On the Stability of the Best Reply Map for Noncooperative Differential Games

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "On the Stability of the Best Reply Map for Noncooperative Differential Games"

Transcription

1 On the Stability of the Best Reply Map for Noncooperative Differential Games Alberto Bressan and Zipeng Wang Department of Mathematics, Penn State University, University Park, PA, 68, USA DPMMS, University of Cambridge, Cambridge, CB3 WB, UK s: January 3, Abstract Consider a differential game for two players in infinite time horizon, with exponentially discounted costs. A pair of feedback controls u x, u x is Nash equilibrium solution if u is the best strategy for Player in reply to u, and u is the best strategy for Player, in reply to u. Aim of the present note is to investigate the stability of the best reply map: u, u R u, R u. For linear-quadratic games, we derive a condition which yields asymptotic stability, within the class of feedbacks which are affine functions of the state x IR n. An example shows that stability is lost, as soon as nonlinear perturbations are considered. Introduction Consider non-cooperative differential game for two-players, where the state of the system evolves according to ẋ = fx, u, u.. Here x IR n while the control functions u and u range over the domains u U IR m, u U IR m. The upper dot denotes a derivative w.r.t. time. The goal of each player is to minimize his own cost functional J i = J i x, u = e γt L i xt, u t, u t dt i =,.. This corresponds to an infinite horizon problem, with exponentially discounted cost. Given a feedback strategy x u x implemented by Player, we say that the feedback strategy x u x is a best reply for Player, and write u R u, if u is optimal for

2 the problem with dynamics minimize: J = More precisely, we are here requiring that i for every initial state x IR n, the Cauchy problem e γt L xt, u xt, u dt,.3 ẋ = fx, u x, u..4 ẋ = fx, u x, u x, x = x,.5 has at least one Carathéodory solution, defined for all times t. ii Every Carathéodory solution of.5 is optimal in the sense that, given the initial state x and the feedback u, the control u minimizes the cost J among all strategies u available to Player. Given a feedback strategy x u x implemented by Player, a best reply u R u, for Player is defined in a similar way. Two feedback strategies u = u x, u = u x constitute a Nash equilibrium solution to the differential game.-. if at the same time one has u R u, u R u..6 One can regard the Nash solution as a fixed point of the best reply map u, u R u, R u..7 Assuming that this best reply is unique, a natural question is whether the fixed point is asymptotically stable. In other words, let u, u be a pair of feedback controls sufficiently close to a Nash equilibrium u, u, and define the iterates u k+, u k+. = R u k, R u k. Is it true that u k, uk u, u as k? In the present note we provide a positive answer for a class of games with linear dynamics and quadratic costs, as long as the feedback controls u k i are affine functions of the state x IR n. In general, this convergence is not expected to hold for nonlinear systems. Indeed, we show by an example that, even for a linear-quadratic game, the fixed point of the best reply map is not stable w.r.t. nonlinear perturbations of the feedback controls, even if these perturbations have uniformly bounded support and are arbitrarily small in any C k norm. The paper is organized as follows. Section reviews the basic theory of linear-quadratic optimal control problems in infinite time horizon, focusing on how the optimal feedback changes as a consequence of small variations in the dynamics and in the cost function. In Section 3 we briefly review the equations determining a Nash equilibrium solution to a linear-quadratic differential game.

3 After these preliminaries, Section 4 analyzes the stability of the best reply maps for linearquadratic games, within the class of feedback controls which are affine functions of the state. Finally, in Section 5 we provide an example showing that, even for a simple linear-quadratic game, the Nash equilibrium feedbacks are not stable w.r.t. nonlinear perturbations. For a general introduction to differential games we refer to [, 5]. Linear-quadratic games have an extensive literature, see for example [6, ] and references therein. For nonlinear problems, the papers [7, 8] analyze the relations between solutions to differential games and optimal feedback controls. Examples of feedback solutions to nonlinear differential games in infinite time horizon were studied in [4, 9]. For a special class of nearly decoupled games, an iterative procedure yielding a Nash solution can be found in []. Review of the linear-quadratic optimal control problem Consider a system on IR n, with dynamics ẋ = Ax + Bu + c. and a cost functional J = Jx, u. = [ ] e γt x P x + x Qu + u + a x + b u dt.. Here x IR n, u IR m are column vectors, while the superscript denotes transposition. Moreover A, P IR n n, B, Q IR n m, a, c IR n, b IR m. Without loss of generality we can assume P = P. We also remark that, if R IR m m is a symmetric, strictly positive definite matrix, then the more general cost functional J =. [ e γt x P x + x Qu + ] u Ru + a x + b u dt can be reduced to.. Indeed, it suffices to use a new set of control variables v = Λu, with Λ Λ = R. This yields v = u Λ Λu = u Ru. Let V be the value function for the optimization problem.-.. More precisely, let t xt, u, x be the solution to. corresponding to the control function u and the initial data x = x..3 We then define V x. = inf u Jxu, x, u..4 Calling ξ. = V x = Vx,..., V xn the row vector describing the gradient of V, the optimal feedback control u is provided by { u x, ξ = argmin ξ Bω + x Qω + ω } ω + b ω..5 3

4 Differentiating w.r.t. ω, we obtain ξ B + x Q + u + b =, u x, ξ = B ξ + Q x + b..6 It is well known that, if the value function V is continuously differentiable function, then it provides a solution to the Hamilton-Jacobi equation where γv = V ẋ + Lx, u,.7 ẋ = Ax + Bu + c,.8 Lx, u. = x P x + x Qu + u + a x + b u.9 After some calculations, this yields [ ] γv = V Ax B B V + Q x + b + c + x P x + a x x Q + b B V + Q x + b. + V B + x Q + b B V + Q x + b. This can be written as γv = V à V + V Bx + V c + x P x + q x + r,. where à = BB, B = A BQ, c = c Bb, P = P QQ, q = a Qb, r = b b.. Now assume V x = x Mx + n x + e.3 for some symmetric matrix M, some vector n and a scalar e. This implies Inserting.3-.4 in. one obtains γ x Mx + γn x + γe V x = x M + n..4 = x M + n ÃMx + n + x M + n Bx + x M + n c + x P x + q x + r..5 4

5 Equating homogeneous terms of the same degree, and observing that x M Bx = x B Mx because M is symmetric, we finally obtain γm = MÃM + M B + B T M + P, γn = n ÃM + n B + c M + q,.6 γe = n + n c + r. The first equation in.6 is a quadratic equation for the n n symmetric matrix M, whose solution depends on the matrices A, B, P, Q. Existence and uniqueness of solutions is not guaranteed, in general. As soon as the matrix M is determined, the last two equations in.6 yield the values of the vector n and of the scalar e. These last two equations are linear w.r.t. n, e. Next, assume that a solution of the equations.6 has been found. According to.6 the optimal feedback control is [ ] [ ] u x = B V + Q x + b = B Mx + n + Q x + b..7 The system dynamics is thus described by [ ] ẋ = Ax B B Mx + n + Q x + b + c..8 Our basic assumption will be that this dynamics is asymptotically stable. Equivalent conditions for this to happen are: i The linear homogeneous system is asymptotically stable. ẋ = Y x, Y. = A BB M BQ.9 ii All the eigenvalues of the matrix Y in.9 have strictly negative real part. iii There exist constants C, ω > such that norm of the exponential matrix satisfies e ty C e tω for all t.. We write.7 in the form where the m n-matrix U and the m-vector v are given by u x = Ux + v,. U = B M + Q, v = B n + b.. Clearly, this optimal feedback u depends on the coefficients A, B, c of the system. and on the coefficients P, Q, a, b of the cost functional.. Keeping B, Q, b constant, we wish 5

