Online Supplement for Trade and Inequality: From Theory to Estimation

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Online Supplement for Trade and Inequality: From Theory to Estimation"

Transcription

1 Online Supplement for Trade and Inequality: From Theory to Estimation Elhanan Helpman Harvard University and CIFAR Oleg Itskhoki Princeton University and NBER Marc-Andreas Muendler UC San Diego and NBER Stephen Redding Princeton University and NBER May Contents A Introduction 3 B Reduced-form Empirical Findings for Other Countries 3 C Theory Appendix 4 C.1 Theoretical model C.2 Derivation of the empirical model C.3 Reduced-form coefficients and structural parameters C.4 Counterfactuals D Econometric Inference 14 D.1 Derivation of the likelihood function D.2 Maximum Likelihood estimation D.3 Overidentified GMM estimation D.4 GMM Bounds D.5 Identification E Extensions and Generalizations 29 E.1 Isomorphisms E.2 Two sources of heterogeneity E.3 Measurement error We thank the National Science Foundation for financial support. See the paper for our acknowledgements. 1

2 E.4 Estimation with sector-region heterogeneity E.5 Multiple destinations F Dynamic model 41 G Data Appendix 48 H Additional Empirical Results and Robustness 51 H.1 Export Participation H.2 Wage inequality within versus between sectors and occupations H.3 Non-manufacturing industries H.4 Worker observables and residual wage inequality H.5 Regional Robustness H.6 Returns to education and tenure H.7 Robustness test using more disaggregated education measures H.8 Between-sector wage differentials H.9 Between versus within-firm wage inequality H.10 Between versus within-firm wage inequality by occupation H.11 Between versus within-firm wage inequality by sector H.12 Between versus Within-Firm Wage Inequality for Exporters and Non-Exporters H.13 Firm-year rather than firm-occupation-year fixed effects H.14 Constant composition residual wage inequality H.15 Firm and Worker Fixed Effects Estimates H.16 Counterfactuals Robustness Test H.17 Robustness Test using Colombian Data H.18 Robustness Test Using Brazilian Household Survey Data I Data Supplement with Industry and Occupation Concordances 78 2

3 A Introduction This online supplement contains the technical derivations for the theoretical results in the paper and reports additional empirical results and other information. Section B discusses reduced-form empirical findings for other countries that are consistent with our stylized facts for Brazil in Section 3 of the paper. Section C provides a full characterization of the structural model and discusses the relationship between the reduced-form coefficients and structural parameters. Section D deals with econometric inference including the derivation of the likelihood function and the generalized method of moments (GMM) bounds analysis. Section G discusses the data sources and definitions. Section H contains additional empirical results and robustness checks referred to in the paper. B Reduced-form Empirical Findings for Other Countries In this section we discuss that our stylized facts for Brazil are consistent with empirical findings for a number of other countries including the United States. First our reduced-form results on wage inequality within and between sectors and occupations (subsection 3.1 of the paper) are consistent with the findings of a number of existing studies. Katz and Murphy (1992) find that much of the growth of wage inequality in the United States from occurred within industry-occupation cells. Berman Bound and Griliches (1994) and Berman Bound and Machin (1998) find substantial increases in the relative employment and relative wages of skilled workers within industries in the United States and other OECD countries respectively (see also the survey by Katz and Autor 1999). Second our evidence on worker observables and wage inequality (subsection 3.2 of the paper) is in line with the conclusions of the existing labor literature. Juhn Murphy and Pierce (1993) find that much of the growth in wage inequality in the United States from is explained by a growth in residual wage inequality within narrowly-defined education and labor market experience groups (see also Autor Katz and Kearney 2008 Lemieux 2006). Similarly Akerman Helpman Itskhoki Muendler and Redding (2013) Machin (1996) and Attanasio Goldberg and Pavcnik (2004) show that a substantial component of the level and growth of wage inequality is unexplained by observed worker characteristics in countries as diverse as Sweden the United Kingdom and Colombia respectively. Third our stylized facts on wage inequality between versus within firms (subsection 3.3 of the paper) are consistent with existing studies for other countries. For example Davis and Haltiwanger (1991) find that between-plant wage dispersion accounts for around one half of the level and growth of wage inequality in U.S. manufacturing from Using data for a later time period Barth Bryson Davis and Freeman (2011) find that more than 70 percent of the increased dispersion of U.S. earnings among individuals from occurred across establishments. Using West German data Card Heining and Kline (2013) find that increasing plant-level heterogeneity and rising assortativeness in the assignment of workers to establishments explain a large share of the rise in wage inequality from Finally using data on U.K. manufacturing Faggio Salvanes and Van Reenen (2010) find that most of the increase in individual wage inequality can be accounted for by an increase in inequality between firms within industries. 3

4 Finally as discussed in the paper our reduced-form results relating between-firm wage differences to firm size and export status are supported by a large empirical trade literature following Bernard and Jensen ( ). Our estimate of the employer-size wage premium using data on raw wages for Brazilian manufacturing of 0.12 compares to a value of 0.14 reported for U.S. manufacturing in Bayard and Troske (1999). Similarly using raw firm wages we estimate an exporter premium of 0.26 in Table 7 (after controlling for firm size) which compares to the value of 0.29 reported for U.S. manufacturing in Table 8 of Bernard Jensen Redding and Schott (2007). C Theory Appendix C.1 Theoretical model Consider the model in Helpman Itskhoki and Redding (2010 henceforth HIR) with the following two extensions: 1. Screening costs are heterogenous across firms and given by e η C δ ( ac ) δ where η varies across firms while C and δ are common to all firms. In the original HIR model η Fixed costs of exporting are heterogenous across firms and given by e ε F x where ε varies across firms and the fixed export cost F x is common to all firms. In the original HIR model ε 0. Simplifying HIR slightly we set the fixed cost of production to zero for all firms (f d = 0). Here we describe the solution to the problem of a given firm in an industry taking industry labor market tightness as given. The details of the general equilibrium can be found in HIR. A firm with a shock triplet (θ η ε) solves the following problem as explained in the text and HIR: where: 1 Π(θ η ε) = { 1 max Na cι {01} 1 + βγ R(N a c ι; θ) bn e η C } δ (a c) δ ιe ε F x (C.1) 1 Revenues given export status ι {0 1} are a function of total output of the firm defined by: { R(Y ι) = max A d Y β d + ιax(yx/τ)β} Y d +Y x Y where A d Y β are revenues from domestic sales and A x(y x/τ) β are revenues from exporting. The parameter τ reflects variable trade costs (including iceberg transport costs). The demand is derived from a CES aggregator with elasticity 1/(1 β) and A d and A x are demand shifters which depend on total industry expenditure and a price index as detailed in HIR. The optimal allocation of sales across markets for an exporter satisfies Y x/y d = τ β/(1 β) (A x/a d ) 1/(1 β) and therefore we can write 4

5 and R(N a c ι; θ) = [1 + ι(υ x 1)] 1 β A d Y (N a c ; θ) β Y (N a c ; θ) = kaγk min k 1 eθ N γ (a c ) 1 γk ( ) 1 Υ x = 1 + τ β Ax 1 β 1 β. A d As described in the text the employment of the firm is given by The bargained wage rate of the firm is given by: 2 H(N a c ) = N (a min /a c ) k. W (N a c ι; θ) = βγ 1 + βγ R(N a c ι; θ) H(N a c ) and the remaining share 1/(1 + βγ) of revenues goes to the firm. Taking the first-order conditions in (C.1) with respect to N and a c and using the expression for H and W above we arrive at expressions (9) (11) in the text: [ R = κ r 1 + ι (Υx 1) ] 1 β Γ [ H = κ h 1 + ι (Υx 1) ] (1 β)(1 k/δ) Γ [ W = κ w 1 + ι (Υx 1) ] k(1 β) δγ (e θ) β Γ ( e η) β(1 γk) δγ (e θ) β(1 k/δ) Γ βk (e θ) ( ( δγ e η) k δ (e η) β(1 γk)(1 k/δ) k δγ δ 1+ β(1 γk) δγ where the expressions for the constants can be found in HIR (in particular see the Appendix to HIR at The first-order conditions further imply that the firm s profits are Π(θ η ε; ι) = Γ 1 + βγ R(θ η; ι) ιeε F x Y d = Y/Υ x and Y x = (Υ x 1)Y/Υ x where Υ x is defined in the text. The resulting revenues from domestic sales are R d = A d (Y/Υ x) β = R/Υ x. 2 As detailed in HIR at the bargaining stage the firm s costs are sunk and the firm bargains with its workers to divide revenues from production R(N a c ι; θ). The firm s revenues are a power function of employment H with power γβ and the firm and the workers know only that each worker has an ability of at least a c and hence an expected ability of ā. The outside option of the worker is normalized to zero and the Stole and Zwiebel (1996a) bargaining condition under these circumstances is [ ] R(H) W (H)H = W (H) H where we emphasize that at the bargaining stage the revenues and the resulting wage rate depend only on employment of the firm. The solution to this differential equation in H is W = βγ/(1 + βγ) R/H. ) 5

6 where Γ = 1 βγ β(1 γk)/δ. Revenues are a function of the firm s export status ι {0 1}. Similarly the optimally chosen N and a c are a function of export status given (θ η). The firm chooses to export when Π(θ η ε; ι = 1) Π(θ η ε; ι = 0) which can be written as condition (12) in the text: ι = I {κ π ( ) ( Υ 1 β Γ x 1 e θ) β ( Γ e η) β(1 γk) δγ F x e ε } where κ π = Γκ r /(1 + βγ) and I{ } is the indicator function. The above statements describe the relevant equilibrium conditions of the model. The remaining general equilibrium conditions can be found in HIR. C.2 Derivation of the empirical model We start by taking logs of the expressions for H W and inside the indicator function in the expression for ι: where h = α h + ( 1 k ) [ ( δ ι 1 β Γ log Υ x + β Γ θ + β(1 γk) [ ( ) ] w = α w + k δ ι 1 β Γ log Υ x + β Γ θ β(1 γk) δγ η { ( ) } ι = I 1 β σ Γ θ + β(1 γk) δγ η ε f δγ k/δ 1 k/δ f = 1 ( [ ]) α π + log F x log Υ 1 β Γ x 1 σ ) ] η α s = log κ s (for s = h w π) and σ is the variance of [(β/γ) θ + β(1 γk)/(δγ) η ε] explicitly given in (C.2) below. It is convenient to introduce the following notation to simplify the expressions in subsequent derivations: χ = k/δ 1 k/δ λ 1 = β Γ λ 2 = β(1 γk) δγ µ h = 1 1 β 1 + χ Γ log Υ x and µ w = χ 1 β 1 + χ Γ log Υ x = χµ h. With this notation we can write the structural model simply as: Using the definition of Γ we show that: h = α h + µ h ι + λ 1 1+χ θ + λ 2 χ 1+χ η w = α w + µ w ι + χλ 1 1+χ θ + χ(1+λ 2) 1+χ η ι = I {( λ 1 θ + λ 2 η ε ) /σ f } λ 2 χ = χ Γ ( 1 β ) < 0 k 6

