DIVERSITY AND RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN EQUITY MARKETS

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "DIVERSITY AND RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN EQUITY MARKETS"

Transcription

1 DIVERSITY AND RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN EQUITY MARKETS ROBERT FERNHOLZ INTECH, One Palmer Square Princeton, NJ 8542 IOANNIS KARATZAS Departments of Mathematics and Statistics Columbia University, New York, NY 27 CONSTANTINOS KARDARAS Department of Statistics, Columbia University New York, NY 27 January 2, 24 Abstract An equity market is called diverse if no single stock is ever allowed to dominate the entire market in terms of relative capitalization. In the context of the standard Itô-process model initiated by Samuelson 965 we formulate this property and the allied, successively weaker notions of weak diversity and asymptotic weak diversity in precise terms. We show that diversity is possible to achieve, but delicate. Several examples are provided which illustrate these notions and show that weaklydiverse markets contain relative arbitrage opportunities: it is possible to outperform or underperform such markets over any given time-horizon. The existence of this type of relative arbitrage does not interfere with the development of contigent claim valuation, and has consequences for the pricing of long-term warrants and for put-call parity. Several open questions are suggested for further study. Key Words and Phrases: Financial markets, portfolios, diversity, relative arbitrage, order statistics, local times, stochastic differential equations, strict local martingales. AMS 2 Subject Classifications: Primary 6H, 9B28; secondary 6J55. JEL Subject Classification: G.

2 Introduction The descriptive notion of diversity for equity markets was introduced and studied recently by Fernholz 999, 22. It postulates, roughly, that no individual stock ever be allowed to dominate the entire market in terms of relative capitalization. In the context of the standard Itô-process, geometric-brownian-motion-based model introduced by Samuelson 965, it is shown in Fernholz 22 how to generate fully-invested, all-long portfolios that outperform a diverse market over sufficiently long time-horizons and how to exploit this property for passive asset management. The present paper complements this effort by showing that diversity is indeed possible under appropriate, though rather delicate, conditions. These mandate, roughly, that the largest stock have strongly negative rate of growth, resulting in a sufficiently strong drift away from an appropriate boundary, and that all other stocks have sufficiently high rates of growth. We also show that in diverse markets, relative arbitrage opportunities exist over arbitrary time-horizons: it is possible to construct two portfolios so that one outperforms the other with probability one. In particular, no equivalent martingale measure can exist for such markets. Section 2 sets up the model and the notation used throughout the paper. Section 3 introduces the market portfolio, in terms of which the notion of diversity and the allied, successively weaker notions of weak diversity and asymptotic weak diversity are defined in section 4. The dynamics for the ranked market weights are studied in section 5, and in terms of them sufficient conditions for diversity are established in section 6. These are illustrated by means of several examples, including models that are weakly diverse but fail to be diverse. Section 7 contains a model for which weak diversity fails on finite time-horizons but prevails as the time-horizon becomes infinite, in the asymptotic sense of section 4. We study in a diversity-weighted portfolio that outperforms significantly any weakly-diverse market over sufficiently long time-horizons, leading to arbitrage relative to the market. In section 8 we introduce the mirror portfolios and study their properties; these are then used to show that, in the context of a weakly-diverse market, it is possible to outperform or underperform the market-portfolio over arbitrary time-horizons. Finally, in section 9 we study diverse market models that contain a risk-free instrument and allow for general trading strategies with short-selling and borrowing. Such models admit no equivalent martingale measure, no arbitrage opportunities in the classical sense of non-negative wealth with probability one and positive wealth with positive probability, but do admit so-called free lunches with vanishing risk or free snacks. Nevertheless, familiar techniques for hedging contingent claims can be carried out in their context. This has ramifications for put-call parity and for the hedging prices of call-options over exceedingly 2

3 long time-horizons: these are shown to approach zero rather than the initial stock-price as they do when an equivalent martingale measure exists for every finite time-horizon. 2 The Model We shall place ourselves in the standard Itô-process model for a financial market which goes back to Samuelson 965. This model contains n risky assets stocks, with values-per-share X i driven by m independent Brownian motions as follows: [ ] m dx i t = X i t b i t dt + σ iν t dw ν t, i =,..., n 2. ν= for t <, with m n. Here X i t stands for the value of the i th asset at time t and W = W,..., W m is a vector of m independent standard Brownian motions, the factors of the model. All processes are defined on a probability space Ω, F, P and are adapted to a given filtration F = {Ft} t< with F = {, Ω} mod. P ; this satisfies the usual conditions right-continuity, augmentation by P negligible sets and may be strictly larger than the one generated by the driving m dimensional Brownian motion W. The vector-valued process b = b,..., b n of rates of return, and the n m matrix-valued process σ = {σ iν } i n, ν m of volatilities, are assumed to be F progressively measurable and to satisfy almost surely a.s. the conditions bt 2 dt <, T,, 2.2 ε ξ 2 ξ σtσ tξ M ξ 2, t [, and ξ IR n, 2.3 for some real constants M > ε >. We may re-write 2. in the equivalent form d log X i t m = γ i t dt + σ iν t dw ν t, i =,..., n. 2.4 ν= Here we have denoted by γ i t := b i t 2 a iit, i =,..., n the individual stock growthrates, and by a = {a ij } i,j n the n n matrix of variation-covariation rate processes a ij t := m σ iν tσ jν t = σtσ t = d ij ν= dt log X i, log X j t. 2.5 Placed in the above market-model M of , an economic agent can decide what proportion π i t of his wealth to invest in each of the stocks i =,..., n at every time t [,. The resulting portfolio process π = π,..., π n takes values in the set { n + = π,..., π n IR } n π,..., π n and π i = 3

4 i.e., there is no money-market or hoarding of wealth and is F progressively measurable. Starting with initial capital z >, the value process Z π of the portfolio π satisfies dz π t Z π t = π i t dx it X i t by analogy with equation 2., where m = b π t dt + σν π t dw ν t, Z π = z 2.6 ν= b π t := π i tb i t, σν π t := π i tσ iν t 2.7 for ν =,..., m, are respectively the rate-of-return and the volatility coëfficients of the portfolio. As in 2.4 we may write the solution of the equation 2.6 in the form d log Z π t m = γ π t dt + σν π t dw ν t, with ν= γ π t := π i tγ i t+γ π t, γ π t := π i ta ii t π i ta ij tπ j t j= denoting, respectively, the growth-rate and the excess-growth-rate of the portfolio π. In order to set the stage for notions and developments that follow, let us introduce the order-statistics notation for the weights max π it =: π t π 2 t... π n t π n t =: min π it 2.9 i n i n of a portfolio π, ranked at time t from the largest π t to the smallest π n t. We introduce two notions of relative arbitrage. Given any two portfolios π, ρ with initial capital Z π = Z ρ = z >, we shall say that π represents relative to ρ an arbitrage opportunity over the fixed, finite time-horizon [, T ] if we have P [Z π T Z ρ T ] = and P [Z π T > Z ρ T ] > ; 2. a superior long-term growth opportunity, if L π,ρ := lim T T log Z π T Z ρ T > holds a.s The Market Portfolio Suppose we normalize so that each stock has one share outstanding; then the stock-value X i t can be interpreted as the capitalization of the i th company at time t, and the quantities Zt := X t X n t and µ i t := X it Zt 4, i =,..., n 3.

5 as the total capitalization of the market and the relative capitalizations of the individual companies, respectively. Since < µ i t <, i =,..., n and n µ i t =, we may think of the vector process µ = µ,..., µ as a portfolio rule that invests a proportion µ i t of current wealth in the i th asset, at all times t [,. Then the resulting value-process Z µ satisfies dz µ t Z µ t = µ i t dx it X i t = dx i t Zt = dzt Zt, as postulated by 2.6 and 3.; and if we start with initial capital Z µ = Z we get Z µ Z, the total market capitalization. In other words, investing according to the portfolio process µ amounts to ownership of the entire market in proportion to the original investment. For this reason we call µ the market portfolio for M. 4 Notions of Diversity The notion of diversity for a financial market corresponds to the intuitive and descriprive idea that no single company should be allowed to dominate the entire market in terms of relative capitalization. To make this precise, let us say that the model M of is diverse on the time-horizon [, T ], if there exists a number δ, such that the quantities of 3. satisfy almost surely µ t < δ, t T 4. in the notation of 2.9. In a similar vein, we say that M is weakly diverse on the time-horizon [, T ] if for some δ, we have T µ t dt < δ 4.2 almost surely. We say that M is uniformly weakly diverse over [T,, if there exists a δ, such that 4.2 holds a.s. for every T [T,. And M is called asymptotically weakly diverse if, for some δ,, we have almost surely: lim T T µ t dt < δ. 4.3 The first two of these notions were introduced in the paper by Fernholz 999 and are studied in detail in the recent monograph Fernholz 22. In particular, it is shown in Example of this book that if the model M of is weakly diverse, then it contains arbitrage opportunities relative to the market portfolio. 5

6 We provide here another example of such an arbitrage opportunity, in a weakly diverse market and for the so-called diversity-weighted portfolio π p = π p,..., π n p. For some fixed < p <, this is defined in terms of the market portfolio µ of 3., by π p i t := µ i t p nj= µ j t p, i =,..., n. 4.4 Compared to µ, the portfolio π p in 4.4 decreases the proportions held in the largest stocks and increases those placed in the smallest stocks, while preserving the relative rankings of all stocks. The actual performance of this portfolio relative to the S&P5 index over a 22-year period is discussed in detail by Fernholz 22, along with issues of practical implementation in the context of passive asset management. We show in the Appendix that if the model M of is weakly diverse on a finite time-horizon [, T ], then π p outperforms the market portfolio µ : starting with initial capital equal to Z µ, the value Z πp of the portfolio in 4.4 satisfies P [ Z πp T > Z µ T ] =, provided that T T := 2 log n ; 4.5 pεδ and if M is uniformly weakly diverse over [T, then π p is a superior long-term growth opportunity relative to the market, i.e., L πp, µ εδ p/2 a.s. in the notation of 2.. What conditions on the coëfficients b, σ of M are sufficient for guaranteeing diversity, as in 4.? Certainly M cannot be diverse if b,..., b n are bounded uniformly in t, ω, or even if they satisfy a condition of the Novikov type E [ exp { 2 bt 2 dt }] <, T,. 4.6 The reason is that, under the condition 4.6, the Girsanov theorem produces an equivalent probability measure Q under which the processes X,..., X n in 2. become martingales. This proscribes 2., let alone the equation of 4.5, for any T, ; see the Appendix for an argument in a somewhat more general context. We shall see in section 6 that diversity is ensured by a strongly negative rate of growth for the largest stock, resulting in a sufficiently strong repelling drift e.g., a log-pole-type singularity away from an appropriate boundary, and by non-negative growth-rates for all the other stocks. It turns out, however, that such a structure does not prohibit the familiar treatments of option pricing, hedging or portfolio optimization problems in the context of diverse markets; we elaborate on this point in section 9. 6

