Business Cycle Dynamics under Rational Inattention

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Business Cycle Dynamics under Rational Inattention"

Transcription

1 Business Cycle Dynamics under Rational Inattention Bartosz Maćkowiak European Central Bank and CEPR Mirko Wiederholt Northwestern University First draft: June 27 This draft: October 28 Preliminary Version Abstract This paper develops a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model with rational inattention Decision-makers have limited attention and choose the optimal allocation of their attention We study the implications of rational inattention for business cycle dynamics For example, we study how rational inattention affects the impulse responses of prices and quantities to monetary policy, aggregate technology and micro-level shocks The impulse responses under rational inattention have several properties of empirical impulse response functions, eg, (i) prices respond slowly to monetary policy shocks, (ii) prices respond faster to aggregate technology shocks, and (iii) prices respond very fast to disaggregate shocks In addition, profit losses due to deviations of the actual price from the profit-maximizing price are an order of magnitude smaller than in the Calvo model that generates the same real effects We thank for helpful comments: Paco Buera, Larry Christiano, James Costain, Martin Eichenbaum, Christian Hellwig, Giorgio Primiceri and seminar as well as conference participants at Bank of Canada, Chicago Fed, Columbia, DePaul, European Central Bank, European University Institute, ESSIM 28, MIT, Minneapolis Fed, NBER Summer Institute 28, North American Winter Meeting of the Econometric Society 28, Riksbank, SED 28, Stony Brook and UCSD The views expressed in this paper are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the European Central Bank bartoszmackowiak@ecbint and m-wiederholt@northwesternedu

2 Introduction This paper develops a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model with rational inattention We model the idea that agents cannot attend perfectly to all available information Therefore, the mapping between economic conditions and the price and quantity decisions taken by agents is not perfect Decision-makers make mistakes However, decision-makers try to minimize these mistakes The economy consists of households, firms and a government Households supply differentiated types of labor, consume a variety of goods, and hold nominal government bonds Firms supply differentiated goods that are produced with the differentiated types of labor The central bank sets the nominal interest rate according to a Taylor rule Households take wage setting and consumption decisions Firms take price setting and factor mix decisions In the model, prices and wages are physically fully flexible The only source of slow adjustment is decision-makers limited attention We compute the impulse responses of all variables to monetary policy shocks, aggregate technology shocks and micro-level shocks under rational inattention Rational inattention means that decision-makers have limited attention and that they choose how to allocate their attention Following Sims (23), we model attention as a flow of information, and we model limited attention as a constraint on the flow of information We let agents decide how to allocate the information flow For example, agents decide how to allocate their attention across their different decision problems Furthermore, agents decide how closely they attend to the different factors that may affect an optimal decision We find that rational inattention by decision-makers in firms has the following implications First, for our parameter values, rational inattention by decision-makers in firms implies that the impulse response of the price level to monetary policy shocks resembles the impulse response in a Calvo model with an average price duration of 75 months At the same time, prices respond fairly quickly to aggregate technology shocks and almost perfectly to micro-level shocks The reason is the optimal allocation of attention Decision-makers in firms decide to pay little attention to monetary policy, about twice as much attention to aggregate technology, and a lot of attention to firm-specific conditions Therefore, prices respond slowly to monetary policy shocks, but fairly quickly to aggregate technology shocks, 2

3 and almost perfectly to micro-level shocks Second, losses in profits due to deviations of the actual price from the profit-maximizing price are an order of magnitude smaller than in the Calvo model that generates the same real effects In particular, losses in profits due to sub-optimal price responses to aggregate conditions are 23 times smaller than in the Calvo model;andlossesinprofits due to sub-optimal price responses to firm-specific conditions are 57 times smaller than in the Calvo model that generates the same real effects One reason is the optimal allocation of attention, which implies that prices respond slowly to monetary policy shocks, but fairly quickly to aggregate technology shocks, and almost perfectly to micro-level shocks In contrast, in the Calvo model prices respond slowly to all these shocks The other reason is that under rational inattention deviations of the actual price from the profit-maximizing price are less likely to be extreme than in the Calvo model This also reduces profit losses Third, rational inattention on the side of decision-makers in firms implies that firms produce with a factor mix that tends to deviate from the optimal factor mix Adding rational inattention by households yields responses of consumption to shocks that look similar to the impulse responses of consumption in a model with habit formation This paper is related to two strands of literature: (i) the literature on business cycle models with imperfect information (eg Lucas (972), Woodford (22), Mankiw and Reis (22), and Lorenzoni (28)) and (ii) the literature on rational inattention (eg Sims (23, 26), Luo (28), Maćkowiak and Wiederholt (28), Van Nieuwerburgh and Veldkamp (28), and Woodford (28)) The main difference to the existing literature on business cycle models with imperfect information is that in the model presented below agents choose the information structure The main innovation with respect to the existing literature on rational inattention is that we solve a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model The paper is organized as follows Section 2 describes all features of the economy apart from the decision-makers problem of allocating attention Section 3 describes the steady state of the non-stochastic version of the economy In Section 4 we derive the objective that decision-makers in firms maximize when they choose the allocation of attention In Section 5 we derive the objective that households maximize when they choose the allocation of attention Section 6 describes issues related to aggregation Section 7 characterizes the 3

4 solution of the model under perfect information Section 8 shows numerical solutions of the model under rational inattention by decision-makers in firms Section 9 studies the implications of adding rational inattention by households Section concludes 2 Model In this section we describe all features of the economy apart from the information structure Afterwards we solve the model for alternative assumptions about the information structure: (i) perfect information and (ii) rational inattention 2 Households There are J households Households supply differentiated types of labor, consume a variety of goods, and hold nominal government bonds Each household seeks to maximize the expected sum of discounted period utility The discount factor is β (, ) The period utility function is given by with U (C jt,l jt,,l jnt )= C γ jt γ i= ϕ NX n= e χ jnt L +ψ jnt +ψ, () Ã IX! θ C jt = C θ θ θ ijt (2) Here C jt is composite consumption by household j in period t and C ijt is consumption of good i by household j in period t The household can consume I different goods The parameter θ> is the elasticity of substitution between different goods The parameter γ> is the inverse of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution We assume that households supply differentiated types of labor We also assume that each household supplies multiple types of labor and that the disutility of supplying a particular type of labor is subject to a preference shock Here L jnt denotes the household s supply of his or her nth type of labor, and χ jnt is a preference shock affecting the disutility of supplying this type of labor We introduce labor-type-specific preference shocks to generate variation in relative wage rates The assumption of a constant elasticity of substitution between different varieties is only for ease of exposition One could also use a general constant returns-to-scale aggregator 4

5 Some variation in relative wage rates is needed for an equilibrium to exist The reason is the following If there is no variation in relative wage rates, decision-makers in firms have no incentive to attend to all wage rates Then, for some type of labor, the demand for labor does not depend on the wage rate for that type of labor, implying that the household supplying this type of labor could set an infinite wage rate 2 We assume that each household supplies multiple types of labor to allow households to insure against labor-type-specific preference shocks within the household We will assume that N is large The parameter ϕ> affects the disutility of supplying labor The parameter ψ istheinverseofthe Frisch elasticity of labor supply The flow budget constraint of household j in period t reads IX NX P it C ijt + B jt = R t B jt +(+τ w ) W jnt L jnt + D t J T t J (3) i= Here P it is the price of good i in period t, B jt are bond holdings by household j between periods t and t +, R t is the nominal interest rate on bond holdings between periods t and t, W jnt is the nominal wage rate for household j s nth type of labor in period t, τ w is a wage subsidy, (D t /J) is a pro-rata share of nominal aggregate profits, and (T t /J) is a pro-rata share of nominal lump-sum taxes We assume that all J households have the same initial bond holdings, B j, > Furthermore, we assume that bond holdings cannot be negative or zero, B jt > One can think of households having an account The account holds only nominal government bonds and the balance on the account has to be positive In every period, each household chooses a consumption vector, (C jt,,c Ijt ),anda vector of nominal wage rates, (W jt,,w jnt ) Each household commits to supply any quantity of labor at the chosen nominal wage rates Bond holdings, B jt,thenfollowasa residual from the flow budget constraint (3) and the labor demand function derived below Each household takes as given: all wage rates set by other households, all prices set by n= firms, the nominal interest rate, and all aggregate variables 2 To generate variation in relative wage rates, one could also introduce labor-type-specific productivity shocks instead of labor-type-specific preference shocks 5

