Indeterminacy, Aggregate Demand, and the Real Business Cycle

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Indeterminacy, Aggregate Demand, and the Real Business Cycle"

Transcription

1 Indeterminacy, Aggregate Demand, and the Real Business Cycle Jess Benhabib Department of Economics New York University Yi Wen Department of Economics Cornell University October 24, 2000 Abstract We show that under indeterminacy aggregate demand shocks are able to explain not only aspects of actual fluctuations that standard RBC models predict fairly well, but also aspects of actual fluctuations that standard RBC models cannot explain, such as the hump-shaped, trend reverting impulse responses to transitory shocks found in US output, investment, and hours. Indeterminacy arises in our model due to capacity utilization andmildincreasingreturnstoscale. We wish to thank Jordi Gali, Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé, Karl Shell, and Martin Uribe for very useful discussions and comments. Technical support from the C.V. Starr Center for Applied Economics at New York University is gratefully acknowledged.

2 1. Introduction Recently, general equilibrium real business cycle models have been subject to a number of criticisms. A basic criticism is the heavy reliance of such models on technology shocks to explain business cycle facts (for example, Blanchard, 1993; Cochrane, 1994; Evans, 1992; Gordon, 1993; Mankiw, 1989; Summers, 1986). Another is the lack of an endogenous amplification and propagation mechanism, which has resulted in the failure of standard RBC models to explain the large hump-shaped, trend-reverting output responses to transitory shocks (Cogley and Nason, 1995, Watson, 1993). Finally, real business cycle models have been criticized for failing to match the forecastable comovements of basic macroeconomic variables observed in the data (see Rotemberg and Woodford, 1996). 1 These problems are not unrelated. Demand shocks are thought to be important for generating the business cycle because components of aggregate demand, such as consumption and investment, may reinforce each other, resulting in a multiplieraccelerator mechanism that can generate highly persistent, trend-reverting output dynamics. The mutual reinforcement among components of aggregate demand is possible if there exists unutilized resources that allow for the expansion of output with little or no increase in marginal costs in the short run, meeting or fulfilling the rise of total demand. In contrast, all resources in equilibrium business cycle models are fully utilized because prices adjust quickly to clear the markets. Under the assumption of the diminishing marginal product of labor, demand shocks would have a crowdingout effect, resulting in the negative comovements of the components of aggregate demand and in having minimal impact on aggregate employment and output. Consequently, standard RBC models have relied on supply shocks to explain the business cycle. In this paper we show how to capture the more Keynesian features of the demand-shock driven business cycle without abandoning the hypotheses of market clearing and flexible prices. There are three essential elements in our model that when acting together, can generate the business cycle facts observed in data, and meet the criticisms directed at the RBC model. The first is variable capacity 1 Recently many efforts have been made to find ways to enrich the internal propagation mechanisms of RBC models driven by technology shocks. Prominent examples include Burnside and Eichenbaum, 1996, Andolfatto, 1996, and Carlstrom and Fuerst,

3 utilization. The second is the presence of demand shocks that exhibit some persistence. The third is the presence of small and empirically reasonable externalities that gives rise to indeterminacy. 2 We show that these three elements are essential and indispensable in order to generate a propagation mechanism that amplifies the impact of temporary demand shocks on output, investment and hours in a hump-shaped manner. 3,4 Variable capacity utilization has the effect ofincreasingthemarginalproduct of labor in the short-run by enhancing the output elasticity of labor. Coupled with a mild production externality that is consistent with recent empirical estimates, it makes the model behave as if there were short-run increasing returns to the labor input. This factor is crucial not only because it generates the desired forecastable comovements in consumption, investment, hours and output, but also because it gives rise to the indeterminacy that generates the hump-shaped, trend reverting time series observed in the data by enriching the internal dynamics of the model. We examine three different types of aggregate demand shocks: shocks to consumption demand, shocks to government spending, and sunspot shocks to investors animal spirits. 5 We investigate whether the endogenous propagation mechanism induced by indeterminacy is capable of giving these demand shocks a primary role in explaining the business cycle. Among other things, we find: a) All three types of demand shocks can each generate positive comovements among output, consumption, investment and hours that are comparable to predictions of standard RBC models under technology shocks. b) Small transitory demand shocks to consumption and government expenditure can generate large, humpshaped, trend-reverting impulse responses for output, investment and hours. c) Combined with shocks to investors animal spirits, each of these fundamental de- 2 For an excellent and thorough analysis of why models of indeterminacy driven by sunspots alone cannot improve much upon the standard RBC model, see Schmitt-Grohe (2000), and also Schmitt-Grohe, (1997). For a general survey of the literature of indeterminacy and sunspots in macroeconomics, see Benhabib and Farmer (1999). 3 Although small external effects can give rise to indeterminacy, externalities that do not generate indeterminacy will not give rise to hump-shaped dynamics. In our model, the minimum degree of returns to scale induced by externalities necessary for indeterminacy is in the range of , which is plausible even judged by the more recent empirical estimates on returns to scale (e.g., Basu and Fernald, 1997; and Burnside, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo, 1995). 4 The emergence of hump-shaped impulse responses to monetary shocks has been discussed in models with credit constraints when there are investment delays. See Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist, Sunspot shocks or extrinsic uncertainty were intoduced into the economics literature by Shell (1977) and by Cass and Shell (1983). 3

4 mand shocks can generate autocorrelation functions for output growth, investment growth, and hours growth that closely match the post-war US economy. 6 The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we present further empirical evidence on the trend-reverting dynamics for the US economy. In particular, we show that the responses of consumption, investment, and hours to temporary demand shocks all have hump-shaped features, and they are strongly correlated with output. In section 3, we show that a general equilibrium model featuring indeterminacy is capable of explaining these stylized dynamics with aggregate demand shocks. The model is tested using the method proposed by Cogley and Nason (1995) in section 4. Section 5 concludes the paper. 2. Stylized Responses to Demand Following Blanchard and Quah (1989) and Cogley and Nason (1995), we decompose aggregate output, consumption, investment, and hours into two components, one that pertains to permanent shocks, and the other that pertains to transitory shocks. The transitory components in these variables are interpreted by Blanchard and Quah as fluctuations due to aggregate demand shocks. We use the ratio of investment to output as the covariate in a series of bivariate VAR analyses to carry out the Blanchard -Quah decomposition. 7 Balanced growth in RBC models implies that the investment to output ratio is stationary. The demand shocks so identified have the natural interpretation of being disturbances that affect shortrun aggregate savings, such as temporary changes in government spending, in consumers preferences, and in firms autonomous investment. These demand shocks are perfectly matched by our general equilibrium model. 8 Figure 1 shows impulse responses to demand from output, consumption, investment, and hours respectively. They all exhibit the familiar hump-shaped, trend-reverting dynamics. These dynamics are very similar to those identified by 6 Sunspots cannot by themselves generate the hump-shaped dynamics, as has been demonstrated by Schmitt-Grohe (2000). 7 Namely, the growth rate of output, consumption, investment, and hours are each paired with the investment to output ratio to identify the permanent and transitory components of each series. This is similar to Cochrane (1994) who uses consumption to output ratio as the covariate. 8 Cogley and Nason (1995) use per capita hours as the covariate in carrying out the Blanchard- Quah decomposition. We choose the investment to output ratio also because it seems to be more stationary than the per capita hours series for post-war US economy. The impulse responses identified for the two covariates are nevertheless very similar. 4

