VARIATIONAL ANALYSIS OF NASH EQUILIBRIA FOR A MODEL OF TRAFFIC FLOW

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "VARIATIONAL ANALYSIS OF NASH EQUILIBRIA FOR A MODEL OF TRAFFIC FLOW"

Transcription

1 QUARTERLY OF APPLIED MATHEMATICS VOLUME LXX, NUMBER 3 SEPTEMBER 2012, PAGES S X(2012) Article electronically published on May 2, 2012 VARIATIONAL ANALYSIS OF NASH EQUILIBRIA FOR A MODEL OF TRAFFIC FLOW By ALBERTO BRESSAN (Department of Mathematics, Penn State University, University Park, Pennsylvania ), CHEN JIE LIU (Department of Mathematics, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, Shanghai, , China), WEN SHEN (Department of Mathematics, Penn State University, University Park, Pennsylvania ), and FANG YU (Department of Mathematics, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, Shanghai, , China) Dedicated to Constantine Dafermos in the occasion of his 70th birthday Abstract The paper is concerned with Nash equilibrium solutions for the Lighthill- Whitham model of traffic flow, where each driver chooses his own departure time in order to minimize the sum of a departure cost and an arrival cost Estimates are provided on how much the Nash solution may change, depending on the cost functions and on the flux function of the conservation law It is shown that this equilibrium solution can also be determined as a global minimizer for a functional Φ, measuring the maximum total cost among all drivers, in a given traffic pattern The last section of the paper introduces two evolution models, describing how the traffic pattern can change, day after day It is assumed that each driver adjusts his departure time based on previous experience, in order to lower his own cost Numerical simulations are reported, indicating a possible instability of the Nash equilibrium 1 Introduction In this paper we study properties of Nash equilibrium solutions for a model of traffic flow introduced in [1] Car drivers starting from a location A (a residential neighborhood) need to reach a destination B (a working place) all at a given time T 0 There is a cost ϕ for starting early and a cost ψ for arriving late Denoting Received November 16, Mathematics Subject Classification Primary 35L65; Secondary 35Q93, 49J21, 49N70, 49N90 address: bressan@mathpsuedu address: cjliusjtu@gmailcom address: shen w@psuedu address: yufang0820@sjtueducn c 2012 Brown University Reverts to public domain 28 years from publication 495

2 496 ALBERTO BRESSAN, CHEN JIE LIU, WEN SHEN, AND FANG YU by τ d and τ a respectively the departure and the arrival time of an individual driver, his total cost is thus measured by Ψ = ϕ(τ d )+ψ(τ a ) (11) We assume that each driver can choose his departure time in order to minimize this total cost A distribution of departure times is called a Nash equilibrium if no driver can reduce his total cost by choosing a different departure time Of course, in this case all drivers will bear the same total cost It is assumed that all cars travel along the same highway Calling ρ = ρ(t, x) the density of cars at time t at the point x along the road, the Lighthill-Whitham model [9] describes the evolution of ρ in terms of the conservation law ρ t +[ρv(ρ)] x = 0 (12) Here v = v(ρ) is a decreasing function, determining how the velocity of cars varies with the density In a typical setting (Fig 1, left), the flux function ρ ρv(ρ) isconcave down and attains a maximum M = ρ v(ρ )atsomevalueρ of the density As remarked in [1], it is convenient to write (12) as a conservation law for the traffic flux u = ρv(ρ), namely u x + f(u) t = 0 (13) Here we define f(u) =ρ as a partial inverse of the original flux function (Fig 1, center) More precisely, for u [0,M]weset f(u) = ρ iff u = ρv(ρ), ρ [0,ρ ] (14) Then we extend f outside the interval [0,M] by setting f(u) = + if u<0oru>m (15) The Legendre transform of this extended flux function (Fig 1, right) will be denoted by f (p) = maxpu f(u) (16) u u ρ M ρ v( ρ) ρ* f(u) f *(p) 0 ρ* ρ 0 M u 0 f (0) p Fig 1 Left: the function ρ ρv(ρ) describing the flux of cars Middle: the function f, implicitly defined by f(ρv(ρ)) = ρ and extended according to (15) Right: the Legendre transform f Throughout the following, for notational convenience we shall invert the role of the independent variables t, x, and write (13) in the form u t + f(u) x = 0 (17)

3 VARIATIONAL ANALYSIS OF NASH EQUILIBRIA FOR A MODEL OF TRAFFIC FLOW 497 Introducing the integral function U(t, x) = x u(t, s) ds, the conservation law (17) can be equivalently written as a Hamilton-Jacobi equation U t + f(u x ) = 0 (18) For our model of traffic flow, one should keep in mind that now the x variable denotes time, while t [0,T] denotes a specific point on a highway of total length T Hence U(t, x) measures the total number of cars that have crossed the point t along the highway during thetimeinterval],x] As initial data for (18) we consider any bounded nondecreasing function Q : R R +, with Q( ) = 0, Q(+ ) = κ (19) Here Q(x) denotes the total number of cars that have entered the queue at the entrance of the highway up to time x, while κ is the total number of departing cars Being monotone, the function Q is continuous with the possible exception of countably many times x To fix the ideas, we shall consider the left-continuous version where Q(x) =Q(x ) coincides with its left limit at every x When needed, we shall denote by Q(x+) = lim y x+ Q(y) the right limit of Q at x For t>0, the entropy-admissible solution to the Cauchy problem (18) is provided by the Lax formula: ( ) x y U(t, x) = min tf + Q(y) : y R (110) t Notice that, since Q( ) is nondecreasing and left continuous, the minimum in (110) is well defined As shown in [1], one has U(0+,x) = U(x) = min Q(y)+M(x y) : y x Q(x) (111) Indeed, there is a maximum flux M of cars that can enter the highway If Q is discontinuous, or simply if Q x >M, then a queue is formed at the entrance of the highway The quantity Q(x) U(x) measures the length of this queue at time x, while U(x) denotes the total number of drivers that have actually departed (after clearing the queue) up to time x With the above notation, the map x U(T,x) describes how many cars have arrived at the destination, ie at the end of the highway, within time x Given a nondecreasing, left continuous initial data Q( ) as in (19), for β [0,κ[we define the times x q (β), x d (β), and x a (β) by setting x q (β) = maxx R : Q(x) β, x d (β) = maxx R : U(0+,x) β, (112) x a (β) = maxx R : U(T,x) β Here β is a Lagrangian variable labelling a particular driver, x q (β) accounts for the time where this driver joins the queue, x d (β) is the actual departure time (after clearing the

4 498 ALBERTO BRESSAN, CHEN JIE LIU, WEN SHEN, AND FANG YU queue), and x a (β) is the arrival time Observe that, for all except countably many β, the above times are uniquely determined by the relations Q(x q (β)) β Q(x q (β)+), U(x d (β)) = β, U(T,x a (β)) = β (113) More generally, if a driver starts at time x, to determine his arrival time we consider two possibilities If there is no traffic at all, then the total time needed for the trip is μ = Tf [length of the highway] (0) = (114) [maximum speed] On the other hand, if the driver starting at time x encounters traffic, his arrival time will simply be the supremum among the arrival times of all cars that departed earlier Combining the above cases, the arrival time of a driver who starts at time x is thus defined as A(x) = max x + μ, sup β<q(x) x a (β) (115) As in [1], a Nash equilibrium solution can be defined as follows Definition We say that a bounded, nondecreasing initial data Q( ) satisfying (19) yields a Nash solution of the Cauchy problem (18)-(111) with initial and terminal cost functions ϕ, ψ if there exists a constant c such that: (i) For almost every β [0,κ], one has (ii) For all x R, one has ϕ(x q (β)) + ψ(x a (β)) = c (116) ϕ(x)+ψ(a(x)) c (117) According to (i) all drivers bear the same cost c, while (ii) implies that no one can achieve a cost <c For a given total number κ of drivers, the main result in [1] established the existence and uniqueness of a Nash equilibrium solution The aim of this paper is to analyze the properties of this solution In Section 2 we prove that the Nash equilibrium depends continuously on the cost functions ϕ, ψ and on the speed of the cars v = v(ρ) Assuming (without loss of generality) that the total cost to each driver is zero, our main results can be summarized as follows Given a total number of drivers κ and cost functions ϕ i,ψ i,v i, i =1, 2, the departure distributions Q 1,Q 2 of the corresponding Nash equilibria satisfy an estimate of the form ( ) Q 1 Q 2 L 1 C ϕ 1 ϕ 2 C 0 + ψ 1 ψ 2 C 0 + v 1 v 2 1/2 C 0 Section 3 provides a minimax property of the Nash solution Given any departure distribution Q( ), let Ψ(Q) be the maximum cost among all drivers For a fixed number of drivers, we show that the Nash equilibrium solution is a global minimizer of the functional Ψ

