On Pure-Strategy Nash Equilibria in Price-Quantity Games

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "On Pure-Strategy Nash Equilibria in Price-Quantity Games"

Transcription

1 On Pure-Strategy Nash Equilibria in Price-Quantity Games Iwan Bos Dries Vermeulen April 5, 2016 Abstract This paper examines the existence and characteristics of pure-strategy Nash equilibria in oligopoly models in which firms simultaneously set prices and quantities. Existence is proved for a broad and natural class of price-quantity games. With differentiated products, the equilibrium outcome is similar to that of a price-only model. With undifferentiated products and limited spillover demand, there are rationing equilibria in which combined production falls short of market demand. Moreover, there might again be an equilibrium reflecting the outcome of a price game. Competition in price and quantity thus yields Bertrand outcomes under a wide variety of market conditions. Keywords: Bertrand Oligopoly; Bertrand-Edgeworth Competition; Cournot Oligopoly; Oligopoly Theory; Price-Quantity Competition. JEL Codes: D4; L1. We appreciate the comments of Attila Tasnádi, participants at the 2015 Oligo Workshop (Carlos III University of Madrid), the 2015 Society for Economic Design Conference (Istanbul Bilgi University), the 2015 European Association for Research in Industrial Economics Conference (Ludwig-Maximilians University Munich) and seminar participants at the University of East Anglia (Norwich, UK) and the University of Exeter (Exeter, UK). All opinions and errors are ours alone. Department of Organization & Strategy, Maastricht University. Corresponding author at: P.O. Box 616, 6200 MD Maastricht, The Netherlands. i.bos@maastrichtuniversity.nl. Department of Quantitative Economics, Maastricht University. 1

2 1 Introduction Imagine a remote village with two bakeries baking breads that are close substitutes in the eyes of the villagers. If this was a Cournot market, then both bakers would decide how much bread to bake and bring to the marketplace. An auctioneer would be waiting there to set the price in such a way that market demand equals the total amount offered. If, instead, this was a Bertrand market, then each bakery would set its selling price and wait for customers. After the realization of demand, both would be obliged to bake exactly the amount of bread their clients are asking for. A glance at reality shows, however, that such a bread market is neither a Cournot nor a Bertrand market. 1 It is not a Cournot market as bakeries commonly choose their own prices, but it is not a Bertrand market either as it is usually up to the bakers to decide how much bread to make. More generally, in free-market societies there typically is no law telling firms how much to supply and what price to charge. 2 A natural assumption in theories of oligopoly would therefore be that firms choose both their price and quantity of output. Edgeworth (1922, 1925). 3 The foundation for this type of analysis is due to Francis He recognized that price-setting oligopolists may be unable or unwilling to meet their demand. For example, an undertaking might not be able to generate sufficient supplies when there is a shortage and it is already producing at capacity. Similarly, it can be de facto capacity-constrained when production precedes sales and cannot be boosted instantly. Also, even when a firm has the ability, it will lack the incentive to satisfy all its customers when demand exceeds its competitive supply. 4 As is well-known, the disturbing conclusion of Edgeworth s explorations was that oligopoly prices are essentially indeterminate. In more modern language, we would say that no pure-strategy Nash equilibrium exists. This non-existence problem received much attention ever since and has been demonstrated in a variety of settings where firms compete in prices and quantities. It is often conjectured that the non-existence problem is, at least in part, driven by the frequently used homogeneous goods assumption as it gives rise to discontinuities in demand. In fact, Edgeworth himself hypothesized the degree of indeterminateness to diminish with an increase in product differentiation. 5 generally yield a solution. Assuming imperfect substitutes does, however, not Price-quantity games with heterogeneous products have been studied by Shapley and Shubik (1969), Alger (1979), Friedman (1988), Benassy (1989) and 1 For a detailed discussion of classical models of oligopoly, see Vives (1999). 2 Evidently, there may be regulated markets, but these are the exception rather than the rule. 3 The original version of his 1925-paper dates back to This may occur when firms cost functions exhibit decreasing returns to scale. Edgeworth (1922) studies the case of quadratic costs, whereas capacity constraints are considered in Edgeworth (1925). 5 See Edgeworth (1925, p. 121). 2

3 Canoy (1996). Under a variety of cost and demand conditions, all establish that the problem of non-existence remains for industries with a few firms selling sufficiently close substitutes. In this paper, we re-examine price-quantity competition in oligopolies. 6 Specifically, our purpose is to shed light on the non-existence problem by presenting conditions under which a pure-strategy equilibrium does and does not exist. We consider price-quantity games with continuous as well as discontinuous demand in terms of the own prices. The first is characteristic for differentiated goods, whereas the second applies to perfect substitutes. For both cases, we establish that there is a broad and natural class of price-quantity games with a pure-strategy equilibrium. Additionally, we are able to characterize these equilibria. With differentiated products, the equilibrium is shown to coincide with that of a basic Bertrand model. Moreover, and contrary to previous findings, its existence need not directly depend on the number of firms or the degree of differentiation. With discontinuous demand, equilibria come in two types. First, there is a range of rationing equilibria in which combined production falls short of market demand. This result is surprising as it has long been argued that the competitive outcome would be the only equilibrium candidate. 7 Although we do find that firms in equilibrium price at marginal costs, these prices are typically too low to ensure saturation of the market. Second, there may again be an equilibrium reflecting the outcome of a price-only model. Therefore, our analysis additionally provides a foundation for Bertrand price models. The non-existence problem pertains to pure-strategy Nash equilibria. Mixed-strategy equilibria have been repeatedly shown to exist under a variety of assumptions. 8 Mixed equilibria are, however, problematic within this context for at least two reasons. Perhaps the most prominent problem is simply that it is at odds with reality. Indeed, butchers, brewers or bakers typically do not roll dice to determine their prices or quantities of output. This is especially cumbersome when considering repeated interaction among firms. 9 Another issue 6 Regarding price-quantity models, it is not uncommon in the literature to distinguish between, on the one hand, production to order or Bertrand-Edgeworth competition and, on the other hand, production in advance (see, e.g., Shubik (1955, 1960), Maskin (1986) or Tasnádi (2004)). In case of the former, production takes place after the realization of demand, whereas in case of the latter production precedes sales. All results derived in this paper apply equally well to both cases. 7 See the pioneering works of Shubik (1955, 1960) and, in particular, Theorem 2 in Shubik (1960, p. 100). 8 See, among others, Levitan and Shubik (1972), Dixon (1984), Gertner (1986), Maskin (1986) and Tasnádi (2004). 9 In this regard, Friedman (1988, p. 608) stated that:... a deep understanding of oligopolistic behavior cannot be achieved by means of singleperiod models with results that are unreasonable in a multiperiod setting. This article is intended as a prelude to the study of dynamic models. Mixed strategies, under which prices and outputs are randomly selected in each period, seem bizarre in an infinite-horizon oligopoly. 3

4 is that models of oligopoly become significantly more complicated when allowing for random strategies. In particular, it is often difficult to provide an explicit characterization of mixedstrategy equilibria. As such, this concept is of limited use in applied research on oligopolistic industries. The next section gives a general outline of the model and offers some preliminary insights that serve as a basis for the ensuing study. The main analysis and results are presented in sections 3 and 4. Section 3 considers price-quantity competition with continuous demand, whereas the discontinuous demand case is described in Section 4. A few illustrative examples are presented in Section 5. Section 6 concludes. 2 A Model of Price-Quantity Competition In this section, we lay out the basics of our price-quantity oligopoly model. It is assumed there are n 2 profit-maximizing firms where the set of firms is N = {1,..., n}. Each firm i N simultaneously picks a price-quantity pair (p i, q i ), with p i 0 and q i 0. Let the vector of prices and quantities be respectively given by p = (p 1,..., p n ) and q = (q 1,..., q n ). Moreover, p i = (p j ) j i and q i = (q j ) j i. Given the price-quantity choices of competitors, demand for the products of firm i is denoted D i (p i, p i, q i ). Firm i s cost of production is given by C i (q i ), which is a strictly increasing continuous function of its own output q i. Both the demand and cost structure will be further specified below. The firm s objective is then to pick a profit-maximizing price-quantity pair: max Π i (p, q) = p i s i (p, q) C i (q i ), i N, (1) p i,q i where s i (p, q) denotes firm i s sales. It is clear that a firm cannot offer more than it produces and cannot sell more than is demanded. Therefore, sales equals the minimum of production and demand: 10 s i (p, q) = min {q i, D i (p i, p i, q i )}. A price-quantity pair (p i, q i ) is firm i s best response to (p i, q i ) when for each choice ( p i, q i ) it holds that Π i (p i, q i, p i, q i ) Π i ( p i, q i, p i, q i ). 10 Note that, due to the profit-maximizing assumption, firms bring all produced quantities to the market. Additionally, they will not produce more than the profit-maximizing output at the price set. This condition, albeit more general, therefore effectively coincides with the voluntary-trading constraint in standard Bertrand- Edgeworth settings. 4