5 Blanchard and Quah (1989), and the responses of different variables move very closely together. To further ensure that the responses so identified reflect responses to demand disturbances, we also use the government expenditure to GDP ratio as the covariate in carrying out the Blanchard-Quah decomposition. The identified responses to innovations in the government expenditure to GDP ratio are very similar to those identified using the investment to output ratio. 9 Figure 2 shows the implied autocorrelation functions (ACF) for growth rates. The transitory components of all four variables exhibit positive serial correlation in growth rates for lags of the first two quarters, and show negative serial correlation in growth rates for lags beyond three to four quarters. This is consistent with the empirical findings of Cogley and Nason (1995). As is pointed out by Cogley and Nason, a central weakness of the real-businesscycle paradigm as a convincing explanation of the business cycle is its failure to account for the above stylized business cycle dynamics. Under transitory demand shocks, standard RBC models generate monotonic impulse responses for output, negative serial autocorrelation for output growth, and negative cross correlation of consumption and investment. In other words, contrary to conventional wisdom and postwar US data, demand shocks do not seem to have fully expansionary multiplier effects in RBC models. This is illustrated in figure Searching for the Propagation Mechanism In this section, we show how to bring the real business cycle paradigm into closer conformity with the data. In particular, we show that indeterminacy arising from 9 The data used are log quarterly US real fixed investment, consumption expenditure on nondurables and services, and total government expenditure. All data series are from CITIBASE (1960:1-1994:4). Output is defined as the sum of consumption, investment, and government expenditure. 2 lags are used in the VAR estimation. Both the investment to output ratio and the government spending to GDP ratio have a weak time trend. We used two different detrending methods in the VAR estimation to render stationarity for the covariate. One uses a linear time trend and the other uses the Hodrick-Prescott trend (i.e., the HP filtered investment to output ratio was used as the covariate in bivariate VAR analyses). The results are very similar for both typesoftrend.thehp-trendcasesarereportedinfigure1. 10 Figure 3 shows the impulse responses of output and investment in the King-Plosser-Rebelo (1988) model to a consumption demand shock. The responses of the model to a government spending shock are very similar. The consumption demand shock follows an AR(1) process and is modeled as a disturbance to the subsistence level in the utility function, as in Baxter and King (1992). For more detailed description about shocks to consumption demand and government expenditure, see Section 3. 5

6 variable capacity utilization and mild externalities enables demand shocks to play an essential role in replicating the actual business cycle fluctuations The Model This is the one-sector RBC model with variable capacity utilization studied by Wen (1998), based on Greenwood et al. (1989), Burnside and Eichenbaum (1996), Baxter and King (1992), Benhabib and Farmer (1994), and Farmer and Guo (1994). A representative agent in the model chooses sequences of consumption, hours, capacity utilization, and capital accumulation to solve Ã! X max E 0 β t log(c t t ) a n1+γ t 1+γ t=0 subject to c t + i t + g t = Φ t (e t k t ) α n (1 α) t, (3.1) k t+1 = i t +(1 δ t )k t ; where is a random shock to the subsistence level of consumption, which can generate the urge to consume (Baxter and King, 1992); g is government spending and is modeled as an exogenous stochastic process representing a pure resource drain on the economy (Christiano and Eichenbaum, 1992); e [0, 1] denotes capital utilization rate, and Φ is a measure of production externalities and is defined as a function of average aggregate output which individuals take as parametric: Φ = h (ek) α n 1 αi η, η 0. (3.2) When the externality parameter η is zero, the model is reduced to a standard RBC model studied by Greenwood et al (1988). To have an interior solution for e in the steady state, we follow Greenwood et al. by assuming that the capital stock depreciates faster if it is used more intensively: δ t = λe θ t, θ > 1; (3.3) which imposes a convex cost structure on capital utilization. To facilitate comparison with the existing literature, we assume that all shocks to fundamentals follow univariate AR(1) processes in log: " log( t ) log(g t ) # = " 1 ρ ρ g #" γ γ g # 6 + " ρ 0 0 ρ g #" log( t 1 ) log(g t 1 ) # + " ε t ε gt #,

7 where Ã! " # ε t σ 2 var = 0 ε gt 0 σg 2. Notice that innovations in the fundamental shocks are assumed to be orthogonal. To solve the model, we log-linearize the first order conditions around the steady state as in King et al. (1988). To allow for the study of investors animal spirits as a possible source of aggregate demand uncertainty, we arrange the system of linearized equations in a way such that investment rather than the Lagrangian multiplier appears in the state vector. Denoting S as the state vector, and Z as the vector of control variables, the model can be reduced to the following system of linear difference equations (the hat variables denote percentage deviations from their steady state values): S t+1 = WS t + RΘ t+1, Z t = HS t ; where S t = h ˆkt î t ˆ t ĝ t i 0, Zt = h ĉ t ˆn t ê t i 0 and Θ t+1 is a vector of one-step ahead forecasting errors that satisfy ĝ t+1 Θ t+1 = S t+1 E t S t+1, and E t Θ t+1 =0. Notice that the first element in Θ t+1 = k t+1 E t k t+1 =0, since k t+1 is known at the beginning of time t; the last two elements in Θ t+1 =[ε +1 ε gt+1 ] 0, and the second element in Θ t+1 = i t+1 E t i t+1. Thus the law of motion for the model s state vector can be written as: ˆk t+1 ω 11 ω 12 ω 13 ω 14 ˆk t î t+1 ˆ = ω 21 ω 22 ω 23 ω 24 î t t ρ 0 ˆ + r 1 r 2 r ε t+1 3 ε t gt+1 (3.4) v ρ g st+1 where v st+1 î t+1 E t î t+1. When the equilibrium is unique, one of the eigenvalues of W should lie outside the unit circle, so that investment i t can be determined uniquely by solving forward the system under the expectation operator E t to obtain a decision rule for i(t) that depends only on current capital stock k t and 7 ĝ t

8 time t realizations to the fundamentals { t,g t }. If both eigenvalues of W lie inside the unit circle, however, the steady state is stable. In that case, the model is indeterminate and has multiple equilibria. Hence, the state space of the model includes not only the capital stock and the realizations of the exogenous state variables, { t,g t }, but also the time t investment i t. Notice that under indeterminacy the decision rule for the initial investment at time t (starting from the steady state) takes the special form: î t = r 1 ε t + r 2 ε gt + r 3 v st. Under rational expectations, the forecasting error, v st = i t E t 1 i t, follows i.i.d processes, implying that rational agents do not make systematic errors in forecasting the future. Since v st can either reflect innovations in fundamentals or be purely extraneous, it can be called sunspots or animal spirits, and can be interpreted as shocks to autonomous investment. We define the vector V t =(ε t, ε gt,v st ) 0, where v st denotes sunspots. 11 There are potentially three types of aggregate demand disturbances in the model: innovations to government spending ε g, innovations to consumption demand ε, and innovations to autonomous investment v s. Hence, sunspots can act as an equilibrium selection device. The covariance matrix for V is given by: Σ = σ 2 0 σ s 0 σ 2 g σ gs σ s σ gs σ 2 s where the correlations between sunspots and innovations in the fundamentals can take values in the interval [ 1, 1]. Since the linear version of the model imposes no restrictions on the variance and covariance of sunspots, they need to be specified exogenously. Notice that in the decision rule for î t, the first two terms including r 1 and r 2 are completely determined by preferences and technologies of the model, but the third term is arbitrary, depending on the variance of sunspots. We can thereforetakethenormalizationr 3 =1. To see how the model responds to shocks under indeterminacy, take the simpler case where the shocks are all i.i.d (ρ = ρ g =0). Starting from the steady state at time t, wehave: ³ˆkt 1, î t 1, ˆ t 1, ĝ t 1 =0. In addition, we have ˆkt =0. Time t innovations (ε t, ε gt,v st )thusaffect the control vector Z t through their impact on 11 When v s contains innovations to the fundamental shocks, it implies that the sunspots are correlated with fundamental shocks. 8,

9 (i t, t,g t ). Therefore, autonomous investment is clearly important in determining the initial responses of the model. However, how the initial impact of shocks gets propagated through time does not depend so much on autonomous investment. Rather, it depends crucially on the eigenvalues of the matrix, " # ω11 ω Ω = 12. ω 21 ω 22 This is so because impulse responses j periods ahead are determined by the autoregressive equation: " ˆkt+j î t+j # = Ω j " ˆkt î t #, j =1, 2, 3,...,. The eigenvalues of Ω therefore govern the patterns of propagation. If the eigenvalues are complex, for example, the model economy will oscillate around the steady state after an initial disturbance, showing profoundly different propagation mechanism from the cases where the eigenvalues are real valued. If the model is determinate, however, it has only monotonic transitional dynamics (in the standard RBC case where ω > 0) because the law of motion for the state vector reduces to ˆk t+1 = ωˆk t. This illustrates why indeterminacy can profoundly change the propagation mechanism of a RBC model. To quantify the model s eigenvalues, we calibrate the structural parameters of the model as follows. We set the capital share α to 0.3, thetimediscountfactorβ to 0.99, the inverse elasticity of labor supply γ to 0, and choose θ such that the rate of capital depreciation in the steady state is 10 percent a year. The externality parameter η is most crucial in the model and is left free for experiments. Table 1 reports the model s eigenvalues when the externality η takes on different values. The first column lists the values of η, the second column lists the corresponding eigenvalues, and the third column lists the modulus of the complex eigenvalues, which indicate indeterminacy if the modulus is less than one. 9