7 5 The Dynamics of Ranked Market-Weights A simple application of Itô s rule to the equation 2.4 gives d log µ i t = γ i t γ µ t dt + in the notation of 2.7, 2.8, or equivalently dµ i t µ i t = γ i t γ µ t + 2 τ iit µ dt + for i =,..., n. Here, by analogy with 2.5, we have introduced τ π ijt := m σ iν t σ ν µ t dw ν t, i =,..., n 5. ν= m σ iν t σ ν µ t dw ν t 5.2 ν= m σ iν t σν π t σ jν t σν π t = a ij t a π i t a π j t + a ππ t, 5.3 ν= the relative covariance matrix-valued process of an arbitrary portfolio π, and set a π i t := π j ta ij t, a ππ t := j= π i ta ij tπ j t. j= In terms of the quantities of 5.3 we can express the excess rate of growth of 2.8 as γ π t = π i tτ 2 iit π, 5.4 and for arbitrary portfolios π, ρ we have the numéraire-invariance property γ π t = π i tτ ρ 2 iit π i tπ j tτ ρ ijt ; 5.5 j= see Lemmata.3.4 and.3.6 in Fernholz 22. Now let us denote by {p t,..., p t n} the random permutation of {,..., n} for which µ ptkt = µ k t, and p t k < p t k + if µ k t = µ k+ t, 5.6 hold for k =,..., n. This means, roughly, that p t k is the name index of the stock with the k th largest relative capitalization at time t, and that ties are resolved by resorting to the lowest index. Using Itô s rule for convex functions of semimartingales it is shown in Fernholz 2, 22 that the ranked market-weights of 2.9 satisfy the dynamics d log µ k t = γ ptkt γ µ t m dt + σptkνt σ ν µ t dw ν t 5.7 ν= + 2 [dλ k,k+ t dλ k,k t ]. 7

8 Here, for each k =,..., n, the quantity Λ k,k+ t := Λ log µk log µ k+ t is the local time that the non-negative semimartingale log µ k /µ k+ has accumulated at the origin by calendar time t ; and we set Λ log µ log µ and Λ log µn log µ n+. On the event {µ t > /2} we have µ 2 t < /2, thus {µ t>/2} dλ,2 t =. Therefore, with k = the equation 5.7 reads d log µ t = γ t γ µ t dt + 2 {µ t /2} dλ,2 t + τ µ t dbt 5.8 where B is standard Brownian motion and γ k t := γ ptkt, τ µ kk t := τ µ iit i=ptk Remark: For a portfolio π the conditions of 2.3 lead to the inequalities ε π i t 2 τ π ii t M π i t 2 π i t 5. for the quantities of 5.3, and in the case of the market-portfolio to ε µ t 2 τ µ kkt 2M, t, k =,..., n. 5. On the other hand, we show in the Appendix that the inequalities of 2.3 imply the bounds in the notation of 2.8, 2.9. ε π t γ π t M π t, t < Ensuring Diversity Suppose that we select a number δ, µ where µ = max i n X i /X + + X n, and ask under what conditions we might have µ t < δ, t < 6. almost surely; this condition implies the requirement 4. of diversity on any finite timehorizon [, T ]. To simplify the analysis we shall assume µ 2 < δ and consider { R := inf t µ t }, 2 S := inf { t µ t δ }, 6.2 as well as the stopping times S k := inf { t µ t δ k }, δk = δ + k 6.3 8

9 for all k N sufficiently large. For diversity, it will be enough to guarantee lim k P [S k < R] = ; 6.4 because then P [S < R] lim k P [S k < R] =, and this leads to THEOREM: Suppose that on the event { 2 µ t < δ } we have min γ kt γ t + ε 2 k n 2 M δqt γ k t γ t, k = 2,..., n 6.5, where Qt := log δ µ t. 6.6 Then 6.4, 6. are satisfied. On any given, finite time-horizon [, T ] the market is diverse and Q 2 t dt < holds a.s. 6. Remark: The condition 6.6 holds, in particular, if all stocks but the largest have nonnegative growth rates, whereas the growth rate of the largest stock is negative and exhibits a log-pole-type singularity as the relative capitalization of the largest stock approaches δ : namely, γ t M δqt on the event {/2 µ t < δ}. 6.2 REMARK: In terms of our market-model M of Section 2 we may specify, for instance, a constant volatility matrix σ = {σ iν } i n, ν m with the properties 2.3 and a vector g = g,..., g n of non-negative numbers, and impose 2.4 in the form of a system d log X i t = g i O c i Xt M δ Oi Xt m log δ nj= X i X t j t dt + σ iν dw ν t 6.7 ν= of stochastic differential equations for the vector of stock-capitalization processes X = X,..., X n. We are using here the notation O := O i := { } { } x, n x max x j, O n := x, n x n > max x j, 2 j n j n { x, n x i > max x j, x i j i } max x j, for i = 2,..., n i+ j n in order to keep track of the name of the stock with the largest capitalization in accordance with the convention of 5.6: Xt O i p t = i. With this specification all stocks but the largest behave like geometric Brownian motions with growth rates g i as long as i p t, and variances m ν= σiν 2, whereas the log-capitalization of the largest stock is subjected to a log-pole-type singularity in its drift, away from an appropriate rightboundary. Standard theory see Veretennikov 98 guarantees that the system of 6.7 9

10 has a pathwise unique, strong solution X on each interval [, S k ], for all k N sufficiently large, and thus also on [, S = [, by the Theorem. The equations 6.7 prescribe rates b i t = 2 a ii + g i O c i Xt M δ Oi Xt log δ nj= X i X t j t, i =,, n for the model of 2., 2.5. From the last assertion of Theorem 6. these rates satisfy n b it 2 dt < a.s., which is the requirement 2.2. Proof of Theorem 6.: On the event { µ 2 t < δ } under consideration the conditions of 6.5 and 6.6 lead to γ µ t γ t = µ k tγ k t γ t + γ µ t 6.8 = k= k=2 µ k tγ k t µ t γ t + γ µ t µ t min γ kt γ t + ε 2 k n 2 µ t [ δ min γ kt γ t + ε ] M 2 k n 2 Qt, almost surely, with the help of 5.4, 5.2 and 6.. For the process Q of 6.6 we have from Itô s rule and 5.8 the semimartingale decomposition dlog Qt = γ µ t γ t τ µ t dt Qt 2Qt τ µ t dbt + {µ t /2} dλ,2 t ; Qt Qt 6.9 in conjunction with 6.8 and the second inequality in 5., this gives for all integers l and k large enough: log Ql R S k Q l R Sk l R Sk 2M τ µ t dt 2Q 2 t l T Sk τ µ t dbt Qt τ µ t dbt, a.s. 6. Qt Now let us take expectations in 6.. On the event {t R S k } we have δ δ εδ 2 τ µ t 2M, log Qt log δ k /2 from 5. and , 6.6. These bounds imply that the expectation of the stochastic integral is equal to zero. We are led to the inequalities logq E [ log Q l R S k ] δ log log P [S k < l R] + log log δ k δ P [l R S k ], /2

11 and letting l we obtain δ log log P [S k < R] log log δ k δ µ + log log 2 δ P [R S k ]. 6. This inequality is valid for all k N sufficiently large. Finally, we divide by the number log log δ δ k > in 6., and then let k ; the desired conclusion 6.4 follows. Now from 6.9 the quadratic variation of the semimartingale log Q satisfies εδ 2 T Q 2 t dt < τ µ t dt = log Q T <, Q 2 t a.s. in conjunction with 5. and 6., and the last claim of the theorem follows. The part of this proof leading up to 6. is similar to the argument used to establish the non-attainability of the origin by Brownian motion in dimension n 2; see, for instance, pp.6-62 in Karatzas & Shreve 99. The fact that a pole-type singularity creates opportunities for relative arbitrage is reminiscent of a well-known example due to A.V. Skorohod e.g. Karatzas & Shreve 998, p., or of the work by Delbaen & Schachermayer 995 and by Levental & Skorohod REMARK: The inequality of condition 6.6 can be replaced by min 2 k n γ kt γ t + ε 2 M δ F Qt, 6.2 where F :,, is a continuous function with the property that the associated scale function Ux := x [ y ] exp F zdz dy, < x < 6.3 satisfies U+ =. For instance, Ux = log x when F x = /x as in 6.6 or 6.8. The function U of 6.3 is of class C 2,, so we can apply Itô s rule to the process UQt, t < S as in 6.9. Using the strict increase and strict concavity properties U >, U < of the scale function in 6.3, as well as the equation U +F U =, we can now repeat the steps of the argument that leads to the analogue U log δ δ k P [S k < R] U log δ µ + U log2 δ P [R S k ] of 6., and hence to 6.4 with the help of the requirement U+ =.

12 7 An Asymptotically Weakly Diverse Market Suppose we have a two-stock market model of the form [ dx i t = X i t b i t dt + ] dw i t, X i = x, for i =, driven by the planar Brownian Motion W = W, W 2. Then W := 2 W 2 W is standard Brownian motion, and we have X 2 t = X t expzt, where Zt := µ t = X t X t + X 2 t = + e, µ 2t = Zt t b 2 s b s ds + W t, e Zt, thus µ t = + e Zt 7.3 for t <. Now let us select b and b 2 α Z [, for a suitable real constant α > to be determined below. With these choices the process Z of 7.2 becomes Zt = W t for t and Zt = W α t Zs ds + W t for t <, 7.4 where { W t := W t W, t < } is standard Brownian Motion and independent of Z = W. In other words, the process {Zt, t < } is Ornstein-Uhlenbeck, with gaussian initial distribution N, and gaussian invariant distribution N, /2α ; see Karatzas & Shreve 99, page 358 for the latter assertion. With the choice α = /2 the process Z is stationary, and its ergodic behavior gives lim T T + µ t dt = lim T T for any < δ < E e Z +e = 2 Z π asymptotically weakly diverse. dt = E + e Zt+ + e Z < δ, a.s. e z +e z e z2 /2 dz. Thus, the model M of 7. is However, diversity fails for this model. For any T [, and δ, we have P [ µ T δ ] = P [ ZT ξ ] = 2 δ e u2 /2 du >, ξ := log. 2π ξ δ In fact, weak diversity fails as well. For an arbitrary T, and δ,, select ε/t +e ζ ε, T and ζ > so that δ ; then it is straightforward that the event +e ζ := {inf ε t T Zt ζ} has positive probability P A ε,ζ > and that A ε,ζ T ε µ t dt = T ε dt + e Zt T ε T + e ζ δ 2 holds a.e. on A ε,ζ

