1 Stochastic Dynamic Programming

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "1 Stochastic Dynamic Programming"

Transcription

1 1 Stochastic Dynamic Programming Formally, a stochastic dynamic program has the same components as a deterministic one; the only modification is to the state transition equation. When events in the future are uncertain, the state does not evolve deterministically; instead, states and actions today lead to a distribution over possible states in the future. We ll assume that P (B,x,a) is the induced probability that tomorrow s state will lie in the set B given that today s state is x and today s action is a. Let s take a look at the Bellman equation for a stochastic dynamic program: { } v(x) = max r(x,a)+ v(x )P (dx,x,a). a Γ(x) We have to relate this expression to V (x 0 ) = max {x t,a t} t=0 { [ ]} 0 β t r(x t,a t ), the value function defined over the sequential problem. It turns out to be a bit more work than it was before because we need to be clear how to construct expectations in the recursive case we are taking expectations over tomorrow s states while in the sequential case we are taking expectations over sequences of future states, and it is not obvious that the two ideas can be reconciled. There are three important concepts buried in here that we need conditional expectations, expectations over sequences of events that unfold over time, and the law of iterated expectations. To understand these concepts formally we need to take a detour into measure theory. t=0 1.1 Measure Theory Detour Definition 1 Let S be a space. A family F of subsets of S is called a σ-algebra if (i) A F implies S\A F; (ii) if A n F n then n=1a n F; and (iii) S F. The pair (S,F) is called a measurable space. Note that because the union of sets is equal to the intersection of the complements of those sets, σ-algebras are also closed under countable intersections. Also, F because = S\S and S F. The largest σ-algebra on S consists of all subsets of S and the smallest consists of S and the empty set; in general, we cannot assign size to every member of the largest σ-algebra (for example, in R n the Banach-Tarski paradox constructs a set which cannot be assigned size) so this σ-algebra is only useful if S is countable. The σ- algebra generated by open sets (meaning that it is obtained by taking open sets and then adding whatever is needed to make the collection closed under unions and complements; it is therefore the smallest σ-algebra containing all the open sets) is called the Borel field and is typically denoted B(S) (or B n if S = R n ); this field contains all open and closed sets as well 1

2 as arbitrary unions of open sets and arbitrary intersections of closed sets (but not arbitrary unions of closed sets or arbitrary intersections of open sets, only countable ones). The restriction of B n to a subset of R n is also a σ-algebra, so that ([0,1],B 1 0) is a measurable space, where B 1 0 is the σ-algebra generated by intersecting elements of B with [0,1]. We will call a σ-algebra finer than F (written F ) if every set in F is also in. Definition 2 A sequence of σ-algebras {F t } t with F t F t+1 is called a filtration. Filtrations are a sequence of increasingly-fine σ-algebras, and are the natural method for expressing the flow of information. To see this, let s imagine a world that lasts two periods. Before period 1 nature selects a sequence of two outcomes, good or bad, in each period. Thus, the space of outcomes is S = {(,) (,B) (B,) (B,B)}. at time 0 the agent knows only that nature chose; therefore, the appropriate σ-algebra is F 0 = {,S}. At time 1 the first part is revealed, meaning that the agent now has the σ-algebra F 1 = {{(,) (,B)},{(B,) (B,B)},,S}. Finally, at time 2 everything is revealed, yielding F 2 = {(,),(,B),(B,),(B,B),,S} unioned with all the appropriate unions and complements (which take up too much space to write out). Note that F 0 F 1 F 2, so that this sequence is a filtration. Definition 3 A probability measure on (S,F) is a mapping µ : F [0,1] such that (i) µ( ) = 0; (ii) µ( n=1a n ) = n=1 µ(a n) if A n A m = n m and A n F; and (iii) µ(s) = 1. Thus, µ(a) is interpreted as the probability of event A; sets not in F cannot be assigned probabilities; for the remainder of this part we will just refer to µ as a measure (any finite measure can be normalized into a probability measure). Measures are monotone: µ(a) µ(b) if A B. Also, if {A n } F and A 1 A 2 and A = n A n, then µ(a n ) ր µ(a). Also, if {A n } F and A 1 A 2 and A = n A n, then µ(a n ) ց µ(a). And finally, for any collection of sets {A n } n=1 F we have where the A n may not be disjoint. µ( n A n ) n µ(a n) 2

3 One measure that will be of particular interest is the Lebesgue measure λ(b). Suppose that B can be written as the countable union of disjoint open intervals {(a 1,b 1 ),(a 2,b 2 ),...} (that is, it is a Borel set) and denote the collection of all such sets as I. Then where λ(b) = inf A I,B A {λ(a)} λ(a) = n (b n a n ); that is, the Lebesgue measure of B is the size of the smallest Borel set that contains B. It is not difficult to show that λ is a measure on B 1, the Borel sets of one dimension. Higher dimensions are handled analogously as the cross-product of intervals. In one dimension, countable collections of discrete points (like the rational numbers) have zero Lebesgue measure; in two dimensions, countable collections of discrete points and one-dimensional curves have zero measure; and so on. Definition 4 A triple (S,F,µ) is called a probability space. The key thing we need are concepts of integration and random variables. In particular, we need to know how to decide whether a function can be integrated with respect to a particular σ-algebra, which will matter when we start thinking about expectations. Definition 5 Let (S,F) and (T,) be measurable spaces. A function f : S T is measurable if and only if A we have f 1 (A) F, where f 1 (A) = {s S : f (s) A}. In particular, if we have F = B n then f is measurable if and only if the sets {s S : f (s) r} are contained in F for each r. Any continuous function is measurable, since those sets are all closed and thus must be in B n ; however, certain step functions are also measurable, so the class is clearly larger than the class of continuous functions. The notion of measurable function leads directly to the idea of a random variable. Definition 6 If (S,F,µ) is a probability space and f : S R n is measurable, then we call f a random variable. It is straightforward to apply the definition of measurability to prove the following facts: Proposition 1 Suppose f n : S R is measurable n and that f n (x) f (x) x. Then f is measurable. 3

4 Proposition 2 If f : S R is measurable and g : R R then g f is measurable where (g f)(s) = g(f (s)). Proposition 3 If f : S R and g : S R are measurable then f + g and f g are measurable. Proposition 4 If f : S R is measurable and α is a constant, then αf is measurable. Proposition 5 If f : S R and g : S R are measurable, then fg is measurable where (fg)(s) = f (s)g(s). f/g is measurable if g(s) 0 s, where (f/g)(s) = f (s)/g(s). To define integration, we need to define some types of functions. Definition 7 A function 1 A : S R is called the indicator function for A (sometimes called the characteristic function of A) if it takes the form 1 A (s) = { 1 if s A 0 if s / A. A function f : S R is called a simple function if it takes the form f (s) = n α i 1 Ai (s) i=1 for n <, real numbers {α i } n i=1, and disjoint sets {A i} n i=1 such that n i=1a i = S. Indicator functions are nonzero only over the set A, and simple functions are step functions created through finite linear combinations of indicator functions over disjoint sets(using disjoint sets puts the simple function in the standard representation). It is straightforwardtoseethatindicatorfunctionsaremeasurableifandonlyifa F; thatis,theσ-algebra must allow you to identify whether the event A did happen or did not happen. To see how this process works, consider r 1; then {s S : 1 A (s) r} = S F because indicator functions always take values less than or equal to 1. For r < 0 we have {s S : 1 A (s) r} = F. For any r (0,1) we have {s S : 1 A (s) r} = S\A, so that 1 A is measurable if and only if A F (because it needs to have S\A F). Simple functions are measurable if and only if every A i F; that is, we need to be able to identify whether each A i happened. Thus, measurability of a simple function with respect to a 4