5 VARIATIONAL ANALYSIS OF NASH EQUILIBRIA FOR A MODEL OF TRAFFIC FLOW 499 In Section 4 we introduce two evolution equations, modeling how the departure distribution changes from one day to the next In both cases, the Nash equilibrium corresponds to the unique steady state The stability of this invariant configuration is a difficult issue, because the evolution equation contains nonlocal terms Our numerical simulations suggest that the equilibrium configuration may be unstable, while the orbits approach a chaotic attractor For future reference, we state the basic assumptions that will be used, on the flux function f in (14)-(15) and on the cost functions ϕ, ψ in (11) (A1) Restricted to the open interval ]0,M[, the flux function f is twice continuously differentiable and satisfies f (u) > 0, f (u) γ > 0 u ]0,M[ (118) Moreover, the following limits exist: lim f(u) = 0, lim u 0+ f (u) > 0, u 0+ lim f (u) = +, u M (A2) The cost functions ϕ, ψ are continuously differentiable and satisfy ϕ < 0, ψ,ψ 0, lim ϕ(x) =+, lim x x + lim f (u) < + u 0+ (119) ( ϕ(x)+ψ(x) ) =+ (120) For a review of the extensive literature on mathematical models of traffic flow we refer to [4] See also [2, 3, 5, 6] for related optimization problems 2 Continuous dependence In this section we study how the Nash equilibrium changes, depending on the cost functions ϕ, ψ and on the flux f We always assume that (A1)-(A2) are satisfied Givenacommoncostc, foreachx R, letλ(x) be the point such that ϕ(λ(x)) + ψ(x) = c, (21) with the provision that Λ(x) =+ if ψ(x) c inf ϕ(y) Since ϕ is strictly decreasing, y R Λ(x) is uniquely defined Remark 1 Recalling the definition of arrival time in (115), a Nash equilibrium solution U of (18) with common cost c to all drivers can be equivalently characterized by the two requirements: (N1) Q(Λ(x)) U(T,x) Q(Λ(x)+) for ae x such that U x (T,x) > 0, (N2) x A(Λ(x)) for all x R By this characterization, the Nash solution is entirely determined by the flux function f and by the map Λ We also observe that, by replacing ϕ with ϕ c, itisnotrestrictive to consider the special case where the common cost to all drivers is zero For a given flux function f, it will be convenient to introduce the function ( ) s h(s) = Tf ; (22) T

6 500 ALBERTO BRESSAN, CHEN JIE LIU, WEN SHEN, AND FANG YU see Fig 2, left Given an initial data Q( ), by (110) the terminal profile U(T, ) is computed by (see Fig 2, right) U(T,x) = min Q(y) h(y x) (23) y R We now review some identities satisfied by the Legendre transform For each p ]f (0), + [, let u(p) denote the point where the maximum in (16) is attained Then one has f (u(p)) = p, f (p) = pu(p) f(u(p)) (24) Differentiating the two identities in (24) wrt p, one obtains f (u(p))u (p) =1, (f ) (p) =u(p), (f ) (p) =u 1 (p) = f (u(p)) (25) As in (114), let μ = Tf (0) We now write a second-order Taylor expansion of the function h at the point μ, observing that f (f (0)) = (f ) (f (0)) = 0 (Fig 1, right) By the assumptions (118)-(119), since f (u) γ>0, for every s< μ one obtains h(s) = ( (s + μ)2 h (s + μ)2 (s 1 ) = (f ) s1 2 2T T ) (s + μ)2, (26) 2γT where s 1 [s, μ] is a suitable point Using (23) and (26), for every ε 0 we deduce U(T,x) Q(x μ ε)+ ε2 2γT (27) Given departure and arrival costs ϕ, ψ, as proved in [1], the departure distribution Q ( ) for the Nash equilibrium solution, where all drivers bear the common cost c =0, can be obtained as Q (x) = sup Q(x); Q Q 0 (28) Here Q 0 is the family of all starting distributions where each driver pays a cost 0, ie Q 0 = Q( ) : ϕ(x q (β)) + ψ(x a (β)) 0 for ae β [0, Q(+ )] (29) = Q( ) : x q (β) Λ(x a (β)) for ae β [0, Q(+ )] We recall that the starting time x q and the arrival time x a of the β-driver are defined as in (112) Of course, these depend on the overall traffic pattern, hence on the flux function f as well as on Q( ) Theorem 1 (comparison) Let Q ( ) be the initial data for the Nash equilibrium solution (with zero total cost to each driver), corresponding to the departure and arrival costs ϕ, ψ and to the flux function f Similarly, let Q( ) be the initial data for the Nash solution given the costs ϕ, ψ and the flux function f Asin(21),letΛ, Λ be implicitly defined by If ϕ(λ(x)) + ψ(x) = 0, ϕ( Λ(x)) + ψ(x) = 0 (210) Λ(x) Λ(x) x R, (211) f(u) f(u) u 0, (212)

7 VARIATIONAL ANALYSIS OF NASH EQUILIBRIA FOR A MODEL OF TRAFFIC FLOW 501 then Q(x) Q (x) x R (213) Proof Thanks to (28), it suffices to show that Q( ) Q 0 Let h(s) and h(s) be the functions defined in (22), corresponding to f and f respectively For the initial data Q(x), the terminal profile Ũ(T,x) with the flux f is computed by Ũ(T,x) = min y R Q(y) h(y x) As in (112), we shall denote by x q (β) and x a (β) the starting time and the arrival time of the driver labelled by β [0, Q(+ )] On the other hand, the terminal profile Û(T,x) for the same initial data Q(x) but with flux f is computed by Û(T,x) = min y R Q(y) h(y x) In this case, the starting time and the arrival time for the driver β [0, Q(+ )], will be denoted by ˆx q (β), ˆx a (β), respectively Using (16), (22), and (212), we obtain h(s) h(s) Hence Ũ(T,x) Û(T,x) for all x R From (112) it thus follows that ˆx q (β) = x q (β), ˆx a (β) x a (β) for ae β [0, Q(+ )] Since Q( ) is the Nash equilibrium solution given the costs ϕ, ψ and the flux function f, for almost every β one has the identity x q (β) = Λ( x a (β)) Using (211) and the monotonicity of the map x Λ(x), for the initial data Q we obtain ˆx q (β) = x q (β) = Λ( x a (β)) Λ(ˆx a (β)) Λ(ˆx a (β)) for ae β [0, Q(+ )] Therefore Q( ) Q 0 and Q(x) Q (x) for all x R Remark 2 Since ϕ, ϕ are strictly decreasing, the inequality (211) trivially holds if ϕ ϕ and ψ ψ Moreover, (212) holds in the case where f, f are defined as in (14), for speeds ṽ(ρ) v(ρ) In this case, Theorem 1 yields an intuitively obvious fact: by increasing the departure and arrival costs and decreasing the speed of the cars, the total number of cars in a Nash equilibrium solution (where every driver still pays zero cost) will decrease 21 Continuous dependence on the cost functions Next, we wish to relate two Nash equilibrium solutions with different cost and flux functions, without the assumptions (211)-(212) The first result describes how the Nash equilibrium changes when the cost functions ϕ, ψ are changed Theorem 2 Let the flux function f and the cost functions ϕ i,ψ i, i =1, 2 satisfy the assumptions (A1)-(A2) Let Q 1,Q 2 be the starting distributions of the corresponding Nash equilibria Assume that all drivers in both cases start and arrive within a time interval I =[a, b] Then there exists a constant C not depending on Q 1,Q 2 such that Q 1 Q 2 L1 ([a,b]) C Λ 1 Λ 2 L ([a,b]) (214)

8 502 ALBERTO BRESSAN, CHEN JIE LIU, WEN SHEN, AND FANG YU U Q h(s) 0 U(T,x) y(x) x y Fig 2 Left: the graph of the function h( ) introduced in (22) Right: by the Lax formula, U(T,x) is the amount by which one can push up the graph of h( x) until it touches the graph of Q( ) Clearly, U(T,x) Q(x μ) Proof Let ε = sup x [a,b] Λ 1 (x) Λ 2 (x) (215) It is clearly not restrictive to assume 0 <ε 1 1 Let any x [a, b] be given Our goal is to prove an estimate of the form Q 2 (Λ 1 ( x) ε) Q 1 (Λ 1 ( x)) C 0 ε (216) for some constant C 0 For this purpose, we construct two decreasing sequences x = x 0 > x 1 > > x n, y k = Λ 1 (x k ), according to the following inductive rule Given x k, consider two cases: Case 1 y k x k μ ε In this case, we choose y k+1 to be the smallest point where the minimum defining U 1 (T,x k ) is attained More precisely: y k+1 = min ỹ : Q 1 (ỹ) h(ỹ x k ) = min Q 1 (y) h(y x k ) (217) y x k We then set x k+1 = minx : Λ1 (x) =y k+1 (218) Case 2 y k > x k μ ε In this case we set y k+1 = yk ε and define x k+1 as in (218) The construction terminates when y n a for some n 1 Observe that, for some constant c 0 > 0 suitably small, one has either Q 1 (y k+1 ) Q 1 (y k )+h( μ ε) Q 1 (y k ) c 0 ε 2 or y k+1 y k ε Therefore the induction must terminate after a finite number of steps

9 VARIATIONAL ANALYSIS OF NASH EQUILIBRIA FOR A MODEL OF TRAFFIC FLOW 503 T x k+1 x k Q1 μ 1 y k+1 y k x y k yk+1 x k x Fig 3 Construction of the points x k,y k in Case 1 Here the thick solid lines denote car trajectories, while the dotted lines denote characteristics The point x k is the arrival time of the driver who starts at time y k =Λ 1 (x k ) Moreover, y k+1 is the initial point of the characteristic through the point (T,x k ) If several characteristics reach the same point x k (this can happen if x k is the location of a shock), then we choose y k+1 on the minimal backward characteristic 2 In Case 1, since y k+1 =Λ 1 (x k+1 )andh 0, our construction yields Q 2 (Λ 1 (x k ) ε) Q 1 (Λ 1 (x k )) [ ] [ ] Q 2 (y k+1 ε) h(y k+1 ε x k ) Q 1 (y k+1 ) h(y k+1 x k ) [ ] Q 2 (Λ 1 (x k+1 ) ε) Q 1 (Λ 1 (x k+1 )) + h (y k+1 ε x k ) ε (219) In Case 2, by (26) our construction yields Q 2 (y) h(y x k ) U 2 (T,x k ) = Q 2 (Λ 2 (x k )) Q 2 (Λ 1 (x k ) ε) for all y x k Sincey k x k > μ ε, taking y = y k+1 ε = y k 2ε we obtain Q 2 (y k ε) Q 2 (y k+1 ε) h(y k+1 ε x k ) Q 2 (y k+1 ε) h( μ 2ε) Q 2 (y k+1 ε)+ 4ε2 2γT, Q 2 (y k ε) Q 1 (y k ) Q 2 (y k+1 ε)+ 2ε2 γt Q 1(y k+1 ) (220) Since y n a, wehaveq 2 (y n ε) =Q 1 (y n ) = 0 Splitting the set of indices I = 1,,n = I 1 I 2 according to whether Case 1 or Case 2 applies, we obtain Q 2 (Λ 1 ( x) ε) Q 1 (Λ 1 ( x)) = Q 2 (y 0 ε) Q 1 (y 0 ) ε h (y k+1 ε x k )+ 2ε2 = J 1 + J 2 γt k I 1 k I 2 (221) 3 Since the total number of steps where Case 2 can occur is (b a)/ε, the second summation in (221) is estimated by J 2 2ε2 γt b a ε = 2(b a) γt ε (222)

