ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME. Keywords: Corporate Governance, Agency, CEO Compensation JEL Classification Codes: C70, G30

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME. Keywords: Corporate Governance, Agency, CEO Compensation JEL Classification Codes: C70, G30"

Transcription

1 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME GALINA A. SCHWARTZ Abstract. We model costly interactions (contracts) between managers and investors. We suggest that globalization of production and favorable technology shock of the 1990s altered economic environment of manager-investor interactions. These changes exacerbate agency conflict due to the increased managerial gains from ex post reneging, and, simultaneously, decreased costs of managerial reneging. In this case, the managerial share of surplus increases at investor expense. Keywords: Corporate Governance, Agency, CEO Compensation JEL Classification Codes: C70, G30 1. Introduction Most business leaders aren t crooks, after all, and they understand that free markets and property rights require the rule of law to function. 1 The occurrence of the terms corporate fraud, accounting scandal and financial crime in the business sections of major news publications has recently noticeably increased, see Table I, p. 35. Increased frequencies of these words hint at an escalation of the agency problem. Typically, the involved parties (management and investors) have conflicting interests. Despite the inherent conflict, they are unanimous about the necessity to Date: This version: December Address: galka@citi.umich.edu. 1 From Review & Outlook (Editorial), CEOs in Handcuffs, Wall Street Journal; New York, N.Y.; Jul 26, 2002.

2 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 2 improve accounting and disclosure rules, oversight structure, etc. Related questions have been raised in Congress repeatedly, resulting in the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of The act established the Public Company Accounting Oversight Board, legislated enhancements of disclosure and audit practices, and raised fines and criminal penalties for violators. We relate the ongoing corporate scandals and shaken investor confidence with technology driven changes in the functioning of contractual arrangements. Greenspan, in his July Testimony to Congress (2002) eloquently summarizes the systemic problems of the economy: It is not that humans have become any more greedy than in generations past. It is that the avenues to express greed had grown so enormously. In our view, this is a non-technical expression by Greenspan of his concern with the principal-agent problem. Our model permits to name the avenues (parameters) which create managerial incentives to engage in legal and accounting violations. We model manager-investor interactions as the principal-agent problem, in which players can engage in costly ex post reneging of their ex ante contract. We suggest that managerial reneging manifests itself through various forms of managerial misconduct. We propose that recent corporate scandals are rooted in an exogenous (technology driven) shift of parameters characterizing production and contractual environments. We analyze the effects of parameter changes on equilibrium. We argue that recent changes in environment cause an increase in equilibrium managerial reneging. We interpret anecdotic evidence of increased scope of managerial misconduct as support to our inferences. We model manager-investor interactions as a game between parties, which make specific irreversible investments into a project (firm), and thereafter (ex post) divide the profit of the joint project according to an endogenously determined ownership allocation (surplus sharing). In such environments, the players have ex post incentives of reneging ex ante ownership allocation. In our model, ex post, players can unilaterally renege on ex ante contact at a cost. Player reneging costs are exogenous, increasing and concave in the magnitude of the requested adjustment of the ex ante contract: the higher this magnitude, the higher reneging expenses. We view reneging costs as characteristics of contractual institutions, with more advanced institutions characterized by higher costs. Ceteris paribus, higher costs create disincentives

3 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 3 for player reneging by lowering their expected reneging gains, hence, making their expected gains lower. With higher reneging costs, player ex ante property rights are more secure, and investment incentives less distorted. We show that higher reneging costs lead to lower equilibrium expenses on ex post reneging. The study of the manager-investor conflict and its effects on corporate performance was originated by Berle and Means (1932). The literature has been advanced by Jensen and Meckling (1976), who established a connection between ownership structure and corporate incentives. Modern contract theory literature addresses the agency conflict in different economic environments. This literature aims to resolve the agency problem stemming from separation of ownership (investor) and control (manager). It is concerned with maximizing investor returns (or social surplus) in specific environments, see reviews by Holmstrom and Tirole (1989), and a comprehensive coverage in Laffont and Martimort (2002). 2 For a contract theory perspective on the issues of corporate governance, see Tirole (2001). 3 The corporate governance literature catering macro-level implications was surveyed by Shleifer and Vishny (1997), and La Porta et. al. (2000). They conclude that legal protection of investors and concentration of ownership are complementary approaches to governance, but do not provide theoretical foundations for the conclusion. We address the question of micro-foundations, and achieve results agreeable with their inferences. Our model is consistent with the stylized fact that improved investor and management legal protection is favorable for investment incentives. We prove that investment incentives improve with higher reneging costs, which we see as reflecting more advanced contractual institutions. Only a fraction of agency literature takes Demsetz (1983) perspective of endogenous ownership rights. The Demsetz and Lehn (1985) paper can be considered a starting point of empirical investigations of ownership endogeneity. Their framework was extended by Himmelberg et. al. (1999), who demonstrate that both managerial ownership and performance are endogenously determined by exogenous (and only partly observed) changes in the firm s contracting environment. Palia (2001), builds 2 Tirole (1999) review provides more technically demanding and open-ended perspective with suggestive directions for future research. 3 The literature bearing on the principal-agent problem is far too extensive for reviewing, or even listing it here. For recent developments see Review of Economic Studies, (1999), Vol. 66, Issue I. Numerous references to the literature will be found throughout the paper though we make no claim to completeness.

4 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 4 on this literature. 4 His paper compellingly demonstrates that CEO compensation is indeed endogenous. Ownership endogeneity implies that differences in ownership structure should not affect firm value if production technology and contractual environment are controlled. Our model gives theoretical foundations for these findings, because our game yields endogenous surplus division between management and investors. Agency models usually assume that surplus is evenly divided between the players (Nash bargaining), thus, ignoring the empirical data, which confirms ownership endogeneity. 5 The folklore view of financial scholars on managerial misconduct is surprisingly uniform. According to this view, management always cheats investors (and always will), whereas the promulgation of these cheatings by newspapers is sensation driven. Like natural disasters, such as hurricanes and earthquakes, managerial misconduct happens regularly, and makes its way to the headlines. Consequently, the current situation is a minor statistical aberration, and should not be taken for an indication of systemic problems. We challenge this prevailing view, which discounts the anecdotal evidence of increased managerial cheating as a minor deviation of no theoretical importance. Indeed, we explain the current evidence by technology driven shift in production and contractual environments. Let us informally present the dynamics of manager-investor interactions implied by the folklore view. The management continuously looks for holes in the contractual system to exploit and enrich itself. Similarly, the investors continuously monitor these self-serving managerial activities, aiming to expose and fix the holes. The system is self-tuning. If the management finds a hole and acquires substantial extra wealth, investors experience a decrease in their wealth, which prompts them to search for the hole, and fix it. To sum up, the recurrence of managerial misconduct stays, only specific misdemeanors change with time. We completely agree that managerial misconduct is a recurring phenomenon. We are interested in determinants of frequency and scope of such a misconduct. We suggest that recently increased frequency and scope of corporate crime is real, 4 Palia (2001) works with panel data, and uses the fixed effects methodology to control for firm specific effects. He has separate equations for CEO compensation and firm value (using Tobin s Q as a proxy), and simultaneously estimates this system of equations. 5 See Anderlini and Felli (1997) for a setup with explicitly endogenous ownership.

5 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 5 and reflects an increase of managerial equilibrium share of surplus at the investors expense. We advocate that favorable technology shock of the 1990s and globalization of industrial production created ample holes in contractual system, i.e. the possibilities to exploit its imperfections. The present-day contractual environment alters parties costs of ex post reneging advantageously for management. We identify five factors contributing to an increase of managerial reneging: advancement of production technology, decrease of player outside options (investment returns and executive compensation), and two factors related with the contractual system. The latter factors reflect the changes of contractual capabilities, induced by a favorable technology shock of the 1990s and globalization of industrial production, both of which turned out to be unfavorable for ownership security. Firstly, internationalization of production makes it more costly to prove a breach of contract, and, once it is proven, to receive a compensation. The latter statement is an expression of the fact that legal systems of advanced economies (U.S., Germany, Japan, etc.) are more mature than the international legal system, which features cross-country contractual incompatibilities, worsened by weak international enforcement mechanisms, see Staiger (1995), La Porta et. al. (1999), and Carpio et. al. (2001) for review. Secondly, technological changes alter information processing, and amplify CEOs informational advantage over investors. Simultaneously, the globalization of production and advancement of the financial system give the CEOs new means to utilize their informational advantage, thus, exacerbating the agency conflict. These factors weaken the contractual system, and affect both parties, CEO and investor, albeit differently. The resulting effect is an increase in managerial informational advantage over investors. To summarize our contribution, we identify the factors affecting the firm s contractual environment, and formulate testable predictions, connecting production technology and ownership structure with firm value and performance. From our model, the managerial ownership share increases with weaker contractual institutions, more advanced production technology, and when managerial reneging costs decrease relative to the investor ones. Consistent with data, our results predict lower aggregate profits when contractual institutions are weak (La Porta et. al. (1999)), or investor protection is low (Daines (2001)), and an increase in the managerial ownership share when technology is more advanced (Holderness et. al. (1999)). We