10 Table 1. Ext. (η) Eigenvalues Modulus , , , , , ±0.377i ±0.375i ±0.351i ±0.327i ±0.289i ±0.085i ±0.060i ±0.049i It is seen from Table 1 that indeterminacy and complex roots emerge under mild externalities. The minimum degree of the externality required for indeterminacy is 0.104, 12 and that for complex roots is 0.105, implying a degree of aggregate returns at the scale around , which is very plausible even when judged by recent empirical studies (e.g., Basu and Fernald, 1997; and Burnside et al., 1995). 13 Notice that the aggregate labor demand curve is downward sloping as in Benhabib and Farmer (1996) when indeterminacy arises in the model, which is in sharp contrast to the earlier model of Benhabib and Farmer (1994) Impulse responses to demand shocks Asabenchmark,weassumethatΣ is diagonal. The parameters associated with exogenous variables are chosen as follows. We set the persistence parameter for g as ρ g =0.9 (a magnitude similar to that estimated by Christiano and Eichenbaum, 12 One of the eigenvalues changes sign from + to between η = and η = The degree of externality required for indeterminacy can be reduced even further if the time discount factor β is larger or if the steady-state depreciation rate is higher. For example, when β = 0.995, the minimum value of η for indeterminacy reduces to Complex eigenvalues arise for η = The slope of the aggregate labor demand curve (in logs) is given by (1 α)(1 + η) 1. For example, when η =0.108, the slope is

11 1992), and the persistence parameter for as ρ =0.9 (a magnitude similar to that estimated by Baxter and King, 1992). In order to highlight the dramatic effect of indeterminacy, two different values of η are used in generating impulse responses of the model. Figure 4 corresponds to the case of η =0.1 where the steady state is a saddle and the equilibrium is unique. It shows the impulse responses of output, consumption, investment and hours to one standard deviation increases in ε (solid lines) and ε g (dashed lines) respectively. Figure 5 corresponds to the case of η =0.108 where the steady state is a sink and the equilibrium is indeterminate. It shows impulse responses of income, consumption, investment and hours to a one standard deviation increase in ε (solid lines), in ε g (long dashed lines), and in ε s (short dashed lines) respectively. Several features of the model that generate Figure 4 deserve mention. First, capacity utilization and a mild externality can generate positive comovements in the model under shocks to demand. This is in stark contrast with the standard RBC model examined by Baxter and King (1992), where an extremely high externality is necessary to generate positive comovements. Second, the impulse responses of all variables to demand shocks are still monotonic, as opposed to hump-shaped, when the steady state is a saddle, despite the presence of capacity utilization and increasing returns. Figure 5 shows a completely different picture when the externality η is slightly increased to a level such that the capacity-utilization augmented short-run returns to labor are greater than one and indeterminacy is present. 15 The impulse response of output to fundamental demand shocks becomes hump-shaped, revealing a significant change in the model s dynamic structure. The output response to sunspots (long dashed lines), although continuing to show positive comovements with other variables, nevertheless fails to exhibit the initial hump. This observation, that sunspots cannot generate hump-shaped impulse responses for output, has been discussed by Schmitt-Grohe (2000) The social returns to labor is only 1.108(1 α) = Variable capacity utilization makes the model behave as if the short-run output elasticity of labor is greater than one. According to Wen (1998), the capacity utilization augmented short-run elasticity of labor is θ (1 α)(1 + η) θ α(1 + η) = See Wen (1998c) for detailed analyses on the dynamic effect of capacity utilization on returns to labor. 16 It is worth emphasizing that the hump-shaped impulse responses of output to the funda- 11

12 So far we have not allowed the model to respond simultaneously to both fundamental shocks and sunspots. Figure 5 suggests that mixing fundamental shocks and sunspots shocks should not destroy the hump-shaped impulse response patterns of the model as long as the variance of sunspots is not extremely large relative to that of fundamental shocks. Figure 6 compares several possible response functions of output to a fundamental shock (ε ) and sunspots (ε s ) when the correlation between ε and ε s takes five possible values: σ s = {1, 0.5, 0, 0.5, 1}. We choose the standard deviation of ε to be one, and that of the sunspots to be It is seen in figure 6 that regardless the correlations between sunspots and fundamentals, the impulse response functions of output are always hump-shaped. As a matter of fact, if the relative standard deviation of sunspots is allowed to vary instead of being fixed at 0.5, the model can generate any one of those impulse response functions shown in figure 6 for any given σ s. This means that adding sunspots will certainly improves the model s empirical fit since the model tends to generate too much hump under fundamental shocks alone (Figure 5). 18 The hump-shaped propagation mechanism that arises under indeterminacy can be understood as follows. In a standard RBC model without indeterminacy, the only channel of propagation is capital accumulation. This, however, is an extremely weak channel for transmitting the impact of shocks, because capital is a stock while investment is a flow. Given that the steady-state investment to capital ratio is small, even a large change in the current investment flow induced by a technology shock would have little impact on the next period capital stock. In addition, since higher consumption in the next period is accompanied by higher leisure, labor supply would immediately fall after the impact period, which would effectively terminate the possibility of continuous increases in output. For the same reason, a demand shock can only generate a negative comovement between and consumption and investment. Therefore, in the standard RBC model, output mental demand shocks do not depend on the persistence of these shocks. Even when they are i.i.d processes, the impulse responses are still hump-shaped, except that the humps are too sharp and are less smooth than the data. 17 To compute the impulse responses of output to multiple shocks, we draw two i.i.d processes from standard normal distributions (taking the first process as ε t ), and mix them in various degrees to form the sunspots variable ε st so that the correlation between sunspots and the first series equal exactly to the pre-specified values. We then generate artificial time series of output by simulating the model. The impulse response functions of output for each possible case in figure 6 are estimated using the corresponding artificial data sample. 18 Sunspots help here because they change the magnitude of initial responses of the model, so as to make them less hump-shaped. 12

13 dynamics mirrors the dynamics of technology shocks (for more detailed analyses of the propagation mechanism of standard RBC models, see Wen, 1995). By contrast, in our model, variable capacity utilization offers an additional channel of propagation that can propagate not only supply shocks but also demand shocks in a manner that better conforms to the data. Variable capacity utilization coupled with a mild externality on labor mimics increasing returns to labor, inducing consumption and labor to comove in response to a demand shock. Therefore, even in response to a demand shock, output can rise sufficiently to permit positive investment and a higher capital stock in the next period. Since consumption follows permanent income, a higher future capital stock, coupled with the persistence of demand shocks, leads to higher future consumption, and therefore to higher future labor supply and higher future output. Continuous output expansion is thus sustainable by aggregate demand. In other words, the propagation mechanism in our model is powerful not because more capital stock leads to more output, but because more capital stock leads to more consumption demand (the permanent-income or wealth effect), which in turn leads to higher capacity utilization, more employment and more output (the returns-to-scale effect) in subsequent periods. This is a cumulative process of expansion, similar to a classic multiplier-accelerator mechanism. As the expansion continues, the rising marginal cost of capacity utilization, and the diminishing marginal product of capital dictate a tapering off in the increases of output and a decline in the growth rate of the capital stock. The result is that sooner or later, the capital stock and output must stop growing, and hence consumption must begin to fall. A reduction in consumption demand then triggers a contraction in labor supply and in output. As the contraction begins, the propagation mechanism reverses direction, leading to a cumulative process of contraction. When the capital stock falls, however, its marginal product starts to rise, and a new round of expansion eventually follows. The non-monotonic and cumulative dynamics of output growth therefore depends crucially on the richer two-dimensional dynamics of indeterminacy that allows these oscillatory hump-shaped impulse responses. 4. An Econometric Test Cogley and Nason demonstrate that standard RBC models cannot explain two stylized facts about US GDP: positive serial correlation of GDP growth and a hump-shaped, trend reverting impulse response function to innovations in the 13

