1 Objective. 2 Constrained optimization. 2.1 Utility maximization. Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "1 Objective. 2 Constrained optimization. 2.1 Utility maximization. Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics"

Transcription

1 BEE020 { Basic Mathematical Economics Week 2, Lecture Thursday Constrained optimization Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics University of Exeter Objective We give the \ rst order conditions" for constrained optimization problems like utility maximization and costs minimization. The Lagrangean method to obtain these conditions is introduced and its economic interpretation is discussed. The relevant reading for this handout is Chapter 7, Sections 4. See also the book by Begg on the consumer optimum and on cost minimization. 2 Constrained optimization 2. Utility maximization The preferences of a consumer are described by a family of indi erence curves. A mathematically convenient way to describe a family of indi erence curves is to describe them as the level curves of a utility function u (x; y). The utility u (x; y) can be interpreted as a numerical measure of the satisfaction the consumer has when consuming x units of the rst commodity (say, apples) and y units of the second commodity (say oranges). Along a level curve utility is constant, so all commodity bundles on a level curve bring equal satisfaction, they are hence the indi erence curves. If one bundle has more utility than another, the consumer will prefer it. As an example consider the utility function u (x; y) = xy. The indi erence curves for u =,u =2andu =havetheform x where consumption on higher indi erence curves yields higher utility. Suppose the price of apples is p, the price of oranges is q and the consumer has a budget b. Then the budget constraint px + qy b

2 must be satis ed for the consumption bundle (x; y) which the consumer buys, i.e., his total expenditure on the two commodities cannot exceed his budget. The aim of the consumer is to maximize his utility subject to the budget constraint. This is a constrained optimization problem because the consumer would consume in nite amounts of both commodities if he were not constrained by his budget. u (x; y) isthe objective function for this problem because the objective is to maximize this function. We call total expenditure g (x; y) = px + qy the constraining function because it appears in the constraint. We expect the budget constraint to be binding in optimum, i.e., we expect the budget inquality to hold with equality in the optimum. This is so because by assumption the consumer has no possibility to save and because no other commodities are available. From the Principles lecture you know the essential condition which must hold in an optimum: The budget line must be tangential to the indi erence curve. Now the budget line is given by the equation px + qy = b or y = b q p q x so it has the slope p, which, apart form the sign, is the relative price of apples in terms q of oranges. (To buy an apple more the consumer must give up p units of oranges.) q The slope of the indi erence curve is { apart from the sign { the marginal rate of substitution. In the previous handout we tried to explain that the marginal rate of substitution Thus in optimum the marginal rate of substitution must be to the = p q () This is the rst equation which characterizes the constrained optimum. For the example u (x; y) =xy = y and = x. The y x = p (2) q or qy = px; () i.e., in optimum the consumer spends equal amounts on each commodity. We need a second equation for the optimum. This second equation is the budget equation px + qy = b (4) To repeat: the constrained optimum (x ;y ) is the solution of a simultaneous system of two equations in two unknowns. The rst equation expresses that in the optimum the marginal rate of substitution is equal to the relative price. The second one states that the consumer spends all his money in the optimum. 2

3 gives In our example condition () gives y = p x. Substituting this into the budget equation q µ p px + q q x = px + px =2px = b x = b 2p y = p q x = p q b 2p = b 2q We have found the optimum. For instance, when the budget is b = 00 and the prices are p =2andq = 5 the optimal consumption is x = =25 y = =0: 2.2 Cost minimization The cost minimization problem is in many ways dual to the utility maximization problem and leads to very similar conditions. Consider a price-taking rm with production function Q (K; L) =KL. Suppose the rm wants to nd the least costly way to produce Q 0 units of output given the prices r and w for the inputs. Then she wants to minimize total costs rk + wl subject to the constraint that she produces at least Q 0 units Q 0 Q (K; L) : Here expenditure on inputs is the objective function whereas the production function is the constraining function. Again from the principles lecture we know that in the cost minimum the iso-cost line must be tangential to the isoquant. Since the slope of an iso-cost line rk + wl =constant is the negative of the relative price of inputs r it follows that in the optimum the marginal w rate of must equal the relative In @Q=@L = r w : = = K, so L K = r w wl = rk

4 so in optimum equal amounts are spend on both inputs. This is the rst equation. As the second equation we have that in the optimum the rm will produce exactly Q 0 units and no more, the cost-minimizing optimum (K ;L ) must lie on the isoquant for Q 0 Q 0 = Q (K; L) : In our example suppose that r =2,thatw = 5 and that the rm wants to produce 250 units of output at the lowest costs. Then the optimum (K ;L ) must satisfy the conditions and L K = 2 5 or 250 = KL: Substituting in the last equation L = 2 5 K yields L = 2 5 K 250 = 2 25 = 2 5 = 2 5 K2 5 4 = K 2 K =5 2 =25 L = 2 5 K =0: The optimal input combination is (K ;L )=(5; 0). 2. The general problem In general we want to maximize or to minimize an objective function susbject to a constraint z = f (x; y) g (x; y) c where c is a constant. We are interested in the case where the constraint is binding in the optimum, i.e., where g (x; y) = c holds at the optimum. (Otherwise the constraint is always satis ed near the optimum and the optimum must be a critical point of f.) The optimum must then solve the two g (x; y) = c 4

5 The Lagrangian approach The Lagrangian method is an alternative way to derive these two conditions. The method transform the constrained optimization problem into an unconstrained optimization problem in conjunction with a pricing problem. We discuss here only the maximization problem. First we form out of the two given functions f and g a new function which depends on an additional parameter, the so-called Lagrange multiplier. This new function { called the Lagrangian { is L (x; y) =f (x; y) (g (x; y) c) Then we lookfor an unconstrained maximum or a minimum of this function and determine the Lagrange multiplier such that the constraint holds with equality in the optimum. For a maximization problem the interpretation is as follows: Instead of strictly forbidding that the constraint g (x; y) c ever gets violated, we allow to violate it, but at a price. This price is : It is a ctituous price in a ctitious problem and hence called a \shadow price". Suppose the constraint is violated. g (x; y) c is then the number of units by which the constraint is violated. When each unit of violation costs, the total amount (g (x; y) c) must then be paid for violation. This amount is subtracted from the value of the objective function which we want to maximize. (If the constraint is not violated, there is a reward.) Now we look for an unconstrained maximum (x ;y ) of the Lagrangian. Suppose we have found an absolute maximum (x ;y ) of this function and suppose and we were able to choose a positive such that (x ;y ) satis es the constraint g (x ;y )=c. Then(x ;y ) is automatically an optimum of the constrained optimization problem: We have L (x ;y )=f (x ;y ) (g (x ;y ) c) =f (x ;y ). Now consider any pair (x; y) that does not violate the constraint, i.e., that satis es g (x; y) c. Then L (x; y) L(x ;y )because(x ;y ) is an absolute maximum. Moreover (g (x; y) c) is positive since (x; y) satis es the constraint. Hence f (x; y) L (x; y) and overall we obtain that f (x; y) f (x ;y ) holds for all (x; y) satisfying the constraint. This means that (x ;y ) is a constrained maximum. To nd the maximum of the Lagrangian we solve the rst @x @y @y Notice that if we divide the two equations on the right @g=@y : (7) In addition we want the constraint to hold with equality in the optimum, i.e., we impose the equation (6) g (x; y) =c: (8) 5