5 The above specifications are sufficient to show the following basic and useful result stating that none of the firms find it optimal to produce in excess of demand. Lemma 1. For all i N, a strategy (p i, q i ) for which q i > D i (p i, p i, q i ) is not a best response to (p i, q i ). Proof Suppose that (p i, q i ) is firm i s best response to (p i, q i ) and suppose further that q i > D i (p i, p i, q i ). Since s i = min{q i, D i (p i, p i, q i )}, it holds that s i = D i (p i, p i, q i ). Now define q i = q i + D i (p i, p i, q i ). 2 As C i is continuous and strictly increasing, it follows that C i (q i ) > C i ( q i ). Combining with s i = D i (p i, p i, q i ), this implies Π i (p i, q i, p i, q i ) < Π i (p i, q i, p i, q i ), which contradicts the assumption of (p i, q i ) being a best response. In light of the purpose of this study, we restrict ourselves in the following to pure-strategy Nash equilibria. A price-quantity vector (p, q) is an equilibrium when for all i N and each choice ( p i, q i ) it holds that Π i (p i, q i, p i, q i ) Π i ( p i, q i, p i, q i ). Lemma 1 excludes the possibility that in equilibrium a firm operates above its demand curve. As will become clear in the ensuing analysis, and depending on the specifics of the model, the two other types of outcome might occur in equilibrium. Akin to the Bertrand model, all firms may choose to meet their demand at the price set. Alternatively, one or more firms may find it optimal to satisfy only a subset of their consumers. To indicate these possibilities, we will use the following definitions: An equilibrium (p, q ) is a Bertrand equilibrium when (p i, q i ) is a solution to: subject to max p i Π i (p i, q i, p i, q i) = p i s i (p i, q i, p i, q i) C i (q i ), q i = D i (p i, p i, q i ), i N. An equilibrium (p, q ) is a rationing equilibrium when q i D i (p i, p i, q i ) for each firm i and qj < D j(p j, p j, q j ) for at least one firm j. 5

6 3 Price-Quantity Competition with Continuous Demand Let us begin by considering price-quantity competition with differentiated products. If goods are less than perfect substitutes, firms typically do not lose their entire clientele when setting their price just above that of the competition. In a similar vein, slightly undercutting rivals prices is unlikely to yield the market. To capture this idea that small changes should have small effects, it is natural to think of demand as a continuous function of prices. Hotelling (1929, p. 44) formulated this as follows:...a discontinuity, like a vacuum, is abhorred by nature. More typical of real situations is the case in which the quantity sold by each merchant is a continuous function of two variables, his own price and his competitor s. Quite commonly, a tiny increase in price by one seller will send only a few customers to the other. To formalize, let Z i (p i, q i )(p i ) = D i (p i, p i, q i ) be the (residual) demand of firm i and let p i be the firm s marginal costs at zero output. We start by making the following assumptions on demand and cost. For all (p i, q i ) and i N: A1 Z i (p i, q i )(p i ) is continuous and non-increasing in p i. A2 Z i (p i, q i )(p i ) > 0. A3 C i (q i ) is differentiable and C i (0) = 0. Moreover, C i (q i) is continuous and non-decreasing with C i (q i) > 0 at all q i > 0. A1 reflects the law of demand for firm i s product. A2 and A3 together ensure that firms have an incentive to be productive. In particular, note that p i C i (0) and that cost functions are assumed to exhibit constant or decreasing returns to scale. Because both price and quantity are decision variables, it is in principle possible that production and demand do not coincide. Recall, however, that overproduction will not occur in equilibrium (Lemma 1). As the next result shows, the properties A1-A3 are sufficient to show that, in equilibrium, shortages will not occur either. Moreover, equilibrium profits are strictly positive. Lemma 2. Under A1-A3, all equilibria are Bertrand equilibria and equilibrium profits are strictly positive. 6

7 Proof Suppose that (p i, q i ) is a best reply of firm i to (p i, q i ). For an equilibrium to be a Bertrand equilibrium it must hold that q i = D i (p, q i ) for all i N. By Lemma 1, we know that q i > D i (p, q i ) cannot occur in equilibrium. Therefore, it remains to be shown that q i < D i (p, q i ) cannot occur either. Towards that end, we assume q i < D i (p, q i ) and derive a contradiction. To begin, we show that equilibrium profits are strictly positive. By A2, there is a price p i > p i with D i ( p i, p i, q i ) > 0. Because marginal cost functions are continuous and nondecreasing by A3, there exists a q i > 0 such that C i ( q i) < p i and D i ( p i, p i, q i ) > q i. As C i (q i) < p i for all q i < q i and C i (0) = 0 by A3, taking integrals on both sides of the inequality over the range [0, q i ] gives C i ( q i ) < p i q i. Since s i ( p i, q i, p i, q i ) = q i, we conclude that Π i ( p i, q i, p i, q i ) > 0. Thus, equilibrium profits are strictly positive. By the preceding argument, we can exclude the possibility that a firm s best response is to produce nothing, i.e., q i = 0 cannot occur in equilibrium. Therefore, suppose that 0 < q i < D i (p i, p i, q i ). By A1, there exists a ε > 0 such that for p i = p i + ε it still holds that q i < D i ( p i, p i, q i ). However, this implies Π i ( p i, q i, p i, q i ) = p i q i C i (q i ) > p i q i C i (q i ) = Π i (p i, q i, p i, q i ), which contradicts (p i, q i ) being a best reply of firm i to (p i, q i ). We conclude that in equilibrium it must hold that q i = D i (p, q i ), for all i N. A best reply (p i, q i ) of firm i to (p i, q i ) thus satisfies q i = D i (p i, p i, q i ). Consequently, (p i, q i ) is a best reply to (p i, q i ) precisely when p i maximizes R i (p i ) := p i D i (p i, p i, q i ) C i (D i (p i, p i, q i )) and q i = D i(p i, p i, q i ). Hence, all equilibria are Bertrand equilibria. Firms thus have a strict preference for price-quantity pairs on their demand curve; a finding that appears to be very robust. Indeed, it has repeatedly been found to hold under a variety of mild conditions. 11 This result greatly reduces the number of equilibrium candidates and is commonly taken as a basis for establishing non-existence of an equilibrium. By contrast, we will now use it as a foundation for proving existence. Towards that end, we introduce two assumptions on demand. In stating these assumptions, let E i (p i, p i, q i ) be a function such that D i (p i, p i, q i ) = max{e i (p i, p i, q i ), 0}. 11 See, for instance, Alger (1979, Theorem 3.1), Friedman (1988, Lemma 3), Benassy (1989, Theorem 1) and Canoy (1996, Lemma 1). In the context of an evolutionary model, Khan and Peeters (2015) have recently shown that this outcome may also result from firms imitating the most profitable producer. 7

8 For all (p i, q i ) and i N: B1 E i (p i, p i, q i ) is continuously differentiable and non-increasing in p i. Moreover, ξ > 0 such that E i p i ξ < 0. B2 K > 0 such that D i (p i, p i, q i ) K. i N B1 is similar to A1, but adds the requirement that a firm s demand is differentiable with respect to its own price and that this derivative is bounded away from zero. B2 states that market demand is bounded. Together with assumptions A2 and A3, these two conditions are sufficient for showing existence. Theorem 3. Under A2-A3 and B1-B2, there exists at least one equilibrium. Proof By Lemma 2, we know that all equilibria are Bertrand equilibria. In particular, (p i, q i ) is a best reply to (p i, q i ) precisely when p i maximizes R i (p i ) := p i D i (p i, p i, q i ) C i (D i (p i, p i, q i )) and q i = D i (p i, p i, q i ). Using this fact, we now proceed in three steps to prove existence of a pure-strategy Nash equilibrium. Step 1. We show that there is a unique price p i > 0 that maximizes R i. To begin, we know by Lemma 2 that equilibrium profits are strictly positive. Consequently, a price that maximizes R i is strictly positive and D i = E i. Specifically, using A3 and B1, this profit-maximizing price is obtained by equating marginal revenue with marginal cost: Rearranging gives E i = E i p i [ dci p i E i + p i E i p i dc i E i p i = 0. ]. (2) We now compare the LHS of (2) with the RHS. Define A i (p i ) = E i (p i, p i, q i ). By B1 and A2, we know that A i is non-increasing and A i (0) > 0. We now analyze the RHS of (2). Define F i (p i ) = E i p i [ dci (E i (p i, p i, q i )) p i Let us first have a closer look at the part between square brackets. Define B i (p i ) = dc i (E i (p i, p i, q i )) p i. 8 ].

9 Since E i is non-increasing in p i by B1 and C i (q i) is strictly positive and non-decreasing by A3, it follows that G i (p i ) = dc i (E i (p i, p i, q i )) is strictly positive and non-increasing. As all functions involved are continuous, there is a unique p m i > 0 with G i (p m i ) = p m i. Thus, B i (p m i ) = 0 and B i(p i ) p i. Because E i p i < ξ by B1, it follows that F i (p m i ) = 0 and F i (p i ) ξ (p i p m i ), for all p i > p m i. Finally, combining the previous observations on A i and F i, there is a unique p i > p m i > 0 with A i (p i ) = F i(p i ). Since dr i dp i = A i F i, dr i dp i (p i ) = 0. Moreover, dr i dp i (p i ) > 0 for p i < p i and dr i dp i (p i ) < 0 for p i > p i. We conclude that p i is the unique maximizer of R i. For each firm i N and a given choice vector (p, q), we can now define f i (p, q) := p i. Before proceeding, let us define a function H : R 2n + R 2n + for each choice vector (p, q) R 2n + : H(p, q) = (f 1 (p, q),..., f n (p, q), D 1 (p, q 1 ),..., D n (p, q n )). Step 2. We show that there is a point (p, q ) with H(p, q ) = (p, q ). By B2, we know that E i (0, p i, q i ) K and by B1 we further know that E i (p i, p i, q i ) K + ξ p i. Therefore, 0 p i K ξ and, following B2, 0 D i(p i, p i, q i ) K. Define M = max{k, K ξ }. Then, for any choice vector (p, q), H(p, q) 2n M. Next, we argue that H is continuous. Recall that f i (p, q) := p i is the unique maximizer of R i (p i ) := p i D i (p i, p i, q i ) C i (D i (p i, p i, q i )). Because both D i and C i are continuous, the maximum principle implies continuity of f i. As the demand of each rival is also continuous, H is continuous. By the Brouwer Fixed Point Theorem, we then know there is a point (p, q ) with H(p, q ) = (p, q ). Step 3. We show that (p, q ) is an equilibrium. Since p i = f i(p, q ), p i maximizes the function R i (p i ) := p i D i (p i, p i, q i) C i (D i (p i, p i, q i)). 9