6 to understand how U, v depend on the remaining parameters A, P, c, a. In other words, we study the differential of the map A, c, P, a Φ U, v..3 Assume that we replace A, c, P, a by A + εa, c + εc, P + εp, a + εa. Then the optimal feedback will have the form u εx = U + εu x + v + εv + oε..4 We seek an expression for U, v as a linear function of A, P, c, a, depending on A, P, c, a. Inserting = M + εm + oε inside the first equation in.6 and recalling. one obtains M ε γm ε = M ε BB M ε + M ε A + εa BQ + A + εa BQ M ε + P + εp QQ. Collecting terms of order ε we find γm = MBB M M BB M + M A BQ + A BQ M + MA + A M + P, [ ] [ γm + M BB M A + BQ + M BB M A + BQ ] = MA + MA + P. We thus seek an n n symmetric matrix M such that where γm M Y M Y = S,.5 Y. = A BB M BQ, S. = MA + MA + P..6 Notice that S is symmetric, but Y may not be symmetric. Of course, the left hand side of.5 is always symmetric. The solution to.5 is provided by the formula M = e γt e ty Se ty dt..7 Notice that the integral is absolutely convergent, because of.. Observing that M is symmetric, the above formula can be verified by writing γm M Y M Y d = e γt e ty Se ty dt = S..8 dt According to., the first order variations of the matrix U and of the vector v are computed by U = B M, v = B n..9 The symmetric matrix M has already been computed at.7. Notice that M depends only on the first order variations A, P and not on c, a. For future use, we seek an expression for n in the special case where A =, P =. By., the second equation in.6 yields n = γi + MBB A + QB Mc Bb + a Qb. 6

7 Hence Notice that the matrix n = γi + MBB A + QB Mc + a..3 γi + MBB A + QB = γi Y is certainly invertible. Indeed, the stability assumption. implies all of its eigenvalues have real part > γ. 3 A linear-quadratic differential game We now consider a differential game for two players, with controls u IR m, u IR m. In place of., the dynamics is now described by ẋ = Ax + B u + B u + f. 3. Assume that the cost functionals for the two players have the form J i = e γt x P i x + a i x + u i + x Q ij u j + b ij dt i =,. 3. j=, Assume that the value functions V, V are second order polynomials in the space variables x,..., x n : so that V i x = x M i x + n i x + e i i =,, 3.3 V i x = M i x + n i. 3.4 Then the optimal feedback controls u, u for the two players are determined by { u i x = argmin V i B i ω + ω } ω +x Q ii ω +b ii ω = B i M ix+n i +Q ii x+b ii. 3.5 The strategies 3.5 yield a Nash equilibrium solution in feedback form provided that the value functions V, V satisfy the system of P.D.E s γv i = V i ẋ + L i x, u, u i =,, 3.6 where ẋ = Ax + B u + B u + f, 3.7 L i x, u, u = x P i x + a i x + u i + x Q ij + b ij u j. 3.8 j=, 7

8 Inserting in 3.6 the expressions 3.3 for V, V, and using 3.4, 3.7, 3.8, one obtains γ x M x + γn x + γe [ = x M + n Ax B B M x + n + Q x + b B B M x + n + Q x + b ] x P x + a x + j=, x Q j + b j B j M jx + n j + Q jj x + b jj x M + n B + x Q + b B M x + n + Q x + b, and an entirely similar equation holds for V. We regard 3.9 as an identity between two polynomials of degree in the variables x,..., x n. Equating the coefficients of the quadratic terms, one obtains a system of algebraic equations for the coefficients of the symmetric matrices M, M. A direct computation yields M B B M M B B M + M C M B Q + C =, M B B M M B B M + M C M B Q + C = 3. where C. = A γ I B Q B Q, C. = P Q Q Q Q C. = P Q Q Q Q. 3. Throughout the following, we assume that there exists a pair of n n symmetric matrices M, M providing a solution to the above system. Moreover, we assume that the resulting dynamics is asymptotically stable, so that all the eigenvalues of the matrix Y =. A B B M + B B M + B Q + B Q 3. have strictly negative real parts. Next, equating the coefficients of the linear terms in 3.9, we obtain a system of linear equations for the vectors n, n : Y γi R n = R Y γi n T 3.3 T where. R = M B B + Q B, R. = M B B + Q B, T = a + M B j b jj + Q j b jj + Q jj b j + M B b Q b. j=, 8

9 T = a + j=, M B j b jj + Q j b jj + Q jj b j + M B b Q b. Finally, equating the constant terms on the two sides of 3.9, one obtains an expression for e, e : γe i = n i B j B j n j + b jj b ij b jj + n B + b. 3.4 j=, j=, 4 Affine perturbations Now consider the differential game Let the feedback controls u i x = U i x + v i, i =,, 4. provide a Nash equilibrium solution. Let V, V be the value functions for the two players, so that all the identities hold. We wish to understand whether this solution is stable w.r.t. iterations of the best reply map. In this section we study the case of affine perturbations, while in the next section is concerned with general nonlinear perturbations. As we shall see, the answer is quite different in the two cases. To state the question more precisely, consider two perturbed feedback controls u i x = U i x + v i, i =,. 4. By induction on N, define a sequence of feedback controls u k i x = U k i x + v k i, i =,, 4.3 where u k is the optimal feedback for Player, in reply to the feedback u k implemented by Player, and similarly u k is the optimal feedback for Player, in reply to u k. We seek conditions which guarantee that, if the pair u, u is sufficiently close to u, u, then one has the convergence u k, uk u, u as k. 4.4 For this purpose, we consider the two maps Φ : U k U k, Φ : U k U k and compute the differential of the composite mapping Φ Φ at the equilibrium point U, U. Consider a small perturbation of the feedback for the first player: u,ε x = U i + εu ix + v + εv. Then the optimal feedback for the second player will also be changed, say u,ε x = U + εu x + v + εv + oε. 9

10 The perturbation U is computed as in.9,.7. Indeed, from the point of view of the second player, perturbing U and v amounts to replacing the dynamics with Moreover, the cost functional J = is replaced by ẋ = A + B U x + B u + B v + f 4.6 ẋ ε = A + B U + εu x + B u + B v + εv + f. 4.7 e γt [ x P x + a x + u J,ε = e γt [ x P x + a x + u ] + x Q + b u + x Q + b U x + v dt + x Q + b u ] + x Q + b U x + εu x + v + εv dt By the analysis in Section, the differential of the map Φ in 4.5 is the linear map U U defined by U = B M, 4. M = e γt e ty S e ty dt, 4. S. = M A + M A + P = M B U + M B U + Q U + Q U. 4. The differential of the map Φ is computed by the same formulas, 4. 4., permuting the indices,. We now consider the composition of two iterations, say Ũ = DΦ U = DΦ DΦ U. Observing that Ũ = B M, U = B M, U = B M, where the matrices B, B do not change from one iteration to the next. We have the estimate can be estimated by M = e γt e ty S e ty dt = e γt e ty M B U + M B U + Q U + Q U e ty dt e γt e ty e ty dt M B + Q B M Calling e γt e ty e ty dt I. = 4 M B + Q M B + Q B B M. e γt e ty e ty dt, 4.3

11 we can now state Theorem. Let V i, i =, be the value functions corresponding to a Nash equilibrium feedback solution. Assume that 4 M B + Q M B + Q B B I <. 4.4 γi Y M + Q M + Q B B <. 4.5 Then the Nash equilibrium is asymptotically stable w.r.t. iterations of the best reply map, within the class of piecewise affine feedback controls. Proof. Consider the composite mapping U, v U, v Ũ, ṽ, 4.6 where u x = U x+v is the best reply for Player to the feedback u x = U x+v used by Player, while ũ x = Ũx+ṽ is the best reply for Player to the feedback u x = U x+v. Consider the corresponding value functions V x = x M x + n x + e, V x = x M x + n x + e, Ṽ x = x M x + ñ x + ẽ. 4.7 By 3.5 U i = B i M i + Q ii, v i = B i n i + b ii. Therefore, to prove convergence of the iterates of the best reply map, it suffices to prove the convergence of the iterates of the composite map M, n M, n M, ñ. 4.8 Consider the differential of this mapping, computed at the Nash equilibrium: Λ. = M / M M / n. 4.9 ñ / M ñ / n To prove the theorem, it suffices to show that the powers of this matrix converge to zero: Λ N as N. 4. Since M / n =, the convergence in 4. will follow from the two inequalities M / M <, ñ / n <. 4. By 4.3, the first inequality follows from the assumption 4.4. Next, applying.3 with c = v = B n, a = Q v = Q B n,