7 since the model s parameter restrictions are β < 1 < k. This implies that the effect of η on h is negative. Finally we make the distributional assumption on the shocks: (θ η ε) N (0 Σ) Σ = σ 2 θ σ θη σ 2 η σ θε σ ηε σ 2 ε The above four expressions for h w ι and the distribution of (θ η ε) together with the definitions of the parameters (χ µ h µ w λ 1 λ 2 f) fully describe the structural model. The model implies that the following parameter restrictions: 3 χ µ h µ w λ 1 λ 2 > 0 λ 2 < χ µ w = χµ h and µ h + µ w = log Υ (1 β)/γ x. We now derive the relationship between the structural parameters of the model and the reducedform coefficients of our econometric model. Our derivation involves an orthogonalization of the shocks in the wage and employment equations. Define the first reduced-form shock u = λ χ θ + λ 2 χ 1 + χ η. so that h = α h + µ h ι + u. Next rewrite the wage equation as w = α w + µ w ι + χu + χη = α w + µ w ι + χ(1 + π)u + χ ( η πu ) where π is the projection coefficient of η on u so that (η πu) is uncorrelated with u. Under our normality assumption we further have E{η u} = πu. We can now define the second reduced-form shock v = χ ( η πu ) so that cov(u v) = 0 and we can write w = α w + µ w ι + ζu + v where ζ = χ(1 + π) < χ. Note that the orthogonality of u and v is without loss of generality because it is a normalization. 3 The parameter restrictions are discussed in detail in HIR and we require Υ x > 0 β (0 1) 1 < k < δ 0 < γk < 1 and Γ > 0 which leads to these restrictions on the derived parameters. 7

8 Consider now the selection equation. Note that λ 1 θ + λ 2 η = (1 + ζ)u + v. Define where and z = 1 σ [ (1 + ζ)u + v ε ] σ 2 = (1 + ζ) 2 σ 2 u + σ 2 v + σ 2 ε 2(1 + ζ)σ uε 2σ vε σ 2 u = λ 2 1 (1 + χ) 2 σ2 θ + (λ 2 χ) 2 (1 + χ) 2 σ2 η σ 2 v = χ 2 ( σ 2 η + π 2 σ 2 u 2πcov(η u) ) = χ 2 ( σ 2 η π 2 σ 2 u) σ uε = λ χ σ θε + λ 2 χ 1 + χ σ ηε σ vε = χ ( σ ηε πσ uε ). (C.2) Therefore we have σ 2 z = var(z) = 1. We hence rewrite the selection equation simply as ι = I {z f}. The joint distribution of the reduced-form shocks (u v z) is given by: (u v z) N (0 Σ R ) Σ R = σu 2 0 σv 2 ρ u σ u ρ v σ u 1 (C.3) where ρ u σ u = 1 σ ( (1 + ζ)σ 2 u σ uε ) ρ v σ v = 1 σ ( σ 2 v σ vε ). This completes the derivation of the reduced-form system. We now discuss the model s restrictions on the reduced-form coefficients Θ = (α h α w ζ σ u σ v ρ u ρ v µ h µ w f). As derived above we have µ h µ w > 0 µ w /µ h = χ and ζ = χ(1 + π) < χ. As discussed in the paper we estimate the model under the structural identifying assumption of a covariance condition on the structural shocks (σ θη = 0) as is common in the structural econometrics literature following Koopmans (1949) Fisher (1966) and Wolpin (2013). Under this structural covariance restriction the expression for 8

9 the projection coefficient π is: π = cov(η u) var(u) = λ 2 χ 1+χ σ2 η λ 2 1 (1+χ) 2 σ 2 θ + (λ 2 χ) 2 (1+χ) 2 σ 2 η 0 (C.4) where π < 0 follows from the model s parameter restriction λ 2 < χ. The structural covariance restriction (σ θη = 0) helps to separately identify the market access and selection forces by placing bounds on the relative market access effects (µ h /µ w ): Lemma S.1 Under the structural covariance restriction σ θη = 0 the reduced-form coefficients must satisfy the inequality constraint: ζ µ w µ h < ζ + σ 2 v (1 + ζ)σu 2. (C.5) Proof: Consider the definition of π in (C.4) which combined with the definition of σ 2 u can be written as: Rearranging we can rewrite: π = (λ 2 χ)ση 2 (1 + χ)σu 2. ( 1 λ ) 2 χ 2 ση 2 χ (1 + χ)σu 2 Since 0 < λ 2 < χ we have 0 < 1 λ 2 /χ < 1 and therefore so that 0 ( 1 λ ) 2 χ 2 ση 2 χ (1 + χ)σu 2 = (χπ). 0 (χπ) < χ2 ση 2 (1 + χ)σu 2. Next we use the definition of σ 2 v to substitute in for χ 2 σ 2 η: < χ2 ση 2 (1 + χ)σu 2 Note that this is equivalent to: 0 (χπ) < σ2 v + (χπ) 2 σu 2 (1 + χ)σu 2. σ 2 v 0 (χπ) < (1 + ζ)σu 2 where we have used the fact that (1 + χ + χπ) = 1 + ζ from the definition of ζ. Finally note that χπ = ζ χ and χ = µ w /µ h. Hence the above inequalities are equivalent to the inequality constraint (C.5). We summarize the reduced-form empirical specification by: h = α h + µ h ι + u w = α w + µ w ι + ζu + v ι = I {z f} (C.6) 9

10 with the shocks (u v z) distributed according to (C.3). The data is x = (h w ι) and Θ = (α h α w ζ σ u σ v ρ u ρ v µ h µ w f) is the 10 1 vector of reduced-form coefficients. We estimate the reduced-form coefficients Θ subject to the inequality constraint (C.5) implied by our structural covariance restriction. We check whether the resulting parameter estimates ˆΘ satisfy the theoretical restriction that ˆµ h ˆµ w 0 (without imposing this additional restriction on the estimation). C.3 Reduced-form coefficients and structural parameters The model has 10 reduced-form coefficients Θ and 12 structural parameters Ξ = (α h α w µ h χ λ 1 λ 2 f σ θ σ η σ ε σ θε σ ηε ) where we have taken into account our structural covariance restriction that σ θη = 0. The coefficients (µ w σ π) are not part of the structural parameter vector Ξ because we can fully recover (µ w σ π) from Ξ using (C.4) (C.2) and the condition µ w = χµ h. The parameters (k δ β γ) are related to (χ λ 1 λ 2 ) as shown above and can be recovered after one of the parameters (k δ β γ) is calibrated. Some other parameters like b and C are related to the constants (α h α w ) as described in HIR but we do not attempt to recover them and hence do not discuss them here. We can relate the reduced-form coefficients Θ back to the structural parameters Ξ using the derivations in subsection C.2. We summarize the according relationships below: ζ = χ(1 + π) χ = k/δ 1 k/δ σu 2 = λ2 1 (1+χ) σ 2 2 θ + (λ2 χ)2 (1+χ) ση 2 λ 2 1 = β Γ σv 2 = χ ( ) 2 ση 2 π 2 σu 2 λ2 = β(1 γk) δγ ρ u = 1 σσ u ( (1 + ζ)σ 2 u σ uε ) (1+χ)(λ 2 χ)σ π = 2 η λ 2 1 σ2 θ +(λ2 χ)2 ση 2 ρ v = 1 σσ v ( σ 2 v σ vε ) σ 2 = (1 + ζ) 2 σ 2 u + σ 2 v + σ 2 ε 2(1 + ζ)σ uε 2σ vε µ h = 1 1 β 1+χ Γ log Υ x σ uε = λ1 1+χ σ θε + λ2 χ 1+χ σ ηε µ w = χµ h σ vε = χ ( ) σ ηε πσ uε. ( [ ]) f = 1 σ α π + log F x log Υ 1 β Γ x 1 while (α h α w ) are a part of both the reduced-form coefficients Θ and the structural parameters Ξ. The constants (α h α w ) market access effects (µ h µ w ) and export threshold (f) depend on Υ x which in turn depends on variable trade costs (τ) and relative market demands in the export and domestic markets (A x /A d ) that are likely to change over time. The coefficients (α h α w µ h µ w f) can be estimated directly with the reduced-form model. We can identify χ and hence k/δ from χ = µ w /µ h. Furthermore we can identify the market access effect from log Υ 1 β Γ x = µ h + µ w. From the reduced-form estimate of ζ we can recover π = ζ/χ 1 which is itself a derived pa- 10

11 rameter and provides information about structural parameters. Estimates of the covariance matrix (σ u σ v ρ u ρ v ) impose four conditions on the following five parameter combinations: ( λ1 σ θ (λ 2 χ)σ η σ ε λ 1 σ θε (λ 2 χ)σ ηε ). Therefore the structural parameters are under-identified. Nonetheless this does not constitute a limitation for our counterfactual exercises because the coefficients of the reduced-form model Θ are sufficient statistics for the impact of trade on wage inequality as discussed in detail below. We now briefly discuss what information about the structural parameters can nonetheless be obtained from the reduced-form estimates. Instead of 12 structural parameters in Ξ there are only 11 that can be identified in principle since λ 1 and σ θ always show up together multiplicatively (λ 1 σ θ ) even in the structural equations. We split the above relationships between the reduced-form coefficients and structural parameters into two blocks the first one defines the second moments and the second one defines the selection correlations given the second moments: Block 1 (variances) Estimates of (σ u σ v χ) allow to recover (λ 1 σ θ χσ η λ 2 /χ 1) where we treat χ µ w /µ h as an estimated parameter. Given that the inequality constraint (C.5) on the reducedform coefficients is satisfied this block always has a solution. Block 2 (selection) Estimates of (ρ u ρ v ) along with the parameter estimates from the previous block and definitions of the auxiliary parameters (σ σ uε σ vε ) provide information about (σ ε σ θε σ ηε ). This block is under-identified as we have two relationships tieing together three parameters. Therefore we need to calibrate one of the structural parameters here and this block imposes no additional restrictions on the reduced-form coefficients. Despite the under-identification in the second (selection) block we can nonetheless assess the strength of the selection effect in the estimated model. Indeed the knowledge of (ρ u ρ v ) is sufficient to quantify the overall contribution of productivity and screening shocks (θ η) to variation in export status. Note first that the amount of information in (θ η) is the same as in (u v) since the latter is a linear non-degenerate transformation of the former. Further given the joint distribution (C.3) the regression of z on (u v) is given by E{z u v} = ρ u u σ u + ρ v v σ v and its R-squared equals ρ 2 u+ρ 2 v. Therefore ρ 2 u + ρ 2 v is an overall measure of the selection correlation in the model and it can be calculated based on the reduced-form model. Note however that a particular value of this measure does not determine whether selection is mostly due to variation in (θ η) or due to the covariance between (θ η) and ε. C.4 Counterfactuals Consider an estimated reduced-form model characterized by (C.6) (C.3) ˆΘ. This allows us to simulate a counterfactual dataset of {(h i w i ι i )} i for a large number of firms i and calculate measures of 11