6 We then solve the two equations (7) and (8) for x and y. The Lagrangian was just a tool to derive these equations. If the need arises, we can calculate the value of the Lagrange multiplier from equation (5) or (6).. Utility maximization again In this case the Lagrangian is L (x; y) =u (x; y) (px + qy b) =u (x; y)+ (b px + py) It can be interpreted as follows: In the original problem saving is not possible. suppose it is possible to save and also to go into debt. The savings are Now s = b px + py Now suppose there is some future utility from saving because the money can be spend in the future. For simplicity we assume that this future utility is linear in savings and given by s Then is the marginal utility of saving a penny. One also speaks of the marginal utility of money. The Lagrangian can then be interpreted as the total utility from consumption today and in the future. When we solve the constrained optimization problem with the Lagrangian approach we e ectively ask: What would the marginal utility of saving have to be such that it is optimal not to save and not to go into debt..2 Cost minimization again The rm wants to minimize the costs rk + wl subject to the constraint Q 0 Q (K; L). First we transorm the problem such that it ts with our general framework above. Minimizing rk + wl is the same as maximizing rk wl. Now we have a maximization problem. Next we had the constraint in the form g (x; y) c with the constant on the right. Therefore we rewrite Q 0 Q (K; L) as Q (K; L) Q 0. The Lagrangian becomes: L (K; L) = rk wl ( Q (K; L)+Q 0 ) = ( Q (K; L) rk wl) Q 0 We see that { up to a constant which will drop out in the di erentiation { the Lagrangian is just the pro t function of the rm when the output price is. Whenwesolvethecost minimization problem with the Lagrangian method we therefore ask: What would the output price have to be such that it is optimal to produce exactly Q 0 units of output. 6

7 4 Objective Two types of optimization problems frequently occur in economics: unconstrained optimization problems like pro t maximization problems and constrained optimization problems like the utility maximization problem of consumer constrained by a budget. In this handout we discuss the main step to solve an unconstrained optimization problem - namely to nd the two \ rst order conditions" and how to solve them. The solutions for this system of two equations in two unknowns can be local maxima, minima or saddle points. How to distinguish between these types will be discussed in a later handout, after we have discussed constrained optimization problems. The relevant reading for the previous handout is Chapter 7, Sections and 2 in the textbook of Ho mann and Bradley. The relevant reading for this handout is Chapter 7, Sections. 5 Optimization problems 5. Unconstrained optimization Suppose we want to nd the absolute maximum of a function z = f (x; y) in two variables, i.e., we want to nd the pair of numbers (x ;y ) such that f (x ;y ) f (x; y) holds for all (x; y). If (x ;y ) is such a maximum the following must hold: If we freeze the variable y at the optimal value y and vary only the variable x then the function f (x; y ) { which is now just a function in just one variable { has a maximum at x. Typically the maximum of this function in one variable will be a critical point. Hence we expect the partial to be zero at the optimum. Similarly we expect the partial to be zero at the optimum. We are thus led to the rst ;y=y jx=x ;y=y = 0 which must typically be satis ed. We speak of rst order conditions because only the rst derivatives are involved. The conditions do not tell us whether we have a maximum, a minimum or a saddle point. To nd out the latter we will have to look at the second derivatives and the so-called \second order conditions", as will be discussed in a later lecture. 7

8 Example Consider a price-taking rm with the production function Q (K; L). Let r be the interest rate (the price of capital K), let w be the wage rate (the price of labour L) and let P be the price of the output the rm is producing. When the rm uses K units of capital and L units labour she can produce Q (K; L) units of the output and hence make a revenue of P Q (K; L) by selling each unit of output at the market price P. Her production costs will then be her total expenditure on the inputs capital and labour Her pro t will be the di erence rk + wl: (K; L) =PQ(K; L) rk rl: The rm tries to nd the input combination (K ;L ) which maximizes her pro t. To nd it we want to solve the rst = r @L w = 0 (0) These conditions are intuitive: Suppose for r>0: is product of capital, i.e., it tells us how much more can be produced by using one more unit of capital. is the marginal increase in revenue when one more unit of capital used and the additional output is sold on the market. r is the marginal cost of using one more unit of capital. r>0 means that the marginal pro t from using one unit of capital is positive, i.t., it increases pro ts to produce more by using more capital and therefore we cannot be in a pro t optimum. Correspondingly, mean that pro t can be increased by producing less and using less capital. So (9) should hold in the optimum. Similarly (0) should hold. It is useful to rewrite the two rst order = r = w (2) P Thus, for both inputs it must be the case that the marginal product is equal to the price ratio of input- to output price. When we divide here the two left-hand sides and equate them with the quotient of the right hand sides we obtain as a = r. w P P = r () w so the marginal rate of substitution must be equal to the price ratio of the input price (which is the relative price of capital in terms of labour). 8

9 Example 2 Let us be more speci c and assume that the production function is Q (K; L) =K 6 L 2 and that the output- and input prices are P = 2, r =andw = 6 = 6 K 5 6 L = 2 K 6 L Á 2 K 6 L 2 = The rst order conditions () and (2) become 2 K 5 6 L 2 K 6 L 2 = 5 6 K 6 L 2 = (4) 2 2 K 6 L 2 = 2 : (5) This is a simultaneous system of two equations in two unknowns. The implied condition () becomes L K which simpli es to L K = L = K Example A monopolist with total cost function TC(Q) =Q 2 sells his product in two di erent countries. When he sells Q A units of the good in country A he will obtain the price P A =22 Q A for each unit. When he sells Q B units of the good in country B he obtains the price P B =4 4Q B : How much should the monopolist sell in the two countries in order to maximize pro ts? To solve this problem we calculate rst the pro t function as the sum of the revenues in each country minus the production costs. Total revenue in country A is Total revenue in country B is Total production costs are TR A = P A Q A =(22 Q A ) Q A TR B = P B Q B =(4 4Q B ) Q B TC =(Q A + Q B ) 2 9