13 thus leading to P µ t dt δt >. It can be shown that the model of 7. admits a unique equivalent martingale measure. 7. REMARK: The examples of section 6 can be easily modified to produce a model M which is weakly diverse but not diverse. Indeed, let us start by considering a model M 2δ with constant volatilities σ ij and with rates of return b 2δ i, i =,, n such that P µ t < 2δ, t T = is satisfied for some T, and δ, /4. The idea is to divide the time-horizon [, T ] into the two intervals [, T/2 and [T/2, T ], select η 2δ, /2, and set b i t := b 2δ i t {S t T, S T/2}, where S := inf{ t µ t η } T. 7.5 We claim that the model M, with volatilities σ ij and rates of return given by 7.5, is weakly diverse on [, T ]. To see this, consider two cases: For ω {S T/2} the recipe 7.5 and 4. guarantee µ t, ω < 2δ < δ, t T ; and for ω {S > T/2} we have T µ t, ω dt T /2 η dt + T T/2 dt = η/2 < δ. But for this M the property 4. fails: the event B := {S > T/2} has positive probability, and with A := { max t T µ t δ } we have P A B >. To see this, consider the special case n = 2, σ 2 = σ 2 =, σ = σ 22 = / 2 as in 7., and observe that on the event B = {S > T/2} we have Z W in 7.2 and Consequently, max µ t δ max Zt K := log t T t T P A B = P [ max W t K ; S > T/2 ] P [ t T = P P max T/2 t T max W t W T/2 2K S > T/2 T/2 t T max W t 2K t T/2 P S > T/2 >, δ. δ W t W T/2 2K ; S > T/2 ] P S > T/2 since {W t W T/2; T/2 t < } is a Brownian Motion and independent of FT/2, a σ algebra that contains the event {S > T/2}. 3

14 8 Mirror Portfolios, Short-Horizon Relative Arbitrage We saw in 4.5 that, in weakly diverse markets and over sufficiently long time-horizons, there exist portfolios e.g., the diversity-weighted portfolio π p of 4.4 that represent arbitrage opportunities relative to the market portfolio µ. We shall show in this section that relative arbitrage can be constructed on arbitrary time-horizons; there always exist portfolios that constistently outperform or underperform a weakly diverse market. In order to do this we have to introduce the notion of extended portfolio: a progressively measurable and uniformly bounded process π = π,, π n with values in n = {π,, π n IR n n π i = }. In other words, an extended portfolio can sell one or more stocks short, but certainly not all. By contrast, the portfolios of section 2 are all-long portfolios: they allow no short-selling. Let us fix a baseline portfolio m ; this will typically, though not necessarily, be the market portfolio µ. For any extended portfolio π and any fixed real number p we define the p mirror-image of π with respect to µ by π p := p π + p m. 8. This is clearly an extended portfolio, and a portfolio in the strict all-long sense of section 2 if this is the case for π and < p <. If p = we call π = 2m π the mirror image of π with respect to m. We notice π p q = π pq, π p /p = π. 8.2 Let us recall the notation τ m = { τij m } of 5.3 for the matrix-valued covariance i,j n process of m, define the relative covariance of π with respect to m by τ m ππt := πt mt at πt mt ε πt mt 2, 8.3 and make the elementary observations τ m m, τ m ππ = π τ m π = τ π mm, τ m π p π p = p 2 τ m ππ. 8.4 We shall take m µ from now on. The relative performance of π with respect to µ is given in.2.6 of Fernholz 22 by d log Z π t Z µ t = π i t µ i t d log µ i t + γ π t γ µ t dt

15 Writing this expression for π p in place of π, recalling π p µ = pπ µ from 8., and then subtracting 8.5 multiplied by p, we obtain d log t = p d log Z µ t Z πp Z π t Z µ t But now recall the expressions of 5.5, 8.4 and 5.4, to obtain 2 γ πp t pγ π t = + p γ µ t dt + γ πp t p γ π t dt. 8.6 π p i t p π i t τ iit µ τ µ π p π t + p τ ππt µ p = p µ i t τ iit µ + p τ ππt µ p 2 τ ππt µ = p [ 2 γ µ t + p τ ππt µ ]. Substituting back into 8.6 we get log T = p log Z µ T Z πp Z π T Z µ T and note that the last term is non-negative, by p p 2 τ µ ππt dt Lemma: Suppose that the extended portfolio π is such that the conditions and P Z π T Z π Z µ T β T = or P Z µ T = 8.8 β T P τ ππt µ dt η = 8.9 hold, for some β > and η >. Then there exists an extended portfolio π such that P Z π T < Z µ T = Remark: Condition 8.8 postulates that the extended portfolio π is not very different from the market portfolio. But condition 8.9 mandates that π must be sufficiently different from the market portfolio; indeed, τ µ ππt dt ε n π it µ i t 2 dt from 8.3, so 8.9 holds if the expression π µ L 2 [,T ] is bounded away from zero, a.s. Proof of Lemma 8.: If we have P [ Z π T /Z µ T /β ] =, then it suffices to take p > + 2/η log/β and observe from 8.9, 8.7 that π π p satisfies log Z π [ T p log Z µ T + η2 ] β p 5 <, a.s.

16 If on the other hand we have P [ Z π T /Z µ T β ] =, then it suffices to take p < min, 2/η log/β and observe from 8.7 that π π p satisfies log Z π [ T p log Z µ T + η2 ] β p <, a.s. 8. Example: With π = e =,,, and m µ the market portfolio, take a number p > to be detemined in a moment and define the extended portfolio πt := π p t = p e + p µt, t <, 8. which takes a long position in the first stock and a short position in the market. This is not a very easy portfolio to implement in actual practice. In particular, π t = p + p µ t and π i t = p µ i t for i = 2,, n. Then we have log Z π [ T = p log Z µ T µ T µ p 2 τ µ t dt ] 8.2 from 8.7. But taking β := µ we have µ T /µ /β, and if the market is weakly diverse on [, T ] we obtain from 5. and the Cauchy-Schwarz inequality τ µ t dt ε µ t 2 dt > εδ 2 T =: η. 8.3 From Lemma 8. the market portfolio represents then an arbitrage opportunity with respect to the extended portfolio π of 8., provided that for any given T, we select p > pt := + 2 log εδ 2 T µ. Note that limt pt =. The extended portfolio π of 8. can be used to create all-long portfolios that underperform Example 8.2 or outperform Example 8.3 the market portfolio µ, over any given time-horizon T,. The idea is to embed π in a sea of market portfolio, swamping the short positions while retaining the essential portfolio characteristics. Crucial in these constructions is the a.s. comparison Z π t p µ t Z µ t, t <, 8.4 µ a direct consequence of 8.2. Here and in what follows we assume Z µ = Z π =. 8.2 Example: Consider an investment strategy ρ that places one dollar in the portfolio π of 8. and p /µ p dollars in the market portfolio µ at time t =, and makes no change afterwards. The number p is chosen as in Example 8.. The value Z ρ 6

17 of this strategy is clearly Z ρ t = Z π t + p µ p Zµ t >, t <, and is generated by the extended portfolio with weights ρ i t = [ π Z ρ i t Z π t + p ] t µ p µ i t Z µ t, for i =,, n. Clearly n ρ i t = ; and since both π t and µ t are positive, we have ρ t > as well. To check that ρ is an all-long portfolio, observe that the dollar amount it invests at time t in any stock i = 2,, n is p µ i t Z π t + p µ p µ i t Z µ t p µ it µ p [ µ t p ] Z µ t > thanks to 8.4. On the other hand, ρ underperforms at t = T a market portfolio that starts out with the same initial capital z := Z ρ = + p /µ p, since ρ holds a mix of µ and π, and π underperforms the market at t = T : Z ρ T = Z π T + p µ p Z µ T < zz µ T = Z z,µ T a.s., from Example: Now consider a strategy η that invests p/µ p dollars in the market portfolio and dollar in π at time t =, and makes no change thereafter. The number p > is chosen again as in Example 8.. The value Z η of this strategy is Z η t = p µ p Z µ t Z π t Zµ t µ p [ p µ t p ] >, t < 8.5 thanks to 8.4 and p > > µ t p. As before, Z η is generated by an extended portfolio η with weights η i t = Z η t [ ] p µi t µ p Z µ t π i t Z π t, i =,, n 8.6 that clearly satisfy n η i t =. Now for i = 2,, n we have π i t = p µ i t <, so η 2,..., η n are strictly positive. To check that η is actually an all-long portfolio, it remains to verify η t ; but the dollar amount pµ t µ p Z µ t [ p p µ t ] Z π t invested by η in the first stock at time t, dominates p Z µ t, or equivalently the quantity µ t µ pµ t µ p Zµ t [p p µ t] Z µ tµ t µ p [ p µ t p + p { µ t p } ] >, 7

18 again thanks to 8.4 and p > > µ t p. Thus η is indeed an all-long portfolio. On the other hand, η outperforms at t = T a market portfolio with the same initial capital of ζ := Z η = p/µ p > dollars, because η is long in the market µ and short in the extended portfolio π, which underperforms the market at t = T : Z η T = p µ p Z µ T Z π T > ζz µ T = Z ζ,µ T a.s., from Hedging in Weakly Diverse Markets Suppose now that we place a small investor in a market M as in and allow him to invest also in a money-market with interest rate r : [, Ω [,, a progressively measurable, locally square-integrable process. A dollar invested at time t = in the money market grows to BT = exp{ ru du} at time t = T. Starting with initial capital z >, the investor can choose at any time t a trading strategy ϕt = ϕ t,, ϕ n t. With Z z,ϕ t denoting the value of the strategy at time t, the quantity ϕ i t is the dollar amount invested in the i th stock and Z z,ϕ t n ϕ i t the amount in the money-market. These quantities are real-valued, and any one of them may be negative: selling stock short is allowed, as is borrowing from as opposed to depositing into the money-market. We require only that the trading strategy ϕ be progressively measurable and satisfy n [ ϕ it 2 + ϕ i t b i t rt ] dt < a.s., on any given time-horizon [, T ]. With this understanding the value-process Z Z z,ϕ satisfies dzt = ϕ i t dx it X i t + Zt ϕ i t dbt Bt 9. m = rtztdt + ϕ i t b i t rt dt + σ iν t dw ν t = rtztdt + ϕ tσtdŵ t, ν= a simple linear equation. We have introduced the processes Ŵ t := W t + t ϑs ds, ϑt := σ tσtσ t [bt rt] 9.2 with =,, IR n and ϑt 2 dt < a.s. for any T, ; recall here the conditions 2.2, 2.3 and the local square-integrability of r. In this notation we can write the equation 2. as d Xi t Bt = Xi t Bt m σ iν t dŵνt, i =,, n. 9.3 ν= 8