5 particular σ-algebra really comes down to one simple condition the function must be constant on disjoint sets that are not elements of the σ-algebra, because if it changes value we can learn more by observing its value than we are supposed to know. We then define the Lebesgue integral of a simple function f (which is nonnegative) as f (s)λ(ds) = n α i λ(a i ); the notation λ(ds) is meant to make clear that we are summing the height of the simple function times the size of the interval ds. If f is both positive and negative we simply define the positive and negative parts separately and then put them together: { f (s) if f (s) 0 f + (s) = 0 otherwise i=1 and so that f (s) = f (s)µ(ds) = { f (s) if f (s) 0 0 otherwise f + (s)µ(ds) f (s)µ(ds). This function is not measurable if both terms are infinite. For nonsimple functions we define their integral as the limit of the integrals of simple functions that fit under f. That is, { } f (s)µ(ds) = sup g(s)µ(ds) : g is a simple function and 0 g(s) f (s) s. g Again, to integrate a function that has both negative and positive parts we simply do each piece separately and reassemble them. Definition 8 A function f is integrable if f (s) µ(ds) <. It is straightforward to see that f (s)µ(ds) = A f (s)1 A (s)µ(ds), which is the notion of integrating over a limited domain; obviously, if f is integrable over S it is integrable over any subset of S. One helpful property that we will use later is the fact that f (s)µ(ds) f (s) µ(ds); this is just an application of the triangle inequality. Other facts are equally easy to establish, once we note the property of almost everywhere. 5

6 Definition 9 A property P of f is said to hold almost everywhere (a.e) if the set P c = {s S : f (s) does not have property P} has measure µ(p c ) = 0. Properties that hold only on P with µ(p) = 0 are said to hold almost nowhere. We then can easily establish the following. Proposition 6 Let f,g be integrable. Then f +g is integrable, αf is integrable α, and (f +g)(s)µ(ds) = f (s)µ(ds)+ g(s)µ(ds) (αf)(s)µ(ds) = α f (s)µ(ds). Proposition 7 If f = 0 almost everywhere, then f (s)µ(ds) = 0. Proposition 8 If f g almost everywhere, then f (s)µ(ds) g(s)µ(ds). Proposition 9 If f = g almost everywhere, then f (s)µ(ds) = g(s)µ(ds). Proposition 10 If f 0 and µ({s S : f (s) > 0}) > 0 then f (s)µ(ds) > 0. Now we will define a space that will be relevant for our application to dynamic programming. Definition 10 Let (S,F,µ) be a probability space. The space L 1 (S,F,µ) is the space of all functions that are integrable with respect to µ. We will now prove that L 1 is a Banach space; the one caveat is that we must interpret L 1 as a space of equivalence classes, not functions, where an equivalence class is the collection of all functions that equal a reference function f almost everywhere. That is, for our purposes if two functions differ only on a set of Lebesgue measure zero then they are equal (because their expectations will be equal). The proof requires two theorems. Theorem 1 (Monotone Convergence Theorem) Suppose is a measurable set. Let {f n } be a sequence of measurable functions such that 0 f 1 (x) f 2 (x) for x. Let f be defined by f n (x) f (x) as n. Then f n (x)µ(dx) f (x)µ(dx). 6

7 Proof. As n, for some α; since f n f, we have α f n (x)µ(dx) α f (x)µ(dx). Choose c such that 0 < c < 1 and let s be a simple measurable function such that 0 s f. Put n = {x : f n (x) cs(x)}. By monotonicity, 1 2 and by the convergence of f n to f we have For every n, = n=1 n. f n (x)µ(dx) f n (x)µ(dx) c s(x)µ(dx). n n Let n ; since the integral is countably additive set function we can obtain α c s(x)µ(dx). Letting c 1 we have Therefore, α α s(x)µ(dx). f (x)µ(dx). Theorem 2 (Fatou s Lemma) Suppose is measurable. If {f n } is a sequence of nonnegative measurable functions and f (x) = lim inf n {f n(x)} then f (x)µ(dx) lim inf f n (x)µ(dx). n Proof. Set g n (x) = inf i n {f i (x)}. g n is measurable on and 0 g 1 (x) g 2 (x) g n (x) f n (x) g n (x) f (x). 7

8 Therefore, by the Monotone Convergence Theorem g n (x)µ(dx) f (x)µ(dx). The conclusion is now immediate. Theorem 3 (Riesz-Fischer Theorem) L 1 is a Banach space. Proof. We need to show that if {f n } is a Cauchy sequence in L 1, then there exists f L 1 such that {f n } f in L 1. Since f n is Cauchy, there exists a sequence {n k }, k = 1,2,..., such that f nk f nk+1 < 1 2 k. Choose g L 1. By the Schwarz inequality g ( ) f nk f nk+1 µ(dx) g 2. k Hence, k=1 g ( f nk f nk+1 ) µ(dx) g. Interchanging the order of integration and summation, we have g(x) f nk (x) f nk+1 (x) < k=1 almost everywhere on. Therefore, f nk (x) f nk+1 (x) <, k=1 for otherwise we could take g(x) 0 on a subset of of positive measure and contradict the previous inequality. Since the kth partial sum of is ( fnk+1 (x) f n k (x) ) k=1 f nk+1 (x) f nk (x) and the series converges almost everywhere on, we have f (x) = lim k f nk (x) defines f (x) for almost all x ; it does not matter how we define f (x) on those other points. 8

9 To show that f has the desired properties, let ǫ > 0 be given and choose N such that n N and m N implies f n f m ǫ (which is possible because f n is Cauchy). If n k > N, Fatou s lemma shows that f n f nk liminf i f n i f nk ǫ. Thus, f f nk L 1 and sincef = (f f m )+f nk, we have f L 1. Since ǫ is arbitrary, Finally, the inequality lim k f f n k = 0. f f n f f nk + f nk f n shows that f n converges to f in L 1, for if we take n and n k large enough each of the terms on the RHS can be made small. This result will be useful, because it will enable us to apply the Banach fixed point theorem (contraction mapping theorem) to a stochastic dynamic programming problem. Another small point involves the order of integration if we have multiple integrals, it should not matter the order in which we do them. but of course infinities can make things tricky. Define the product σ-algebra F as the smallest σ-algebra that contains all crossproducts of elements of F with elements of. A function f : S T R is measurable if it is measurable with respect to F. We get this result from Fubini s theorem, which we will not prove. Theorem 4 (Fubini s Theorem) Let f : S T R be measurable and let µ be a measure on (S,F) and ν be a measure of (T,). Then ( ) f (s,t)ν(dt) µ(ds) < if and only if S T ( whenever these are finite they are equal. T S ) f (s,t)µ(ds) ν(dt) < ; The final step is to define an expectation, which is just an integral. Definition 11 Let (S,F,µ) be a probability space. If f : S R is a random variable then the expectation of f with respect to µ is defined to be µ [f] = f (s)µ(ds). 9

10 When the measure is not ambiguous, it will be dropped from the expression leaving just [f]. What we are interested in is the conditional expectation of a random variable, which is a bit more challenging to define since we must worry about the possibility that our conditioning event has probability 0 (say, if a random variable has a continuous support the realization of any single real number is 0). What we will do is define a conditional expectation as a random variable over a σ-algebra that is smaller than F so that F; that is, any set that is measurable with respect to is also measurable with respect to F. Definition 12 A measurable partition of S is a collection of subsets of S such that (i) = ; (ii) = S; and (iii) F if. Suppose that is the σ-algebra generated by the partition. If g is a measurable function with respect to, then g must take on constant values over nonempty sets in. As noted before, this idea makes sense as a theory of information if is to represent the things you know then any function which you can take expectations of must not provide you any information about stuff you don t; that is, it cannot take on different values inside sets because then you would know more than you do. We can now define a conditional expectation. Definition 13 The conditional expectation of f relative to isafunction µ [f;](s) that is measurable with respect to and that satisfies the requirement µ [f;](s)µ(ds) = f (s)µ(ds) for any. It can be shown that µ [f;] defined in this way is unique up to a set of measure zero. Since µ [f;] must take on a constant value over, we have µ [f;](s)µ(ds) = µ [f;] µ(ds) If µ() > 0, we have the familiar expression µ [f;] = = µ [f;]µ(). f (s)µ(ds) ; µ() if µ() = 0, we still can employ this concept by thinking in limits (a sequence of sets n with µ( n ) 0). Conditional probabilities are then obtained by letting f be an indicator function: µ [1 A ;] = 1 A(s)µ(ds) µ() 10