10 504 ALBERTO BRESSAN, CHEN JIE LIU, WEN SHEN, AND FANG YU We now work toward an estimate of J 1 By the properties of the function h in (22), there exists a constant C 1 such that h (s) C 1 ( μ s) s [a b, μ] (223) Define the constant h(s) M 1 = inf a b<s< μ (s + μ) 2 > 0 (224) and choose a suitably small constant 0 <c 2 <M 1 /(3C 1 ) Two possibilities need to be considered If observing that in Case 1 we have we conclude y k y k+1 c 2 (x k μ y k+1 ), (225) ε x k μ y k x k μ y k+1, h (y k+1 ε x k ) C 1 ( μ y k+1 + ε + x k ) 2C 1 (y k y k+1 ) (226) c 2 On the other hand, if (225) fails, then we claim that either k =0orelse h (y k+1 ε x k ) C 3 (x k 1 x k ) (227) Indeed, if k 1, at the previous iteration one has (see Fig 4) Q 1 (y k 1 ) = Q 1 (y k ) h(y k x k 1 ) = min Q 1 (y) h(y x k 1 ) y Q 1 (y k+1 ) h(y k+1 x k 1 ), Q 1 (y k ) Q 1 (y k+1 ) = h(y k+1 x k ) h(y k x k 1 ) h(y k+1 x k 1 ) h (y k+1 x k 1 )(y k y k+1 ) C 1 (x k 1 μ y k+1 ) c 2 (x k μ y k+1 ) Using (224) and recalling that c 2 M 1 /(3C 1 ), we obtain x k 1 μ y k+1 We can thus write h(y k+1 x k ) C 1 c 2 (x k μ y k+1 ) M 1(x k μ y k+1 ) 2 C 1 c 2 (x k μ y k+1 ) 3(x k μ y k 1 ) (228) x k 1 x k = (x k 1 μ y k+1 ) x k + μ + y k+1 2(x k μ y k+1 ) (229) On the other hand, by (223) one has h (y k+1 ε x k ) C 1 ( μ y k+1 + ε + x k ) 2C 1 (x k μ y k+1 ), which yields (227) Together, (226)-(227) yield the estimate h (y k+1 ε x k ) [ ] 2C1 (y k y k+1 )+C 3 (x k x k+1 ) c 2 k k ( ) 2C1 + C 3 (b a) c 2 (230)

11 VARIATIONAL ANALYSIS OF NASH EQUILIBRIA FOR A MODEL OF TRAFFIC FLOW 505 μ h y k+1 y k x x k Fig 4 If the difference y k y k+1 is small compared with x k μ y k+1, then at the previous iteration the slope h (y x k 1 )mustbe much larger, on the interval [y k+1,y k ] Therefore x k 1 x k must be large 4 Using (222) and (230) in (221), we conclude that there exists a constant C 4 such that Q 2 (y ε) Q 1 (y) C 4 (b a)ε y [a, b] (231) Inverting the roles of Q 1,Q 2 one obtains the similar inequality Q 1 (y ε) Q 2 (y) C 4 (b a)ε y [a, b] (232) Denoting by κ an upper bound for both functions Q 1,Q 2, we thus conclude that Q 2 Q 1 L1 ([a,b]) = b a b a b + Q 2 (y) Q 1 (y) dy [Q 2 (y ε) Q 1 (y)] + dy + a Q 1 (y) Q 1 (y ε) dy + 2C 4 (b a) 2 ε +2κε b a b a [Q 1 (y ε) Q 2 (y)] + dy Q 2 (y) Q 2 (y ε) dy 22 Continuous dependence on the flux function The main goal of this subsection is to understand how the Nash equilibrium solution changes if the velocity function v = v(ρ) in (12) is changed Our main result will be formulated in terms of the inverse of the function h in (22) More precisely, given a flux function f satisfying the assumptions (A1), for y 0 we define h 1 (y) = min s 0: T f ( s T ) y (233) Theorem 3 Fix κ>0 and let the cost functions ϕ and ψ satisfy the assumptions (A2) Let f 1,f 2 be two flux functions, both satisfying (A1), and let Q 1,Q 2 be the starting distributions of the Nash equilibria with flux functions f 1,f 2, respectively Assume that in both cases the total number of drivers is κ, and every driver starts and arrives within

12 506 ALBERTO BRESSAN, CHEN JIE LIU, WEN SHEN, AND FANG YU a time interval I =[a, b], and has zero total cost Then there exists a constant C not depending on Q 1,Q 2 such that Q 1 Q 2 L 1 ([a,b]) C h 1 1 h 1 2 L ([ κ,0]) (234) Proof The estimate (234) will be derived from the bound (214) stated in Theorem 2 1 Consider the map x Λ 2 (x), implicitly defined by ϕ(λ 2 (x)) + ψ(x) = 0 By assumption, the initial datum Q 2 yields a Nash equilibrium solution in connection with the flux f 2, determined by the map Λ 2 ( ) We claim that Q 2 also yields a Nash solution in connection with the flux f 1, for some different costs ϕ, ψ, and a corresponding map Λ 1 ( ) Indeed, call κ 2 = Q2 (+ ) For every β [0,κ 2 ]letx a 1(β) bethearrivaltimeofthe β-driver if the starting distribution is Q 2 and the flux function is f 1 As in (22), consider the functions where fi setting h i (s) = Tf i ( ) s, i =1, 2, (235) T is the Legendre transform of f i We define the inverse functions h 1 1, h 1 2 by h 1 i (w) Using (22) and (23), we obtain the representation = mins : h i (s) w w 0 (236) x a 1(β) = sup ξ<β x q (ξ) h 1 1 (ξ β) (237) Observe that, in connection with the same initial distribution Q 2, if the flux function is f 2, then the arrival time is x a 2(β) = sup x q (ξ) h 1 2 (ξ β) (238) ξ<β From (237) and (238) it follows that sup β [0,κ 2 ] x a 1(β) x a 2(β) sup ξ [ κ 2,0] 2 For ae β [0,κ 2 ], by assumption we have h 1 1 ϕ(λ 2 (x a 2(β))) + ψ(x a 2(β)) = 0 We seek new cost functions ϕ, ψ, andamapx Λ 1 (x) such that (ξ) h 1(ξ) (239) ϕ(λ 1 (x a 1(β))) + ψ(x a 1(β)) = 0 (240) Since we are assuming that all drivers depart and arrive within a given time interval [a, b], using (239) and the identities Λ 1 (x a 1(β)) = x q 1 (β) = xq 2 (β) = Λ 2(x a 2(β)), the difference Λ 1 Λ 2 can be estimated by ( sup Λ 1 (x) Λ 2 (x) x [a,b] inf x [a,b] x Λ 1(x) ) 1 ( sup β [0,κ 2 ] 2 ) x a 1(β) x a 2(β), (241)

13 VARIATIONAL ANALYSIS OF NASH EQUILIBRIA FOR A MODEL OF TRAFFIC FLOW 507 or equivalently by ( ) ( ) ) 1 sup Λ 1 (x) Λ 2 (x) sup ψ (x) inf x [a,b] x [a,b] y [a,b] ϕ (y) ( sup x a 1 (β) xa 2 (β) β [0,κ 2 ] (242) The first two factors on the right-hand side of (242) depend only on the cost functions ϕ, ψ The third factor is estimated by (239) Using Theorem 2 in connection with the flux function f 2 and the two maps Λ 1, Λ 2,wethusobtain Q 1 Q 2 L1 ([a,b]) C sup ξ [ κ 2,0] h 1 1 (ξ) h 1(ξ) (243) 2 * f 1 f 2 s f* 2 f* 1 0 u M1 M2 0 f (0) f (0) 2 1 p p 2 1 p Fig 5 Comparing two flux functions f 1,f 2 and their corresponding Legendre transforms h 1 To make use of the above theorem, one needs to understand how the distance h L ([ κ,0]) between the two inverse functions can be related to the difference between the flux functions f 1,f 2 and, in turn, with the difference between the velocity functions v 1,v 2 in (12) Up to a linear rescaling of coordinates, it is not restrictive to assume T = 1 In the following, we thus seek to relate the distance v 1 v 2 L with the distance (f1 ) 1 (f2 ) 1 L between the inverses of the Legendre transforms Let v 1,v 2 be smooth, nonincreasing velocity functions such that 2 ρ 2 ρv i(ρ) η 0 < 0, i =1, 2 Call ρ i the value where the flux function ρ ρv i (ρ) attains its global maximum, and let ρ =maxρ 1,ρ 2 Moreover, consider the distance δ = v 1 v 2 L ([0,ρ ]) (244) Let κ>0begiven For any s [0,κ], assume that the Legendre transforms of the corresponding functions f 1,f 2 in (14)-(15) satisfy We seek an estimate on p 1 p 2 f 1 (p 1 ) = f 2 (p 2 ) = s (245)