12 worker wage inequality in this simulated dataset. In the paper we carry out four types of counterfactuals: (i) autarky; (ii) variation in fixed exporting costs F x ; (iii) variation in variable trade cost τ (iv) variation in the dispersion of the employment and wage shocks (σ u and σ v ). We discuss each of these counterfactuals in turn. Autarky counterfactual This is the most immediate counterfactual to carry out. This counterfactual maintains the estimated coefficient vector ˆΘ and the distributional assumption (C.3) but substitutes the model in (C.6) with its special case that shuts down the effects of trade on the employment and wage distributions: { h i = α h + u i w i = α w + ζu i + v i. Model (C.7) relies on 5 coefficients (α h α w ζ σ u σ v ) which form a subset of Θ. The trade-related coefficients (ρ u ρ v µ h µ w f) are irrelevant for the autarky counterfactual. We use the autarky model (C.7) setting (α h α w ζ σ u σ v ) as in ˆΘ to simulate the counterfactual dataset {(h i w i )} i in autarky and calculate the measures of worker wage dispersion in autarky which are directly comparable to the inequality measures calculated for the full model (C.6) under ˆΘ. Note that (α h α w ) depend on general equilibrium variables and in general change between the autarkic and open economy equilibria. This however has no effect on measures of log wage dispersion since α h and α w introduce proportional shifts to the distributions of employment and wages which are inconsequential for wage inequality. Therefore our autarky counterfactual holds regardless of the general equilibrium changes in α h α w. Variation in the fixed exporting cost F x Recall from Subsection (C.3) that F x affects directly only the reduced-form export threshold f and no other coefficient in Θ. Therefore variation in F x translates into variation in the export threshold f (which is a linear monotonically increasing function of F x ). In our fixed exporting cost counterfactuals we consider a special case in which µ h and µ w are held constant which implicitly holds constant the relative export market demand A x /A d as is the case with symmetric countries when Υ x = 1 + τ β/(1 β). In our variable trade cost counterfactuals below we allow changes in τ to affect µ h µ w and f both directly and indirectly through changes in relative export market demand A x /A d. Any general equilibrium effects of changes in the fixed exporting cost (F x ) in the domestic market are captured by α h and α w which are again inconsequential for our inequality measures as discussed above. Therefore we maintain the model (C.6) (C.3) and all estimated coefficients ˆΘ except for f which we vary from infinity (when no firm exports) to minus infinity (when all firms export). For each counterfactual value of f we simulate a dataset of {(h i w i ι i )} i and calculate measures of worker wage dispersion and trade openness (the fraction of exporters and the employment share in exporting firms). We then plot measures of worker wage dispersion against measures of trade openness (see Figure 1 in the paper). Variation in the variable trade cost τ This is the most involved counterfactual that we consider. Recall that τ affects the market access variable Υ x = 1 + τ β 1 β (A x /A d ) 1 1 β which in turn directly determines the reduced-form market access coefficients µ h = 1 1 β Γ 1+χ log Υx and µ w = χ 1 β Γ 1+χ log Υx. (C.7) 12

13 Furthermore through the market access variable τ also affects the reduced-form coefficient f which decreases linearly in Υ 1 β Γ x. To summarize movements in τ directly affect three reduced-form coefficients (µ h µ w f) but in each case the effect of τ happens through the market access variable Υ 1 β Γ x which allows us to jointly move (µ h µ w f) in an internally-consistent way without any further knowledge of the structural parameters. Specifically we gradually move τ from infinity (which results in Υ x = 1) to 1 (at which point Υ x reaches high values) and change (µ h µ w f) accordingly keeping other coefficients in ˆΘ unchanged. For each value of τ (and hence Υ x ) we simulate a counterfactual dataset {(h i w i ι i )} i and calculate measures of worker wage dispersion and trade openness (the fraction of exporters and the employment share in exporting firms). We then plot measures of worker wage dispersion against measures of trade openness (see Figure 1 in the paper). There are two caveats that need to be discussed. First as discussed before movements in τ can have indirect general equilibrium effects on the intercepts (α h α w ) and on A x /A d where the latter also affects Υ x. This however does not lead to any loss of generality for our counterfactual since we plot wage inequality against measures of trade openness such as the share of employment in exporting firms and for both of these measures Υ x is a sufficient statistic so that knowledge of τ and A x /A d is not needed. Therefore as long as τ has a monotonically decreasing effect on Υ x in equilibrium our counterfactual in the right panel of Figure 2 in the paper holds regardless of the general equilibrium effect of τ on the relative demand shifter A x /A d. Second we reproduce the expression for f = 1 ( [ ]) α π + log F x log Υ 1 β Γ x 1. σ Note that the effect of Υ x on f depends on σ one of the derived parameters of the model that is not identified (see discussion in Subsection C.3). Therefore in order to carry out this counterfactual we need to calibrate σ. Recall that σ 2 = (1 + ζ) 2 σu 2 + σv 2 + σε 2 2(1 + ζ)σ uε 2σ vε. We make the natural assumption that the contribution of σu 2 and σv 2 to σ 2 is equal to ρ 2 u + ρ 2 v the R 2 in the regression of z on (u v). That is we assume: σ 2 = (1 + ζ)2 σu 2 + σv 2 ρ 2 u + ρ 2. v While this constitutes a natural benchmark we experiment with a wide range of smaller and larger values of σ 2 and find largely the same outcomes of the counterfactual. 13

14 D Econometric Inference D.1 Derivation of the likelihood function The likelihood function for observation j is the probability of observing a data vector x j = (h j w j ι j ) given the model (C.6) and coefficient vector Θ. Since we treat all observations in our cross-section as iid the likelihood function for the full sample X = {x j } j is a product of the conditional probabilities for individual observations: L(Θ X) = P{x j Θ}. j We now derive the expression for P Θ {x j } = P{x j Θ}. We omit Θ whenever the omission causes no confusion. Consider first an observation for a non-exporter ι = 0: P{h w ι = 0} = P{h w z < f} = P{u = h α h v = (w α w ) ζ(h α h ) z < f} = P{u = h α h v = (w α w ) ζ(h α h ) z = z}d z z<f Similarly for an exporter with ι = 1 we can write: P{h w ι = 1} = z f Consider now the joint density of (u v z): 4 From (C.3) it follows that: P{u = h α h µ h v = (w α w µ w ) ζ(h α h µ h ) z = z}d z. P{u v z} = P{z u v} P{u v} u N (0 σ 2 u) v N (0 σ 2 v) and z (u v) N ( ρ u u/σ u + ρ v v/σ v 1 ρ 2 u ρ 2 v) with (u v) jointly normal and independent. We can therefore write: P{u v z} = 1 ( ) u φ σ u σ u ( ) 1 u φ σ v σ v ( 1 φ 1 ρ 2 u ρ 2 v z ρ u u/σ u ρ v v/σ v 1 ρ 2 u ρ 2 v where φ( ) is the standard normal probability density function given by φ(t) = 1 2π e t2 /2. 4 We can base an alternative derivation on the complementary decomposition P{u v z} = P{u v z} P{z} to show that (( ) ( )) ρuσ uz (1 ρ 2 z N (0 1) and (u v) z N u )σu 2 ρ uσ uρ vσ v ρ vσ vz ρ uσ uρ vσ v (1 ρ 2 v)σv 2 and then rearrange P{u v z} P{z} to separate out terms with z. ) 14

15 Integrating this expression over z we obtain: P{u v z < f} = 1 ( u φ σ u σ u P{u v z f} = 1 ( u φ σ u σ u ) ) ( 1 v φ σ v 1 σ v φ σ v ( v σ v ) ( Φ ) [ ( 1 Φ f ρ u u/σ u ρ v v/σ v 1 ρ 2 u ρ 2 v ) f ρ u u/σ u ρ v v/σ v 1 ρ 2 u ρ 2 v where Φ( ) is the standard normal cumulative distribution function Φ(t) = t φ(s)ds. Finally we relate these expressions to the probability of the data: P{h w ι = 0} = P{u = h α h v = (w α w ) ζ(h α h ) z < f} ( ) = 1 φ (û(x)) 1 f ρ u û(x) ρ φ (ˆv(x)) Φ vˆv(x) σ u σ v 1 ρ 2 u ρ 2 v P{h w ι = 1} = P{u = h α h µ h v = (w α w µ w ) ζ(h α h µ h ) z f} [ ( )] = 1 φ (û(x)) 1 f ρ u û(x) ρ φ (ˆv(x)) 1 Φ vˆv(x) σ u σ v 1 ρ 2 u ρ 2 v )] where û(x) = h α h µ h ι σ ( u w αw µ w ι ) ζ ( h α h µ h ι ) ˆv(x) = σ v. Combining these two expressions into one we obtain our result (17) for P{x j Θ} in the text of the paper. D.2 Maximum Likelihood estimation Maximum likelihood (ML) estimates are obtained by numerically maximizing the log-likelihood function with respect to the coefficient vector given the dataset: ˆΘ ML = arg max log L(Θ X) Θ subject to the inequality constraint (C.5) implied by our structural covariance restriction. To ease the numerical optimization routine we make the following transformations: σ u σ v σ 2 u σ 2 v f ρ u ρ v f 1 ρ 2 u ρ 2 v ρ u 1 ρ 2 u ρ 2 v ρ v. 1 ρ 2 u ρ 2 v We numerically maximize the log-likelihood function with respect to the transformed coefficient vector and upon completion we make the reverse transformation to the original vector of coefficients. Note 15

16 that this transformation automatically ensures that σ u and σ v are positive and that (ρ u ρ v ) lies inside the unit circle that is ρ 2 u + ρ 2 v < 1. As a result we do not need to impose upper and lower bounds in the estimation of the transformed coefficients. We use ML asymptotic theory to calculate standard errors for ˆΘ ML. Standard asymptotics imply that under the correct specification N( ˆΘML Θ) d N (0 V ML ) where for robustness we use the sandwich form of the covariance matrix V ML = ( { }) 1 E 2 log L(Θ x) Θ Θ E which we consistently estimate with ˆV ML = 1 N j 2 log L( ˆΘ ML x j ) Θ Θ 1 N j { log L(Θ x) Θ 1 1 N 2 log L( ˆΘ ML x j ) Θ Θ } ( { }) 1 log L(Θ x) Θ E 2 log L(Θ x) Θ Θ j log L( ˆΘ ML x j ) log L( ˆΘ ML x j ) Θ Θ When a constraint binds in the estimation (e.g. when ζ = µ w /µ h which corresponds to the lower bound of (C.5)) we use the resulting equality to substitute out redundant parameters and thus reduce the problem to an unconstrained maximization with a smaller parameter vector. We then apply standard asymptotic theory to the reduced problem and recover the covariance matrix for the remaining parameters using the -method. D.3 Overidentified GMM estimation As discussed in subsection 4.3 of the paper we also consider an overidentified generalized method of moments (GMM) estimator using eleven conditional first and second moments reported in Table 5 of the paper. In the context of GMM estimation it is convenient to make the following substitutions: so that the new triplet of shocks is distributed ω = ζu + v 1 σ 2 ω = ζ 2 σ 2 u + σ 2 v ρ ω σ ω = ζρ u σ u + ρ v σ v (u ω z) N ( 0 Σ R) Σ R =. σ 2 u ζσ 2 u σ 2 ω ρ u σ u ρ ω σ ω 1. 16