12 we obtain Similarly, Hence ñ / n n = γi Y M B + Q B n. ñ = γi Y M B + Q B n. γi Y M + Q M + Q B B. and the second inequality in 4. follows from the assumption 4.5. Example. The previous result applies, in particular, to a differential game with one weak player, considered in [, 3]. Let the cost functionals be as in 3., but assume that the dynamics has the form ẋ = Ax + B u + θb u + f. 4. When θ =, the Nash equilibrium solution is attained after one iteration. Indeed, in this case the second player cannot affect the evolution of the system. His best strategy is thus the myopic one: { ω u } x = argmin ω + x Q ω + b ω regardless of the feedback u implemented by the first player. = Q x + b, On the other hand, for θ >, replacing the term B by θb it is clear that the assumptions are satisfied, as long as θ remains small enough. 5 Nonlinear perturbations The convergence result proved in the previous section strongly relied on the linear-quadratic structure of the game, and on the fact that all perturbed feedback controls remained within the class of affine functions of the state x. In this section we show that, even for a linear-quadratic game, the iterates of the best reply map may fail to converge, as soon as we consider feedback controls which are not affine functions of the state. Example. Consider the game with linear dynamics and quadratic payoff functionals ẋ = fx, u, u. = x + u + u 5. J J. =. = e t[ ax u ] dt, 5. e t[ bx u ] dt. 5.3

13 We assume here < a < b. Call V x, V x the value functions for the two players. Their derivatives will be written as The optimal controls are then computed as ξ. = V = V,x, η. = V = V,x. u x, ξ = argmax ω ξ ω ω = ξ, 5.4 u x, η = argmax η ω ω = η. 5.5 ω The value functions V, V can be found by solving the system of Hamilton-Jacobi equations { V = Hx, V, V, V = Kx, V, V, 5.6 where Notice that Hx, ξ, η = ξ x + u x, ξ + v x, η + ax u x, ξ = ξ Kx, ξ, η = η + a ξx + ξη, x + u x, ξ + v x, η + bx v x, η = ξη + b ηx + η. Differentiating 5.6 we obtain the system H ξ = K η = x + ξ + η = fx, ξ, η. 5.9 { ξ = Hx + H ξ ξ + H η η, η = K x + K ξ ξ + K η η. 5. In matrix notation, this can be written as ξ + η x ξ η ξ + η x ξ η = ξ a η b. 5. The system 5. admits the constant solution ξ a, η b. 5. This correspond to a Nash equilibrium solution of the differential game consisting of two constant feedback controls: u x = a, u x = b

14 Next, we study whether there exist other solutions, possibly described by nonlinear feedbacks u x, u x. Following [, 3], we write 5. as a Pfaffian system ω. = a ξ dx + ξ + η x dξ + ξ dη =, ω. = b η dx + η dξ + ξ + η x dη =. 5.4 The graph of a solution to 5. can then be obtained by suitably concatenating trajectories of the vector field ξ + η x ξη v = ω ω = ξ + η xξ a ξη b. 5.5 ξ + η xη b ηξ a Notice that the first component of v vanishes along the conical surface Γ =. { } x, ξ, η ; ξ + η x ξη =. 5.6 At a point P Γ we either have vp = IR 3, or else the vector vp is vertical. The only way to connect trajectories of the vector field v forming the graph of a smooth function x W x = yx, zx is to cross the surface Γ somewhere along the two curves where v vanishes, namely γ ±. = {x, ξ, η ; x = ξ + η ± ξη, ξ a = ± Observe that the map } ξ η b. 5.7 η t P t. = xt, a, b, xt = p+ + p e κt + e κt, κ =, p ± = a + b ± ab ab 5.8 describes a heteroclinic orbit of the vector field v in 5.5, connecting the two stationary points P + = a + b + ab, a, b γ +, P = a + b ab, a, b γ. Setting Xt. = a + b xt, the Jacobian matrix of the vector field v at the point P t is At = Xt Xt b Xt a Xt a. 5.9 b Xt The eigenvalues λ i and the corresponding eigenvectors w i of the matrix At are: λ t = Xt, λ t = Xt + ab, λ 3 t = Xt ab, 5. 4

15 w =, w = b a, w 3 = b a + b a. 5. b a In particular, at the point P the three eigenvalues are ab < < ab, while at the point P + the eigenvalues are ab < < ab. Since the eigenvectors are constant, the general solution to the linear equation ẏ = Aty can be written as { t yt = c exp } λ sds w for some constants c, c, c 3. By , we have { t } { t } + c exp λ sds w + c 3 exp λ 3 sds w 3, 5. lim yt = + if and only if c 3, t lim yt = + if and only if c, t Let us call Σ + the -dimensional manifold of points P = x, ξ, η such that the solution to P = vp, P = P 5.4 satisfies P t γ + as t. Similarly, call Σ the -dimensional manifold of points P = x, ξ, η such that the solution of 5.4 satisfies P t γ as t +. By 5.3, these two manifolds intersect transversally along the segment P P +. We conclude that there can be no other solutions to 5., in a neighborhood of the constant solution 5.. We claim that this pair of feedback controls, providing a fixed point of the best reply map is unstable w.r.t. nonlinear perturbations. More precisely: Proposition. There exists δ > and a sequence of smooth perturbations φ k C c IR such that the following holds. The C k norms of φ k satisfy φ k C k. 5.5 For any k, starting with the values u x = a + φ kx, u x = b, 5.6 the iterates u N, u N of the best reply map do not converge to the solution u, u in 5.3. Indeed, lim sup N { u N x a + u N x b ; a + b < x < a + b + 6δ } > δ

16 Proof. To construct the nonlinear perturbations φ k, choose < δ << and let x Consider the standard C function with compact support if x <, φs = exp { s } if x.. = a+b +3δ. Then define. x x φ k x = c k φ k. ε k Choosing sequences of numbers numbers < c k << ε k converging to zero sufficiently fast, the condition 5.5 can be easily satisfied. We now examine the sequence of iterations of the best reply map, starting from the initial feedbacks ξ x = a + ψ kx, η x = b. 5.8 Assume ξ N, η N have been determined. By 5., the next iteration yields a pair of functions ξ N+ x and η N+ x, respectively providing solutions to ξ = ξ ξ + η N x x a η N x ξ, η = η η + ξ N x x b ξ N x η. Iterating once more, we find that ξ N+ provides a solution to [ ξ = ξ + η N+ x x ] ξ a η N+ + ξ N x x η N+ b ξ N x η ξ At this stage, one should observe that the system of ODEs 5., as well as the two ODEs in 5.9, are not supplemented by initial data. It is the singularity in the coefficients that determines one particular, globally defined solution. For the system 5., the matrix of coefficients fails to be invertible on the conical surface Γ at 5.6. A globally smooth solution is found by concatenating trajectories of the vector field v in 5.5. As we have seen, these trajectories must cross Γ at points where v vanishes. Since the manifolds Σ +, Σ intersect transversally, the segment P + P is the only heteroclinic orbit, and the unique Nash equilibrium solution is 5.3. On the other hand, the right hand sides of 5.9 are both singular at points where ξ+η x =. At each iteration, the only solution which is regular across the surface where ξ + η x = is the one for which ξ N x = a, η Nx = b for all x x ε k, N. 5.3 The functions ξ N+, η N+ can thus be constructed by solving 5.9 one the half line [x ε k, + [, with boundary data ξx ε k =, ηx ε k =