6 22 Firms There are I firms in the economy Firms supply differentiated goods that are produced with the different varieties of labor The technology of firm i is given by Y it = e a t e a it L α it, (4) with JX NX L it = j= n= η η L ijnt η η (5) Here Y it is output of firm i in period t, L it is composite labor input at firm i in period t and L ijnt is input of household j s nth type of labor at firm i in period t There are JN types of labor because there are J households each supplying N differentiated types of labor 3 The parameter α (, ] is the elasticity of output with respect to composite labor The parameter η> is the elasticity of substitution between different types of labor Total factor productivity, (e at e a it ), has an aggregate component, e at,andafirm-specific component, e a it Nominal profits of firm i in period t equal where τ p is a production subsidy ( + τ p ) P it Y it JX j= n= NX W jnt L ijnt, (6) ³ˆLit,,ˆL ij(n )t In every period, each firm chooses a price, P it,andafactormix, where ˆL ijnt =(L ijnt /L it ) Each firm commits to supply any quantity of the good at the chosen price The composite labor input, L it, then follows from the production function (4) and the demand function derived below Each firm takes as given: all prices set by other firms, all wage rates set by households, the nominal interest rate, and all aggregate variables 3 The assumption that all types of labor appear in the labor aggregator (5) is only for ease of exposition One could also use a labor aggregator in which a firm-specific subset of types of labor appears 6

7 23 Government There is a monetary authority and a fiscal authority Let Π µ t =(P t /P t ) denote inflation XI of a price index, P t,thatwillbedefined later, and let Y t = denote aggregate i= Y it output The central bank sets the nominal interest rate according to the rule R t R = µ Rt R ρr " µπt Π φπ µ # ρr φy Yt e εr t, (7) Y where ε R t is a monetary policy shock Here R, Π and Y are the values of the nominal interest rate, inflation and aggregate output in the non-stochastic steady state The policy parameters satisfy ρ R [, ), φ π > and φ y The government budget constraint in period t reads à JX NX IX! T t +(B t B t )=(R t ) B t + τ w W jnt L jnt + τ p P it Y it (8) j= n= i= The government has to finance interest on nominal government bonds, the wage subsidy and the production subsidy government bonds The government can collect lump-sum taxes or issue new We assume that the government sets the production subsidy, τ p, and the wage subsidy, τ w,soastocorrectthedistortionsarisingfromfirms market power in the goods market and households market power in the labor market In particular, we assume that and +τ p = ϑ ϑ, (9) +τ w = ζ ζ, () where ϑ denotes the price elasticity of demand and ζ denotes the wage elasticity of labor demand 4 24 Shocks There are four types of shocks in the economy: monetary policy shocks, aggregate technology shocks, firm-specific productivity shocks and labor-type-specific preference shocks We 4 If households have perfect information then ϑ = θ, andiffirms have perfect information then ζ = η However, under limited attention, ϑ will differ from θ and ζ will differ from η 7

8 assume that, for all i and jn, the processes ε R ª t, {at }, {a it } and ª χ jnt are independent Furthermore, we assume that the firm-specific productivity processes, {a it }, are independent across firms and the labor-type-specific preference shocks, χ jnt ª, are independent across types of labor In addition, we assume that I and N are sufficiently large so that IX a it =, () I and N i= NX χ jnt = (2) n= Finally, we assume that the processes ε R ª t, {at }, {a it } and ª χ jnt are stationary Gaussian processes with mean zero In the following, we denote the period t innovation to a t, a it and χ jnt by ε A t, ε I it and εχ jnt, respectively 3 Non-stochastic steady state Before studying the economy described in Section 2 that is hit by shocks, we study the non-stochastic version of the economy In particular, we study the non-stochastic steady state defined as a solution of the non-stochastic version of the economy with the property that real quantities, relative prices, the nominal interest rate and inflation are constant over time In the following, variables without subscript t denote values in the non-stochastic steady state In this section, P t denotes the following price index P t = Ã IX i= and W t denotes the following wage index JX NX W t = j= n= P θ it W η jnt Furthermore, ˆP it denotes the relative price of good i! θ, (3) η (4) ˆP it = P it P t, (5) 8

9 Ŵ jnt denotes the relative wage rate for type jn labor Ŵ jnt = W jnt, (6) W t W jnt denotes the real wage rate for type jn labor and W t denotes the real wage index W jnt = W jnt P t, (7) W t = W t (8) P t It is straightforward to show that in the non-stochastic steady state the households first-order conditions read and R Π = β, (9) C ij C j = ˆP θ i, (2) W jn = ϕ ³Ŵ η jn L ψ C γ j, (2) where L is the aggregate composite labor input IX L = L i (22) i= Furthermore, the firms first-order conditions read L ijn L i = Ŵ η jn, (23) and ˆP i = W ³ ˆP θ α i C, (24) α where C is aggregate composite consumption C = JX C j (25) j= In the non-stochastic version of the model, all households face the same decision problem Therefore, all households choose the same composite consumption definition of aggregate composite consumption (25) that It follows from the C j C = J (26) 9

10 ³ The households wage setting equation (2), equation (26) and Ŵjn = Wjn / W imply that the wage rate is the same for all different types of labor Thus firmsdecidetohireall different types of labor in equal amounts It follows from the labor aggregator (5) and the definition of the wage index (4) that µ Lijn L i η η = Ŵ η jn = JN (27) The firms price setting equation (24) implies that all firms set the same price Thus households decide to consume the different goods in equal amounts, implying that all firms produce the same amount Since all firms also have the same technology, all firms have the same composite labor input It follows from the consumption aggregator (2), the definition of the price index (3), the definition of aggregate output and the definition of aggregate composite labor input (22) that µ Cij C j θ θ = ˆP θ i = Y i Y = L i L = I (28) We will use equations (9)-(2), equations (23)-(24) and equations (26)-(28) below In the non-stochastic steady state, only the real interest rate, (R/Π), is determined Neither the nominal interest rate, R, nor inflation, Π, is determined We will assume that Π equals some value Π Furthermore, in the model, the initial price level, P,isnot determined We will assume that P equals some value P Together Π and P pin down the price level at each point in time in the non-stochastic steady state [Finally, in the non-stochastic steady state, Ricardian equivalence holds, and we have not specified a fiscal rule Therefore, taxes are not determined We will assume that the government runs a balanced budget in the non-stochastic steady state Actually, this assumption is implied by the definition of a non-stochastic steady state] 4 Derivation of the firms objective In this section, we derive an expression for the expected sum of discounted profits We will use this expression in Section 6 when we assume that decision-makers in firms choose the allocation of their attention so as to maximize the expected sum of discounted profits

11 First, we guess that the demand function for good i has the form C it = ς µ Pit where ς> and ϑ> are undetermined coefficients satisfying P t ϑ C t, (29) ς ˆP ϑ i = ˆP θ i, (3) C t is aggregate composite consumption and P t is some price index satisfying = C t = JX C jt, (3) j= IX d i= µ Pit P t, (32) where d is a twice continuously differentiable function We will always make assumptions to ensure that the guess (29)-(32) concerning the demand function is correct When households have perfect information, ς =, ϑ = θ and the price index P t is given by equation (3) When households have limited attention, we will add assumptions concerning the exogenous processes to ensure that the demand function still has the form (29)-(32) Second, given the technology (4)-(5), the expression for nominal profits (6) and a demand function, we can derive the profit function for this demand function We first rewrite the expression for nominal profits (6) using the fact that the wage bill equals the product of the composite labor input and the wage bill per unit of composite labor input JX NX ( + τ p ) P it Y it L it W jntˆlijnt, (33) j= n= where ˆL ijnt =(L ijnt /L it ) Afterwards, we rearrange the production function (4) L it = µ Yit e a t e a it α, (34) and the labor aggregator (5) = JX NX j= n= η η ˆL ijnt