6 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 6 suggest that our model provides micro-foundations for the empirical evidence of endogenous ownership, and gives refutable predictions, which fit existing data. The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 a stage game is presented and its equilibrium properties outlined. In Sections 3 and 4, comparative analysis is provided, with Section 3 focusing on parameters of contractual institutions, and Section 4 on technology. In Section 5, modified games are introduced and analyzed. The discussion and the concluding remark are presented in Section 6. Proofs and technical details are relegated to Appendices. 2. Model We start with a game between two players, a CEO (manager) and an investor (owner), and denote the corresponding game by Γ. The game Γ is the game of complete information with the following order of moves. First, one of the players proposes a contract which allocates player ownership shares for a jointly implemented project; i.e., it allocates the project s surplus share x [0, 1] to the CEO, and (1 x) to the investor. We consider the games with x chosen by either player, and let Γ 1 denote the game in which the CEO chooses x, and Γ 2 the game in which the investor chooses x. In addition, we consider a benchmark the game Γ p in which ex ante ownership allocation is chosen by a social planner, whose objective is to maximize total society surplus, which equals player surplus and their reneging costs. To simplify the notation we drop the subscript i when possible. Second, the CEO and the investor simultaneously and independently choose to dedicate to the joint project irreversible effort q 1 and investment q 2, which are expressed in monetary terms. Each player has an outside option, the CEO an alternative job with a fixed return ω to his effort, and the investor an alternative project with a fixed investment return ξ. We let the joint CEO-investor project s net value be equal to µp (F (q)) ωq 1 ξq 2, q = (q 1, q 2 ), F (q) = min(q 1, q 2 ), (1) where a constant µ > 0 characterizes technology, and µp (F (q)) is the probability of successful operation of the project (for example, reliable operation of the project s product), when player actions are q. We call the actions q 1 and q 2 investments. We borrowed this production function and its interpretation from Varian (2002), who refers to it as the prototype case of weakest link. In this case, the value of the

7 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 7 project depends on the minimum investment (aka Leontieff production function). 6 One also may interpret the values of ω and ξ as reflective of the degree of market competition for the CEOs and investors, with lower ω and ξ corresponding to higher competition in the respective market. Third, after the project has been undertaken, each player can unilaterally change the ex ante contract (i.e., renege) with the respective actions denoted by r and s through costly ex post reneging. The players choose r and s simultaneously and independently. Their ex post ownership shares are respectively equal to t and (1 t) for the CEO and the investor, where t is defined as: t = x + r s. We call a player s ability to alter his share reneging, and his expenses on modifying ownership shares reneging costs, emphasizing the direct player actions to alter the shares. The word reneging is somewhat narrow. Our definition of reneging costs includes any expenses on activities intended to modify player surplus shares. Reneging expenses include legal, political, bureaucratic, and, possibly, penalty costs for breach of contract. From our definition, reneging expenses and to ex post contractual expenses (i.e. transaction costs) are the synonyms. Consider CEO interactions with the Board of Directors. Then, the constants β and γ proxy player costs of ex post contractual adjustment. The data provides that CEO reneging costs decrease with (i.e., β decreases) with the length of CEO tenure, and increase with the number of board members and frequency of board meetings, see Hermalin and Weisbach (1988), (1991). Each player, the CEO and the investor, maximizes his net gain from the project, denoted by W (a) and Π(a), respectively, and equal to the value of his ownership share net of reneging expenses and the outside option return: W (a) = tφ(q) βb(r) ωq 1, a = (x, r, s, q), β 0, ω 0, (2) Π(a) = (1 t)φ(q) γb(s) ξq 2, Φ(q) =µp (F (q)), γ 0, ξ 0, (3) where max(β, γ) > 0 and max(ω, ξ) > 0. The vector a A, where A is the set of action profiles of the game Γ. The constants β and γ reflect that player reneging costs; and β γ indicates that their costs differ. In our game, ex post reneging is a 6 See Kremer (1993) for demonstration of wide applicability of this production function.

8 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 8 mechanism with which the players change their ex ante contract, and we interpret their reneging costs βb(r) and γb(s) as their ex post transaction costs. From equation (1), neither player can implement the project alone. We assume that the function µp (F ) evaluated at zero exceeds the outside options. 7 The function P is continuous, concave and three times continuously differentiable for F (0, ); the function B is continuous, convex and three times continuously differentiable for v (0, ), and is zero for v < 0: P (F ) > 0, P (F ) < 0, P (F ) < 0 : F (0, ), lim µp (F ) > min(ω, ξ), F 0 B (v) > 0, B (v) > 0, B (v) 0 : v (0, ), B(v) 0 : v < 0. The condition B(v) 0 for v < 0 means that each player can reduce his ownership share at no cost. To ease presenting the proofs, we impose P 0 and B 0, and lim B(v) = 0 and lim v 0 v 0 B (v) = 0, which entails zero fixed cost of reneging. We will allow nonzero fixed-cost of reneging in Section 5. For the given functions P and B, the game Γ i has 5 parameters: µ, β, γ and ξ, ω: Γ i = Γ i (o), where o = (µ, β, γ, ξ, ω), and i = 1, 2 or p correspond to the CEO s, the investor s or the social planner choice of an ex ante contract (i.e., x). To sum up, the game Γ i has three stages. First, player i chooses x. Second, the players simultaneously and independently choose q 1 and q 2. Third, after investments are sunk, the players simultaneously and independently choose r and s, and the project surplus is divided between the CEO and investor, with respective ownership shares t and (1 t). In our model the CEO and the investor differ only by parameter values. Both players make irreversible investments into the project, and share its surplus ex post. Our specification is similar to a standard principal-agent problem, but we emphasize player similarity, which constitutes a departure from the standard perspective. 7 Absent reneging, the project would be implemented if property allocation gives each player a positive ownership share, i.e., for any t (0, 1) investments are positive.

9 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 9 In our model, CEO-investor relationship is analogous to a relationship of two monopolists, each of whom maximizes his share of profit from relationship-specific investment in a jointly manufactured product. We assume players to coordinate on Pareto efficient subgame perfect Nash equilibrium, and use such an equilibrium as the solution concept for our game. We denote equilibrium outcomes and payoffs by the superscript. Definition 1. Let ˆΓ i denote the game Γ i, in which ex ante and ex post contracts are restricted to be identical: x t. 8 In the game ˆΓ i the players are committed to their ex ante contract. The game ˆΓ i is identical to the game Γ i, in which high sunk costs of reneging make non-reneging optimal for the players. Theorem 1. An equilibrium of the game ˆΓ i exists, and is unique. Proof. See Appendix. Let ˆ denote equilibrium outcomes and payoffs in the games ˆΓ i, with i = 1, 2 or p. From equation (1) and player objectives (equations (2) and (3)), in any equilibrium q 1 = q 2. We will interpret the statement q I < q II component-wise. For the intuition behind the proof of Theorem 1, notice that in the subgame ˆΓ i (x), which starts after any x, best responses q 1 and q 2 are unique. We show that for each i, ownership assignment ˆt i, at which player i payoff is the highest exists and is unique. Clearly, the equilibrium of the game ˆΓ i depends on the identity of the player who chooses surplus sharing. Naturally, the equilibrium playoff is higher for the player who chooses x. Proposition 1. In the equilibria of the games ˆΓ i investment distortion is smaller when ownership contract is proposed by the player with a higher outside option: ˆq 1 ˆq 2 if ω ξ. Proof. See Appendix. Proposition 1 relates the size of investment distortion with player outside options, see Figure 1, p. 36. Proposition 1 and Theorem 1, in the game ˆΓ i with (i = 1 or 2), efficiency is achievable in the equilibrium, only when the outside option of the player who does not choose the ownership allocation is zero. 8 For example, non-reneging is optimal, when sunk cost of reneging is equal to (or exceeds) the project value in the game Γ p with ω and ξ approaching zero.

