ϕ = ϕ / ϕs ). It is easy to show that ϕ ϕ B 1. Similarly, iviing orthern FE conition by Southern FE conition yiels the relative FE conition: B = B(µ, ϕ). (RF E) In the above RFE conition, ϕ { ϕ, ϕs, ϕ, ϕ S } must satisfy the ZCP conitions an hence B is enogenously etermine (for given ω). Furthermore, B in the RFE conition shoul be inepenent of ϕ an ϕ as long as the ZCP conitions hol (see Appeni for proof): B ϕ = B ϕ = 0. Shifts in ϕ have only a secon-orer effect on B in the RFE conition for any istribution G(ϕ), since the prouctivity threshols are etermine to satisfy the ZCP conitions in equilibrium. A first-orer effect comes solely from eogenous µ in this setting (see also Appeni): B z = B µ µ z + B ϕ ϕ z + B ϕ ϕ z > In the full general equilibrium moel, there shoul be B ω in the right-han sie of this equation. Since ω z the relative wage in orth is the same across sectors, this has no effect on this relationship. 13

15 B B B, 1, z 1 z Figure 3. Comparative avantage an prouctivity cutoffs The intuition for B (z) > 0 is eplaine by recalling that B is proportional to the price ine ratio P = P /P S. 13 If z is close to one, the institutional ifferential is almost negligible but there eists the wage ifferential (i.e., ω > 1). Thus, South can prouce goos relatively cheaply, leaing to P > P S an B > 1 in the neighborhoo of z = 1. If z is close to zero, the ifferential in µ is sufficiently large to ominate the ifferential in ω (ue to log-supermoularity), resulting in P < P S an B < 1 aroun z = 0. ote from Figure 2 that ϕ = ϕ / ϕs an ϕ = ϕ / ϕ S are equal if an only if π i an πj are parallel at z = z an therefore ϕ ( z) = ϕ ( z) B( z) = 1. Roughly speaking, this mirrors the iea that a country has comparative avantage in the sectors where the aggregate price is relatively lower. Figure 3 illustrates the relationships among the key variables. The first quarant epicts the relationship between z an B. As shown above, B satisfies the ZCP conitions with B (z) > 0 an B( z) = The secon quarant epicts the relationship between B, ϕ, an ϕ from the RZCP conitions. In this figure, once B is enogenously etermine in the first quarant, the horizontal line of the RFE conition is rawn in the secon quarant since B is inepenent of ϕ an ϕ (although it is not epicte in the figure). From the intersections among these three curves, it follows that 0 < z < z B < 1 ϕ > ω 1/(ɛ 1) > ϕ, z = z B = 1 ϕ = ω 1/(ɛ 1) = ϕ, z < z < 1 B > 1 ϕ < ω 1/(ɛ 1) < ϕ, where either ϕ or ϕ is greater than one uner the conition ω > 1. For instance, comparative avantage sectors of orth z (0, z) must satisfy ϕ > ω 1/(ɛ 1) > 1 but whether ϕ 1 is ineterminate in this setup. Base upon this observation, Figure 4 illustrates the relationship among ϕ in comparative avantage sectors of orth (left panel) an South (right panel). While the figure epicts the case of ϕ > 1 an ϕ > 1, this might not hol in the sectors where z is close to zero an 13 From B i = λe i (αp i ) ɛ 1 (1 α), the relative aggregate eman is B = ωlp ɛ 1 = B(µ, ), which implies that etermining B = B /B S are ientical with etermining P = P /P S in equilibrium. 14 The figure epicts lim z 0 B(z) = 0 an lim z 1 B(z) =, but these are not necessarily true in the moel. 14

16 0 s 0, 0 S S S 0 S S S 0 zz z z1 Figure 4. Relationships among ϕ across sectors one. Regarless of whether or not they are greater than one, the gap ϕ i ϕ i is narrower than the gap ϕ j ϕ j in country i s comparative avantage sectors. In aition, this former (latter) gap becomes smaller (bigger) as countries comparative avantage is stronger. More formally, it follows from the ZCP conitions that ϕ ϕ = ( B f ) 1/(ɛ 1), f ϕ S ϕ S = ( ) 1 f 1/(ɛ 1). B f Since B (z) > 0, ϕ / ϕ ( ϕs / ϕ S ) is strictly increasing (ecreasing) in z. This means that, as country i s comparative avantage is stronger, 15 not only are omestic firms more prouctive, but also the prouctivity cutoff for eporting ϕ i is closer to that for omestic prouction ϕ i an relatively less prouctive firms are able to enter the foreign market. Consequently, the ratio of eporting firms to overall surviving firms graually becomes higher in the stronger comparative avantage sectors. The above equations also inicate that the prouctivity cutoff for eporting is bigger than that of omestic prouction ( ϕ i > ϕ i ) in the comparative isavantage sectors for i {, S}.16 In the comparative avantage sectors, the usual outcome ( ϕ i > ϕ i ) occurs in both countries if whereas the perverse outcome ( ϕ i > ϕi ) arises if f f < B < f f, (1) B < f f if i =, f f < B if i = S. ϕ i > ϕi implies that, among surviving firms in i, less prouctive firms serve the foreign market in j only, while more prouctive firms serve the foreign market in j an the home market in i. Clearly, this arises in a sector where countries comparative avantage measure by B is strong enough relative to the fie-cost ratio between f an f. 15 oting that µ(z) = a(z, µ S )/a(z, µ ) is the relative unit labor requirement satisfying µ (z) < 0, comparative avantage of orth (South) is sai to be stronger if z is closer to zero (one) in this moel. 16 From f > f, comparative isavantage sectors of orth, for eample, must satisfy z < z < 1 B > 1 = ϕ > ϕ. (ote also that Assumption 1 has an influence on the relationship between ϕ i an ϕ j for i j {, S}.) 15