12 The last equation can be stated as ˆL ijnt = X jn6=jn η η ˆL ijnt η η (35) Substituting equations (34), (35) and (29) into the expression for nominal profits (33) yields the profit function for the demand function (29): ( + τ p ) P it ς ³ ς Pit e a t e a it µ Pit P t P t ϑ Ct ϑ C t α X jn6=jn W jntˆlijnt + W JNt X jn6=jn η η ˆL ijnt η η (36) Nominal profits of firm i in period t depend on variables that the decision-maker in the firm chooses (P it and ˆL it,,ˆl ij(n )t ) as well as variables that the decision-maker in the firmtakesasgiven(p t, C t, a t, a it and W t,,w JNt ) Third, we assume that in period nominal profits in period t are discounted with the following stochastic discount factor Q,t = β t λ (C t,,c Jt ) P t, (37) where λ is a twice continuously differentiable function with the property λ (C,,C J )=C γ j, (38) and P t is the price index that appears in the demand function (29) 5 Then, in period, the expected sum of discounted profits equals: X E i, β t λ (C t,,c Jt ) X jn6=jn ϑ ˆP it C t ( + τ p ) ς µ ϑ ς ˆP it e a te a it W jntˆlijnt + W JNt α C t X jn6=jn η η ˆL ijnt η η, (39) 5 For example, if the function λ is a weighted average of the marginal utilities of the different households (ie λ (C t,,c Jt )=λ C γ t + + λ J C γ Jt with λ j and J λ j =), equation (38) is satisfied j= This is because all households have the same marginal utility in the non-stochastic steady state 2

13 where E i, is the expectation operator conditioned on the information of the decisionmaker in firm i in period, ˆPit =(P it /P t ) is the relative price of good i in period t, W jnt =(W jnt /P t ) is the real wage rate for type jn labor in period t, andp t is the price index that appears in the demand function (29) and the stochastic discount factor (37) One can rewrite expression (39) in terms of log-deviations from the non-stochastic steady state In the following, small variables denote log-deviations from the non-stochastic steady state For example, c t =ln(c t /C) Using the equation for the production subsidy (9), the ³ steady state relationships (23), (24), (27) and L i = ˆP θ α i C, and the guess (3) yields the following expression for the expected sum of discounted profits: ϑ ϑ α e( ϑ)ˆp it+c t X E i, β t λ (C e c t,,c J e c Jt ) WL e ϑ α ˆp it+ α c t α (a t+a it) i JN X jn6=jn e w jnt+ˆl ijnt + e w JNt JN where WL i is the real wage bill of firm i in the non-stochastic steady state X jn6=jn e η η (4) ˆl ijnt η η, Proposition (Expected sum of discounted profits) Let E i, denote the expectation operator conditioned on the information of the decision-maker in firm i in period Letf denote the functional inside the expectation operator in expression (4) Let f denote the second-order Taylor approximation to f at the non-stochastic steady state Let x t, z t and v t denote the following vectors ³ x t = ˆp it ˆlit ˆliJ(N )t, (4) ³ z t = c t c Jt c t a t a it w t w JNt, (42) ³ v t = x t zt (43) Let v m,t denote the mth element of v t Suppose that, for all m, k and for each period t, E i, v m,t v k,t <, (44) and, for all m, k, lim t βt E i, v m,t v k,t = (45) 3

14 Then = h i E i, f (x,z,x,z,) β t E i, 2 (x t x t ) H (x t x t ) where the matrix H is given by H = C γ j WL i h i E i, f (x,z,x,z,) ϑ α + α α ϑ 2 ηjn ηjn, (46) ηjn ηjn ηjn ηjn ηjn 2 ηjn, (47) and the vector x t is given by ˆp it = α α + α α ϑc t α + α α ϑ (a t + a it )+ + α α ϑ JN JX NX j= n= w jnt, (48) and ˆl ijnt = η w jnt JN JX NX j= n= w jnt (49) Proof See Appendix A To interpret Proposition, note the following First, in expression (4) variables dated t only affect discounted profits at date t (not at other dates) Furthermore, discounted profits at date t equal β t times real profits, where real profits are defined as Q,t /β t h i times nominal profits Thus, E i, f (x,z,x,z,) is simply the expression for the expected sum of discounted profits that one obtains after a log-quadratic approximation to the real profit function around the non-stochastic steady state Second, in Appendix A the vector x t is defined as the vector that maximizes real profits in period t after the log-quadratic approximation to the real profit function For the real profit function in expression (4), the vector x t is given by equations (48)-(49) It is now easy to interpret Proposition After the log-quadratic approximation of the real profit function, the profit-maximizing price in period t is given by equation (48) and the profit-maximizing factor mix in period t isgivenbyequation(49) Furthermore,after 4

15 the log-quadratic approximation of the real profit function, the loss in profits in the case of a deviation from the profit-maximizing decisions in period t (ie x t 6= x t )isgivenbythe quadratic form in expression (46) The upper-left element of the matrix H determines the loss in profits in the case of a sub-optimal price setting decision The loss is increasing in the price elasticity of demand, ϑ, and increasing in (/α) The lower-right block of the matrix H determines the loss in profits in the case of a sub-optimal factor mix decision The loss depends on the elasticity of substitution between different types of labor, η, and the number of different types of labor, JN The diagonal elements of H determine the loss in profits in the case of a deviation in a single variable The off-diagonal elements of H determine how a deviation in one variable affects the loss in profits due to a deviation in another variable Finally, conditions (44) and (45) ensure that, after the log-quadratic approximation to the real profit function, in the expression for the expected sum of discounted profits one can change the order of integration and summation, all moments are finite and all infinite sums converge 5 Derivation of the households objective In this section, we derive an expression for the expected sum of discounted period utility We will use this expression in Section 7 when we assume that households choose the allocation of their attention so as to maximize the expected sum of discounted period utility First, we guess that the demand function for type jn labor has the form µ ζ Wjnt L jnt = ξ L t, (5) where ξ> and ζ> are undetermined coefficients satisfying W t ξŵ ζ jn = Ŵ η jn, (5) L t is the aggregate composite labor input and W t is some wage index satisfying = L t = JX j= n= IX L it, (52) i= NX h 5 µ Wjnt W t, (53)

16 where h is a twice continuously differentiable function We will always make assumptions to ensure that the guess (5)-(53) concerning the labor demand function is correct When firms have perfect information, ξ =, ζ = η and the wage index W t is given by equation (4) When firms have limited attention, we will add assumptions concerning the exogenous processes to ensure that the labor demand function still has the form (5)-(53) Second, just like we derived the profit function for firms by substituting the production function, the labor aggregator and the demand function into the expression for nominal profits, we now derive a period utility function by substituting the flow budget constraint (3), the consumption aggregator (2) and the labor demand function (5) into the expression for period utility () We first rewrite the flow budget constraint (3) using the fact that consumption expenditure equals the product of composite consumption and expenditure per unit of composite consumption C jt à IX i= P it Ĉ ijt! + B jt = R t B jt +(+τ w ) NX n= W jnt L jnt + D t J T t J, where Ĉijt =(C ijt /C jt ) is the relative consumption of good i Dividing the last equation by P t,wherep t is some price index, and rearranging yields C jt = R t Π t Bjt B jt +(+τ w ) NX n= W jnt L jnt + D t J T t J (54) IX ˆP it Ĉ ijt i= Here ˆP it =(P it /P t ) is the relative price of good i, Wjnt =(W jnt /P t ) istherealwageratefor type jn labor, B jt =(B jt /P t ) are real bond holdings by household j, D t =(D t /P t ) are real aggregate profits, Tt =(T t /P t ) are real lump-sum taxes, and Π t =(P t /P t ) is inflation Next, we rewrite the equation for the consumption aggregator (2) The last equation can be stated as = IX i= i= Ĉ θ θ ijt Ã! XI θ Ĉ Ijt = Ĉ θ θ θ ijt (55) 6

17 Substituting equations (54), (55) and (5) into the period utility function () yields a period utility function that incorporates the flow budget constraint, the consumption aggregator and the labor demand function: γ N γ ϕ X R t Π t Bjt B jt +(+τ w ) n= e χ jnt XI i= NX n= ˆP it Ĉ ijt + ˆP XI It à Ã! ζ Wjnt ξ L t +ψ W t ³ ζ Wjnt W jnt ξ Lt + D t W t J T t J i= +ψ! θ Ĉ θ θ θ ijt γ (56) Here W t =(W t /P t ) where W t is the wage index appearing in the labor demand function and P t is the price index that we divided by to obtain equation (54) Finally, we express the period utility function (56) in terms of log-deviations from the non-stochastic steady state In the following, small variables denote log-deviations from the non-stochastic steady state For example, b ³ jt =ln Bjt / j B Using the equation for the wage subsidy (), the steady state relationships (9)-(2) and (28), and the guess (5) yields the following expression for the utility of household j in period t: C γ j γ ω Bβ e r t π t+ b jt ω B e b jt + X γ C γ j ω W +ψ N I I i= ζ ω WN ζ eˆp it+ĉ ijt + I eˆp It N X e ( ζ) w jnt+ζ w t+l t + ω D e d t ω T e t t n= Ã! XI θ θ I e θ θ ĉijt i= NX e χ jnt ζ(+ψ)( w jnt w t )+(+ψ)l t, (57) n= γ where ω B, ω W, ω D and ω T denote the following steady state ratios: à ³ X N W ω B ω W ω D ω T = B jn L jn j n= C j C j D J C j T J C j! (58) Proposition 2 (Expected sum of discounted period utility) Let E j, denote the expectation operator conditioned on information of household j in period Let g denote the functional that is obtained by multiplying the expression for period utility (57) by β t and summing over 7