10 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 10 Next, we study the game Γ. Without loss of generality, and reflective of the current managerial fraud and accounting violations we impose β γ, which implies that reneging is cheaper for the CEO than for the investor. following theorem establishes the existence of equilibrium in the game Γ. The Theorem 2. An equilibrium of the game Γ i exists. Each player investment and surplus are bounded from above by his equilibrium surplus in ˆΓ i. Equilibria of the games Γ i with i = 1, 2 are unique. Proof. See Appendix. To improve investment efficiency, two issues should be addressed, which can be called ex ante efficiency and ex post efficiency. The latter issue concerns with how to induce ex ante ownership allocation optimally, and, the former player adherence to the ex ante contract. Ex post reneging makes player commitment to the ex ante contract incomplete, and causes underinvestment due to the divergence of ex ante and ex post incentives. Our main interest is ex post contractual efficiency. We focus on investment suboptimality driven by ex post reneging. Our treatment of ex ante efficiency is primitive: clearly, the games Γ i with i = 1, 2 are extremes, each game gives full advantage to the player who proposes an ex ante contract. We admit that take it or leave it offer about surplus sharing (which is exactly how ex ante ownership is allocated in our game) is unrealistic. It is more appropriate to model ex ante ownership allocation as a bargaining game between the players (similar to Rubinstein (1982) bargaining model). One would expect bargaining mechanism to reduce investment suboptimality. Remark 1. The game Γ p has two equilibria, which differ by CEO shares only: and inequalities are strict if β γ. q p ˆq p, and t p 2 ˆt p t p 1, Proof. Follows from the proofs of Theorems 1 and 2. Remark 1 establishes that in the equilibrium of the game Γ p, the CEO s ex post ownership share is higher than his ex ante share. This occurs because reneging is cheaper for the CEO, and his optimal share adjustment is higher than for the

11 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 11 investor. From Remark 1, the firm value peaks at CEO equilibrium share of the game Γ p, see Figure 2, p. 37. Proposition 2. In the equilibria of the games Γ i we have: x t and q i q p, and t 2 ˆt 2, ˆt 1 t 1 and if ω ξ, q 1 q 2, where the inequalities are strict if β γ. From Proposition 2 in the equilibria of the games Γ i, CEO ex post share is higher than his ex ante share, see Figures 3 and 4, pp. 38 and 39. One can distinguish two sources of investment distortions in the games Γ i. The first group is rooted in investment market and property allocation imperfections. It relates to market and technology structure (player outside options, monopoly power and production function); and ownership structure (the choice ownership allocation); the resulting investment distortions mimic the distortions of the game ˆΓ i. We focus on the second group of distortions, stemming from insecure property rights due to positive transaction costs. These distortions are driven by player reneging, which causes underinvestment due to divergence of ex ante and ex post incentives to invest (x t ), and due to the suboptimal choice of ex ante share (t 2 ˆt 2 or ˆt 1 t 1 ) a result of player concern by the magnitude of their reneging expenses. Remark 2. For any fixed q, the CEO s and the investor s optimal reneging expenses are unique and respectively decreasing with β and γ. Proof. Follows from the proof of Theorem 2. Theorem 2, Propositions 1 and 2 and Remark 2 permit us to investigate how the equilibria of the games Γ i change with parameters. As we suggest below, the observed increase of CEO reneging follows from the present-day technological and contractual parameters. 3. Effects of Contractual Institutions As we suggested, player reneging costs proxy their contractual costs, or more precisely, ex post contractual costs, such as legal or settlement resolution expenses, or fines and penalty costs, etc. Clearly, these costs are dependant on contractual environment, and on relative player capacity to function in this environment. Clearly,

12 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 12 the difference of β and γ reflects that player resources differ. These resources could be relative information available to them, their relative ability to process this information; and financial, legal and organizational resources at their disposal. Technology and contractual system are interdependent.thus, exogenous technological shift likely affects the parameters β and γ. Proposition 3. Let the games Γ(o I ) and Γ(o II ) differ only in β, and let β I < β II. Then, the equilibrium of Γ(o II ) Pareto dominates the equilibrium of Γ(o I ). In equilibrium, the CEO s share is lower, and project value higher in Γ(o II ) than in Γ(o I ). Proof. See Appendix. When β I > β II the CEO is better off, despite the fact that his equilibrium share is lower. Proposition 3 is in tune with the findings of Daines (2001), whose evidence is consistent with the theory that Delaware corporate law improves firm value. Using the firm s Q as an estimate of firm value, he finds that Delaware firms are worth significantly more than similar firms incorporated elsewhere. Daines suggests that state competition to sell corporate charters and legal rules produces a winning state, Delaware, whose law appears to be more valuable than that of other states. He argues that investor willingness to pay more for Delaware firms and Delaware s increasing market share are also inconsistent with claims that state corporate law is uniform or trivial. Proposition 4. Let the games Γ(o I ) and Γ(o II ) differ only in γ, and let γ I < γ II. Then, the equilibrium of the game Γ(o I ) Pareto dominates the equilibrium of Γ(o II ). In equilibrium, the CEO s share is lower, and project value higher in Γ(o I ) than in Γ(o II ). Proof. See Appendix. From Proposition 3, player equilibrium payoffs in the game Γ increase with β. Interestingly, from Proposition 4, an increase in γ has a reverse effect on player equilibrium payoffs. The intuition of this result is transparent if β and γ are interpreted as reflecting player relative bargaining powers, with lower β corresponding to higher bargaining power. From β γ, investor bargaining power is lower than the CEO s, and, from Proposition 4, further reduction of investor bargaining power adversely affects both players. From Proposition 3, equilibrium surplus increases

13 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 13 with β. The surplus is the highest when β reaches γ, and player reneging costs get equal. At the first glance, Propositions 3 and 4 should not hold simultaneously. In fact, Proposition 4 does not hold in the game Γ p : it holds when i = 1 or 2 only. The intuition is based at the proof of Theorem 2. Consider the subgame Γ x of the game Γ, in which x is fixed. At every fixed CEO s share, or at every game Γ x, investor reneging expenses decrease with γ, see Remark 2. If social planner employs the same equilibrium share in the gameγ(o II ) as in the game Γ(o I ), the surplus would be higher in the game Γ(o II ), because for any x, the ex post distortion [distance between t and x] is smaller, and ex ante share in the game Γ p is optimal. From the proof of Proposition 4, in the games Γ(o II ) with i = 1 or 2, the distortion stemming from ex post share suboptimality is smaller and the distortion stemming from higher reneging expenses due to a lower γ is bigger, than in the game Γ(o II ) but the latter effect dominates. 4. Comparative Analysis Next, we investigate how parameters of the game Γ i affect its equilibrium. To simplify the exposition, focus on the game Γ 1, and drop the superscript 1, thus denoting it by Γ. We interpret µ as a characteristic of technology. Higher constants µ, ξ, or ω imply, respectively, more advanced technology, or higher investor or CEO outside option. We compare the equilibria of the games Γ which differ by technologies or outside options. Proposition 5. Let the games Γ(o I ) and Γ(o II ) differ only in µ, and let µ I > µ II. Then, in equilibrium, the CEO s share and project value is higher, and investments lower in Γ(o I ) than Γ(o II ). Proof. Analogous to Proposition 4. Proposition 5 is in tune with data. Consider, for example, the technological advancement of the 1990 s: the inferences of Proposition 5 are robustly supported by corporate profits and stock market data, and, clearly, by CEO compensation data, see Holderness (1999).

14 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 14 Proposition 5 implies that with technology advancement the equilibrium project value, the CEO s share, and reneging expenses increase. From Proposition 5, reneging expenses increase as technology improves, so does the surplus loss from player commitment conflict. Therefore, the importance of contracts increases with technology advancement. To mitigate this increase of reneging expenses, technology improvement should be accompanied by the improvement of contractual institutions. We suggest that the current corporate scandals reflect the necessity to strengthen contractual institutions. Proposition 6. Let the games Γ(o I ) and Γ(o II ) differ only in ω, and let ω I < ω II. Then, in equilibrium, investments are higher and the CEO s share lower in Γ(o I ) than Γ(o II ). Proof. Analogous to Proposition 4. From Proposition 6, lower CEO s outside option makes higher effort optimal for him. Thus, when the CEO s outside option decreases, equilibrium investment increases, which leads to higher reneging expenses of both players. We suggest that the CEO s outside option ω can be instrumented by the level of executive compensation, which has dramatically increased during the 20th century. Thus, Proposition 6 permits to rationalize Holderness et. al. (1999) empirical observation of a raise in managerial ownership from 13 percent for the universe of exchange-listed corporations in 1935 (the earliest year for which such data exist) to 21 percent in Proposition 7. Let the games Γ(o I ) and Γ(o II ) differ only in ξ, and let ξ I < ξ II. Then, in equilibrium, investments and the CEO s share are higher in Γ(o I ) than Γ(o II ). Proof. Analogous to Proposition 4. In general, data provides that the players outside options decrease in recessions. Thus, from Propositions 6 and 7, in recessions, when worthy projects are scarce, investment in the actually undertaken projects increases, which causes an increase in player reneging expenses. Interestingly, from Propositions 6 and 7, a lower outside option of one of the players not only benefits the other player, but also makes the equilibrium project value higher.

15 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 15 Comment about Propositions The conditions of Propositions 3-7 are restrictive. They let us compare the games in which only one parameter differs, yet the parameters of the game Γ are likely endogenous. In reality, these parameters may change simultaneously. For example, historically, technology advancement (an increase in µ) has been accompanied by the advancement of the contractual mechanism (an increase in β and γ); similarly, historically, player outside options improve with technology as well. These empirical regularities clearly violate the condition of Propositions 3-7 that all other parameters are fixed. 5. Modified Games Non-Zero Sunk Cost of Reneging Our results generalize to the case of non-zero transaction costs. Let Γ i b denote the game Γ i, in which the reneging cost function has a sunk cost. Let B b be the reneging cost function in the game Γ i b : B b (v) = b + B(v) : v (0, ), and b 0 is a constant. Then, b is a sunk cost of reneging: lim B b(v) = b 0. v 0 Let denote investor gain from choosing reneging over non reneging when investment in the game Γ i is equal to q i : = pφ(q ) γb(s ), Remark 3. For any b < the equilibrium of the game Γ i b is the same as of Γi. 9 Proof. Follows from the proofs of Theorems 1 and 2. The Game T Definition 2. Let T i b denote the game Γi b, with an additional requirement: reneging in the game T i occurs only if at least one player announces his intent to renege ex ante contract. 9 Schwartz (2000) shows that Theorem 2 holds for any b [0, ).