14 temporary component. Accordingly, this section employs the same econometric procedure proposed by Cogley and Nason to test whether indeterminacy has the potential to account for the aspects of actual fluctuations which the standard realbusiness-cycle paradigm cannot explain. Specifically, we calibrate and estimate the model s parameters and ask how likely it is that the actual US sample time series are generated from a world that is equivalent to our model. We calibrate most of the parameters following the existing literature. Specifically, we set the capital share α to 0.3, thetimediscountfactorβ to 0.99, the steady-state rate of capital depreciation δ to 0.025, the inverse labor supply elasticity γ to 0 (Hansen, 1985), the persistence parameter for government spending ρ g to 0.96 (estimated by Christiano and Eichenbaum, 1992), the persistence parameter for consumption shock ρ to 0.97 (estimated by Baxter and King, 1992), and the externality parameter η to (consistent with indeterminacy). We arbitrarily set the standard deviation of sunspots, σ s =0.01, and choose parameters, {σ, σ g }, so that each of them acting alone with the sunspots can generate autocorrelation functions of output growth that matches the data as closely as possible. 19 To show the robustness of our empirical results, we let the correlation between sunspots and fundamental shocks take different values between 1 and 1, so as to show that the model s successes do not depend on whether and how sunspots are correlated with fundamentals. These parameterizations are reported in Table 2 (the pre-specified values for cross correlation between sunspots and fundamentals are listed on the last two columns). 19 This is equivalent to an informal estimation procedure called methods of moments widely adopted in the RBC literature. Notice in table 2 that as the correlation parameter changes, σ changes accordingly but σ g barely changes at all. 14

15 Table 2. Calibration σ σ g σ s σ s σ gs Model Ω 0.01 Model A Model A Model A Model A Model A Model B Model B Model B Model B Model B Model Ω is our benchmark that has sunspots shocks only. Then we add consumption demand shocks (models A 1 A 5 ) and government shocks (models B 1 B 5 ) respectively into the environment. We test each of these versions of the model with respect to impulse response functions and autocorrelation functions by computing the generalized Q test statistics, which are defined as follows: Q =(ĉ c) 0 ˆV 1 c (ĉ c). The vector ĉ is the sample impulse response function or autocorrelation function, and c is the mean of N (= 500) simulated impulse response functions or autocorrelation functions computed from simulated time series of the same length as the actual data, namely, 140 quarters. 20 That is, c = 1 N P Ni=1 c i. The covariance matrix, ˆV c, is estimated by ˆV c = 1 N NX (c i c)(c i c) 0. i=1 The test statistic Q has approximate χ 2 distribution with degrees of freedom equal to the number of elements in c. Following Cogley and Nason, the number of lags 20 Since all shocks in the model are transitory demand shocks (there are no permanent demand shocks), we do not use the Blanchard-Quah decomposition to estimate conditional impulse response functions. Instead, a univariate VAR is sufficient to obtain the conditional impulse response functions for each variable. We use a lag length of four in the univariate VARs. The autocorrelatiion functions are simply computed by their formula. 15

16 chosen is 8, which gives a critical value of 20.1 at the 1% significance level and a critical value of 15.5 atthe5%significance level. The test results for autocorrelation function of growth are reported in table 3. The benchmark model Ω driven by sunspots only perform poorly in matching the data, consistent with the findings of Schmitt-Grohe (2000). The various versions of the model (A 1 B 5 ) driven by a combination of one of the fundamental demand shocks and sunspots, however, perform extremely well with respect to all variables except consumption growth. The results indicate that the covariance between sunspots and fundamental shocks do not matter, as long as both types of shocks are present. We have also added in table 3 (last row) the version (Model C) in which all three types of shocks are present, so as to see whether it can improve the match on consumption growth. Figure 5 suggests that the 3 types of shocks have very different effect on consumption, suggesting that a mixture of them can generate a hump-shaped consumption response function similar to the data. The last row in table 3 confirmsthisconjecture. Table 3. Q Statistics Q acf y i n c Model Ω A A A A A B B B B B Model C The test statistics for the output impulse response function show similar results. Namely, the models driven by fundamental shocks (either ε or ε g )along with sunspots perform much better than the models driven by sunspot shocks alone. To see this graphically, figures 7, 8, and 9 show the output impulse response functions of three different versions of the model respectively. Figure 7 corresponds to model Ω, figure 8 corresponds to model A (version 3), and figure 8 16

17 corresponds to model B (version 3). 21 It is seen that allowing for demand shocks to preferences or government expenditure in the model produces very good matches to the data with regard to output dynamics (the Q test statistics are 4.1 and 2.5 respectively), while the benchmark model (driven by sunspots only) fails to generate the initial hump in the response function of output, resulting in an autocorrelation function of output growth that falls short in matching the data. Hence, persistent AR(1) demand shocks to fundamentals are essential for explaining the US business cycles. 22 The impulse response functions for investment and hours, even though they have very similar shapes to those of the data (see Figure 10), fail the Q test. This is so because our model does not generate the exact relative volatilities for investment and hours. 23 The Q test statistics are very sensitive to even such small level differentials and therefore tend to magnify the difference between model and data. Hence, despite the very close matches for the impulse response functions between our model and the data, our model fails the Q test with respect to investment and hours. Finally, we check whether the model is able to explain aspects of actual fluctuations that standard RBC models predict fairly well, with respect to the small number of second moments stressed by Kydland and Prescott (1982). Table 4 shows that our model is comparable to the standard model of King, Plosser and Rebelo (1988) It makes little difference which version of type A or type B to use. 22 Notice that persistent AR(1) shocks do not generate hump-shaped impulse responses in standard RBC models (see figure 3 and Cogley and Nason, 1995). 23 The variance of the shocks in our model are adjusted to match the response of output to the impulse at the period of impact. An alternative strategy may be to choose the variance of the shocks to match a weighted sum of the initial responses of these key variables to the impulse so as to further improve their Q statistics. 24 The common parameters of the models are the same. Notice that, as expected, consumption is too smooth under the government and sunspot demand shocks, but not under the preference shock. A combination of the three demand shocks and the technology shock, properly weighted, can be used to further improve the match between the data and the model. 17

18 Table 4. Selective Moments σ c /σ y σ i /σ y σ n /σ y corr(c, y) corr(i, y) corr(n, y) US Economy (1960:4-1994:4) RBC Model: Technology Shock EBC Model: Consumption Shock EBC Model: Government Shock EBC Model: Sunspot Shock EBC Model: Consumption + Sunspot EBC Model: Government + Sunspot Comovements of Output, Hours, and Consumption Rotemberg and Woodford (1996) highlight another characteristic of economic fluctuations that is difficult for the real-business-cycle paradigm to explain. They show that, in US data, forecastable changes in output, hours, investment and consumption are positively correlated, whereas standard RBC models imply that hours and consumption move in opposite directions in approaching the steady state after the impact period of a permanent technology shock. They also show that the problem can be solved within the standard RBC framework if the preferences are such that the degree of intertemporal substitution and the elasticity of labor supply are both substantially reduced. These modifications however significantly worsen the model s ability to explain the moments of the data along other dimensions. Specifically, the volatility of hours becomes too low and that of consumption becomes too high in comparison with the data. Our model addresses the co-movement problem by mimicking short-run increasing returns to labor, which induce hours and consumption to move together along the model s transition path towards the steady state. The whole issue can 25 The data are detrended by the HP filter. 26 The AR(1) autocoefficient is EBC stands for our endogenous business cycle model. 18