17 Given the structure of the model (C.6) and the distributional assumption above we can calculate in closed form the first and second moments of employment and wages conditional on export status as well as the fraction of exporters: m h0 (Θ) = m h1 (Θ) = m w0 (Θ) = m w1 (Θ) = s 2 h0 (Θ) = s 2 h1 (Θ) = s 2 w0 (Θ) = s 2 w1 (Θ) = Eι j = 1 Φ(f) E{h j ι j = 0} = α h ρ u σ u λ( f) E{h j ι j = 1} = α h + µ h + ρ u σ u λ(f) E{w j ι j = 0} = α w ρ ω σ ω λ( f) E{w j ι j = 1} = α w + µ w + ρ ω σ ω λ(f) V{h j ι j = 0} = σ 2 u ρ 2 uσ 2 uλ( f) V{h j ι j = 1} = σ 2 u ρ 2 uσ 2 uλ(f) V{w j ι j = 0} = σ 2 ω ρ 2 ωσ 2 ωλ( f) V{w j ι j = 1} = σ 2 ω ρ 2 ωσ 2 ωλ(f) c 0 (Θ) = C{w j h j ι j = 0} = C(ω j ρ ω σ ω z j u j ρ u σ u z j ) + ρ ω σ ω ρ u σ u V{z j z j < f} = (ζσ 2 u ρ ω σ ω ρ u σ u ) + ρ ω σ ω ρ u σ u [ 1 Λ( f) ] c 1 (Θ) = = ζσ 2 u ρ ω σ ω ρ u σ u Λ( f) C{w j h j ι j = 1} = ζσ 2 u ρ ω σ ω ρ u σ u Λ(f) (D.1) where λ(f) =φ(f)/[1 Φ(f)] λ( f) =φ( f)/[1 Φ( f)] = φ(f)/φ(f) Λ(f) =λ(f)[λ(f) f] Λ( f) =λ( f)[λ( f) + f] and Θ is our 10 1 coefficient vector. In the derivation we have used the expressions for the first and second moments of a truncated standard normal variable: E{z j z j < f} = λ( f) E{z j z j f} = λ(f) V{z j z j < f} = 1 λ( f)[λ( f) + f] V{z j z j f} = 1 λ(f)[λ(f) f] for a standard normal variable z j. In the derivation of conditional covariances we used the fact that we can write w j = α w + µ w ι j + ω j = α w + µ w ι j + ρ ω σ ω z j + (ω j ρ ω σ ω z j ) h j = α h + µ h ι j + ρ u σ u z j + (u j ρ u σ u z j ) 17

18 where (ω j ρ ω σ ω z j ) and (u j ρ u σ u z j ) are both independent of z j. Efficient Overidentified GMM estimator For numerical GMM estimation it proves convenient to use the unconditional versions of these moments which are given by the following moment function: m(x j Θ) = ι j [1 Φ(f)] h j (1 ι j ) m h0 (Θ)Φ(f) h j ι j m h1 (Θ)[1 Φ(f)] h 2 j (1 ι j) (s 2 h0 (Θ) + m2 h0 (Θ))Φ(f) h 2 j ι j (s 2 h1 (Θ) + m2 h1 (Θ))[1 Φ(f)] w j (1 ι j ) m w0 (Θ)Φ(f) w j ι j m w1 (Θ)[1 Φ(f)] w 2 j (1 ι j) (s 2 w0 (Θ) + m2 w0 (Θ))Φ(f) wj 2ι j (s 2 w1 (Θ) + m2 w1 (Θ))[1 Φ(f)] h j w j (1 ι j ) (c 0 (Θ) + m h0 (Θ)m w0 (Θ)) Φ(f) h j w j ι j (c 1 (Θ) + m h1 (Θ)m w1 (Θ)) [1 Φ(f)] where we have an overidentified system of 11 moments and 10 parameters. The efficient GMM estimator solves ˆΘ GMM = arg max 1 m (x j Θ) W 1 m(x j Θ) Θ N N j subject to the reduced-form inequality (C.5) implied by our structural covariance restriction where at the first stage W = I 11 is an identity matrix and at the second stage the optimal weighting matrix is W E = ( E{m(Θ)m (Θ)} ) 1 j which we consistently estimate by Ŵ E ( ˆΘ) = 1 N m(x j ˆΘ)m (x j ˆΘ) j 1 using ˆΘ from the first stage. In a Monte Carlo study the efficient overidentified GMM estimator has similar properties to the ML estimator but is slightly inferior. In the sample the overidentified GMM estimates are quantitatively very close to the ML estimates and we do not report them for brevity. In section 5.1 of the paper we report the square root of the overidentified GMM objective function 18

19 where as the weighting matrix we use the diagonal (matrix) of ŴE( ˆΘ): 1 N m (x j ˆΘ) Ŵ D ( ˆΘ) 1 N j m(x j ˆΘ) j 1/2 11 = k=1 ( 1 N j m k(x j ˆΘ) ˆσ 2 mk ( ˆΘ) ) 2 1/2. D.4 GMM Bounds We provide here the derivations for the GMM Bounds in section 5.3 of the paper which were omitted from the main text. The underidentified system of moments used in the GMM bounds analysis includes a number of the same moments as the overidentified GMM estimation discussed above (in particular the fraction of exporters and the conditional first moments of wages and employment). We derive here the unconditional second moments of employment and wages: σ 2 h = var(α h + µ h ι + u) = σ 2 u + µ 2 h var(ι) + 2µ hcov(ι u) = σ 2 u + µ 2 h Φ(f)[1 Φ(f)] + 2µ hρ u σ u φ(f) where we used the fact that var(ι) = Φ(f)[1 Φ(f)] since ι = I{z f} is a Bernoulli zero-one random variable with P{ι = 1} = P{z f} = 1 Φ(f) and that: cov(ι u) = E{ιu} Eι Eu = E{ιu} = [1 Φ(f)] E{u ι = 1} = [1 Φ(f)] ρ u σ u φ(f) 1 Φ(f) = ρ uσ u φ(f) where the expression for E{u ι = 1} = E{u z f} was derived above. Following similar steps we derive the expressions for: σ 2 w = var(w) = σ 2 ω + µ 2 wφ(f)[1 Φ(f)] + 2µ w ρ ω σ ω φ(f) σ hw = cov(h w) = ζσ 2 u + µ h µ w Φ(f)[1 Φ(f)] + [µ h ρ ω σ ω + µ w ρ u σ u ]φ(f) where w = α w + µ w ι + ω and we used the fact that cov(u ω) = cov(u ζu + v) = ζσ 2 u. We also make use of the following result: cov(ι u + ω) = [ρ u σ u + ρ ω σ ω ]φ(f) = [(1 + ζ)ρ u σ u + ρ v σ v ]φ(f) which parallels the derivations for cov(ι u) above. We next discuss the coefficients in the regression of wages on employment and export status. 19

20 We have: E{w h ι = 1} = α h + µ h + = α h + µ h + z f z f E{ω u z} dφ(z) 1 ˆΦ E { ρ ω σ ω z + (ω ρ ω σ ω z) (u ρ u σ u z) z } dφ(z) 1 ˆΦ = [α h + µ h + ρ ω σ ω λ(f)] + b[h α h µ h ρ u σ u λ(f)] E{w h ι = 0} = α h + E{ω u z} dφ(z) ˆΦ z<f where b is the regression coefficient in: = [α h ρ ω σ ω λ( f)] + b[h α h + ρ u σ u λ( f)] E { ω ρ ω σ ω z u ρ u σ u z } = b(u ρ u σ u z) which is independent from z as (u ρ u σ u z) and (ω ρ ω σ ω z) are jointly normal and independent from z and the regression coefficient b is given by: b = cov( u ρ u σ u z ω ρ ω σ ω z ) var ( u ρ u σ u z ) Combining the above expressions together we can write: where = σ uω ρ u σ u ρ ω σ ω σ 2 u(1 ρ 2 u) E{w h ι} = λ o + λ s h + λ x ι λ o = [α h ρ ω σ ωˆλ( f)] b[αh ρ u σ uˆλ( f)] λ s = b λ x = (µ w bµ h ) + [ˆλ(f) ˆλ( f)](ρ ω σ ω bρ u σ u ). Additionally we calculate the R 2 in this regression: = ζ ρ uσ u ρ v σ v σ 2 u(1 ρ 2 u). R 2 = 1 var (w E{w h ι}) σ 2 w = 2cov (w E{w h ι}) var (E{w h ι}) σ 2 w 20

21 = 2 bσ uω + µ w (bµ h + λ x )ˆΦ(1 ˆΦ) + [bµ w ρ u σ u + (bµ h + λ x )ρ ω σ ω ] ˆφ σ 2 ω + µ 2 w ˆΦ(1 ˆΦ) + 2µ w ρ ω σ ω ˆφ b2 σ 2 u + (bµ h + λ x ) 2 ˆΦ(1 ˆΦ) + 2b[bµh + λ x ]ρ u σ u ˆφ σ 2 ω + µ 2 w ˆΦ(1 ˆΦ) + 2µ w ρ ω σ ω ˆφ = (2ζ b)bσ 2 u + (bµ h + λ x ) [ 2µ w bµ h λ x]ˆφ(1 ˆΦ) + 2 [ b(µw bµ h λ x )ρ uσ u +(bµ h +λ x )ρ ωσ ω σ 2 ω + µ 2 w ˆΦ(1 ˆΦ) + 2µ w ρ ω σ ω ˆφ ] ˆφ. With this we can prove the following result: Lemma S.2 λ s contains additional information beyond what is already known from the moments in (A7) in the appendix at the end of the paper while λ o λ x and R 2 provide no additional information beyond what is contained in λ s. Proof: The value of b cannot be reconstructed from the unconditional second moments because it depends on the covariance between h and w conditional on export status. However given b we can reconstruct the values of λ o λ x and R 2 from the first conditional and second unconditional moments of the data (h w ι). For example λ x = E{w bh h ι = 1} E{w bh h ι = 0} = E{w bh ι = 1} E{w bh ι = 0} = [ w 1 b h 1 ] [ w 0 b h 0 ] λ o = Ew beh λ x Eι and a similar result can be shown for the R 2 using the expression above. D.5 Identification We first report the results of a Monte Carlo exercise in which we show that our estimation procedure correctly recovers the true parameters when the data are generated according to the model. We next provide an analytical characterization of the relationship between the model s parameters and moments in the data. For our maximum likelihood estimator we derive closed-form expressions for the score of the likelihood function. For the overidentified GMM estimator considered in Section D.3 above we derive closed-form expressions for the relationship between the parameters of the model and the first and second moments of the wage and employment distributions conditional on export status. Monte Carlo: We assume the following data generation process: h = α h + µ h ι + u w = α w + µ w ι + ζu + v ι = I {z f}. (D.2) 21

22 (u v z) N (0 Σ R ) Σ R = σu 2 0 σv 2 ρ u σ u ρ v σ u 1. (D.3) We assume the following parameter values: α h = 0 α w = 0 µ h = 1 µ w = 0.5 σ u = 1.1 σ v = 0.8 ρ u = 0.4 ρ v = 0.2 ζ = 0.5 which satisfy the inequality constraint (C.5) implied by our structural covariance restriction: σ θη = 0 ζ µ w µ h < ζ + σ 2 v (1 + ζ)σu 2. We consider 50 replications of the model. For each replication we draw realizations of (u v z) for hypothetical firms from the joint normal distribution (D.3). Given these realizations for (u v z) we compute employment wages and export status (h w ι) using the structure of the reduced-form model (D.2). Given these values for (h w ι) we estimate the parameters of the model using maximum likelihood. We repeat this exercise for each of the 50 replications. In Figure D.1 we display the distribution of the estimated parameters across the 50 replications. Each panel corresponds to a different parameter. Each panel shows the true value of the parameter (as the red vertical line) and the histogram of the parameter estimates across the 50 replications. We find that the estimated parameters are tightly clustered around the true values of the model s parameters. Therefore our estimation procedure indeed correctly recovers the true values of the parameters when the data are generated according to the model. Score of the Likelihood Function: We now provide closed-form solutions for the first-order conditions of the log likelihood function with respect to the parameters (the score of the likelihood function). These closed-form solutions directly relate the estimated parameters of the model to moments in the data. The log likelihood function is: { ( )} ln L = ι=0 ln σ u + ln φ (û) ln σ v + ln φ (ˆv) + ln Φ ˆf + { ι=1 ln σ u + ln φ (û) ln σ v + ln φ (ˆv) + ln [ 1 Φ ( ˆf )]} 22