10 Therefore the pro t is (Q A ;Q B )=(22 Q A ) Q A +(4 4Q B ) Q B (Q A + Q B ) 2 ; a quadratic function in Q A and Q B. In order to nd the pro t maximum we must nd the critical points, i.e., we must solve the rst order A = Q A +(22 Q A ) 2(Q A + Q B )=22 8Q A 2Q B = 4Q B +(4 4Q B ) 2(Q A + Q B )=4 2Q A 0Q B =0 8Q A +2Q B = 22 (6) 2Q A +0Q B = 4: Thus we have to solve a linear simultaneous system of two equations in two unknowns. 6 Simultaneous systems of equations 6. Linear systems We illustrate four methods to solve a linear system of equations using the example 6.. Using the slope-intercept form We rewrite both linear equations in slope-intercept form 5x +7y = 50 (7) 4x 6y = 8 7y = 50 5x y = x 4x 6y = 8 4x +8 = 6y y = 2 x x 0

11 The solutions to each equation form a line, which we have now described as the graph of linear functions. At the intersection point of the two lines the two linear functions must have the same y-value. Hence x = y = 2 x = 2 x + 5 j = 4x +5x 87 = 29x x = = We have found the value of x in a solution. To calculate the value of y we use one of the linear functions in slope-intercept form y = 2 =2 The solution to the system of equations is x =;y =2 It is strongly recommended to check the result for the original system of equations The method of substitution = = = 2 0 = 8 First we solve one of the equations in (7), say the second, for one of the variables, say y: 4x 6y = 8 4x +8 = 6y y = 4 6 x += 2 x + (8) Then we replace y in the other equation by the result. (Do not forget to place brackets aroundtheexpression.) Weobtainanequationinonlyonevariable,x, whichwesolve for x. 5x +7y = 50 µ 2 5x +7 x + = 50 5x + 4 x +2 = 50 5 x + 4 x +2 = x = 50 2 = 29 x = =

12 We have found x and can now use (8) to nd y: Hence the solution is x =;y= The method of elimination y = 2 x += 2 +=5 To eliminate x we proceed in two stages: First we multiply the rst equation by the coef- cient of x in the second equation and we multiply the second equation by the coe±cient of x in the rst equation 5x +7y = 50 j 4 4x 6y = 8 j 5 20x +28y = x 0y = 90 Then we subtract the second equation from the rst equation 20x +28y = x 0y = 90 j 0+28y ( 0y) =200 ( 90) 58y =290 y = 290 =5 58 Having found y we use one of the original equations to nd x 5x +7y = 50 5x +5 = 50 5x = 5 x = Instead of rst eliminating x we could have rst eliminated y: 6..4 Cramer's rule 5x +7y = 50 j 6 4x 6y = 8 j 7 0x +42y = 00 28x 42y = 26 j + 58x = 74 x = This is a little preview on linear algebra. In linear algebra the system of equations is written as 5 7 x 50 = 4 6 y 8 2

13 x 50 where and are so-called columns vectors, simply two numbers written x beloweachotherandsurroundedbysquarebrackets. is the 2 2-matrix 4 6 of coe±cients. A 2 2-matrix is a system of four numbers arranged in a square and surrounded by square brackets. With each 2 2-matrix a b A = c d we associate a new number called the determinant det A = a b c d = ad cb Notice that the determinant is indicated by vertical lines in contrast to square brackets. For instance, =5 ( 6) 4 7= 0 28 = 58 Cramer's rule uses determinants to give an explicit formula for the solution of a linear simultaneous system of equations of the form ax + by = e cx + dy = f or a b b d x y = e f : Namely, x = e f a c b d b d = ed bf ad bc y = a c a c e f b d = ae ce ad bc Thus x and y are calculated as the quotients of two determinants. In both cases we divide by the determinant of the matric of the coe±cients. For x the determinant in the numerator is the determinant of the matrix obtained by replacing in the matrix of coe±cients the coe±cients a and c of x by the constant terms e and f, i.e., the rst row is replaced by the row vector with the constant terms. Similarly, for y the determinant in the numerator is the determinant of the matrix obtained by replacing in the matrix of coe±cients the coe±cients b and d of y by the constant terms e and f, i.e., the second row is replaced by the row vector with the constant terms. The method works only if the determinant in the denominator is not zero.

14 In our example, 50 7 x 8 6 = 5 7 = y 4 8 = 5 7 = ( 6) ( 8) 7 5 ( 6) ( 8) ( 6) 4 7 = = = = = =5 Exercise Use the above methods to nd the optimum in Example Existence and uniqueness. A linear simultaneous system of equations ax + by = e cx + dy = f can have zero, exactly one or in nitely many solution. To see that only these cases can arise, bring both equations into slope-intercept form y = e f a b x y = f d c d x If the slopes of these two linear functions are the same, they describe identical or parallel lines. The slopes are identical when a = c, i.e., when the determinant of the matrix of b d coe±cients ad cb is zero. If in addition the intercepts are equal, both equations describe the same line. In this case all points (x; y) on the line are solutions. If the intercepts are di erent the two equations describe parallel lines. These do not intersect and hence there is no solution. Example 4 has no solution: The two lines x +2y = 2x +4y = 4 y = 2 2 x y = 2 x We assume here for simplicity that the coe±cients b and d are not zero. The arguments can be easily extended to these cases, except when all four coe±cients are zero. The latter case is trivial - either there is no solution or all pairs of numbers (x; y) are solutions. 4