11 has the interpretation as the probability of event A conditional on, provided again that µ() > 0. The law of iterated expectations can now be defined that is, the conditional expectation of a conditional expectation. Suppose we have two σ-algebras contained in F such that 1 2 (that is, the sequence { i } defines a filtration). Define the random variables µ [f; 1 ](s) and µ [f; 2 ](s), which are the conditional expectations with respect to each σ-algebra. By the definition of a conditional expectation we have µ [f; i ](s)µ(ds) = f (s)µ(ds) over any set i. Let s now consider the conditional expectation of µ [f; 2 ](s) with respect to 1, which must by definition be µ [ µ [f; 2 ]; 1 ](s)µ(ds) = [f; 2 ](s)µ(ds). Since 1 implies 2 the RHS is [f; 2 ](s)µ(ds) = For any 1 we must also have [f; 1 ](s)µ(ds) = Therefore, for any 1 µ [ µ [f; 2 ]; 1 ](s)µ(ds) = f (s)µ(ds). f (s)µ(ds). [f; 1 ](s)µ(ds). In the sequential problem this law enables us to get rid of expectations of future events with respect to information we gain only in the future; that is, taking the expectation with respect to information today is not inconsistent with the fact that the agent knows that some things will be learned and used to form expectations in the future. We can now be very precise about the term stochastic transition. Definition 14 A mapping P : F A [0,1] is a stochastic transition function on (,F) if, x and a A, P (,x,a) is a probability measure on F and for each B F P (B,, ) is a measurable function on A. An important class of stochastic processes are called Markov processes with stationary transitions. Markov means that the transition probabilities only depend on a finite history of past realizations and stationary means that calender time is irrelevant. These properties are important for dynamic programming, as they imply that t is again irrelevant and that computing expectations does not require the entire history of past events. Some familiar 11

12 stochastic processes are Markovian with stationary transitions. For example, let Φ(x) denote the cdf of a standard normal. Then the transition function describes an AR(1) process P ({x : x r},x) = 1 Φ(r ρx) x t+1 = ρx t +ǫ t+1 with ǫ t+1 iidn (0,1). Another familiar and useful stochastic process is a Markov chain, which arises when is a finite set. The transition function is usually written as P = [p ij ] i,j=1,...,n, with the interpretation that p ij = Pr{x t+1 = x i : x t = x j }; to be consistent with rules of probability requires p ij 0 and i p ij = 1. Stochastic transition functions can be used to define probability measures over sequences, which we need to define the sequential problem. That is, we can define µ T (B;x 0 ) = P (dx T,x T 1 )P (dx T 1,x T 2 ) P (dx 1,x 0 ) A 2 A T A 1 as the probability of B = {x t } T t=1 given the initial state x 0, so µ T ( ;x 0 ) = Pr{x 1 A 1,x 2 A 2,,x T A T x 0 }. It is not hard to show that µ T is in fact a probability measure on the product σ-algebra F T = F F F. As T we can define µ which is technically not a measure on F but something a bit weaker; we use the σ-algebra H which is the smallest σ-algebra that contains all finite unions of sets of the form B = A 1 A 2 A 3 A T where A t F for each t and all but finitely many of the sets equal so that µ (B;x 0 ) = P (dx T,x T 1 )P (dx T 1,x T 2 ) P (dx 1,x 0 ) A 2 A T A 1 where T is the largest date beyond which A t = t > T. We can uniquely extend this measure to all events (that is, those that do not require A t = t T) in H using one of the Hahn-Caratheodory extension theorems; by slight abuse of notion we ll refer to this measure as µ as well. Consider the functions F T (x 1,x 2,...,x T ) = T β t 1 f (x t ) t=1 12

13 and F (x 1,x 2,...) = β t 1 f (x t ); you can interpret F as the lifetime return once a policy function has been selected: F (x 1,x 2,...) = β t 1 r(x t,π(x t )). t=1 ach F T is measurable with respect to H (since it involves events that only differ from at finitely-many dates, namely those up to and including date T) and {F T } converges pointwise to F, so F is measurable with respect to H. We can therefore write [F;x 0 ] = f (x 1 )P (dx 1,x 0 )+ [ ] β f (x 2 )P (dx 2,x 1 ) P (dx 1,x 0 )+ [ [ ] ] β 2 f (x 3 )P (dx 3,x 2 ) P (dx 2,x 1 ) P (dx 1,x 0 )+ and is immediate that [F;x 0 ] =. t=1 [f (x 1 )+β[f;x 1 ]]P (dx 1,x 0 ). That is exactly what we want to have the lifetime expected value is the sum of the firstperiod return and the lifetime expected value from tomorrow onward, discounted back to today. 1.2 Back to Dynamic Programming Again Consider the functional equation { } v(x) = max r(x,a)+β v(x )P (dx,x,a) a Γ(x) where x is a set of events tomorrow. We want to relate this functional equation to the sequential problem { [ ]} V (x 0 ) = max 0 β t r(x t,a t ) {x t,a t} t=0 subject to the restrictions embedded in the state transition and feasible control sets. The sequences which solve the sequential problem should be interpreted as conditional on outcomes that is, they unfold over event trees. This expression is often written as { V (x 0 ) = max β t π ( } ) s t s 0 r(xt,a t ) {x t,a t} t=0 t=0 13 t=0

14 where s t is the history of events up through time t (s t = {s 0,s 1,...,s t }) and π(s t s 0 ) is the probability of that history conditional on s 0. We want to prove that v(x) exists and is unique. Define (Tw)(x) = max a Γ(x) { r(x,a)+β } w(x )P (dx,x,a). We make the same continuity assumptions as before. To apply the Blackwell-Boyd conditionsweneedaφ(x) > 0function; thisfunctionmustadditionallynowsatisfyanintegrability condition. Theorem 5 Assume (1) the one-period return function r is continuous on A and the feasible actions correspondence Γ is continuous and compact-valued; (2) there is a function φ Ξ with φ(x) > 0 such that (i) there exists an M < with x, (ii) and (iii) max { r(x,a) } Mφ(x) (1) a Γ(x) { { }} φ(x ) βsup max x a Γ(x) φ(x) P (dx,x,a) < 1, (2) φ(x )P (dx,x,a) < x and a Γ(x); and (3) for any continuous w Ξ φ w(x )P (dx,x,a) is continuous on A. Under these conditions the Bellman operator is a strict contraction map. Condition (2)(iii) guarantees the integrability of any member of Ξ φ, since { } f (x) f φ = sup x φ(x) and therefore f is bounded in absolute ) value by an) integrable function φ. We now show that T : (Ξ φ, φ (Ξ φ, φ. If w Ξ φ then Tw is continuous by ) ) the maximum theorem, so T : (Ξ φ, φ (Ξ, φ. To see that Tw has finite φ-norm, note that { (Tw)(x) = max r(x,a)+β w(x )P (dx,x,a)} a Γ(x) { } max { r(x,a) }+β max w(x ) P (dx,x,a) a Γ(x) a Γ(x) { } w(x ) = max { r(x,a) }+β max a Γ(x) a Γ(x) φ(x ) φ(x )P (dx,x,a) { } max { r(x,a) }+β w φ max φ(x )P (dx,x,a) a Γ(x) a Γ(x) 14