17 Observe that the Cauchy problem for the system ξ ξ + η x ξ = η ξ + η x ξη η ξ + η x ξ a η b with initial data 5.3 is well posed in a neighborhood of x, and its solution provides a fixed point of the iteration scheme 5.9. However, this iteration scheme, motivated by the best-reply map, is highly unstable for x close to a+b. Indeed, contrary to the usual Picard integral map, the right hand sides of 5.9 depend also on the derivatives ξ N, η N. Since ξ a/, η b/, x a + b/ + 3δ, from 5.3 it follows ξ N+ x ab a + b x 4 ξ N x, We thus expect that ξ N x + for x ε k < x < x. A more careful argument is as follows. Assume a ξ Nx a + δ, b δ η N+x b + δ, for all x [x ε k, ȳ], for some ȳ [x ε k, x ]. Then 5.3 yields 5.33 ξ N+ x ab 3δ 4 ξ N x δ η N+ x b Moreover, the second equation in 5.9 yields η N+ x = ] [ξ N x η ξ N x x η η + b b δ + δ Hence, integrating and inserting in 5.34, we obtain ξ N+ x 3δ ab 4 ξ N x δ b δ + 4 x x ε k ξ N It is not restrictive to assume that ε k > is so small that b δ + 4 all x [x ε k, ȳ] one has ξ N+ x a = x x ε k ξ N+ y dy ξ N x 5.35 y dy ε k ab 7. If this holds, for ab x 3δ 4 ξ N y dy b x x ε k δ δ + 4 [x x ε k ] ξ N y dy x ε k ab x 3δ 8 ξ N y dy = ab x ε k 3δ 8 ξ N x a 5.37 Since < δ <<, the above estimate shows that, for every x ε k < x < ȳ, the sequence ξ N x a/ keeps increasing, as long as the bounds 5.33 hold. By continuity, for any given N we can now find yn > x ε k such that the estimates 5.33 hold for all N N and x [x ε k, yn ]. By 5.37, the sequence ξ N x keeps increasing. Hence there exists N > N such that one of the bounds in 5.33 fails at some x [x ε k, yn ]. This establishes the limit

18 Acknowledgment. The first author was partially supported by NSF through grant DMS- 874, New problems in nonlinear control. References [] T. Basar and G. J. Olsder, Dynamic Noncooperative Game Theory, reprint of the second edition, SIAM, Philadelphia, 999. [] A. Bressan, From optimal control to non-cooperative differential games: a homotopy approach. Control and Cybernetics, 38 9, 8-6. [3] A. Bressan, Bifurcation analysis of a noncooperative differential game with one weak player. J. Differential Equations 48, [4] A. Bressan and F. Priuli, Infinite horizon noncooperative differential games, J. Differential Equations 7 6, [5] E. Dockner, S. Jorgensen, N. Van Long, and G. Sorger, Differential games in economics and management science, Cambridge University Press,. [6] J. Engwerda, Linear quadratic differential games: an overview. In: Advances in dynamic games and their applications, pp. 37-7, Ann. Internat. Soc. Dynam. Games, Birkhuser, Boston, 9. [7] S. Mirica, Verification theorems for optimal feedback strategies in differential games. Int. Game Theory Rev. 5 3, [8] S. Mirica, Reducing a differential game to a pair of optimal control problems. In Differential Equations, Chaos and Variational Problems, pp , Birkhäuser, Basel, 8. [9] F. S. Priuli, Infinite horizon noncooperative differential games with nonsmooth costs. J. Math. Anal. Appl , [] R. Srikant and T. Basar, Iterative computation of noncooperative equilibria in nonzerosum differential games with weakly coupled players. J. Optim. Th. Appl. 7 99, [] A.J.T.M. Weeren, J.M. Schumacher, and J.C. Engwerda, Asymptotic analysis of linear feedback Nash equilibria in nonzero-sum linear-quadratic differential games. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 999,

Stability of Feedback Solutions for Infinite Horizon Noncooperative Differential Games

Stability of Feedback Solutions for Infinite Horizon Noncooperative Differential Games Stability of Feedback Solutions for Infinite Horizon Noncooperative Differential Games Alberto Bressan ) and Khai T. Nguyen ) *) Department of Mathematics, Penn State University **) Department of Mathematics,

More information

Alberto Bressan. Department of Mathematics, Penn State University

Alberto Bressan. Department of Mathematics, Penn State University Non-cooperative Differential Games A Homotopy Approach Alberto Bressan Department of Mathematics, Penn State University 1 Differential Games d dt x(t) = G(x(t), u 1(t), u 2 (t)), x(0) = y, u i (t) U i

More information

An Introduction to Noncooperative Games

An Introduction to Noncooperative Games An Introduction to Noncooperative Games Alberto Bressan Department of Mathematics, Penn State University Alberto Bressan (Penn State) Noncooperative Games 1 / 29 introduction to non-cooperative games:

More information

Hyperbolicity of Systems Describing Value Functions in Differential Games which Model Duopoly Problems. Joanna Zwierzchowska

Hyperbolicity of Systems Describing Value Functions in Differential Games which Model Duopoly Problems. Joanna Zwierzchowska Decision Making in Manufacturing and Services Vol. 9 05 No. pp. 89 00 Hyperbolicity of Systems Describing Value Functions in Differential Games which Model Duopoly Problems Joanna Zwierzchowska Abstract.

More information

Piecewise Smooth Solutions to the Burgers-Hilbert Equation

Piecewise Smooth Solutions to the Burgers-Hilbert Equation Piecewise Smooth Solutions to the Burgers-Hilbert Equation Alberto Bressan and Tianyou Zhang Department of Mathematics, Penn State University, University Park, Pa 68, USA e-mails: bressan@mathpsuedu, zhang

More information

Lecture Notes on PDEs

Lecture Notes on PDEs Lecture Notes on PDEs Alberto Bressan February 26, 2012 1 Elliptic equations Let IR n be a bounded open set Given measurable functions a ij, b i, c : IR, consider the linear, second order differential

More information

Laplace s Equation. Chapter Mean Value Formulas

Laplace s Equation. Chapter Mean Value Formulas Chapter 1 Laplace s Equation Let be an open set in R n. A function u C 2 () is called harmonic in if it satisfies Laplace s equation n (1.1) u := D ii u = 0 in. i=1 A function u C 2 () is called subharmonic

More information

Optimal Control Feedback Nash in The Scalar Infinite Non-cooperative Dynamic Game with Discount Factor

Optimal Control Feedback Nash in The Scalar Infinite Non-cooperative Dynamic Game with Discount Factor Global Journal of Pure and Applied Mathematics. ISSN 0973-1768 Volume 12, Number 4 (2016), pp. 3463-3468 Research India Publications http://www.ripublication.com/gjpam.htm Optimal Control Feedback Nash

More information

Lyapunov Stability Theory

Lyapunov Stability Theory Lyapunov Stability Theory Peter Al Hokayem and Eduardo Gallestey March 16, 2015 1 Introduction In this lecture we consider the stability of equilibrium points of autonomous nonlinear systems, both in continuous

More information

Hyperbolic Systems of Conservation Laws

Hyperbolic Systems of Conservation Laws Hyperbolic Systems of Conservation Laws III - Uniqueness and continuous dependence and viscous approximations Alberto Bressan Mathematics Department, Penn State University http://www.math.psu.edu/bressan/

More information

1 Lyapunov theory of stability

1 Lyapunov theory of stability M.Kawski, APM 581 Diff Equns Intro to Lyapunov theory. November 15, 29 1 1 Lyapunov theory of stability Introduction. Lyapunov s second (or direct) method provides tools for studying (asymptotic) stability

More information

7 Planar systems of linear ODE

7 Planar systems of linear ODE 7 Planar systems of linear ODE Here I restrict my attention to a very special class of autonomous ODE: linear ODE with constant coefficients This is arguably the only class of ODE for which explicit solution

More information

Chap. 3. Controlled Systems, Controllability

Chap. 3. Controlled Systems, Controllability Chap. 3. Controlled Systems, Controllability 1. Controllability of Linear Systems 1.1. Kalman s Criterion Consider the linear system ẋ = Ax + Bu where x R n : state vector and u R m : input vector. A :

More information

Math Ordinary Differential Equations

Math Ordinary Differential Equations Math 411 - Ordinary Differential Equations Review Notes - 1 1 - Basic Theory A first order ordinary differential equation has the form x = f(t, x) (11) Here x = dx/dt Given an initial data x(t 0 ) = x

