ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "ECON2285: Mathematical Economics"

Transcription

1 ECON2285: Mathematical Economics Yulei Luo SEF of HKU September 9, 2017 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

2 Constrained Static Optimization So far we have focused on nding the maximum or minimum value of a function without restricting the choice variables. In many economic problems, the choice variables must be constrained by economic considerations. E.g., consumers maximizes their utility functions with the budget constraints. A rm minimizes the cost of production with the constraint of production technology. Such constraints may lower the maximum (or increase the minimum) for the objective function being maximized (or minimized). Because we are not able to choose freely among all choice variables, the objective function may not be as large as it can be. The constraints would be said to be nonbinding if we could obtain the same level of the objective function with or without imposing the constraint. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

3 Finding the Stationary Values For illustration, consider a consumer s choice problem: maximize his utility as follows u (x 1, x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 + 2x 1, (1) subject to the budget constraint 4x 1 + 2x 2 = 60. (2) For this simple constrained problem, we can solve it by substituting the budget constraint into the objective utility function without using any new technique: The budget constraint can be rewritten as x 2 = 60 4x 1 2 = 30 2x 1,which combining with the utility function gives u (x 1 ) = x 1 (30 2x 1 ) + 2x 1. (3) By setting u x 1 = 32 4x 1 = 0, we get x1 = 8 and x 2 = 14. Since d 2 u = 4 < 0, the stationary value constitutes a constrained dx1 2 maximum. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

4 The Lagrange multiplier method However, when the constraint is itself a complicated function or when the constraint cannot be solved to express one variable as an explicit function of the other variables, the technique of substitution and elimination is not enough to solve the constrained optimization problem. We will introduce a new method: the Lagrange multiplier method to solve the constrained optimization problem. The essence of the LM method is to convert a constrained extremum problem into a form such that the FOC of the free extremum problem can still be applied. In general, given an objective function subject to the constraint z = f (x, y) (4) g (x, y) = c where c is a constant, (5) we can write the Lagrange function as follows Z = L (x, y, λ) = f (x, y) + λ [c g (x, y)]. (6) Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

5 (Conti.) The symbol, λ, is called a Lagrange multiplier and will be determined and discussed later. If c g (x, y) = 0 always holds, the last term of Z will vanish regardless of the value of λ. Hence, nding the constrained maximum value of z is equivalent to nding a critical value of Z. The question now is: How can we make the parenthetical expression in (6) vanish? Let s proceed to do so, treating λ also as an additional choice variable (in addition to x and y). From the Lagrange function (6), the FOCs are L x = f x λg x = 0, (7) L y = f y λg y = 0, (8) L λ = c g (x, y) = 0. (9) The nal equation will automatically guarantee the satisfaction of the constraint. Since λ [c g (x, y)] = 0, the stationary values of Z in (6) must be identical with those of (4), subject to (5). Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

6 Reconsider the above consumer s choice problem, rst, we can write the Lagrange function as follows Z = L (x 1, x 2, λ) = x 1 x 2 + 2x 1 + λ [60 (4x 1 + 2x 2 )]. (10) The FOCs are: L x 1 = x λ = 0, (11) L x 2 = x 1 2λ = 0, (12) L λ = 60 (4x 1 + 2x 2 ) = 0, (13) solving the above equation for the critical values gives x 1 = 8, x 2 = 14, and λ = 4. (14) Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

7 Summary of the Procedure Step 1: Forming the Lagrange function Z = L(x, y, λ) = f (x, y) + λ[c g(x, y)]. (15) Step 2: Find the critical points of the Lagrangian function L(x, y, λ) by computing L/ x, L/ y, and L/ λ and setting each equal to 0 to solve for optimal (x, y, λ ) : L x = 0, L y L = 0, and λ = 0. Note that since λ just multiplies the constraint in the de nition of L, the equation L/ λ = 0 is equivalent to the constraint c g(x, y) = 0. Note that by introducing the Lagrange multiplier λ into the constrained problem, we have transformed a two-variable constrained problem to the three-variable unconstrained problem of nding the critical points of a function L(x, y, λ). Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

8 Total Di erential Approach In the discussion of the free extremum of z = f (x, y), it is learned that the necessary FOC can be stated in terms of the total di erential dz : dz = f x dx + f y dy = 0. (16) This statement remains valid after adding the constraint g(x, y) = c. However, with the constraint, we can no longer take both dx and dy as arbitrary change as before because now dx and dy are dependent each other: g(x, y) = c =) (dg =) g x dx + g y dy = 0. (17) Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