16 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 16 If such an announcement occurs, players choose their ex post actions simultaneously and independently, and the game T b coincides with Γ b. In the absence of the announcement, the surplus is divided between the players in accordance with the ex ante contract. Then, in the equilibrium of the game T b player reneging expenses are zero, and the equilibria of the games T b and ˆΓ coincide. In the equilibrium of the game T reneging occurs only when the CEO s net gain from reneging is positive, while in the equilibrium of the game Γ b reneging could occur even when both players lose from reneging. Theorem 3. An equilibrium of the game T i b exists, and is unique. For any finite β and γ, there exists b 0 such that the equilibrium of T i b is the same as in ˆΓ i if b b, and as in Γ i b if b < b. Proof. See Appendix (Follows from the proofs of Theorems 1 and 2). From Theorem 2, in the game Γ i investment distortion disappears when β = γ and player outside options approach zero, but their equilibrium payoffs are below their game ˆΓ i payoffs due to the dissipation of surplus on reneging expenses. From Theorem 3, when equilibrium reneging expenses in the game T b are zero, players may achieve their equilibrium payoffs of the game ˆΓ in the equilibrium of T b. In this case, player payoffs are unaffected by imperfections of contractual system, and player equilibrium surplus is the same as with zero transaction costs, i.e., as in the game ˆΓ. Remark 4. If β = γ the equilibrium of the game T does not depend on player reneging costs. Proof. Follows from the proofs of Theorems 1 3. From Remark 4, when player equilibrium reneging expenses are equal, even poorly working contractual institutions (low β) permit to sustain the game ˆΓ equilibrium in the game T. From Theorem 3 and Remarks 2 and 4, for any fixed sunk cost b, the equilibria of the games ˆΓ and T are more likely to coincide when player reneging costs are similar. Thus, we infer that player similarity mitigates contractual inefficiencies. There are two possibilities to make the gap between β and γ smaller: by an increase of β or by a decrease of γ. From Propositions 3 and 4, and Remark 2, making β higher is more attractive. We regard the game T to be more realistic than Γ. It is likely that players would

17 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 17 switch to the game T, because it Pareto dominates Γ. Next, we suggest another modification of the game Γ, which permits players to achieve equilibrium payoffs even higher than in the game T. The Game G Definition 3. Let G i denote the game derived from the game Γ i b (or Ti b ) by subtracting the investor s reneging costs from player objectives. From Definition 3, player objectives in the game G i are: W (a) = tφ(q) D(r, s) ωq 1, D(r, s) = βb(r) γb(s), Π(a) = (1 t)φ(q) ξq 2, a = (x, r, s, q), Φ(q) =P (F (q)), where the function D denotes the CEO s costs of reneging in the game G i. The investor in the game G i cannot renege. In all other respects the game G i is identical to the game Γ i (or T i ). The game G i has the following order of moves: first, player i chooses x, second, players simultaneously and independently make their investments q 1 and q 2, and third (ex post) the CEO chooses r and s. The project s surplus is divided between the players, with the CEO s share equal to t, and investor share to (t 1). From Definition 3 and the proofs of Theorems 1 3, we have: Theorem 4. An equilibrium of the game G i exists, and is unique. In the equilibrium of the game G i, each player receives at least his game T i payoff. Comparative analysis of the games G and T which differ in one of the parameters is analogous to the analysis for the game Γ. 6. Discussion Technology and contractual institutions are hardly independent. The factors contributing to pressures on contractual mechanism in present-day global economy include incompatibilities of contract law between the countries and deficiencies of international law and its enforcement (reviewed in Staiger (1995)), and difficulties of contract enforcement in the countries with poor legal systems, to where production was relocated due to the increase in foreign direct investment (reviewed in La Porta et. al. (1999), see also Carpio et. al. (2001)). To sum up, firstly, internationalization of production makes it more costly to prove a breach of contract and receive a compensation once it is proven. This inference is just a restatement of the fact that legal systems of advanced economies are

18 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 18 more mature than the international legal system, which cross-country contractual incompatibilities are exacerbated by weak international enforcement mechanisms. Perhaps, these developments result in downward pressure on β, and, accordingly, translate into worsening of investments incentives (Proposition 3). In this case, the current economic slowdown may be rooted in contractual system weakening. Secondly, technological changes have markedly altered information processing, and have increased CEOs informational advantage over investors. Simultaneously, globalization of production and advancement of financial system provide the CEOs with new means to utilize their informational advantage. The overall effect of these changes is increased disparity between β and γ due to a decrease in β, not accompanied by a matching decrease in γ. We show that with costly contracts, the hold-up problem is less acute when players reneging costs are similar (Theorem 3 and Remark 4). We investigate how technological and contractual parameters affect ex ante ownership contract, incentives to invest, and ex post incentives to renege the ex ante contract. Currently observed increase of player reneging (corporate fraud and accounting violations), can be attributed to several economic parameters. We show that the increased frequency and scope of corporate crime can be driven by advancement of production technology (an increase in µ), decrease of outside options (a decrease in investment returns (ξ) and executive compensation (ω)), and effects of technological changes on contractual mechanism (decrease in β and γ, and increase in their disparity), see Propositions 5, 6-7, and 3 6, respectively. Making specific conclusions about the underlying changes of parameters causing an increase of CEO reneging requires further theoretical modelling and data analysis. One need not address the specifics of parameter changes to infer from the pattern of CEO reneging that investment distortions worsened. Our results affirm the importance of well-functioning contractual institutions for investment efficiency in current economic environment, and call for attention to the issue of ownership endogeneity in the analysis of corporate financial and production decisions. Concluding Remark The data decisively shows that in countries with weak contact enforcement institutions, investment is suboptimal, see La Porta et. al. (1999), (2000) reviews. This

19 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 19 suboptimality reflects current production technology, with its dependence on contractual institutions. We suggest that recent managerial misconduct reflects managerial ex post activities to attain more favorable surplus sharing, as a consequence of technology change of the 1990s. The ideas expressed herein, agree with empirical results of Himmelberg et. al. (1999), Demsetz and Villalonga (2001), and Palia (2001) who find no statistically significant relation between ownership structure and firm performance, if ownership is made multi-dimensional and also is treated as an endogenous variable. Galina A. Schwartz University of Michigan Ann Arbor, MI, Address: galka@citi.umich.edu URL:

20 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 20 References 1. Anderlini, Luca and Felli, Leonardo, 1997, Costly Coasian Contracts, CARESS Working paper, Bailey, Warren, Li, Haitao, Mao, Connie X. and Zhong, Rui, 2003, Regulation Fair Disclosure and Earnings Information: Market, Analyst, and Corporate Responses, The Journal of Finance, 58 (6), Berle, Adolf. A and Means, Gardiner C., 1932, The Modern Corporation and Private Property, Macmillan: New York. 4. Bolton, Patrick, Scheinkman, Jose and Xiong, Wei, 2003, Executive Compensation and Short-termist Behavior in Speculative Markets, URL: pbolton/aerceobsx6.dvi.pdf 5. Carpio, Gerard, Honohan, Patrick, and Stiglitz, Joseph (eds.), 2001, Financial Liberalization. How Far, How Fast?. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. 6. Coase, Ronald, 1960, The Problem of Social Cost, Journal of Law and Economics 3, Daines, Robert, 2001, Does Delaware Law Improve Firm Value?, Journal of Financial Economics 62:3, Demsetz, Harold, 1983, The Structure of Ownership and the Theory of the Firm. Journal of Law and Economics 26, Demsetz, Harold and Lehn, Kenneth, 1985, The Structure of Corporate Ownership: Causes and Consequences. Journal of Political Economy 93, Demsetz, Harold, and Villalonga, Belén, 2001, Ownership Structure and Corporate Performance. Journal of Corporate Finance 7:3, Greenspan, Alan. Testimony to Congress, July, Hermalin, Benjamin, E. and Weisbach, Michael, S., 1988, The Determinants of Board Composition. Rand Journal of Economics 19, Hermalin, Benjamin, E. and Weisbach, Michael, S., 1991, The Effects of Board Composition and Direct Incentives on Firm Performance. Financial Management, Winter, Himmelberg, Charles P., Hubbard, R. Glenn, and Palia, Darius, 1999, Understanding the Determinants of Managerial Ownership and the Link Between Ownership and Performance. Journal of Financial Economics 53:3, Holderness, Clifford G., Kroszner, Randall S,. and Sheehan, Dennis P., 1999, Were the Good Old Days That Good? Changes in Managerial Stock Ownership Since the Great Depression. Journal of Finance 54:2, Holmstrom, Bengt and Tirole, Jean, The Theory of the Firm, in Schmalensee R. and Willig R.D., eds. Handbook of Industrial Organisation, Vol. I, North-Holland: Amsterdam. 17. Hubbard, Glenn and Palia, Darius, 1995, Benefits of Control, Managerial Ownership, and the Stock Returns of Acquiring Firms. Rand Journal of Economics 39:1, Jensen, Michael C., and William H. Meckling, 1976, Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3,