More information

An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control

An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control Vasile Staicu University of Aveiro UNICA, May 2018 Vasile Staicu (University of Aveiro) An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control UNICA, May 2018

More information

Dynamic Blocking Problems for a Model of Fire Propagation

Dynamic Blocking Problems for a Model of Fire Propagation Dynamic Blocking Problems for a Model of Fire Propagation Alberto Bressan Department of Mathematics, Penn State University, University Park, Pa 16802, USA bressan@mathpsuedu February 6, 2012 Abstract This

More information

Extremal Solutions of Differential Inclusions via Baire Category: a Dual Approach

Extremal Solutions of Differential Inclusions via Baire Category: a Dual Approach Extremal Solutions of Differential Inclusions via Baire Category: a Dual Approach Alberto Bressan Department of Mathematics, Penn State University University Park, Pa 1682, USA e-mail: bressan@mathpsuedu

More information

Topic # /31 Feedback Control Systems. Analysis of Nonlinear Systems Lyapunov Stability Analysis

Topic # /31 Feedback Control Systems. Analysis of Nonlinear Systems Lyapunov Stability Analysis Topic # 16.30/31 Feedback Control Systems Analysis of Nonlinear Systems Lyapunov Stability Analysis Fall 010 16.30/31 Lyapunov Stability Analysis Very general method to prove (or disprove) stability of

More information

Convergence Rate of Nonlinear Switched Systems

Convergence Rate of Nonlinear Switched Systems Convergence Rate of Nonlinear Switched Systems Philippe JOUAN and Saïd NACIRI arxiv:1511.01737v1 [math.oc] 5 Nov 2015 January 23, 2018 Abstract This paper is concerned with the convergence rate of the

More information

Linear Quadratic Zero-Sum Two-Person Differential Games Pierre Bernhard June 15, 2013

Linear Quadratic Zero-Sum Two-Person Differential Games Pierre Bernhard June 15, 2013 Linear Quadratic Zero-Sum Two-Person Differential Games Pierre Bernhard June 15, 2013 Abstract As in optimal control theory, linear quadratic (LQ) differential games (DG) can be solved, even in high dimension,

More information

UNIQUENESS OF POSITIVE SOLUTION TO SOME COUPLED COOPERATIVE VARIATIONAL ELLIPTIC SYSTEMS

UNIQUENESS OF POSITIVE SOLUTION TO SOME COUPLED COOPERATIVE VARIATIONAL ELLIPTIC SYSTEMS TRANSACTIONS OF THE AMERICAN MATHEMATICAL SOCIETY Volume 00, Number 0, Pages 000 000 S 0002-9947(XX)0000-0 UNIQUENESS OF POSITIVE SOLUTION TO SOME COUPLED COOPERATIVE VARIATIONAL ELLIPTIC SYSTEMS YULIAN

More information

Noncooperative continuous-time Markov games

Noncooperative continuous-time Markov games Morfismos, Vol. 9, No. 1, 2005, pp. 39 54 Noncooperative continuous-time Markov games Héctor Jasso-Fuentes Abstract This work concerns noncooperative continuous-time Markov games with Polish state and

More information

Structurally Stable Singularities for a Nonlinear Wave Equation

Structurally Stable Singularities for a Nonlinear Wave Equation Structurally Stable Singularities for a Nonlinear Wave Equation Alberto Bressan, Tao Huang, and Fang Yu Department of Mathematics, Penn State University University Park, Pa. 1682, U.S.A. e-mails: bressan@math.psu.edu,

More information

LMI Methods in Optimal and Robust Control

LMI Methods in Optimal and Robust Control LMI Methods in Optimal and Robust Control Matthew M. Peet Arizona State University Lecture 15: Nonlinear Systems and Lyapunov Functions Overview Our next goal is to extend LMI s and optimization to nonlinear

More information

Problem: A class of dynamical systems characterized by a fast divergence of the orbits. A paradigmatic example: the Arnold cat.

Problem: A class of dynamical systems characterized by a fast divergence of the orbits. A paradigmatic example: the Arnold cat. À È Ê ÇÄÁ Ë ËÌ ÅË Problem: A class of dynamical systems characterized by a fast divergence of the orbits A paradigmatic example: the Arnold cat. The closure of a homoclinic orbit. The shadowing lemma.

More information

Entrance Exam, Differential Equations April, (Solve exactly 6 out of the 8 problems) y + 2y + y cos(x 2 y) = 0, y(0) = 2, y (0) = 4.

Entrance Exam, Differential Equations April, (Solve exactly 6 out of the 8 problems) y + 2y + y cos(x 2 y) = 0, y(0) = 2, y (0) = 4. Entrance Exam, Differential Equations April, 7 (Solve exactly 6 out of the 8 problems). Consider the following initial value problem: { y + y + y cos(x y) =, y() = y. Find all the values y such that the

More information

Oblique derivative problems for elliptic and parabolic equations, Lecture II

Oblique derivative problems for elliptic and parabolic equations, Lecture II of the for elliptic and parabolic equations, Lecture II Iowa State University July 22, 2011 of the 1 2 of the of the As a preliminary step in our further we now look at a special situation for elliptic.

More information

minimize x subject to (x 2)(x 4) u,

minimize x subject to (x 2)(x 4) u, Math 6366/6367: Optimization and Variational Methods Sample Preliminary Exam Questions 1. Suppose that f : [, L] R is a C 2 -function with f () on (, L) and that you have explicit formulae for

More information

PH.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MATHEMATICS

PH.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MATHEMATICS UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY Dept. of Civil and Environmental Engineering FALL SEMESTER 2014 Structural Engineering, Mechanics and Materials NAME PH.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MATHEMATICS Problem

More information

Threshold behavior and non-quasiconvergent solutions with localized initial data for bistable reaction-diffusion equations

Threshold behavior and non-quasiconvergent solutions with localized initial data for bistable reaction-diffusion equations Threshold behavior and non-quasiconvergent solutions with localized initial data for bistable reaction-diffusion equations P. Poláčik School of Mathematics, University of Minnesota Minneapolis, MN 55455

More information

An introduction to Birkhoff normal form

An introduction to Birkhoff normal form An introduction to Birkhoff normal form Dario Bambusi Dipartimento di Matematica, Universitá di Milano via Saldini 50, 0133 Milano (Italy) 19.11.14 1 Introduction The aim of this note is to present an

More information

ODE Homework 1. Due Wed. 19 August 2009; At the beginning of the class

ODE Homework 1. Due Wed. 19 August 2009; At the beginning of the class ODE Homework Due Wed. 9 August 2009; At the beginning of the class. (a) Solve Lẏ + Ry = E sin(ωt) with y(0) = k () L, R, E, ω are positive constants. (b) What is the limit of the solution as ω 0? (c) Is

More information

A CHARACTERIZATION OF STRICT LOCAL MINIMIZERS OF ORDER ONE FOR STATIC MINMAX PROBLEMS IN THE PARAMETRIC CONSTRAINT CASE

A CHARACTERIZATION OF STRICT LOCAL MINIMIZERS OF ORDER ONE FOR STATIC MINMAX PROBLEMS IN THE PARAMETRIC CONSTRAINT CASE Journal of Applied Analysis Vol. 6, No. 1 (2000), pp. 139 148 A CHARACTERIZATION OF STRICT LOCAL MINIMIZERS OF ORDER ONE FOR STATIC MINMAX PROBLEMS IN THE PARAMETRIC CONSTRAINT CASE A. W. A. TAHA Received

More information

STABILITY. Phase portraits and local stability

STABILITY. Phase portraits and local stability MAS271 Methods for differential equations Dr. R. Jain STABILITY Phase portraits and local stability We are interested in system of ordinary differential equations of the form ẋ = f(x, y), ẏ = g(x, y),

More information

Applied Math Qualifying Exam 11 October Instructions: Work 2 out of 3 problems in each of the 3 parts for a total of 6 problems.