15 which is finite in the φ-norm by conditions (i) and (iii). Now we check monotonicity. Let v w. Then { } (Tv)(x) = max r(x,a)+β v(x )P (dx,x,a) a Γ(x) { } max r(x,a)+β w(x )P (dx,x,a) a Γ(x) = (Tw)(x). And then discounting constant functions: { } (T (w +Aφ))(x) = max r(x,a)+β [w(x )+Aφ(x )]P (dx,x,a) a Γ(x) { } (Tw)(x)+βA max φ(x )P (dx,x,a) a Γ(x) { } φ(x ) (Tw)(x)+Aφ(x)β max a Γ(x) φ(x) P (dx,x,a) (Tw)(x)+θAφ(x) with θ < 1 by condition (ii). Therefore, we know that v is the unique function that satisfies the Bellman equation. It is not as straightforward to prove that v = V; it turns out that it could be the case that V is not measurable, meaning that it could not satisfy the Bellman equation (the example is due to Blackwell and can be found in SLP). We will now show that our assumptions rule out this pathological case. To begin, let Π denote the collection of all policies π : A such that π(x) Γ(x), the function Q(B,x) = P (B,x,π(x)) is a stochastic transition on (,F,µ), and r(x,π(x)) is a measurable function with respect to F. Π is nonempty under the conditions that r is continuous, P is continuous (condition 3 guarantees this), and that Γ admits a continuous selection (continuity of Γ guarantees this). A given π Π defines a probability measure over realizations {x t } T t=1 for any finite T defined by Q(B,x) = P (B,x,π(x)) = Pr{x t+1 B x t = x}; call this measure µ T ( ;x 0,π) for each T. That is, ( µ T T t=1 A t ;x 0,π ) = Q(dx T,x T 1 ) Q(dx 1,x 0 ). A 2 A T A 1 15

16 For finite T we therefore have ] 0 [ T t=0 β t r(x t,a t ) = r(x 0,π(x 0 ))+ β β 2.β T r(x 1,π(x 1 ))Q(dx 1,x 0 )+ r(x 2,π(x 2 ))Q(dx 2,x 1 )Q(dx 1,x 0 )+ r(x T,π(x T ))Q(dx T,x T 1 ) Q(dx 1,x 0 ). We need to show that this sum converges to a finite number as T. Since we have assumed that r is bounded by φ, we have r( x,π( x)) φ( x) M for every x and π Π. Take last term in the summation and consider the innermost integral: r(x T,π(x T ))Q(dx T,x T 1 ) r(x T,π(x T )) Q(dx T,x T 1 ) r(x T,π(x T )) φ(x T )Q(dx T,x T 1 ) φ(x T ) M φ(x T )Q(dx T,x T 1 ) { } φ(x ) Mφ(x T 1 )sup x φ(x) Q(dx,x). { } φ(x By assumption βsup ) x φ(x) Q(dx,x) = βa < 1. Thus, the innermost integral is bounded by MAφ(x T 1 ) in absolute value. If we repeat this procedure for every integral we get that the entire last term of the summation is bounded by M (βa) T φ(x) in absolute value. If we then move to the next-to-last term we get it is bounded by M (βa) T 1 φ(x), and so on. Thus, the entire summation is bounded by Mφ(x) ( 1+βA+β 2 A 2 + β T A T) = Mφ(x) 1 (βa)t+1 1 βa. 1 AsT wethereforehavethatthesummationisboundedbymφ(x) andtheinfinite 1 βa expected value is well-defined, since βa < 1. Define [ ] w π (x) = π β t r(x t,π(x t )) x 0 = x, t=0 16

17 the lifetime expected utility at x obtained by using π. The value function is V (x) = sup π Π {w π (x)}; since we know that w π Ξ φ then so is V. For any π Π it is true that there exists a unique V π Ξ φ that satisfies V π (x) = r(x,π(x))+β V π (x )P (dx,x,π(x)) by immediate application of the CMT; that is, V π is the unique fixed point of the strict contraction mapping T π defined as (T π u)(x) = r(x,π(x))+β u(x )P (dx,x,π(x)). Now we need to show that V π = w π ; that is, w π is the unique function in Ξ φ that satisfies w π (x) = (T π w π )(x) = r(x,π(x))+β w π (x )P (dx,x,π(x)). That this is true is again an immediate implication of the CMT along with the definition of w π. Tosumup, wehavedefinedthreefunctions. First, wehavethefixedpointofthebellman equation { } v(x) = max r(x,a)+β v(x )P (dx,x,a). a Γ(x) Second, we have the lifetime return to policy π, which satisfies w π (x) = r(x,π(x))+β v(x )P (dx,x,π(x)). And third, we have the value function V (x) = sup{w π (x)}. π Π We want to show that (i) v = V and (ii) V = w π for some optimal policy π. Take any function u Ξ φ and any policy π Π. It is true that w π u φ T πu u φ 1 θ where θ < 1; this property is immediately obtained using the definition of a strict contraction mapping and the triangle inequality. Also ǫ > 0 there exists a policy π Π such that w π v φ ǫ; that is, there exists a policy that nearly delivers lifetime returns equal to v, which should be easy to accept given the form of the fixed point operators that generate v and w π. 17

18 Now suppose v > V. Since there exists a policy π such that w π is arbitrarily close to v we can find one such that w π > V. This contradicts the fact that V is the value function and therefore the supremum over all such policies. So we know that v V. By the definitions of T and T π we must have T π v Tv = v (because T performs a maximization and T π does not). T π is monotone so that Tπv n v as well. Taking the limit yields w π v, which holds for arbitrary π. If v(x) w π (x) for every x and π, we must have v(x) V (x) = sup{w π (x)}. π Π Therefore, v V. Combined with the previous result we get v = V. To check the optimal policy condition v = w π, note that v(x) = r(x,π (x))+β v(x )P (dx,x,π (x)); that is, π attains the maximum on the RHS of the Bellman equation. Since v = V, we have T π V = T π v = Tv = v = V, so that T π V = V. Thus, the value function is the fixed point of T π, which is equal to w π. Therefore, v = w π. 18

1 Stochastic Dynamic Programming

1 Stochastic Dynamic Programming 1 Stochastic Dynamic Programming Formally, a stochastic dynamic program has the same components as a deterministic one; the only modification is to the state transition equation. When events in the future

More information

THEOREMS, ETC., FOR MATH 515

THEOREMS, ETC., FOR MATH 515 THEOREMS, ETC., FOR MATH 515 Proposition 1 (=comment on page 17). If A is an algebra, then any finite union or finite intersection of sets in A is also in A. Proposition 2 (=Proposition 1.1). For every

More information

Measure Theory on Topological Spaces. Course: Prof. Tony Dorlas 2010 Typset: Cathal Ormond

Measure Theory on Topological Spaces. Course: Prof. Tony Dorlas 2010 Typset: Cathal Ormond Measure Theory on Topological Spaces Course: Prof. Tony Dorlas 2010 Typset: Cathal Ormond May 22, 2011 Contents 1 Introduction 2 1.1 The Riemann Integral........................................ 2 1.2 Measurable..............................................

More information

Measure and integration

Measure and integration Chapter 5 Measure and integration In calculus you have learned how to calculate the size of different kinds of sets: the length of a curve, the area of a region or a surface, the volume or mass of a solid.

More information

Lebesgue Integration: A non-rigorous introduction. What is wrong with Riemann integration?