23 Frequency Frequency Frequency Frequency Frequency Frequency Frequency Frequency 50 Panel A : 7 h 50 Panel B : 7 w 50 Panel C : ; u Panel D : ; v 50 Panel D : < u 50 Panel E : < v Panel F : f 50 Panel G : Figure D.1: Monte Carlo Results where (û ˆv ˆf) are related to the observed data (h w ι) and model parameters (αh α w µ h µ w σ u σ v ρ u ρ v ζ) as follows: f = û = h α h µ h ι σ ( u w αw µ w ι ) ζ ( h α h µ h ι ) ˆv = f ρ u = 1 ρ 2 u ρ 2 v ˆf = f ρ u û ρ vˆv σ v ρ u ρ v = 1 ρ 2 u ρ 2 v ρ v 1 ρ 2 u ρ 2 v where φ ( ) is the standard normal density function and Φ ( ) is the standard normal cumulative distribution function. 23

24 First-order condition for σ u ln L σ u = ι=0 1 σ u + φ (û) / σ u φ (û) ( ) Φ ˆf / σ u + ( ) Φ ˆf + ι=1 1 σ u + φ (û) / σ u φ (û) ( ) Φ ˆf / σ u ( ) 1 Φ ˆf. where we have used φ (ˆv) / σ u = 0. φ (û) σ u φ (û) û = φ (û) û û σ u = ûφ (û) û = û σ u σ u ( ) ( ) Φ ˆf Φ ˆf = σ u ˆf ( ) Φ ˆf ˆf ( ) = φ ˆf ρ u û σ u First-order condition for σ v ln L σ v = ι=0 1 σ v + φ (ˆv) / σ v φ (ˆv) ( ) Φ ˆf / σ v + ( ) Φ ˆf + ι=1 1 σ v + φ (ˆv) / σ v φ (ˆv) ( ) Φ ˆf / σ v ( ) 1 Φ ˆf. where we have used φ (û) / σ v = 0. φ (ˆv) σ v φ (ˆv) ˆv = φ (ˆv) ˆv ˆv σ v = ˆvφ (ˆv) ˆv = ˆv σ v σ v ( ) ( ) Φ ˆf Φ ˆf = σ v ˆf ( ) Φ ˆf ˆf ( ) = φ ˆf ρ v ˆv σ v 24

25 First-order condition for ζ ln L ζ = ι=0 φ (ˆv) / ζ φ (ˆv) ( ) Φ ˆf / ζ + ( ) Φ ˆf + φ (ˆv) ζ φ (ˆv) ˆv = ι=1 φ (ˆv) ˆv ˆv ζ = ˆvφ (ˆv) ˆv ζ = (h α h µ h ι) σ v ( ) ( ) Φ ˆf Φ ˆf ˆv = ζ ˆf ρ v ζ ( ) Φ ˆf ˆf ( ) = φ ˆf. φ (ˆv) / ζ φ (ˆv) ( ) Φ ˆf / ζ ( ) 1 Φ ˆf. First-order condition for α h { ln L φ(û)/ α α h = h ι=0 φ(û) + φ(ˆv)/ α h φ(ˆv) + Φ( } { [ ˆf)/ α h Φ( ˆf) φ(û)/ α + h ι=1 φ(û) + φ(ˆv)/ α h φ(ˆv) ( ) Φ ˆf α h φ (û) α h φ (û) û φ (ˆv) α h = φ (û) û û α h = ûφ (û) û α h = 1 σ u φ (ˆv) ˆv = φ (ˆv) ˆv ˆv α h = ˆvφ (ˆv) ˆv α h = ζ σ v [ û ˆv = ρ u + ρ v α h α h ) Φ ( ˆf ˆf ( ) = φ ˆf. ( ) ] Φ ˆf ˆf Φ( ˆf)/ α h 1 Φ( ˆf) ]} 25

26 First-order condition for µ h { ln L φ(û)/ µ µ h = h ι=0 φ(û) + φ(ˆv)/ µ h φ(ˆv) + Φ( } { [ ˆf)/ µ h Φ( ˆf) φ(û)/ µ + h ι=1 φ(û) + φ(ˆv)/ µ h φ(ˆv) φ (û) µ h = φ (û) û φ (û) û û µ h = ûφ (û) û µ h = ι σ u φ (ˆv) µ h = φ (ˆv) ˆv φ (ˆv) ˆv ˆv µ h = ˆvφ (ˆv) ˆv = ζι µ h σ v ( ) Φ ˆf [ û ˆv = ρ u + ρ v µ h µ h ( ) Φ ˆf ˆf µ h ( ) = φ ˆf. ( ) ] Φ ˆf ˆf Φ( ˆf)/ µ h 1 Φ( ˆf) ]} First-order condition for α w ln L α w = ι=0 φ (ˆv) / α w φ (ˆv) ( ) Φ ˆf / α w + ( ) Φ ˆf + φ (ˆv) α w φ (ˆv) ˆv = φ (ˆv) ˆv ι=1 ˆv α w = ˆvφ (ˆv) ˆv = 1 α w σ v ( ) ( Φ ˆf ˆv Φ ˆf) = ρ v α w α w ˆf ( ) Φ ˆf ( ) ˆf = φ ˆf. φ (ˆv) / α w φ (ˆv) ( ) Φ ˆf / α w ( ) 1 Φ ˆf 26

27 First-order condition for µ w ln L µ w = ι=0 φ (ˆv) / µ w φ (ˆv) ( ) Φ ˆf / µ w + ( ) Φ ˆf + φ (ˆv) µ w = φ (ˆv) ˆv φ (ˆv) ˆv ι=1 ˆv µ w = ˆvφ (ˆv) ˆv = ι µ w σ v ( ) ( Φ ˆf ˆv Φ ˆf) = ρ v µ w µ w ˆf ( ) Φ ˆf ( ) ˆf = φ ˆf. φ (ˆv) / µ w φ (ˆv) ( ) Φ ˆf / µ w ( ) 1 Φ ˆf First-order condition for ρ u ln L ρ u = ι=0 ( ) Φ ˆf / ρ u ( ) Φ ˆf ι=1 ( ) ( ) Φ ˆf Φ ˆf = ˆf ρ u ˆf ρ u ˆf = û ρ u ( ) Φ ˆf ( ) ˆf = φ ˆf. ( ) Φ ˆf / ρ u ( ) 1 Φ ˆf First-order condition for ρ v ln L ρ v = ι=0 ( ) Φ ˆf / ρ v ( ) Φ ˆf ι=1 ( ) ( ) Φ ˆf Φ ˆf = ˆf ρ v ˆf ρ v ˆf ρ v = ˆv ( ) Φ ˆf / ρ v ( ) 1 Φ ˆf 27

28 First-order condition for f ln L f = ι=0 ( ) Φ ˆf ˆf ( ) Φ ˆf ( ) = φ ˆf. / f ( ) Φ ˆf ι=1 ( ) Φ ˆf / f ( ) 1 Φ ˆf ( ) Φ ˆf f = ( ) Φ ˆf ˆf ˆf f Exactly-identified GMM: ˆf = 1 f ( ) Φ ˆf ( ) ˆf = φ ˆf. We now characterize the relationship between the model parameters and the moments in the data used in the overidentified GMM estimator considered in Section D.3 above. We consider an exactly-identified specification of the GMM system (D.1) in terms of first and second moments of wages and employment conditional on export status. In this case the mapping between the model parameters and moments in the data is particularly transparent as the exactly-identified GMM system has a recursive structure in which we can sequentially solve for the model parameters using the moments in the data. In a first equation bloc the export threshold f can be determined from the observed fraction of firms that export: ῑ 1 = Eι j = 1 Φ(f) which implies: f = Φ 1 (f) Φ (f) = 1 ῑ 1 where a bar above a variable denotes a value observed in the data. In a second block of equations the market access standard deviation and correlation parameters (µ h σ u ρ u ) can be determined from the conditional and unconditional first and second moments of employment in (D.1) and the solution for f above which imply: ρ 2 uσu 2 s 2 0 = s2 1 Λ (f) Λ ( f) µ h = [ m h1 m h0 ] ρ u σ u [λ (f) λ ( f)] σu 2 = s 2 h µ2 h Φ (f) [1 Φ (f)] 2µ hρ u σ u φ (f). In a third block of equations the market access standard deviation and correlation parameters (µ w σ v 28

29 ρ v ) can be determined from the conditional and unconditional first and second moments of wages in (D.1) and the solution for f above which imply: ρ 2 ωσω 2 = s2 w0 s2 w1 Λ (f) Λ ( f) µ w = [ w 1 w 0 ] ρ ω σ ω [λ (f) λ ( f)] σ 2 ω = s 2 w µ 2 wφ (f) [1 Φ (f)] 2µ w ρ ω σ ω φ (f). In a fourth block of equations the covariance parameter ζ can be determined from the conditional covariance of wages and employment in (D.1) and the solutions for (f σ u σ ω ρ u ρ ω ) above which imply: ζ = c hw {µ h µ w Φ (f) [1 Φ (f)] + µ h ρ ω σ ω φ (f) + µ w ρ u σ u φ (f)}. Having determined {f α h α w µ h µ w σ u σ ω ρ u ρ ω ζ} from the above moments in the data we obtain (σ v ρ v ) from the definitions of (σ ω ρ ω ): σ v = [ σω 2 ζ 2 σu 2 ] 1 2 ρ v = ρ ωσ ω ζρ u σ u σ v. E Extensions and Generalizations E.1 Isomorphisms Class of theoretical models: We now provide a formal analysis of the class of models that are isomorphic in terms of their predictions for wages employment and export status to the Helpman Itskhoki Muendler and Redding (henceforth HIMR) model developed above. This class of models is defined by the following assumptions: (a) Revenues and employment are power functions of export status and two stochastic shocks (b) Profits and wage bills are constant shares of revenues (c) Fixed exporting costs are subject to a third stochastic shock (d) The three stochastic shocks are joint normally distributed. The class of models defined by these assumptions can be represented as follows: R = κ r [1 + ι (Υ x 1)] ψr (e θ) ξ r (e η ) φr (E.4) H = κ h [1 + ι (Υ x 1)] ψ h ( e θ) ξ h (e η ) φ h (E.5) W = κ w [1 + ι (Υ x 1)] ψw (e θ) ξ w (e η ) φw (E.6) ( ) ι = I {κ π Υ ψr x 1 (e θ) } ξ r (e η ) φr F x e ε (E.7) Υ x > 1 F x > 0 29

30 ξ h + ξ w = ξ r φ h + φ w = φ r ψ h + ψ w = ψ r. Reduced-form representation: Taking logarithms in (E.4)-(E.7) we obtain: h = α h + µ h ι + ξ h θ + φ h η (E.8) w = α w + µ w ι + ξ w θ + φ w η (E.9) { } 1 ι = I σ (ξ rθ + φ r η ε) f (E.10) α s = log κ s s {r h w π} µ s = ψ s log Υ x s {h w} f = 1 ( [ ]) α π + log F x log Υ ψr x 1. σ We now transform this empirical system by orthogonalizing the errors in the employment and wage equations. We define: v = u = ξ h θ + φ h η ( φ w ξ ) w φ h η πu ξ h ζ = ξ w ξ h + π z = 1 [(1 + ζ) u + v ε] σ where π is the projection coefficient of η on u. Using these definitions we can re-write the empirical system (E.8)-(E.10) as: h = α h + µ h ι + u (E.11) w = α w + µ w ι + ζu + v ι = I {z f}. (E.12) (E.13) Under the assumptions above we have the following theoretical restriction: µ h + µ w = log Υ x > 0. Under the additional assumptions that ψ h ψ w > 0 we also obtain the following additional theoretical restriction: µ h µ w > 0. 30