10 Moreover, qi = D i(p i, p i, q i ). Thus, (p i, q i ) is a best reply to (p i, q i ). As this holds for each firm i N, (p, q ) is an equilibrium. This finding complements the results of Benassy (1989). Under the assumption of symmetry, he established that (i) for a given number of firms, there does not exist an equilibrium when the degree of substitutability between heterogeneous goods is sufficiently high, and (ii) for a given level of imperfect substitutability, there does exist an equilibrium provided that the number of undertakings is sufficiently large. 12 Theorem 3 not only allows for asymmetry, but also admits demand curves to be very flat independent of market size. In particular, an equilibrium may also exist when a small number of sellers produce close but imperfect substitutes. Let us conclude this part of our analysis by showing conditions under which an equilibrium does not exists. The next demand property is, in conjunction with A1-A3, sufficient. For all (p i, q i ) and i N: C1 If (p, q) is such that q j = D j (p j, p j, q j ), for all j, then Z i (p i, q i )(p i ) has a left derivative L and a right derivative R at p i. Moreover, both derivatives are strictly negative and the right derivative is larger than the left derivative (i.e., L < R < 0). C1 states that residual demand Z i (p i, q i )(p i ) has a (convex) kink when firms meet their demand. Therefore, and in contrast to assumption B1 above, firms demand functions are not differentiable when C1 holds. Theorem 4. Under A1-A3 and C1, there exists no equilibrium. Proof Suppose that (p, q ) is an equilibrium. In the following, we derive a contradiction. To begin, note that by A1-A3 Lemma 2 applies so that each equilibrium is a Bertrand equilibrium, i.e., qi = D i(p i, p i, q i ) for each firm i N. Next, define Zi = Z i (p i, q i )(p i ) and consider firm i. By C1, there exists an ε > 0 and numbers X and Y with X < L < Y < R < 0 such that for all p i with p i ε < p i p i it holds that Z i (p i, q i )(p i) Zi X (p i p i ) and for all p i with p i p i < p i + ε it holds that Z i (p i, q i )(p i) Z i Y (p i p i ). 12 The first finding has been confirmed by Canoy (1996), whereas the second conclusion can also be found in Shapley and Shubik (1969). 10

11 Since X < Y, Z i (p i, q i )(p i) Zi X (p i p i ) for all p i with p i ε < p i < p i + ε. Thus, (p i, q i ) is a solution to the following optimization problem: max p i q i C i (q i ) subject to q i = Z i X (p i p i ) and p i ε < p i < p i + ε. Using these constraints, this implies that p i of the function: is a solution to the problem of finding a maximum h X (p i ) = p i (Z i X (p i p i )) C i (Z i X (p i p i )) with domain p i ε < p i < p i + ε. Taking the derivative with respect to p i gives dh X dp i (p i ) = Z i + X p i 2X p i + X dc i (Z i X (p i p i )). Following A3, it is easy to see that dh X dp i (p i ) is strictly decreasing. Consequently, the equation dh X dp i (p i ) = 0 has at most one solution, which is the unique maximum. As we already established that p i is a solution to the above optimization problem, it holds that dh X dp i (p i ) = 0 and this equation can be rewritten to p i = dc i (Zi ) + Z i X. In a similar fashion, it can be deduced that p i = dc i (Zi ) + Z i Y. Yet, as X < Y, both cannot hold simultaneously. We believe it is instructive to clarify how this finding compares to Friedman (1988), because he also established non-existence in a simultaneous-move price-quantity setting. 13 Following Friedman s Assumption 3, it is easy to verify that our cost conditions (A3) are satisfied with the exception of C i (0) = 0. Regarding the demand side, both A1 and C1 follow from his demand specifications. 14 Therefore, the only two conditions that are in some sense more restrictive are C i (0) = 0 and Z i (p i, q i )(p i ) > 0, for all i N (see assumptions A2 and A3). The key difference with Friedman (1988) is that he establishes non-existence of interior equilibria, but allows oligopoly models that may have equilibria in which some or all firms have zero production levels. Theorem 4 above also excludes equilibria on the boundary. That is, as we impose C i (0) = 0 and Z i (p i, q i )(p i ) > 0, for all i N, our analysis precludes any type of pure-strategy equilibrium; also ones where one or more firms produce nothing. In sum, this section presents sufficient conditions for the (non-)existence of a pure-strategy equilibrium in price-quantity games with continuous demand. Specifically, we have shown 13 See Friedman (1988, p. 611), Theorem Specifically, condition C1 follows from the observation that the left derivative in Friedman (1988) equals fi i (p) < 0, whereas the right derivative equals fi i (p) + j i f j i (p) < 0 and f j i (p) > 0, for all j i. 11

12 there is a broad and natural class of differentiated goods games with an equilibrium. This class is broad and natural in the sense that many well-known oligopoly models meet the required assumptions. A few standard textbook examples are presented in Section 5 of this paper. Moreover, all equilibria exhibit Bertrand behavior. Indeed, even though sellers have no obligation to satisfy the demand forthcoming to them, they are happy to do so. 4 Price-Quantity Competition with Discontinuous Demand Let us now direct our attention to price-quantity games with demand functions that are discontinuous in price. Discontinuous demand is characteristic of industries with undifferentiated products. Though arguably not as realistic as price-quantity competition with continuous demand, this case is of interest because it plays a central role in classical theories of oligopoly and remains popular today. To begin, let us list some assumptions on cost and demand that will hold throughout this section. For all (p i, q i ) and i N: D1 C i (q i ) is differentiable and C i (0) = 0. Moreover, C i (q i) is continuous and non-decreasing with C i (q i) > 0 at all q i > 0 and p i C i (0) = 0. D2 Z i (p i, q i )(p i ) is non-increasing in p i. D3 δ, κ > 0 such that for all p i δ with p i p j, j i, it holds that Z i (p i, q i )(p i ) > κ. Our assumptions on cost are comparable to the continuous demand analysis. Specifically, D1 is identical to A3, but the requirement that marginal costs are zero at zero output. Regarding residual demand, we impose D2, which is standard and a weaker version of A1. Finally, D3 ensures that each firm can guarantee itself demand by charging a sufficiently low price. 15 In general, the demand of each firm comprises direct and indirect or spillover demand. Note that in case goods are homogeneous, a firm faces direct demand only when there is no cheaper supplier in the market. Indeed, when consumers are only concerned with price, those that are not among the lowest-priced firms may only receive demand from unserved customers who still plan to purchase the product or service even at a higher price. In the following, the degree of spillover demand is captured by the parameter α [0, 1], where α = 1 allows for 15 This is ensured when demand is continuous and strictly positive at price zero. Yet, as this section deals with discontinuous demand, we need such a slightly more technical assumption. 12

13 complete spillover and α = 0 indicates the absence of spillover demand. Specifically, we make two additional assumptions on firm demand. For all (p i, q i ) and i N: D4 α > 0 such that for every (p, q) and i with p i = p j, for at least one j i, and for every p i with p i < p i it holds that Z i (p i, q i )(p i) α Z i (p i, q i )(p i ). D5 r i > 0 for which D i (r i, p i, q i ) = 0. D4 captures a certain type of consumer behavior. Specifically, it states that there is a fraction of at least 1 α of customers that base their decisions only on price and visit at most one firm. Furthermore, note that any demand function that satisfies D4 for α < 1 is automatically discontinuous. D5 in some sense mirrors D3 by imposing a choke price. That is, each firm will find itself without customers when it charges a sufficiently high price. These assumptions are sufficient to show the existence of a pure-strategy equilibrium in which at least one firm does not meet its demand, i.e., there are rationing equilibria. Theorem 5. Under D1-D5, ᾱ (0, 1) such that α < ᾱ rationing equilibria exist. Proof Consider a fixed quantity ˆQ > 0 and let ˆP = min i { dc i ( ˆQ)}. By D1, we know that dc i ( ˆQ) > 0 for each firm i N and therefore ˆP > 0. Next, consider a value P with 0 < P < ˆP. By D1 and the definition of ˆP, we know there is a quantity q i (P ) with dc i (q i (P )) = P. Now take δ > 0 and κ > 0 as in D3. By D1, there exists a P > 0 with (i) P < ˆP, (ii) P δ and (iii) q j (P ) < κ, j. Next, we write p i = P and q i = q i(p ) and argue that is an equilibrium. (p, q ) = (P,..., P, q 1,..., q n) Consider firm i and let the strategies of the other firms be as given above. We will argue in three steps that (P, qi ) is a best response. Step 1. We show that q i < D i(p, q i ). Note that 0 < p i = P δ. So, following D3, D i (p, q i ) > κ and therefore q i = q j (P ) < κ < D i (p, q i ). Step 2. Let (p i, q i ) be any best response. We show that p i = P. 13