19 The solution of the equation 9. is given by Z z,ϕ t/bt = z + t ϕ s/bs σs dŵ s, t <. 9.4 We shall denote by Φ T z the class of trading strategies ϕ that satisfy P [ Z z,ϕ t, t T ] = for a given T,, and set Φz := <T < Φ T z. This class contains the extended portfolios of section 8: if π is an extended portfolio and Z π its value-process with initial capital Z π = z >, then ϕ i := π i Z π, i n defines a trading strategy, and Z z,ϕ Z π > satisfies the analogue of 9.4 dz π t/bt = Z π t/bt π tσtdŵ t. 9. Remark: If M is weakly diverse on some finite horizon [, T ], then the process t Lt := exp ϑ s dw s t ϑs 2 ds 2 >, t < 9.5 is a local martingale and a supermartingale, but is not a martingale. For if it were, then the measure Q T A := E[LT A ] would be a probability on FT. Under this probability measure the process Ŵ of 9.2 would be Brownian motion, and the discounted capitalization-processes X i /B would be martingales on the interval [, T ], from 9.3, 2.3. But this would proscribe 2. on this interval for any two extended portfolios π and ρ, contradicting 4.5 and the examples of section 8 see the Appendix for a formal argument along these lines. Thus, in a weakly diverse market the process L of 9.5 is a strict local martingale in the sense of Elworthy et al. 997: we have E[Lt] < for every t,. 9.2 Remark: Because L is a local martingale there exists an increasing sequence {S k } k N of stopping times with lim k S k = a.s. such that L S k is a martingale for every k N for instance, take S k = inf{t t ϑs 2 ds k }. Thus, if we replace T by T S k in 2., this property cannot hold for any extended portfolios π and ρ : there is no possibility for relative arbitrage on the horizon [, T S k ] for any k N. But in the limit as k a relative arbitrage of the type 2. appears, as in 4.5 or in Example 8., if M is weakly diverse on [, T ]. The failure of the exponential process L in 9.5 to be a martingale does not preclude, however, the possibility for hedging contingent claims in a market M which is weakly diverse on some finite horizon [, T ]. To see why, consider an FT measurable random variable Y : Ω [, that satisfies < y := E[ Y LT /BT ] <

20 If we view Y as a liability contingent claim that the investor faces and has to cover hedge at time t = T, the question is to characterize the smallest amount of initial capital that allows the investor to hedge this liability without risk; namely, the hedging price h Y := inf{z > there exists ϕ Φ T z such that Z z,ϕ T Y holds a.s.}. 9.7 We proceed as in the standard treatment of this question e.g. Karatzas & Shreve 998, Chapter 2 but under the probability measure P, the only one now at our disposal. From and the differential equation dlt = Lt ϑ t dw t for the exponential process L of 9.5, we obtain that each of the processes X i t := LtX it t X i Bt = + X i s Z ϕ t := LtZz,ϕ t zbt = + t m σ iν s ϑ ν s dw ν s, i =,, n 9.8 ν= Ls ϕ sσs Z z,ϕ sϑ s dw s 9.9 zbs products of L with the discounted stock-capitalizations and with the discounted values of investment strategies in Φz, respectively is a non-negative local martingale, hence a supermartingale. It is not hard to see in the Appendix that the processes X i, i =,, n of 9.8 are strict local martingales. 9. In particular, E[ LT X i T /BT ] < X i holds for all T,. And for any z > in the set of 9.7, there exists some ϕ Φ T z such that so y = E[Y LT /BT ] h Y. E[ Y LT /BT ] E[ Z z,ϕ T LT /BT ] z, 9. Let us suppose from now on that m = n, i.e., that we have exactly as many sources of randomness as there are stocks in the market M; that the square-matrix σt, ω = {σ ij t, ω} i,j n is invertible for every t, ω [, T ] Ω; and that the filtration F = {Ft} t T is generated by the Brownian Motion W itself, namely, Ft = σw s; s t. The martingale representation property of this Brownian filtration gives Mt := E [ Y LT BT ] Ft = y + t ψ s dw s, t T 9.2 for some progressively measurable process ψ : [, T ] Ω IR n with n ψ it 2 dt < B a.s. Setting Ẑ := M B /L, ϕ := L σ ψ + M ϑ and comparing 9.9 with 9.2, we observe Ẑ = y, ẐT = Y and Ẑ Zy, ϕ, almost surely. 2

21 Therefore, the trading strategy ϕ is in Φ T y and satisfies the exact replication property Z y, ϕ T = Y a.s. This implies that y belongs to the set on the right-hand-side of 9.7, and so y h Y. But we have already established the reverse inequality, actually in much greater generality, so for the hedging price of 9.7 we get the Black-Scholes-type formula under the assumptions of the preceding paragraph. h Y = E[ Y LT /BT ] 9.3 In particular, a market M that is weakly diverse hence without an equivalent probability measure under which discounted stock-prices are at least local martingales can nevertheless be complete. But in such a market we shall have from 9., 9.3 that h X T < X, namely, that the hedging price for the stock value capitalization at time T > is strictly less than the current value X : the existence of relative arbitrage has made this reduction possible. 9.3 Remark: In order to make a connection with the classical non-arbitrage theory e.g. Delbaen & Schachermayer 994, 998, Lowenstein & Willard 2, let us note that we have constrained ourselves to trading strategies that start from a strictly positive wealth and stay strictly positive while the classical notions of arbitrage including the so-called free lunches with vanishing risk or free snacks require that wealth start from zero and remain bounded from below. A slight reformulation of these arbitrage notions for our model makes them completely equivalent to the ones in the above-mentioned papers. With this in mind it can be seen that equation 4.5 implies the existence of a classical arbitrage opportunity not in the original market, but in one where the market portfolio is the numeraire. We are indebted to Profs. Steven Shreve and Julien Hugonnier for helpful discussions on these issues. 9. EXAMPLE: A European Call-Option. Consider the contingent claim Y = X T q + : this is a European call-option with strike q > on the first stock. Let us assume also that the interest-rate process r is bounded away from zero, namely that P [ rt r, t ] = holds for some r >, and that the market M is weakly diverse on all time-horizons T, sufficiently large. Then for the hedging price of this contingent claim, written now as a function ht of the time-horizon, we have from 9., 9.3 and E[LT ] < : X > E[ LT X T /BT ] E[ LT X T q + /BT ] = ht E[ LT X T /BT ] q E LT e T + rt dt E[ LT X T /BT ] q e rt E[LT ] + E[ LT X T /BT ] q e rt + because L X /B is a supermartingale and a strict local martingale. 2

22 Therefore h := lim ht = lim E T T LT X T BT < X : 9.4 the hedging price of the option is strictly less than the capitalization of the underlying stock at time t =, and tends to h [, X as the horizon increases without limit. We claim that if M is uniformly weakly diverse over some [T,, then the limit in 9.4 is actually zero: a European call-option that can never be exercised has zero hedging price. Indeed, for every fixed p, and T 2 log n T pεδ, the quantity E LT LT LT BT X T E BT Zµ T E Zπp T BT is dominated by Z n p p n p p e εδ pt/2 e εδ pt/2, from 3.,.4 and the supermartingale property of L Z πp /B. Letting T as in 9.4, this leads to h =. 9.4 Remark: Note the sharp difference between this case and the situation where an equivalent martingale measure exists on every finite time-horizon; namely, when both L and L X /B are martingales. Then E[LT X T /BT ] = X holds for all T,, and h = X : as the time-horizon increases without limit, the hedging price of the call-option approaches the current stock value Karatzas & Shreve 998, p EXAMPLE: Put-Call Parity. Suppose that Ξ, Ξ 2 are positive, continuous and adapted processes, representing the values of two different assets in a market M with r. Let us set Y := Ξ T Ξ 2 T + and Y2 := Ξ 2 T Ξ T + ; then from 9.3 the quantity h j = E[LT Y j ] is the hedging price at time t = of a contract that offers its holder the right, but not the obligation, to exchange asset 2 for asset with j = resp., asset for asset 2 with j = 2 at time t = T. We have clearly h h 2 = E[ LT Ξ T Ξ 2 T ], and say that the two assets are in put-call parity if h h 2 = Ξ Ξ 2. This will be the case when both L Ξ, L Ξ 2 are martingales. For instance, whenever 4.6 is valid we can take Ξ j X i or Ξ j Z π for any i =,, n, j =, 2 and any extended portfolio π ; then put-call parity holds as in Karatzas & Shreve 998, p.5. It is easy to see that put-call parity need not hold if M is weakly diverse: for instance, take Ξ Z µ, Ξ 2 Z π with Z µ = Z π in the notation of 3. and 8., and observe from 8. that h h 2 = E[ LT Z µ T Z π T ] > = Z µ Z π. A similar observation appears in Lowenstein & Willard 2. 22

23 Concluding Remarks We have presented examples of diverse and weakly diverse market models posited in Fernholz 999, 22, and shown that the diversity-weighted portfolio of 4.4 represents an arbitrage relative to a weakly-diverse market over sufficiently long time-horizons. We have also shown that weakly-diverse markets are themselves arbitrages relative to suitable extended portfolios, over arbitratry time-horizons. In particular, no equivalent martingale measure can exist for such markets. But we have also shown that, even in diverse markets, this does not interfere with the development of option pricing; quite the contrary, one is led to more realistic hedging-prices for warrants over exceedingly long time-horizons. Similar treatments are possible for solving utility maximization problems along the lines of Karatzas et al. 99, for showing that diversity is compatible with economic equilibrium considerations as in chapter 4 of Karatzas & Shreve 998, and for treating general semimartingale market models see Kardaras 24. It would be of interest to determine the optimal hedging strategy ϕ under suitable e.g. Markovian structure conditions, and to treat in the framework of section 9 the hedging of American options. Appendix A: Proofs of Selected Results Proof of : With e i =,,,,,, the i th unit vector in IR n, we have τiit π = πt e i at πt e i ε πt e i 2 = ε [ π i t 2 + j i πj 2 t ] ε π i t 2 from 5.3 and 2.3. Back into 5.4, this gives γ π t ε 2 π i t π i t 2 + πj 2 t j i = ε 2 π i t π i t 2 + πj 2 t π j t j= = ε 2 π i t π i t ε 2 π t. Similarly, we get τiit π M [ π i t 2 + j i πj 2 t ] M π i t 2 π i t as claimed in 5., and this leads to 5. and to γ π t M 2 π i t π i t = M [ ] 2 π t π t + π k t π k t k=2 M [ ] 2 π t + π k t = M π t. k=2 23