18 all t from zero to infinity Let g denote the second-order Taylor approximation to g at the non-stochastic steady state Let x t, z t and v t denote the following vectors x t = z t = v t = ³ bjt w jt w jnt ĉ jt ĉ I jt, (59) ³ r t π t w t l t dt t t ˆp t ˆp It χ jt χ jnt, (6) ³ x t zt (6) Let v m,t denote the mth element of v t Suppose that for all m, for all m and k, forτ =, and for each period t, and for all m and k, andforτ =,, E j, h b2 j, i <, (62) E j, bj, v m, <, (63) E j, v m,t v k,t+τ <, (64) lim t βt E j, v m,t v k,t+τ = (65) Then where = H = C γ j i h i E j, h g ³ bj,,x,z,x,z, E j, g ³ bj,,x,z,x,z, β t E j, 2 (x t x t ) H (x t x t )+(x t x t ) H xt+ x t+, (66) γω 2 B ³ + β γω B ζω W N γω B ζω W N ζω W N γω B ζω W ³ γζωw N N ++ζψ ³ 2 γ ζωw N ³ 2 γ ζωw N ζω W N γω B ζω W N ³ γζωw N ++ζψ 2 θi θi 2 θi θi (67), 8

19 H = C γ j γω B ζω W γω N B ζω W N, (68) γω 2 B and the process {x t } is given by: (i) the requirement that the vector v t with x t = x t satisfies conditions (63)-(65), and (ii) the requirement that, for each period t, " Ã c jt = E t r t π t+ γ I IX ˆp it+ + I i=! # IX ˆp it + c jt+, (69) w jnt γ = +ζψ c jt + ψ +ζψ (ζ w t + l t )+ +ζψ χ jnt + IX ˆp it, (7) +ζψ I i= Ã! ĉ ijt = θ ˆp it IX ˆp it, (7) I i= i= where the variable c jt is defined as c jt = ω B β ³ r t π t + b jt + ζ ω W ζ N +ω D dt ω T t t I NX ( ζ) w jnt + ζ w t + l t n= IX ˆp it ω B b jt (72) i= Here E t denotes the expectation operator conditioned on the complete history of the economy up to and including period t Proof See Appendix B The vector x t is the vector of variables appearing in the expression for period utility (57) that the household can affect in period t Proposition 2 states that, after the log-quadratic approximation to the sum of discounted period utility, and if information about initial bond holdings satisfies condition (62) and the processes {x t } and {x t } satisfy conditions (63)-(65), then the difference between expected utility for the process {x t } and expected utility for the process {x t } is given by equation (66) Here the process {x t } is defined as the sequence of 9

20 decisions that the household would take, after the log-quadratic approximation to the sum of discounted period utility, if the household had perfect information at each point in time Thus, equation (66) provides a simple way to compute the household s loss in expected utility from taking a sequence of decisions that may deviate from the household s sequence of decisions under perfect information Conditions (62)-(65) are a set of sufficient conditions for equation (66) to hold They ensure that, after the log-quadratic approximation to the sum of discounted utility, in the expression for the expected sum of discounted utility one can change the order of integration and summation, all moments are finite and all infinite sums converge 6 Aggregation In this section, we describe issues related to aggregation In the following, we will work with log-linearized equations for the aggregate variables Log-linearizing the equations for aggregate output, aggregate composite consumption (3) and aggregate composite labor input (52) yields y t = I IX y it, (73) i= c t = J and l t = I JX c jt, (74) j= IX l it (75) Log-linearizing the equations for the price index (32) and the wage index (53) yields IX = ˆp it, i= i= and JX NX = ŵ jnt The last two equations can also be stated as j= n= p t = I IX p it, (76) i= 2

21 and w t = JN JX j= n= NX w jnt (77) Furthermore, in the following, we will also work with log-linearized equations when we compute the demand for an individual good or for an individual type of labor Formally, c it = J JX c ijt, (78) j= and l jnt = I IX l ijnt (79) Finally, note that the production function (4) and the monetary policy rule (7) are already log-linear y it = a t + a it + αl it, (8) and r t = ρ R r t +( ρ R ) φ π π t + φ y y t + ε R t (8) i= 7 Case : Perfect information In this section, we study the solution of the model under perfect information This solution will serve as a benchmark We define a solution under perfect information as follows: in each period all agents know the complete history of the economy up to and including the current period; decision-makers in firms choose the profit-maximizing price and factor mix; households choose the utility-maximizing consumption vector and nominal wage rates; the government sets the nominal interest rate according to the monetary policy rule, pays subsidies so as to correct the distortions due to market power, and chooses a fiscal policy that satisfies the government budget constraint; aggregate variables are given by their respective equations; and households have rational expectations The following proposition characterizes the solution under perfect information after the log-quadratic approximation of the firms objective (see Section 4), the log-quadratic approximation of the households objective (see Section 5) and the log-linearization of the equations for the aggregate variables (see Section 6) 2

22 Proposition 3 (Solution under perfect information) A solution to the system of equations (48)-(49), (69)-(72), (73)-(8), ()-(2), (5)-(8), y it = c it, ˆl ijnt = l ijnt l it and ĉ ijt = c ijt c jt with the same initial bond holdings for each household and a non-explosive bond h sequence for each household (ie lim s E t β s+ ³ bjt+s+ jt+s i b =)satisfies: and Proof See Appendix C y t = +ψ c t = α + αγ + ψ a t, (82) l t = γ α + αγ + ψ a t, (83) w t = γ + ψ α + αγ + ψ a t, (84) r t E t [π t+ ] = +ψ γ α + αγ + ψ E t [a t+ a t ], (85) ˆp it = α + α α + α α θ a it, (86) ĉ ijt = θ α θ a it, (87) w jnt w t = +ψη χ jnt, (88) ˆlijnt = η +ψη χ jnt (89) In the case of perfect information, aggregate output, aggregate composite consumption, aggregate composite labor input, the real wage index and the real interest rate depend only on aggregate technology The relative price of good i and relative consumption of good i depend only on firm-specific productivity The relative wage rate for type jn labor and relative input of type jn labor depend only on the labor-type-specific preference shock Monetary policy has no real effects The nominal interest rate and inflation then follow from the monetary policy rule (8) and the real interest rate (85) Since ( ρ R ) φ π > and ( ρ R ) φ π + ρ R >, the equilibrium paths of the nominal interest rate and inflation are locally determinate 6 6 See Woodford (23), Chapter 2, Proposition 28 22

23 8 Case 2: Firms have limited attention, households have perfect information In this section, we solve the model under rational inattention by decision-makers in firms, ie we assume that decision-makers in firms have limited attention and that they choose how to allocate their attention For the moment, we continue to assume that households have perfect information to isolate the implications of rational inattention by decision-makers in firms 8 Firms attention problem Following Sims (23), we model attention as a flow of information, and we model limited attention as a constraint on the flow of information We let agents choose the allocation of information flow In particular, agents decide how much information flow they allocate to their different decision problems Furthermore, for each decision problem, agents decide how much information flow they allocate to the different factors that determine the optimal decision We will refer to the allocation of information flow as the allocation of attention We assume that decision-makers in firms choose the allocation of attention in period so as to maximize the expected sum of discounted profits Formally, the attention problem of the decision-maker in firm i reads: max B(L),C(L) β t E i, 2 (x t x t ) H (x t x t ), (9) where x t x t = p it ˆlit p it ˆl it, (9) ˆliJ(N )t ˆl ij(n )t subject to: the equations characterizing the profit-maximizing decisions p it = A (L) ε A t + A {z } 2 (L) ε R t {z } p A it p R it + A 3 (L) ε I it {z } p I it (92) ˆl ijnt = A 4 (L) ε χ jnt, (93) 23