14 508 ALBERTO BRESSAN, CHEN JIE LIU, WEN SHEN, AND FANG YU Consider any slope p p 0 =maxf 1 (0),f 2(0) Draw the lines with slope p tangent to the graphs of f 1,f 2 Callαthe distance between the interceptions of these lines with the ρ-axis, and β the distance between the interceptions with the u-axis (see Fig 5) Then Moreover, β = g 1(1/p) g 2(1/p), where α = f 1 (p) f 2 (p) = pβ g i (q) = min q ρ ρv i (ρ) ρ Given any p >p 0 > 0, for all p [p 0, p] wethushave f1 f2 L ([0, p]) p sup ρv 1 (ρ) ρv 2 (ρ) pρ v 1 v 2 L ([0,ρ ]) ρ [0,ρ ] Recalling (24)-(25), consider the minimum of the second derivative γ i = min p [p 0,p] (f i ) (p) = ( 1 max f i (u)) u [0,u i ( p)] Set η = minγ 1,γ 2 If (245) holds with s =0,then p 1 p 2 = f 1(0) f 2(0) = 1 v 1 (0) 1 v 2 (0) More generally, for s [0,κ] one has the estimate f 2 ( ) p 1 + f 1(0) f 2(0) +δ f2 (p 1 )+ η 2 δ2 f1 (p 1 ) f1 f2 L ([p 0, p]) + η 2 δ2 (246) The right-hand side of (246) is f1 (p 1 )assoonasδ (245) holds, we thus have ( 2η 1 f 1 f 2 L ) 1/2 If p 2 p 1 + f 1(0) f 2(0) + 2 η f 1 f 2 L ([p 0, p]) In conclusion, we obtain the estimate (f1 ) 1 (f2 ) 1 L ([0,κ]) C 0 v 1 v 2 L ([0, ρ]), for a suitable constant C 0 In the setting of Theorem 3, the difference (234) between the starting distributions in the Nash equilibria with velocity functions v 1,v 2 can now be estimated by Q 1 Q 2 L1 ([a,b]) C v 1 v 2 L ([0, ρ]), (247) for a suitable constant C

15 VARIATIONAL ANALYSIS OF NASH EQUILIBRIA FOR A MODEL OF TRAFFIC FLOW A minimax property of Nash equilibria Fix κ>0 and let Q κ be the family of all left continuous, nondecreasing functions satisfying (19) For Q Q κ, recalling (112) define the functional Ψ(Q) = ess sup β [0,κ] ϕ(x q (β)) + ψ(x a (β)) (31) The next result shows that the Nash equilibrium provides a global minimizer to the functional Ψ Theorem 4 If Q is the initial distribution of the Nash equilibrium solution with a number κ>0 of drivers, then Ψ(Q ) = minψ(q) : Q Q κ (32) Proof Let Q Q κ be the departure distribution for the Nash equilibrium solution with κ>0 drivers Let c =Ψ(Q ) be the common total cost payed by each driver, in the Nash solution Call Q c the family of all departure distributions (with an arbitrary number of drivers), where each driver pays a total cost c Asprovedin[1],theNash solution can be characterized as Q (x) = supq(x) : Q Q c (33) To prove (32) assume that, on the contrary, there exists another departure distribution Q Q κ Q c ε,forsomeε>0 By the analysis in [1], we can then construct a second distribution Q + Q κ+δ Q c,forsomeδ>0 But this provides a contradiction with (33), because κ = lim x + Q (x) < lim x + Q+ (x) = κ + δ Remark 3 In general Q is not the unique global minimizer for the functional Ψ For example, recalling (111), consider the initial data Q(x) = U (0+,x) = min Q (y)+m(x y) : y x y Q (x) Then the corresponding solution Ũ satisfies Ũ(t, x) =U (t, x) for all t>0andx R In particular, for any β [0,κ], the departure and arrival times of the β-driver satisfy Hence x q (β) = x d (β) x q (β), x a (β) = x a (β) ϕ( x q (β)) + ψ( x a (β)) ϕ(x q (β)) + ψ(x a (β)) = c = Ψ(Q ),

16 510 ALBERTO BRESSAN, CHEN JIE LIU, WEN SHEN, AND FANG YU showing that Q Q κ Q c also provides a minimizer for the functional Ψ It is quite possible that Q Q This happens when, in the Nash solution, some of the drivers wait in the queue By allowing these drivers to depart exactly at time x q (β) = x d (β), they avoid waiting in line, and hence pay a total cost strictly smaller than c 4 Dynamic stability of Nash equilibria A natural modeling assumption is that Nash equilibria should describe actual traffic patterns However, a rigorous justification of this claim requires a nontrivial stability analysis Indeed, assume that on a given day the drivers start their journey at times described by the distribution Q( ) If this is not a Nash equilibrium, on the next day some drivers may decide to change their schedule, starting at a different time, hopefully yielding a lower individual cost We can thus consider a transformation T : Q( ) Q( ), describing how the distribution of departure times varies from one day to the next For some meaningful choice of T we expect that, for any given initial distribution Q( ), the limit of iterates lim n T n Q should yield the unique Nash equilibrium solution Rather than a discrete transformation, we propose here two evolution equations for the distribution Q( ), depending on a continuous parameter s Assume that the departure rate is absolutely continuous wrt Lebesgue measure, so that Q x (x) = ū(x) Let U = U(t, x) be the corresponding solution of the Hamilton-Jacobi equation (18) computed by the Lax formula (110) Moreover, let u(t, x) = U x (t, x) For each x R, cally(x) the arrival time of a driver departing at time x implicitly defined by This is Q(x) = U(T,y(x)) (41) We also define Φ(x) = ϕ(vx)+ψ(y(x)), (42) the total cost to a driver starting at time x It is important to keep in mind that the map x y(x), and hence Φ( ), depends on the overall traffic distribution, ie on u Next, consider a one-parameter family of initial data: ū(x, s) =Q x (x, s), depending on the auxiliary parameter s R + We seek an evolution equation of the form d dsū = Υ(ū) (43) for some (possibly nonlocal) functional Υ, describing how drivers may change their departure time, in an attempt to reduce their total cost Two choices for the right-hand side of (43) seem natural

17 VARIATIONAL ANALYSIS OF NASH EQUILIBRIA FOR A MODEL OF TRAFFIC FLOW 511 Model 1 Drivers who initially depart at x continuously modify their departure time, forward or backward depending on the gradient Φ x (x) of the cost In this case we can take Υ(ū) =(Φ x ū) x and the evolution of the starting distribution ū =ū(x, s) is described by the conservation law ū s (Φ x ū) x = 0 (44) Model 2 Drivers who depart at time x may decide to jump to a different departure time ξ R, with probability proportional to the difference in cost This leads to the integro-differential evolution equation d ds ū(x) = [ ] ū(ξ) Φ(ξ) Φ(x) dξ + [ ] ū(x) Φ(x) Φ(ξ) dξ (45) + In both cases the key issue is whether, as s +, the distribution with density ū(,s) converges to the initial data of the Nash equilibrium solution 41 Numerical simulations A numerical computation of the Nash equilibrium can be achieved through the necessary condition of the optimal control problem Let c be the cost for every driver in the Nash solution We discretize the Lagrangian variable β identifying a particular driver, and set β i = i δ, forafixedmeshδ>0 The departure time x q i = xq (β i ) and the arrival time x a i = x a (β i )ofthei-th driver are computed by the following procedure The first car finds no traffic ahead and travels with maximum speed v(0) The total time needed for the trip is μ, as defined in (114) The departure time x q 1 of the first car is the smallest root of the equation ϕ(x)+ψ(x + μ) = c (46) This can be found by a secant iterative method We set x q 1 = t 1, x a 1 = t 1 + μ The largest root of the equation (46) provides an upper bound for the departure time of the last car For i 2, the times x q i (when the β i-driver begins his journey, possibly joining the queue) are computed in a sequential way Given x q j for all j<i, we determine x q i [xq i 1, [ as the smaller root of the equation ϕ(x)+ψ(x a i (x)) = c (47) Here x a i (x) = min x x q i 1 = min x x q i 1 x + μ, sup j<i x + μ, sup j<i x q (β j ) h 1 (β j β i ) (48) x q j h 1 ((j i)δ)

18 512 ALBERTO BRESSAN, CHEN JIE LIU, WEN SHEN, AND FANG YU is the arrival time of the β i -driver if he departs at time x This root of (47) can be efficiently computed by secant iteration, starting with the two initial guesses x = x q i 1, x = xq i 2 It is found that 2 to 3 iterations of the secant method suffice If for i = N + 1 no solution of (47) is found, then the iteration stops The value κ(c) =β N = Nδ is the total number of cars in the Nash equilibrium solution with common cost c to all drivers In a more realistic situation, instead of the cost c, one is given the total number of cars κ In this case, to compute the corresponding Nash solution one needs to invert the map c κ(c) and find a cost c such that κ( c) = κ This can be done numerically, again using secant iterations For this purpose, it is found that 4 to 5 iterations suffice Fig 6 Numerical solutions for the model (49) The total (departure + arrival) cost Φ (blue) and the rate of departures ū (green) are plotted as functions of departure time x, for the Nash equilibrium solution and for the Pareto optimal solution In both cases, the total number of cars is In our numerical simulations we consider a highway of length l =2 Thevelocity function in (12) and the departure and arrival costs in (11) are taken to be v(ρ) =2 ρ, ϕ(x) = x, ψ(x) =e x, (49) respectively Figure 6 shows the rate ū(x) at which cars depart (possibly joining the queue) and the total cost Ψ(x) as functions of the departure time The plots on the left refer to the Nash equilibrium solution, while the plots on the right yield the Pareto