15 are parallel x There is no common solution. Trying to nd one yields a contradiction 2 2 x = y = 2 x j + 2 x 2 = 6.2 One equation non-linear, one linear Consider, for instance, y 2 + x = 0 y + 2 x = In this case we solve the linear equation for one of the variables and substitute the result into the non-linear equation. As a result we obtain one non-linear equation in a single unknown. This makes the problem simpler, but admittedly some luck is needed to solve the non-linear equation in one variable. Solving the linear equation for x can sometimes give a simpler non-linear equation than solving for y and vice versa. One may have to try both possibilities. In our example it is convenient to solve for x: 2 x = y x = 2 2y y 2 +(2 2y) = y 2 2y +=(y ) 2 =0 So the unique solution is y =andx =2 2 =0. 6. Two non-linear equations There is no general method. One needs to memorize some tricks which work in special cases. 5

16 In the example of pro t-maximization with a Cobb-Douglas production function we were led to the system 5 6 K 6 L 2 = 2 2 K 6 L 2 = 2 : This is a simultaneous system of two equations in two unknowns which looks hard to solve. However, as we have seen, division of the two equations shows that L = K must hold in a critical point. We can substitute this into, say, the rst equation and obtain 2 = 6 K K = 2 p = K 2 p K = 2 K = 2 =8 5 6 L 2 = 6 K 5 6 K 2 = 6 K = 6 K 2 6 = 6 K Thus the solution to the rst order conditions (and, in fact, the optimum) is K = L =8. Remark This method works with any Cobb-Douglas production function Q (K; L) = K a L b where the indices a and b are positive and have a sum less than. Remark 2 The rst order conditions (4) and (5) form a \hidden" linear system of equations. Namely, if you take the logarithms (introduced later!) you get the system ln ln K + 2 ln L = ln 2 ln ln K 2 ln L = ln 2 which is linear in ln K and ln L. One can solve this system for ln K and ln L, whichthen givesusthevaluesforl and K. 6

z = f (x; y) f (x ; y ) f (x; y) f (x; y )

z = f (x; y) f (x ; y ) f (x; y) f (x; y ) BEEM0 Optimization Techiniques for Economists Lecture Week 4 Dieter Balkenborg Departments of Economics University of Exeter Since the fabric of the universe is most perfect, and is the work of a most

More information

z = f (x; y) = x 3 3x 2 y x 2 3

z = f (x; y) = x 3 3x 2 y x 2 3 BEE Mathematics for Economists Week, ecture Thursday..7 Functions in two variables Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics University of Exeter Objective This lecture has the purpose to make you familiar

More information

BEE1024 Mathematics for Economists

BEE1024 Mathematics for Economists BEE1024 Mathematics for Economists Dieter and Jack Rogers and Juliette Stephenson Department of Economics, University of Exeter February 1st 2007 1 Objective 2 Isoquants 3 Objective. The lecture should

More information

BEE1020 Basic Mathematical Economics Dieter Balkenborg Week 14, Lecture Thursday Department of Economics

BEE1020 Basic Mathematical Economics Dieter Balkenborg Week 14, Lecture Thursday Department of Economics BEE1020 Basic Mathematical Economics Dieter Balkenborg Week 14, Lecture Thursday 26.01.2006 Department of Economics Optimization University of Exeter Sincethefabricoftheuniverseismostperfect,and is the

More information

BEEM103 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER. BUSINESS School. January 2009 Mock Exam, Part A. OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions

BEEM103 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER. BUSINESS School. January 2009 Mock Exam, Part A. OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions BEEM03 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER BUSINESS School January 009 Mock Exam, Part A OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions Duration : TWO HOURS The paper has 3 parts. Your marks on the rst part will be

More information

Econ Review Set 2 - Answers

Econ Review Set 2 - Answers Econ 4808 Review Set 2 - Answers EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS 1. De ne the concept of equilibrium within the con nes of an economic model. Provide an example of an economic equilibrium. Economic models contain

More information

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction Microeconomic Theory -- Introduction. Introduction. Profit maximizing firm with monopoly power 6 3. General results on maximizing with two variables 8 4. Model of a private ownership economy 5. Consumer

More information

Constrained optimization.

Constrained optimization. ams/econ 11b supplementary notes ucsc Constrained optimization. c 2016, Yonatan Katznelson 1. Constraints In many of the optimization problems that arise in economics, there are restrictions on the values

More information

Tutorial 3: Optimisation

Tutorial 3: Optimisation Tutorial : Optimisation ECO411F 011 1. Find and classify the extrema of the cubic cost function C = C (Q) = Q 5Q +.. Find and classify the extreme values of the following functions (a) y = x 1 + x x 1x

More information

INTRODUCTORY MATHEMATICS FOR ECONOMICS MSCS. LECTURE 3: MULTIVARIABLE FUNCTIONS AND CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION. HUW DAVID DIXON CARDIFF BUSINESS SCHOOL.

INTRODUCTORY MATHEMATICS FOR ECONOMICS MSCS. LECTURE 3: MULTIVARIABLE FUNCTIONS AND CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION. HUW DAVID DIXON CARDIFF BUSINESS SCHOOL. INTRODUCTORY MATHEMATICS FOR ECONOMICS MSCS. LECTURE 3: MULTIVARIABLE FUNCTIONS AND CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION. HUW DAVID DIXON CARDIFF BUSINESS SCHOOL. SEPTEMBER 2009. 3.1 Functions of more than one variable.

More information

Bi-Variate Functions - ACTIVITES

Bi-Variate Functions - ACTIVITES Bi-Variate Functions - ACTIVITES LO1. Students to consolidate basic meaning of bi-variate functions LO2. Students to learn how to confidently use bi-variate functions in economics Students are given the

More information

a = (a 1; :::a i )

a = (a 1; :::a  i ) 1 Pro t maximization Behavioral assumption: an optimal set of actions is characterized by the conditions: max R(a 1 ; a ; :::a n ) C(a 1 ; a ; :::a n ) a = (a 1; :::a n) @R(a ) @a i = @C(a ) @a i The rm

More information

Microeconomic Theory-I Washington State University Midterm Exam #1 - Answer key. Fall 2016

Microeconomic Theory-I Washington State University Midterm Exam #1 - Answer key. Fall 2016 Microeconomic Theory-I Washington State University Midterm Exam # - Answer key Fall 06. [Checking properties of preference relations]. Consider the following preference relation de ned in the positive

More information

Chapter 4 Differentiation

Chapter 4 Differentiation Chapter 4 Differentiation 08 Section 4. The derivative of a function Practice Problems (a) (b) (c) 3 8 3 ( ) 4 3 5 4 ( ) 5 3 3 0 0 49 ( ) 50 Using a calculator, the values of the cube function, correct