31 Under the assumption that {θ η ε} are joint normally distributed {u v z} are also joint normally distributed. The reduced-form equations (E.11)-(E.13) are identical to those in the HIMR model. Therefore any structural model that can be mapped to the mathematical structure in (E.4)-(E.7) has the same reducedform econometric specification as the HIMR structural model. Likelihood function: Since the reduced-form equations (E.11)-(E.13) take exactly the same form as in the HIMR model the likelihood function also takes exactly the same form as in the HIMR model. L(Θ X) = j P{h j w j ι j = 0} j P{h j w j ι j = 1} P{h w ι = 0} = P{u = h α h v = (w α w ) ζ(h α h ) z < f} ( ) = 1 φ (û(x)) 1 f ρ u û(x) ρ φ (ˆv(x)) Φ vˆv(x) σ u σ v 1 ρ 2 u ρ 2 v P{h w ι = 1} = P{u = h α h µ h v = (w α w µ w ) ζ(h α h µ h ) z f} [ ( )] = 1 φ (û(x)) 1 f ρ u û(x) ρ φ (ˆv(x)) 1 Φ vˆv(x) σ u σ v 1 ρ 2 u ρ 2 v where û(x) = h α h µ h ι σ ( u w αw µ w ι ) ζ ( h α h µ h ι ) ˆv(x) =. σ v Counterfactuals: For all models within this class the reduced-form coefficients Θ {α h α w ζ σ u σ v ρ u ρ v µ h µ w f} are sufficient statistics for wages employment and export status (and hence wage inequality). Therefore for all models within this class counterfactuals can be undertaken following exactly the same procedure as for the HIMR model above. Fair wages example: Finally we provide an example of another model within the class defined by assumptions (a)-(d) above that is isomorphic to the HIMR model. This example is based on an extension of the fair wages model of Egger and Kreickemeier (2012). As in the HIMR model each firm faces a fixed exporting cost (e ε F x ) and an iceberg variable trade cost (τ). A firm of productivity θ that employs a measure h of workers produces the following measure of output: y = e θ h. 31

Trade and Inequality: From Theory to Estimation

Trade and Inequality: From Theory to Estimation Trade and Inequality: From Theory to Estimation Elhanan Helpman Oleg Itskhoki Marc Muendler Stephen Redding Harvard Princeton UC San Diego Princeton MEF Italia Dipartimento del Tesoro September 2014 1

More information

Wages, Unemployment and Inequality with Heterogeneous Firms and Workers

Wages, Unemployment and Inequality with Heterogeneous Firms and Workers Wages, Unemployment and Inequality with Heterogeneous Firms and Workers Elhanan Helpman Oleg Itskhoki Stephen Redding Harvard and CIFAR Harvard LSE and CEP Penn State June 12, 2008 1 / 28 Introduction

More information

SELECTION EFFECTS WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS: ONLINE APPENDIX

SELECTION EFFECTS WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS: ONLINE APPENDIX SELECTION EFFECTS WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS: ONLINE APPENDIX Monika Mrázová University of Geneva and CEPR J. Peter Neary University of Oxford, CEPR and CESifo Appendix K: Selection into Worker Screening

More information

Web Appendix for Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Not for Publication)

Web Appendix for Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Not for Publication) Web Appendix for Heterogeneous Firms and Trade Not for Publication Marc J. Melitz Harvard University, NBER and CEPR Stephen J. Redding Princeton University, NBER and CEPR December 17, 2012 1 Introduction

More information

CROSS-COUNTRY DIFFERENCES IN PRODUCTIVITY: THE ROLE OF ALLOCATION AND SELECTION

CROSS-COUNTRY DIFFERENCES IN PRODUCTIVITY: THE ROLE OF ALLOCATION AND SELECTION ONLINE APPENDIX CROSS-COUNTRY DIFFERENCES IN PRODUCTIVITY: THE ROLE OF ALLOCATION AND SELECTION By ERIC BARTELSMAN, JOHN HALTIWANGER AND STEFANO SCARPETTA This appendix presents a detailed sensitivity

More information

Global Production with Export Platforms

Global Production with Export Platforms Discussion of Global Production with Export Platforms by Felix Tintelnot Oleg Itskhoki Princeton University NBER ITI Summer Institute Boston, July 2013 1 / 6 Introduction Question: Where should firms locate

More information

International Prices and Exchange Rates Econ 2530b, Gita Gopinath

International Prices and Exchange Rates Econ 2530b, Gita Gopinath International Prices and Exchange Rates Econ 2530b, Gita Gopinath Model variable mark-ups CES demand: Constant mark-ups: ( ) εin µ in = log ε in 1 Given that markups are constant, Γ in = 0. ( ) θ = log.

More information

SUPPLEMENT TO MARKET ENTRY COSTS, PRODUCER HETEROGENEITY, AND EXPORT DYNAMICS (Econometrica, Vol. 75, No. 3, May 2007, )

SUPPLEMENT TO MARKET ENTRY COSTS, PRODUCER HETEROGENEITY, AND EXPORT DYNAMICS (Econometrica, Vol. 75, No. 3, May 2007, ) Econometrica Supplementary Material SUPPLEMENT TO MARKET ENTRY COSTS, PRODUCER HETEROGENEITY, AND EXPORT DYNAMICS (Econometrica, Vol. 75, No. 3, May 2007, 653 710) BY SANGHAMITRA DAS, MARK ROBERTS, AND

More information

Inequality, Costly Redistribution and Welfare in an Open Economy

Inequality, Costly Redistribution and Welfare in an Open Economy Inequality, Costly Redistribution and Welfare in an Open Economy Pol Antràs Alonso de Gortari Oleg Itskhoki Harvard Harvard Princeton TRISTAN Workshop University of Bayreuth June 2016 1 / 29 Introduction

More information

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models Dave Donaldson (MIT) CEMMAP MC July 2018 1 All material based on earlier courses taught

More information

Trade, Inequality and Costly Redistribution

Trade, Inequality and Costly Redistribution Trade, Inequality and Costly Redistribution Pol Antràs Alonso de Gortari Oleg Itskhoki Harvard Harvard Princeton ILO Symposium September 2015 1 / 30 Introduction International trade raises real income

More information

More on Roy Model of Self-Selection

More on Roy Model of Self-Selection V. J. Hotz Rev. May 26, 2007 More on Roy Model of Self-Selection Results drawn on Heckman and Sedlacek JPE, 1985 and Heckman and Honoré, Econometrica, 1986. Two-sector model in which: Agents are income

More information

Online Appendix: Entry into Export Markets

Online Appendix: Entry into Export Markets Online Appendix: Entry into Export Markets Data All the firms in our sample have Chile as country of origin and we restrict our analysis to firms whose main activity is the manufacture of chemicals and

More information

Import Protection as Export Destruction

Import Protection as Export Destruction Import Protection as Export Destruction Hiroyuki Kasahara Beverly Lapham December 2005 Incomplete Abstract his paper develops a dynamic, stochastic industry model of heterogeneous firms to examine the

More information

Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection

Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection Eric Bartelsman, John Haltiwanger & Stefano Scarpetta American Economic Review (2013) Presented by Beatriz González January

More information

Chapter 6. Panel Data. Joan Llull. Quantitative Statistical Methods II Barcelona GSE

Chapter 6. Panel Data. Joan Llull. Quantitative Statistical Methods II Barcelona GSE Chapter 6. Panel Data Joan Llull Quantitative Statistical Methods II Barcelona GSE Introduction Chapter 6. Panel Data 2 Panel data The term panel data refers to data sets with repeated observations over

More information

Notes on Heterogeneity, Aggregation, and Market Wage Functions: An Empirical Model of Self-Selection in the Labor Market

Notes on Heterogeneity, Aggregation, and Market Wage Functions: An Empirical Model of Self-Selection in the Labor Market Notes on Heterogeneity, Aggregation, and Market Wage Functions: An Empirical Model of Self-Selection in the Labor Market Heckman and Sedlacek, JPE 1985, 93(6), 1077-1125 James Heckman University of Chicago

More information

Lecture 11/12. Roy Model, MTE, Structural Estimation

Lecture 11/12. Roy Model, MTE, Structural Estimation Lecture 11/12. Roy Model, MTE, Structural Estimation Economics 2123 George Washington University Instructor: Prof. Ben Williams Roy model The Roy model is a model of comparative advantage: Potential earnings

More information

Team Production and the Allocation of Creativity across Global and Local Sectors

Team Production and the Allocation of Creativity across Global and Local Sectors RIETI Discussion Paper Series 15-E-111 Team Production and the Allocation of Creativity across Global and Local Sectors NAGAMACHI Kohei Kagawa University The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry

More information

Linear models. Linear models are computationally convenient and remain widely used in. applied econometric research

Linear models. Linear models are computationally convenient and remain widely used in. applied econometric research Linear models Linear models are computationally convenient and remain widely used in applied econometric research Our main focus in these lectures will be on single equation linear models of the form y

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INEQUALITY AND UNEMPLOYMENT IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY. Elhanan Helpman Oleg Itskhoki Stephen Redding

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INEQUALITY AND UNEMPLOYMENT IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY. Elhanan Helpman Oleg Itskhoki Stephen Redding NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INEQUALITY AND UNEMPLOYMENT IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY Elhanan Helpman Oleg Itskhoki Stephen Redding Working Paper 14478 http://www.nber.org/papers/w14478 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances Johannes Brumm University of Zurich Georgios Georgiadis European Central Bank Johannes Gräb European Central Bank Fabian Trottner Princeton

More information

Dealing With Endogeneity

Dealing With Endogeneity Dealing With Endogeneity Junhui Qian December 22, 2014 Outline Introduction Instrumental Variable Instrumental Variable Estimation Two-Stage Least Square Estimation Panel Data Endogeneity in Econometrics

More information

Econometrics of Panel Data

Econometrics of Panel Data Econometrics of Panel Data Jakub Mućk Meeting # 6 Jakub Mućk Econometrics of Panel Data Meeting # 6 1 / 36 Outline 1 The First-Difference (FD) estimator 2 Dynamic panel data models 3 The Anderson and Hsiao

More information

Multivariate GARCH models.