Lebesgue Integration: A non-rigorous introduction. What is wrong with Riemann integration? Lebesgue Integration: A non-rigorous introduction What is wrong with Riemann integration? xample. Let f(x) = { 0 for x Q 1 for x / Q. The upper integral is 1, while the lower integral is 0. Yet, the function

More information

MATHS 730 FC Lecture Notes March 5, Introduction

MATHS 730 FC Lecture Notes March 5, Introduction 1 INTRODUCTION MATHS 730 FC Lecture Notes March 5, 2014 1 Introduction Definition. If A, B are sets and there exists a bijection A B, they have the same cardinality, which we write as A, #A. If there exists

More information

Notes on Measure Theory and Markov Processes

Notes on Measure Theory and Markov Processes Notes on Measure Theory and Markov Processes Diego Daruich March 28, 2014 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Motivation The objective of these notes will be to develop tools from measure theory and probability to allow

More information

Lebesgue measure and integration

Lebesgue measure and integration Chapter 4 Lebesgue measure and integration If you look back at what you have learned in your earlier mathematics courses, you will definitely recall a lot about area and volume from the simple formulas

More information

LEBESGUE MEASURE AND L2 SPACE. Contents 1. Measure Spaces 1 2. Lebesgue Integration 2 3. L 2 Space 4 Acknowledgments 9 References 9

LEBESGUE MEASURE AND L2 SPACE. Contents 1. Measure Spaces 1 2. Lebesgue Integration 2 3. L 2 Space 4 Acknowledgments 9 References 9 LBSGU MASUR AND L2 SPAC. ANNI WANG Abstract. This paper begins with an introduction to measure spaces and the Lebesgue theory of measure and integration. Several important theorems regarding the Lebesgue

More information

Lebesgue Integration on R n

Lebesgue Integration on R n Lebesgue Integration on R n The treatment here is based loosely on that of Jones, Lebesgue Integration on Euclidean Space We give an overview from the perspective of a user of the theory Riemann integration

More information

Math 4121 Spring 2012 Weaver. Measure Theory. 1. σ-algebras

Math 4121 Spring 2012 Weaver. Measure Theory. 1. σ-algebras Math 4121 Spring 2012 Weaver Measure Theory 1. σ-algebras A measure is a function which gauges the size of subsets of a given set. In general we do not ask that a measure evaluate the size of every subset,

More information

Analysis Comprehensive Exam Questions Fall 2008

Analysis Comprehensive Exam Questions Fall 2008 Analysis Comprehensive xam Questions Fall 28. (a) Let R be measurable with finite Lebesgue measure. Suppose that {f n } n N is a bounded sequence in L 2 () and there exists a function f such that f n (x)

More information

Tools from Lebesgue integration

Tools from Lebesgue integration Tools from Lebesgue integration E.P. van den Ban Fall 2005 Introduction In these notes we describe some of the basic tools from the theory of Lebesgue integration. Definitions and results will be given

More information

Stochastic Dynamic Programming: The One Sector Growth Model

Stochastic Dynamic Programming: The One Sector Growth Model Stochastic Dynamic Programming: The One Sector Growth Model Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Princeton University March 26, 2012 Esteban Rossi-Hansberg () Stochastic Dynamic Programming March 26, 2012 1 / 31 References

More information

The Lebesgue Integral

The Lebesgue Integral The Lebesgue Integral Brent Nelson In these notes we give an introduction to the Lebesgue integral, assuming only a knowledge of metric spaces and the iemann integral. For more details see [1, Chapters

More information

(U) =, if 0 U, 1 U, (U) = X, if 0 U, and 1 U. (U) = E, if 0 U, but 1 U. (U) = X \ E if 0 U, but 1 U. n=1 A n, then A M.

(U) =, if 0 U, 1 U, (U) = X, if 0 U, and 1 U. (U) = E, if 0 U, but 1 U. (U) = X \ E if 0 U, but 1 U. n=1 A n, then A M. 1. Abstract Integration The main reference for this section is Rudin s Real and Complex Analysis. The purpose of developing an abstract theory of integration is to emphasize the difference between the

More information

L p Spaces and Convexity

L p Spaces and Convexity L p Spaces and Convexity These notes largely follow the treatments in Royden, Real Analysis, and Rudin, Real & Complex Analysis. 1. Convex functions Let I R be an interval. For I open, we say a function

More information

Measures. 1 Introduction. These preliminary lecture notes are partly based on textbooks by Athreya and Lahiri, Capinski and Kopp, and Folland.

Measures. 1 Introduction. These preliminary lecture notes are partly based on textbooks by Athreya and Lahiri, Capinski and Kopp, and Folland. Measures These preliminary lecture notes are partly based on textbooks by Athreya and Lahiri, Capinski and Kopp, and Folland. 1 Introduction Our motivation for studying measure theory is to lay a foundation

More information

If Y and Y 0 satisfy (1-2), then Y = Y 0 a.s.

If Y and Y 0 satisfy (1-2), then Y = Y 0 a.s. 20 6. CONDITIONAL EXPECTATION Having discussed at length the limit theory for sums of independent random variables we will now move on to deal with dependent random variables. An important tool in this

More information

MATH MEASURE THEORY AND FOURIER ANALYSIS. Contents

MATH MEASURE THEORY AND FOURIER ANALYSIS. Contents MATH 3969 - MEASURE THEORY AND FOURIER ANALYSIS ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Measure Theory 2 1.1. Properties of Measures 3 1.2. Constructing σ-algebras and measures 3 1.3. Properties of the Lebesgue measure

More information

Notions such as convergent sequence and Cauchy sequence make sense for any metric space. Convergent Sequences are Cauchy

Notions such as convergent sequence and Cauchy sequence make sense for any metric space. Convergent Sequences are Cauchy Banach Spaces These notes provide an introduction to Banach spaces, which are complete normed vector spaces. For the purposes of these notes, all vector spaces are assumed to be over the real numbers.

More information

Contents. An example 5. Mathematical Preliminaries 13. Dynamic programming under certainty 29. Numerical methods 41. Some applications 57

Contents. An example 5. Mathematical Preliminaries 13. Dynamic programming under certainty 29. Numerical methods 41. Some applications 57 T H O M A S D E M U Y N C K DY N A M I C O P T I M I Z AT I O N Contents An example 5 Mathematical Preliminaries 13 Dynamic programming under certainty 29 Numerical methods 41 Some applications 57 Stochastic

More information

Real Analysis Notes. Thomas Goller

Real Analysis Notes. Thomas Goller Real Analysis Notes Thomas Goller September 4, 2011 Contents 1 Abstract Measure Spaces 2 1.1 Basic Definitions........................... 2 1.2 Measurable Functions........................ 2 1.3 Integration..............................

More information

2 (Bonus). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure?

2 (Bonus). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure? MA 645-4A (Real Analysis), Dr. Chernov Homework assignment 1 (Due 9/5). Prove that every countable set A is measurable and µ(a) = 0. 2 (Bonus). Let A consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is

More information

n [ F (b j ) F (a j ) ], n j=1(a j, b j ] E (4.1)

n [ F (b j ) F (a j ) ], n j=1(a j, b j ] E (4.1) 1.4. CONSTRUCTION OF LEBESGUE-STIELTJES MEASURES In this section we shall put to use the Carathéodory-Hahn theory, in order to construct measures with certain desirable properties first on the real line

More information

Physics 129a Measure Theory Frank Porter

Physics 129a Measure Theory Frank Porter Physics 129a Measure Theory 071126 Frank Porter 1 Introduction The rigorous mathematical underpinning of much of what we have discussed, such as the construction of a proper Hilbert space of functions,

More information

Reminder Notes for the Course on Measures on Topological Spaces

Reminder Notes for the Course on Measures on Topological Spaces Reminder Notes for the Course on Measures on Topological Spaces T. C. Dorlas Dublin Institute for Advanced Studies School of Theoretical Physics 10 Burlington Road, Dublin 4, Ireland. Email: dorlas@stp.dias.ie

More information

Compendium and Solutions to exercises TMA4225 Foundation of analysis

Compendium and Solutions to exercises TMA4225 Foundation of analysis Compendium and Solutions to exercises TMA4225 Foundation of analysis Ruben Spaans December 6, 2010 1 Introduction This compendium contains a lexicon over definitions and exercises with solutions. Throughout

More information

Notes on Measure, Probability and Stochastic Processes. João Lopes Dias

Notes on Measure, Probability and Stochastic Processes. João Lopes Dias Notes on Measure, Probability and Stochastic Processes João Lopes Dias Departamento de Matemática, ISEG, Universidade de Lisboa, Rua do Quelhas 6, 1200-781 Lisboa, Portugal E-mail address: jldias@iseg.ulisboa.pt

More information

2 Lebesgue integration

2 Lebesgue integration 2 Lebesgue integration 1. Let (, A, µ) be a measure space. We will always assume that µ is complete, otherwise we first take its completion. The example to have in mind is the Lebesgue measure on R n,

More information

Math212a1413 The Lebesgue integral.