More information

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions. a11 a 12. x 2

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions. a11 a 12. x 2 LONDON SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS Professor Leonardo Felli Department of Economics S.478; x7525 EC400 2010/11 Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions 1. Show that the general

More information

Chapter 4. Maximum Theorem, Implicit Function Theorem and Envelope Theorem

Chapter 4. Maximum Theorem, Implicit Function Theorem and Envelope Theorem Chapter 4. Maximum Theorem, Implicit Function Theorem and Envelope Theorem This chapter will cover three key theorems: the maximum theorem (or the theorem of maximum), the implicit function theorem, and

More information

Maximum Value Functions and the Envelope Theorem

Maximum Value Functions and the Envelope Theorem Lecture Notes for ECON 40 Kevin Wainwright Maximum Value Functions and the Envelope Theorem A maximum (or minimum) value function is an objective function where the choice variables have been assigned

More information

The Kuhn-Tucker Problem

The Kuhn-Tucker Problem Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 8: Nonlinear Programming - The Kuhn-Tucker Problem Note 8 is based on de la Fuente (2000, Ch. 7) and Simon and Blume (1994, Ch. 18 and 19). The Kuhn-Tucker

More information

Nonlinear Programming (NLP)

Nonlinear Programming (NLP) Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 6: Nonlinear Programming - Unconstrained Optimization Note 6 is based on de la Fuente (2000, Ch. 7), Madden (1986, Ch. 3 and 5) and Simon and Blume

More information

Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 5: Optimization Kuhn-Tucker conditions for problems with inequality constraints 1

Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 5: Optimization Kuhn-Tucker conditions for problems with inequality constraints 1 Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 5: Optimization Kuhn-Tucker conditions for problems with inequality constraints 1 Session: 15 Aug 2015 (Mon), 10:00am 1:00pm I. Optimization with

More information

Lecture 3 - Axioms of Consumer Preference and the Theory of Choice

Lecture 3 - Axioms of Consumer Preference and the Theory of Choice Lecture 3 - Axioms of Consumer Preference and the Theory of Choice David Autor 14.03 Fall 2004 Agenda: 1. Consumer preference theory (a) Notion of utility function (b) Axioms of consumer preference (c)

More information

ECON 186 Class Notes: Optimization Part 2

ECON 186 Class Notes: Optimization Part 2 ECON 186 Class Notes: Optimization Part 2 Jijian Fan Jijian Fan ECON 186 1 / 26 Hessians The Hessian matrix is a matrix of all partial derivatives of a function. Given the function f (x 1,x 2,...,x n ),

More information

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics Yulei Luo SEF of HKU January 12, 2009 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) MME January 12, 2009 1 / 35 Course Outline Economics: The study of the choices people (consumers,

More information

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice Economics 101 Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice 1 Uncle Léon The canonical model of exchange in economics is sometimes referred to as the Walrasian Model, after the early economist Léon

More information

How to Characterize Solutions to Constrained Optimization Problems

How to Characterize Solutions to Constrained Optimization Problems How to Characterize Solutions to Constrained Optimization Problems Michael Peters September 25, 2005 1 Introduction A common technique for characterizing maximum and minimum points in math is to use first

More information

System of Linear Equations. Slide for MA1203 Business Mathematics II Week 1 & 2

System of Linear Equations. Slide for MA1203 Business Mathematics II Week 1 & 2 System of Linear Equations Slide for MA1203 Business Mathematics II Week 1 & 2 Function A manufacturer would like to know how his company s profit is related to its production level. How does one quantity

More information

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution)

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution) Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution) 1. Checking properties of the Cobb-Douglas utility function. Consider the utility function u(x) Y n i1 x i i ; where x denotes a vector of n di erent goods x 2 R n +,

More information

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

September Math Course: First Order Derivative September Math Course: First Order Derivative Arina Nikandrova Functions Function y = f (x), where x is either be a scalar or a vector of several variables (x,..., x n ), can be thought of as a rule which

More information

EconS Cost Structures

EconS Cost Structures EconS 425 - Cost Structures Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 34 Introduction Today, we ll review

More information

Contents CONTENTS 1. 1 Straight Lines and Linear Equations 1. 2 Systems of Equations 6. 3 Applications to Business Analysis 11.

Contents CONTENTS 1. 1 Straight Lines and Linear Equations 1. 2 Systems of Equations 6. 3 Applications to Business Analysis 11. CONTENTS 1 Contents 1 Straight Lines and Linear Equations 1 2 Systems of Equations 6 3 Applications to Business Analysis 11 4 Functions 16 5 Quadratic Functions and Parabolas 21 6 More Simple Functions

More information

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7 Mathematical Foundations -- Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization An intuitive approach First Order Conditions (FOC) 7 Constraint qualifications 9 Formal statement of the FOC for a maximum

More information

Workbook. Michael Sampson. An Introduction to. Mathematical Economics Part 1 Q 2 Q 1. Loglinear Publishing

Workbook. Michael Sampson. An Introduction to. Mathematical Economics Part 1 Q 2 Q 1. Loglinear Publishing Workbook An Introduction to Mathematical Economics Part U Q Loglinear Publishing Q Michael Sampson Copyright 00 Michael Sampson. Loglinear Publications: http://www.loglinear.com Email: mail@loglinear.com.

More information

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics ECON2285: Mathematical Economics Yulei Luo Economics, HKU September 17, 2018 Luo, Y. (Economics, HKU) ME September 17, 2018 1 / 46 Static Optimization and Extreme Values In this topic, we will study goal

More information

Review of Optimization Methods

Review of Optimization Methods Review of Optimization Methods Prof. Manuela Pedio 20550 Quantitative Methods for Finance August 2018 Outline of the Course Lectures 1 and 2 (3 hours, in class): Linear and non-linear functions on Limits,

More information

EconS Vertical Integration

EconS Vertical Integration EconS 425 - Vertical Integration Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 26 Introduction Let s continue

More information

The Kuhn-Tucker and Envelope Theorems

The Kuhn-Tucker and Envelope Theorems The Kuhn-Tucker and Envelope Theorems Peter Ireland EC720.01 - Math for Economists Boston College, Department of Economics Fall 2010 The Kuhn-Tucker and envelope theorems can be used to characterize the

More information

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1 Microeconomics, Block I Part 1 Piero Gottardi EUI Sept. 26, 2016 Piero Gottardi (EUI) Microeconomics, Block I Part 1 Sept. 26, 2016 1 / 53 Choice Theory Set of alternatives: X, with generic elements x,

More information

Modelling Production

Modelling Production Modelling Production David N. DeJong University of Pittsburgh Econ. 1540, Spring 2010 DND () Production Econ. 1540, Spring 2010 1 / 23 Introduction The production function is the foundation upon which

More information

2. Which of the following is the ECONOMISTS inverse of the function y = 9/x 2 (i.e. find x as a function of y, x = f(y))

2. Which of the following is the ECONOMISTS inverse of the function y = 9/x 2 (i.e. find x as a function of y, x = f(y)) Anwers for Review Quiz #1. Material Covered. Klein 1, 2; Schaums 1, 2 1. Solve the following system of equations for x, y and z: x + y = 2 2x + 2y + z = 5 7x + y + z = 9 Answers: x = 1, y = 1, z = 1. 2.