21 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME Laffont, Jean-Jacques and Martimort, David, 2002, The Theory of Incentives: The Principal- Agent Model, Princeton University Press. 20. McConnell, J.J. and Servaes, H. 1990, Additional Evidence on Equity Ownership and Corporate Value. Journal of Financial Economics 27, Mørck, Randall, Shleifer, Andrei and Vishny, Robert W., 1988, Management Ownership and Market Valuation. Journal of Financial Economics 20, Kremer, Michael, 1993, The O-Ring Theory of Economic Development. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108:3, La Porta, Rafael, Lopez-De-Silanes, F., and Shleifer, Andrei, 1999, Corporate Ownership Around the World. Journal of Finance 54:2, La Porta, Rafael, Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, Andrei, and Vishny, Robert, 2000, Investor Protection and Corporate Governance. Journal of Financial Economics 58, Osborne, Martin J. and Rubinstein, Ariel, 1994, A Course in Game Theory. The MIT Press: Cambridge, Massachusetts. 26. Review and Outlook (Editorial), CEOs in Handcuffs, Wall Street Journal, New York, N.Y., July 26, Palia, Darius, 2001, The Endogeneity of Managerial Compensation in Firm Valuation: A Solution, Review of Financial Studies, 2001, vol. 14, issue 3, Rubinstein, Ariel, 1982, Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model. Econometrica 50, Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, Public Law , 107-th Congress, July 30, Schwartz, Galina, 2000, Contract Incompleteness, Contractual Enforcement and Bureaucracies, Princeton University Ph.D. Dissertation. 31. Schwarz, Galina, 2003, Repeated Interactions Under Costly Contractual Enforcement, in preparation, URL: Shleifer, Andrei and Vishny, Robert, 1997, A Survey of Corporate Governance Journal of Finance 52, Staiger, Robert, 1995, International Rules and Institutions for Trade Policy. in Grossman, G. M. and Rogoff, K., eds., Handbook of International Economics, Vol. III, North-Holland: Amsterdam. 34. Tirole, Jean, 1999, Incomplete Contracts: Where Do We Stand. Econometrica 67:4, Tirole, Jean, 2001, Corporate Governance. Econometrica 69:1, Varian, Hal, 2002, System Reliability and Free Riding. Berkeley University Workshop on Economics and Information Security, May, Proofs Proof of Theorem 1: To simplify, we say that a function is defined on a closed interval, when the function is actually well defined only on the respective open interval. At the boundary points the left or the right limit of the function is considered.

22 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 22 Lemma 1. Consider the following system of equations for t [0, ť]: and the following system of equations for t [ť, 1]: tφ (q) ω = 0, q = (q 1, q 2 ) (4) (1 t)φ (q) ξ 0 (5) q 1 = q 2 0, (6) tφ (q) ω 0, q = (q 1, q 2 ) (7) (1 t)φ (q) ξ = 0, (8) q 1 = q 2 0, (9) Then, there exists a unique solution ˆq(t) = (ˆq(t), ˆq(t)) for any t [0, ť], of the system (4) (6), and a unique solution ˆq(t) = (ˆq(t), ˆq(t)) of the system (7) (9) for any t [ť, 1]. The function ˆq is continuous and twice continuously differentiable for any for any t ť, where ť = ω ω + ξ, and Φ (ˆq(ť)) = ω + ξ, (10) and ˆq(t) is a solution of the following equation: { Φ ω t : t [0, ť] (ˆq(t)) = : t [ť, 1] ξ (1 t). (11) Proof of Lemma 1: The derivation is straightforward, also see Varian (2002). Step 2. Let ˆΓ i (t), with i = 1, 2, or p, denote a subgame of the game ˆΓ i which starts with a fixed t [0, 1]. There exists an equilibrium of the game ˆΓ i (t). The equilibrium is unique and player investments are ˆq(t) = (ˆq(t), ˆq(t)), where ˆq(t) is a solution of the system of equations (4) (6). Proof of Step 2: Let q i (t) = ( q i 1 (t), qi 2 (t)) denote equilibrium investment in the game ˆΓ i (t). Since it is suboptimal for either player to invest more than the other player invests, in any equilibrium q i 1 (t) = qi 1 (t), and equation (6) holds in any equilibrium. From player optimization and from Pareto considerations, equations (4) and (5) or (7) and (8) hold in equilibrium as well. From Lemma 1, the systems (4) (6) and (7) (9) always have a unique solution. Thus, q i (t) = ˆq(t) and Step 2 is proven. Step 3: There exists a unique equilibrium of the game ˆΓ p, and equilibrium actions are (ˆq p, ˆt p ), where ˆt p = ť.

23 ENDOGENEITY OF CEO COMPENSATION AND CORPORATE CRIME 23 Proof of Step 3: From Steps 1 and 2 social planner objective in the game ˆΓ p can be written as: T (t) = max [Φ(ˆq(t)) (ω + ξ)ˆq(t)]. t [0,1] Since T (0) = T (1) = 0, in any equilibrium of the game ˆΓ p we have t (0, 1) because T (t) > 0 for any t (0, 1). From the social planner optimization in any equilibrium: A(t) dˆq(t) dt = 0, where Â(t) = [ Φ (ˆq(t)) (ω + ξ) ]. (12) From differentiation of equation (11) with respect to t: dˆq(t) ω t = 2 Φ (ˆq(t)) = [Φ (ˆq(t))] 2 ωφ (ˆq(t)) dt ξ (1 t) 2 Φ (ˆq(t)) = [Φ (ˆq(t))] 2 ξφ (ˆq(t)) > 0 : t [0, ť) < 0 : t (ť, 1] Thus, the derivative dˆq(t) dt 0, and in any equilibrium of the game ˆΓ p :, (13) Φ (ˆq(t)) ω + ξ = 0 (14) which holds at t = ť only, see equation (10). Thus, the game ˆΓ p has a unique equilibrium, and Step 3 is proven. Step 4. There exist a unique equilibrium in each game ˆΓ i, with i = 1, 2, and we have: ˆt 2 ˆt p ˆt 1 and ˆq i = ˆq(ˆt i ) ˆq p. (15) Proof of Step 4. Our proof is by contradiction. Let the outcome õ with actions ( t, q), t < ť be an equilibrium of the game ˆΓ 1. From Lemma 1, there exists an outcome ŏ, with actions ( t, q), in which q = q and t 1 > ť. Since the CEO s payoff in ŏ is higher than in õ, the outcome õ cannot be an equilibrium, and equation (15) is proven. From Lemma 1 and equation (15), player objectives in the games ˆΓ 1 and ˆΓ 2 can be written as: ˆΓ 1 : ˆΓ 2 : ˆV (t) = max [tφ(ˆq(t)) ωˆq(t)], (16) t [ť,1] ˆΠ(t) = max [(1 t)φ(ˆq(t)) ξˆq(t)]. (17) t [0,ť]

SURPLUS SHARING WITH A TWO-STAGE MECHANISM. By Todd R. Kaplan and David Wettstein 1. Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel. 1.

SURPLUS SHARING WITH A TWO-STAGE MECHANISM. By Todd R. Kaplan and David Wettstein 1. Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel. 1. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW Vol. 41, No. 2, May 2000 SURPLUS SHARING WITH A TWO-STAGE MECHANISM By Todd R. Kaplan and David Wettstein 1 Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel In this article we consider

More information

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College 2015 Course Overview 1. Bargaining 2. Hidden information and self-selection Optimal contracting with hidden information

More information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers September 6, 016 ONLINE APPENDIX In this Appendix we present in full additional results and extensions which are only mentioned in the paper. In the exposition

More information

A New and Robust Subgame Perfect Equilibrium in a model of Triadic Power Relations *

A New and Robust Subgame Perfect Equilibrium in a model of Triadic Power Relations * A New and Robust Subgame Perfect Equilibrium in a model of Triadic Power Relations * by Magnus Hatlebakk ** Department of Economics, University of Bergen Abstract: We present a new subgame perfect equilibrium

More information

The Role of Pre-trial Settlement in International Trade Disputes (1)

The Role of Pre-trial Settlement in International Trade Disputes (1) 183 The Role of Pre-trial Settlement in International Trade Disputes (1) Jee-Hyeong Park To analyze the role of pre-trial settlement in international trade dispute resolutions, this paper develops a simple

More information

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Yongmin Chen and David Sappington University of Colorado and University of Florida February 2016 1 / 32 1. Introduction Patent policy: patent protection