14 Suppose p i < P. We derive a contradiction. We first argue that q i < q i. Since p i < P = p i, D i (p, q i) = Z i (p i, q i)(p i ) Z i (p i, q i)(p i ) = D i (p i, p i, q i), by D2. By Step 1, therefore, q i < D i(p, q i ) D i(p i, p i, q i ). Consider the function f i (q i ) = p i q i C i (q i ). This function is concave in q i, with derivative f i (q i) = p i dc i (q i ). Notice that f i(q i ) = p i dc i (q i ) = p i dc i (q i (P )) = p i P < 0. Thus, since q i is a best choice given p i, it holds that p i = dc i (q i ). Then dc i (q i ) = p i < P = dc i (q i ), or dc i (q i ) < dc i (q i ). So, since dc i is non-decreasing, q i < q i. We argue that (p i, q i) is a strictly better choice than (p i, q i ). Since q i < qi, we know by Step 1 that q i < D i (p, q i ). Hence, Π i (p i, q i, p i, q i) = p i q i C i (q i ) < p i q i C i (q i ) = Π(p i, q i, p i, q i). We show that p i = P. By the analysis above, we know that p i P. Suppose (p i, q i ) is such that p i > P. Write Π i = p i q i C i (q i ). By Step 1, Π i is the profit for firm i corresponding to (p, q ). Let r i be as in D5 and suppose Π that α < i r i D i (p,q i ). We show that (p i, q i ) yields a strictly higher payoff than (p i, q i ). Since p i > P, using D4 to get the second inequality, the resulting profit of (p i, q i ) is Π i (p i, q i, p i, q i) = p i s i (p i, q i, p i, q i) C i (q i ) We conclude that p i = P. Step 3. p i D i (p i, p i, q i) r i α D i (p, q i) Π i < r i r i D i (p, q i ) D i(p, q i) = Π i. Given p i = P, we show that the quantity q i maximizes profit. Consider the function g i (q i ) = p i q i C i (q i ). This function is concave in q i, with derivative g i (q i) = p i dc i (q i ). Then, by the definition of q i, g i (q i ) = 0. So, since q i < D i(p, q i ) by 14

15 Step 1, q i indeed maximizes the profit function of firm i given price p i. This completes the proof that (p, q ) is an equilibrium. Finally, note that, for any choice of P as above, the corresponding quantity q i is strictly less than the demand for firm i s products. Thus, there exists rationing equilibria for α sufficiently small. The above result shows there are pure-strategy solutions when spillover demand is not too strong. The logic behind this result is as follows. On the one hand, none of the firms should have an incentive to cut price. Clearly, a price cut will be profitable only when it generates sufficient additional sales. Since firms are operating on their competitive supply curve, however, none of them would be willing to serve more demand. Indeed, when firms are already unwilling to meet demand at the going price, shortages would be even larger at lower prices. On the other hand, none of the firms should have an incentive to elevate prices. This is the case when a price increase would result in a sufficient drop of sales. In the context of our model, this implies that spillover demand as reflected by α must be sufficiently small. It is noteworthy that this significant drop in demand requirement is at the heart of various known existence solutions to the Edgeworth paradox. 16 What is more surprising is the type of equilibrium. In particular, there is an interesting contrast with the pioneering work of Shubik (1955, 1960). Even though he did not solve the Edgeworth paradox, he did establish the efficient point as the sole equilibrium candidate. 17 In the efficient point, firms price at marginal cost and saturate the market. The above result confirms the first requirement (i.e., firms indeed produce at a level where price equals marginal cost), but not the second. That is, sellers may not meet their demand at the price set and satisfy only part of their customers in equilibrium. In particular, and as reflected by equilibrium rationing, market prices might be too low to be efficient. To be clear, this is not to say that the efficient point is never an equilibrium. In fact, with identical technologies and absent spillover demand, there does exist a Bertrand equilibrium. In accordance with Theorem 5, however, there also still is a range of rationing equilibria. Theorem 6. Assume α = 0 and C i (q i ) = C(q i ), i N. There exists a set of symmetric equilibria. Precisely one of these equilibria is a Bertrand equilibrium. The remaining equilibria are rationing equilibria. 16 See, among others, Levitan and Shubik (1972) and Dixon (1990, 1992). The underlying logic can already be found in Shubik (1955, 1960). More recently, Tasnádi (1999) proves the existence of a pure-strategy equilibrium when demand is sufficiently elastic. 17 See Theorem 2 in Shubik (1960, p. 100). 15

16 Proof Using the symmetry conditions, all equilibria (p, q ) = (P,..., P, q 1,..., q n) from Theorem 5 reduce to (P,..., P, Q,..., Q ). In this case, Q D i (p, q i ). All equilibria with Q < D i (p, q i ) are rationing equilibria. The equilibrium with Q = D i (p, q i ) is a Bertrand equilibrium. Similar to the previous section, let us conclude this part by presenting a non-existence result. Towards that end, we introduce the following two assumptions. For all i N: E1 If (p, q) is such that q j D j (p, q j ), j, then there is an ε > 0 and K > 0 such that for each p i with p i < p i < p i + ε it holds that Z i (p i, q i )(p i) Z i (p i, q i )(p i ) K (p i p i ). E2 If q j D j (p, q j ), j, and p i < p i, then D i (p i, p i, q i ) D i (p, q i ) + D j (p, q j ) for each p j p i, j i. Property E1 captures a spillover effect. It states that a seller who raises his price slightly will not lose too much demand when his competitors are capacity-constrained. One can imagine consumers to accept a somewhat higher price when they cannot get the product or service somewhere else. Notice that as Z i (p i, q i )(p i ) is non-increasing by D2, Z i (p i, q i )(p i ) is right-continuous at p i. E2 ensures that buyers visit the lowest-priced firms first. They may visit a higher-priced firm, but only when the cheapest suppliers produce strictly less than their demand. E2 thus forces the demand function to be discontinuous. Together with some of the previous assumptions, these conditions are sufficient to undermine the existence of an equilibrium. Theorem 7. Under D1-D3 and E1-E2, there exists no equilibrium. Proof Assume that (p, q ) is an equilibrium. We proceed in five steps to derive a contradiction. Step 1. We show that Π i (p, q ) > 0, for all i. 16

17 Consider a firm i. Given (p i, q i ) it is sufficient to show that there exists a strategy (p i, q i ) for which firm i s profits are strictly positive. Suppose p i = 0 so that firm i has at most zero profits. By D2 and E1, we know that Z i (p i, q i )(p i) is right-continuous at p i = 0. As Z i(p i, q i )(0) > 0 by D3, there is a p i > 0 with Z i (p i, q i )(p i) > 0. Moreover, C i (0) = 0 by D1 and dc i (0) = 0 by D1. Consequently, firm i s profits are strictly positive for q i sufficiently small; a contradiction. Suppose now that p j > 0, for all j, and assume that δ and κ are as in D3. Furthermore, define ε = min{δ, p j j i}. Observe that ε > 0. Hence, and following D1, there is an η > 0 with C i (q i ) < ε q i for all q i η. Next, define p i = ε and q i = min{η, κ}. Thus, q i κ < D i ( p i, p i, q i ) and therefore s i = q i. Moreover, 0 < q i η so that C i ( q i ) < ε q i. In turn, this implies Π i ( p i, q i, p i, q i ) = p i q i C i ( q i ) = ε q i C i ( q i ) > 0. We conclude that equilibrium profits of all firms are strictly positive. Step 2. We show that qi = D i(p, q i ), for all i. By Lemma 1, q j D j(p, q j ), for all j. Suppose now that q i < D i (p, q i ). Since q j D j (p, q j ), for all j, Z i(p i, q i )(p i) is right-continuous at p i by assumptions D2 and E1. Thus, firm i can increase its payoff by raising its price slightly, while still selling the same amount q i as at p i. Step 3. We show that p i C i (q i ), for all i. Consider a firm i and notice that, for a given price p i, q i solves: max p i q i C i (q i ) subject to 0 q i D i (p, q i ). By D1, the objective function is concave in q i. At q i, we then either have that q i < D i(p, q i ) and p i = dc i (qi ) or q i = D i (p, q i ) and p i dc i (qi ). By Step 2, we know that q i = D i (p, q i ) and therefore p i C i (q i ). 17

18 Step 4. We show that p i C i (q i ), for all i. Consider a firm i and suppose that p i = dc i (qi ). Following Step 2, we can choose ε > 0 and K > 0 such that E1 holds. Let L > K and consider the following optimization problem: max p i q i C i (q i ) Using Lagrange, it must hold that subject to q i = Z i (p, q )(p i ) L (p i p i ) and p i p i. p i = dc i (q i ) + q i L. Notice that by D1, if q i > q i, then p i > p i. Furthermore, by picking q i > q i sufficiently close to q i and by choosing L sufficiently large, we can ensure that p i = dc i (q i ) + q i L < dc i (q i ) + ε 2 + q i L < p i + ε. For this choice, therefore, the profit at (p i, q i ) is strictly larger than at (p i, q i ) provided that firm i will sell its entire production, q i. Note that by our choice of ε and K it holds that: Z i (p i, q i)(p i ) Z i (p i, q i)(p i ) K (p i p i ) > Z i (p, q )(p i ) L (p i p i ) = q i. Thus, firm i will indeed sell all its output. Step 5. Suppose that p i p j, j. We construct p i and q i such that Π i(p i, p i, q i, q i ) > Π i(p i, p i, q i, q i ). Let us first define q i. As there are at least two firms, there is at least one firm j with p i p j. By Step 1, we know that p i > 0 and by Step 2 we know that q j D j (p, q j ), for all j. Now consider a price p i < p i, which by E2 means that: D i (p i, p i, q i) D i (p, q i) + D j (p, q j). Define A = D j (p, q j ). Note that by Step 1, A > 0. Moreover, we know by Step 2 that qi = D i(p, q i ) and by Step 3 and 4 that p i > dc i (qi ). Thus, because dc i is continuous in q i by D1, we can take q i > q i such that dc i (q i ) < p i and q i < D i(p, q i ) + A. Next, let us define p i. Given p i, define the function F i (q i ) = p i q i C i (q i ). 18