19 be illustrated using the labor market equilibrium condition given by u n (1 n) =u c w where the left-hand side is the marginal cost of labor supply measured in utility terms and the right-hand side is the marginal benefit of labor supply measured in utility terms. In a standard RBC model capital moves little in the short run. As hours go up, the real wage, w, goes down, so the right-hand side of the equation decreases. On the other hand, since leisure goes down, the marginal utility of leisure goes up. So the left-hand side increases. To balance the equation, consumption has to decrease in order to increase the marginal utility u c. RBC models solve the co-movement problem by introducing technology shocks that increase the real wage. However, as is noted by Rotemberg and Woodford, this solves the problem at the impact period, but at least with permanent shocks, negative comovements are likely during the periods of transition towards the steady state. In the reduced form of our model the real wage is an increasing function of hours due to the combination of variable capacity utilization and external effects, and therefore the labor market equation above implies a positive co-movement between consumption and hours. 5. Conclusion In this paper we have demonstrated that an equilibrium real business cycle model incorporating variable capacity utilization, persistent demand shocks and indeterminacy is capable of explaining aggregate fluctuations. In such a model demand shocks can generate not only positive comovements among consumption, investment, hours and output, but also the trend reverting hump-shaped time series exhibited by these macroeconomic variables. It should be possible to further enrich the model by combining it with equilibrium models that introduce a role for money. 19

20 References [1] D. Andolfatto, 1996, Business cycles and labor-market search, American Economic Review 86 (March), [2] S. Basu and J. Fernald, 1997, Returns to scale in US production: estimates and implications, Journal of Political Economy 105 (April), [3] M. Baxter and R. King, 1992, Productive externality and cyclical volatility. Working paper 245, University of Rochester. [4] J. Benhabib and R. Farmer, Indeterminacy and increasing returns, Journal of Economic Theory 63 (1994), [5] J. Benhabib and R. Farmer, 1996, Indeterminacy and sector-specific externalities, Journal of Monetary Economics 37, [6] J. Benhabib and R. Farmer, 1999, Indeterminacy and sunspots in macroeconomics, Handbook for Macroeconomics, eds. John Taylor and Michael Woodford, North-Holland, New York, volume 1A, [7] B. S. Bernanke, M. Gertler and S. Gilchrist, 1999, The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework, in Handbook of Macroeconomics, eds. J. Taylor and M. Woodford, Elsevier, volume 1C, [8] O. Blanchard, 1993, Consumption and the recession of , American Economic Review 93 (May), [9] O. Blanchard and D. Quah, 1989, The dynamic effects of aggregate demand and supply disturbances, American Economic Review 79, [10] C. Burnside and M. Eichenbaum, 1996, Factor hoarding and the propagation of business cycle shocks, American Economic Review 86 (December), [11] C. Burnside, M. Eichenbaum and S. Rebelo, 1993, Labor hoarding and the business cycle, Journal of Political Economy 101, [12] C. Carlstrom and T. Fuerst, 1997, Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuations: A computable general equilibrium analysis, American Economic Review 87 (December),

21 [13] D. Cass and K. Shell, 1983, Do sunspots matter? Journal of Political Economy 91, [14] L. Christiano and M. Eichenbaum, 1992, Current real-business-cycle theories and aggregate labor-market fluctuations, American Economic Review 82, [15] J. Cochrane, 1994, Shocks, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 41, [16] T. Cogley and J. Nason, 1995, Output dynamics in real-business-cycle models, American Economic Review 85, [17] C. Evans, 1992, Productivity shocks and real business cycles, Journal of Monetary Economics 29, [18] R. Farmer and J. T. Guo, 1994, Real business Cycles and the animal spirits hypothesis, Journal of Economic Theory 63, [19] R. Gordon, 1993, Are procyclical productivity fluctuations a figment of measurement error? Manuscript, Northwestern University. [20] J. Greenwood, Z. Hercowitz and G. Huffman, 1988, Investment, capacity utilization, and the real business cycle, American Economic Review 78, [21] G. Hansen, 1985, Indivisible labor and the business cycle, Journal of Monetary Economics 16, [22] King, R., C. Plosser and S. Rebelo, 1988, Production, growth and business cycles: I. The basic neoclassical model, Journal of Monetary Economics 21, [23] G. Mankiw, 1989, Real business cycles: A new Keynesian perspective, Journal of Economic Perspectives 3, [24] R. Perli, 1998, Indeterminacy, home production, and the business cycle: A calibrated analysis, Journal of Monetary Economics 41. [25] J. Rotemberg and M. Woodford (1996), Real-business-cycle models and the forecastable movements in output, hours, and consumption, American Economic Review 86 (March),

22 [26] S. Schmitt-Grohe, 1997, Comparing four models of aggregate fluctuations due to self-fulfilling expectations, Journal of Economic Theory 72, [27] S. Schmitt-Grohe, 2000, Endogenous business cycles and the dynamics of output, hours, and consumption, American Economic Review, forthcoming. [28] K. Shell, 1977, Monnaie et allocation intertemporelle, Mimeo, Seminaire d Econometrie Roy-Malinvaud, Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique, Paris. [29] L. Summers, 1986, Some skeptical observations on real business cycle theory, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, Fall, [30] M. Watson, 1993, Measures of fit for calibrated models, Journal of Political Economy 101, no.6, [31] Y. Wen, 1995, Where s the beef? The trivial dynamics of real business cycle models, Manuscript, The University of Iowa. [32] Y. Wen, 1998, Capacity utilization under increasing returns to scale, Journal of Economic Theory 81,

23 Fig. 1. Responses to Demand Shocks (US 1960:1-1994:4) 23

24 Fig. 2. Autocorrelation Function of Growth Rates (US 1960:1-1994:4) 24

25 Fig. 3. Predictions of a Standard RBC model (Solic Symbols). First row: Impulse responses to demand shocks. Second row: ACF of growth rates. 25

26 Fig. 4. Impulse Responses (η =0.1). Solid lines: responses to a consumption shock. Dashed lines: responses to a government shock. 26

27 Fig. 5. Impulse Responses (η = 0.108). Solid lines: responses to consumption shock. Long dashed lines: responses to government shock. Short dashed lines: responses to sunspots. 27

28 Fig. 6. Impulse Responses of Output when the covariances between sunspots and fundamental shocks take different values. 28

29 Fig. 7. Predictions of Model Ω (solid symbols). Upper window: Impulse Response Function. Lower window: Autocorrelation Function. 29

30 Fig. 8. Predictions of Model A (solid symbols). Upper window: Impulse Response Function. Lower window: Autocorrelation Function. 30

31 Fig. 9. Predictions of Model B (solid symbols). Upper window: Impulse Response Function. Lower window: Autocorrelation Function. 31

32 Fig. 10. Impulse responses of model (solid lines) and data (dashed lines). 32

Granger Causality and Equilibrium Business Cycle Theory

Granger Causality and Equilibrium Business Cycle Theory Granger Causality and Equilibrium Business Cycle Theory Yi Wen Department of Economics Cornell University Abstract Post war US data show that consumption growth causes output and investment growth. This

More information

OUTPUT DYNAMICS IN AN ENDOGENOUS GROWTH MODEL

OUTPUT DYNAMICS IN AN ENDOGENOUS GROWTH MODEL OUTPUT DYNAMICS IN AN ENDOGENOUS GROWTH MODEL by Ilaski Barañano and M. Paz Moral 2003 Working Paper Series: IL. 05/03 Departamento de Fundamentos del Análisis Económico I Ekonomi Analisiaren Oinarriak

More information

Macroeconomics Theory II

Macroeconomics Theory II Macroeconomics Theory II Francesco Franco FEUNL February 2011 Francesco Franco Macroeconomics Theory II 1/34 The log-linear plain vanilla RBC and ν(σ n )= ĉ t = Y C ẑt +(1 α) Y C ˆn t + K βc ˆk t 1 + K

More information

Can the Kydland Prescott Model Pass the Cogley Nason Test?

Can the Kydland Prescott Model Pass the Cogley Nason Test? Can the Kydland Prescott Model Pass the Cogley Nason Test? Patrick Fève 1 University of Toulouse (CNRS GREMAQ and IDEI) and Banque de France (Research Division) Julien Matheron Banque de France (Research

More information

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999) Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999) The question we are asking is: What are the consequences of a monetary policy shock a shock which is purely related to monetary conditions

More information

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4 Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4 1 Basic Model 1.1 Uzawa Utility E 0 t=0 θ t U (c t, h t ) θ 0 = 1 θ t+1 = β (c t, h t ) θ t ; β c < 0; β h > 0. Time-varying discount factor With a constant

More information

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany October 3, 2018 Contents I 1 Central Planner 2 3 B. Heer c Public Economics: Chapter

More information

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 36 I Motivation This Lecture considers some applications

More information

RBC Model with Indivisible Labor. Advanced Macroeconomic Theory

RBC Model with Indivisible Labor. Advanced Macroeconomic Theory RBC Model with Indivisible Labor Advanced Macroeconomic Theory 1 Last Class What are business cycles? Using HP- lter to decompose data into trend and cyclical components Business cycle facts Standard RBC

More information

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks Eric R. Sims University of Notre Dame and NBER January 17, 2012 Abstract In a standard New Keynesian model, a Taylor-type interest rate rule moves the equilibrium real

More information

Equilibrium Conditions (symmetric across all differentiated goods)

Equilibrium Conditions (symmetric across all differentiated goods) MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION IN A DSGE MODEL: PART II SEPTEMBER 30, 200 Canonical Dixit-Stiglitz Model MONOPOLISTICALLY-COMPETITIVE EQUILIBRIUM Equilibrium Conditions (symmetric across all differentiated goods)

More information

Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations?

Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations? Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations? A Bayesian DSGE Approach Ippei Fujiwara 1 Yasuo Hirose 1 Mototsugu 2 1 Bank of Japan 2 Vanderbilt University August 4, 2009 Contributions of this paper

More information

Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities

Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities Jang-Ting Guo University of California, Riverside Sharon G. Harrison Barnard College, Columbia University July 9, 2008

More information

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics DSGE-Models Calibration and Introduction to Dynare Dr. Andrea Beccarini Willi Mutschler, M.Sc. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics willi.mutschler@uni-muenster.de Summer 2012 Willi Mutschler

More information

Chapter 11 The Stochastic Growth Model and Aggregate Fluctuations

Chapter 11 The Stochastic Growth Model and Aggregate Fluctuations George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomics, 2016 Chapter 11 The Stochastic Growth Model and Aggregate Fluctuations In previous chapters we studied the long run evolution of output and consumption, real

More information

Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework

Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework Dongpeng Liu Nanjing University Sept 2016 D. Liu (NJU) Solving D(S)GE 09/16 1 / 63 Introduction Targets of the

More information

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Dynamics of Externalities: A Second-Order Perspective Yi Wen and Huabin Wu Working Paper 8-44B http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/8/8-44.pdf

More information

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models 4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models Basic Economic Models In Economics, we use theoretical models to explain the economic processes in the real world. These models de ne a relation

More information

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC) Real Business Cycle Model (RBC) Seyed Ali Madanizadeh November 2013 RBC Model Lucas 1980: One of the functions of theoretical economics is to provide fully articulated, artificial economic systems that

More information

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING James Bullard* Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 33rd Annual Economic Policy Conference St. Louis, MO October 17, 2008 Views expressed are

More information

With Realistic Parameters the Basic Real Business Cycle Model Acts Like the Solow Growth Model

With Realistic Parameters the Basic Real Business Cycle Model Acts Like the Solow Growth Model Preliminary Draft With Realistic Parameters the Basic Real Business ycle Model Acts Like the Solow Growth Model Miles Kimball Shanthi P. Ramnath mkimball@umich.edu ramnath@umich.edu University of Michigan

More information

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Imperfect Competition and Sunspots Pengfei Wang and Yi Wen Working Paper 2006-05A http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2006/2006-05.pdf

More information

Introduction to Macroeconomics

Introduction to Macroeconomics Introduction to Macroeconomics Martin Ellison Nuffi eld College Michaelmas Term 2018 Martin Ellison (Nuffi eld) Introduction Michaelmas Term 2018 1 / 39 Macroeconomics is Dynamic Decisions are taken over

More information

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno Background Much progress made on constructing and estimating models that fit quarterly data well (Smets-Wouters,

More information

Economics 701 Advanced Macroeconomics I Project 1 Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 2011

Economics 701 Advanced Macroeconomics I Project 1 Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 2011 Department of Economics University of Maryland Economics 701 Advanced Macroeconomics I Project 1 Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 2011 Objective As a stepping stone to learning how to work with and computationally

More information

The Neo Fisher Effect and Exiting a Liquidity Trap

The Neo Fisher Effect and Exiting a Liquidity Trap The Neo Fisher Effect and Exiting a Liquidity Trap Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé and Martín Uribe Columbia University European Central Bank Conference on Monetary Policy Frankfurt am Main, October 29-3, 218

More information

1 The Basic RBC Model

1 The Basic RBC Model IHS 2016, Macroeconomics III Michael Reiter Ch. 1: Notes on RBC Model 1 1 The Basic RBC Model 1.1 Description of Model Variables y z k L c I w r output level of technology (exogenous) capital at end of

More information

Deep Habits, Nominal Rigidities and Interest Rate Rules

Deep Habits, Nominal Rigidities and Interest Rate Rules Deep Habits, Nominal Rigidities and Interest Rate Rules Sarah Zubairy August 18, 21 Abstract This paper explores how the introduction of deep habits in a standard new-keynesian model affects the properties

More information

Citation Working Paper Series, F-39:

Citation Working Paper Series, F-39: Equilibrium Indeterminacy under F Title Interest Rate Rules Author(s) NAKAGAWA, Ryuichi Citation Working Paper Series, F-39: 1-14 Issue Date 2009-06 URL http://hdl.handle.net/10112/2641 Rights Type Technical

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 2011 This note describes very briefly how to conduct quantitative analysis on a linearized

More information

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA On the Solution of the Growth Model with Investment-Specific Technological Change Jesús Fernández-Villaverde and Juan Francisco Rubio-Ramírez Working Paper 2004-39 December

More information

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I Name: Students ID: ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I I. Short Questions (21/2 points each) Mark the following statements as True (T) or False (F) and give a brief explanation of your answer in each case. 1. 2.

More information

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Solving Linear Difference Systems with Lagged Expectations by a Method of Undetermined Coefficients Pengfei Wang and Yi Wen Working

More information

Inthis article, I investigate the size of the returns to scale in aggregate

Inthis article, I investigate the size of the returns to scale in aggregate Economic Quarterly Volume 102, Number 1 First Quarter 2016 Pages 79 10 3 How Large Are Returns to Scale in the U.S.? A View Across the Boundary Thomas A. Lubik Inthis article, I investigate the size of

More information

CREDIT SEARCH AND CREDIT CYCLES

CREDIT SEARCH AND CREDIT CYCLES CREDIT SEARCH AND CREDIT CYCLES Feng Dong Pengfei Wang Yi Wen Shanghai Jiao Tong U Hong Kong U Science and Tech STL Fed & Tsinghua U May 215 The usual disclaim applies. Motivation The supply and demand

More information

1.2. Structural VARs

1.2. Structural VARs 1. Shocks Nr. 1 1.2. Structural VARs How to identify A 0? A review: Choleski (Cholesky?) decompositions. Short-run restrictions. Inequality restrictions. Long-run restrictions. Then, examples, applications,

More information

Topic 3. RBCs

Topic 3. RBCs 14.452. Topic 3. RBCs Olivier Blanchard April 8, 2007 Nr. 1 1. Motivation, and organization Looked at Ramsey model, with productivity shocks. Replicated fairly well co-movements in output, consumption,

More information

Monetary Policy and Equilibrium Indeterminacy in a Cash in Advance Economy with Investment. Abstract

Monetary Policy and Equilibrium Indeterminacy in a Cash in Advance Economy with Investment. Abstract Monetary Policy and Equilibrium Indeterminacy in a Cash in Advance Economy with Investment Chong Kee Yip Department of Economics, The Chinese University of Hong Kong Ka Fai Li Department of Economics,

More information

1 The social planner problem

1 The social planner problem The social planner problem max C t;k t+ U t = E t X t C t () that can be written as: s.t.: Y t = A t K t (2) Y t = C t + I t (3) I t = K t+ (4) A t = A A t (5) et t i:i:d: 0; 2 max C t;k t+ U t = E t "

More information

Housing and the Business Cycle

Housing and the Business Cycle Housing and the Business Cycle Morris Davis and Jonathan Heathcote Winter 2009 Huw Lloyd-Ellis () ECON917 Winter 2009 1 / 21 Motivation Need to distinguish between housing and non housing investment,!

More information

Explaining the Effects of Government Spending Shocks on Consumption and the Real Exchange Rate. M. Ravn S. Schmitt-Grohé M. Uribe.