17 Proposition 2. (i) Relative to ϕ j ϕ j, the gap ϕi ϕ i is narrow in country i s comparative avantage sectors an this gap is monotonically ecreasing in countries comparative avantage strength. (ii) While ϕ i > ϕ i always hols in country i s comparative isavantage sectors, ϕi > ϕi is possible in etremely strong comparative avantage sectors. These two finings fit well with recent empirical research. The first fining among omestic firms, more firms eport in stronger comparative avantage sectors is consistent with evience in Introuction. The logic of this result comes from the interplay between Ricarian institutional ifference an relative buren of fie eport costs: log-supermoularity in country an sector characteristics allows relatively less prouctive firms to incur fie eport costs relatively easily in comparative avantage sectors. Strictly speaking, however, this is not satisfactory because the percentage of firms that eport cannot be aresse without the number of varieties prouce an eporte. Later I investigate what etermines this number in equilibrium. The secon fining is also in keeping with Lu s (2011) empirical evience that manufacturing eporters in China are typically less prouctive than omestic firms in labor-intensive sectors, but eporters are more prouctive in capital-intensive sectors. To rationalize this evience, Lu evelops a Heckscher-Ohlin moel with heterogeneous firms, emphasizing that allowing factor intensity to vary across sectors is crucial for the Melitz moel of orth-south trae. Although my theoretical focus is apparently ifferent from hers, the central message is surprisingly similar: eporters can be less prouctive than omestic firms in comparative avantage sectors, whereas eporters are always more prouctive in comparative isavantage sectors. The rationale for this outcome is as follows. In comparative isavantage sectors of i, a foreign market in j is more competitive than a omestic market in i since foreign firms are relatively better at proucing. Thus, eporters from i must be sufficiently prouctive, not only because they have to cover the fie eport cost, but also because they have to compete with more efficient foreign rivals in the eport market. In comparative avantage sectors of i, on the other han, foreign competitors are relatively less efficient an hence relatively less prouctive firms in i coul fin it profitable to enter the foreign market. This is the reason why the partitioning of firms by eport status might not be inuce only with f > f in comparative avantage sectors. If ϕ i > ϕi were true, however, all surviving firms in i coul eport, which is not supporte by evience. 17 This result shoul be interprete as meaning that aggregate prouctivity premia of eporters relative to omestic firms are smaller in a stronger comparative avantage sector. I eclue ϕ i > ϕi by assuming that f is large enough to satisfy (1) in any sector. Full General Equilibrium The previous subsection provies implicit solutions of B an ϕ for given ω (an z). This subsection eplores full general-equilibrium interactions by eplicitly incorporating the LMC conitions. I show that the relative wage in orth is greater than one, a sufficient conition of orth-south trae require in Proposition In Lu s (2011) ataset, ϕ i > ϕ i occurs because it inclues Chinese eporters involve in processing trae. If firms engage in final-goo trae only as in the current moel, this possibility woul not eist. 16

18 Recall that, while the ZCP an FE conitions must hol for each sector, the LMC conition must hol for all sectors. To obtain the corresponing LMC conition for each sector, I use the assumption that consumers epeniture is equally istribute across sectors in both countries, i.e., λ i z = λ. Uner this assumption, the previous LMC conition can be written as ϕ i l i (ϕ)g(ϕ) + l(ϕ)g(ϕ) i = λl i, ϕ i where 1 0 λli z = L i. otice that the result of Proposition 1(i) (i.e., two-way trae can occur in any sector) greatly simplifies the analysis. From the first-orer conitions in Section 2, labor emans for omestic prouction an eporting by an iniviual firm with prouctivity ϕ are respectively given by l i (ɛ 1)Bi ( (ϕ) = ϕµ i ) ɛ 1 + f (w i ) ɛ, l(ϕ) i (ɛ 1)Bi ( = ϕµ i ) ɛ 1 + f (w i ) ɛ. Substituting these values into the above LMC conition an iviing orthern LMC conition by Southern LMC conition, the relative LMC conition is efine as below (see Appeni for etails): ( Bµ ɛ 1 ) 1/ɛ Ψ ξ =, (RLMC) Γ where both Ψ an Γ are a function of prouctivity cutoffs ϕ, an Γ is also a function of labor supply L i. It is verifie that ξ is an increasing function of z satisfying lim z 1 ξ(z) > 1 (for B an ϕ seen in the last subsection). Intuitively, these properties follow from the fact that orth has stronger comparative avantage in the sectors where the relative wage (summarize in ξ) is relatively lower. Figure 5 epicts ξ curve in (z, ω) space. The other conition that pins own z an ω is the relative partial contactibility in orth µ = µ /µ S in Section 3. Among µ s properties, µ > 1 (orthern absolute avantage) an µ > 0 (log-supermoularity) are of particular importance. It is clear from the figure that ω is always greater than one. ξ an µ curves shoul intersect at ( z, ω) because ω = ω(b(z), ϕ (z), ϕ (z)) is epresse in terms of ω at z = z, i.e., B( z) = 1 an ϕ ( z) = ϕ ( z) = ω 1/(ɛ 1), implying also that ω is enogenous. This ω in turn leas to enogenous solutions of B, ϕ, an ϕ, which completes the characterization of the eight unknowns in equilibrium. Proposition 3. The relative wage in orth is greater than one in general equilibrium, i.e., ω > 1. It is worthwhile to stress that the above channel is akin to that evelope by Antràs (2005), who shows (with homogeneous firms) that, irrespective of the relative country size L = L /L S, better contracting environments in orth lea to the higher relative wage in general equilibrium. As in his moel, the equilibrium outcome ω > 1 irectly reflects that orth has superior partial contractibility which helps mitigate the serious holup problem. This in turn gives rise to better prouction efficiency an overall higher prouctivity (i.e., wage) in orth. 17