More information

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics Yulei Luo SEF of HKU January 14, 2009 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) MME January 14, 2009 1 / 44 Comparative Statics and The Concept of Derivative Comparative Statics

More information

Lecture Notes for Chapter 12

Lecture Notes for Chapter 12 Lecture Notes for Chapter 12 Kevin Wainwright April 26, 2014 1 Constrained Optimization Consider the following Utility Max problem: Max x 1, x 2 U = U(x 1, x 2 ) (1) Subject to: Re-write Eq. 2 B = P 1

More information

2 Roots, peaks and troughs, in ection points

2 Roots, peaks and troughs, in ection points BEE1 { Basic Mathematical Economics Week 9, Lecture Wednesday.1. Discussing graphs of functions Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics University of Exeter 1 Objective We show how the rst and the second

More information

STUDY MATERIALS. (The content of the study material is the same as that of Chapter I of Mathematics for Economic Analysis II of 2011 Admn.

STUDY MATERIALS. (The content of the study material is the same as that of Chapter I of Mathematics for Economic Analysis II of 2011 Admn. STUDY MATERIALS MATHEMATICAL TOOLS FOR ECONOMICS III (The content of the study material is the same as that of Chapter I of Mathematics for Economic Analysis II of 2011 Admn.) & MATHEMATICAL TOOLS FOR

More information

BEE1004 / BEE1005 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER FACULTY OF UNDERGRADUATE STUDIES SCHOOL OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS. January 2002

BEE1004 / BEE1005 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER FACULTY OF UNDERGRADUATE STUDIES SCHOOL OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS. January 2002 BEE / BEE5 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER FACULTY OF UNDERGRADUATE STUDIES SCHOOL OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS January Basic Mathematics for Economists Introduction to Mathematical Economics Duration : TWO HOURS Please

More information

Notes on the Mussa-Rosen duopoly model

Notes on the Mussa-Rosen duopoly model Notes on the Mussa-Rosen duopoly model Stephen Martin Faculty of Economics & Econometrics University of msterdam Roetersstraat 08 W msterdam The Netherlands March 000 Contents Demand. Firm...............................

More information

; p. p y p y p y. Production Set: We have 2 constraints on production - demand for each factor of production must be less than its endowment

; p. p y p y p y. Production Set: We have 2 constraints on production - demand for each factor of production must be less than its endowment Exercise 1. Consider an economy with produced goods - x and y;and primary factors (these goods are not consumed) of production A and. There are xedcoe±cient technologies for producing x and y:to produce

More information

Tutorial 2: Comparative Statics

Tutorial 2: Comparative Statics Tutorial 2: Comparative Statics ECO42F 20 Derivatives and Rules of Differentiation For each of the functions below: (a) Find the difference quotient. (b) Find the derivative dx. (c) Find f (4) and f (3)..

More information

GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production

GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 8, September 21 Outline 1 Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preferences 2 Afriat s Theorem 3 Production Sets and Production Functions 4 Profits

More information

Constrained Optimization

Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization Joshua Wilde, revised by Isabel Tecu, Takeshi Suzuki and María José Boccardi August 13, 2013 1 General Problem Consider the following general constrained optimization problem:

More information

Adv. Micro Theory, ECON

Adv. Micro Theory, ECON Adv. Micro Theor, ECON 6-9 Assignment Answers, Fall Due: Monda, September 7 th Directions: Answer each question as completel as possible. You ma work in a group consisting of up to 3 members for each group

More information

School of Business. Blank Page

School of Business. Blank Page Maxima and Minima 9 This unit is designed to introduce the learners to the basic concepts associated with Optimization. The readers will learn about different types of functions that are closely related

More information

Previously in this lecture: Roughly speaking: A function is increasing (decreasing) where its rst derivative is positive

Previously in this lecture: Roughly speaking: A function is increasing (decreasing) where its rst derivative is positive BEE14 { Basic Mathematics for Economists Dieter Balkenborg BEE15 { Introduction to Mathematical Economics Department of Economics Week 6, Lecture, Notes: Sign Diagrams 6/11/1 University of Exeter Objective

More information

EconS 301. Math Review. Math Concepts

EconS 301. Math Review. Math Concepts EconS 301 Math Review Math Concepts Functions: Functions describe the relationship between input variables and outputs y f x where x is some input and y is some output. Example: x could number of Bananas

More information

Intro to Economic analysis

Intro to Economic analysis Intro to Economic analysis Alberto Bisin - NYU 1 Rational Choice The central gure of economics theory is the individual decision-maker (DM). The typical example of a DM is the consumer. We shall assume

More information

Introductory Microeconomics

Introductory Microeconomics Prof. Wolfram Elsner Faculty of Business Studies and Economics iino Institute of Institutional and Innovation Economics Introductory Microeconomics The Ideal Neoclassical Market and General Equilibrium

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6 Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO April 10, 017 Administrative Stuff Homework # is due at the end of class. I will post the solutions on the website later today. The midterm

More information

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice Olivier Blanchard April 2002 14.452. Spring 2002. Topic 2. 14.452. Spring, 2002 2 Want to start with a model with two ingredients: ²

More information

The Interpretation of λ

The Interpretation of λ The Interpretation of λ Lecture 49 Section 7.5 Robb T. Koether Hampden-Sydney College Wed, Apr 26, 2017 Robb T. Koether (Hampden-Sydney College) The Interpretation of λ Wed, Apr 26, 2017 1 / 6 Objectives

More information

Revealed Preferences and Utility Functions

Revealed Preferences and Utility Functions Revealed Preferences and Utility Functions Lecture 2, 1 September Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Outline 1 Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference 2 Equivalence between Axioms and Rationalizable Choices. 3 An Application:

More information

ECON 255 Introduction to Mathematical Economics

ECON 255 Introduction to Mathematical Economics Page 1 of 5 FINAL EXAMINATION Winter 2017 Introduction to Mathematical Economics April 20, 2017 TIME ALLOWED: 3 HOURS NUMBER IN THE LIST: STUDENT NUMBER: NAME: SIGNATURE: INSTRUCTIONS 1. This examination

More information

Econ 101A Midterm 1 Th 29 September 2004.