19 VARIATIONAL ANALYSIS OF NASH EQUILIBRIA FOR A MODEL OF TRAFFIC FLOW 513 optimal solution, where the sum of the costs to all drivers is globally minimized A detailed analysis of this globally optimal solution can be found in [1] Simulations of the two dynamic models To simulate Model 1, the conservation law (43) is solved by a Lax-Friedrichs scheme, satisfying the CFL conditions To compute the flux Φ u x, we apply a smooth filter (cubic spline) to guarantee that Φ is in C 2 This eliminates numerical oscillations The presence of this filter corresponds to a numerical diffusion term, leading to a more stable dynamical system To simulate Model 2, the trapezoid rule is used to numerically compute the integral on the right-hand side of (45) The resulting evolution equation is solved with a forward Euler scheme The time step is chosen small enough so that ū 0 for all s In both cases, we take the Pareto optimal solution as the initial data As s becomes larger, the profile ū(,s) gets somewhat closer to the departure rate for the Nash equilibrium However, numerical data do not provide evidence of asymptotic convergence as s + Fig 7 Numerical simulations for Model 1 Here the total cost Φ and the rate of departures ū are plotted as functions of the departure time x, for increasing values of s Remark A rigorous analysis of the models (44)-(45) is difficult, because in both cases the evolution operator is nonlocal Even the linearized stability of these evolution equations, at the Nash equilibrium, remains an open problem

20 514 ALBERTO BRESSAN, CHEN JIE LIU, WEN SHEN, AND FANG YU Fig 8 Numerical simulations for Model 2 The total cost Φ and the rate of departures ū are plotted as functions of the departure time x Here the time step is taken to be Δs =0005; hence a plot after n steps shows a solution of (45) at time s n =0005 n Acknowledgements The research of A Bressan was partially supported by the NSF through grant EFRI A theory of complex transportation network design C Liu and F Yu were both supported by the NNSF of China with grants and , and by the Shanghai Jiao Tong University Innovation Fund for Postgraduates References [1] A Bressan and K Han, Optima and equilibria for a model of traffic flow SIAM J Math Anal 43 (2011), [2] T L Friesz, T Kim, C Kwon, and M A Rigdon, Approximate network loading and dual-time-scale dynamic user equilibrium Transportation Research Part B (2010) [3] A Fügenschuh, M Herty, and A Martin, Combinatorial and continuous models for the optimization of traffic flows on networks SIAM J Optim 16 (2006), MR (2007k:90009) [4] M Garavello and B Piccoli, Traffic Flow on Networks Conservation Laws Models AIMS Series on Applied Mathematics, American Institute of Mathematical Sciences, Springfield, Mo, 2006 MR (2008g:90023) [5] M Gugat, M Herty, A Klar, and G Leugering, Optimal control for traffic flow networks J Optim Theory Appl 126 (2005), MR (2006m:49043) [6] M Herty, C Kirchner, and A Klar, Instantaneous control for traffic flow Math Methods Appl Sci 30 (2007), MR (2007k:93074) [7] LCEvans,Partial Differential Equations Second edition American Mathematical Society, Providence, RI, 2010 MR (2011c:35002) [8] P D Lax, Hyperbolic systems of conservation laws II Comm Pure Appl Math 10 (1957), MR (20:176)

21 VARIATIONAL ANALYSIS OF NASH EQUILIBRIA FOR A MODEL OF TRAFFIC FLOW 515 [9] M Lighthill and G Whitham, On kinematic waves II A theory of traffic flow on long crowded roads Proceedings of the Royal Society of London: Series A, 229 (1955), MR (17:310a) [10] J Smoller, Shock waves and reaction-diffusion equations Second edition Springer-Verlag, New York, 1994 MR (95g:35002)

Variational Analysis of Nash Equilibria for a Model of Traffic Flow

Variational Analysis of Nash Equilibria for a Model of Traffic Flow Variational Analysis of Nash Equilibria for a Model of Traffic Flow Alberto Bressan ( ), Chen Jie Liu ( ), Wen Shen ( ), and Fang Yu ( ) ( ) Department of Mathematics, Penn State University University

More information

Conservation laws and some applications to traffic flows

Conservation laws and some applications to traffic flows Conservation laws and some applications to traffic flows Khai T. Nguyen Department of Mathematics, Penn State University ktn2@psu.edu 46th Annual John H. Barrett Memorial Lectures May 16 18, 2016 Khai

More information

Intersection Models and Nash Equilibria for Traffic Flow on Networks

Intersection Models and Nash Equilibria for Traffic Flow on Networks Intersection Models and Nash Equilibria for Traffic Flow on Networks Alberto Bressan Department of Mathematics, Penn State University bressan@math.psu.edu (Los Angeles, November 2015) Alberto Bressan (Penn

More information

Optima and Equilibria for Traffic Flow on Networks with Backward Propagating Queues

Optima and Equilibria for Traffic Flow on Networks with Backward Propagating Queues Optima and Equilibria for Traffic Flow on Networks with Backward Propagating Queues Alberto Bressan and Khai T Nguyen Department of Mathematics, Penn State University University Park, PA 16802, USA e-mails:

More information

Optima and Equilibria for a Model of Traffic Flow

Optima and Equilibria for a Model of Traffic Flow Optima and Equilibria for a Model of raffic Flow Alberto Bressan and Ke Han Department of Mathematics, Penn State University University Park, Pa 16802, USA e-mails: bressan@mathpsuedu, kxh323@psuedu July

More information

Stability of Feedback Solutions for Infinite Horizon Noncooperative Differential Games

Stability of Feedback Solutions for Infinite Horizon Noncooperative Differential Games Stability of Feedback Solutions for Infinite Horizon Noncooperative Differential Games Alberto Bressan ) and Khai T. Nguyen ) *) Department of Mathematics, Penn State University **) Department of Mathematics,

More information

Hyperbolic Systems of Conservation Laws. in One Space Dimension. I - Basic concepts. Alberto Bressan. Department of Mathematics, Penn State University

Hyperbolic Systems of Conservation Laws. in One Space Dimension. I - Basic concepts. Alberto Bressan. Department of Mathematics, Penn State University Hyperbolic Systems of Conservation Laws in One Space Dimension I - Basic concepts Alberto Bressan Department of Mathematics, Penn State University http://www.math.psu.edu/bressan/ 1 The Scalar Conservation

More information

Traffic models on a network of roads

Traffic models on a network of roads Traic models on a network o roads Alberto Bressan Department o Mathematics, Penn State University bressan@math.psu.edu Center or Interdisciplinary Mathematics Alberto Bressan (Penn State) Traic low on

More information

Structurally Stable Singularities for a Nonlinear Wave Equation

Structurally Stable Singularities for a Nonlinear Wave Equation Structurally Stable Singularities for a Nonlinear Wave Equation Alberto Bressan, Tao Huang, and Fang Yu Department of Mathematics, Penn State University University Park, Pa. 1682, U.S.A. e-mails: bressan@math.psu.edu,

More information

Piecewise Smooth Solutions to the Burgers-Hilbert Equation

Piecewise Smooth Solutions to the Burgers-Hilbert Equation Piecewise Smooth Solutions to the Burgers-Hilbert Equation Alberto Bressan and Tianyou Zhang Department of Mathematics, Penn State University, University Park, Pa 68, USA e-mails: bressan@mathpsuedu, zhang

More information

The Riemann Solver for Traffic Flow at an Intersection with Buffer of Vanishing Size

The Riemann Solver for Traffic Flow at an Intersection with Buffer of Vanishing Size The Riemann Solver for Traffic Flow at an Intersection with Buffer of Vanishing Size Alberto Bressan ( ) and Anders Nordli ( ) (*) Department of Mathematics, Penn State University, University Par, Pa 16802,

More information

A Very Brief Introduction to Conservation Laws

A Very Brief Introduction to Conservation Laws A Very Brief Introduction to Wen Shen Department of Mathematics, Penn State University Summer REU Tutorial, May 2013 Summer REU Tutorial, May 2013 1 / The derivation of conservation laws A conservation

More information

Hyperbolic Systems of Conservation Laws. I - Basic Concepts

Hyperbolic Systems of Conservation Laws. I - Basic Concepts Hyperbolic Systems of Conservation Laws I - Basic Concepts Alberto Bressan Mathematics Department, Penn State University Alberto Bressan (Penn State) Hyperbolic Systems of Conservation Laws 1 / 27 The

More information

On Asymptotic Variational Wave Equations

On Asymptotic Variational Wave Equations On Asymptotic Variational Wave Equations Alberto Bressan 1, Ping Zhang 2, and Yuxi Zheng 1 1 Department of Mathematics, Penn State University, PA 1682. E-mail: bressan@math.psu.edu; yzheng@math.psu.edu

More information

M. HERTY, CH. JÖRRES, AND B. PICCOLI

M. HERTY, CH. JÖRRES, AND B. PICCOLI EXISTENCE OF SOLUTION TO SUPPLY CHAIN MODELS BASED ON PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATION WITH DISCONTINUOUS FLUX FUNCTION M. HERTY, CH. JÖRRES, AND B. PICCOLI Abstract. We consider a recently [2] proposed model

More information

Singularity formation for compressible Euler equations

Singularity formation for compressible Euler equations Singularity formation for compressible Euler equations Geng Chen Ronghua Pan Shengguo Zhu Abstract In this paper, for the p-system and full compressible Euler equations in one space dimension, we provide

More information

Optima and Equilibria for Traffic Flow on a Network

Optima and Equilibria for Traffic Flow on a Network Opima and Equilibria for Traffic Flow on a Nework Albero Bressan Deparmen of Mahemaics, Penn Sae Universiy bressan@mah.psu.edu Albero Bressan (Penn Sae) Opima and equilibria for raffic flow 1 / 1 A Traffic

More information

L 1 stability of conservation laws for a traffic flow model

L 1 stability of conservation laws for a traffic flow model Electronic Journal of Differential Equations, Vol. 2001(2001), No. 14, pp. 1 18. ISSN: 1072-6691. URL: http://ejde.math.swt.edu or http://ejde.math.unt.edu ftp ejde.math.swt.edu ftp ejde.math.unt.edu (login:

More information

Alberto Bressan. Department of Mathematics, Penn State University

Alberto Bressan. Department of Mathematics, Penn State University Non-cooperative Differential Games A Homotopy Approach Alberto Bressan Department of Mathematics, Penn State University 1 Differential Games d dt x(t) = G(x(t), u 1(t), u 2 (t)), x(0) = y, u i (t) U i

More information

Lecture Notes on Hyperbolic Conservation Laws

Lecture Notes on Hyperbolic Conservation Laws Lecture Notes on Hyperbolic Conservation Laws Alberto Bressan Department of Mathematics, Penn State University, University Park, Pa. 16802, USA. bressan@math.psu.edu May 21, 2009 Abstract These notes provide

More information

c 2007 Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics

c 2007 Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics SIAM J MATH ANAL Vol 38, No 5, pp 474 488 c 007 Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics OPTIMAL TRACING OF VISCOUS SHOCKS IN SOLUTIONS OF VISCOUS CONSERVATION LAWS WEN SHEN AND MEE REA PARK Abstract

More information

A model for a network of conveyor belts with discontinuous speed and capacity

A model for a network of conveyor belts with discontinuous speed and capacity A model for a network of conveyor belts with discontinuous speed and capacity Adriano FESTA Seminario di Modellistica differenziale Numerica - 6.03.2018 work in collaboration with M. Pfirsching, S. Goettlich

More information

Hyperbolic Systems of Conservation Laws

Hyperbolic Systems of Conservation Laws Hyperbolic Systems of Conservation Laws III - Uniqueness and continuous dependence and viscous approximations Alberto Bressan Mathematics Department, Penn State University http://www.math.psu.edu/bressan/

More information

Continuum Modelling of Traffic Flow

Continuum Modelling of Traffic Flow Continuum Modelling of Traffic Flow Christopher Lustri June 16, 2010 1 Introduction We wish to consider the problem of modelling flow of vehicles within a traffic network. In the past, stochastic traffic

More information

c 0000 Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics

c 0000 Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics SIAM J MAH ANAL Vol 0, No 0, pp 000 000 c 0000 Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics OPIMA AND EQUILIBRIA FOR A MODEL OF RAFFIC FLOW ALBERO BRESSAN AND KE HAN Abstract he paper is concerned with

More information

Numerical Methods for Hyperbolic Conservation Laws Lecture 4

Numerical Methods for Hyperbolic Conservation Laws Lecture 4 Numerical Methods for Hyperbolic Conservation Laws Lecture 4 Wen Shen Department of Mathematics, Penn State University Email: wxs7@psu.edu Oxford, Spring, 018 Lecture Notes online: http://personal.psu.edu/wxs7/notesnumcons/

More information

The Minimum Speed for a Blocking Problem on the Half Plane

The Minimum Speed for a Blocking Problem on the Half Plane The Minimum Speed for a Blocking Problem on the Half Plane Alberto Bressan and Tao Wang Department of Mathematics, Penn State University University Park, Pa 16802, USA e-mails: bressan@mathpsuedu, wang

More information

Solving the Payne-Whitham traffic flow model as a hyperbolic system of conservation laws with relaxation

Solving the Payne-Whitham traffic flow model as a hyperbolic system of conservation laws with relaxation Solving the Payne-Whitham traffic flow model as a hyperbolic system of conservation laws with relaxation W.L. Jin and H.M. Zhang August 3 Abstract: In this paper we study the Payne-Whitham (PW) model as

More information

On the Stability of the Best Reply Map for Noncooperative Differential Games

On the Stability of the Best Reply Map for Noncooperative Differential Games On the Stability of the Best Reply Map for Noncooperative Differential Games Alberto Bressan and Zipeng Wang Department of Mathematics, Penn State University, University Park, PA, 68, USA DPMMS, University

More information

An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control

An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control Vasile Staicu University of Aveiro UNICA, May 2018 Vasile Staicu (University of Aveiro) An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control UNICA, May 2018

More information

Coupling conditions for transport problems on networks governed by conservation laws

Coupling conditions for transport problems on networks governed by conservation laws Coupling conditions for transport problems on networks governed by conservation laws Michael Herty IPAM, LA, April 2009 (RWTH 2009) Transport Eq s on Networks 1 / 41 Outline of the Talk Scope: Boundary

More information

The LWR model on a network

The LWR model on a network Mathematical Models of Traffic Flow (October 28 November 1, 2007) Mauro Garavello Benedetto Piccoli DiSTA I.A.C. Università del Piemonte Orientale C.N.R. Via Bellini, 25/G Viale del Policlinico, 137 15100

More information

Instability of Finite Difference Schemes for Hyperbolic Conservation Laws

Instability of Finite Difference Schemes for Hyperbolic Conservation Laws Instability of Finite Difference Schemes for Hyperbolic Conservation Laws Alberto Bressan ( ), Paolo Baiti ( ) and Helge Kristian Jenssen ( ) ( ) Department of Mathematics, Penn State University, University

More information

Generic Singularities of Solutions to some Nonlinear Wave Equations

Generic Singularities of Solutions to some Nonlinear Wave Equations Generic Singularities of Solutions to some Nonlinear Wave Equations Alberto Bressan Deartment of Mathematics, Penn State University (Oberwolfach, June 2016) Alberto Bressan (Penn State) generic singularities

More information

Threshold behavior and non-quasiconvergent solutions with localized initial data for bistable reaction-diffusion equations

Threshold behavior and non-quasiconvergent solutions with localized initial data for bistable reaction-diffusion equations Threshold behavior and non-quasiconvergent solutions with localized initial data for bistable reaction-diffusion equations P. Poláčik School of Mathematics, University of Minnesota Minneapolis, MN 55455

More information

Hyperbolic Systems of Conservation Laws. in One Space Dimension. II - Solutions to the Cauchy problem. Alberto Bressan

Hyperbolic Systems of Conservation Laws. in One Space Dimension. II - Solutions to the Cauchy problem. Alberto Bressan Hyperbolic Systems of Conservation Laws in One Space Dimension II - Solutions to the Cauchy problem Alberto Bressan Department of Mathematics, Penn State University http://www.math.psu.edu/bressan/ 1 Global

More information

On the Cauchy Problems for Polymer Flooding with Gravitation

On the Cauchy Problems for Polymer Flooding with Gravitation On the Cauchy Problems for Polymer Flooding with Gravitation Wen Shen Mathematics Department, Penn State University Abstract We study two systems of conservation laws for polymer flooding in secondary

More information

On a Lyapunov Functional Relating Shortening Curves and Viscous Conservation Laws

On a Lyapunov Functional Relating Shortening Curves and Viscous Conservation Laws On a Lyapunov Functional Relating Shortening Curves and Viscous Conservation Laws Stefano Bianchini and Alberto Bressan S.I.S.S.A., Via Beirut 4, Trieste 34014 Italy. E-mail addresses: bianchin@mis.mpg.de,

More information

Numerical discretization of tangent vectors of hyperbolic conservation laws.

Numerical discretization of tangent vectors of hyperbolic conservation laws. Numerical discretization of tangent vectors of hyperbolic conservation laws. Michael Herty IGPM, RWTH Aachen www.sites.google.com/michaelherty joint work with Benedetto Piccoli MNCFF 2014, Bejing, 22.5.2014

More information

The Scalar Conservation Law

The Scalar Conservation Law The Scalar Conservation Law t + f() = 0 = conserved qantity, f() =fl d dt Z b a (t, ) d = Z b a t (t, ) d = Z b a f (t, ) d = f (t, a) f (t, b) = [inflow at a] [otflow at b] f((a)) f((b)) a b Alberto Bressan

More information

Chapter 3 Second Order Linear Equations

Chapter 3 Second Order Linear Equations Partial Differential Equations (Math 3303) A Ë@ Õæ Aë áöß @. X. @ 2015-2014 ú GA JË@ É Ë@ Chapter 3 Second Order Linear Equations Second-order partial differential equations for an known function u(x,

More information

Equilibria with a nontrivial nodal set and the dynamics of parabolic equations on symmetric domains

Equilibria with a nontrivial nodal set and the dynamics of parabolic equations on symmetric domains Equilibria with a nontrivial nodal set and the dynamics of parabolic equations on symmetric domains J. Földes Department of Mathematics, Univerité Libre de Bruxelles 1050 Brussels, Belgium P. Poláčik School

More information

Solution of Impulsive Hamilton-Jacobi Equation and Its Applications

Solution of Impulsive Hamilton-Jacobi Equation and Its Applications Nonlinear Analysis and Differential Equations, Vol. 7, 219, no. 1, 1-8 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com https://doi.org/1.12988/nade.219.888 Solution of Impulsive Hamilton-Jacobi Equation and Its Applications

More information

On the Dependence of Euler Equations on Physical Parameters

On the Dependence of Euler Equations on Physical Parameters On the Dependence of Euler Equations on Physical Parameters Cleopatra Christoforou Department of Mathematics, University of Houston Joint Work with: Gui-Qiang Chen, Northwestern University Yongqian Zhang,

More information

Research Article Splitting of Traffic Flows to Control Congestion in Special Events

Research Article Splitting of Traffic Flows to Control Congestion in Special Events International Journal of Mathematics and Mathematical Sciences Volume 0, Article ID 567, 8 pages doi:0.550567 Research Article Splitting of Traffic Flows to Control Congestion in Special Events Ciro D

More information

On the Cauchy Problems for Polymer Flooding with Gravitation

On the Cauchy Problems for Polymer Flooding with Gravitation On the Cauchy Problems for Polymer Flooding with Gravitation Wen Shen Mathematics Department, Penn State University. Email: wxs27@psu.edu November 5, 2015 Abstract We study two systems of conservation

More information

On finite time BV blow-up for the p-system

On finite time BV blow-up for the p-system On finite time BV blow-up for the p-system Alberto Bressan ( ), Geng Chen ( ), and Qingtian Zhang ( ) (*) Department of Mathematics, Penn State University, (**) Department of Mathematics, University of

More information

On fluido-dynamic models for urban traffic

On fluido-dynamic models for urban traffic On fluido-dynamic models for urban traffic Mauro Garavello Dipartimento di Scienze e Tecnologie Avanzate, Università del Piemonte Orientale A. Avogadro, via Bellini 25/G, 15100 Alessandria (Italy). Benedetto

More information

Author(s) Huang, Feimin; Matsumura, Akitaka; Citation Osaka Journal of Mathematics. 41(1)

Author(s) Huang, Feimin; Matsumura, Akitaka; Citation Osaka Journal of Mathematics. 41(1) Title On the stability of contact Navier-Stokes equations with discont free b Authors Huang, Feimin; Matsumura, Akitaka; Citation Osaka Journal of Mathematics. 4 Issue 4-3 Date Text Version publisher URL

More information

Scaling Limits of Waves in Convex Scalar Conservation Laws under Random Initial Perturbations

Scaling Limits of Waves in Convex Scalar Conservation Laws under Random Initial Perturbations Scaling Limits of Waves in Convex Scalar Conservation Laws under Random Initial Perturbations Jan Wehr and Jack Xin Abstract We study waves in convex scalar conservation laws under noisy initial perturbations.