Institutions as a Ricardian Source of Comparative Advantage

Institutions as a Ricardian Source of Comparative Advantage Institutions as a Ricarian Source of Comparative Avantage Tomohiro Ara Fukushima University June 2013 Abstract Why oes the fraction of firms that export vary with countries comparative avantage? To aress

More information

Comparative Advantage, Monopolistic Competition, and Heterogeneous Firms in a Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Sectors

Comparative Advantage, Monopolistic Competition, and Heterogeneous Firms in a Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Sectors Comparative Avantage, Monopolistic Competition, an Heterogeneous Firms in a Ricarian Moel with a Continuum of Sectors Tomohiro Ara Fukushima University July 25 Abstract Why oes the fraction of firms that

More information

Web Appendix to Firm Heterogeneity and Aggregate Welfare (Not for Publication)

Web Appendix to Firm Heterogeneity and Aggregate Welfare (Not for Publication) Web ppeni to Firm Heterogeneity an ggregate Welfare Not for Publication Marc J. Melitz Harvar University, NBER, an CEPR Stephen J. Reing Princeton University, NBER, an CEPR March 6, 203 Introuction his

More information

Web-Based Technical Appendix: Multi-Product Firms and Trade Liberalization

Web-Based Technical Appendix: Multi-Product Firms and Trade Liberalization Web-Base Technical Appeni: Multi-Prouct Firms an Trae Liberalization Anrew B. Bernar Tuck School of Business at Dartmouth & NBER Stephen J. Reing LSE, Yale School of Management & CEPR Peter K. Schott Yale

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FIRM HETEROGENEITY AND AGGREGATE WELFARE. Marc J. Melitz Stephen J. Redding

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FIRM HETEROGENEITY AND AGGREGATE WELFARE. Marc J. Melitz Stephen J. Redding NBER WORKING PPER SERIES FIRM HEEROGENEIY ND GGREGE WELFRE Marc J. Melitz Stephen J. Reing Working Paper 899 http://www.nber.org/papers/w899 NIONL BUREU OF ECONOMIC RESERCH 050 Massachusetts venue Cambrige,

More information

Online Appendix for Trade Policy under Monopolistic Competition with Firm Selection

Online Appendix for Trade Policy under Monopolistic Competition with Firm Selection Online Appenix for Trae Policy uner Monopolistic Competition with Firm Selection Kyle Bagwell Stanfor University an NBER Seung Hoon Lee Georgia Institute of Technology September 6, 2018 In this Online

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FACTOR PRICES AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE: A UNIFYING PERSPECTIVE. Ariel Burstein Jonathan Vogel

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FACTOR PRICES AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE: A UNIFYING PERSPECTIVE. Ariel Burstein Jonathan Vogel NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FACTOR PRICES AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE: A UNIFYING PERSPECTIVE Ariel Burstein Jonathan Vogel Working Paper 6904 http://www.nber.org/papers/w6904 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH

More information

Lecture 6: Calculus. In Song Kim. September 7, 2011

Lecture 6: Calculus. In Song Kim. September 7, 2011 Lecture 6: Calculus In Song Kim September 7, 20 Introuction to Differential Calculus In our previous lecture we came up with several ways to analyze functions. We saw previously that the slope of a linear

More information

II. First variation of functionals

II. First variation of functionals II. First variation of functionals The erivative of a function being zero is a necessary conition for the etremum of that function in orinary calculus. Let us now tackle the question of the equivalent

More information

Quality competition versus price competition goods: An empirical classification

Quality competition versus price competition goods: An empirical classification HEID Working Paper No7/2008 Quality competition versus price competition goos: An empirical classification Richar E. Balwin an Taashi Ito Grauate Institute of International an Development Stuies Abstract

More information

Math 1271 Solutions for Fall 2005 Final Exam

Math 1271 Solutions for Fall 2005 Final Exam Math 7 Solutions for Fall 5 Final Eam ) Since the equation + y = e y cannot be rearrange algebraically in orer to write y as an eplicit function of, we must instea ifferentiate this relation implicitly

More information

MATH 205 Practice Final Exam Name:

MATH 205 Practice Final Exam Name: MATH 205 Practice Final Eam Name:. (2 points) Consier the function g() = e. (a) (5 points) Ientify the zeroes, vertical asymptotes, an long-term behavior on both sies of this function. Clearly label which

More information

lim Prime notation can either be directly applied to a function as previously seen with f x 4.1 Basic Techniques for Finding Derivatives

lim Prime notation can either be directly applied to a function as previously seen with f x 4.1 Basic Techniques for Finding Derivatives MATH 040 Notes: Unit Page 4. Basic Techniques for Fining Derivatives In the previous unit we introuce the mathematical concept of the erivative: f f ( h) f ( ) lim h0 h (assuming the limit eists) In this

More information

3.7 Implicit Differentiation -- A Brief Introduction -- Student Notes

3.7 Implicit Differentiation -- A Brief Introduction -- Student Notes Fin these erivatives of these functions: y.7 Implicit Differentiation -- A Brief Introuction -- Stuent Notes tan y sin tan = sin y e = e = Write the inverses of these functions: y tan y sin How woul we

More information

Survey Sampling. 1 Design-based Inference. Kosuke Imai Department of Politics, Princeton University. February 19, 2013