Multivariate GARCH models. Multivariate GARCH models. Financial market volatility moves together over time across assets and markets. Recognizing this commonality through a multivariate modeling framework leads to obvious gains

More information

Online Appendix The Growth of Low Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market. By David H. Autor and David Dorn

Online Appendix The Growth of Low Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market. By David H. Autor and David Dorn Online Appendix The Growth of Low Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market By David H. Autor and David Dorn 1 2 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MONTH YEAR I. Online Appendix Tables

More information

Trade, Neoclassical Growth and Heterogeneous Firms

Trade, Neoclassical Growth and Heterogeneous Firms Trade, Neoclassical Growth and eterogeneous Firms Julian Emami Namini Department of Economics, University of Duisburg Essen, Campus Essen, Germany Email: emami@vwl.uni essen.de 10th March 2006 Abstract

More information

Granular Comparative Advantage

Granular Comparative Advantage Granular Comparative Advantage Cecile Gaubert cecile.gaubert@berkeley.edu Oleg Itskhoki itskhoki@princeton.edu Stanford University March 2018 1 / 26 Exports are Granular Freund and Pierola (2015): Export

More information

EC212: Introduction to Econometrics Review Materials (Wooldridge, Appendix)

EC212: Introduction to Econometrics Review Materials (Wooldridge, Appendix) 1 EC212: Introduction to Econometrics Review Materials (Wooldridge, Appendix) Taisuke Otsu London School of Economics Summer 2018 A.1. Summation operator (Wooldridge, App. A.1) 2 3 Summation operator For

More information

Consumption-led Growth

Consumption-led Growth Consumption-led Growth (preliminary work in progress) Markus Brunnermeier markus@princeton.edu Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas pog@berkeley.edu Oleg Itskhoki itskhoki@princeton.edu Princeton University November

More information

Worker Heterogeneity, Wage Inequality, and International Trade: Theory and Evidence from Brazil

Worker Heterogeneity, Wage Inequality, and International Trade: Theory and Evidence from Brazil Worker Heterogeneity, Wage Inequality, and International Trade: Theory and Evidence from Brazil Rodrigo Adão Princeton University / University of Chicago rradao@princeton.edu December, 2016 World commodity

More information

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill remium Ariel Burstein UCLA and NBER Jonathan Vogel Columbia and NBER April 22 Abstract In this Addendum we set up a perfectly competitive version

More information

DSGE Methods. Estimation of DSGE models: GMM and Indirect Inference. Willi Mutschler, M.Sc.

DSGE Methods. Estimation of DSGE models: GMM and Indirect Inference. Willi Mutschler, M.Sc. DSGE Methods Estimation of DSGE models: GMM and Indirect Inference Willi Mutschler, M.Sc. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics University of Münster willi.mutschler@wiwi.uni-muenster.de Summer

More information

Lecture 11 Roy model, MTE, PRTE

Lecture 11 Roy model, MTE, PRTE Lecture 11 Roy model, MTE, PRTE Economics 2123 George Washington University Instructor: Prof. Ben Williams Roy Model Motivation The standard textbook example of simultaneity is a supply and demand system

More information

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008) Getting to page 31 in Galí 2008) H J Department of Economics University of Copenhagen December 4 2012 Abstract This note shows in detail how to compute the solutions for output inflation and the nominal

More information

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory)

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory) 14.581 MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory) Dave Donaldson Spring 2011 Introduction to Gravity Models Recall that in this course we have so far seen a wide range of trade models:

More information

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton Figure a. Aggregate exchange rate disconnect (levels) 28.5

More information

Fall 2017 STAT 532 Homework Peter Hoff. 1. Let P be a probability measure on a collection of sets A.

Fall 2017 STAT 532 Homework Peter Hoff. 1. Let P be a probability measure on a collection of sets A. 1. Let P be a probability measure on a collection of sets A. (a) For each n N, let H n be a set in A such that H n H n+1. Show that P (H n ) monotonically converges to P ( k=1 H k) as n. (b) For each n

More information

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory)

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory) 14.581 International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory) 14.581 Week 9 Spring 2013 14.581 (Week 9) Gravity Models (Theory) Spring 2013 1 / 44 Today s Plan 1 The Simplest Gravity Model: Armington

More information

The Origins of Firm Heterogeneity: A Production Network Approach

The Origins of Firm Heterogeneity: A Production Network Approach The Origins of Firm Heterogeneity: A Production Network Approach A. Bernard E. Dhyne G. Magerman K. Manova A. Moxnes Tuck@Dartmouth NBB ECARES Oxford Oslo CEPR, NBER UMons NBB CEPR CEPR Princeton, September

More information

DSGE-Models. Limited Information Estimation General Method of Moments and Indirect Inference

DSGE-Models. Limited Information Estimation General Method of Moments and Indirect Inference DSGE-Models General Method of Moments and Indirect Inference Dr. Andrea Beccarini Willi Mutschler, M.Sc. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics University of Münster willi.mutschler@uni-muenster.de

More information

Importing Skill-Biased Technology

Importing Skill-Biased Technology Importing Skill-Biased Technology Ariel Burstein Javier Cravino Jonathan Vogel January 2012 Intro Motivation Observations Capital equipment (e.g. computers and industrial machinery): Implication embodies

More information

A Robust Approach to Estimating Production Functions: Replication of the ACF procedure

A Robust Approach to Estimating Production Functions: Replication of the ACF procedure A Robust Approach to Estimating Production Functions: Replication of the ACF procedure Kyoo il Kim Michigan State University Yao Luo University of Toronto Yingjun Su IESR, Jinan University August 2018

More information

Globalization, Inequality and Welfare

Globalization, Inequality and Welfare Globalization, Inequality and Welfare Pol Antràs Harvard University Alonso de Gortari Harvard University Oleg Itskhoki Princeton University Harvard - September 7, 2016 Antràs, de Gortari and Itskhoki Globalization,

More information

Labor-Supply Shifts and Economic Fluctuations. Technical Appendix

Labor-Supply Shifts and Economic Fluctuations. Technical Appendix Labor-Supply Shifts and Economic Fluctuations Technical Appendix Yongsung Chang Department of Economics University of Pennsylvania Frank Schorfheide Department of Economics University of Pennsylvania January

More information

Econometrics I KS. Module 2: Multivariate Linear Regression. Alexander Ahammer. This version: April 16, 2018

Econometrics I KS. Module 2: Multivariate Linear Regression. Alexander Ahammer. This version: April 16, 2018 Econometrics I KS Module 2: Multivariate Linear Regression Alexander Ahammer Department of Economics Johannes Kepler University of Linz This version: April 16, 2018 Alexander Ahammer (JKU) Module 2: Multivariate

More information

Linear Regression. Junhui Qian. October 27, 2014

Linear Regression. Junhui Qian. October 27, 2014 Linear Regression Junhui Qian October 27, 2014 Outline The Model Estimation Ordinary Least Square Method of Moments Maximum Likelihood Estimation Properties of OLS Estimator Unbiasedness Consistency Efficiency

More information

An Efficient Estimation Method for Longitudinal Surveys with Monotone Missing Data

An Efficient Estimation Method for Longitudinal Surveys with Monotone Missing Data An Efficient Estimation Method for Longitudinal Surveys with Monotone Missing Data Jae-Kwang Kim 1 Iowa State University June 28, 2012 1 Joint work with Dr. Ming Zhou (when he was a PhD student at ISU)

More information

More formally, the Gini coefficient is defined as. with p(y) = F Y (y) and where GL(p, F ) the Generalized Lorenz ordinate of F Y is ( )

More formally, the Gini coefficient is defined as. with p(y) = F Y (y) and where GL(p, F ) the Generalized Lorenz ordinate of F Y is ( ) Fortin Econ 56 3. Measurement The theoretical literature on income inequality has developed sophisticated measures (e.g. Gini coefficient) on inequality according to some desirable properties such as decomposability

More information

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness On-Line Appendix Jérôme Dugast Thierry Foucault August 30, 07 This note is the on-line appendix for Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. It contains

More information

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999) Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999) The question we are asking is: What are the consequences of a monetary policy shock a shock which is purely related to monetary conditions

More information

Measuring the Gains from Trade: They are Large!

Measuring the Gains from Trade: They are Large! Measuring the Gains from Trade: They are Large! Andrés Rodríguez-Clare (UC Berkeley and NBER) May 12, 2012 Ultimate Goal Quantify effects of trade policy changes Instrumental Question How large are GT?

More information

Applied Microeconometrics (L5): Panel Data-Basics

Applied Microeconometrics (L5): Panel Data-Basics Applied Microeconometrics (L5): Panel Data-Basics Nicholas Giannakopoulos University of Patras Department of Economics ngias@upatras.gr November 10, 2015 Nicholas Giannakopoulos (UPatras) MSc Applied Economics

More information

GMM and SMM. 1. Hansen, L Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators, Econometrica, 50, p

GMM and SMM. 1. Hansen, L Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators, Econometrica, 50, p GMM and SMM Some useful references: 1. Hansen, L. 1982. Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators, Econometrica, 50, p. 1029-54. 2. Lee, B.S. and B. Ingram. 1991 Simulation estimation

More information

The Effects of Monetary Policy on Stock Market Bubbles: Some Evidence

The Effects of Monetary Policy on Stock Market Bubbles: Some Evidence The Effects of Monetary Policy on Stock Market Bubbles: Some Evidence Jordi Gali Luca Gambetti ONLINE APPENDIX The appendix describes the estimation of the time-varying coefficients VAR model. The model

More information

Prices and Exchange Rates: A Theory of Disconnect

Prices and Exchange Rates: A Theory of Disconnect Prices and Exchange Rates: A Theory of isconnect Jose Antonio Rodriguez-Lopez September 2010 Appendix B Online) B.1 The Model with CES Preferences The purpose of this section is to show the similarities

More information

Appendix to The Life-Cycle and the Business-Cycle of Wage Risk - Cross-Country Comparisons

Appendix to The Life-Cycle and the Business-Cycle of Wage Risk - Cross-Country Comparisons Appendix to The Life-Cycle and the Business-Cycle of Wage Risk - Cross-Country Comparisons Christian Bayer Falko Juessen Universität Bonn and IGIER Technische Universität Dortmund and IZA This version:

More information

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market Daron Acemoglu MIT September 20, 2016. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Technology and the Labor Market September 20, 2016. 1 / 51 Technology

More information

Determining Changes in Welfare Distributions at the Micro-level: Updating Poverty Maps By Chris Elbers, Jean O. Lanjouw, and Peter Lanjouw 1

Determining Changes in Welfare Distributions at the Micro-level: Updating Poverty Maps By Chris Elbers, Jean O. Lanjouw, and Peter Lanjouw 1 Determining Changes in Welfare Distributions at the Micro-level: Updating Poverty Maps By Chris Elbers, Jean O. Lanjouw, and Peter Lanjouw 1 Income and wealth distributions have a prominent position in

More information

Robust Predictions in Games with Incomplete Information

Robust Predictions in Games with Incomplete Information Robust Predictions in Games with Incomplete Information joint with Stephen Morris (Princeton University) November 2010 Payoff Environment in games with incomplete information, the agents are uncertain

More information

Estimating the Technology of Children s Skill Formation

Estimating the Technology of Children s Skill Formation Estimating the Technology of Children s Skill Formation Francesco Agostinelli W.P. Carey School of Business, Arizona State University Matthew Wiswall W.P. Carey School of Business, Arizona State University

More information

Binary Models with Endogenous Explanatory Variables

Binary Models with Endogenous Explanatory Variables Binary Models with Endogenous Explanatory Variables Class otes Manuel Arellano ovember 7, 2007 Revised: January 21, 2008 1 Introduction In Part I we considered linear and non-linear models with additive

More information

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms Andrew Bernard, Tuck and NBER Stephen e Redding, LSE and CEPR Peter Schott, Yale and NBER 1 Introduction How do economies respond when opening to trade? Classical

More information

Learning and Global Dynamics

Learning and Global Dynamics Learning and Global Dynamics James Bullard 10 February 2007 Learning and global dynamics The paper for this lecture is Liquidity Traps, Learning and Stagnation, by George Evans, Eran Guse, and Seppo Honkapohja.