Math212a1413 The Lebesgue integral. Math212a1413 The Lebesgue integral. October 28, 2014 Simple functions. In what follows, (X, F, m) is a space with a σ-field of sets, and m a measure on F. The purpose of today s lecture is to develop the

More information

7 Convergence in R d and in Metric Spaces

7 Convergence in R d and in Metric Spaces STA 711: Probability & Measure Theory Robert L. Wolpert 7 Convergence in R d and in Metric Spaces A sequence of elements a n of R d converges to a limit a if and only if, for each ǫ > 0, the sequence a

More information

Integration on Measure Spaces

Integration on Measure Spaces Chapter 3 Integration on Measure Spaces In this chapter we introduce the general notion of a measure on a space X, define the class of measurable functions, and define the integral, first on a class of

More information

Chapter 8. General Countably Additive Set Functions. 8.1 Hahn Decomposition Theorem

Chapter 8. General Countably Additive Set Functions. 8.1 Hahn Decomposition Theorem Chapter 8 General Countably dditive Set Functions In Theorem 5.2.2 the reader saw that if f : X R is integrable on the measure space (X,, µ) then we can define a countably additive set function ν on by

More information

MAT 570 REAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES. Contents. 1. Sets Functions Countability Axiom of choice Equivalence relations 9

MAT 570 REAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES. Contents. 1. Sets Functions Countability Axiom of choice Equivalence relations 9 MAT 570 REAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES PROFESSOR: JOHN QUIGG SEMESTER: FALL 204 Contents. Sets 2 2. Functions 5 3. Countability 7 4. Axiom of choice 8 5. Equivalence relations 9 6. Real numbers 9 7. Extended

More information

Probability and Measure

Probability and Measure Part II Year 2018 2017 2016 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2018 84 Paper 4, Section II 26J Let (X, A) be a measurable space. Let T : X X be a measurable map, and µ a probability

More information

l(y j ) = 0 for all y j (1)

l(y j ) = 0 for all y j (1) Problem 1. The closed linear span of a subset {y j } of a normed vector space is defined as the intersection of all closed subspaces containing all y j and thus the smallest such subspace. 1 Show that

More information

MATH 202B - Problem Set 5

MATH 202B - Problem Set 5 MATH 202B - Problem Set 5 Walid Krichene (23265217) March 6, 2013 (5.1) Show that there exists a continuous function F : [0, 1] R which is monotonic on no interval of positive length. proof We know there

More information

Three hours THE UNIVERSITY OF MANCHESTER. 24th January

Three hours THE UNIVERSITY OF MANCHESTER. 24th January Three hours MATH41011 THE UNIVERSITY OF MANCHESTER FOURIER ANALYSIS AND LEBESGUE INTEGRATION 24th January 2013 9.45 12.45 Answer ALL SIX questions in Section A (25 marks in total). Answer THREE of the

More information

Lecture 5: The Bellman Equation

Lecture 5: The Bellman Equation Lecture 5: The Bellman Equation Florian Scheuer 1 Plan Prove properties of the Bellman equation (In particular, existence and uniqueness of solution) Use this to prove properties of the solution Think

More information

Economics 204 Summer/Fall 2011 Lecture 5 Friday July 29, 2011

Economics 204 Summer/Fall 2011 Lecture 5 Friday July 29, 2011 Economics 204 Summer/Fall 2011 Lecture 5 Friday July 29, 2011 Section 2.6 (cont.) Properties of Real Functions Here we first study properties of functions from R to R, making use of the additional structure

More information

Examples of Dual Spaces from Measure Theory

Examples of Dual Spaces from Measure Theory Chapter 9 Examples of Dual Spaces from Measure Theory We have seen that L (, A, µ) is a Banach space for any measure space (, A, µ). We will extend that concept in the following section to identify an

More information

Measures and Measure Spaces

Measures and Measure Spaces Chapter 2 Measures and Measure Spaces In summarizing the flaws of the Riemann integral we can focus on two main points: 1) Many nice functions are not Riemann integrable. 2) The Riemann integral does not

More information

Measures. Chapter Some prerequisites. 1.2 Introduction

Measures. Chapter Some prerequisites. 1.2 Introduction Lecture notes Course Analysis for PhD students Uppsala University, Spring 2018 Rostyslav Kozhan Chapter 1 Measures 1.1 Some prerequisites I will follow closely the textbook Real analysis: Modern Techniques

More information

Analysis Finite and Infinite Sets The Real Numbers The Cantor Set

Analysis Finite and Infinite Sets The Real Numbers The Cantor Set Analysis Finite and Infinite Sets Definition. An initial segment is {n N n n 0 }. Definition. A finite set can be put into one-to-one correspondence with an initial segment. The empty set is also considered

More information

1 Topology Definition of a topology Basis (Base) of a topology The subspace topology & the product topology on X Y 3

1 Topology Definition of a topology Basis (Base) of a topology The subspace topology & the product topology on X Y 3 Index Page 1 Topology 2 1.1 Definition of a topology 2 1.2 Basis (Base) of a topology 2 1.3 The subspace topology & the product topology on X Y 3 1.4 Basic topology concepts: limit points, closed sets,

More information

i. v = 0 if and only if v 0. iii. v + w v + w. (This is the Triangle Inequality.)

i. v = 0 if and only if v 0. iii. v + w v + w. (This is the Triangle Inequality.) Definition 5.5.1. A (real) normed vector space is a real vector space V, equipped with a function called a norm, denoted by, provided that for all v and w in V and for all α R the real number v 0, and

More information

5 Measure theory II. (or. lim. Prove the proposition. 5. For fixed F A and φ M define the restriction of φ on F by writing.

5 Measure theory II. (or. lim. Prove the proposition. 5. For fixed F A and φ M define the restriction of φ on F by writing. 5 Measure theory II 1. Charges (signed measures). Let (Ω, A) be a σ -algebra. A map φ: A R is called a charge, (or signed measure or σ -additive set function) if φ = φ(a j ) (5.1) A j for any disjoint

More information

REAL AND COMPLEX ANALYSIS

REAL AND COMPLEX ANALYSIS REAL AND COMPLE ANALYSIS Third Edition Walter Rudin Professor of Mathematics University of Wisconsin, Madison Version 1.1 No rights reserved. Any part of this work can be reproduced or transmitted in any

More information

( f ^ M _ M 0 )dµ (5.1)

( f ^ M _ M 0 )dµ (5.1) 47 5. LEBESGUE INTEGRAL: GENERAL CASE Although the Lebesgue integral defined in the previous chapter is in many ways much better behaved than the Riemann integral, it shares its restriction to bounded

More information

Problem Set 2: Solutions Math 201A: Fall 2016

Problem Set 2: Solutions Math 201A: Fall 2016 Problem Set 2: s Math 201A: Fall 2016 Problem 1. (a) Prove that a closed subset of a complete metric space is complete. (b) Prove that a closed subset of a compact metric space is compact. (c) Prove that

More information

Construction of a general measure structure

Construction of a general measure structure Chapter 4 Construction of a general measure structure We turn to the development of general measure theory. The ingredients are a set describing the universe of points, a class of measurable subsets along

More information

02. Measure and integral. 1. Borel-measurable functions and pointwise limits

02. Measure and integral. 1. Borel-measurable functions and pointwise limits (October 3, 2017) 02. Measure and integral Paul Garrett garrett@math.umn.edu http://www.math.umn.edu/ garrett/ [This document is http://www.math.umn.edu/ garrett/m/real/notes 2017-18/02 measure and integral.pdf]

More information

CHAPTER I THE RIESZ REPRESENTATION THEOREM

CHAPTER I THE RIESZ REPRESENTATION THEOREM CHAPTER I THE RIESZ REPRESENTATION THEOREM We begin our study by identifying certain special kinds of linear functionals on certain special vector spaces of functions. We describe these linear functionals

More information

3 Integration and Expectation

3 Integration and Expectation 3 Integration and Expectation 3.1 Construction of the Lebesgue Integral Let (, F, µ) be a measure space (not necessarily a probability space). Our objective will be to define the Lebesgue integral R fdµ

More information

CHAPTER 6. Differentiation

CHAPTER 6. Differentiation CHPTER 6 Differentiation The generalization from elementary calculus of differentiation in measure theory is less obvious than that of integration, and the methods of treating it are somewhat involved.