24 Proof of 4.5: Let us start by introducing the function Dx := n x p i /p, which we shall interpret as a measure of diversity. An application of Itô s rule to the process {Dµt, t < } leads after some computation to the expression log T = log Z µ T Zπp DµT Dµ + p γ πp tdt, T <. for the value-process Z π p of the diversity-weighted portfolio π p of 4.4. Useful in the computation. is the numéraire-invariance property 5.5. Suppose that the market is weakly diverse on the finite time-horizon [, T ], namely, that T µ t dt > δ T holds almost surely, for some < δ <. We have then = n µ i t n µ i t p = Dµt p n p minimum diversity occurs when the entire market is concentrated in one stock, and maximum diversity when all stocks have the same capitalization, so that log DµT Dµ p p log n..2 This provides, in particular, the lower bound Z πp /Z µ n p/p. On the other hand, we have already remarked in section 4 that the largest weight of the portfolio π p in 4.4 does not exceed the maximum weight of the market portfolio, namely π p t := max i n πp i t = µ t p nk= µ k t p µ t.3 the reverse inequality holds for the smallest weights, namely π p n t := min i n π p i t µ n t. From 5.2 and.3 we see that the assumption 4.2 of weak diversity implies γ πp t dt ε 2 and in conjunction with.2 this lead to 4.5 via log Zπp µ t dt > ε 2 δ T, a.s. [ T εt > p Z µ T 2 δ ] p log n..4 Now if M is uniformly weakly diverse over [T,, then.4 gives the long-term comparison L πp, µ = lim T T logzπp T /Z µ T p εδ >, a.s. 2 Proof that the martingale property of L valid under condition 4.6 proscribes 2.: Suppose that the exponential process {Lt; t T } of 9.5 is a 24

25 P martingale; then {Ŵ t; t T } of 9.2 is Brownian motion under the equivalent probability measure Q T A = E[ LT A ] on FT, by the Girsanov theorem. For instance, this will be the case under the Novikov condition 4.6; cf. Theorem 3.5. and Proposition in Karatzas & Shreve 99. For any extended portfolio π we have m dz z,π t/bt = Z z,π t/bt π i t σ iν t dŵνt, Z z,π = z > ν= from 9.4 and the discussion following it; this shows that the process Z z,π /B is then a martingale under Q T with moments of all orders in particular, square-integrable. If ρ is another extended portfolio, the difference H := Z z,π Z z,ρ /B is again a square-integrable martingale with H =, therefore E Q T [HT ] =. But if HT holds a.s. with respect to P, or equivalently with respect to Q T, then this gives HT = a.s. and rules out the second requirement P [HT > ] > of 2.. Proof of 9.: Suppose that the processes L X i /B for i =,, n are all martingales; then so is their sum, the process Z := L Z µ /B with Z µ := n X i as in 3.. With z =, ϕ Z µ µ and ϑ µ t := σ tµt ϑt, the equation 9.9 takes the form d Z µ t = Z µ tϑ µ t dw t or equivalently and we get t Z µ t = exp ϑ µ s dw s t ϑ µ s 2 ds,.5 2 t Z µ t = exp ϑ µ s d W s t ϑ µ s 2 ds, where W := W ϑ µ s ds. 2 Now on any given finite horizon [, T ], this process W is Brownian motion under the equivalent probability measure P T A := E[ Z µ T A ] on FT, and Itô s rule gives d Z π t Z µ t = Z π t m π Z µ i t µ i t σ iν t d W ν t.6 t ν= for an arbitrary extended portfolio π. From 2.3 we see that, for any such π, the ratio Z π /Z µ is a martingale under P T ; in particular, E P T [ Z π T /Z µ T ] =. But if π satisfies P [ Z π T Z µ T ] =, we must have also P T [ Z π T /Z µ T ] = ; in conjunction with E P T [ Z π T /Z µ T ] =, this leads to P T [ Z π T = Z µ T ] =, or equivalently Z π T = Z µ T a.s. P, contradicting 4.5. Thus the process t X j t = exp ϑ j s dw s t ϑ j s 2 ds, t <

26 of 9.8 is a strict local martingale, for some at least one j {,, n}; we have set ϑ k ν t := σ kν t ϑ ν t, ν =,, n, for any k {,, n}. Suppose now that 9. fails, i.e., that X i is a martingale for some i j. Then for any T, the measure P i T A := E[ X i T A ] is a probability on FT, under which the process W i t := W t t ϑi s ds, t T is standard IR n valued Brownian motion. By analogy with.5-.7 we have now t X i t = exp ϑ i s dw i s t ϑ i s 2 ds, 2 and d Xj t X i t = Xj t X i t m σ jν t σ iν t d ν= W i ν t. Thus, thanks to condition 2.3, the process X j /X i is a P i T martingale on [, T ], with moments of all orders. In particular, X j X i = EP i T [ Xj T X i T ] = E [ LT Xi T BT X i XjT ], X i T which contradicts E[LT X j T /BT ] < X j and thus the strict local martingale property of L X j /B under P. 2 Acknowledgements We are grateful for the helpful remarks offered by seminar audiences at Columbia, Yale, Princeton, the Sloan School of MIT, Boston University, the Mathematical Institute in Oberwolfach, and the Universities of Athens, Connecticut/Storrs and Texas/Austin. Special thanks go to Professors Jérôme Detemple, Julien Hugonnier, Ralf Korn, Andrew Lo, Mark Lowenstein and Steven Shreve. We are also indebted to Dr. Adrian Banner for a number of discussions that helped sharpen our thinking about these problems, and to the referees and editors for suggestions that improved the exposition. A significant part of this work was completed in the spring semester of 22, while the second author was on sabbatical leave at the Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics, Yale University. He is grateful to the Foundation for its hospitality. 3 References Delbaen, F. & Schachermayer, W. 994 A general version of the fundamental theorem of asset pricing. Mathematische Annalen 3,

27 Delbaen, F. & Schachermayer, W. 995 Arbitrage possibilities in Bessel processes and their relations to local martingales. Probability Theory & Related Fields 2, Delbaen, F. & Schachermayer, W. 998 The fundamental theorem of asset pricing for unbounded stochastic processes. Mathematische Annalen 32, Elworthy, K.D., X.-M. Li & M. Yor 997 On the tails of the supremum and the quadratic variation of strictly local martingales. In Séminaire de Probabilités XXXI, Lecture Notes in Mathematics 655, pp Springer-Verlag, Berlin. Fernholz, E.R. 999 On the diversity of equity markets. Journal of Mathematical Economics 3, Fernholz, E.R. 2 Equity portfolios generated by ranked market-weights. Finance & Stochastics 5, Fernholz, E.R. 22 Stochastic Portfolio Theory. Springer-Verlag, New York. Karatzas, I., Lehoczky, J.P., Shreve, S.E. & Xu, G.L. 99 Martingale and duality methods for utility maximization in an incomplete market. SIAM Journal on Control & Optimization 29, Karatzas, I. & Shreve, S.E. 99 Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus. Second Edition. Springer-Verlag, New York. Karatzas, I. & Shreve, S.E. 998 Methods of Mathematical Finance. Springer-Verlag, New York. Kardaras, C. 24 Stochastic Portfolio Theory in Semimartingale Markets. Columbia University. Preprint, Levental, S. & Skorohod, A. 995 A necessary and sufficient condition for absence of arbitrage with tame portfolios. Annals of Applied Probability 5, Lowenstein, M. & Willard, G.A. 2 Local martingales, arbitrage and viability. Economic Theory 6, Lowenstein, M. & Willard, G.A. 2 Rational equilibrium asset-pricing bubbles in continuous trading models. Journal of Economic Theory 9, Samuelson, P.A. 965 Proof that properly anticipated prices fluctuate randomly. Industrial Management Review 6, 4-5. Veretennikov, A. Yu. 98 On strong solutions and explicit formulas for solutions of stochastic integral equations. Math. USSR Sbornik 39,

IOANNIS KARATZAS Mathematics and Statistics Departments Columbia University

IOANNIS KARATZAS Mathematics and Statistics Departments Columbia University STOCHASTIC PORTFOLIO THEORY IOANNIS KARATZAS Mathematics and Statistics Departments Columbia University ik@math.columbia.edu Joint work with Dr. E. Robert FERNHOLZ, C.I.O. of INTECH Enhanced Investment

More information

Stochastic Portfolio Theory: An Overview

Stochastic Portfolio Theory: An Overview Stochastic Portfolio Theory: An Overview ROBERT FERNHOLZ INTECH One Palmer Square Princeton, NJ 8542, USA bob@enhanced.com IOANNIS KARATZAS Departments of Mathematics and Statistics Columbia University

More information

LOCAL TIMES OF RANKED CONTINUOUS SEMIMARTINGALES

LOCAL TIMES OF RANKED CONTINUOUS SEMIMARTINGALES LOCAL TIMES OF RANKED CONTINUOUS SEMIMARTINGALES ADRIAN D. BANNER INTECH One Palmer Square Princeton, NJ 8542, USA adrian@enhanced.com RAOUF GHOMRASNI Fakultät II, Institut für Mathematik Sekr. MA 7-5,

More information

EQUITY MARKET STABILITY

EQUITY MARKET STABILITY EQUITY MARKET STABILITY Adrian Banner INTECH Investment Technologies LLC, Princeton (Joint work with E. Robert Fernholz, Ioannis Karatzas, Vassilios Papathanakos and Phillip Whitman.) Talk at WCMF6 conference,

More information

OPTIONAL DECOMPOSITION FOR CONTINUOUS SEMIMARTINGALES UNDER ARBITRARY FILTRATIONS. Introduction

OPTIONAL DECOMPOSITION FOR CONTINUOUS SEMIMARTINGALES UNDER ARBITRARY FILTRATIONS. Introduction OPTIONAL DECOMPOSITION FOR CONTINUOUS SEMIMARTINGALES UNDER ARBITRARY FILTRATIONS IOANNIS KARATZAS AND CONSTANTINOS KARDARAS Abstract. We present an elementary treatment of the Optional Decomposition Theorem

More information

Some Aspects of Universal Portfolio

Some Aspects of Universal Portfolio 1 Some Aspects of Universal Portfolio Tomoyuki Ichiba (UC Santa Barbara) joint work with Marcel Brod (ETH Zurich) Conference on Stochastic Asymptotics & Applications Sixth Western Conference on Mathematical

More information

Hybrid Atlas Model. of financial equity market. Tomoyuki Ichiba 1 Ioannis Karatzas 2,3 Adrian Banner 3 Vassilios Papathanakos 3 Robert Fernholz 3

Hybrid Atlas Model. of financial equity market. Tomoyuki Ichiba 1 Ioannis Karatzas 2,3 Adrian Banner 3 Vassilios Papathanakos 3 Robert Fernholz 3 Hybrid Atlas Model of financial equity market Tomoyuki Ichiba 1 Ioannis Karatzas 2,3 Adrian Banner 3 Vassilios Papathanakos 3 Robert Fernholz 3 1 University of California, Santa Barbara 2 Columbia University,