Applied Math Qualifying Exam 11 October Instructions: Work 2 out of 3 problems in each of the 3 parts for a total of 6 problems. Printed Name: Signature: Applied Math Qualifying Exam 11 October 2014 Instructions: Work 2 out of 3 problems in each of the 3 parts for a total of 6 problems. 2 Part 1 (1) Let Ω be an open subset of R

More information

Control, Stabilization and Numerics for Partial Differential Equations

Control, Stabilization and Numerics for Partial Differential Equations Paris-Sud, Orsay, December 06 Control, Stabilization and Numerics for Partial Differential Equations Enrique Zuazua Universidad Autónoma 28049 Madrid, Spain enrique.zuazua@uam.es http://www.uam.es/enrique.zuazua

More information

MCE693/793: Analysis and Control of Nonlinear Systems

MCE693/793: Analysis and Control of Nonlinear Systems MCE693/793: Analysis and Control of Nonlinear Systems Systems of Differential Equations Phase Plane Analysis Hanz Richter Mechanical Engineering Department Cleveland State University Systems of Nonlinear

More information

EE363 homework 7 solutions

EE363 homework 7 solutions EE363 Prof. S. Boyd EE363 homework 7 solutions 1. Gain margin for a linear quadratic regulator. Let K be the optimal state feedback gain for the LQR problem with system ẋ = Ax + Bu, state cost matrix Q,

More information

On Discontinuous Differential Equations

On Discontinuous Differential Equations On Discontinuous Differential Equations Alberto Bressan and Wen Shen S.I.S.S.A., Via Beirut 4, Trieste 3414 Italy. Department of Informatics, University of Oslo, P.O. Box 18 Blindern, N-316 Oslo, Norway.

More information

A Perron-type theorem on the principal eigenvalue of nonsymmetric elliptic operators

A Perron-type theorem on the principal eigenvalue of nonsymmetric elliptic operators A Perron-type theorem on the principal eigenvalue of nonsymmetric elliptic operators Lei Ni And I cherish more than anything else the Analogies, my most trustworthy masters. They know all the secrets of

More information

Z i Q ij Z j. J(x, φ; U) = X T φ(t ) 2 h + where h k k, H(t) k k and R(t) r r are nonnegative definite matrices (R(t) is uniformly in t nonsingular).

Z i Q ij Z j. J(x, φ; U) = X T φ(t ) 2 h + where h k k, H(t) k k and R(t) r r are nonnegative definite matrices (R(t) is uniformly in t nonsingular). 2. LINEAR QUADRATIC DETERMINISTIC PROBLEM Notations: For a vector Z, Z = Z, Z is the Euclidean norm here Z, Z = i Z2 i is the inner product; For a vector Z and nonnegative definite matrix Q, Z Q = Z, QZ

More information

Dynamical Systems & Lyapunov Stability

Dynamical Systems & Lyapunov Stability Dynamical Systems & Lyapunov Stability Harry G. Kwatny Department of Mechanical Engineering & Mechanics Drexel University Outline Ordinary Differential Equations Existence & uniqueness Continuous dependence

More information

Theorem 1. ẋ = Ax is globally exponentially stable (GES) iff A is Hurwitz (i.e., max(re(σ(a))) < 0).

Theorem 1. ẋ = Ax is globally exponentially stable (GES) iff A is Hurwitz (i.e., max(re(σ(a))) < 0). Linear Systems Notes Lecture Proposition. A M n (R) is positive definite iff all nested minors are greater than or equal to zero. n Proof. ( ): Positive definite iff λ i >. Let det(a) = λj and H = {x D

More information

Nonlinear Control. Nonlinear Control Lecture # 2 Stability of Equilibrium Points

Nonlinear Control. Nonlinear Control Lecture # 2 Stability of Equilibrium Points Nonlinear Control Lecture # 2 Stability of Equilibrium Points Basic Concepts ẋ = f(x) f is locally Lipschitz over a domain D R n Suppose x D is an equilibrium point; that is, f( x) = 0 Characterize and

More information

1 Relative degree and local normal forms

1 Relative degree and local normal forms THE ZERO DYNAMICS OF A NONLINEAR SYSTEM 1 Relative degree and local normal orms The purpose o this Section is to show how single-input single-output nonlinear systems can be locally given, by means o a

More information

Solution of Linear State-space Systems

Solution of Linear State-space Systems Solution of Linear State-space Systems Homogeneous (u=0) LTV systems first Theorem (Peano-Baker series) The unique solution to x(t) = (t, )x 0 where The matrix function is given by is called the state

More information

Chapter Introduction. A. Bensoussan

Chapter Introduction. A. Bensoussan Chapter 2 EXPLICIT SOLUTIONS OFLINEAR QUADRATIC DIFFERENTIAL GAMES A. Bensoussan International Center for Decision and Risk Analysis University of Texas at Dallas School of Management, P.O. Box 830688

More information

DUALIZATION OF SUBGRADIENT CONDITIONS FOR OPTIMALITY

DUALIZATION OF SUBGRADIENT CONDITIONS FOR OPTIMALITY DUALIZATION OF SUBGRADIENT CONDITIONS FOR OPTIMALITY R. T. Rockafellar* Abstract. A basic relationship is derived between generalized subgradients of a given function, possibly nonsmooth and nonconvex,

More information

Chap. 1. Some Differential Geometric Tools

Chap. 1. Some Differential Geometric Tools Chap. 1. Some Differential Geometric Tools 1. Manifold, Diffeomorphism 1.1. The Implicit Function Theorem ϕ : U R n R n p (0 p < n), of class C k (k 1) x 0 U such that ϕ(x 0 ) = 0 rank Dϕ(x) = n p x U

More information

Explicit solutions of some Linear-Quadratic Mean Field Games

Explicit solutions of some Linear-Quadratic Mean Field Games Explicit solutions of some Linear-Quadratic Mean Field Games Martino Bardi Department of Pure and Applied Mathematics University of Padua, Italy Men Field Games and Related Topics Rome, May 12-13, 2011

More information

What can be expressed via Conic Quadratic and Semidefinite Programming?

What can be expressed via Conic Quadratic and Semidefinite Programming? What can be expressed via Conic Quadratic and Semidefinite Programming? A. Nemirovski Faculty of Industrial Engineering and Management Technion Israel Institute of Technology Abstract Tremendous recent

More information

OPTIMAL CONTROL. Sadegh Bolouki. Lecture slides for ECE 515. University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign. Fall S. Bolouki (UIUC) 1 / 28

OPTIMAL CONTROL. Sadegh Bolouki. Lecture slides for ECE 515. University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign. Fall S. Bolouki (UIUC) 1 / 28 OPTIMAL CONTROL Sadegh Bolouki Lecture slides for ECE 515 University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign Fall 2016 S. Bolouki (UIUC) 1 / 28 (Example from Optimal Control Theory, Kirk) Objective: To get from

More information

Nonlinear Systems and Control Lecture # 12 Converse Lyapunov Functions & Time Varying Systems. p. 1/1

Nonlinear Systems and Control Lecture # 12 Converse Lyapunov Functions & Time Varying Systems. p. 1/1 Nonlinear Systems and Control Lecture # 12 Converse Lyapunov Functions & Time Varying Systems p. 1/1 p. 2/1 Converse Lyapunov Theorem Exponential Stability Let x = 0 be an exponentially stable equilibrium

More information

OR MSc Maths Revision Course

OR MSc Maths Revision Course OR MSc Maths Revision Course Tom Byrne School of Mathematics University of Edinburgh t.m.byrne@sms.ed.ac.uk 15 September 2017 General Information Today JCMB Lecture Theatre A, 09:30-12:30 Mathematics revision

More information

Duality and dynamics in Hamilton-Jacobi theory for fully convex problems of control

Duality and dynamics in Hamilton-Jacobi theory for fully convex problems of control Duality and dynamics in Hamilton-Jacobi theory for fully convex problems of control RTyrrell Rockafellar and Peter R Wolenski Abstract This paper describes some recent results in Hamilton- Jacobi theory