19 Following D1, F i is concave and F i (0) = 0. Furthermore, F i (q i ) is strictly increasing as long as p i > dc i (q i ). Since q i > q i and dc i (q i ) < p i, it follows that F i (q i) > F i (q i ). Notice that when p i converges to p i, the expression p i q i C i (q i). converges to p i q i C i(q i ) = F i(q i ). We can therefore choose p i < p i such that p i q i C i (q i) > F i (q i ). Finally, suppose that firm i charges price p i and produces quantity q i. Observe that D i (p i, p i, q i) = D i (p i, p i, q i) D i (p, q i) + A > q i. As q i < D i(p i, p i, q i ), it follows that Π i (p i, p i, q i, q i) = p i q i C i (q i) > F i (q i ) = Π i (p, q ). Thus, we conclude that (p i, q i ) is not a best response against (p i, q i ), which contradicts the assumption that (p, q ) is an equilibrium. The intuition behind this result is similar to the one underlying the original analyses of Edgeworth. Moreover, and unlike the continuous demand case, Theorems 5 and 6 show that with discontinuous demand it is the degree of spillover that plays a critical role in establishing existence. Specifically, firms have no incentive to put their focus on indirect rather than direct demand when spillover is sufficiently small. The willingness to fight for direct demand will be strong when, for example, a substantial part of unlucky customers prefers to leave the market after having failed to obtain the product or service directly. Also, it might be suspected that spillover demand will not endure in fairly stable markets. Under the assumption that time is valuable and transportation costly, it seems evidently suboptimal for customers to repeatedly receive their product indirectly. In other words, one would expect indirect demand to diminish in cases where the same customers are served each period. 18 Let us conclude this section with a note on costs. Recall that our assumptions on production technologies are the same as in the continuous demand analysis with the exception of p i 18 This suggests that spillover demand is more likely to last when products are sold on a first-come-first-served basis rather than under efficient rationing or any other situation where the same customers are (un)served. 19

20 C i (0) = 0, i.e., marginal costs are zero at zero output. The latter ensures that all firms are productive in equilibrium, but also excludes the possibility that marginal costs are constant at all output levels. In that particular case, our findings would be different, although the underlying logic remains. One notable difference is that, under the assumption that firms choose to meet their demand in case of zero economic profits, rationing equilibria will no longer exist leaving Bertrand-like outcomes as the only equilibrium candidates. Results, in this case, have more of an all-or-nothing flavor. With heterogeneous costs, it will be the lowest-cost firm that serves the entire market. With identical cost functions, by contrast, an equilibrium exists when there is no spillover demand (i.e., when α = 0). Note that this latter outcome is equivalent to the traditional Bertrand-Nash equilibrium. 5 Examples Let us now illustrate our main findings with a few representative examples. In this section, we present five cases; the first three of which deal with a differentiated duopoly. Example 1 serves to show how equilibrium prices and quantities can be derived in a well-known textbook model. Example 2 illustrates how an equilibrium may fail to exist when demand is nondifferentiable (a violation of assumption B1), whereas Example 3 shows that an equilibrium may still exist when demand functions exhibit a kink. Example 2 and 3 specifically highlight how (non-)existence of equilibrium depends critically on whether a firm s spillover demand is a function of its own selling price. The final two examples, Example 4 and 5, consider a homogeneous good oligopoly with and without spillover demand. 5.1 Heterogeneous Products EXAMPLE 1. (Bowley (1924)) In this first example, we examine a well-known representative consumer model as introduced by Bowley (1924). The (quasi-linear) utility of consuming a quantity s 1 at a price p 1 and a quantity s 2 at price p 2 is given by U = α (s 1 + s 2 ) 1 2 β (s θs 1 s 2 + s 2 2) p 1 s 1 p 2 s 2, which is the gain from consumption V = α (s 1 + s 2 ) 1 2 β (s θs 1 s 2 + s 2 2) minus the total expenditure of p 1 s 1 + p 2 s 2. Notice that utility depends on sales (s i ) and not on demand (D i ) or production (q i ). The degree of differentiation is captured by the differentiation (or distance ) parameter θ [0, 1]. Both goods are perfect substitutes when 20

21 θ = 1 and independent in demand when θ = 0. For simplicity, it is assumed in the following that firms have common, constant marginal cost c > 0. To determine the utility-maximizing allocation of sales, take the first-order conditions with respect to s 1 and s 2 : α βs 1 βθs 2 p 1 = 0, α βs 2 βθs 1 p 2 = 0. Rearranging gives the inverse demand function for both firms: p 1 = α β (s 1 + θs 2 ), p 2 = α β (s 2 + θs 1 ). Thus, given prices p 1 and p 2, the representative consumer aims to acquire [ 1 s 1 = β (1 + θ) α p 1 1 θ + θp ] 2, 1 θ s 2 = 1 β (1 + θ) [ α p 2 1 θ + θp 1 1 θ ]. Note that this model meets the requirements of A1-A3 and B1-B2 provided that production is not too expensive. Thus, by Theorem 3, we know there is a pure-strategy equilibrium. Moreover, by Lemma 2, we know that this equilibrium is a Bertrand equilibrium. Thus, firm 1 maximizes Π 1 = (p 1 c) [ 1 β (1 + θ) α p 1 1 θ + θp ] 2, 1 θ which yields the following corresponding best reply function: p 1 = 1 2 [c + (1 θ) α + θ p 2]. Using symmetry and solving the resulting system of best response functions gives the equilibrium (p, q ): p 1 = p 2 = c + α (1 θ) 2 θ and D 1 = D 2 = q 1 = q 2 = α c β (1 + θ) (2 θ). For instance, suppose that α = 18, β = 2 3, θ = 1 2 and C i(q i ) = 3q i for i = 1, 2. This gives demand functions D 1 (p 1, p 2 ) = [18 2p 1 + p 2 ] + and D 2 (p 1, p 2 ) = [18 2p 2 + p 1 ] + and the following equilibrium prices and quantities: p 1 = p 2 = c + α (1 θ) 2 θ = 8 and D 1 = D 2 = q 1 = q 2 = α c β (1 + θ) (2 θ) =

22 EXAMPLE 2. ((Almost) Friedman (1988)) Let us now use the previous specifications (i.e., α = 18, β = 2 3, θ = 1 2 and c = 3) and extend the model by adding the possibility of complete spillover. Thus, a firm s demand includes all its competitors unserved customers. Demand for the products of firm 1 is then given by { [18 2p 1 + p 2 ] + if 18 + p 1 2p 2 q 2, D 1 (p 1, p 2, q 2 ) = [36 p 1 p 2 q 2 ] + if 18 + p 1 2p 2 > q 2. Firm 2 s demand function is symmetric. Such a setting closely mimics the framework of Friedman (1988) and the underlying logic for non-existence of equilibrium is comparable. 19 To see that this demand specification does indeed not admit an equilibrium, first observe that assumptions A1-A3 still hold. Hence, Lemma 2 applies so that in equilibrium q i = D i, for i = 1, 2. This implies D 1 = [18 2p 1 + p 2 ] + and D 2 = [18 2p 2 + p 1 ] +. Note that this is precisely the demand structure of Example 1 leaving p 1 = p 2 = 8 and q 1 = q 2 = 10 as the only equilibrium candidate. Given that p 2 = 8 and q 2 = 10, firm 1 s demand function reduces to D 1 (p 1 ) = { [26 2p 1 ] + if 2 + p 1 10, [18 p 1 ] + if 2 + p 1 > 10. It can now be easily verified that (p 1, q 1 ) = (8, 10) is no longer a best reply. In fact, given (p 2, q 2 ) = (8, 10), firm 1 has an incentive to generate spillover demand by hiking its price. Specifically, it maximizes Π 1 = (p 1 3) [18 p 1 ] +, which reaches its maximum at p 1 = Thus, in this case, a best reply to (p 2, q 2 ) = (8, 10) is no longer (p 1, q 1 ) = (8, 10), but (p 1, q 1 ) = (10.5, 7.5). EXAMPLE 3. (Kinked Demand with a Solution) Following Friedman (1988) and the previous example, it may be tempting to conclude that no equilibrium can exist in models with complete spillover. We will now present an example showing that such a conclusion would be premature. We again use the above Bowley model and assume that c = 3, β = 1 and θ = 0 (i.e., both firms are (local) monopolists). Absent spillover, demand functions are D 1 (p 1 ) = α p 1, D 2 (p 2 ) = α p Formally, this setting does not fall within the class of models considered by Friedman (1988) as it allows for strictly positive demand even when direct demand is zero. That is, for a sufficiently high price, demand of a firm may consist exclusively of customers that visited the rival first. Unfortunately, we have been unable so far to construct meaningful or tractable demand specifications that fully fit the Friedman (1988) context. 22