More information

1.4 Outer measures 10 CHAPTER 1. MEASURE

1.4 Outer measures 10 CHAPTER 1. MEASURE 10 CHAPTER 1. MEASURE 1.3.6. ( Almost everywhere and null sets If (X, A, µ is a measure space, then a set in A is called a null set (or µ-null if its measure is 0. Clearly a countable union of null sets

More information

1/12/05: sec 3.1 and my article: How good is the Lebesgue measure?, Math. Intelligencer 11(2) (1989),

1/12/05: sec 3.1 and my article: How good is the Lebesgue measure?, Math. Intelligencer 11(2) (1989), Real Analysis 2, Math 651, Spring 2005 April 26, 2005 1 Real Analysis 2, Math 651, Spring 2005 Krzysztof Chris Ciesielski 1/12/05: sec 3.1 and my article: How good is the Lebesgue measure?, Math. Intelligencer

More information

Review of measure theory

Review of measure theory 209: Honors nalysis in R n Review of measure theory 1 Outer measure, measure, measurable sets Definition 1 Let X be a set. nonempty family R of subsets of X is a ring if, B R B R and, B R B R hold. bove,

More information

Measure Theory. John K. Hunter. Department of Mathematics, University of California at Davis

Measure Theory. John K. Hunter. Department of Mathematics, University of California at Davis Measure Theory John K. Hunter Department of Mathematics, University of California at Davis Abstract. These are some brief notes on measure theory, concentrating on Lebesgue measure on R n. Some missing

More information

Chapter 4. Measure Theory. 1. Measure Spaces

Chapter 4. Measure Theory. 1. Measure Spaces Chapter 4. Measure Theory 1. Measure Spaces Let X be a nonempty set. A collection S of subsets of X is said to be an algebra on X if S has the following properties: 1. X S; 2. if A S, then A c S; 3. if

More information

Homework 11. Solutions

Homework 11. Solutions Homework 11. Solutions Problem 2.3.2. Let f n : R R be 1/n times the characteristic function of the interval (0, n). Show that f n 0 uniformly and f n µ L = 1. Why isn t it a counterexample to the Lebesgue

More information

3 (Due ). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure?

3 (Due ). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure? MA 645-4A (Real Analysis), Dr. Chernov Homework assignment 1 (Due ). Show that the open disk x 2 + y 2 < 1 is a countable union of planar elementary sets. Show that the closed disk x 2 + y 2 1 is a countable

More information

Measure Theory and Integration

Measure Theory and Integration CHAPTER 1 Measure Theory and Integration One fundamental result of measure theory which we will encounter inthischapteristhatnoteverysetcanbemeasured. Morespecifically, if we wish to define the measure,

More information

Summary of Real Analysis by Royden

Summary of Real Analysis by Royden Summary of Real Analysis by Royden Dan Hathaway May 2010 This document is a summary of the theorems and definitions and theorems from Part 1 of the book Real Analysis by Royden. In some areas, such as

More information

1 Measurable Functions

1 Measurable Functions 36-752 Advanced Probability Overview Spring 2018 2. Measurable Functions, Random Variables, and Integration Instructor: Alessandro Rinaldo Associated reading: Sec 1.5 of Ash and Doléans-Dade; Sec 1.3 and

More information

INTRODUCTION TO MEASURE THEORY AND LEBESGUE INTEGRATION

INTRODUCTION TO MEASURE THEORY AND LEBESGUE INTEGRATION 1 INTRODUCTION TO MEASURE THEORY AND LEBESGUE INTEGRATION Eduard EMELYANOV Ankara TURKEY 2007 2 FOREWORD This book grew out of a one-semester course for graduate students that the author have taught at

More information

2 Measure Theory. 2.1 Measures

2 Measure Theory. 2.1 Measures 2 Measure Theory 2.1 Measures A lot of this exposition is motivated by Folland s wonderful text, Real Analysis: Modern Techniques and Their Applications. Perhaps the most ubiquitous measure in our lives

More information

Stochastic Dynamic Programming. Jesus Fernandez-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Stochastic Dynamic Programming. Jesus Fernandez-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania Stochastic Dynamic Programming Jesus Fernande-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania 1 Introducing Uncertainty in Dynamic Programming Stochastic dynamic programming presents a very exible framework to handle

More information

Measure Theory, 2009

Measure Theory, 2009 Measure Theory, 2009 Contents 1 Notational issues 2 2 The concept of a measure 4 3 The general notion of integration and measurable function 15 4 Convergence theorems 23 5 Radon-Nikodym and Conditional

More information

Lebesgue Measure on R n

Lebesgue Measure on R n CHAPTER 2 Lebesgue Measure on R n Our goal is to construct a notion of the volume, or Lebesgue measure, of rather general subsets of R n that reduces to the usual volume of elementary geometrical sets

More information

g 2 (x) (1/3)M 1 = (1/3)(2/3)M.

g 2 (x) (1/3)M 1 = (1/3)(2/3)M. COMPACTNESS If C R n is closed and bounded, then by B-W it is sequentially compact: any sequence of points in C has a subsequence converging to a point in C Conversely, any sequentially compact C R n is

More information

MATH5011 Real Analysis I. Exercise 1 Suggested Solution

MATH5011 Real Analysis I. Exercise 1 Suggested Solution MATH5011 Real Analysis I Exercise 1 Suggested Solution Notations in the notes are used. (1) Show that every open set in R can be written as a countable union of mutually disjoint open intervals. Hint:

More information

II - REAL ANALYSIS. This property gives us a way to extend the notion of content to finite unions of rectangles: we define

II - REAL ANALYSIS. This property gives us a way to extend the notion of content to finite unions of rectangles: we define 1 Measures 1.1 Jordan content in R N II - REAL ANALYSIS Let I be an interval in R. Then its 1-content is defined as c 1 (I) := b a if I is bounded with endpoints a, b. If I is unbounded, we define c 1

More information

THEOREMS, ETC., FOR MATH 516

THEOREMS, ETC., FOR MATH 516 THEOREMS, ETC., FOR MATH 516 Results labeled Theorem Ea.b.c (or Proposition Ea.b.c, etc.) refer to Theorem c from section a.b of Evans book (Partial Differential Equations). Proposition 1 (=Proposition

More information

REAL ANALYSIS I Spring 2016 Product Measures

REAL ANALYSIS I Spring 2016 Product Measures REAL ANALSIS I Spring 216 Product Measures We assume that (, M, µ), (, N, ν) are σ- finite measure spaces. We want to provide the Cartesian product with a measure space structure in which all sets of the

More information

MEASURE AND INTEGRATION. Dietmar A. Salamon ETH Zürich

MEASURE AND INTEGRATION. Dietmar A. Salamon ETH Zürich MEASURE AND INTEGRATION Dietmar A. Salamon ETH Zürich 9 September 2016 ii Preface This book is based on notes for the lecture course Measure and Integration held at ETH Zürich in the spring semester 2014.