Explaining the Effects of Government Spending Shocks on Consumption and the Real Exchange Rate. M. Ravn S. Schmitt-Grohé M. Uribe. Explaining the Effects of Government Spending Shocks on Consumption and the Real Exchange Rate M. Ravn S. Schmitt-Grohé M. Uribe November 2, 27 Effects of Government Spending Shocks: SVAR Evidence A rise

More information

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Spring 2016 Karl Whelan (UCD) Real Business Cycles Spring 2016 1 / 38 Working Through A DSGE Model We have

More information

Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions

Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions William D. Lastrapes Department of Economics Terry College of Business University of Georgia Athens,

More information

Macroeconomics Theory II

Macroeconomics Theory II Macroeconomics Theory II Francesco Franco FEUNL February 2016 Francesco Franco Macroeconomics Theory II 1/23 Housekeeping. Class organization. Website with notes and papers as no "Mas-Collel" in macro

More information

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models Fall 22 Contents Introduction 2. An illustrative example........................... 2.2 Discussion...................................

More information

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics Friday September 8 th : Lecture 10 Gerzensee, September 2017 Roger E. A. Farmer Warwick University and NIESR Topics for Lecture 10 Tying together the pieces

More information

Deep Habits: Technical Notes

Deep Habits: Technical Notes Deep Habits: Technical Notes Morten Ravn Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martín Uribe October 18, 2004 This note derives in detail the model, its associated equilibrium conditions, the steadystate equilibrium,

More information

Income Effects and Indeterminacy in a Calibrated One-Sector Growth Model

Income Effects and Indeterminacy in a Calibrated One-Sector Growth Model This work is distributed as a Discussion Paper by the STANFORD INSTITUTE FOR EONOMI POLIY RESEARH SIEPR Discussion Paper No. 07-12 Income Effects and Indeterminacy in a alibrated One-Sector Growth Model

More information

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model Macroeconomics II Dynamic AD-AS model Vahagn Jerbashian Ch. 14 from Mankiw (2010) Spring 2018 Where we are heading to We will incorporate dynamics into the standard AD-AS model This will offer another

More information

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes Macroeconomics II Dynamic AD-AS model Vahagn Jerbashian Ch. 14 from Mankiw (2010) Spring 2018 Where we are heading to We will incorporate dynamics into the standard AD-AS model This will offer another

More information

Graduate Macroeconomics - Econ 551

Graduate Macroeconomics - Econ 551 Graduate Macroeconomics - Econ 551 Tack Yun Indiana University Seoul National University Spring Semester January 2013 T. Yun (SNU) Macroeconomics 1/07/2013 1 / 32 Business Cycle Models for Emerging-Market

More information

What s News In Business Cycles

What s News In Business Cycles What s News In Business Cycles Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martín Uribe First Draft: November 7 This Draft: December 6, 8 Abstract In this paper, we perform a structural Bayesian estimation of the contribution

More information

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2015 1 / 36 Production Economy Last time: studied equilibrium in an endowment economy Now: study equilibrium in an economy

More information

Stochastic Trends & Economic Fluctuations

Stochastic Trends & Economic Fluctuations Stochastic Trends & Economic Fluctuations King, Plosser, Stock & Watson (AER, 1991) Cesar E. Tamayo Econ508 - Economics - Rutgers November 14, 2011 Cesar E. Tamayo Stochastic Trends & Economic Fluctuations

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHAT'S NEWS IN BUSINESS CYCLES. Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe Martin Uribe. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHAT'S NEWS IN BUSINESS CYCLES. Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe Martin Uribe. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHAT'S NEWS IN BUSINESS CYCLES Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe Martin Uribe Working Paper 14215 http://www.nber.org/papers/w14215 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 15 Massachusetts

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Real Business Cycle Models. Jordi Galí. Universitat Pompeu Fabra Spring 2018

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Real Business Cycle Models. Jordi Galí. Universitat Pompeu Fabra Spring 2018 Advanced Macroeconomics II Real Business Cycle Models Jordi Galí Universitat Pompeu Fabra Spring 2018 Assumptions Optimization by consumers and rms Perfect competition General equilibrium Absence of a

More information

The Price Puzzle: Mixing the Temporary and Permanent Monetary Policy Shocks.

The Price Puzzle: Mixing the Temporary and Permanent Monetary Policy Shocks. The Price Puzzle: Mixing the Temporary and Permanent Monetary Policy Shocks. Ida Wolden Bache Norges Bank Kai Leitemo Norwegian School of Management BI September 2, 2008 Abstract We argue that the correct

More information

Theoretical premises of the Keynesian approach

Theoretical premises of the Keynesian approach origin of Keynesian approach to Growth can be traced back to an article written after the General Theory (1936) Roy Harrod, An Essay in Dynamic Theory, Economic Journal, 1939 Theoretical premises of the

More information

Closed economy macro dynamics: AD-AS model and RBC model.

Closed economy macro dynamics: AD-AS model and RBC model. Closed economy macro dynamics: AD-AS model and RBC model. Ragnar Nymoen Department of Economics, UiO 22 September 2009 Lecture notes on closed economy macro dynamics AD-AS model Inflation targeting regime.

More information

DOCUMENTOS DE TRABAJO BILTOKI. Consumption-Leisure Trade-offs and Persistency in Business Cycles. Ilaski Barañano y Paz Moral

DOCUMENTOS DE TRABAJO BILTOKI. Consumption-Leisure Trade-offs and Persistency in Business Cycles. Ilaski Barañano y Paz Moral DOCUMENTOS DE TRABAJO BILTOKI D.T. 2007.05 Consumption-Leisure Trade-offs and Persistency in Business Cycles. Ilaski Barañano y Paz Moral Facultad de Ciencias Económicas. Avda. Lehendakari Aguirre, 83

More information

Assessing Structural VAR s

Assessing Structural VAR s ... Assessing Structural VAR s by Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Robert Vigfusson Zurich, September 2005 1 Background Structural Vector Autoregressions Address the Following Type of Question:

More information

Econ 5110 Solutions to the Practice Questions for the Midterm Exam

Econ 5110 Solutions to the Practice Questions for the Midterm Exam Econ 50 Solutions to the Practice Questions for the Midterm Exam Spring 202 Real Business Cycle Theory. Consider a simple neoclassical growth model (notation similar to class) where all agents are identical

More information

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case.

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case. Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case. Ragnar Nymoen Department of Economics, University of Oslo October 20, 2008 1 Ch 17, 19 and 20 in IAM Since our primary concern is to

More information

Are Structural VARs Useful Guides for Developing Business Cycle Theories? by Larry Christiano

Are Structural VARs Useful Guides for Developing Business Cycle Theories? by Larry Christiano Discussion of: Chari-Kehoe-McGrattan: Are Structural VARs Useful Guides for Developing Business Cycle Theories? by Larry Christiano 1 Chari-Kehoe-McGrattan: Are Structural VARs Useful Guides for Developing

More information

Chaotic Interest-Rate Rules

Chaotic Interest-Rate Rules ON TAYLOR RULES AND MONETARY POLICY Chaotic Interest-Rate Rules By JESS BENHABIB, STEPHANIE SCHMITT-GROHÉ, AND MARTíN URIBE* In much of the recent literature on monetary economics it is assumed that monetary

More information

Learning-by-Doing or Habit Formation?

Learning-by-Doing or Habit Formation? Learning-by-Doing or Habit Formation? Hafedh Bouakez Takashi Kano This Version: January 26, 2005 Abstract In a recent paper, Chang, Gomes, and Schorfheide (American Economic Review 2002, p. 1498 1520)

More information

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania A Modern Equilibrium Model Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania 1 Household Problem Preferences: max E X β t t=0 c 1 σ t 1 σ ψ l1+γ t 1+γ Budget constraint: c t + k t+1 = w t l t + r t

More information

Gold Rush Fever in Business Cycles

Gold Rush Fever in Business Cycles Gold Rush Fever in Business Cycles Paul Beaudry, Fabrice Collard & Franck Portier University of British Columbia & Université de Toulouse UAB Seminar Barcelona November, 29, 26 The Klondike Gold Rush of

More information

Macroeconomics Theory II

Macroeconomics Theory II Macroeconomics Theory II Francesco Franco FEUNL February 2016 Francesco Franco (FEUNL) Macroeconomics Theory II February 2016 1 / 18 Road Map Research question: we want to understand businesses cycles.