More information

arxiv: v2 [math.ap] 28 Nov 2016

arxiv: v2 [math.ap] 28 Nov 2016 ONE-DIMENSIONAL SAIONARY MEAN-FIELD GAMES WIH LOCAL COUPLING DIOGO A. GOMES, LEVON NURBEKYAN, AND MARIANA PRAZERES arxiv:1611.8161v [math.ap] 8 Nov 16 Abstract. A standard assumption in mean-field game

More information

NONTRIVIAL SOLUTIONS TO INTEGRAL AND DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS

NONTRIVIAL SOLUTIONS TO INTEGRAL AND DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS Fixed Point Theory, Volume 9, No. 1, 28, 3-16 http://www.math.ubbcluj.ro/ nodeacj/sfptcj.html NONTRIVIAL SOLUTIONS TO INTEGRAL AND DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS GIOVANNI ANELLO Department of Mathematics University

More information

An homotopy method for exact tracking of nonlinear nonminimum phase systems: the example of the spherical inverted pendulum

An homotopy method for exact tracking of nonlinear nonminimum phase systems: the example of the spherical inverted pendulum 9 American Control Conference Hyatt Regency Riverfront, St. Louis, MO, USA June -, 9 FrA.5 An homotopy method for exact tracking of nonlinear nonminimum phase systems: the example of the spherical inverted

More information

Inertial Game Dynamics

Inertial Game Dynamics ... Inertial Game Dynamics R. Laraki P. Mertikopoulos CNRS LAMSADE laboratory CNRS LIG laboratory ADGO'13 Playa Blanca, October 15, 2013 ... Motivation Main Idea: use second order tools to derive efficient

More information

FIXED POINT ITERATIONS

FIXED POINT ITERATIONS FIXED POINT ITERATIONS MARKUS GRASMAIR 1. Fixed Point Iteration for Non-linear Equations Our goal is the solution of an equation (1) F (x) = 0, where F : R n R n is a continuous vector valued mapping in

More information

Multivariable Calculus

Multivariable Calculus 2 Multivariable Calculus 2.1 Limits and Continuity Problem 2.1.1 (Fa94) Let the function f : R n R n satisfy the following two conditions: (i) f (K ) is compact whenever K is a compact subset of R n. (ii)

More information

EXISTENCE OF THREE WEAK SOLUTIONS FOR A QUASILINEAR DIRICHLET PROBLEM. Saeid Shokooh and Ghasem A. Afrouzi. 1. Introduction

EXISTENCE OF THREE WEAK SOLUTIONS FOR A QUASILINEAR DIRICHLET PROBLEM. Saeid Shokooh and Ghasem A. Afrouzi. 1. Introduction MATEMATIČKI VESNIK MATEMATIQKI VESNIK 69 4 (217 271 28 December 217 research paper originalni nauqni rad EXISTENCE OF THREE WEAK SOLUTIONS FOR A QUASILINEAR DIRICHLET PROBLEM Saeid Shokooh and Ghasem A.

More information

PH.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MATHEMATICS

PH.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MATHEMATICS UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY SPRING SEMESTER 207 Dept. of Civil and Environmental Engineering Structural Engineering, Mechanics and Materials NAME PH.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MATHEMATICS Problem

More information

THE INVERSE FUNCTION THEOREM

THE INVERSE FUNCTION THEOREM THE INVERSE FUNCTION THEOREM W. PATRICK HOOPER The implicit function theorem is the following result: Theorem 1. Let f be a C 1 function from a neighborhood of a point a R n into R n. Suppose A = Df(a)

More information

Modeling & Control of Hybrid Systems Chapter 4 Stability

Modeling & Control of Hybrid Systems Chapter 4 Stability Modeling & Control of Hybrid Systems Chapter 4 Stability Overview 1. Switched systems 2. Lyapunov theory for smooth and linear systems 3. Stability for any switching signal 4. Stability for given switching

More information

Math 5630: Iterative Methods for Systems of Equations Hung Phan, UMass Lowell March 22, 2018

Math 5630: Iterative Methods for Systems of Equations Hung Phan, UMass Lowell March 22, 2018 1 Linear Systems Math 5630: Iterative Methods for Systems of Equations Hung Phan, UMass Lowell March, 018 Consider the system 4x y + z = 7 4x 8y + z = 1 x + y + 5z = 15. We then obtain x = 1 4 (7 + y z)

More information

Deterministic Dynamic Programming

Deterministic Dynamic Programming Deterministic Dynamic Programming 1 Value Function Consider the following optimal control problem in Mayer s form: V (t 0, x 0 ) = inf u U J(t 1, x(t 1 )) (1) subject to ẋ(t) = f(t, x(t), u(t)), x(t 0

More information

8.1 Bifurcations of Equilibria

8.1 Bifurcations of Equilibria 1 81 Bifurcations of Equilibria Bifurcation theory studies qualitative changes in solutions as a parameter varies In general one could study the bifurcation theory of ODEs PDEs integro-differential equations

More information

The Minimum Speed for a Blocking Problem on the Half Plane

The Minimum Speed for a Blocking Problem on the Half Plane The Minimum Speed for a Blocking Problem on the Half Plane Alberto Bressan and Tao Wang Department of Mathematics, Penn State University University Park, Pa 16802, USA e-mails: bressan@mathpsuedu, wang

More information

Dynamic Blocking Problems for Models of Fire Propagation

Dynamic Blocking Problems for Models of Fire Propagation Dynamic Blocking Problems for Models of Fire Propagation Alberto Bressan Department of Mathematics, Penn State University bressan@math.psu.edu Alberto Bressan (Penn State) Dynamic Blocking Problems 1 /

More information

Linear Quadratic Zero-Sum Two-Person Differential Games

Linear Quadratic Zero-Sum Two-Person Differential Games Linear Quadratic Zero-Sum Two-Person Differential Games Pierre Bernhard To cite this version: Pierre Bernhard. Linear Quadratic Zero-Sum Two-Person Differential Games. Encyclopaedia of Systems and Control,

More information

B5.6 Nonlinear Systems

B5.6 Nonlinear Systems B5.6 Nonlinear Systems 4. Bifurcations Alain Goriely 2018 Mathematical Institute, University of Oxford Table of contents 1. Local bifurcations for vector fields 1.1 The problem 1.2 The extended centre

More information

Intersection Models and Nash Equilibria for Traffic Flow on Networks

Intersection Models and Nash Equilibria for Traffic Flow on Networks Intersection Models and Nash Equilibria for Traffic Flow on Networks Alberto Bressan Department of Mathematics, Penn State University bressan@math.psu.edu (Los Angeles, November 2015) Alberto Bressan (Penn

More information

Converse Lyapunov theorem and Input-to-State Stability

Converse Lyapunov theorem and Input-to-State Stability Converse Lyapunov theorem and Input-to-State Stability April 6, 2014 1 Converse Lyapunov theorem In the previous lecture, we have discussed few examples of nonlinear control systems and stability concepts

More information

Equilibria with a nontrivial nodal set and the dynamics of parabolic equations on symmetric domains

Equilibria with a nontrivial nodal set and the dynamics of parabolic equations on symmetric domains Equilibria with a nontrivial nodal set and the dynamics of parabolic equations on symmetric domains J. Földes Department of Mathematics, Univerité Libre de Bruxelles 1050 Brussels, Belgium P. Poláčik School

More information

Tilburg University. An equivalence result in linear-quadratic theory van den Broek, W.A.; Engwerda, Jacob; Schumacher, Hans. Published in: Automatica

Tilburg University. An equivalence result in linear-quadratic theory van den Broek, W.A.; Engwerda, Jacob; Schumacher, Hans. Published in: Automatica Tilburg University An equivalence result in linear-quadratic theory van den Broek, W.A.; Engwerda, Jacob; Schumacher, Hans Published in: Automatica Publication date: 2003 Link to publication Citation for

More information

Minimum-Phase Property of Nonlinear Systems in Terms of a Dissipation Inequality

Minimum-Phase Property of Nonlinear Systems in Terms of a Dissipation Inequality Minimum-Phase Property of Nonlinear Systems in Terms of a Dissipation Inequality Christian Ebenbauer Institute for Systems Theory in Engineering, University of Stuttgart, 70550 Stuttgart, Germany ce@ist.uni-stuttgart.de