24 the equations specifying the admissible processes for the actual decisions p it = B (L) ε A t + C (L) ν A it + B {z } 2 (L) ε R t + C 2 (L) ν R it + B {z } 3 (L) ε I it + C 3 (L) ν I it {z } p A it p R it p I it ˆlijnt = B 4 (L) ε χ jnt + C 4 (L) ν χ ijnt, (95) (94) and the information flow constraint I ³n p A it,p R it,p I it, ˆl o it,,ˆl ij(n )t ; np A it,p R it,p I it, ˆl o it,,ˆl ij(n )t κ (96) The noise terms ν A it, νr it, νi it and νχ ijnt are assumed to follow unit-variance Gaussian white noise processes that are (i) firm-specific, (ii) independent of all other processes in the economy and (iii) independent of each other Here A (L) to A 4 (L), B (L) to B 4 (L) and C (L) to C 4 (L) are infinite-order lag polynomials The operator I measures the information flow between stochastic processes and will be defined below Finally, κ is the decision-maker s overall attention devoted to setting the price and choosing the factor mix in every period After the log-quadratic approximation to the real profit function, expression (9) equals the expected discounted sum of profit losses due to sub-optimal decisions See Proposition The matrix H is given by equation (47) and the vector x t x t isgivenbyequation (9) The last equation follows from the definition of x t in Proposition and the equality ˆp it ˆp it = p it p it Equations (92)-(93) characterize the profit-maximizing decisions in period t After the log-quadratic approximation to the real profit function, the profitmaximizing decisions in period t are given by equations (48)-(49), p it =ˆp it + p t and the variables p t, c t, a t, a it and w jnt Here we guess that, after substituting in the equilibrium processes for p t, c t, a t, a it and w jnt, the profit-maximizing decisions in period t have the representation (92)-(93) We will verify this guess Equations (94)-(95) specify the actual decisions Here we assume that actual decisions follow a Gaussian process and that actual decisions in period t cannot depend on the realization of shocks drawn in the future The decision-maker chooses the lag polynomials B (L) to B 4 (L) and C (L) to C 4 (L) The lag polynomials are a way of specifying the joint distribution of actual decisions and profitmaximizing decisions For example, if B (L) =A (L) and C (L) =,thenp A it = pa it, which simply means that the price set by the decision-maker responds perfectly to aggregate technology shocks The decision-maker has to respect the constraint on information flow 24

25 (96) In the next two paragraphs, we discuss the information flow constraint (96) in detail, and we discuss the assumptions about the noise terms The operator I measures the information flow between stochastic processes The operator is defined as follows Let H (X,,X T ) denote the entropy of the sequence of random variables X,,X T given information in period LetH (X,,X T Y,,Y T ) denote the conditional entropy of the sequence of random variables X,,X T and information in period The operator I is then defined as given Y,,Y T I ({X t } ; {Y t })= lim T T [H (X,,X T ) H (X,,X T Y,,Y T )] (97) Since entropy is a measure of uncertainty, the operator I is a measure of how much knowledge of Y,,Y T reduces uncertainty concerning X,,X T We have assumed that the actual decisions follow a Gaussian process One can show that a Gaussian process for the actual decisions is optimal because the objective (9) is quadratic and the profit-maximizing decisions (92)-(93) follow a Gaussian process 7 Furthermore, we have assumed that the noise in the actual decisions is firm-specific This assumption accords well with the idea that the friction is the limited attention of an individual decision-maker rather than the limited availability of information Finally, we have assumed that the noise terms ν A it, νr it, νi it and νχ ijnt are independent of each other This assumption captures the idea that paying attention to the state of aggregate technology, to monetary policy shocks, to firm-specific productivity and to relative wage rates are independent activities In the future, we also plan to study the case where the noise terms can be correlated 82 Computing the equilibrium We use an iterative procedure to solve for the equilibrium of the model First, we make a guess concerning the process for the profit-maximizing price (92) and a guess concerning the process for the profit-maximizing factor mix (93) Second, we solve the firms attention problem (9)-(96) Third, we aggregate the individual prices to obtain the aggregate price level: p t = I IX p it (98) i= 7 See Sims (26) or Maćkowiak and Wiederholt (28) 25

26 Fourth, we compute the aggregate dynamics implied by those price level dynamics The following equations have to be satisfied in equilibrium: r t = ρ R r t +( ρ R ) φ π (p t p t )+φ y y t + ε R t, (99) c t = E t γ (r t p t+ + p t )+c t+, () The first equation is the monetary policy rule y t = c t, () y t = a t + αl t, (2) a t = ρ A a t + ε A t, (3) w t = γc t + ψl t (4) The second equation follows from the assumption that households have perfect information and equations (69), (74) and (76) The third equation follows from the requirement that output has to equal demand The fourth equation follows from the production function The fifth equation is the assumed process for aggregate technology The last equation follows from the assumption that households have perfect information and equations (7), (74), (76), (77) and (2) We employ a standard solution method for linear rational expectations models to solve the system of equations containing the price level dynamics and those six equations We obtain the law of motion for (r t,c t,y t,l t,a t, w t ) implied by the price level dynamics Fifth, we compute the law of motion for the profit-maximizing price from equations (48) and (77): p it = p t + α α + α α ϑc t α + α α ϑ (a t + a it )+ + α α ϑ w t (5) In the last equation, we set ϑ = θ because the assumption that households have perfect information and equations (7) and (78) imply that the price elasticity of demand equals θ If the process for the profit-maximizing price differs from our guess, we update our guess until we reach a fixed point Finally, we compute the equilibrium relative wage rates and the equilibrium factor mix This is explained in Appendix D 26

27 83 Benchmark parameter values and solution In this section, we report the numerical solution of the model for the following parameter values We set β =99, γ =, ψ =, θ =4, α =2/3 and η =4 To set the parameters governing the process for aggregate technology, equation (3), we consider quarterly US data from 96 Q to 26 Q4 We first compute a time series for aggregate technology, a t, using equation (2) and measures of y t and l t Weusethelog of real output per person, detrended with a linear trend, as a measure of y t Weusethelog of hours worked per person, demeaned, as a measure of l t 8 We then fit equation (3) to thetimeseriesfora t obtaining ρ A =96 and a standard deviation of the innovation equal to 85 In the benchmark economy, we set ρ A =95 and we set the standard deviation of ε A t equal to 85 To set the parameters of the Taylor rule, we consider quarterly US data on the Federal Funds rate, inflation and real GDP from 96 Q to 26 Q4 9 We fit thetaylorrule (99) to the data obtaining ρ R =89, φ π =53, φ y =33, and a standard deviation of the innovation equal to 2 In the benchmark economy, we set ρ R =9, φ π =5, φ y =33, and the standard deviation of ε R t equal to 2 We assume that firm-specific productivity follows a first-order autoregressive process Recent papers calibrate the autocorrelation of firm-specific productivity to be about twothirds in monthly data, eg Klenow and Willis (27) use 68, Midrigan (26) uses 5, and Nakamura and Steinsson (27) use 66 Since (2/3) 3 equals about 3, we set the autocorrelation of firm-specific productivity in our quarterly model equal to 3 We then choose the standard deviation of the innovation to firm-specific productivity such that the average absolute size of price changes in our model equals 97 percent under perfect information The value 97 percent is the average absolute size of price changes excluding sales reported in Klenow and Kryvtsov (27) This yields a standard deviation of the 8 We use data for the non-farm business sector The source of the data is the website of the Federal Reserve Bank of StLouis 9 We compute a time series for four-quarter inflation rate from the price index for personal consumption expenditures excluding food and energy We compute a time series for percentage deviations of real GDP from potential real GDP The sources of the data are the websites of the Federal Reserve Bank of StLouis and the Congressional Budget Office 27