More information

Assessing Structural VAR s

Assessing Structural VAR s ... Assessing Structural VAR s by Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Robert Vigfusson Minneapolis, August 2005 1 Background In Principle, Impulse Response Functions from SVARs are useful as

More information

Indeterminacy and E-stability in Real Business Cycle Models with Factor-Generated Externalities

Indeterminacy and E-stability in Real Business Cycle Models with Factor-Generated Externalities in Real Business Cycle Models with Factor-Generated Externalities Qinglai Meng a,b and Jianpo Xue b a Department of Economics, Oregon State Univeristy, Corvallis, OR 97330, USA b Department of Economics,

More information

Long-Run Growth Uncertainty

Long-Run Growth Uncertainty Long-Run Growth Uncertainty Pei Kuang a,, Kaushik Mitra a, a University of Birmingham 27 November 2015 Abstract Observed macroeconomic forecasts display gradual recognition of the long-run growth of endogenous

More information

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013) The Ramsey Model (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 213) 1 Introduction The Ramsey model (or neoclassical growth model) is one of the prototype models in dynamic macroeconomics.

More information

Shiftwork in the Real Business Cycle

Shiftwork in the Real Business Cycle Preliminary: 11/02 Shiftwork in the Real Business Cycle Yoram Halevy Department of Economics, UBC and James M. Nason Department of Economics, UBC Research Department, FRB-Atlanta The usual disclaimers

More information

Relative Deep Habits

Relative Deep Habits Relative Deep Habits Morten Ravn Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martín Uribe May 5, 25 Abstract This note presents a detailed formal derivation of the equilibrium conditions of a variation of the deep habit model

More information

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter 013 Test 1 February 1, 013 Answer ALL Questions Time Allowed: 1 hour 0 min Attention: Please write your answers on the answer book provided Use the right-side pages

More information

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model Virginia Sánchez-Marcos Macroeconomics, MIE-UNICAN Macroeconomics (MIE-UNICAN) A simple macro dynamic model with

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Business Cycle Accounting and Wedges

Graduate Macro Theory II: Business Cycle Accounting and Wedges Graduate Macro Theory II: Business Cycle Accounting and Wedges Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 2017 1 Introduction Most modern dynamic macro models have at their core a prototypical real business

More information

The Small-Open-Economy Real Business Cycle Model

The Small-Open-Economy Real Business Cycle Model The Small-Open-Economy Real Business Cycle Model Comments Some Empirical Regularities Variable Canadian Data σ xt ρ xt,x t ρ xt,gdp t y 2.8.6 c 2.5.7.59 i 9.8.3.64 h 2.54.8 tb y.9.66 -.3 Source: Mendoza

More information

A Discussion of Arouba, Cuba-Borda and Schorfheide: Macroeconomic Dynamics Near the ZLB: A Tale of Two Countries"

A Discussion of Arouba, Cuba-Borda and Schorfheide: Macroeconomic Dynamics Near the ZLB: A Tale of Two Countries A Discussion of Arouba, Cuba-Borda and Schorfheide: Macroeconomic Dynamics Near the ZLB: A Tale of Two Countries" Morten O. Ravn, University College London, Centre for Macroeconomics and CEPR M.O. Ravn

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano January 5, 2018 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand.

More information

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions Daniel Němec Faculty of Economics and Administrations Masaryk University Brno, Czech Republic nemecd@econ.muni.cz ESF MU (Brno)

More information

Macroeconomics Field Exam. August 2007

Macroeconomics Field Exam. August 2007 Macroeconomics Field Exam August 2007 Answer all questions in the exam. Suggested times correspond to the questions weights in the exam grade. Make your answers as precise as possible, using graphs, equations,

More information

Foundation of (virtually) all DSGE models (e.g., RBC model) is Solow growth model

Foundation of (virtually) all DSGE models (e.g., RBC model) is Solow growth model THE BASELINE RBC MODEL: THEORY AND COMPUTATION FEBRUARY, 202 STYLIZED MACRO FACTS Foundation of (virtually all DSGE models (e.g., RBC model is Solow growth model So want/need/desire business-cycle models

More information

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martín Uribe Duke University September 2007 1 Welfare-Based Policy Evaluation: Related Literature (ex: Rotemberg and Woodford,

More information

What are we going to do?

What are we going to do? RBC Model Analyzes to what extent growth and business cycles can be generated within the same framework Uses stochastic neoclassical growth model (Brock-Mirman model) as a workhorse, which is augmented

More information

Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle

Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle David de la Croix 1,3 Gregory de Walque 2 Rafael Wouters 2,1 1 dept. of economics, Univ. cath. Louvain 2 National Bank of Belgium

More information

Did Sunspot Forces Cause the Roaring Twenties?

Did Sunspot Forces Cause the Roaring Twenties? Did Sunspot Forces Cause the Roaring Twenties? Sharon G. Harrison Department of Economics Barnard College Columbia University 3009 Broadway New York, NY 10027 U.S.A. Mark Weder School of Economics University

More information

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen October 15, 2013 Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen () Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations October 15, 2013 1 / 43 Introduction

More information

Macroeconomics Theory II

Macroeconomics Theory II Macroeconomics Theory II Francesco Franco Nova SBE February 2012 Francesco Franco Macroeconomics Theory II 1/31 Housekeeping Website TA: none No "Mas-Collel" in macro One midterm, one final, problem sets

More information

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP Measuring monetary policy deviations from the Taylor rule

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP Measuring monetary policy deviations from the Taylor rule Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP-1803 Measuring monetary policy deviations from the Taylor rule João Madeira Nuno Palma February 2018 Economics School of Social Sciences The University of Manchester

More information

Assessing Structural VAR s

Assessing Structural VAR s ... Assessing Structural VAR s by Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Robert Vigfusson Yale, October 2005 1 Background Structural Vector Autoregressions Can be Used to Address the Following Type

More information

Technical appendices: Business cycle accounting for the Japanese economy using the parameterized expectations algorithm

Technical appendices: Business cycle accounting for the Japanese economy using the parameterized expectations algorithm Technical appendices: Business cycle accounting for the Japanese economy using the parameterized expectations algorithm Masaru Inaba November 26, 2007 Introduction. Inaba (2007a) apply the parameterized

More information

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from: Working Paper Series This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/ Labor Supply Shifts and Economic Fluctuations * Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working

More information

Technology Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations: How Well Does the RBC Model Fit Postwar U.S. Data?

Technology Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations: How Well Does the RBC Model Fit Postwar U.S. Data? Technology Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations: How Well Does the RBC Model Fit Postwar U.S. Data? by Jordi Gali and Pau Rabanal Comments by Ellen R. McGrattan, Minneapolis Fed Overview of Gali-Rabanal Part

More information

WORKING PAPER NO NON-STATIONARY HOURS IN A DSGE MODEL. Yongsung Chang Seoul National University. Taeyoung Doh University of Pennsylvania

WORKING PAPER NO NON-STATIONARY HOURS IN A DSGE MODEL. Yongsung Chang Seoul National University. Taeyoung Doh University of Pennsylvania WORKING PAPER NO. 06-3 NON-STATIONARY HOURS IN A DSGE MODEL Yongsung Chang Seoul National University Taeyoung Doh University of Pennsylvania Frank Schorfheide University of Pennsylvania, CEPR, and Visiting

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano March, 28 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand. Derive

More information

Evaluating Structural Vector Autoregression Models in Monetary Economies

Evaluating Structural Vector Autoregression Models in Monetary Economies Evaluating Structural Vector Autoregression Models in Monetary Economies Bin Li Research Department International Monetary Fund March 9 Abstract This paper uses Monte Carlo simulations to evaluate alternative

More information

Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model

Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martín Uribe Duke University 1 Objective of the Paper: Within a mediumscale estimated model of the macroeconomy

More information

Assessing the Fed s Performance through the Effect of Technology Shocks: New Evidence

Assessing the Fed s Performance through the Effect of Technology Shocks: New Evidence through the Effect of Technology Shocks: New Evidence Carlo Coen Castellino September 2010 Abstract In this work I revisit the paper by Galí et al. (2003), which explains how the changes over time in the

More information