More information

Scalar conservation laws with moving density constraints arising in traffic flow modeling

Scalar conservation laws with moving density constraints arising in traffic flow modeling Scalar conservation laws with moving density constraints arising in traffic flow modeling Maria Laura Delle Monache Email: maria-laura.delle monache@inria.fr. Joint work with Paola Goatin 14th International

More information

Numerical Methods for Modern Traffic Flow Models. Alexander Kurganov

Numerical Methods for Modern Traffic Flow Models. Alexander Kurganov Numerical Methods for Modern Traffic Flow Models Alexander Kurganov Tulane University Mathematics Department www.math.tulane.edu/ kurganov joint work with Pierre Degond, Université Paul Sabatier, Toulouse

More information

Differential Inclusions and the Control of Forest Fires

Differential Inclusions and the Control of Forest Fires Differential Inclusions and the Control of Forest Fires Alberto Bressan November 006) Department of Mathematics, Penn State University University Park, Pa. 1680 U.S.A. e-mail: bressan@math.psu.edu Dedicated

More information

Extremal Solutions of Differential Inclusions via Baire Category: a Dual Approach

Extremal Solutions of Differential Inclusions via Baire Category: a Dual Approach Extremal Solutions of Differential Inclusions via Baire Category: a Dual Approach Alberto Bressan Department of Mathematics, Penn State University University Park, Pa 1682, USA e-mail: bressan@mathpsuedu

More information

Various lecture notes for

Various lecture notes for Various lecture notes for 18311. R. R. Rosales (MIT, Math. Dept., 2-337) April 12, 2013 Abstract Notes, both complete and/or incomplete, for MIT s 18.311 (Principles of Applied Mathematics). These notes

More information

1. Introduction. Consider a strictly hyperbolic system of n conservation laws. 1 if i = j, 0 if i j.

1. Introduction. Consider a strictly hyperbolic system of n conservation laws. 1 if i = j, 0 if i j. SIAM J MATH ANAL Vol 36, No, pp 659 677 c 4 Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics A SHARP DECAY ESTIMATE FOR POSITIVE NONLINEAR WAVES ALBERTO BRESSAN AND TONG YANG Abstract We consider a strictly

More information

Dynamic Blocking Problems for Models of Fire Propagation

Dynamic Blocking Problems for Models of Fire Propagation Dynamic Blocking Problems for Models of Fire Propagation Alberto Bressan Department of Mathematics, Penn State University bressan@math.psu.edu Alberto Bressan (Penn State) Dynamic Blocking Problems 1 /

More information

NONTRIVIAL SOLUTIONS TO INTEGRAL AND DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS

NONTRIVIAL SOLUTIONS TO INTEGRAL AND DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS Fixed Point Theory, Volume 9, No. 1, 28, 3-16 http://www.math.ubbcluj.ro/ nodeacj/sfptcj.html NONTRIVIAL SOLUTIONS TO INTEGRAL AND DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS GIOVANNI ANELLO Department of Mathematics University

More information

SHOCK WAVES FOR RADIATIVE HYPERBOLIC ELLIPTIC SYSTEMS

SHOCK WAVES FOR RADIATIVE HYPERBOLIC ELLIPTIC SYSTEMS SHOCK WAVES FOR RADIATIVE HYPERBOLIC ELLIPTIC SYSTEMS CORRADO LATTANZIO, CORRADO MASCIA, AND DENIS SERRE Abstract. The present paper deals with the following hyperbolic elliptic coupled system, modelling

More information

Non-linear Wave Propagation and Non-Equilibrium Thermodynamics - Part 3

Non-linear Wave Propagation and Non-Equilibrium Thermodynamics - Part 3 Non-linear Wave Propagation and Non-Equilibrium Thermodynamics - Part 3 Tommaso Ruggeri Department of Mathematics and Research Center of Applied Mathematics University of Bologna January 21, 2017 ommaso

More information

A REMARK ON THE GLOBAL DYNAMICS OF COMPETITIVE SYSTEMS ON ORDERED BANACH SPACES

A REMARK ON THE GLOBAL DYNAMICS OF COMPETITIVE SYSTEMS ON ORDERED BANACH SPACES PROCEEDINGS OF THE AMERICAN MATHEMATICAL SOCIETY Volume 00, Number 0, Pages 000 000 S 0002-9939(XX)0000-0 A REMARK ON THE GLOBAL DYNAMICS OF COMPETITIVE SYSTEMS ON ORDERED BANACH SPACES KING-YEUNG LAM

More information

Some lecture notes for Math 6050E: PDEs, Fall 2016

Some lecture notes for Math 6050E: PDEs, Fall 2016 Some lecture notes for Math 65E: PDEs, Fall 216 Tianling Jin December 1, 216 1 Variational methods We discuss an example of the use of variational methods in obtaining existence of solutions. Theorem 1.1.

More information

NONCLASSICAL SHOCK WAVES OF CONSERVATION LAWS: FLUX FUNCTION HAVING TWO INFLECTION POINTS

NONCLASSICAL SHOCK WAVES OF CONSERVATION LAWS: FLUX FUNCTION HAVING TWO INFLECTION POINTS Electronic Journal of Differential Equations, Vol. 2006(2006), No. 149, pp. 1 18. ISSN: 1072-6691. URL: http://ejde.math.txstate.edu or http://ejde.math.unt.edu ftp ejde.math.txstate.edu (login: ftp) NONCLASSICAL

More information

Propagating terraces and the dynamics of front-like solutions of reaction-diffusion equations on R

Propagating terraces and the dynamics of front-like solutions of reaction-diffusion equations on R Propagating terraces and the dynamics of front-like solutions of reaction-diffusion equations on R P. Poláčik School of Mathematics, University of Minnesota Minneapolis, MN 55455 Abstract We consider semilinear

More information

A MACROSCOPIC TRAFFIC MODEL FOR ROAD NETWORKS WITH A REPRESENTATION OF THE CAPACITY DROP PHENOMENON AT THE JUNCTIONS

A MACROSCOPIC TRAFFIC MODEL FOR ROAD NETWORKS WITH A REPRESENTATION OF THE CAPACITY DROP PHENOMENON AT THE JUNCTIONS A MACROSCOPIC TRAFFIC MODEL FOR ROAD NETWORKS WITH A REPRESENTATION OF THE CAPACITY DROP PHENOMENON AT THE JUNCTIONS B. Haut G. Bastin Y. Chitour Aspirant FNRS, haut@auto.ucl.ac.be, Centre for Systems

More information

Critical Thresholds in a Relaxation Model for Traffic Flows

Critical Thresholds in a Relaxation Model for Traffic Flows Critical Thresholds in a Relaxation Model for Traffic Flows Tong Li Department of Mathematics University of Iowa Iowa City, IA 52242 tli@math.uiowa.edu and Hailiang Liu Department of Mathematics Iowa State

More information

Dynamic Blocking Problems for a Model of Fire Propagation

Dynamic Blocking Problems for a Model of Fire Propagation Dynamic Blocking Problems for a Model of Fire Propagation Alberto Bressan Department of Mathematics, Penn State University, University Park, Pa 16802, USA bressan@mathpsuedu February 6, 2012 Abstract This

More information

Convergence of a first order scheme for a non local eikonal equation

Convergence of a first order scheme for a non local eikonal equation Convergence of a first order scheme for a non local eikonal equation O. Alvarez, E. Carlini, R. Monneau, E. Rouy March 22, 2005 Abstract We prove the convergence of a first order finite difference scheme

More information

Global Existence of Large BV Solutions in a Model of Granular Flow

Global Existence of Large BV Solutions in a Model of Granular Flow This article was downloaded by: [Pennsylvania State University] On: 08 February 2012, At: 09:55 Publisher: Taylor & Francis Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered

More information

The Skorokhod reflection problem for functions with discontinuities (contractive case)

The Skorokhod reflection problem for functions with discontinuities (contractive case) The Skorokhod reflection problem for functions with discontinuities (contractive case) TAKIS KONSTANTOPOULOS Univ. of Texas at Austin Revised March 1999 Abstract Basic properties of the Skorokhod reflection

More information

The Aw-Rascle traffic flow model with phase transitions

The Aw-Rascle traffic flow model with phase transitions The traffic flow model with phase transitions Paola Goatin Laboratoire d Analyse Non linéaire Appliquée et Modélisation I.S.I.T.V., Université du Sud Toulon - Var B.P. 56, 83162 La Valette du Var Cedex,

More information

1 Basic Second-Order PDEs

1 Basic Second-Order PDEs Partial Differential Equations A. Visintin a.a. 2011-12 These pages are in progress. They contain: an abstract of the classes; notes on some (few) specific issues. These notes are far from providing a

More information

Estimates for probabilities of independent events and infinite series

Estimates for probabilities of independent events and infinite series Estimates for probabilities of independent events and infinite series Jürgen Grahl and Shahar evo September 9, 06 arxiv:609.0894v [math.pr] 8 Sep 06 Abstract This paper deals with finite or infinite sequences

More information

Shock on the left: locus where cars break behind the light.