28 innovation to firm-specific productivity equal to 22 We assume that labor-type-specific preference shocks follow a white noise process This simplifying assumption implies that solving for the equilibrium relative wage rates and the equilibrium factor mix is straightforward See Appendix D We compute the solution of the model by fixing the marginal value of information flow instead of κ The overall information flow, κ, is then determined within the model The idea is the following When the marginal value of information flow is high, decision-makers in firms have a high incentive to increase information flow in order to take better decisions In contrast, when the marginal value of information flow is low, decision-makers in firms have little incentive to increase information flow We set the marginal value of information flowequaltopercentofafirm s steady state output We first report the optimal allocation of attention at the rational inattention fixed point The decision-maker in a firm allocates 3 bits of information flow to tracking firm-specific productivity, bit of information flow to tracking aggregate technology, and 35 bits of information flow to tracking monetary policy The expected per-period loss in profits due to imperfect tracking of firm-specific productivity equals 7 percent of the firm s steady state output; the expected per-period loss in profits due to imperfect tracking of aggregate technology equals 5 percent of the firm s steady state output; and the expected perperiod loss in profits due to imperfect tracking of monetary policy equals 3 percent of the firm s steady state output Together these numbers imply that the expected per-period loss in profits due to deviations of the actual price from the profit-maximizing price equals 5 percent of the firm s steady state output We think this is a reasonable number Figures and 2 show impulse responses of the price level, inflation, output, and the nominal interest rate at the rational inattention fixed point (green lines with circles) For comparison, the figures also include impulse responses of the same variables at the equilibrium under perfect information derived in Section 6 (blue lines with points) All impulse responses are to shocks of one standard deviation All impulse responses are drawn such that an impulse response equal to one means a one percent deviation from the non-stochastic steady state Time is measured in quarters along horizontal axes Consider Figure The price level shows a dampened and delayed response to a mone- 28

29 tary policy shock compared with the case of perfect information The response of inflation to a monetary policy shock is persistent Output falls after a positive innovation in the Taylor rule and the decline in output is persistent The nominal interest rate increases on impact and then converges slowly to zero The impulse responses to a monetary policy shock under rational inattention differ markedly from the impulse responses to a monetary policy shock under perfect information Under perfect information, the price level adjusts fully on impact to a monetary policy shock, there are no real effects, and the nominal interest rate fails to change Consider Figure 2 The price level and inflation show a dampened response to an aggregate technology shock compared with the case of perfect information The output gap is negative for a few quarters after the shock Output and the nominal interest rate show hump-shaped impulse responses to an aggregate technology shock Note that under rational inattention the response of the price level to an aggregate technology shock is less dampened and less delayed than the response of the price level to a monetary policy shock The reason is the optimal allocation of attention Decision-makers in firms allocate about three times as much attention to aggregate technology than to monetary policy Therefore, prices respond faster to aggregate technology shocks than to monetary policy shocks As a result, the output gap is negative for only 5 quarters after an aggregate technology shock, while the output gap is negative for quarters after a monetary policy shock Figure 3 shows the impulse response of an individual price to a firm-specific productivity shock Prices respond almost perfectly to firm-specific productivity shocks The reason is the optimal allocation of attention 84 Comparison to the Calvo model For comparison, we solved the Calvo model for the same parameter values and assuming that prices change every 25 quarters on average Figures 4 and 5 show the impulse responses See also Paciello (27) Paciello solves the white noise case of a similar model analytically, where white noise case means that: (i) all exogenous processes are white noise processes, (ii) there is no lagged interest rate in the Taylor rule, and (iii) the price level instead of inflation appears in the Taylor rule The analytical solution in the white noise case helps to understand in more detail the differential response of prices to aggregate technology shocks and to monetary policy shocks 29

Business Cycle Dynamics under Rational Inattention

Business Cycle Dynamics under Rational Inattention Business Cycle Dynamics under Rational Inattention Bartosz Maćkowiak European Central Bank and CEPR Mirko Wiederholt Northwestern University First draft: June 27 This draft: April 29 Preliminary Version

More information

Business Cycle Dynamics under Rational Inattention

Business Cycle Dynamics under Rational Inattention Business Cycle Dynamics under Rational Inattention Bartosz Maćkowiak European Central Bank and CEPR Mirko Wiederholt Northwestern University First draft: June 27 This draft: September 29 Preliminary Version

More information

Business Cycle Dynamics under Rational Inattention

Business Cycle Dynamics under Rational Inattention Business Cycle Dynamics under Rational Inattention Bartosz Maćkowiak ECB and CEPR Mirko Wiederholt Northwestern University November 2, 2007 Abstract This paper studies a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium

More information

Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy

Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy Luigi Paciello Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance Mirko Wiederholt Northwestern University March 200 Abstract Should the central bank care whether

More information

Rational Inattention

Rational Inattention Rational Inattention (prepared for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics) Mirko Wiederholt Northwestern University August 2010 Abstract Economists have studied for a long time how decision-makers allocate

More information

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy Leonardo Melosi London Business School 24 May 2012 Motivation Disperse information about aggregate fundamentals Morris and Shin (2003), Sims (2003), and Woodford (2002)

More information

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999) Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999) The question we are asking is: What are the consequences of a monetary policy shock a shock which is purely related to monetary conditions

More information

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania A Modern Equilibrium Model Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania 1 Household Problem Preferences: max E X β t t=0 c 1 σ t 1 σ ψ l1+γ t 1+γ Budget constraint: c t + k t+1 = w t l t + r t

More information

Endogenous Information Choice

Endogenous Information Choice Endogenous Information Choice Lecture 7 February 11, 2015 An optimizing trader will process those prices of most importance to his decision problem most frequently and carefully, those of less importance

More information

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics DSGE-Models Calibration and Introduction to Dynare Dr. Andrea Beccarini Willi Mutschler, M.Sc. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics willi.mutschler@uni-muenster.de Summer 2012 Willi Mutschler

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano January 5, 2018 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand.

More information

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007 Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models December 4, 2007 Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models Random shocks to generate trajectories that look like the observed national accounts. Rational

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano March, 28 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand. Derive

More information

Macroeconomics Theory II

Macroeconomics Theory II Macroeconomics Theory II Francesco Franco FEUNL February 2011 Francesco Franco Macroeconomics Theory II 1/34 The log-linear plain vanilla RBC and ν(σ n )= ĉ t = Y C ẑt +(1 α) Y C ˆn t + K βc ˆk t 1 + K

More information

1 The Basic RBC Model

1 The Basic RBC Model IHS 2016, Macroeconomics III Michael Reiter Ch. 1: Notes on RBC Model 1 1 The Basic RBC Model 1.1 Description of Model Variables y z k L c I w r output level of technology (exogenous) capital at end of

More information

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martín Uribe Duke University September 2007 1 Welfare-Based Policy Evaluation: Related Literature (ex: Rotemberg and Woodford,

More information

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions Daniel Němec Faculty of Economics and Administrations Masaryk University Brno, Czech Republic nemecd@econ.muni.cz ESF MU (Brno)

More information

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING James Bullard* Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 33rd Annual Economic Policy Conference St. Louis, MO October 17, 2008 Views expressed are

More information

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective Jordi Galí CREI, UPF and Barcelona GSE April 215 Jordi Galí (CREI, UPF and Barcelona GSE) Monetary Policy and Unemployment April 215 1 / 16

More information

The Natural Rate of Interest and its Usefulness for Monetary Policy

The Natural Rate of Interest and its Usefulness for Monetary Policy The Natural Rate of Interest and its Usefulness for Monetary Policy Robert Barsky, Alejandro Justiniano, and Leonardo Melosi Online Appendix 1 1 Introduction This appendix describes the extended DSGE model

More information

Demand Shocks with Dispersed Information

Demand Shocks with Dispersed Information Demand Shocks with Dispersed Information Guido Lorenzoni (MIT) Class notes, 06 March 2007 Nominal rigidities: imperfect information How to model demand shocks in a baseline environment with imperfect info?

More information

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks Eric R. Sims University of Notre Dame and NBER January 17, 2012 Abstract In a standard New Keynesian model, a Taylor-type interest rate rule moves the equilibrium real

More information

Optimal Monetary Policy with Informational Frictions

Optimal Monetary Policy with Informational Frictions Optimal Monetary Policy with Informational Frictions George-Marios Angeletos Jennifer La O July 2017 How should fiscal and monetary policy respond to business cycles when firms have imperfect information

More information

Demand Shocks, Monetary Policy, and the Optimal Use of Dispersed Information

Demand Shocks, Monetary Policy, and the Optimal Use of Dispersed Information Demand Shocks, Monetary Policy, and the Optimal Use of Dispersed Information Guido Lorenzoni (MIT) WEL-MIT-Central Banks, December 2006 Motivation Central bank observes an increase in spending Is it driven

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano Gerzensee, August 27 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand.

More information

Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model.

Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model. Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model. January 8, 2018 1 Introduction This document describes the equilibrium conditions of Kaplan,

More information

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World Jesper Lindé and Mathias Trabandt ECB-EABCN-Atlanta Nonlinearities Conference, December 15-16, 2014 Sveriges Riksbank and Federal Reserve Board December 16, 2014

More information

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton Figure a. Aggregate exchange rate disconnect (levels) 28.5

More information

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano Foundations for the New Keynesian Model Lawrence J. Christiano Objective Describe a very simple model economy with no monetary frictions. Describe its properties. markets work well Modify the model to

More information

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3) MakØk3, Fall 2 (blok 2) Business cycles and monetary stabilization policies Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen Lecture 3, November 3: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter

More information

Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework

Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework Dongpeng Liu Nanjing University Sept 2016 D. Liu (NJU) Solving D(S)GE 09/16 1 / 63 Introduction Targets of the

More information

Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle

Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle David de la Croix 1,3 Gregory de Walque 2 Rafael Wouters 2,1 1 dept. of economics, Univ. cath. Louvain 2 National Bank of Belgium

More information

The Smets-Wouters Model

The Smets-Wouters Model The Smets-Wouters Model Monetary and Fiscal Policy 1 1 Humboldt Universität zu Berlin uhlig@wiwi.hu-berlin.de Winter 2006/07 Outline 1 2 3 s Intermediate goods firms 4 A list of equations Calibration Source

More information

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008 The Basic New Keynesian Model by Jordi Galí June 28 Motivation and Outline Evidence on Money, Output, and Prices: Short Run E ects of Monetary Policy Shocks (i) persistent e ects on real variables (ii)

More information

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model Toulouse School of Economics, 2009-2010 Macroeconomics II Franck Portier Homework 1 Problem I An AD-AS Model Let us consider an economy with three agents (a firm, a household and a government) and four

More information

Deep Habits: Technical Notes

Deep Habits: Technical Notes Deep Habits: Technical Notes Morten Ravn Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martín Uribe October 18, 2004 This note derives in detail the model, its associated equilibrium conditions, the steadystate equilibrium,

More information

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4 Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4 1 Basic Model 1.1 Uzawa Utility E 0 t=0 θ t U (c t, h t ) θ 0 = 1 θ t+1 = β (c t, h t ) θ t ; β c < 0; β h > 0. Time-varying discount factor With a constant

More information

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC) Real Business Cycle Model (RBC) Seyed Ali Madanizadeh November 2013 RBC Model Lucas 1980: One of the functions of theoretical economics is to provide fully articulated, artificial economic systems that

More information

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle. June 7, 2018

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle. June 7, 2018 Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle Jesper Lindé Sveriges Riksbank Mathias Trabandt Freie Universität Berlin June 7, 218 Motivation Key observations during the Great Recession: Extraordinary contraction

More information

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0 Part 6 1. Borrowing Constraints II 1.1. Borrowing Constraints and the Ricardian Equivalence Equivalence between current taxes and current deficits? Basic paper on the Ricardian Equivalence: Barro, JPE,

More information

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj Macro II (UC3M, MA/PhD Econ) Professor: Matthias Kredler Problem Set 1 Due: 29 April 216 You are encouraged to work in groups; however, every student has to hand in his/her own version of the solution.

More information

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008) Getting to page 31 in Galí 2008) H J Department of Economics University of Copenhagen December 4 2012 Abstract This note shows in detail how to compute the solutions for output inflation and the nominal

More information

Assessing Structural VAR s

Assessing Structural VAR s ... Assessing Structural VAR s by Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Robert Vigfusson Zurich, September 2005 1 Background Structural Vector Autoregressions Address the Following Type of Question:

More information

Lars Svensson 2/16/06. Y t = Y. (1) Assume exogenous constant government consumption (determined by government), G t = G<Y. (2)

Lars Svensson 2/16/06. Y t = Y. (1) Assume exogenous constant government consumption (determined by government), G t = G<Y. (2) Eco 504, part 1, Spring 2006 504_L3_S06.tex Lars Svensson 2/16/06 Specify equilibrium under perfect foresight in model in L2 Assume M 0 and B 0 given. Determine {C t,g t,y t,m t,b t,t t,r t,i t,p t } that

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Macroeconomics II 2 The real business cycle model. Introduction This model explains the comovements in the fluctuations of aggregate economic variables around their trend.

More information

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen October 15, 2013 Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen () Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations October 15, 2013 1 / 43 Introduction

More information

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction The New Keynesian Model: Introduction Vivaldo M. Mendes ISCTE Lisbon University Institute 13 November 2017 (Vivaldo M. Mendes) The New Keynesian Model: Introduction 13 November 2013 1 / 39 Summary 1 What

More information

The Neo Fisher Effect and Exiting a Liquidity Trap

The Neo Fisher Effect and Exiting a Liquidity Trap The Neo Fisher Effect and Exiting a Liquidity Trap Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé and Martín Uribe Columbia University European Central Bank Conference on Monetary Policy Frankfurt am Main, October 29-3, 218

More information

Relative Deep Habits

Relative Deep Habits Relative Deep Habits Morten Ravn Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martín Uribe May 5, 25 Abstract This note presents a detailed formal derivation of the equilibrium conditions of a variation of the deep habit model

More information

APPENDIX TO RESERVE REQUIREMENTS AND OPTIMAL CHINESE STABILIZATION POLICY

APPENDIX TO RESERVE REQUIREMENTS AND OPTIMAL CHINESE STABILIZATION POLICY APPENDIX TO RESERVE REQUIREMENTS AND OPTIMAL CHINESE STABILIZATION POLICY CHUN CHANG ZHENG LIU MARK M. SPIEGEL JINGYI ZHANG Abstract. This appendix shows some additional details of the model and equilibrium

More information

Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations?

Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations? Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations? A Bayesian DSGE Approach Ippei Fujiwara 1 Yasuo Hirose 1 Mototsugu 2 1 Bank of Japan 2 Vanderbilt University August 4, 2009 Contributions of this paper

More information

Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance.

Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance. Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance. Laura Veldkamp New York University, Stern School of Business, CEPR and NBER Spring 2009 1 Veldkamp What information consumes is rather obvious: It consumes

More information

Assessing Structural VAR s

Assessing Structural VAR s ... Assessing Structural VAR s by Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Robert Vigfusson Columbia, October 2005 1 Background Structural Vector Autoregressions Can be Used to Address the Following

More information

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model Macroeconomics II Dynamic AD-AS model Vahagn Jerbashian Ch. 14 from Mankiw (2010) Spring 2018 Where we are heading to We will incorporate dynamics into the standard AD-AS model This will offer another

More information

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes Macroeconomics II Dynamic AD-AS model Vahagn Jerbashian Ch. 14 from Mankiw (2010) Spring 2018 Where we are heading to We will incorporate dynamics into the standard AD-AS model This will offer another

More information

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany October 3, 2018 Contents I 1 Central Planner 2 3 B. Heer c Public Economics: Chapter

More information

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective Jordi Galí CREI, UPF and Barcelona GSE May 218 Jordi Galí (CREI, UPF and Barcelona GSE) Monetary Policy and Unemployment May 218 1 / 18 Introducing

More information

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2015 1 / 36 Production Economy Last time: studied equilibrium in an endowment economy Now: study equilibrium in an economy

More information

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Endogenous Growth with Human Capital Consider the following endogenous growth model with both physical capital (k (t)) and human capital (h (t)) in continuous time. The representative household solves

More information

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World Jesper Lindé Sveriges Riksbank Mathias Trabandt Freie Universität Berlin November 28, 2016 Lindé and Trabandt Multipliers () in Nonlinear Models November 28, 2016

More information

Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics

Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics Lawrence Christiano and Yuta Takahashi July 26, 2018 Multiple Equilibria Standard NK Model Standard, New Keynesian (NK) Monetary Model: Taylor rule satisfying Taylor

More information

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8 New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8 1 General Assumptions Ignore variations in the capital stock There are differentiated goods with Calvo price stickiness Wages are not sticky Monetary policy is a choice

More information

Problem 1 (30 points)

Problem 1 (30 points) Problem (30 points) Prof. Robert King Consider an economy in which there is one period and there are many, identical households. Each household derives utility from consumption (c), leisure (l) and a public

More information

An Introduction to Rational Inattention

An Introduction to Rational Inattention An Introduction to Rational Inattention Lecture notes for the course Bounded Rationality and Macroeconomics December 2, 2005 1 Introduction The objective of modelling economic agents as being rationally

More information

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models 4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models Basic Economic Models In Economics, we use theoretical models to explain the economic processes in the real world. These models de ne a relation

More information

WORKING PAPER NO INTEREST RATE VERSUS MONEY SUPPLY INSTRUMENTS: ON THE IMPLEMENTATION OF MARKOV-PERFECT OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY

WORKING PAPER NO INTEREST RATE VERSUS MONEY SUPPLY INSTRUMENTS: ON THE IMPLEMENTATION OF MARKOV-PERFECT OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY WORKING PAPER NO. 07-27 INTEREST RATE VERSUS MONEY SUPPLY INSTRUMENTS: ON THE IMPLEMENTATION OF MARKOV-PERFECT OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY Michael Dotsey Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Andreas Hornstein

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 2011 This note describes very briefly how to conduct quantitative analysis on a linearized

More information

Online Appendix for Slow Information Diffusion and the Inertial Behavior of Durable Consumption

Online Appendix for Slow Information Diffusion and the Inertial Behavior of Durable Consumption Online Appendix for Slow Information Diffusion and the Inertial Behavior of Durable Consumption Yulei Luo The University of Hong Kong Jun Nie Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Eric R. Young University

More information

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 December 14, 2006 Exercise 1 A Households Households maximise their intertemporal utility function by optimally choosing consumption, savings, and the mix of

More information

Expectation Formation and Rationally Inattentive Forecasters

Expectation Formation and Rationally Inattentive Forecasters Expectation Formation and Rationally Inattentive Forecasters Javier Turén UCL October 8, 016 Abstract How agents form their expectations is still a highly debatable question. While the existing evidence

More information

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 36 I Motivation This Lecture considers some applications

More information

Assessing Structural VAR s

Assessing Structural VAR s ... Assessing Structural VAR s by Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Robert Vigfusson Minneapolis, August 2005 1 Background In Principle, Impulse Response Functions from SVARs are useful as

More information

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro Stagnation Traps Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro May 2015 Research question and motivation Can insu cient aggregate demand lead to economic stagnation? This question goes back, at least, to the Great

More information

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano Foundations for the New Keynesian Model Lawrence J. Christiano Objective Describe a very simple model economy with no monetary frictions. Describe its properties. markets work well Modify the model dlto

More information

Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies:

Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies: Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies: Explorations with a Dynamic General Equilibrium Model of Labor Earnings based on Heckman, Lochner and Taber, Review of Economic

More information

Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model

Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martín Uribe Duke University 1 Objective of the Paper: Within a mediumscale estimated model of the macroeconomy

More information

New Keynesian Macroeconomics

New Keynesian Macroeconomics New Keynesian Macroeconomics Chapter 4: The New Keynesian Baseline Model (continued) Prof. Dr. Kai Carstensen Ifo Institute for Economic Research and LMU Munich May 21, 212 Prof. Dr. Kai Carstensen (LMU

More information

News Driven Business Cycles in Heterogenous Agents Economies

News Driven Business Cycles in Heterogenous Agents Economies News Driven Business Cycles in Heterogenous Agents Economies Paul Beaudry and Franck Portier DRAFT February 9 Abstract We present a new propagation mechanism for news shocks in dynamic general equilibrium

More information

Learning and Global Dynamics

Learning and Global Dynamics Learning and Global Dynamics James Bullard 10 February 2007 Learning and global dynamics The paper for this lecture is Liquidity Traps, Learning and Stagnation, by George Evans, Eran Guse, and Seppo Honkapohja.

More information

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. Ph.D. Core Exam -- Macroeconomics 5 January 2015 -- 8:00 am to 3:00 pm Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. A1 (required): Ending Quantitative Easing Now that the U.S.

More information

Assessing Structural VAR s

Assessing Structural VAR s ... Assessing Structural VAR s by Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Robert Vigfusson Yale, October 2005 1 Background Structural Vector Autoregressions Can be Used to Address the Following Type

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital. Lawrence J. Christiano

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital. Lawrence J. Christiano Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano Outline Formulate the nonlinear equilibrium conditions of the model. Need actual nonlinear conditions to study Ramsey optimal policy, even

More information

Introduction to Macroeconomics

Introduction to Macroeconomics Introduction to Macroeconomics Martin Ellison Nuffi eld College Michaelmas Term 2018 Martin Ellison (Nuffi eld) Introduction Michaelmas Term 2018 1 / 39 Macroeconomics is Dynamic Decisions are taken over

More information

Potential Output, the Output Gap, and the Labor Wedge

Potential Output, the Output Gap, and the Labor Wedge Potential Output, the Output Gap, and the Labor Wedge Luca Sala Ulf Söderström Antonella Trigari March 1 Preliminary and incomplete Abstract We estimate a monetary business cycle model on post-war U.S.

More information

A t = B A F (φ A t K t, N A t X t ) S t = B S F (φ S t K t, N S t X t ) M t + δk + K = B M F (φ M t K t, N M t X t )

A t = B A F (φ A t K t, N A t X t ) S t = B S F (φ S t K t, N S t X t ) M t + δk + K = B M F (φ M t K t, N M t X t ) Notes on Kongsamut et al. (2001) The goal of this model is to be consistent with the Kaldor facts (constancy of growth rates, capital shares, capital-output ratios) and the Kuznets facts (employment in

More information

The Propagation of Monetary Policy Shocks in a Heterogeneous Production Economy

The Propagation of Monetary Policy Shocks in a Heterogeneous Production Economy The Propagation of Monetary Policy Shocks in a Heterogeneous Production Economy E. Pasten 1 R. Schoenle 2 M. Weber 3 1 Banco Central de Chile and Toulouse University 2 Brandeis University 3 Chicago Booth

More information

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models Fall 22 Contents Introduction 2. An illustrative example........................... 2.2 Discussion...................................

More information

Inference. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Inference. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania Inference Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania 1 A Model with Sticky Price and Sticky Wage Household j [0, 1] maximizes utility function: X E 0 β t t=0 G t ³ C j t 1 1 σ 1 1 σ ³ N j t

More information

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations Chapter 4 Applications/Variations 149 4.1 Consumption Smoothing 4.1.1 The Intertemporal Budget Economic Growth: Lecture Notes For any given sequence of interest rates {R t } t=0, pick an arbitrary q 0

More information

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction Dynamic Optimization An Introduction M. C. Sunny Wong University of San Francisco University of Houston, June 20, 2014 Outline 1 Background What is Optimization? EITM: The Importance of Optimization 2

More information

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010 The Basic New Keynesian Model by Jordi Galí November 2 Motivation and Outline Evidence on Money, Output, and Prices: Short Run E ects of Monetary Policy Shocks (i) persistent e ects on real variables (ii)

More information

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Spring 2016 Karl Whelan (UCD) Real Business Cycles Spring 2016 1 / 38 Working Through A DSGE Model We have

More information

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017 Lecture 15 Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017 Universidad de Costa Rica EC3201 - Teoría Macroeconómica 2 Table of contents

More information

High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics. Thomas M. Mertens

High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics. Thomas M. Mertens High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics Thomas M. Mertens NYU Stern Risk Economics Lab April 17, 2012 1 / 78 Motivation Many problems in finance and economics are high dimensional. Dynamic Optimization:

More information

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Foundations of the Sticky Wage Approach and a Critical Commentary

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Foundations of the Sticky Wage Approach and a Critical Commentary The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Foundations of the Sticky Wage Approach and a Critical Commentary Lawrence J. Christiano March 30, 2013 Baseline developed earlier: NK model with no capital

More information

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Government Purchases and Endogenous Growth Consider the following endogenous growth model with government purchases (G) in continuous time. Government purchases enhance production, and the production

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Business Cycle Accounting and Wedges

Graduate Macro Theory II: Business Cycle Accounting and Wedges Graduate Macro Theory II: Business Cycle Accounting and Wedges Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 2017 1 Introduction Most modern dynamic macro models have at their core a prototypical real business

More information

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University Lecture 7 The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter 2013 Phillips Department of Economics Lakehead University 7.1 Outline 1 2 3 4 5 Phillips Phillips 7.2 Market Equilibrium:

More information

DSGE Models in a Liquidity Trap and Japan s Lost Decade

DSGE Models in a Liquidity Trap and Japan s Lost Decade DSGE Models in a Liquidity Trap and Japan s Lost Decade Koiti Yano Economic and Social Research Institute ESRI International Conference 2009 June 29, 2009 1 / 27 Definition of a Liquidity Trap Terminology

More information

Problem Set 4. Graduate Macro II, Spring 2011 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims

Problem Set 4. Graduate Macro II, Spring 2011 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims Problem Set 4 Graduate Macro II, Spring 2011 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims Instructions: You may consult with other members of the class, but please make sure to turn in your own work. Where

More information