23 In this case, equilibrium prices and quantities are respectively given by p 1 = p 2 = α+3 2 and q 1 = q 2 = α 3 2. In contrast, the demand functions with complete spillover are D 1 (p 1, p 2, q 2 ) = [α p 1 ] + + [α p 2 q 2 ] +, D 2 (p 2, p 1, q 1 ) = [α p 2 ] + + [α p 1 q 1 ] +. By Lemma 2, we know that in equilibrium q i = D i, for i = 1, 2. Thus, actual spillover is zero and therefore q1 = α p 1 and q 2 = α p 2. We conclude that there is an equilibrium with p 1 = p 2 = α+3 2 and q1 = q 2 = α 3 2, which is identical to the equilibrium absent spillover demand. 20 It is worth highlighting the difference with the previous example as in both cases the demand function exhibits a kink. The fundamental distinction lies in the nature of the kink. In this example, it is due to the production level of the rival. In particular, the indirect demand is independent of the own selling price. In Example 2, by contrast, the indirect demand does depend on the own price. That is, the demand functions exhibit a kink in p i and it is precisely this property that destroys the equilibrium in Example Homogeneous Products EXAMPLE 4. (No Spillover) Let total demand be given by D(P ) = A P, A > 0, and suppose that demand is divided equally among equally-priced firms. Moreover, let C i (q i ) = q 2 i, for all i N. This is a symmetric model and a special case of the model in Section 4 with α = 0 (see Theorem 6). Let P be a price associated with a symmetric equilibrium. As C i (q i) = 2 q i, it must be true that q i = 1 2 P. In equilibrium, it holds that qi D(P ) n or 1 2 P A P n, which can be rearranged to P 2A n+2. If P < 2A n+2, then the equilibrium is a rationing equilibrium. The equilibrium is a Bertrand equilibrium when P = 2A n+2. EXAMPLE 5. (Spillover) Consider the model of the previous example, but now with spillover demand (i.e., α > 0). Let P 1 := P and define recursively P k+1 = min{p i p i > P k }. For each k, write N k = {i p i = P k } and let Q k = i N k q i. Demand is defined as follows. Let A 1 = A and D(P ) = A 1 P. Suppose that D k is defined recursively and let A k+1 = D k (P k ) Q k. Furthermore, D k+1 (P ) = α A k+1 (P P k ) for 20 A similar result can be derived in the spatial model of Hotelling (1929). See Alger (1979, Theorem 3.1). 21 It is furthermore noteworthy that assumption B1 may also be satisfied when customers take into account other factors than price. For instance, when there are costs associated with queuing, buyers might approach another supplier well before their most preferred choice (absent queuing costs) is sold out. 23

Advanced Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomics Advanced Microeconomics Leonardo Felli EC441: Room D.106, Z.332, D.109 Lecture 8 bis: 24 November 2004 Monopoly Consider now the pricing behavior of a profit maximizing monopolist: a firm that is the only

More information

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly Daisuke Hirata Graduate School of Economics, University of Tokyo March 2008 Abstract This paper investigates a simultaneous move capacity constrained price competition

More information

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 Bertrand Model of Price Competition Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 ҧ Bertrand Model of Price Competition Consider: An industry with two firms, 1 and 2, selling a homogeneous product Firms face market

More information

Mixed duopolies with advance production

Mixed duopolies with advance production Mixed duopolies with advance production Tamás László Balogh Department of Economic Analysis and Business Informatics, University of Debrecen and Attila Tasnádi MTA-BCE Lendület Strategic Interactions Research

More information

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation Nicolas Schutz Nicolas Schutz Product Differentiation 1 / 57 Introduction We now finally drop the assumption that firms offer homogeneous products.

More information

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games University of Manchester, UK November 25, 2010 Introduction Suppose we make a finite set of observations T = {1,..., m}, m 1, of a perfectly homogeneous-good oligopoly market. There is a finite number

More information

Price vs. Quantity in Oligopoly Games

Price vs. Quantity in Oligopoly Games Price vs. Quantity in Oligopoly Games Attila Tasnádi Department of Mathematics, Corvinus University of Budapest, H-1093 Budapest, Fővám tér 8, Hungary July 29, 2005. Appeared in the International Journal

More information

Basics of Game Theory

Basics of Game Theory Basics of Game Theory Giacomo Bacci and Luca Sanguinetti Department of Information Engineering University of Pisa, Pisa, Italy {giacomo.bacci,luca.sanguinetti}@iet.unipi.it April - May, 2010 G. Bacci and

More information

Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!?

Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!? Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!? Mathias Erlei Clausthal University of Technology Julius-Albert-Str. 2, 38678 Clausthal-Zellerfeld, Germany email: m.erlei@tu-clausthal.de Abstract This

More information

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games 1/10 Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games May 4, 2014 2/10 Outline 1 Bertrand Market Game 2 Bertrand Paradox 3 Asymmetric Firms 3/10 Bertrand Duopoly Market Game Discontinuous Payoff Functions (1 p

More information

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP A new look at the classical Bertrand duopoly

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP A new look at the classical Bertrand duopoly Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP-1702 A new look at the classical Bertrand duopoly Rabah Amir Igor V. Evstigneev February 2017 Economics School of Social Sciences The University of Manchester Manchester

More information

On Hotelling s Stability in Competition

On Hotelling s Stability in Competition On Hotelling s Stability in Competition Claude d Aspremont, Jean Jaskold Gabszewicz and Jacques-François Thisse Manuscript received March, 1978; revision received June, 1978 Abstract The purpose of this

More information

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

Answer Key: Problem Set 3 Answer Key: Problem Set Econ 409 018 Fall Question 1 a This is a standard monopoly problem; using MR = a 4Q, let MR = MC and solve: Q M = a c 4, P M = a + c, πm = (a c) 8 The Lerner index is then L M P

More information

Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly

Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo June 8, 2010 Abstract I investigate an asymmetric duopoly where

More information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers September 6, 016 ONLINE APPENDIX In this Appendix we present in full additional results and extensions which are only mentioned in the paper. In the exposition

More information

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition 4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition Partial equilibrium studies the existence of equilibrium in the market of a given commodity and analyzes its properties. Prices in other markets as well

More information

RATIONING RULES AND BERTRAND-EDGEWORTH OLIGOPOLIES

RATIONING RULES AND BERTRAND-EDGEWORTH OLIGOPOLIES BUDAPEST UNIVERSITY OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES Economics Ph.D. Program Department of Mathematics RATIONING RULES AND BERTRAND-EDGEWORTH OLIGOPOLIES Ph.D. Thesis Main Results Attila Tasnádi Budapest, 1999 Contents

More information

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples February 24, 2011 Summary: We introduce the Nash Equilibrium: an outcome (action profile) which is stable in the sense that no player

More information

Price and Capacity Competition

Price and Capacity Competition Price and Capacity Competition Daron Acemoglu, Kostas Bimpikis, and Asuman Ozdaglar October 9, 2007 Abstract We study the efficiency of oligopoly equilibria in a model where firms compete over capacities

More information

Multimarket Oligopolies with Restricted Market Access

Multimarket Oligopolies with Restricted Market Access Multimarket Oligopolies with Restricted Market Access Tobias Harks 1 and Max Klimm 2 1 Department of Quantitative Economics, Maastricht University, the Netherlands. t.harks@maastrichtuniversity.nl 2 Department

More information

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of... This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of... John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 1 / 1 We will cover the following topics: with Sequential Moves

More information

Volume 29, Issue 3. Strategic delegation and market competitiveness

Volume 29, Issue 3. Strategic delegation and market competitiveness Volume 29, Issue Strategic delegation and market competitiveness Caterina Colombo Università di Ferrara Alessandra Chirco Università del Salento Marcella Scrimitore Università del Salento Abstract Within

More information

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 16-1, 231 253 (2015) Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * Hongkun Ma School of Economics, Shandong University,

More information

Product differences and prices

Product differences and prices Product differences and prices Claude d Aspremont, Jean Jaskold Gabszewicz and Jacques-François Thisse Abstract Under assumptions following Hotelling s 1929 paper Stability in Competition, the possibility

More information

Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot

Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot Class Note: There are supplemental readings, including Werden (008) Unilateral Competitive Effects of Horizontal Mergers I: Basic Concepts and Models, that

More information

Oligopoly. Oligopoly. Xiang Sun. Wuhan University. March 23 April 6, /149

Oligopoly. Oligopoly. Xiang Sun. Wuhan University. March 23 April 6, /149 Oligopoly Xiang Sun Wuhan University March 23 April 6, 2016 1/149 Outline 1 Introduction 2 Game theory 3 Oligopoly models 4 Cournot competition Two symmetric firms Two asymmetric firms Many symmetric firms

More information

Price-quantity competition with varying toughness

Price-quantity competition with varying toughness Price-quantity competition with varying toughness Claude d Aspremont Rodolphe Dos Santos Ferreira Received 27 October 2004; Available online 16 March 2008 Abstract For an industry producing a single homogeneous

More information

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours. University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring 2012 EC941: Game Theory Prof. Francesco Squintani Final Exam Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours. 1. Consider

More information

1 + x 1/2. b) For what values of k is g a quasi-concave function? For what values of k is g a concave function? Explain your answers.