More information

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint that the ON PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION UNDER \DRAWDOWN" CONSTRAINTS JAKSA CVITANIC IOANNIS KARATZAS y March 6, 994 Abstract We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the wealth

More information

EXPLOSIONS AND ARBITRAGE IOANNIS KARATZAS. Joint work with Daniel FERNHOLZ and Johannes RUF. Talk at the University of Michigan

EXPLOSIONS AND ARBITRAGE IOANNIS KARATZAS. Joint work with Daniel FERNHOLZ and Johannes RUF. Talk at the University of Michigan EXPLOSIONS AND ARBITRAGE IOANNIS KARATZAS Department of Mathematics, Columbia University, New York INTECH Investment Management LLC, Princeton Joint work with Daniel FERNHOLZ and Johannes RUF Talk at the

More information

ALEKSANDAR MIJATOVIĆ AND MIKHAIL URUSOV

ALEKSANDAR MIJATOVIĆ AND MIKHAIL URUSOV DETERMINISTIC CRITERIA FOR THE ABSENCE OF ARBITRAGE IN DIFFUSION MODELS ALEKSANDAR MIJATOVIĆ AND MIKHAIL URUSOV Abstract. We obtain a deterministic characterisation of the no free lunch with vanishing

More information

A note on arbitrage, approximate arbitrage and the fundamental theorem of asset pricing

A note on arbitrage, approximate arbitrage and the fundamental theorem of asset pricing A note on arbitrage, approximate arbitrage and the fundamental theorem of asset pricing Claudio Fontana Laboratoire Analyse et Probabilité Université d'évry Val d'essonne, 23 bd de France, 91037, Évry

More information

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Tim Leung 1, Qingshuo Song 2, and Jie Yang 3 1 Columbia University, New York, USA; leung@ieor.columbia.edu 2 City

More information

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.mf] 26 Sep 2018

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.mf] 26 Sep 2018 Trading Strategies Generated by Path-dependent Functionals of Market Weights IOANNIS KARATZAS DONGHAN KIM arxiv:189.1123v1 [q-fin.mf] 26 Sep 218 September 27, 218 Abstract Almost twenty years ago, E.R.

More information

QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE

QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE Research Paper 241 December 2008 Viability of Markets with an Infinite Number of Assets Constantinos Kardaras ISSN 1441-8010 VIABILITY

More information

SEPARABLE TERM STRUCTURES AND THE MAXIMAL DEGREE PROBLEM. 1. Introduction This paper discusses arbitrage-free separable term structure (STS) models

SEPARABLE TERM STRUCTURES AND THE MAXIMAL DEGREE PROBLEM. 1. Introduction This paper discusses arbitrage-free separable term structure (STS) models SEPARABLE TERM STRUCTURES AND THE MAXIMAL DEGREE PROBLEM DAMIR FILIPOVIĆ Abstract. This paper discusses separable term structure diffusion models in an arbitrage-free environment. Using general consistency

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 24 Sep 2018

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 24 Sep 2018 A short note on Anticipative portfolio optimization B. D Auria a,b,1,, J.-A. Salmerón a,1 a Dpto. Estadística, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid. Avda. de la Universidad 3, 8911, Leganés (Madrid Spain b

More information

The multidimensional Ito Integral and the multidimensional Ito Formula. Eric Mu ller June 1, 2015 Seminar on Stochastic Geometry and its applications

The multidimensional Ito Integral and the multidimensional Ito Formula. Eric Mu ller June 1, 2015 Seminar on Stochastic Geometry and its applications The multidimensional Ito Integral and the multidimensional Ito Formula Eric Mu ller June 1, 215 Seminar on Stochastic Geometry and its applications page 2 Seminar on Stochastic Geometry and its applications

More information

STRICT LOCAL MARTINGALE DEFLATORS AND PRICING AMERICAN CALL-TYPE OPTIONS. 0. Introduction

STRICT LOCAL MARTINGALE DEFLATORS AND PRICING AMERICAN CALL-TYPE OPTIONS. 0. Introduction STRICT LOCAL MARTINGALE DEFLATORS AND PRICING AMERICAN CALL-TYPE OPTIONS ERHAN BAYRAKTAR, CONSTANTINOS KARDARAS, AND HAO XING Abstract. We solve the problem of pricing and optimal exercise of American

More information

Optional decomposition for continuous semimartingales under arbitrary filtrations *

Optional decomposition for continuous semimartingales under arbitrary filtrations * Electron. Commun. Probab. 2 (215), no. 59, 1 1. DOI: 1.1214/ECP.v2-49 ISSN: 183-589X ELECTRONIC COMMUNICATIONS in PROBABILITY Optional decomposition for continuous semimartingales under arbitrary filtrations

More information

Optimal Arbitrage under Constraints

Optimal Arbitrage under Constraints Optimal Arbitrage under Constraints Subhankar Sadhukhan Submitted in partial fulfillment of the Requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the Graduate School of Arts and Sciences COLUMBIA

More information

VOLATILITY AND ARBITRAGE

VOLATILITY AND ARBITRAGE The Annals of Applied Probability 218, Vol. 28, No. 1, 378 417 https://doi.org/1.1214/17-aap138 Institute of Mathematical Statistics, 218 VOLATILITY AND ARBITRAGE BY E. ROBERT FERNHOLZ,IOANNIS KARATZAS,,1

More information

Thomas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover

Thomas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover Optimal long term investment under model ambiguity Optimal long term investment under model ambiguity homas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover knispel@stochastik.uni-hannover.de AnStAp0 Vienna, July

More information

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs Lecture Notes by Walter Schachermayer Nachdiplom-Vorlesung, ETH Zürich, WS 15/16 1 Models on Finite Probability Spaces In this section we consider a stock price

More information

OPTIMAL STOPPING OF A BROWNIAN BRIDGE

OPTIMAL STOPPING OF A BROWNIAN BRIDGE OPTIMAL STOPPING OF A BROWNIAN BRIDGE ERIK EKSTRÖM AND HENRIK WANNTORP Abstract. We study several optimal stopping problems in which the gains process is a Brownian bridge or a functional of a Brownian

More information

Optimal Stopping Problems and American Options

Optimal Stopping Problems and American Options Optimal Stopping Problems and American Options Nadia Uys A dissertation submitted to the Faculty of Science, University of the Witwatersrand, in fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Master

More information

Dynamic Risk Measures and Nonlinear Expectations with Markov Chain noise

Dynamic Risk Measures and Nonlinear Expectations with Markov Chain noise Dynamic Risk Measures and Nonlinear Expectations with Markov Chain noise Robert J. Elliott 1 Samuel N. Cohen 2 1 Department of Commerce, University of South Australia 2 Mathematical Insitute, University

More information

Lecture 22 Girsanov s Theorem

Lecture 22 Girsanov s Theorem Lecture 22: Girsanov s Theorem of 8 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 25 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 22 Girsanov s Theorem An example Consider a finite Gaussian random walk X n = n

More information

Risk-Minimality and Orthogonality of Martingales

Risk-Minimality and Orthogonality of Martingales Risk-Minimality and Orthogonality of Martingales Martin Schweizer Universität Bonn Institut für Angewandte Mathematik Wegelerstraße 6 D 53 Bonn 1 (Stochastics and Stochastics Reports 3 (199, 123 131 2

More information

THE ASYMPTOTIC ELASTICITY OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS 1

THE ASYMPTOTIC ELASTICITY OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS 1 The Annals of Applied Probability 1999, Vol. 9, No. 3, 94 95 THE ASYMPTOTIC ELASTICITY OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS 1 By D. Kramkov 2 and W. Schachermayer Steklov Mathematical

More information

On the dual problem of utility maximization

On the dual problem of utility maximization On the dual problem of utility maximization Yiqing LIN Joint work with L. GU and J. YANG University of Vienna Sept. 2nd 2015 Workshop Advanced methods in financial mathematics Angers 1 Introduction Basic

More information

A Second-Order Model of the Stock Market

A Second-Order Model of the Stock Market A Second-Order Model of the Stock Market Robert Fernholz INTECH Conference in honor of Ioannis Karatzas Columbia University, New York June 4 8, 2012 This is joint research with T. Ichiba, I. Karatzas.

More information

Sensitivity analysis of the expected utility maximization problem with respect to model perturbations

Sensitivity analysis of the expected utility maximization problem with respect to model perturbations Sensitivity analysis of the expected utility maximization problem with respect to model perturbations Mihai Sîrbu, The University of Texas at Austin based on joint work with Oleksii Mostovyi University

More information

A Barrier Version of the Russian Option

A Barrier Version of the Russian Option A Barrier Version of the Russian Option L. A. Shepp, A. N. Shiryaev, A. Sulem Rutgers University; shepp@stat.rutgers.edu Steklov Mathematical Institute; shiryaev@mi.ras.ru INRIA- Rocquencourt; agnes.sulem@inria.fr

More information

Stochastic integral. Introduction. Ito integral. References. Appendices Stochastic Calculus I. Geneviève Gauthier.