More information

Volume 29, Issue 3. Strategic delegation and market competitiveness

Volume 29, Issue 3. Strategic delegation and market competitiveness Volume 29, Issue Strategic delegation and market competitiveness Caterina Colombo Università di Ferrara Alessandra Chirco Università del Salento Marcella Scrimitore Università del Salento Abstract Within

More information

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2 EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2 Leonardo Felli 32L.G.06 19 January 2015 Moral Hazard: Consider the contractual relationship between two agents (a principal and an agent) The principal

More information

Martin Gregor IES, Charles University. Abstract

Martin Gregor IES, Charles University. Abstract On the strategic non-complementarity of complements Martin Gregor IES, Charles University Abstract This paper examines the equilibrium provision of a public good if the private monetary contributions of

More information

Capital, Institutions and Urban Growth Systems

Capital, Institutions and Urban Growth Systems Capital, Institutions and Urban Growth Systems Robert Huggins Centre for Economic Geography, School of Planning and Geography, Cardiff University Divergent Cities Conference, University of Cambridge, Cambridge

More information

Introduction. 1 University of Pennsylvania, Wharton Finance Department, Steinberg Hall-Dietrich Hall, 3620

Introduction. 1 University of Pennsylvania, Wharton Finance Department, Steinberg Hall-Dietrich Hall, 3620 May 16, 2006 Philip Bond 1 Are cheap talk and hard evidence both needed in the courtroom? Abstract: In a recent paper, Bull and Watson (2004) present a formal model of verifiability in which cheap messages

More information

Repeated bargaining. Shiran Rachmilevitch. February 16, Abstract

Repeated bargaining. Shiran Rachmilevitch. February 16, Abstract Repeated bargaining Shiran Rachmilevitch February 16, 2017 Abstract Two symmetric players bargain over an infinite stream of pies. There is one exogenously given pie in every period, whose size is stochastic,

More information

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition, Policy and Technological Progress

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition, Policy and Technological Progress 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition, Policy and Technological Progress Daron Acemoglu MIT September 15, 2016. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 15, 2016.

More information

Why Do Firms Conduct Bi-Sourcing? 1

Why Do Firms Conduct Bi-Sourcing? 1 Why Do Firms Conduct Bi-Sourcing? 1 Julan Du Chinese University of Hong Kong Yi Lu University of Hong Kong Zhigang Tao University of Hong Kong Abstract In acquiring the same intermediate inputs, a firm

More information

Patience and Ultimatum in Bargaining

Patience and Ultimatum in Bargaining Patience and Ultimatum in Bargaining Björn Segendorff Department of Economics Stockholm School of Economics PO Box 6501 SE-113 83STOCKHOLM SWEDEN SSE/EFI Working Paper Series in Economics and Finance No

More information

On the Pareto Efficiency of a Socially Optimal Mechanism for Monopoly Regulation

On the Pareto Efficiency of a Socially Optimal Mechanism for Monopoly Regulation MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive On the Pareto Efficiency of a Socially Optimal Mechanism for Monopoly Regulation Ismail Saglam Ipek University 4 May 2016 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/71090/

More information

Appendix of Homophily in Peer Groups The Costly Information Case

Appendix of Homophily in Peer Groups The Costly Information Case Appendix of Homophily in Peer Groups The Costly Information Case Mariagiovanna Baccara Leeat Yariv August 19, 2012 1 Introduction In this Appendix we study the information sharing application analyzed

More information

Supplementary Materials for. Forecast Dispersion in Finite-Player Forecasting Games. March 10, 2017

Supplementary Materials for. Forecast Dispersion in Finite-Player Forecasting Games. March 10, 2017 Supplementary Materials for Forecast Dispersion in Finite-Player Forecasting Games Jin Yeub Kim Myungkyu Shim March 10, 017 Abstract In Online Appendix A, we examine the conditions under which dispersion

More information

Implementation of the Ordinal Shapley Value for a three-agent economy 1

Implementation of the Ordinal Shapley Value for a three-agent economy 1 Implementation of the Ordinal Shapley Value for a three-agent economy 1 David Pérez-Castrillo 2 Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona David Wettstein 3 Ben-Gurion University of the Negev April 2005 1 We gratefully

More information

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with Increasing Returns to Scale Abhijit Sengupta and Yair Tauman February 6, 24 Abstract We consider a Cournot Oligopoly market of firms possessing increasing

More information

Pseudo-Wealth and Consumption Fluctuations

Pseudo-Wealth and Consumption Fluctuations Pseudo-Wealth and Consumption Fluctuations Banque de France Martin Guzman (Columbia-UBA) Joseph Stiglitz (Columbia) April 4, 2017 Motivation 1 Analytical puzzle from the perspective of DSGE models: Physical

More information

Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance.

Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance. Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance. Laura Veldkamp New York University, Stern School of Business, CEPR and NBER Spring 2009 1 Veldkamp What information consumes is rather obvious: It consumes

More information

On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E.

On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E. Tilburg University On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E. Publication date: 1997 Link to publication General rights Copyright and

More information

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction Susumu Sato July 9, 2018 I study a monopoly regulation in the setting where consumers can engage in demand-reducing investments. I first

More information

Discussion Papers in Economics

Discussion Papers in Economics Discussion Papers in Economics No. 10/11 A General Equilibrium Corporate Finance Theorem for Incomplete Markets: A Special Case By Pascal Stiefenhofer, University of York Department of Economics and Related

More information

Voluntary Leadership in Teams and the Leadership Paradox

Voluntary Leadership in Teams and the Leadership Paradox Voluntary Leadership in Teams and the Leadership Paradox Susanne Mayer 1 and Christian Hilbe 2 1 Institute for Social Policy, Department Socioeconomics, Vienna University of Economics and Business, Nordbergstraße

More information

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion Matthew Gentzkow and Emir Kamenica Stanford University and University of Chicago December 2015 Abstract Rothschild and Stiglitz (1970) represent random

More information

Controlling versus enabling Online appendix

Controlling versus enabling Online appendix Controlling versus enabling Online appendix Andrei Hagiu and Julian Wright September, 017 Section 1 shows the sense in which Proposition 1 and in Section 4 of the main paper hold in a much more general

More information

Supplement Jul FINANCE&ECONOMICS. ( benchmark) (analytical tools) , (Coase Theorem), : (Modigliani - Miller Theorem) ( Kenneth Ar2 ,,,,,

Supplement Jul FINANCE&ECONOMICS. ( benchmark) (analytical tools) , (Coase Theorem), : (Modigliani - Miller Theorem) ( Kenneth Ar2 ,,,,, FINANCE&ECONOMICS [ ] : (perspective) ( reference) 20 ( benchmark) (analytical tools) - (Arrow - Debreu Theorem) (Coase Theorem) - : (Modigliani - Miller Theorem) ( Kenneth Ar2 row) : ( ) ( ) ( ( ) ) ;

More information

Introduction: Asymmetric Information and the Coase Theorem

Introduction: Asymmetric Information and the Coase Theorem BGPE Intensive Course: Contracts and Asymmetric Information Introduction: Asymmetric Information and the Coase Theorem Anke Kessler Anke Kessler p. 1/?? Introduction standard neoclassical economic theory

More information

Investor s Increased Shareholding due to Entrepreneur Manager Collusion

Investor s Increased Shareholding due to Entrepreneur Manager Collusion Investor s Increased Shareholding due to Entrepreneur Manager Collusion Özgün Atasoy Sabancı University Mehmet Barlo Sabancı University August, 2007 Abstract This study presents an investor/entrepreneur

More information

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM Discussion Papers in Economics Discussion Paper No. 0/06 CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY by Indraneel Dasgupta July 00 DP 0/06 ISSN 1360-438 UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRICE AND CAPACITY COMPETITION. Daron Acemoglu Kostas Bimpikis Asuman Ozdaglar

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRICE AND CAPACITY COMPETITION. Daron Acemoglu Kostas Bimpikis Asuman Ozdaglar NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRICE AND CAPACITY COMPETITION Daron Acemoglu Kostas Bimpikis Asuman Ozdaglar Working Paper 12804 http://www.nber.org/papers/w12804 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

Defending Multiple Terrorist Targets

Defending Multiple Terrorist Targets Defending Multiple Terrorist Targets Sanghoon Lee May 1, 2006 Abstract This paper analyzes a situation in which multiple targets are exposed to a potential terrorist threat. The probability of an attack

More information

The Non-Existence of Representative Agents

The Non-Existence of Representative Agents The Non-Existence of Representative Agents Matthew O. Jackson and Leeat Yariv November 2015 Abstract We characterize environments in which there exists a representative agent: an agent who inherits the

More information

Endogenous Games and Mechanisms: Side Payments Among Players

Endogenous Games and Mechanisms: Side Payments Among Players Review of Economic Studies (2005) 72, 543 566 0034-6527/05/00220543$02.00 c 2005 The Review of Economic Studies Limited Endogenous Games and Mechanisms: Side Payments Among Players MATTHEW O. JACKSON and

More information

Combinatorial Agency of Threshold Functions

Combinatorial Agency of Threshold Functions Combinatorial Agency of Threshold Functions Shaili Jain 1 and David C. Parkes 2 1 Yale University, New Haven, CT shaili.jain@yale.edu 2 Harvard University, Cambridge, MA parkes@eecs.harvard.edu Abstract.