Shock on the left: locus where cars break behind the light. Review/recap of theory so far. Evolution of wave profile, as given by the characteristic solution. Graphical interpretation: Move each point on graph at velocity c(ρ). Evolution as sliding of horizontal

More information

Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces

Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces Bernhard Schmitzer October 19, 2017 1 Convex non-smooth optimization with proximal operators Remark 1.1 (Motivation). Convex optimization: easier to solve,

More information

Allen Cahn Equation in Two Spatial Dimension

Allen Cahn Equation in Two Spatial Dimension Allen Cahn Equation in Two Spatial Dimension Yoichiro Mori April 25, 216 Consider the Allen Cahn equation in two spatial dimension: ɛ u = ɛ2 u + fu) 1) where ɛ > is a small parameter and fu) is of cubic

More information

On a Class of Multidimensional Optimal Transportation Problems

On a Class of Multidimensional Optimal Transportation Problems Journal of Convex Analysis Volume 10 (2003), No. 2, 517 529 On a Class of Multidimensional Optimal Transportation Problems G. Carlier Université Bordeaux 1, MAB, UMR CNRS 5466, France and Université Bordeaux

More information

Traffic flow on networks: conservation laws models. Benedetto Piccoli I.A.C. C.N.R. Rome

Traffic flow on networks: conservation laws models. Benedetto Piccoli I.A.C. C.N.R. Rome Traffic flow on networks: conservation laws models Benedetto Piccoli I.A.C. C.N.R. Rome Conservation laws on networks u t + f(u) x=0 Dynamics at nodes? 1. The only conservation at nodes does not determine

More information

Dynamical Phenomena induced by Bottleneck

Dynamical Phenomena induced by Bottleneck March 23, Sophia Antipolis, Workshop TRAM2 Dynamical Phenomena induced by Bottleneck Ingenuin Gasser Department of Mathematics University of Hamburg, Germany Tilman Seidel, Gabriele Sirito, Bodo Werner

More information

Convex Functions and Optimization

Convex Functions and Optimization Chapter 5 Convex Functions and Optimization 5.1 Convex Functions Our next topic is that of convex functions. Again, we will concentrate on the context of a map f : R n R although the situation can be generalized

More information

Traffic Flow Problems

Traffic Flow Problems Traffic Flow Problems Nicodemus Banagaaya Supervisor : Dr. J.H.M. ten Thije Boonkkamp October 15, 2009 Outline Introduction Mathematical model derivation Godunov Scheme for the Greenberg Traffic model.

More information

Laplace s Equation. Chapter Mean Value Formulas

Laplace s Equation. Chapter Mean Value Formulas Chapter 1 Laplace s Equation Let be an open set in R n. A function u C 2 () is called harmonic in if it satisfies Laplace s equation n (1.1) u := D ii u = 0 in. i=1 A function u C 2 () is called subharmonic

More information

Presenter: Noriyoshi Fukaya

Presenter: Noriyoshi Fukaya Y. Martel, F. Merle, and T.-P. Tsai, Stability and Asymptotic Stability in the Energy Space of the Sum of N Solitons for Subcritical gkdv Equations, Comm. Math. Phys. 31 (00), 347-373. Presenter: Noriyoshi

More information

E. The Hahn-Banach Theorem

E. The Hahn-Banach Theorem E. The Hahn-Banach Theorem This Appendix contains several technical results, that are extremely useful in Functional Analysis. The following terminology is useful in formulating the statements. Definitions.

More information

h(x) lim H(x) = lim Since h is nondecreasing then h(x) 0 for all x, and if h is discontinuous at a point x then H(x) > 0. Denote

h(x) lim H(x) = lim Since h is nondecreasing then h(x) 0 for all x, and if h is discontinuous at a point x then H(x) > 0. Denote Real Variables, Fall 4 Problem set 4 Solution suggestions Exercise. Let f be of bounded variation on [a, b]. Show that for each c (a, b), lim x c f(x) and lim x c f(x) exist. Prove that a monotone function

More information

b) The system of ODE s d x = v(x) in U. (2) dt

b) The system of ODE s d x = v(x) in U. (2) dt How to solve linear and quasilinear first order partial differential equations This text contains a sketch about how to solve linear and quasilinear first order PDEs and should prepare you for the general

More information

On some weighted fractional porous media equations

On some weighted fractional porous media equations On some weighted fractional porous media equations Gabriele Grillo Politecnico di Milano September 16 th, 2015 Anacapri Joint works with M. Muratori and F. Punzo Gabriele Grillo Weighted Fractional PME

More information

On the piecewise smoothness of entropy solutions to scalar conservation laws for a large class of initial data

On the piecewise smoothness of entropy solutions to scalar conservation laws for a large class of initial data On the piecewise smoothness of entropy solutions to scalar conservation laws for a large class of initial data Tao Tang Jinghua Wang Yinchuan Zhao Abstract We prove that if the initial data do not belong

More information

Some asymptotic properties of solutions for Burgers equation in L p (R)

Some asymptotic properties of solutions for Burgers equation in L p (R) ARMA manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) Some asymptotic properties of solutions for Burgers equation in L p (R) PAULO R. ZINGANO Abstract We discuss time asymptotic properties of solutions

More information

Solving the Poisson Disorder Problem

Solving the Poisson Disorder Problem Advances in Finance and Stochastics: Essays in Honour of Dieter Sondermann, Springer-Verlag, 22, (295-32) Research Report No. 49, 2, Dept. Theoret. Statist. Aarhus Solving the Poisson Disorder Problem

More information

Stochastic Dynamic Programming: The One Sector Growth Model

Stochastic Dynamic Programming: The One Sector Growth Model Stochastic Dynamic Programming: The One Sector Growth Model Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Princeton University March 26, 2012 Esteban Rossi-Hansberg () Stochastic Dynamic Programming March 26, 2012 1 / 31 References

More information

The Mean Value Theorem Rolle s Theorem

The Mean Value Theorem Rolle s Theorem The Mean Value Theorem In this section, we will look at two more theorems that tell us about the way that derivatives affect the shapes of graphs: Rolle s Theorem and the Mean Value Theorem. Rolle s Theorem

More information

Entropy production for a class of inverse SRB measures

Entropy production for a class of inverse SRB measures Entropy production for a class of inverse SRB measures Eugen Mihailescu and Mariusz Urbański Keywords: Inverse SRB measures, folded repellers, Anosov endomorphisms, entropy production. Abstract We study

More information

PARTIAL REGULARITY OF BRENIER SOLUTIONS OF THE MONGE-AMPÈRE EQUATION

PARTIAL REGULARITY OF BRENIER SOLUTIONS OF THE MONGE-AMPÈRE EQUATION PARTIAL REGULARITY OF BRENIER SOLUTIONS OF THE MONGE-AMPÈRE EQUATION ALESSIO FIGALLI AND YOUNG-HEON KIM Abstract. Given Ω, Λ R n two bounded open sets, and f and g two probability densities concentrated

More information

Scaling Limits of Waves in Convex Scalar Conservation Laws Under Random Initial Perturbations

Scaling Limits of Waves in Convex Scalar Conservation Laws Under Random Initial Perturbations Journal of Statistical Physics, Vol. 122, No. 2, January 2006 ( C 2006 ) DOI: 10.1007/s10955-005-8006-x Scaling Limits of Waves in Convex Scalar Conservation Laws Under Random Initial Perturbations Jan

More information

Mathematical Programming Involving (α, ρ)-right upper-dini-derivative Functions

Mathematical Programming Involving (α, ρ)-right upper-dini-derivative Functions Filomat 27:5 (2013), 899 908 DOI 10.2298/FIL1305899Y Published by Faculty of Sciences and Mathematics, University of Niš, Serbia Available at: http://www.pmf.ni.ac.rs/filomat Mathematical Programming Involving

More information

Travelling waves. Chapter 8. 1 Introduction

Travelling waves. Chapter 8. 1 Introduction Chapter 8 Travelling waves 1 Introduction One of the cornerstones in the study of both linear and nonlinear PDEs is the wave propagation. A wave is a recognizable signal which is transferred from one part

More information

MULTI CLASS TRAFFIC MODELS ON ROAD NETWORKS

MULTI CLASS TRAFFIC MODELS ON ROAD NETWORKS COMM. MATH. SCI. Vol. 4, No. 3, pp. 59 68 c 26 International Press MULTI CLASS TRAFFIC MODELS ON ROAD NETWORKS M. HERTY, C. KIRCHNER, AND S. MOUTARI Abstract. We consider a multi class (resp. source destination)

More information

arxiv: v2 [math.ap] 28 Nov 2016

arxiv: v2 [math.ap] 28 Nov 2016 ONE-DIMENSIONAL SAIONARY MEAN-FIELD GAMES WIH LOCAL COUPLING DIOGO A. GOMES, LEVON NURBEKYAN, AND MARIANA PRAZERES arxiv:1611.8161v [math.ap] 8 Nov 16 Abstract. A standard assumption in mean-field game

More information

Math 660-Lecture 23: Gudonov s method and some theories for FVM schemes

Math 660-Lecture 23: Gudonov s method and some theories for FVM schemes Math 660-Lecture 3: Gudonov s method and some theories for FVM schemes 1 The idea of FVM (You can refer to Chapter 4 in the book Finite volume methods for hyperbolic problems ) Consider the box [x 1/,

More information