Econ 101A Midterm 1 Th 29 September 2004. Econ 0A Midterm Th 29 September 2004. You have approximately hour 20 minutes to answer the questions in the midterm. I will collect the exams at 2.30 sharp. Show your work, good luck! Problem. Utility

More information

Rice University. Fall Semester Final Examination ECON501 Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Writing Period: Three Hours

Rice University. Fall Semester Final Examination ECON501 Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Writing Period: Three Hours Rice University Fall Semester Final Examination 007 ECON50 Advanced Microeconomic Theory Writing Period: Three Hours Permitted Materials: English/Foreign Language Dictionaries and non-programmable calculators

More information

Some Notes on Adverse Selection

Some Notes on Adverse Selection Some Notes on Adverse Selection John Morgan Haas School of Business and Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Overview This set of lecture notes covers a general model of adverse selection

More information

Essential Mathematics for Economists

Essential Mathematics for Economists Ludwig von Auer (Universität Trier) Marco Raphael (Universität Trier) October 2014 1 / 343 1 Introductory Topics I: Algebra and Equations Some Basic Concepts and Rules How to Solve Simple Equations Equations

More information

Lecture 6: Contraction mapping, inverse and implicit function theorems

Lecture 6: Contraction mapping, inverse and implicit function theorems Lecture 6: Contraction mapping, inverse and implicit function theorems 1 The contraction mapping theorem De nition 11 Let X be a metric space, with metric d If f : X! X and if there is a number 2 (0; 1)

More information

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I 14.454 - Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I 04/02/2011 Due: Monday 4/11/2011 1 Question 1 - Kocherlakota (2000) Take an economy with a representative, in nitely-lived consumer. The consumer owns a technology

More information

1.1 Basic Algebra. 1.2 Equations and Inequalities. 1.3 Systems of Equations

1.1 Basic Algebra. 1.2 Equations and Inequalities. 1.3 Systems of Equations 1. Algebra 1.1 Basic Algebra 1.2 Equations and Inequalities 1.3 Systems of Equations 1.1 Basic Algebra 1.1.1 Algebraic Operations 1.1.2 Factoring and Expanding Polynomials 1.1.3 Introduction to Exponentials

More information

SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICS FOR PART I ENGINEERING. Self-paced Course

SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICS FOR PART I ENGINEERING. Self-paced Course SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICS FOR PART I ENGINEERING Self-paced Course MODULE ALGEBRA Module Topics Simplifying expressions and algebraic functions Rearranging formulae Indices 4 Rationalising a denominator

More information

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics ECON2285: Mathematical Economics Yulei Luo SEF of HKU September 9, 2017 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, 2017 1 / 81 Constrained Static Optimization So far we have focused on nding the maximum or minimum

More information

MATHEMATICS FOR ECONOMISTS. Course Convener. Contact: Office-Hours: X and Y. Teaching Assistant ATIYEH YEGANLOO

MATHEMATICS FOR ECONOMISTS. Course Convener. Contact: Office-Hours: X and Y. Teaching Assistant ATIYEH YEGANLOO INTRODUCTION TO QUANTITATIVE METHODS IN ECONOMICS MATHEMATICS FOR ECONOMISTS Course Convener DR. ALESSIA ISOPI Contact: alessia.isopi@manchester.ac.uk Office-Hours: X and Y Teaching Assistant ATIYEH YEGANLOO

More information

Study Skills in Mathematics. Edited by D. Burkhardt and D. Rutherford. Nottingham: Shell Centre for Mathematical Education (Revised edn 1981).

Study Skills in Mathematics. Edited by D. Burkhardt and D. Rutherford. Nottingham: Shell Centre for Mathematical Education (Revised edn 1981). Study Skills in Mathematics. Edited by D. Burkhardt and D. Rutherford. Nottingham: Shell Centre for Mathematical Education (Revised edn 1981). (Copies are available from the Shell Centre for Mathematical

More information

It is convenient to introduce some notation for this type of problems. I will write this as. max u (x 1 ; x 2 ) subj. to. p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 m ;

It is convenient to introduce some notation for this type of problems. I will write this as. max u (x 1 ; x 2 ) subj. to. p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 m ; 4 Calculus Review 4.1 The Utility Maimization Problem As a motivating eample, consider the problem facing a consumer that needs to allocate a given budget over two commodities sold at (linear) prices p

More information

Economics th April 2011

Economics th April 2011 Economics 401 8th April 2011 Instructions: Answer 7 of the following 9 questions. All questions are of equal weight. Indicate clearly on the first page which questions you want marked. 1. Answer both parts.

More information

Fall Final Examination Solutions Thursday 10 January 2012

Fall Final Examination Solutions Thursday 10 January 2012 EC 20.2 & 20. Fall 202 Deniz Selman Bo¼gaziçi University Final Examination Solutions Thursday 0 January 202. (9 pts) It is the heart of winter the isl of Ludos has been devastated by a violent snowstorm

More information

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP Prof. Olivier Bochet Room A.34 Phone 3 63 476 E-mail olivier.bochet@vwi.unibe.ch Webpage http//sta.vwi.unibe.ch/bochet Advanced Microeconomics Fall 2 Lecture Note Choice-Based Approach Price e ects, Wealth

More information

Lecture # 1 - Introduction

Lecture # 1 - Introduction Lecture # 1 - Introduction Mathematical vs. Nonmathematical Economics Mathematical Economics is an approach to economic analysis Purpose of any approach: derive a set of conclusions or theorems Di erences:

More information

EC611--Managerial Economics

EC611--Managerial Economics EC611--Managerial Economics Optimization Techniques and New Management Tools Dr. Savvas C Savvides, European University Cyprus Models and Data Model a framework based on simplifying assumptions it helps