1 + x 1/2. b) For what values of k is g a quasi-concave function? For what values of k is g a concave function? Explain your answers. Questions and Answers from Econ 0A Final: Fall 008 I have gone to some trouble to explain the answers to all of these questions, because I think that there is much to be learned b working through them

More information

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing Jianwei Huang & Lin Gao Network Communications and Economics Lab (NCEL) Information Engineering Department The Chinese University of Hong Kong Huang

More information

On strategic complementarity conditions in Bertrand oligopoly

On strategic complementarity conditions in Bertrand oligopoly Economic Theory 22, 227 232 (2003) On strategic complementarity conditions in Bertrand oligopoly Rabah Amir 1 and Isabel Grilo 2 1 CORE and Department of Economics, Université Catholique de Louvain, 34

More information

EconS Oligopoly - Part 2

EconS Oligopoly - Part 2 EconS 305 - Oligopoly - Part 2 Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu November 29, 2015 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 32 November 29, 2015 1 / 28 Introduction Last time,

More information

Market Power. Economics II: Microeconomics. December Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39

Market Power. Economics II: Microeconomics. December Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39 Market Power Economics II: Microeconomics VŠE Praha December 2009 Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39 Microeconomics Consumers: Firms: People. Households. Monopoly. Oligopoly Now Perfect Competition.

More information

Heterogenous Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Behavioral Uncertainty

Heterogenous Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Behavioral Uncertainty Heterogenous Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Behavioral Uncertainty Akio Matsumoto Department of Systems Industrial Engineering Univesity of Arizona, USA Department of Economics Chuo University,

More information

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October 23 2011 1 Scores The exam was long. I know this. Final grades will definitely be curved. Here is a rough

More information

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Hiroaki Ino Institute of Intellectual Property and Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo [Preliminary

More information

ANSWER KEY 2 GAME THEORY, ECON 395

ANSWER KEY 2 GAME THEORY, ECON 395 ANSWER KEY GAME THEORY, ECON 95 PROFESSOR A. JOSEPH GUSE (1) (Gibbons 1.6) Consider again the Cournot duopoly model with demand given by the marginal willingness to pay function: P(Q) = a Q, but this time

More information

Designing Optimal Pre-Announced Markdowns in the Presence of Rational Customers with Multi-unit Demands - Online Appendix

Designing Optimal Pre-Announced Markdowns in the Presence of Rational Customers with Multi-unit Demands - Online Appendix 087/msom070057 Designing Optimal Pre-Announced Markdowns in the Presence of Rational Customers with Multi-unit Demands - Online Appendix Wedad Elmaghraby Altan Gülcü Pınar Keskinocak RH mith chool of Business,

More information

Managerial delegation in multimarket oligopoly

Managerial delegation in multimarket oligopoly Managerial delegation in multimarket oligopoly Arup Bose Barnali Gupta Statistics and Mathematics Unit Department of Economics Indian Statistical Institute Miami University, Ohio INDIA USA bosearu@gmail.com

More information

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016 Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016 1 Modelling incomplete information So far, we have studied games in which information was complete,

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6 Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO April 10, 017 Administrative Stuff Homework # is due at the end of class. I will post the solutions on the website later today. The midterm

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRICE AND CAPACITY COMPETITION. Daron Acemoglu Kostas Bimpikis Asuman Ozdaglar

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRICE AND CAPACITY COMPETITION. Daron Acemoglu Kostas Bimpikis Asuman Ozdaglar NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRICE AND CAPACITY COMPETITION Daron Acemoglu Kostas Bimpikis Asuman Ozdaglar Working Paper 12804 http://www.nber.org/papers/w12804 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

Quantity-setting games with a dominant

Quantity-setting games with a dominant MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Quantity-setting games with a dominant firm Attila Tasnádi Corvinus University of Budapest 24. February 2009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/13612/ MPRA Paper

More information

A theory of recommended price dispersion

A theory of recommended price dispersion A theory of recommended price dispersion Marco Haan Pim Heijnen Martin Obradovits January 3, 017 WORK IN PROGRESS DO NOT CITE Abstract This paper contributes to the theory of recommended retail prices

More information

Free Entry Bertrand Competition

Free Entry Bertrand Competition MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Free Entry Bertrand Competition Prabal Roy Chowdhury Indian Statistical Institute, Delhi Center October 2009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/17837/ MPRA Paper

More information

ONLINE APPENDIX. Upping the Ante: The Equilibrium Effects of Unconditional Grants to Private Schools

ONLINE APPENDIX. Upping the Ante: The Equilibrium Effects of Unconditional Grants to Private Schools ONLINE APPENDIX Upping the Ante: The Equilibrium Effects of Unconditional Grants to Private Schools T. Andrabi, J. Das, A.I. Khwaja, S. Ozyurt, and N. Singh Contents A Theory A.1 Homogeneous Demand.................................

More information

SELECTION OF MARKOV EQUILIBRIUM IN A DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY WITH PRODUCTION TO ORDER. Milan Horniaček 1

SELECTION OF MARKOV EQUILIBRIUM IN A DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY WITH PRODUCTION TO ORDER. Milan Horniaček 1 SELECTION OF MARKOV EQUILIBRIUM IN A DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY WITH PRODUCTION TO ORDER Milan Horniaček 1 CERGE-EI, Charles University and Academy of Sciences of Czech Republic, Prague We use the requirement of

More information

1 Oligopoly: Bertrand Model

1 Oligopoly: Bertrand Model 1 Oligopoly: Bertrand Model Bertrand model: There are two rms and no entry is possible. Homogeneity of product. Single period. Consumers always purchase from the cheapest seller. If the two selllers charge

More information

Mathematical Economics - PhD in Economics

Mathematical Economics - PhD in Economics - PhD in Part 1: Supermodularity and complementarity in the one-dimensional and Paulo Brito ISEG - Technical University of Lisbon November 24, 2010 1 2 - Supermodular optimization 3 one-dimensional 4 Supermodular

More information

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility Toker Doganoglu and Julian Wright July 19, 2005 We would like to thank two anonymous referees and our editor, Simon Anderson, for their very helpful

More information

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2 EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2 Leonardo Felli 32L.G.06 19 January 2015 Moral Hazard: Consider the contractual relationship between two agents (a principal and an agent) The principal

More information

Appendix of Homophily in Peer Groups The Costly Information Case

Appendix of Homophily in Peer Groups The Costly Information Case Appendix of Homophily in Peer Groups The Costly Information Case Mariagiovanna Baccara Leeat Yariv August 19, 2012 1 Introduction In this Appendix we study the information sharing application analyzed

More information

Oblivious Equilibrium: A Mean Field Approximation for Large-Scale Dynamic Games

Oblivious Equilibrium: A Mean Field Approximation for Large-Scale Dynamic Games Oblivious Equilibrium: A Mean Field Approximation for Large-Scale Dynamic Games Gabriel Y. Weintraub, Lanier Benkard, and Benjamin Van Roy Stanford University {gweintra,lanierb,bvr}@stanford.edu Abstract

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012 The time limit for this exam is 4 hours. It has four sections. Each section includes two questions. You are

More information

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Yongmin Chen and David Sappington University of Colorado and University of Florida February 2016 1 / 32 1. Introduction Patent policy: patent protection

More information

Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous?

Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous? Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous? Paolo G. Garella University of Bologna 14 July 004 Abstract The present note shows that innocuous Minimum Quality Standards, namely standards that

More information

No Information Sharing in Oligopoly: The Case of Price Competition with Cost Uncertainty

No Information Sharing in Oligopoly: The Case of Price Competition with Cost Uncertainty No Information Sharing in Oligopoly: The Case of Price Competition with Cost Uncertainty Stephan O. Hornig and Manfred Stadler* Abstract We show that concealing cost information is a dominant strategy

More information

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions.

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions. Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 3: Optimization - interior optima 1 Session: 11-12 Aug 2015 (Thu/Fri) 10:00am 1:00pm I. Optimization: introduction Decision-makers (e.g. consumers,

More information

3. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition Competitive Equilibrium

3. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition Competitive Equilibrium 3. Imperfect Competition 3. Partial Equilirium under Imperfect Competition Competitive Equilirium Partial equilirium studies the existence of equilirium in the market of a given commodity and analyzes

More information

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM Discussion Papers in Economics Discussion Paper No. 0/06 CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY by Indraneel Dasgupta July 00 DP 0/06 ISSN 1360-438 UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM

More information

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley Firms and returns to scale. Increasing returns to scale and monopoly pricing 2. Natural monopoly 1 C. Constant returns to scale 21 D. The CRS economy 26 E. pplication

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 More on strategic games and extensive games with perfect information Block 2 Jun 12, 2016 Food for thought LUPI Many players

More information

Lecture Notes: Industrial Organization Joe Chen 1. The Structure Conduct Performance (SCP) paradigm:

Lecture Notes: Industrial Organization Joe Chen 1. The Structure Conduct Performance (SCP) paradigm: Joe Chen 1 1 Introduction 1.1 The Beginning Joe Bain and Edward Mason (the Harvard tradition): Empirical in nature (loose theories) The Structure Conduct Performance (SCP) paradigm: Structure (market structure):

More information

EC3224 Autumn Lecture #03 Applications of Nash Equilibrium

EC3224 Autumn Lecture #03 Applications of Nash Equilibrium Reading EC3224 Autumn Lecture #03 Applications of Nash Equilibrium Osborne Chapter 3 By the end of this week you should be able to: apply Nash equilibrium to oligopoly games, voting games and other examples.