Stochastic integral. Introduction. Ito integral. References. Appendices Stochastic Calculus I. Geneviève Gauthier. Ito 8-646-8 Calculus I Geneviève Gauthier HEC Montréal Riemann Ito The Ito The theories of stochastic and stochastic di erential equations have initially been developed by Kiyosi Ito around 194 (one of

More information

Convex polytopes, interacting particles, spin glasses, and finance

Convex polytopes, interacting particles, spin glasses, and finance Convex polytopes, interacting particles, spin glasses, and finance Sourav Chatterjee (UCB) joint work with Soumik Pal (Cornell) Interacting particles Systems of particles governed by joint stochastic differential

More information

On the martingales obtained by an extension due to Saisho, Tanemura and Yor of Pitman s theorem

On the martingales obtained by an extension due to Saisho, Tanemura and Yor of Pitman s theorem On the martingales obtained by an extension due to Saisho, Tanemura and Yor of Pitman s theorem Koichiro TAKAOKA Dept of Applied Physics, Tokyo Institute of Technology Abstract M Yor constructed a family

More information

MULTIPLICATIVE APPROXIMATION OF WEALTH PROCESSES INVOLVING NO-SHORT-SALES STRATEGIES VIA SIMPLE TRADING. CONSTANTINOS KARDARAS Boston University

MULTIPLICATIVE APPROXIMATION OF WEALTH PROCESSES INVOLVING NO-SHORT-SALES STRATEGIES VIA SIMPLE TRADING. CONSTANTINOS KARDARAS Boston University Mathematical Finance, Vol. 23, No. 3 (July 2013, 579 590 MULTIPLICATIVE APPROXIMATION OF WEALTH PROCESSES INVOLVING NO-SHORT-SALES STRATEGIES VIA SIMPLE TRADING CONSTANTINOS KARDARAS Boston University

More information

A new approach for investment performance measurement. 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009

A new approach for investment performance measurement. 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009 A new approach for investment performance measurement 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009 Thaleia Zariphopoulou University of Oxford, Oxford-Man Institute and The University of Texas at Austin 1 Performance

More information

ARBITRAGE WITH FRACTIONAL BROWNIAN MOTION

ARBITRAGE WITH FRACTIONAL BROWNIAN MOTION Mathematical Finance, Vol. 7, No. 1 (January 1997), 95 105 ARBITRAGE WITH FRACTIONAL BROWNIAN MOTION L. C. G. ROGERS 1 School of Mathematical Sciences, University of Bath, Bath, United Kingdom Fractional

More information

Stochastic Calculus for Finance II - some Solutions to Chapter VII

Stochastic Calculus for Finance II - some Solutions to Chapter VII Stochastic Calculus for Finance II - some Solutions to Chapter VII Matthias hul Last Update: June 9, 25 Exercise 7 Black-Scholes-Merton Equation for the up-and-out Call) i) We have ii) We first compute

More information

Question 1. The correct answers are: (a) (2) (b) (1) (c) (2) (d) (3) (e) (2) (f) (1) (g) (2) (h) (1)

Question 1. The correct answers are: (a) (2) (b) (1) (c) (2) (d) (3) (e) (2) (f) (1) (g) (2) (h) (1) Question 1 The correct answers are: a 2 b 1 c 2 d 3 e 2 f 1 g 2 h 1 Question 2 a Any probability measure Q equivalent to P on F 2 can be described by Q[{x 1, x 2 }] := q x1 q x1,x 2, 1 where q x1, q x1,x

More information

The Uniform Integrability of Martingales. On a Question by Alexander Cherny

The Uniform Integrability of Martingales. On a Question by Alexander Cherny The Uniform Integrability of Martingales. On a Question by Alexander Cherny Johannes Ruf Department of Mathematics University College London May 1, 2015 Abstract Let X be a progressively measurable, almost

More information

Convex Stochastic Control and Conjugate Duality in a Problem of Unconstrained Utility Maximization Under a Regime Switching Model

Convex Stochastic Control and Conjugate Duality in a Problem of Unconstrained Utility Maximization Under a Regime Switching Model Convex Stochastic Control and Conjugate Duality in a Problem of Unconstrained Utility Maximization Under a Regime Switching Model by Aaron Xin Situ A thesis presented to the University of Waterloo in fulfilment

More information

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING 218. HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROF. YURI BAKHTIN Instructions. You are allowed to work on solutions in groups, but you are required to write up solutions on your own. Please

More information

Model-free portfolio theory and its functional master formula

Model-free portfolio theory and its functional master formula Model-free portfolio theory and its functional master formula arxiv:66.335v [q-fin.pm] 7 Jun 6 Alexander Schied, Leo Speiser, and Iryna Voloshchenko Department of Mathematics University of Mannheim 683

More information

Sample of Ph.D. Advisory Exam For MathFinance

Sample of Ph.D. Advisory Exam For MathFinance Sample of Ph.D. Advisory Exam For MathFinance Students who wish to enter the Ph.D. program of Mathematics of Finance are required to take the advisory exam. This exam consists of three major parts. The

More information

HJB equations. Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance January 10, 2011

HJB equations. Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance January 10, 2011 Department of Probability and Mathematical Statistics Faculty of Mathematics and Physics, Charles University in Prague petrasek@karlin.mff.cuni.cz Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance

More information

The main purpose of this chapter is to prove the rst and second fundamental theorem of asset pricing in a so called nite market model.

The main purpose of this chapter is to prove the rst and second fundamental theorem of asset pricing in a so called nite market model. 1 2. Option pricing in a nite market model (February 14, 2012) 1 Introduction The main purpose of this chapter is to prove the rst and second fundamental theorem of asset pricing in a so called nite market

More information

The Azéma-Yor Embedding in Non-Singular Diffusions

The Azéma-Yor Embedding in Non-Singular Diffusions Stochastic Process. Appl. Vol. 96, No. 2, 2001, 305-312 Research Report No. 406, 1999, Dept. Theoret. Statist. Aarhus The Azéma-Yor Embedding in Non-Singular Diffusions J. L. Pedersen and G. Peskir Let

More information

Brownian motion. Samy Tindel. Purdue University. Probability Theory 2 - MA 539

Brownian motion. Samy Tindel. Purdue University. Probability Theory 2 - MA 539 Brownian motion Samy Tindel Purdue University Probability Theory 2 - MA 539 Mostly taken from Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus by I. Karatzas and S. Shreve Samy T. Brownian motion Probability Theory

More information

Prof. Erhan Bayraktar (University of Michigan)

Prof. Erhan Bayraktar (University of Michigan) September 17, 2012 KAP 414 2:15 PM- 3:15 PM Prof. (University of Michigan) Abstract: We consider a zero-sum stochastic differential controller-and-stopper game in which the state process is a controlled

More information

Stochastic Volatility and Correction to the Heat Equation

Stochastic Volatility and Correction to the Heat Equation Stochastic Volatility and Correction to the Heat Equation Jean-Pierre Fouque, George Papanicolaou and Ronnie Sircar Abstract. From a probabilist s point of view the Twentieth Century has been a century

More information

Portfolio Optimization in discrete time

Portfolio Optimization in discrete time Portfolio Optimization in discrete time Wolfgang J. Runggaldier Dipartimento di Matematica Pura ed Applicata Universitá di Padova, Padova http://www.math.unipd.it/runggaldier/index.html Abstract he paper

More information

1 Brownian Local Time

1 Brownian Local Time 1 Brownian Local Time We first begin by defining the space and variables for Brownian local time. Let W t be a standard 1-D Wiener process. We know that for the set, {t : W t = } P (µ{t : W t = } = ) =

More information

Necessary Conditions for the Existence of Utility Maximizing Strategies under Transaction Costs

Necessary Conditions for the Existence of Utility Maximizing Strategies under Transaction Costs Necessary Conditions for the Existence of Utility Maximizing Strategies under Transaction Costs Paolo Guasoni Boston University and University of Pisa Walter Schachermayer Vienna University of Technology

More information

(6, 4) Is there arbitrage in this market? If so, find all arbitrages. If not, find all pricing kernels.

(6, 4) Is there arbitrage in this market? If so, find all arbitrages. If not, find all pricing kernels. Advanced Financial Models Example sheet - Michaelmas 208 Michael Tehranchi Problem. Consider a two-asset model with prices given by (P, P 2 ) (3, 9) /4 (4, 6) (6, 8) /4 /2 (6, 4) Is there arbitrage in

More information

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 7 9/25/2013

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 7 9/25/2013 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.65/15.070J Fall 013 Lecture 7 9/5/013 The Reflection Principle. The Distribution of the Maximum. Brownian motion with drift Content. 1. Quick intro to stopping times.

More information

Convergence at first and second order of some approximations of stochastic integrals

Convergence at first and second order of some approximations of stochastic integrals Convergence at first and second order of some approximations of stochastic integrals Bérard Bergery Blandine, Vallois Pierre IECN, Nancy-Université, CNRS, INRIA, Boulevard des Aiguillettes B.P. 239 F-5456

More information

Trading strategies generated by Lyapunov functions

Trading strategies generated by Lyapunov functions Finance Stoch 27) 2:753 787 DOI.7/s78-7-332-8 Trading strategies generated by Lyapunov functions Ioannis Karatzas,2 Johannes Ruf 3 Received: 2 July 26 / Accepted: 3 January 27 / Published online: 25 May

More information

Model-free portfolio theory and its functional master formula

Model-free portfolio theory and its functional master formula Model-free portfolio theory and its functional master formula Alexander Schied Leo Speiser Iryna Voloshchenko arxiv:166.3325v3 [q-fin.pm] 8 Dec 216 First version: June 1, 216 This version: December 8,

More information

Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales

Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales Lecture 21: Representations of Martingales 1 of 11 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 215 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales Right-continuous inverses Let

More information

A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations

A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations Michael Röckner Reference: C. Prevot, M. Röckner: Springer LN in Math. 1905, Berlin (2007) And see the references therein for the original

More information

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING 15. HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROF. YURI BAKHTIN Instructions. You are allowed to work on solutions in groups, but you are required to write up solutions on your own. Please

More information

Some SDEs with distributional drift Part I : General calculus. Flandoli, Franco; Russo, Francesco; Wolf, Jochen

Some SDEs with distributional drift Part I : General calculus. Flandoli, Franco; Russo, Francesco; Wolf, Jochen Title Author(s) Some SDEs with distributional drift Part I : General calculus Flandoli, Franco; Russo, Francesco; Wolf, Jochen Citation Osaka Journal of Mathematics. 4() P.493-P.54 Issue Date 3-6 Text

More information

The Cameron-Martin-Girsanov (CMG) Theorem

The Cameron-Martin-Girsanov (CMG) Theorem The Cameron-Martin-Girsanov (CMG) Theorem There are many versions of the CMG Theorem. In some sense, there are many CMG Theorems. The first version appeared in ] in 944. Here we present a standard version,

More information

Mean-Variance Hedging for Continuous Processes: New Proofs and Examples

Mean-Variance Hedging for Continuous Processes: New Proofs and Examples Mean-Variance Hedging for Continuous Processes: New Proofs and Examples Huyên Pham Équipe d Analyse et de Mathématiques Appliquées Université de Marne-la-Vallée 2, rue de la Butte Verte F 9366 Noisy-le-Grand

More information

Information and Credit Risk

Information and Credit Risk Information and Credit Risk M. L. Bedini Université de Bretagne Occidentale, Brest - Friedrich Schiller Universität, Jena Jena, March 2011 M. L. Bedini (Université de Bretagne Occidentale, Brest Information

More information

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3 Brownian Motion Contents 1 Definition 2 1.1 Brownian Motion................................. 2 1.2 Wiener measure.................................. 3 2 Construction 4 2.1 Gaussian process.................................