Survey Sampling. 1 Design-based Inference. Kosuke Imai Department of Politics, Princeton University. February 19, 2013 Survey Sampling Kosuke Imai Department of Politics, Princeton University February 19, 2013 Survey sampling is one of the most commonly use ata collection methos for social scientists. We begin by escribing

More information

Lectures - Week 10 Introduction to Ordinary Differential Equations (ODES) First Order Linear ODEs

Lectures - Week 10 Introduction to Ordinary Differential Equations (ODES) First Order Linear ODEs Lectures - Week 10 Introuction to Orinary Differential Equations (ODES) First Orer Linear ODEs When stuying ODEs we are consiering functions of one inepenent variable, e.g., f(x), where x is the inepenent

More information

Monopoly Part III: Multiple Local Equilibria and Adaptive Search

Monopoly Part III: Multiple Local Equilibria and Adaptive Search FH-Kiel University of Applie Sciences Prof Dr Anreas Thiemer, 00 e-mail: anreasthiemer@fh-kiele Monopoly Part III: Multiple Local Equilibria an Aaptive Search Summary: The information about market eman

More information

New Technology, Human Capital and Growth for Developing Countries.

New Technology, Human Capital and Growth for Developing Countries. New Technology, Human Capital an Growth for Developing Countries Cuong Le Van, Manh-Hung Nguyen an Thai Bao Luong Centre Economie e la Sorbonne, Université Paris-1, Pantheon-Sorbonne 106-112 B e l Hôpital,

More information

Integration Review. May 11, 2013

Integration Review. May 11, 2013 Integration Review May 11, 2013 Goals: Review the funamental theorem of calculus. Review u-substitution. Review integration by parts. Do lots of integration eamples. 1 Funamental Theorem of Calculus In

More information

inflow outflow Part I. Regular tasks for MAE598/494 Task 1

inflow outflow Part I. Regular tasks for MAE598/494 Task 1 MAE 494/598, Fall 2016 Project #1 (Regular tasks = 20 points) Har copy of report is ue at the start of class on the ue ate. The rules on collaboration will be release separately. Please always follow the

More information

Equilibrium in Queues Under Unknown Service Times and Service Value

Equilibrium in Queues Under Unknown Service Times and Service Value University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Finance Papers Wharton Faculty Research 1-2014 Equilibrium in Queues Uner Unknown Service Times an Service Value Laurens Debo Senthil K. Veeraraghavan University

More information

Separation of Variables

Separation of Variables Physics 342 Lecture 1 Separation of Variables Lecture 1 Physics 342 Quantum Mechanics I Monay, January 25th, 2010 There are three basic mathematical tools we nee, an then we can begin working on the physical

More information

Chapter 1 Overview: Review of Derivatives

Chapter 1 Overview: Review of Derivatives Chapter Overview: Review of Derivatives The purpose of this chapter is to review the how of ifferentiation. We will review all the erivative rules learne last year in PreCalculus. In the net several chapters,

More information

Unexplained Gaps and Oaxaca-Blinder Decompositions

Unexplained Gaps and Oaxaca-Blinder Decompositions DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 4159 Uneplaine Gaps an Oaaca-Bliner Decompositions To E. Eler John H. Goeeris Steven J. Haier April 009 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft er Arbeit Institute for the Stuy

More information

SYNCHRONOUS SEQUENTIAL CIRCUITS

SYNCHRONOUS SEQUENTIAL CIRCUITS CHAPTER SYNCHRONOUS SEUENTIAL CIRCUITS Registers an counters, two very common synchronous sequential circuits, are introuce in this chapter. Register is a igital circuit for storing information. Contents

More information

The total derivative. Chapter Lagrangian and Eulerian approaches

The total derivative. Chapter Lagrangian and Eulerian approaches Chapter 5 The total erivative 51 Lagrangian an Eulerian approaches The representation of a flui through scalar or vector fiels means that each physical quantity uner consieration is escribe as a function

More information

UNDERSTANDING INTEGRATION

UNDERSTANDING INTEGRATION UNDERSTANDING INTEGRATION Dear Reaer The concept of Integration, mathematically speaking, is the "Inverse" of the concept of result, the integration of, woul give us back the function f(). This, in a way,

More information

The Principle of Least Action

The Principle of Least Action Chapter 7. The Principle of Least Action 7.1 Force Methos vs. Energy Methos We have so far stuie two istinct ways of analyzing physics problems: force methos, basically consisting of the application of

More information

Calculus of Variations

Calculus of Variations Calculus of Variations Lagrangian formalism is the main tool of theoretical classical mechanics. Calculus of Variations is a part of Mathematics which Lagrangian formalism is base on. In this section,

More information

d dx But have you ever seen a derivation of these results? We ll prove the first result below. cos h 1

d dx But have you ever seen a derivation of these results? We ll prove the first result below. cos h 1 Lecture 5 Some ifferentiation rules Trigonometric functions (Relevant section from Stewart, Seventh Eition: Section 3.3) You all know that sin = cos cos = sin. () But have you ever seen a erivation of

More information

Introduction to the Vlasov-Poisson system

Introduction to the Vlasov-Poisson system Introuction to the Vlasov-Poisson system Simone Calogero 1 The Vlasov equation Consier a particle with mass m > 0. Let x(t) R 3 enote the position of the particle at time t R an v(t) = ẋ(t) = x(t)/t its

More information

Internationa1 l Trade

Internationa1 l Trade 14.581 Internationa1 l Trade Class notes on /19/013 1 Overview Assignment Models in the Trade Literature Small but rapidly growing literature using assignment models in an international context: Trade:

More information

Trade, Neoclassical Growth and Heterogeneous Firms

Trade, Neoclassical Growth and Heterogeneous Firms Trade, Neoclassical Growth and eterogeneous Firms Julian Emami Namini Department of Economics, University of Duisburg Essen, Campus Essen, Germany Email: emami@vwl.uni essen.de 10th March 2006 Abstract

More information

Make graph of g by adding c to the y-values. on the graph of f by c. multiplying the y-values. even-degree polynomial. graph goes up on both sides

Make graph of g by adding c to the y-values. on the graph of f by c. multiplying the y-values. even-degree polynomial. graph goes up on both sides Reference 1: Transformations of Graphs an En Behavior of Polynomial Graphs Transformations of graphs aitive constant constant on the outsie g(x) = + c Make graph of g by aing c to the y-values on the graph

More information

The Impact of Integration on Productivity and Welfare Distortions Under Monopolistic Competition

The Impact of Integration on Productivity and Welfare Distortions Under Monopolistic Competition The Impact of Integration on Prouctivity an Welfare Distortions Uner Monopolistic Competition Swati Dhingra CEP, LSE an Princeton University John Morrow Centre for Economic Performance, LSE This Draft:

More information

Efficiency in a Search and Matching Model with Endogenous Participation

Efficiency in a Search and Matching Model with Endogenous Participation Efficienc in a Search an Matching Moel with Enogenous Participation James Albrecht a Department of Economics, Georgetown Universit an IZA Lucas Navarro Department of Economics, ILADES-Universia Alberto

More information

Computing Exact Confidence Coefficients of Simultaneous Confidence Intervals for Multinomial Proportions and their Functions

Computing Exact Confidence Coefficients of Simultaneous Confidence Intervals for Multinomial Proportions and their Functions Working Paper 2013:5 Department of Statistics Computing Exact Confience Coefficients of Simultaneous Confience Intervals for Multinomial Proportions an their Functions Shaobo Jin Working Paper 2013:5

More information

3.2 Differentiability

3.2 Differentiability Section 3 Differentiability 09 3 Differentiability What you will learn about How f (a) Might Fail to Eist Differentiability Implies Local Linearity Numerical Derivatives on a Calculator Differentiability

More information

Calculus in the AP Physics C Course The Derivative

Calculus in the AP Physics C Course The Derivative Limits an Derivatives Calculus in the AP Physics C Course The Derivative In physics, the ieas of the rate change of a quantity (along with the slope of a tangent line) an the area uner a curve are essential.

More information

Math Notes on differentials, the Chain Rule, gradients, directional derivative, and normal vectors

Math Notes on differentials, the Chain Rule, gradients, directional derivative, and normal vectors Math 18.02 Notes on ifferentials, the Chain Rule, graients, irectional erivative, an normal vectors Tangent plane an linear approximation We efine the partial erivatives of f( xy, ) as follows: f f( x+

More information

Section 2.1 The Derivative and the Tangent Line Problem

Section 2.1 The Derivative and the Tangent Line Problem Chapter 2 Differentiation Course Number Section 2.1 The Derivative an the Tangent Line Problem Objective: In this lesson you learne how to fin the erivative of a function using the limit efinition an unerstan

More information

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms Andrew Bernard, Tuck and NBER Stephen e Redding, LSE and CEPR Peter Schott, Yale and NBER 1 Introduction How do economies respond when opening to trade? Classical

More information

Unit #6 - Families of Functions, Taylor Polynomials, l Hopital s Rule

Unit #6 - Families of Functions, Taylor Polynomials, l Hopital s Rule Unit # - Families of Functions, Taylor Polynomials, l Hopital s Rule Some problems an solutions selecte or aapte from Hughes-Hallett Calculus. Critical Points. Consier the function f) = 54 +. b) a) Fin

More information

Linear First-Order Equations

Linear First-Order Equations 5 Linear First-Orer Equations Linear first-orer ifferential equations make up another important class of ifferential equations that commonly arise in applications an are relatively easy to solve (in theory)

More information

Time-of-Arrival Estimation in Non-Line-Of-Sight Environments

Time-of-Arrival Estimation in Non-Line-Of-Sight Environments 2 Conference on Information Sciences an Systems, The Johns Hopkins University, March 2, 2 Time-of-Arrival Estimation in Non-Line-Of-Sight Environments Sinan Gezici, Hisashi Kobayashi an H. Vincent Poor

More information

A. Incorrect! The letter t does not appear in the expression of the given integral

A. Incorrect! The letter t does not appear in the expression of the given integral AP Physics C - Problem Drill 1: The Funamental Theorem of Calculus Question No. 1 of 1 Instruction: (1) Rea the problem statement an answer choices carefully () Work the problems on paper as neee (3) Question

More information

Spurious Significance of Treatment Effects in Overfitted Fixed Effect Models Albrecht Ritschl 1 LSE and CEPR. March 2009

Spurious Significance of Treatment Effects in Overfitted Fixed Effect Models Albrecht Ritschl 1 LSE and CEPR. March 2009 Spurious Significance of reatment Effects in Overfitte Fixe Effect Moels Albrecht Ritschl LSE an CEPR March 2009 Introuction Evaluating subsample means across groups an time perios is common in panel stuies

More information

This module is part of the. Memobust Handbook. on Methodology of Modern Business Statistics

This module is part of the. Memobust Handbook. on Methodology of Modern Business Statistics This moule is part of the Memobust Hanbook on Methoology of Moern Business Statistics 26 March 2014 Metho: Balance Sampling for Multi-Way Stratification Contents General section... 3 1. Summary... 3 2.