More information

INFERENCE APPROACHES FOR INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLE QUANTILE REGRESSION. 1. Introduction

INFERENCE APPROACHES FOR INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLE QUANTILE REGRESSION. 1. Introduction INFERENCE APPROACHES FOR INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLE QUANTILE REGRESSION VICTOR CHERNOZHUKOV CHRISTIAN HANSEN MICHAEL JANSSON Abstract. We consider asymptotic and finite-sample confidence bounds in instrumental

More information

This note introduces some key concepts in time series econometrics. First, we

This note introduces some key concepts in time series econometrics. First, we INTRODUCTION TO TIME SERIES Econometrics 2 Heino Bohn Nielsen September, 2005 This note introduces some key concepts in time series econometrics. First, we present by means of examples some characteristic

More information

Skilled Factor Abundance and Traded Goods Prices

Skilled Factor Abundance and Traded Goods Prices Skilled Factor Abundance and Traded Goods Prices Eddy Bekkers University of Bern Joseph Francois University of Bern and CEPR London Miriam Manchin University College London ABSTRACT: We develop a monopolistic

More information

Discussion Papers In Economics And Business

Discussion Papers In Economics And Business Discussion Papers In Economics And Business Nonlinear Effects of the Transport Costs on the Wage Inequality Yuichiro Matsumoto Discussion Paper 18-07 Graduate School of Economics and Osaka School of International

More information

Motivation Non-linear Rational Expectations The Permanent Income Hypothesis The Log of Gravity Non-linear IV Estimation Summary.

Motivation Non-linear Rational Expectations The Permanent Income Hypothesis The Log of Gravity Non-linear IV Estimation Summary. Econometrics I Department of Economics Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Master in Industrial Economics and Markets Outline Motivation 1 Motivation 2 3 4 5 Motivation Hansen's contributions GMM was developed

More information

Efficiency of repeated-cross-section estimators in fixed-effects models

Efficiency of repeated-cross-section estimators in fixed-effects models Efficiency of repeated-cross-section estimators in fixed-effects models Montezuma Dumangane and Nicoletta Rosati CEMAPRE and ISEG-UTL January 2009 Abstract PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Exploiting across

More information

Labor Union and the Wealth-Income Ratio

Labor Union and the Wealth-Income Ratio Labor Union and the Wealth-Income Ratio Angus C. Chu Zonglai Kou Xueyue Liu November 2017 Abstract We explore how labor union affects the wealth-income ratio in an innovation-driven growth model and find

More information

Habilitationsvortrag: Machine learning, shrinkage estimation, and economic theory

Habilitationsvortrag: Machine learning, shrinkage estimation, and economic theory Habilitationsvortrag: Machine learning, shrinkage estimation, and economic theory Maximilian Kasy May 25, 218 1 / 27 Introduction Recent years saw a boom of machine learning methods. Impressive advances

More information

Panel Data Models. Chapter 5. Financial Econometrics. Michael Hauser WS17/18 1 / 63

Panel Data Models. Chapter 5. Financial Econometrics. Michael Hauser WS17/18 1 / 63 1 / 63 Panel Data Models Chapter 5 Financial Econometrics Michael Hauser WS17/18 2 / 63 Content Data structures: Times series, cross sectional, panel data, pooled data Static linear panel data models:

More information

Short T Panels - Review

Short T Panels - Review Short T Panels - Review We have looked at methods for estimating parameters on time-varying explanatory variables consistently in panels with many cross-section observation units but a small number of

More information

Structural Change, Demographic Transition and Fertility Di erence

Structural Change, Demographic Transition and Fertility Di erence Structural Change, Demographic Transition and Fertility Di erence T. Terry Cheung February 14, 2017 T. Terry Cheung () Structural Change and Fertility February 14, 2017 1 / 35 Question Question: The force

More information

Applied Econometrics (MSc.) Lecture 3 Instrumental Variables

Applied Econometrics (MSc.) Lecture 3 Instrumental Variables Applied Econometrics (MSc.) Lecture 3 Instrumental Variables Estimation - Theory Department of Economics University of Gothenburg December 4, 2014 1/28 Why IV estimation? So far, in OLS, we assumed independence.

More information

Firms, Informality and Development: Theory and evidence from Brazil. Online Appendix

Firms, Informality and Development: Theory and evidence from Brazil. Online Appendix Firms, Informality and Development: Theory and evidence from Brazil Gabriel Ulyssea Online Appendix A Cross country evidence Figure A.1 s left panel displays informal sector s size in Latin American countries,

More information

Lecture 4: Linear panel models

Lecture 4: Linear panel models Lecture 4: Linear panel models Luc Behaghel PSE February 2009 Luc Behaghel (PSE) Lecture 4 February 2009 1 / 47 Introduction Panel = repeated observations of the same individuals (e.g., rms, workers, countries)

More information

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation Daron Acemoglu MIT September 19, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition and Innovation September 19, 2011. 1 / 51 Competition and Innovation

More information

8. Instrumental variables regression

8. Instrumental variables regression 8. Instrumental variables regression Recall: In Section 5 we analyzed five sources of estimation bias arising because the regressor is correlated with the error term Violation of the first OLS assumption

More information

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy Economics 522 Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Princeton University Spring 2014 ERH (Princeton University ) Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy Spring 2014 1 / 34 Restuccia and Rogerson

More information

Recent Advances in the Field of Trade Theory and Policy Analysis Using Micro-Level Data

Recent Advances in the Field of Trade Theory and Policy Analysis Using Micro-Level Data Recent Advances in the Field of Trade Theory and Policy Analysis Using Micro-Level Data July 2012 Bangkok, Thailand Cosimo Beverelli (World Trade Organization) 1 Content a) Endogeneity b) Instrumental

More information

ECON Introductory Econometrics. Lecture 16: Instrumental variables

ECON Introductory Econometrics. Lecture 16: Instrumental variables ECON4150 - Introductory Econometrics Lecture 16: Instrumental variables Monique de Haan (moniqued@econ.uio.no) Stock and Watson Chapter 12 Lecture outline 2 OLS assumptions and when they are violated Instrumental

More information

Endogenous Information Choice

Endogenous Information Choice Endogenous Information Choice Lecture 7 February 11, 2015 An optimizing trader will process those prices of most importance to his decision problem most frequently and carefully, those of less importance

More information

Quantifying the Losses from International Trade

Quantifying the Losses from International Trade Quantifying the Losses from International Trade Spencer Lyon NYU Michael E. Waugh NYU and NBER June 23, 2017 0/23 Big Picture: The Backlash Against Trade Hard to deny that the benefits of globalization

More information

Using Theory to Identify Transitory and Permanent Income Shocks: A Review of the Blundell-Preston Approach

Using Theory to Identify Transitory and Permanent Income Shocks: A Review of the Blundell-Preston Approach Using Theory to Identify Transitory and Permanent Income Shocks: A Review of the Blundell-Preston Approach October 12, 2004 1 Introduction Statements on changes in income inequality based on the cross-sectional

More information

The Limits to Partial Banking Unions: A Political Economy Approach Dana Foarta. Online Appendix. Appendix A Proofs (For Online Publication)

The Limits to Partial Banking Unions: A Political Economy Approach Dana Foarta. Online Appendix. Appendix A Proofs (For Online Publication) The Limits to Partial Banking Unions: A Political Economy Approach ana Foarta Online Appendix A Appendix A Proofs For Online Publication A.1 Proof of Proposition 1 Consider the problem for the policymaker

More information

The Simple Regression Model. Part II. The Simple Regression Model

The Simple Regression Model. Part II. The Simple Regression Model Part II The Simple Regression Model As of Sep 22, 2015 Definition 1 The Simple Regression Model Definition Estimation of the model, OLS OLS Statistics Algebraic properties Goodness-of-Fit, the R-square

More information

Volatility. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University

Volatility. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University Volatility Gerald P. Dwyer Clemson University February 2016 Outline 1 Volatility Characteristics of Time Series Heteroskedasticity Simpler Estimation Strategies Exponentially Weighted Moving Average Use

More information

Measuring the Bias of Technological Change Online Appendix

Measuring the Bias of Technological Change Online Appendix Measuring the Bias of Technological Change Online Appendix Ulrich Doraszelski University of Pennsylvania Jordi Jaumandreu Boston University June 29, 206 Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, Steinberg

More information

Static and Dynamic Gains from Importing Intermediate Inputs: Theory and Evidence

Static and Dynamic Gains from Importing Intermediate Inputs: Theory and Evidence Static and Dynamic Gains from Importing Intermediate Inputs: Theory and Evidence Hongsong Zhang Department of Economics, Penn State University Gains from Importing" Hongsong Zhang, Penn State University

More information

Seminar Lecture. Introduction to Structural Estimation: A Stochastic Life Cycle Model. James Zou. School of Economics (HUST) September 29, 2017

Seminar Lecture. Introduction to Structural Estimation: A Stochastic Life Cycle Model. James Zou. School of Economics (HUST) September 29, 2017 Seminar Lecture Introduction to Structural Estimation: A Stochastic Life Cycle Model James Zou School of Economics (HUST) September 29, 2017 James Zou (School of Economics (HUST)) Seminar Lecture September

More information

1 Estimation of Persistent Dynamic Panel Data. Motivation

1 Estimation of Persistent Dynamic Panel Data. Motivation 1 Estimation of Persistent Dynamic Panel Data. Motivation Consider the following Dynamic Panel Data (DPD) model y it = y it 1 ρ + x it β + µ i + v it (1.1) with i = {1, 2,..., N} denoting the individual

More information

Pricing To Habits and the Law of One Price

Pricing To Habits and the Law of One Price Pricing To Habits and the Law of One Price Morten Ravn 1 Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé 2 Martin Uribe 2 1 European University Institute 2 Duke University Izmir, May 18, 27 Stylized facts we wish to address Pricing-to-Market:

More information

Controlling for Time Invariant Heterogeneity

Controlling for Time Invariant Heterogeneity Controlling for Time Invariant Heterogeneity Yona Rubinstein July 2016 Yona Rubinstein (LSE) Controlling for Time Invariant Heterogeneity 07/16 1 / 19 Observables and Unobservables Confounding Factors

More information

Identification and Estimation Using Heteroscedasticity Without Instruments: The Binary Endogenous Regressor Case

Identification and Estimation Using Heteroscedasticity Without Instruments: The Binary Endogenous Regressor Case Identification and Estimation Using Heteroscedasticity Without Instruments: The Binary Endogenous Regressor Case Arthur Lewbel Boston College Original December 2016, revised July 2017 Abstract Lewbel (2012)

More information

Heteroskedasticity in Panel Data

Heteroskedasticity in Panel Data Essex Summer School in Social Science Data Analysis Panel Data Analysis for Comparative Research Heteroskedasticity in Panel Data Christopher Adolph Department of Political Science and Center for Statistics

More information

Heteroskedasticity in Panel Data

Heteroskedasticity in Panel Data Essex Summer School in Social Science Data Analysis Panel Data Analysis for Comparative Research Heteroskedasticity in Panel Data Christopher Adolph Department of Political Science and Center for Statistics

More information

Identifying Aggregate Liquidity Shocks with Monetary Policy Shocks: An Application using UK Data

Identifying Aggregate Liquidity Shocks with Monetary Policy Shocks: An Application using UK Data Identifying Aggregate Liquidity Shocks with Monetary Policy Shocks: An Application using UK Data Michael Ellington and Costas Milas Financial Services, Liquidity and Economic Activity Bank of England May

More information

Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 4th ed. Chapter 15: Instrumental variables and two stage least squares

Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 4th ed. Chapter 15: Instrumental variables and two stage least squares Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 4th ed. Chapter 15: Instrumental variables and two stage least squares Many economic models involve endogeneity: that is, a theoretical relationship does not fit

More information