More information

Multi-dimensional Stochastic Singular Control Via Dynkin Game and Dirichlet Form

Multi-dimensional Stochastic Singular Control Via Dynkin Game and Dirichlet Form Multi-dimensional Stochastic Singular Control Via Dynkin Game and Dirichlet Form Yipeng Yang * Under the supervision of Dr. Michael Taksar Department of Mathematics University of Missouri-Columbia Oct

More information

Minimal Sufficient Conditions for a Primal Optimizer in Nonsmooth Utility Maximization

Minimal Sufficient Conditions for a Primal Optimizer in Nonsmooth Utility Maximization Finance and Stochastics manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) Minimal Sufficient Conditions for a Primal Optimizer in Nonsmooth Utility Maximization Nicholas Westray Harry Zheng. Received: date

More information

A monetary value for initial information in portfolio optimization

A monetary value for initial information in portfolio optimization A monetary value for initial information in portfolio optimization this version: March 15, 2002; Jürgen Amendinger 1, Dirk Becherer 2, Martin Schweizer 3 1 HypoVereinsbank AG, International Markets, Equity

More information

On the quantiles of the Brownian motion and their hitting times.

On the quantiles of the Brownian motion and their hitting times. On the quantiles of the Brownian motion and their hitting times. Angelos Dassios London School of Economics May 23 Abstract The distribution of the α-quantile of a Brownian motion on an interval [, t]

More information

Exercises. T 2T. e ita φ(t)dt.

Exercises. T 2T. e ita φ(t)dt. Exercises. Set #. Construct an example of a sequence of probability measures P n on R which converge weakly to a probability measure P but so that the first moments m,n = xdp n do not converge to m = xdp.

More information

A Simple Computational Approach to the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing

A Simple Computational Approach to the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 6, 2012, no. 72, 3555-3562 A Simple Computational Approach to the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing Cherng-tiao Perng Department of Mathematics Norfolk State University

More information

Worst Case Portfolio Optimization and HJB-Systems

Worst Case Portfolio Optimization and HJB-Systems Worst Case Portfolio Optimization and HJB-Systems Ralf Korn and Mogens Steffensen Abstract We formulate a portfolio optimization problem as a game where the investor chooses a portfolio and his opponent,

More information

Supermodular ordering of Poisson arrays

Supermodular ordering of Poisson arrays Supermodular ordering of Poisson arrays Bünyamin Kızıldemir Nicolas Privault Division of Mathematical Sciences School of Physical and Mathematical Sciences Nanyang Technological University 637371 Singapore

More information

A MODEL FOR THE LONG-TERM OPTIMAL CAPACITY LEVEL OF AN INVESTMENT PROJECT

A MODEL FOR THE LONG-TERM OPTIMAL CAPACITY LEVEL OF AN INVESTMENT PROJECT A MODEL FOR HE LONG-ERM OPIMAL CAPACIY LEVEL OF AN INVESMEN PROJEC ARNE LØKKA AND MIHAIL ZERVOS Abstract. We consider an investment project that produces a single commodity. he project s operation yields

More information

Supermartingales as Radon-Nikodym Densities and Related Measure Extensions

Supermartingales as Radon-Nikodym Densities and Related Measure Extensions Supermartingales as Radon-Nikodym Densities and Related Measure Extensions Nicolas Perkowski Institut für Mathematik Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin Johannes Ruf Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance

More information

Applications of Ito s Formula

Applications of Ito s Formula CHAPTER 4 Applications of Ito s Formula In this chapter, we discuss several basic theorems in stochastic analysis. Their proofs are good examples of applications of Itô s formula. 1. Lévy s martingale

More information

LECTURE 2: LOCAL TIME FOR BROWNIAN MOTION

LECTURE 2: LOCAL TIME FOR BROWNIAN MOTION LECTURE 2: LOCAL TIME FOR BROWNIAN MOTION We will define local time for one-dimensional Brownian motion, and deduce some of its properties. We will then use the generalized Ray-Knight theorem proved in

More information

An Introduction to Malliavin calculus and its applications

An Introduction to Malliavin calculus and its applications An Introduction to Malliavin calculus and its applications Lecture 3: Clark-Ocone formula David Nualart Department of Mathematics Kansas University University of Wyoming Summer School 214 David Nualart

More information

2 Statement of the problem and assumptions

2 Statement of the problem and assumptions Mathematical Notes, 25, vol. 78, no. 4, pp. 466 48. Existence Theorem for Optimal Control Problems on an Infinite Time Interval A.V. Dmitruk and N.V. Kuz kina We consider an optimal control problem on

More information

Exercises in stochastic analysis

Exercises in stochastic analysis Exercises in stochastic analysis Franco Flandoli, Mario Maurelli, Dario Trevisan The exercises with a P are those which have been done totally or partially) in the previous lectures; the exercises with

More information

Solving the Poisson Disorder Problem

Solving the Poisson Disorder Problem Advances in Finance and Stochastics: Essays in Honour of Dieter Sondermann, Springer-Verlag, 22, (295-32) Research Report No. 49, 2, Dept. Theoret. Statist. Aarhus Solving the Poisson Disorder Problem

More information

Random Times and Their Properties

Random Times and Their Properties Chapter 6 Random Times and Their Properties Section 6.1 recalls the definition of a filtration (a growing collection of σ-fields) and of stopping times (basically, measurable random times). Section 6.2

More information

Robust Mean-Variance Hedging via G-Expectation

Robust Mean-Variance Hedging via G-Expectation Robust Mean-Variance Hedging via G-Expectation Francesca Biagini, Jacopo Mancin Thilo Meyer Brandis January 3, 18 Abstract In this paper we study mean-variance hedging under the G-expectation framework.

More information

I forgot to mention last time: in the Ito formula for two standard processes, putting

I forgot to mention last time: in the Ito formula for two standard processes, putting I forgot to mention last time: in the Ito formula for two standard processes, putting dx t = a t dt + b t db t dy t = α t dt + β t db t, and taking f(x, y = xy, one has f x = y, f y = x, and f xx = f yy

More information

OPTIMAL SOLUTIONS TO STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL INCLUSIONS

OPTIMAL SOLUTIONS TO STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL INCLUSIONS APPLICATIONES MATHEMATICAE 29,4 (22), pp. 387 398 Mariusz Michta (Zielona Góra) OPTIMAL SOLUTIONS TO STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL INCLUSIONS Abstract. A martingale problem approach is used first to analyze

More information

A Change of Variable Formula with Local Time-Space for Bounded Variation Lévy Processes with Application to Solving the American Put Option Problem 1

A Change of Variable Formula with Local Time-Space for Bounded Variation Lévy Processes with Application to Solving the American Put Option Problem 1 Chapter 3 A Change of Variable Formula with Local Time-Space for Bounded Variation Lévy Processes with Application to Solving the American Put Option Problem 1 Abstract We establish a change of variable

More information

On the Multi-Dimensional Controller and Stopper Games

On the Multi-Dimensional Controller and Stopper Games On the Multi-Dimensional Controller and Stopper Games Joint work with Yu-Jui Huang University of Michigan, Ann Arbor June 7, 2012 Outline Introduction 1 Introduction 2 3 4 5 Consider a zero-sum controller-and-stopper

More information

Skorokhod Embeddings In Bounded Time

Skorokhod Embeddings In Bounded Time Skorokhod Embeddings In Bounded Time Stefan Ankirchner Institute for Applied Mathematics University of Bonn Endenicher Allee 6 D-535 Bonn ankirchner@hcm.uni-bonn.de Philipp Strack Bonn Graduate School

More information

LEAST-SQUARES APPROXIMATION OF RANDOM VARIABLES BY STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

LEAST-SQUARES APPROXIMATION OF RANDOM VARIABLES BY STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS LEAST-SQUARES APPROXIMATION OF RANDOM VARIABLES BY STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS CHUNLI HOU Nomura Securities International 2 World Financial Center, Building B New York, NY 1281 chou@us.nomura.com IOANNIS KARATZAS

More information

Backward martingale representation and endogenous completeness in finance

Backward martingale representation and endogenous completeness in finance Backward martingale representation and endogenous completeness in finance Dmitry Kramkov (with Silviu Predoiu) Carnegie Mellon University 1 / 19 Bibliography Robert M. Anderson and Roberto C. Raimondo.

More information

Proving the Regularity of the Minimal Probability of Ruin via a Game of Stopping and Control

Proving the Regularity of the Minimal Probability of Ruin via a Game of Stopping and Control Proving the Regularity of the Minimal Probability of Ruin via a Game of Stopping and Control Erhan Bayraktar University of Michigan joint work with Virginia R. Young, University of Michigan K αρλoβασi,

More information

Minimization of ruin probabilities by investment under transaction costs

Minimization of ruin probabilities by investment under transaction costs Minimization of ruin probabilities by investment under transaction costs Stefan Thonhauser DSA, HEC, Université de Lausanne 13 th Scientific Day, Bonn, 3.4.214 Outline Introduction Risk models and controls

More information

EXTENSIONS OF CONVEX FUNCTIONALS ON CONVEX CONES

EXTENSIONS OF CONVEX FUNCTIONALS ON CONVEX CONES APPLICATIONES MATHEMATICAE 25,3 (1998), pp. 381 386 E. IGNACZAK (Szczecin) A. PASZKIEWICZ ( Lódź) EXTENSIONS OF CONVEX FUNCTIONALS ON CONVEX CONES Abstract. We prove that under some topological assumptions

More information

(2m)-TH MEAN BEHAVIOR OF SOLUTIONS OF STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS UNDER PARAMETRIC PERTURBATIONS

(2m)-TH MEAN BEHAVIOR OF SOLUTIONS OF STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS UNDER PARAMETRIC PERTURBATIONS (2m)-TH MEAN BEHAVIOR OF SOLUTIONS OF STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS UNDER PARAMETRIC PERTURBATIONS Svetlana Janković and Miljana Jovanović Faculty of Science, Department of Mathematics, University

More information

PROGRESSIVE ENLARGEMENTS OF FILTRATIONS AND SEMIMARTINGALE DECOMPOSITIONS

PROGRESSIVE ENLARGEMENTS OF FILTRATIONS AND SEMIMARTINGALE DECOMPOSITIONS PROGRESSIVE ENLARGEMENTS OF FILTRATIONS AND SEMIMARTINGALE DECOMPOSITIONS Libo Li and Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney NSW 26, Australia July 1, 211 Abstract We

More information

UNCERTAINTY FUNCTIONAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS FOR FINANCE

UNCERTAINTY FUNCTIONAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS FOR FINANCE Surveys in Mathematics and its Applications ISSN 1842-6298 (electronic), 1843-7265 (print) Volume 5 (2010), 275 284 UNCERTAINTY FUNCTIONAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS FOR FINANCE Iuliana Carmen Bărbăcioru Abstract.

More information

MAXIMAL COUPLING OF EUCLIDEAN BROWNIAN MOTIONS

MAXIMAL COUPLING OF EUCLIDEAN BROWNIAN MOTIONS MAXIMAL COUPLING OF EUCLIDEAN BOWNIAN MOTIONS ELTON P. HSU AND KAL-THEODO STUM ABSTACT. We prove that the mirror coupling is the unique maximal Markovian coupling of two Euclidean Brownian motions starting

More information