More information

Math 1B, lecture 8: Integration by parts

Math 1B, lecture 8: Integration by parts Math B, lecture 8: Integration by parts Nathan Pflueger 23 September 2 Introuction Integration by parts, similarly to integration by substitution, reverses a well-known technique of ifferentiation an explores

More information

Table of Common Derivatives By David Abraham

Table of Common Derivatives By David Abraham Prouct an Quotient Rules: Table of Common Derivatives By Davi Abraham [ f ( g( ] = [ f ( ] g( + f ( [ g( ] f ( = g( [ f ( ] g( g( f ( [ g( ] Trigonometric Functions: sin( = cos( cos( = sin( tan( = sec

More information

Balancing Expected and Worst-Case Utility in Contracting Models with Asymmetric Information and Pooling

Balancing Expected and Worst-Case Utility in Contracting Models with Asymmetric Information and Pooling Balancing Expecte an Worst-Case Utility in Contracting Moels with Asymmetric Information an Pooling R.B.O. erkkamp & W. van en Heuvel & A.P.M. Wagelmans Econometric Institute Report EI2018-01 9th January

More information

Incomplete Contracts and the Product Cycle. Pol Antràs. Harvard University, NBER and CEPR

Incomplete Contracts and the Product Cycle. Pol Antràs. Harvard University, NBER and CEPR Incomplete Contracts and the Product Cycle Pol Antràs Harvard University, NBER and CEPR 1 Broad Research Agenda Try to understand how firms organize production in a global economy and study its implications

More information

6 General properties of an autonomous system of two first order ODE

6 General properties of an autonomous system of two first order ODE 6 General properties of an autonomous system of two first orer ODE Here we embark on stuying the autonomous system of two first orer ifferential equations of the form ẋ 1 = f 1 (, x 2 ), ẋ 2 = f 2 (, x

More information

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory)

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory) 14.581 MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory) Dave Donaldson Spring 2011 Introduction to Gravity Models Recall that in this course we have so far seen a wide range of trade models:

More information

The Exact Form and General Integrating Factors

The Exact Form and General Integrating Factors 7 The Exact Form an General Integrating Factors In the previous chapters, we ve seen how separable an linear ifferential equations can be solve using methos for converting them to forms that can be easily

More information

Polynomial Inclusion Functions

Polynomial Inclusion Functions Polynomial Inclusion Functions E. e Weert, E. van Kampen, Q. P. Chu, an J. A. Muler Delft University of Technology, Faculty of Aerospace Engineering, Control an Simulation Division E.eWeert@TUDelft.nl

More information

7.1 Support Vector Machine

7.1 Support Vector Machine 67577 Intro. to Machine Learning Fall semester, 006/7 Lecture 7: Support Vector Machines an Kernel Functions II Lecturer: Amnon Shashua Scribe: Amnon Shashua 7. Support Vector Machine We return now to

More information

Chapter Primer on Differentiation

Chapter Primer on Differentiation Capter 0.01 Primer on Differentiation After reaing tis capter, you soul be able to: 1. unerstan te basics of ifferentiation,. relate te slopes of te secant line an tangent line to te erivative of a function,.

More information

4.2 First Differentiation Rules; Leibniz Notation

4.2 First Differentiation Rules; Leibniz Notation .. FIRST DIFFERENTIATION RULES; LEIBNIZ NOTATION 307. First Differentiation Rules; Leibniz Notation In this section we erive rules which let us quickly compute the erivative function f (x) for any polynomial

More information

The Sokhotski-Plemelj Formula

The Sokhotski-Plemelj Formula hysics 25 Winter 208 The Sokhotski-lemelj Formula. The Sokhotski-lemelj formula The Sokhotski-lemelj formula is a relation between the following generalize functions (also calle istributions), ±iǫ = iπ(),

More information

The derivative of a function f(x) is another function, defined in terms of a limiting expression: f(x + δx) f(x)

The derivative of a function f(x) is another function, defined in terms of a limiting expression: f(x + δx) f(x) Y. D. Chong (2016) MH2801: Complex Methos for the Sciences 1. Derivatives The erivative of a function f(x) is another function, efine in terms of a limiting expression: f (x) f (x) lim x δx 0 f(x + δx)

More information

Topic 7: Convergence of Random Variables

Topic 7: Convergence of Random Variables Topic 7: Convergence of Ranom Variables Course 003, 2016 Page 0 The Inference Problem So far, our starting point has been a given probability space (S, F, P). We now look at how to generate information

More information

Chapter 2 Derivatives

Chapter 2 Derivatives Chapter Derivatives Section. An Intuitive Introuction to Derivatives Consier a function: Slope function: Derivative, f ' For each, the slope of f is the height of f ' Where f has a horizontal tangent line,

More information

Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity Under Firm Heterogeneity

Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity Under Firm Heterogeneity Monopolistic Competition an Optimum Prouct Diversity Uner Firm Heterogeneity Swati Dhingra Centre for Economic Performance, LSE John Morrow Centre for Economic Performance, LSE This Draft: October 2, 212

More information

Chapter 6: Energy-Momentum Tensors

Chapter 6: Energy-Momentum Tensors 49 Chapter 6: Energy-Momentum Tensors This chapter outlines the general theory of energy an momentum conservation in terms of energy-momentum tensors, then applies these ieas to the case of Bohm's moel.