More information

3 Measurable Functions

3 Measurable Functions 3 Measurable Functions Notation A pair (X, F) where F is a σ-field of subsets of X is a measurable space. If µ is a measure on F then (X, F, µ) is a measure space. If µ(x) < then (X, F, µ) is a probability

More information

Topological properties of Z p and Q p and Euclidean models

Topological properties of Z p and Q p and Euclidean models Topological properties of Z p and Q p and Euclidean models Samuel Trautwein, Esther Röder, Giorgio Barozzi November 3, 20 Topology of Q p vs Topology of R Both R and Q p are normed fields and complete

More information

Lecture Notes Introduction to Ergodic Theory

Lecture Notes Introduction to Ergodic Theory Lecture Notes Introduction to Ergodic Theory Tiago Pereira Department of Mathematics Imperial College London Our course consists of five introductory lectures on probabilistic aspects of dynamical systems,

More information

M17 MAT25-21 HOMEWORK 6

M17 MAT25-21 HOMEWORK 6 M17 MAT25-21 HOMEWORK 6 DUE 10:00AM WEDNESDAY SEPTEMBER 13TH 1. To Hand In Double Series. The exercises in this section will guide you to complete the proof of the following theorem: Theorem 1: Absolute

More information

Lebesgue measure on R is just one of many important measures in mathematics. In these notes we introduce the general framework for measures.

Lebesgue measure on R is just one of many important measures in mathematics. In these notes we introduce the general framework for measures. Measures In General Lebesgue measure on R is just one of many important measures in mathematics. In these notes we introduce the general framework for measures. Definition: σ-algebra Let X be a set. A

More information

I. ANALYSIS; PROBABILITY

I. ANALYSIS; PROBABILITY ma414l1.tex Lecture 1. 12.1.2012 I. NLYSIS; PROBBILITY 1. Lebesgue Measure and Integral We recall Lebesgue measure (M411 Probability and Measure) λ: defined on intervals (a, b] by λ((a, b]) := b a (so

More information

18.175: Lecture 2 Extension theorems, random variables, distributions

18.175: Lecture 2 Extension theorems, random variables, distributions 18.175: Lecture 2 Extension theorems, random variables, distributions Scott Sheffield MIT Outline Extension theorems Characterizing measures on R d Random variables Outline Extension theorems Characterizing

More information

CHAPTER II THE HAHN-BANACH EXTENSION THEOREMS AND EXISTENCE OF LINEAR FUNCTIONALS

CHAPTER II THE HAHN-BANACH EXTENSION THEOREMS AND EXISTENCE OF LINEAR FUNCTIONALS CHAPTER II THE HAHN-BANACH EXTENSION THEOREMS AND EXISTENCE OF LINEAR FUNCTIONALS In this chapter we deal with the problem of extending a linear functional on a subspace Y to a linear functional on the

More information

4th Preparation Sheet - Solutions

4th Preparation Sheet - Solutions Prof. Dr. Rainer Dahlhaus Probability Theory Summer term 017 4th Preparation Sheet - Solutions Remark: Throughout the exercise sheet we use the two equivalent definitions of separability of a metric space

More information

Lebesgue-Radon-Nikodym Theorem

Lebesgue-Radon-Nikodym Theorem Lebesgue-Radon-Nikodym Theorem Matt Rosenzweig 1 Lebesgue-Radon-Nikodym Theorem In what follows, (, A) will denote a measurable space. We begin with a review of signed measures. 1.1 Signed Measures Definition

More information

Methods of Applied Mathematics

Methods of Applied Mathematics Methods of Applied Mathematics Todd Arbogast and Jerry L. Bona Department of Mathematics, and Institute for Computational Engineering and Sciences The University of Texas at Austin Copyright 1999 2001,

More information

Filters in Analysis and Topology

Filters in Analysis and Topology Filters in Analysis and Topology David MacIver July 1, 2004 Abstract The study of filters is a very natural way to talk about convergence in an arbitrary topological space, and carries over nicely into

More information

The Caratheodory Construction of Measures

The Caratheodory Construction of Measures Chapter 5 The Caratheodory Construction of Measures Recall how our construction of Lebesgue measure in Chapter 2 proceeded from an initial notion of the size of a very restricted class of subsets of R,

More information

Class Notes for MATH 255.

Class Notes for MATH 255. Class Notes for MATH 255. by S. W. Drury Copyright c 2006, by S. W. Drury. Contents 0 LimSup and LimInf Metric Spaces and Analysis in Several Variables 6. Metric Spaces........................... 6.2 Normed

More information

+ 2x sin x. f(b i ) f(a i ) < ɛ. i=1. i=1

+ 2x sin x. f(b i ) f(a i ) < ɛ. i=1. i=1 Appendix To understand weak derivatives and distributional derivatives in the simplest context of functions of a single variable, we describe without proof some results from real analysis (see [7] and

More information

MAT 571 REAL ANALYSIS II LECTURE NOTES. Contents. 2. Product measures Iterated integrals Complete products Differentiation 17

MAT 571 REAL ANALYSIS II LECTURE NOTES. Contents. 2. Product measures Iterated integrals Complete products Differentiation 17 MAT 57 REAL ANALSIS II LECTURE NOTES PROFESSOR: JOHN QUIGG SEMESTER: SPRING 205 Contents. Convergence in measure 2. Product measures 3 3. Iterated integrals 4 4. Complete products 9 5. Signed measures

More information

(1) Consider the space S consisting of all continuous real-valued functions on the closed interval [0, 1]. For f, g S, define

(1) Consider the space S consisting of all continuous real-valued functions on the closed interval [0, 1]. For f, g S, define Homework, Real Analysis I, Fall, 2010. (1) Consider the space S consisting of all continuous real-valued functions on the closed interval [0, 1]. For f, g S, define ρ(f, g) = 1 0 f(x) g(x) dx. Show that

More information

Basic Deterministic Dynamic Programming

Basic Deterministic Dynamic Programming Basic Deterministic Dynamic Programming Timothy Kam School of Economics & CAMA Australian National University ECON8022, This version March 17, 2008 Motivation What do we do? Outline Deterministic IHDP

More information

Metric Spaces and Topology

Metric Spaces and Topology Chapter 2 Metric Spaces and Topology From an engineering perspective, the most important way to construct a topology on a set is to define the topology in terms of a metric on the set. This approach underlies

More information

The Heine-Borel and Arzela-Ascoli Theorems

The Heine-Borel and Arzela-Ascoli Theorems The Heine-Borel and Arzela-Ascoli Theorems David Jekel October 29, 2016 This paper explains two important results about compactness, the Heine- Borel theorem and the Arzela-Ascoli theorem. We prove them

More information

Annalee Gomm Math 714: Assignment #2

Annalee Gomm Math 714: Assignment #2 Annalee Gomm Math 714: Assignment #2 3.32. Verify that if A M, λ(a = 0, and B A, then B M and λ(b = 0. Suppose that A M with λ(a = 0, and let B be any subset of A. By the nonnegativity and monotonicity

More information

van Rooij, Schikhof: A Second Course on Real Functions

van Rooij, Schikhof: A Second Course on Real Functions vanrooijschikhof.tex April 25, 2018 van Rooij, Schikhof: A Second Course on Real Functions Notes from [vrs]. Introduction A monotone function is Riemann integrable. A continuous function is Riemann integrable.

More information

Chapter 1. Measure Spaces. 1.1 Algebras and σ algebras of sets Notation and preliminaries

Chapter 1. Measure Spaces. 1.1 Algebras and σ algebras of sets Notation and preliminaries Chapter 1 Measure Spaces 1.1 Algebras and σ algebras of sets 1.1.1 Notation and preliminaries We shall denote by X a nonempty set, by P(X) the set of all parts (i.e., subsets) of X, and by the empty set.

More information