More information

General Equilibrium and Welfare

General Equilibrium and Welfare and Welfare Lectures 2 and 3, ECON 4240 Spring 2017 University of Oslo 24.01.2017 and 31.01.2017 1/37 Outline General equilibrium: look at many markets at the same time. Here all prices determined in the

More information

ECON501 - Vector Di erentiation Simon Grant

ECON501 - Vector Di erentiation Simon Grant ECON01 - Vector Di erentiation Simon Grant October 00 Abstract Notes on vector di erentiation and some simple economic applications and examples 1 Functions of One Variable g : R! R derivative (slope)

More information

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 4, September 7 Outline 1 Structural Properties of Utility Functions 1 Local Non Satiation 2 Convexity 3 Quasi-linearity

More information

Mathematics for Economics ECON MA/MSSc in Economics-2017/2018. Dr. W. M. Semasinghe Senior Lecturer Department of Economics

Mathematics for Economics ECON MA/MSSc in Economics-2017/2018. Dr. W. M. Semasinghe Senior Lecturer Department of Economics Mathematics for Economics ECON 53035 MA/MSSc in Economics-2017/2018 Dr. W. M. Semasinghe Senior Lecturer Department of Economics MATHEMATICS AND STATISTICS LERNING OUTCOMES: By the end of this course unit

More information

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4 Solow Growth Model Michael Bar February 28, 208 Contents Introduction 2. Some facts about modern growth........................ 3.2 Questions..................................... 4 2 The Solow Model 5

More information

Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A

Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A December, 2016, Ted Bergstrom, UCSB I asked students to try to answer any 7 of the 8 questions. I intended the exam to have some relatively easy parts and

More information

SCHOOL OF DISTANCE EDUCATION

SCHOOL OF DISTANCE EDUCATION SCHOOL OF DISTANCE EDUCATION CCSS UG PROGRAMME MATHEMATICS (OPEN COURSE) (For students not having Mathematics as Core Course) MM5D03: MATHEMATICS FOR SOCIAL SCIENCES FIFTH SEMESTER STUDY NOTES Prepared

More information

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 6, September 14 Outline 1 Applications of Envelope Theorem 2 Hicksian Demand 3 Duality 4 Connections between

More information

Sometimes the domains X and Z will be the same, so this might be written:

Sometimes the domains X and Z will be the same, so this might be written: II. MULTIVARIATE CALCULUS The first lecture covered functions where a single input goes in, and a single output comes out. Most economic applications aren t so simple. In most cases, a number of variables

More information

1 Numbers, Sets, Algebraic Expressions

1 Numbers, Sets, Algebraic Expressions AAU - Business Mathematics I Lecture #1, February 27, 2010 1 Numbers, Sets, Algebraic Expressions 1.1 Constants, Variables, and Sets A constant is something that does not change, over time or otherwise:

More information

Partial Differentiation

Partial Differentiation CHAPTER 7 Partial Differentiation From the previous two chapters we know how to differentiate functions of one variable But many functions in economics depend on several variables: output depends on both

More information

E 600 Chapter 4: Optimization

E 600 Chapter 4: Optimization E 600 Chapter 4: Optimization Simona Helmsmueller August 8, 2018 Goals of this lecture: Every theorem in these slides is important! You should understand, remember and be able to apply each and every one

More information

Final Exam Review Packet

Final Exam Review Packet 1 Exam 1 Material Sections A.1, A.2 and A.6 were review material. There will not be specific questions focused on this material but you should know how to: Simplify functions with exponents. Factor quadratics

More information

Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade

Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade Alfonso A. Irarrazabal University of Oslo September 25, 2007 Contents 1 Simple Ricardian Model 3 1.1 Preferences................................. 3 1.2 Technologies.................................

More information

Final Exam Review Packet

Final Exam Review Packet 1 Exam 1 Material Sections A.1, A.2 and A.6 were review material. There will not be specific questions focused on this material but you should know how to: Simplify functions with exponents. Factor quadratics

More information

Birmingham MSc International Macro Autumn Lecture 7: Deviations from purchasing power parity explored and explained

Birmingham MSc International Macro Autumn Lecture 7: Deviations from purchasing power parity explored and explained Birmingham MSc International Macro Autumn 2015 Lecture 7: Deviations from purchasing power parity explored and explained 1. Some definitions: PPP, LOOP, absolute and relative [hese notes are very heavily

More information

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume Duality for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume Headwords: CONVEXITY, DUALITY, LAGRANGE MULTIPLIERS, PARETO EFFICIENCY, QUASI-CONCAVITY 1 Introduction The word duality is

More information

Social Science/Commerce Calculus I: Assignment #10 - Solutions Page 1/15

Social Science/Commerce Calculus I: Assignment #10 - Solutions Page 1/15 Social Science/Commerce Calculus I: Assignment #10 - Solutions Page 1/15 1. Consider the function f (x) = x - 8x + 3, on the interval 0 x 8. The global (absolute) maximum of f (x) (on the given interval)

More information

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions.

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions. Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 3: Optimization - interior optima 1 Session: 11-12 Aug 2015 (Thu/Fri) 10:00am 1:00pm I. Optimization: introduction Decision-makers (e.g. consumers,

More information

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018 EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 018 Show all your work clearly and make sure you justify all your answers. NAME 1. Consider the market for smart pencil in which only one firm (Superapiz) enjoys a

More information

3.1 Derivative Formulas for Powers and Polynomials

3.1 Derivative Formulas for Powers and Polynomials 3.1 Derivative Formulas for Powers and Polynomials First, recall that a derivative is a function. We worked very hard in 2.2 to interpret the derivative of a function visually. We made the link, in Ex.

More information

GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 1 September Q1. Are the preferences described below transitive? Strictly monotonic? Convex?

GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 1 September Q1. Are the preferences described below transitive? Strictly monotonic? Convex? GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 1 September 2011 Q1. Are the preferences described below transitive? Strictly monotonic? Convex? Explain briefly. The person consumes 2 goods, food and clothing.

More information

CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES. Likewise, we may define the higher order derivatives. f(x, y, z) = xy 2 + e zx. y = 2xy.

CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES. Likewise, we may define the higher order derivatives. f(x, y, z) = xy 2 + e zx. y = 2xy. April 15, 2009 CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES In this chapter D denotes an open subset of R n. 1. Introduction Definition 1.1. Given a function f : D R we define the second partial derivatives as

More information