More information

A simple model for the small-strain behaviour of soils

A simple model for the small-strain behaviour of soils A simple moel for the small-strain behaviour of soils José Jorge Naer Department of Structural an Geotechnical ngineering, Polytechnic School, University of São Paulo 05508-900, São Paulo, Brazil, e-mail:

More information

Calculus and optimization

Calculus and optimization Calculus an optimization These notes essentially correspon to mathematical appenix 2 in the text. 1 Functions of a single variable Now that we have e ne functions we turn our attention to calculus. A function

More information

Lower Bounds for the Smoothed Number of Pareto optimal Solutions

Lower Bounds for the Smoothed Number of Pareto optimal Solutions Lower Bouns for the Smoothe Number of Pareto optimal Solutions Tobias Brunsch an Heiko Röglin Department of Computer Science, University of Bonn, Germany brunsch@cs.uni-bonn.e, heiko@roeglin.org Abstract.

More information

Chapter 9 Method of Weighted Residuals

Chapter 9 Method of Weighted Residuals Chapter 9 Metho of Weighte Resiuals 9- Introuction Metho of Weighte Resiuals (MWR) is an approimate technique for solving bounary value problems. It utilizes a trial functions satisfying the prescribe

More information

Implicit Differentiation

Implicit Differentiation Implicit Differentiation Thus far, the functions we have been concerne with have been efine explicitly. A function is efine explicitly if the output is given irectly in terms of the input. For instance,

More information

Math 342 Partial Differential Equations «Viktor Grigoryan

Math 342 Partial Differential Equations «Viktor Grigoryan Math 342 Partial Differential Equations «Viktor Grigoryan 6 Wave equation: solution In this lecture we will solve the wave equation on the entire real line x R. This correspons to a string of infinite

More information

Research Article When Inflation Causes No Increase in Claim Amounts

Research Article When Inflation Causes No Increase in Claim Amounts Probability an Statistics Volume 2009, Article ID 943926, 10 pages oi:10.1155/2009/943926 Research Article When Inflation Causes No Increase in Claim Amounts Vytaras Brazauskas, 1 Bruce L. Jones, 2 an

More information

The Extensive Margin of Exporting Products: A Firm-level Analysis Online Supplement

The Extensive Margin of Exporting Products: A Firm-level Analysis Online Supplement The Extensive Margin of Exporting Proucts: A Firm-level Analysis Online Supplement Costas Arkolakis Yale University, CESifo an NBER Marc-Anreas Muenler UC San Diego, CESifo an NBER September 2014 Sharat

More information

A tale of two cities:

A tale of two cities: Highly preliminary. Do not quote or refer to. A tale of two cities: Urban spatial structure an moe of transportation Takaaki Takahashi Center for Spatial Information Science, the University of Tokyo, 5-1-5,

More information

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011 Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano University of Munich July 22, 2011 & 1 / 20 & & 2 / 20 My Bachelor Thesis: Ottaviano et al. (2009) apply the model to study gains from the euro & 3 / 20 Melitz and Ottaviano

More information

05 The Continuum Limit and the Wave Equation

05 The Continuum Limit and the Wave Equation Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU Founations of Wave Phenomena Physics, Department of 1-1-2004 05 The Continuum Limit an the Wave Equation Charles G. Torre Department of Physics, Utah State University,

More information

x = c of N if the limit of f (x) = L and the right-handed limit lim f ( x)

x = c of N if the limit of f (x) = L and the right-handed limit lim f ( x) Limit We say the limit of f () as approaches c equals L an write, lim L. One-Sie Limits (Left an Right-Hane Limits) Suppose a function f is efine near but not necessarily at We say that f has a left-hane

More information

1 dx. where is a large constant, i.e., 1, (7.6) and Px is of the order of unity. Indeed, if px is given by (7.5), the inequality (7.

1 dx. where is a large constant, i.e., 1, (7.6) and Px is of the order of unity. Indeed, if px is given by (7.5), the inequality (7. Lectures Nine an Ten The WKB Approximation The WKB metho is a powerful tool to obtain solutions for many physical problems It is generally applicable to problems of wave propagation in which the frequency

More information

Logarithmic spurious regressions

Logarithmic spurious regressions Logarithmic spurious regressions Robert M. e Jong Michigan State University February 5, 22 Abstract Spurious regressions, i.e. regressions in which an integrate process is regresse on another integrate

More information

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011 Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano University of Munich July 22, 2011 & 1 / 20 & & 2 / 20 My Bachelor Thesis: Ottaviano et al. (2009) apply the model to study gains from the euro & 3 / 20 Melitz and Ottaviano

More information

NOTES ON EULER-BOOLE SUMMATION (1) f (l 1) (n) f (l 1) (m) + ( 1)k 1 k! B k (y) f (k) (y) dy,

NOTES ON EULER-BOOLE SUMMATION (1) f (l 1) (n) f (l 1) (m) + ( 1)k 1 k! B k (y) f (k) (y) dy, NOTES ON EULER-BOOLE SUMMATION JONATHAN M BORWEIN, NEIL J CALKIN, AND DANTE MANNA Abstract We stuy a connection between Euler-MacLaurin Summation an Boole Summation suggeste in an AMM note from 196, which

More information

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models Dave Donaldson (MIT) CEMMAP MC July 2018 1 All material based on earlier courses taught

More information

Transaction Efficiency, the Evolution of Labor Division and the Transform Tendency of Dual Trade Structure

Transaction Efficiency, the Evolution of Labor Division and the Transform Tendency of Dual Trade Structure Transaction Efficiency, the Evolution of Labor Division an the Transform Tenency of Dual Trae Structure Jingfeng (Joe) Zhao 1 Abstract: Through inirect pricing theory an the margin comparison static global

More information

Multinational ownership, intellectual property rights, and knowledge diffusion from FDI

Multinational ownership, intellectual property rights, and knowledge diffusion from FDI NiCE Working Paper 08-110 November 2008 Multinational ownership, intellectual property rights, an knowlege iffusion from FDI Roger Smeets Albert e Vaal Nijmegen Center for Economics (NiCE) Institute for