More information

Introduction to Game Theory

Introduction to Game Theory COMP323 Introduction to Computational Game Theory Introduction to Game Theory Paul G. Spirakis Department of Computer Science University of Liverpool Paul G. Spirakis (U. Liverpool) Introduction to Game

More information

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation Daron Acemoglu MIT September 19, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition and Innovation September 19, 2011. 1 / 51 Competition and Innovation

More information

Price and Capacity Competition

Price and Capacity Competition Price and Capacity Competition Daron Acemoglu, Kostas Bimpikis, and Asuman Ozdaglar October 9, 2007 Abstract We study the efficiency of oligopoly equilibria in a model where firms compete over capacities

More information

Fairness and Redistribution: Response

Fairness and Redistribution: Response Fairness and Redistribution: Response By ALBERTO ALESINA, GEORGE-MARIOS ANGELETOS, AND GUIDO COZZI This paper responds to the comment of Di Tella and Dubra (211). We first clarify that the model of Alesina

More information

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion Matthew Gentzkow and Emir Kamenica Stanford University and University of Chicago September 2015 Abstract Rothschild and Stiglitz (1970) introduce a

More information

Lecture Notes: Industrial Organization Joe Chen 1. The Structure Conduct Performance (SCP) paradigm:

Lecture Notes: Industrial Organization Joe Chen 1. The Structure Conduct Performance (SCP) paradigm: Joe Chen 1 1 Introduction 1.1 The Beginning Joe Bain and Edward Mason (the Harvard tradition): Empirical in nature (loose theories) The Structure Conduct Performance (SCP) paradigm: Structure (market structure):

More information

NASH IMPLEMENTATION USING SIMPLE MECHANISMS WITHOUT UNDESIRABLE MIXED-STRATEGY EQUILIBRIA

NASH IMPLEMENTATION USING SIMPLE MECHANISMS WITHOUT UNDESIRABLE MIXED-STRATEGY EQUILIBRIA NASH IMPLEMENTATION USING SIMPLE MECHANISMS WITHOUT UNDESIRABLE MIXED-STRATEGY EQUILIBRIA MARIA GOLTSMAN Abstract. This note shows that, in separable environments, any monotonic social choice function

More information

Strongly rational expectations equilibria with endogenous acquisition of information

Strongly rational expectations equilibria with endogenous acquisition of information Strongly rational expectations equilibria with endogenous acquisition of information Gabriel Desgranges Maik Heinemann 9 February 004 This paper analyzes conditions for existence of a strongly rational

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer Social learning and bargaining (axiomatic approach)

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer Social learning and bargaining (axiomatic approach) UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2015 Social learning and bargaining (axiomatic approach) Block 4 Jul 31 and Aug 1, 2015 Auction results Herd behavior and

More information

Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!?

Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!? Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!? Mathias Erlei Clausthal University of Technology Julius-Albert-Str. 2, 38678 Clausthal-Zellerfeld, Germany email: m.erlei@tu-clausthal.de Abstract This

More information

Ex Post Cheap Talk : Value of Information and Value of Signals

Ex Post Cheap Talk : Value of Information and Value of Signals Ex Post Cheap Talk : Value of Information and Value of Signals Liping Tang Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh PA 15213, USA Abstract. Crawford and Sobel s Cheap Talk model [1] describes an information

More information

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann Dirk Bergemann Department of Economics Yale University Microeconomic Theory (50b) Problem Set 0. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann 4/5/4 This problem set is due on Tuesday, 4//4..

More information

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Hiroaki Ino Institute of Intellectual Property and Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo [Preliminary

More information

Introduction to Game Theory

Introduction to Game Theory Introduction to Game Theory Part 2. Dynamic games of complete information Chapter 2. Two-stage games of complete but imperfect information Ciclo Profissional 2 o Semestre / 2011 Graduação em Ciências Econômicas

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012 The time limit for this exam is 4 hours. It has four sections. Each section includes two questions. You are

More information

A Solution to the Problem of Externalities When Agents Are Well-Informed

A Solution to the Problem of Externalities When Agents Are Well-Informed A Solution to the Problem of Externalities When Agents Are Well-Informed Hal R. Varian. The American Economic Review, Vol. 84, No. 5 (Dec., 1994), pp. 1278-1293 Introduction There is a unilateral externality

More information

SELECTION OF MARKOV EQUILIBRIUM IN A DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY WITH PRODUCTION TO ORDER. Milan Horniaček 1

SELECTION OF MARKOV EQUILIBRIUM IN A DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY WITH PRODUCTION TO ORDER. Milan Horniaček 1 SELECTION OF MARKOV EQUILIBRIUM IN A DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY WITH PRODUCTION TO ORDER Milan Horniaček 1 CERGE-EI, Charles University and Academy of Sciences of Czech Republic, Prague We use the requirement of

More information

Strategic Properties of Heterogeneous Serial Cost Sharing

Strategic Properties of Heterogeneous Serial Cost Sharing Strategic Properties of Heterogeneous Serial Cost Sharing Eric J. Friedman Department of Economics, Rutgers University New Brunswick, NJ 08903. January 27, 2000 Abstract We show that serial cost sharing

More information

Two-sided investments and matching with multi-dimensional cost types and attributes

Two-sided investments and matching with multi-dimensional cost types and attributes Two-sided investments and matching with multi-dimensional cost types and attributes Deniz Dizdar 1 1 Department of Economics, University of Montréal September 15, 2014 1/33 Investments and matching 2/33

More information

Bilateral Trading in Divisible Double Auctions

Bilateral Trading in Divisible Double Auctions Bilateral Trading in Divisible Double Auctions Songzi Du Haoxiang Zhu March, 014 Preliminary and Incomplete. Comments Welcome Abstract We study bilateral trading between two bidders in a divisible double

More information

Title: The Castle on the Hill. Author: David K. Levine. Department of Economics UCLA. Los Angeles, CA phone/fax

Title: The Castle on the Hill. Author: David K. Levine. Department of Economics UCLA. Los Angeles, CA phone/fax Title: The Castle on the Hill Author: David K. Levine Department of Economics UCLA Los Angeles, CA 90095 phone/fax 310-825-3810 email dlevine@ucla.edu Proposed Running Head: Castle on the Hill Forthcoming:

More information

Arm s Length Relationships without Moral Hazard

Arm s Length Relationships without Moral Hazard 09- Research Group: Industrial Organization November 6, 2009 Arm s Length Relationships without Moral Hazard JACQUES CRÉMER Arm s length relationships without moral hazard Jacques Crémer Toulouse School

More information

Efficient Exploitation Of Waste Heat: Coordination Management For A Waste Heat Utilization Project From Economic Perspectives

Efficient Exploitation Of Waste Heat: Coordination Management For A Waste Heat Utilization Project From Economic Perspectives Efficient Exploitation Of Waste Heat: Coordination Management For A Waste Heat Utilization Project From Economic Perspectives Nguyen Huu Phuc a,, Yoshiyuki Matsuura a, Motonobu Kubo a a Graduate School

More information

Continuity in Mechanism Design without Transfers 1

Continuity in Mechanism Design without Transfers 1 Continuity in Mechanism Design without Transfers 1 David Martimort and Aggey Semenov 3 This Version: March 16, 006 Abstract: We adopt a mechanism design approach to model communication between a principal

More information

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract Entry under an Information-Gathering onopoly Alex Barrachina* June 2016 Abstract The effects of information-gathering activities on a basic entry model with asymmetric information are analyzed. In the

More information

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods 5. Externalities and Public Goods 5. Externalities and Public Goods Externalities Welfare properties of Walrasian Equilibria rely on the hidden assumption of private goods: the consumption of the good

More information

Price and Capacity Competition

Price and Capacity Competition Price and Capacity Competition Daron Acemoglu a, Kostas Bimpikis b Asuman Ozdaglar c a Department of Economics, MIT, Cambridge, MA b Operations Research Center, MIT, Cambridge, MA c Department of Electrical

More information

Mixed duopolies with advance production

Mixed duopolies with advance production Mixed duopolies with advance production Tamás László Balogh Department of Economic Analysis and Business Informatics, University of Debrecen and Attila Tasnádi MTA-BCE Lendület Strategic Interactions Research

More information

Political Economy of Institutions and Development: Problem Set 1. Due Date: Thursday, February 23, in class.