More information

Robust control and applications in economic theory

Robust control and applications in economic theory Robust control and applications in economic theory In honour of Professor Emeritus Grigoris Kalogeropoulos on the occasion of his retirement A. N. Yannacopoulos Department of Statistics AUEB 24 May 2013

More information

Prof. Krstic Nonlinear Systems MAE281A Homework set 1 Linearization & phase portrait

Prof. Krstic Nonlinear Systems MAE281A Homework set 1 Linearization & phase portrait Prof. Krstic Nonlinear Systems MAE28A Homework set Linearization & phase portrait. For each of the following systems, find all equilibrium points and determine the type of each isolated equilibrium. Use

More information

Linear Hyperbolic Systems

Linear Hyperbolic Systems Linear Hyperbolic Systems Professor Dr E F Toro Laboratory of Applied Mathematics University of Trento, Italy eleuterio.toro@unitn.it http://www.ing.unitn.it/toro October 8, 2014 1 / 56 We study some basic

More information

A LOCALIZATION PROPERTY AT THE BOUNDARY FOR MONGE-AMPERE EQUATION

A LOCALIZATION PROPERTY AT THE BOUNDARY FOR MONGE-AMPERE EQUATION A LOCALIZATION PROPERTY AT THE BOUNDARY FOR MONGE-AMPERE EQUATION O. SAVIN. Introduction In this paper we study the geometry of the sections for solutions to the Monge- Ampere equation det D 2 u = f, u

More information

Optimal Control. Lecture 18. Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman Equation, Cont. John T. Wen. March 29, Ref: Bryson & Ho Chapter 4.

Optimal Control. Lecture 18. Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman Equation, Cont. John T. Wen. March 29, Ref: Bryson & Ho Chapter 4. Optimal Control Lecture 18 Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman Equation, Cont. John T. Wen Ref: Bryson & Ho Chapter 4. March 29, 2004 Outline Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation Iterative solution of HJB Equation

More information

Introduction to Nonlinear Control Lecture # 3 Time-Varying and Perturbed Systems

Introduction to Nonlinear Control Lecture # 3 Time-Varying and Perturbed Systems p. 1/5 Introduction to Nonlinear Control Lecture # 3 Time-Varying and Perturbed Systems p. 2/5 Time-varying Systems ẋ = f(t, x) f(t, x) is piecewise continuous in t and locally Lipschitz in x for all t

More information

On finite time BV blow-up for the p-system

On finite time BV blow-up for the p-system On finite time BV blow-up for the p-system Alberto Bressan ( ), Geng Chen ( ), and Qingtian Zhang ( ) (*) Department of Mathematics, Penn State University, (**) Department of Mathematics, University of

More information

EE363 homework 2 solutions

EE363 homework 2 solutions EE363 Prof. S. Boyd EE363 homework 2 solutions. Derivative of matrix inverse. Suppose that X : R R n n, and that X(t is invertible. Show that ( d d dt X(t = X(t dt X(t X(t. Hint: differentiate X(tX(t =

More information

An Exactly Solvable 3 Body Problem

An Exactly Solvable 3 Body Problem An Exactly Solvable 3 Body Problem The most famous n-body problem is one where particles interact by an inverse square-law force. However, there is a class of exactly solvable n-body problems in which

More information

Numerical Methods for Differential Equations Mathematical and Computational Tools

Numerical Methods for Differential Equations Mathematical and Computational Tools Numerical Methods for Differential Equations Mathematical and Computational Tools Gustaf Söderlind Numerical Analysis, Lund University Contents V4.16 Part 1. Vector norms, matrix norms and logarithmic

More information

Symmetric Matrices and Eigendecomposition

Symmetric Matrices and Eigendecomposition Symmetric Matrices and Eigendecomposition Robert M. Freund January, 2014 c 2014 Massachusetts Institute of Technology. All rights reserved. 1 2 1 Symmetric Matrices and Convexity of Quadratic Functions

More information

Input to state Stability

Input to state Stability Input to state Stability Mini course, Universität Stuttgart, November 2004 Lars Grüne, Mathematisches Institut, Universität Bayreuth Part IV: Applications ISS Consider with solutions ϕ(t, x, w) ẋ(t) =

More information

Course Summary Math 211

Course Summary Math 211 Course Summary Math 211 table of contents I. Functions of several variables. II. R n. III. Derivatives. IV. Taylor s Theorem. V. Differential Geometry. VI. Applications. 1. Best affine approximations.

More information

Chapter #4 EEE8086-EEE8115. Robust and Adaptive Control Systems

Chapter #4 EEE8086-EEE8115. Robust and Adaptive Control Systems Chapter #4 Robust and Adaptive Control Systems Nonlinear Dynamics.... Linear Combination.... Equilibrium points... 3 3. Linearisation... 5 4. Limit cycles... 3 5. Bifurcations... 4 6. Stability... 6 7.

More information

Xiyou Cheng Zhitao Zhang. 1. Introduction

Xiyou Cheng Zhitao Zhang. 1. Introduction Topological Methods in Nonlinear Analysis Journal of the Juliusz Schauder Center Volume 34, 2009, 267 277 EXISTENCE OF POSITIVE SOLUTIONS TO SYSTEMS OF NONLINEAR INTEGRAL OR DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS Xiyou

More information

Poincaré Map, Floquet Theory, and Stability of Periodic Orbits

Poincaré Map, Floquet Theory, and Stability of Periodic Orbits Poincaré Map, Floquet Theory, and Stability of Periodic Orbits CDS140A Lecturer: W.S. Koon Fall, 2006 1 Poincaré Maps Definition (Poincaré Map): Consider ẋ = f(x) with periodic solution x(t). Construct

More information

u n 2 4 u n 36 u n 1, n 1.

u n 2 4 u n 36 u n 1, n 1. Exercise 1 Let (u n ) be the sequence defined by Set v n = u n 1 x+ u n and f (x) = 4 x. 1. Solve the equations f (x) = 1 and f (x) =. u 0 = 0, n Z +, u n+1 = u n + 4 u n.. Prove that if u n < 1, then

More information

Introduction to Geometric Control

Introduction to Geometric Control Introduction to Geometric Control Relative Degree Consider the square (no of inputs = no of outputs = p) affine control system ẋ = f(x) + g(x)u = f(x) + [ g (x),, g p (x) ] u () h (x) y = h(x) = (2) h

More information

Stability in the sense of Lyapunov

Stability in the sense of Lyapunov CHAPTER 5 Stability in the sense of Lyapunov Stability is one of the most important properties characterizing a system s qualitative behavior. There are a number of stability concepts used in the study

More information

EN Nonlinear Control and Planning in Robotics Lecture 3: Stability February 4, 2015

EN Nonlinear Control and Planning in Robotics Lecture 3: Stability February 4, 2015 EN530.678 Nonlinear Control and Planning in Robotics Lecture 3: Stability February 4, 2015 Prof: Marin Kobilarov 0.1 Model prerequisites Consider ẋ = f(t, x). We will make the following basic assumptions

More information

Largest dual ellipsoids inscribed in dual cones

Largest dual ellipsoids inscribed in dual cones Largest dual ellipsoids inscribed in dual cones M. J. Todd June 23, 2005 Abstract Suppose x and s lie in the interiors of a cone K and its dual K respectively. We seek dual ellipsoidal norms such that

More information

Linearization at equilibrium points

Linearization at equilibrium points TMA4165 2007 Linearization at equilibrium points Harald Hanche-Olsen hanche@math.ntnu.no This note is about the behaviour of a nonlinear autonomous system ẋ = f (x) (where x(t) R n ) near an equilibrium

More information

Preliminary Exam 2018 Solutions to Morning Exam

Preliminary Exam 2018 Solutions to Morning Exam Preliminary Exam 28 Solutions to Morning Exam Part I. Solve four of the following five problems. Problem. Consider the series n 2 (n log n) and n 2 (n(log n)2 ). Show that one converges and one diverges

More information