More information

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory)

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory) 14.581 International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory) 14.581 Week 9 Spring 2013 14.581 (Week 9) Gravity Models (Theory) Spring 2013 1 / 44 Today s Plan 1 The Simplest Gravity Model: Armington

More information

Final Exam Study Guide and Practice Problems Solutions

Final Exam Study Guide and Practice Problems Solutions Final Exam Stuy Guie an Practice Problems Solutions Note: These problems are just some of the types of problems that might appear on the exam. However, to fully prepare for the exam, in aition to making

More information

Rensselaer. Working Papers in Economics

Rensselaer. Working Papers in Economics Rensselaer Working apers in Economics Department of Economics, Rensselaer olytechnic Institute, 8th Street, Troy, NY, 8-59, US. Tel: +- 58-76-687; Fax: +-58-76-5; URL: http://www.rpi.eu/ept/economics/;

More information

On the Aloha throughput-fairness tradeoff

On the Aloha throughput-fairness tradeoff On the Aloha throughput-fairness traeoff 1 Nan Xie, Member, IEEE, an Steven Weber, Senior Member, IEEE Abstract arxiv:1605.01557v1 [cs.it] 5 May 2016 A well-known inner boun of the stability region of

More information

θ x = f ( x,t) could be written as

θ x = f ( x,t) could be written as 9. Higher orer PDEs as systems of first-orer PDEs. Hyperbolic systems. For PDEs, as for ODEs, we may reuce the orer by efining new epenent variables. For example, in the case of the wave equation, (1)

More information

Scott E. Grasman 1, Zaki Sari 2 and Tewfik Sari 3

Scott E. Grasman 1, Zaki Sari 2 and Tewfik Sari 3 RAIRO Operations Research RAIRO Oper. Res. 41 (27) 455 464 DOI: 1.151/ro:2731 NEWSVENDOR SOLUTIONS WITH GENERAL RANDOM YIELD DISTRIBUTIONS Scott E. Grasman 1, Zaki Sari 2 an Tewfik Sari 3 Abstract. Most

More information

Kinetic Energy Is Important in the Nanoscale World

Kinetic Energy Is Important in the Nanoscale World Kinetic Energy Is Important in the Nanoscale Worl Frank Riou Department of Chemistry College of St. Beneict & St. John's University St. Joseph, MN 56374 Most eplanations of atomic an molecular phenomena

More information

A Model of Discovery

A Model of Discovery Moel of Discovery Michele olrin an Davi K. Levine 1 his version: December 26, 2008 First version: December 13, 2008 Prepare for the 2008 merican Economic ssociation Meetings. Session itle: Intellectual

More information

by using the derivative rules. o Building blocks: d

by using the derivative rules. o Building blocks: d Calculus for Business an Social Sciences - Prof D Yuen Eam Review version /9/01 Check website for any poste typos an upates Eam is on Sections, 5, 6,, 1,, Derivatives Rules Know how to fin the formula

More information

arxiv:hep-th/ v1 3 Feb 1993

arxiv:hep-th/ v1 3 Feb 1993 NBI-HE-9-89 PAR LPTHE 9-49 FTUAM 9-44 November 99 Matrix moel calculations beyon the spherical limit arxiv:hep-th/93004v 3 Feb 993 J. Ambjørn The Niels Bohr Institute Blegamsvej 7, DK-00 Copenhagen Ø,

More information

Computing Derivatives

Computing Derivatives Chapter 2 Computing Derivatives 2.1 Elementary erivative rules Motivating Questions In this section, we strive to unerstan the ieas generate by the following important questions: What are alternate notations

More information

Why Do Firms Conduct Bi-Sourcing? 1

Why Do Firms Conduct Bi-Sourcing? 1 Why Do Firms Conduct Bi-Sourcing? 1 Julan Du Chinese University of Hong Kong Yi Lu University of Hong Kong Zhigang Tao University of Hong Kong Abstract In acquiring the same intermediate inputs, a firm

More information

PDE Notes, Lecture #11

PDE Notes, Lecture #11 PDE Notes, Lecture # from Professor Jalal Shatah s Lectures Febuary 9th, 2009 Sobolev Spaces Recall that for u L loc we can efine the weak erivative Du by Du, φ := udφ φ C0 If v L loc such that Du, φ =

More information

THE VAN KAMPEN EXPANSION FOR LINKED DUFFING LINEAR OSCILLATORS EXCITED BY COLORED NOISE

THE VAN KAMPEN EXPANSION FOR LINKED DUFFING LINEAR OSCILLATORS EXCITED BY COLORED NOISE Journal of Soun an Vibration (1996) 191(3), 397 414 THE VAN KAMPEN EXPANSION FOR LINKED DUFFING LINEAR OSCILLATORS EXCITED BY COLORED NOISE E. M. WEINSTEIN Galaxy Scientific Corporation, 2500 English Creek

More information

18 EVEN MORE CALCULUS

18 EVEN MORE CALCULUS 8 EVEN MORE CALCULUS Chapter 8 Even More Calculus Objectives After stuing this chapter you shoul be able to ifferentiate an integrate basic trigonometric functions; unerstan how to calculate rates of change;

More information

ensembles When working with density operators, we can use this connection to define a generalized Bloch vector: v x Tr x, v y Tr y

ensembles When working with density operators, we can use this connection to define a generalized Bloch vector: v x Tr x, v y Tr y Ph195a lecture notes, 1/3/01 Density operators for spin- 1 ensembles So far in our iscussion of spin- 1 systems, we have restricte our attention to the case of pure states an Hamiltonian evolution. Toay

More information