Political Economy of Institutions and Development: Problem Set 1. Due Date: Thursday, February 23, in class. Political Economy of Institutions and Development: 14.773 Problem Set 1 Due Date: Thursday, February 23, in class. Answer Questions 1-3. handed in. The other two questions are for practice and are not

More information

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ryoji Ohdoi Dept. of Industrial Engineering and Economics, Tokyo Tech This lecture note is mainly based on Ch. 8 of Acemoglu

More information

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 27 October, 207 Pareto Efficient Allocation Recall the following result: Result An allocation x is Pareto-efficient if and only

More information

Preliminary Results on Social Learning with Partial Observations

Preliminary Results on Social Learning with Partial Observations Preliminary Results on Social Learning with Partial Observations Ilan Lobel, Daron Acemoglu, Munther Dahleh and Asuman Ozdaglar ABSTRACT We study a model of social learning with partial observations from

More information

5. Externalities and Public Goods

5. Externalities and Public Goods 5. Externalities and Public Goods Welfare properties of Walrasian Equilibria rely on the hidden assumption of private goods: the consumption of the good by one person has no effect on other people s utility,

More information

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly Daisuke Hirata Graduate School of Economics, University of Tokyo March 2008 Abstract This paper investigates a simultaneous move capacity constrained price competition

More information

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Home exam: ECON 5200 / ECON 9200 Exam period: 5.12.2011, at 09:00 9.12.2011, at 12:30 (unless other individual deadline granted) Grades are given: 3.01.2012.

More information

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam Summer 2013 Microeconomics Qualifying Exam There are 72 points possible on this exam, 36 points each for Prof. Lozada s questions and Prof. Kiefer s questions. However, Prof. Lozada s questions are weighted

More information

Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure: Slides

Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure: Slides Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure: Slides Alexander Tarasov University of Munich Summer 2012 Alexander Tarasov (University of Munich) Antràs (2003) Summer 2012 1 / 34 Motivation For the United States,

More information

Expertise and Complexity in the Social and Engineering Sciences: An Extended Sen s Theorem

Expertise and Complexity in the Social and Engineering Sciences: An Extended Sen s Theorem Expertise and Complexity in the Social and Engineering Sciences: An Extended Sen s Theorem Donald G. Saari Institute for Mathematical Behavioral Sciences University of California Irvine, CA 92617-5100

More information

Moral Hazard: Part 1. April 9, 2018

Moral Hazard: Part 1. April 9, 2018 Moral Hazard: Part 1 April 9, 2018 Introduction In a standard moral hazard problem, the agent A is characterized by only one type. As with adverse selection, the principal P wants to engage in an economic

More information

Graduate Microeconomics II Lecture 5: Cheap Talk. Patrick Legros

Graduate Microeconomics II Lecture 5: Cheap Talk. Patrick Legros Graduate Microeconomics II Lecture 5: Cheap Talk Patrick Legros 1 / 35 Outline Cheap talk 2 / 35 Outline Cheap talk Crawford-Sobel Welfare 3 / 35 Outline Cheap talk Crawford-Sobel Welfare Partially Verifiable

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

CPB Discussion Paper 261. Optimal bail-out policies under renegotiation. Michiel Bijlsma Gijsbert Zwart

CPB Discussion Paper 261. Optimal bail-out policies under renegotiation. Michiel Bijlsma Gijsbert Zwart CPB Discussion Paper 261 Optimal bail-out policies under renegotiation Michiel Bijlsma Gijsbert Zwart Optimal bail-out policies under renegotiation Michiel Bijlsma and Gijsbert Zwart December 5, 2013

More information

Mortenson Pissarides Model

Mortenson Pissarides Model Mortenson Pissarides Model Prof. Lutz Hendricks Econ720 November 22, 2017 1 / 47 Mortenson / Pissarides Model Search models are popular in many contexts: labor markets, monetary theory, etc. They are distinguished

More information

Sharing a Polluted River

Sharing a Polluted River Sharing a Polluted River Debing Ni School of Management University of Electronic Science and Technology of China Chengdu, Sichuan, P.R. China, 610054 Yuntong Wang Department of Economics University of

More information

CSR as a bribe to a government

CSR as a bribe to a government CSR as a bribe to a government Taku Masuda 1 Kosuke Hirose 2 PRELIMINARY. ANY COMMENTS APPRECIATED. 1 Introduction The rationale behind partial privatization of public enterprises or social responsibility

More information

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206)

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206) Theory Field Exam Summer 2011 Instructions You must complete two of the four areas (the areas being (I) contract theory, (II) game theory A, (III) game theory B, and (IV) psychology & economics). Be sure

More information

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KYOTO INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH Discussion Paper No.992 Intertemporal efficiency does not imply a common price forecast: a leading example Shurojit Chatterji, Atsushi

More information

Pledge-and-Review Bargaining

Pledge-and-Review Bargaining Pledge-and-Review Bargaining Bård Harstad University of Oslo August 2018 Harstad (University of Oslo) Pledge-and-Review Bargaining August 2018 1 / 29 Introduction -The pledge-and-review strategy is completely

More information

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion Matthew Gentzkow and Emir Kamenica Stanford University and University of Chicago January 2016 Consider a situation where one person, call him Sender,

More information

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IN ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT Strategic Incentives for Managers in Contests Matthias Kräkel Discussion Paper No. 01-08 GERMAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION - GEABA

More information

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 16-1, 231 253 (2015) Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * Hongkun Ma School of Economics, Shandong University,

More information

A Folk Theorem for Contract Games with Multiple Principals and Agents

A Folk Theorem for Contract Games with Multiple Principals and Agents A Folk Theorem for Contract Games with Multiple Principals and Agents Siyang Xiong March 27, 2013 Abstract We fully characterize the set of deteristic equilibrium allocations in a competing contract game

More information

1. The General Linear-Quadratic Framework

1. The General Linear-Quadratic Framework ECO 37 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 009 Notes for lectures Incentives for Effort - Multi-Dimensional Cases Here we consider moral hazard problems in the principal-agent framewor, restricting the

More information

Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them.

Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them. What is market design? Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them. This requires different tools and ideas than neoclassical economics, which

More information

The Benefit of the Start-Up Handicap. Manfred Dix* and Ram Orzach** February 7, Preliminary Draft

The Benefit of the Start-Up Handicap. Manfred Dix* and Ram Orzach** February 7, Preliminary Draft The Benefit of the Start-Up Handicap Manfred Dix* and Ram Orzach** February 7, 2006 Preliminary Draft Abstract: Why do prestigious companies choose to fund new product development by venture capital instead

More information

Government Outsourcing: Public Contracting with Private Monopoly

Government Outsourcing: Public Contracting with Private Monopoly Government Outsourcing: Public Contracting with Private Monopoly Emmanuelle Auriol University of Toulouse I Pierre M. Picard University of Manchester Introduction The paper studies private participation

More information

Costly Expertise. Dino Gerardi and Leeat Yariv yz. Current Version: December, 2007

Costly Expertise. Dino Gerardi and Leeat Yariv yz. Current Version: December, 2007 Costly Expertise Dino Gerardi and Leeat Yariv yz Current Version: December, 007 In many environments expertise is costly. Costs can manifest themselves in numerous ways, ranging from the time that is required

More information

Non-Enforceability of Trade Treaties and Investment Distortions. 1

Non-Enforceability of Trade Treaties and Investment Distortions. 1 Non-Enforceability of Trade Treaties and Investment Distortions. 1 Galina A. Schwartz 2 University of Michigan Ann Arbor, MI, 48103-4943 Abstract The paper considers incentives for irreversible investments

More information

General idea. Firms can use competition between agents for. We mainly focus on incentives. 1 incentive and. 2 selection purposes 3 / 101

General idea. Firms can use competition between agents for. We mainly focus on incentives. 1 incentive and. 2 selection purposes 3 / 101 3 Tournaments 3.1 Motivation General idea Firms can use competition between agents for 1 incentive and 2 selection purposes We mainly focus on incentives 3 / 101 Main characteristics Agents fulll similar

More information

Hotelling s Beach with Linear and Quadratic Transportation Costs: Existence of Pure Strategy Equilibria

Hotelling s Beach with Linear and Quadratic Transportation Costs: Existence of Pure Strategy Equilibria appearing in Australian Economic Papers, vol. 46(1) Hotelling s Beach with Linear and Quadratic Transportation Costs: Existence of Pure Strategy Equilibria Alain Egli University of Bern Abstract In Hotelling

More information

Public Provision of Scarce Resources when Preferences are Non-Linear

Public Provision of Scarce Resources when Preferences are Non-Linear Public Provision of Scarce Resources when Preferences are Non-Linear Katharina Huesmann February 13, 2017 Abstract This paper considers the problem of assigning an indivisible good of limited availability

More information

Second Welfare Theorem

Second Welfare Theorem Second Welfare Theorem Econ 2100 Fall 2015 Lecture 18, November 2 Outline 1 Second Welfare Theorem From Last Class We want to state a prove a theorem that says that any Pareto optimal allocation is (part

More information

Symmetric Separating Equilibria in English Auctions 1

Symmetric Separating Equilibria in English Auctions 1 Games and Economic Behavior 38, 19 27 22 doi:116 game21879, available online at http: wwwidealibrarycom on Symmetric Separating Equilibria in English Auctions 1 Sushil Bihchandani 2 Anderson Graduate School

More information