More information

EconS Sequential Competition

EconS Sequential Competition EconS 425 - Sequential Competition Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 47 A Warmup 1 x i x j (x

More information

Answer Key: Problem Set 1

Answer Key: Problem Set 1 Answer Key: Problem Set 1 Econ 409 018 Fall Question 1 a The profit function (revenue minus total cost) is π(q) = P (q)q cq The first order condition with respect to (henceforth wrt) q is P (q )q + P (q

More information

Durable goods monopolist

Durable goods monopolist Durable goods monopolist Coase conjecture: A monopolist selling durable good has no monopoly power. Reason: A P 1 P 2 B MC MC D MR Q 1 Q 2 C Q Although Q 1 is optimal output of the monopolist, it faces

More information

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective Alex Possajennikov University of Nottingham January 2012 Abstract Suppose that in aggregative games, in which a player s payoff

More information

Technical Companion to: Sharing Aggregate Inventory Information with Customers: Strategic Cross-selling and Shortage Reduction

Technical Companion to: Sharing Aggregate Inventory Information with Customers: Strategic Cross-selling and Shortage Reduction Technical Companion to: Sharing Aggregate Inventory Information with Customers: Strategic Cross-selling and Shortage Reduction Ruomeng Cui Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington, IN

More information

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS 8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS We have studied competitive markets where there are a large number of rms and each rm takes market prices as given. When a market contain only a few relevant rms, rms may

More information

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7 Mathematical Foundations -- Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization An intuitive approach First Order Conditions (FOC) 7 Constraint qualifications 9 Formal statement of the FOC for a maximum

More information

October 16, 2018 Notes on Cournot. 1. Teaching Cournot Equilibrium

October 16, 2018 Notes on Cournot. 1. Teaching Cournot Equilibrium October 1, 2018 Notes on Cournot 1. Teaching Cournot Equilibrium Typically Cournot equilibrium is taught with identical zero or constant-mc cost functions for the two firms, because that is simpler. I

More information

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS CEP 14-11 Horizontal Mergers in the Presence of Capacity Constraints Zhiqi Chen Carleton University Gang Li Nanjing University September 2014 CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS Department of Economics 1125 Colonel

More information

Game theory lecture 4. September 24, 2012

Game theory lecture 4. September 24, 2012 September 24, 2012 Finding Nash equilibrium Best-response or best-reply functions. We introduced Nash-equilibrium as a profile of actions (an action for each player) such that no player has an incentive

More information

The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers

The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers joint work with Frederic Murphy Climate Policy and Long Term Decisions-Investment and R&D, Bocconi University, Milan,

More information

Y j R L divide goods into produced goods (outputs) > 0 output, call its price p < 0 input, call its price ω

Y j R L divide goods into produced goods (outputs) > 0 output, call its price p < 0 input, call its price ω 4 PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS 4.1 Perfectly Competitive Market Ref: MWG Chapter 10.C and 10.F (but also read 10.A &10.B) Recall: consumers described by preferences over consumption bundles represented

More information

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Supermodular Games

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Supermodular Games 6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Asu Ozdaglar MIT February 25, 2010 1 Introduction Outline Uniqueness of a Pure Nash Equilibrium for Continuous Games Reading: Rosen J.B., Existence

More information

Industrial Organization Lecture 3: Game Theory

Industrial Organization Lecture 3: Game Theory Industrial Organization Lecture 3: Game Theory Nicolas Schutz Nicolas Schutz Game Theory 1 / 43 Introduction Why game theory? In the introductory lecture, we defined Industrial Organization as the economics

More information

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume Duality for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume Headwords: CONVEXITY, DUALITY, LAGRANGE MULTIPLIERS, PARETO EFFICIENCY, QUASI-CONCAVITY 1 Introduction The word duality is

More information

Static (or Simultaneous- Move) Games of Complete Information

Static (or Simultaneous- Move) Games of Complete Information Static (or Simultaneous- Move) Games of Complete Information Introduction to Games Normal (or Strategic) Form Representation Teoria dos Jogos - Filomena Garcia 1 Outline of Static Games of Complete Information

More information

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IN ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT Strategic Incentives for Managers in Contests Matthias Kräkel Discussion Paper No. 01-08 GERMAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION - GEABA

More information

3.3.3 Illustration: Infinitely repeated Cournot duopoly.

3.3.3 Illustration: Infinitely repeated Cournot duopoly. will begin next period less effective in deterring a deviation this period. Nonetheless, players can do better than just repeat the Nash equilibrium of the constituent game. 3.3.3 Illustration: Infinitely

More information

Equilibrium Refinements

Equilibrium Refinements Equilibrium Refinements Mihai Manea MIT Sequential Equilibrium In many games information is imperfect and the only subgame is the original game... subgame perfect equilibrium = Nash equilibrium Play starting

More information

Static Models of Oligopoly

Static Models of Oligopoly Static Models of Oligopoly Cournot and Bertrand Models Mateusz Szetela 1 1 Collegium of Economic Analysis Warsaw School of Economics 3 March 2016 Outline 1 Introduction Game Theory and Oligopolies 2 The

More information

Bertrand-Edgeworth competition with substantial product dierentiation

Bertrand-Edgeworth competition with substantial product dierentiation Bertrand-Edgeworth competition with substantial product dierentiation Robert Somogyi Preliminary version August 21, 2013 Abstract Since Kreps and Scheinkman's seminal article (1983) a large number of papers

More information

Price Competition when Not All Customers Know of All Firms

Price Competition when Not All Customers Know of All Firms Price Competition when Not All Customers Know of All Firms B. Curtis Eaton Department of Economics University of Calgary Ian MacDonald Commerce Division Lincoln University Laura Meriluoto Department of

More information

Revealed Preference Tests of the Cournot Model

Revealed Preference Tests of the Cournot Model Andres Carvajal, Rahul Deb, James Fenske, and John K.-H. Quah Department of Economics University of Toronto Introduction Cournot oligopoly is a canonical noncooperative model of firm competition. In this

More information

Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting

Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting Eric Avenel Université de Rennes I et CREM (UMR CNRS 6) March, 00 Abstract This article presents a model

More information

Limit pricing models and PBE 1

Limit pricing models and PBE 1 EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Limit pricing models and PBE 1 1 Model Consider an entry game with an incumbent monopolist (Firm 1) and an entrant (Firm ) who analyzes whether or not to join the

More information

Volume 35, Issue 2. Cournot Equilibrium Uniqueness in Case of Concave Industry Revenue: a Simple Proof

Volume 35, Issue 2. Cournot Equilibrium Uniqueness in Case of Concave Industry Revenue: a Simple Proof Volume 35, Issue 2 Cournot Equilibrium Uniqueness in Case of Concave Industry Revenue: a Simple Proof Pierre von Mouche Wageningen Universiteit Federico Quartieri Universita degli studi di Napoli Federico

More information

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale. Increasing returns to scale and monopoly pricing 2. Constant returns to scale 19 C. The CRS economy 25 D. pplication to trade 47 E. Decreasing

More information

Market Participation under Delegated and. Intrinsic Common Agency Games

Market Participation under Delegated and. Intrinsic Common Agency Games Market Participation under Delegated and Intrinsic Common Agency Games (Preliminary) David Martimort Lars A. Stole November 25, 2003 *We are grateful to Wouter Dessein, Bruno Jullien and Canice Prendergast

More information

DISCRETE-TIME DYNAMICS OF AN

DISCRETE-TIME DYNAMICS OF AN Chapter 1 DISCRETE-TIME DYNAMICS OF AN OLIGOPOLY MODEL WITH DIFFERENTIATED GOODS K. Andriopoulos, T. Bountis and S. Dimas * Department of Mathematics, University of Patras, Patras, GR-26500, Greece Abstract

More information

Introduction to Game Theory

Introduction to Game Theory COMP323 Introduction to Computational Game Theory Introduction to Game Theory Paul G. Spirakis Department of Computer Science University of Liverpool Paul G. Spirakis (U. Liverpool) Introduction to Game

More information

Empirical Industrial Organization (ECO 310) University of Toronto. Department of Economics Fall Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria

Empirical Industrial Organization (ECO 310) University of Toronto. Department of Economics Fall Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria Empirical Industrial Organization (ECO 30) University of Toronto. Department of Economics Fall 208. Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria FINAL EXAM Tuesday, December 8th, 208. From 7pm to 9pm (2 hours) Exam

More information

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 8: Supermodular and Potential Games

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 8: Supermodular and Potential Games 6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 8: Supermodular and Asu Ozdaglar MIT March 2, 2010 1 Introduction Outline Review of Supermodular Games Reading: Fudenberg and Tirole, Section 12.3.

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS DECISION SCIENCE

MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS DECISION SCIENCE MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS DECISION SCIENCE 1. Decision Science approach is a. Multi-disciplinary b. Scientific c. Intuitive 2. For analyzing a problem, decision-makers should study a. Its qualitative aspects

More information

Industrial Organization

Industrial Organization Industrial Organization Lecture Notes Sérgio O. Parreiras Fall, 2017 Outline Mathematical Toolbox Intermediate Microeconomic Theory Revision Perfect Competition Monopoly Oligopoly Mathematical Toolbox

More information

Hotelling s Beach with Linear and Quadratic Transportation Costs: Existence of Pure Strategy Equilibria

Hotelling s Beach with Linear and Quadratic Transportation Costs: Existence of Pure Strategy Equilibria appearing in Australian Economic Papers, vol. 46(1) Hotelling s Beach with Linear and Quadratic Transportation Costs: Existence of Pure Strategy Equilibria Alain Egli University of Bern Abstract In Hotelling

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 28 Jun 2016

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 28 Jun 2016 On the Inefficiency of Forward Markets in Leader-Follower Competition Desmond Cai, Anish Agarwal, Adam Wierman arxiv:66.864v [math.oc] 8 Jun 6 June 9, 6 Abstract Motivated by electricity markets, this

More information