9 (Conti.) The FOC in terms of total di erential becomes dz = 0 subject to g(x, y) = c and g x dx + g y dy = 0. (18) In order to satisfy this necessary FOC, we must have f x g x = f y g y, (19) which together with the constraint g(x, y) = c will provide two equations to solve for the critical values of x and y. Hence, the total di erential approach yields the same FOC conditions as the Lagrange multiplier method. Note that the LM method gives the value of λ as a direct by-product. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

10 An Interpretation of the Lagrange Multiplier The Lagrange multiplier λ measures the sensitivity of Z (which is the value of Z in optimum) to the change in the constraint. In other words, it gives us a new measure of value of the scarce resources (The e ect of an increase in c would indicate how the optimal solution is a ected by a relaxation of the constraint). If we can express the optimal values of (x, y, λ ) as implicit functions of c : x = x (c) ; y = y (c) ; λ = λ (c) and all of which have continuous derivatives. Further, we have the following identities: f x (x, y ) λ g x (x, y ) = 0, (20) f y (x, y ) λ g y (x, y ) = 0, (21) c g (x, y ) = 0. (22) Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

11 (Conti.) and the Lagrange function in optimum can be written as Z = L(x, y, λ ) = f (x, y ) + λ [c g(x, y )], (23) which means that dz dc dx = f x dc + f dy y dc + dλ dc [c g(x, y )] {z } =0 +λ 1 g dx x dc + g dy y dc = f x = λ. λ g {z x } =0 (FOC for x) dc + f y C A dx λ g y {z } =0 (FOC for x) C A dy dc + λ Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

12 Generalization: n-variable and Multi-constraint Case The optimization problem can be formed as follows: max min z = f (x 1,, x n ), (24) fx 1,,x n g fx 1,,x n g It follows that the Lagrange function is subject to : g(x 1,, x n ) = c (25) Z = L (x 1,, x n, λ) = f (x 1,, x n ) + λ [c g(x 1,, x n )], (26) for which the FOCs are f i (x 1,, x n ) = λg i (x 1,, x n ), i = 1,, n. g(x 1,, x n ) = c Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

13 (Conti.) If the objective function has more than one variable, say, two constraints The Lagrange function is for which the FOCs are g(x 1,, x n ) = c and h(x 1,, x n ) = d (27) Z = f (x 1,, x n ) + λ [c g(x 1,, x n )] (28) +µ [d h(x 1,, x n )], f i (x 1,, x n ) = λg i (x 1,, x n ) + µh i (x 1,, x n ), i = 1,, n. g(x 1,, x n ) = c h(x 1,, x n ) = d. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

14 Second-Order Conditions Note that even though Z is indeed a standard type of extremum w.r.t. the choice variables, it is not so w.r.t. the Lagrange multiplier. (23) shows that unlike (x, y ), if λ is replaced by any other value of λ, no e ect will be produced on Z since c g(x, y ) = 0. Thus the role played by λ in the optimal solution is di ers basically from that of x and y. While it is safe to treat λ as another choice variable in the discussion of FOCs, we should treat λ di erently in the discussion of SOCs. The new SOCs can again be stated in terms of the SO total di erential d 2 z. The presence of the constraint will entail certain signi cant modi cations. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

15 Second-Order Total Di erential The constraint g(x, y) = c implies that dg = g x dx + g y dy = 0. dx and dy are no longer both arbitrary: we may take dx as an arbitrary change, but then dy is dependent on dx, i.e., dy = (g x /g y ) dx. Note that since g x and g y depend on x and y, dy also depends on x and y.thus, d 2 z = d (dz) = (dz) dx + (dz) dy x y (fx dx + f y dy) (fx dx + f y dy) = dx + dy x y dy dy = f xx dx + f xy dy + f y dx + f yx dx + f yy dy + f y x y = f xx dx 2 + 2f xy dxdy + f yy dy 2 dy + f y x dx + f dy y y dy = f xx dx 2 + 2f xy dxdy + f yy dy 2 + f y d 2 y Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

16 (Conti.) The last term disquali es d 2 z as a quadratic form. But d 2 z can be transformed into a quadratic form by virtue of the constraint g(x, y) = c : dg = 0 =) d (dg) = g xx dx 2 + 2g xy dxdy + g yy dy 2 + g y d 2 y = 0. (29) Solving the last equation for d 2 y and substituting the result in the expression of d 2 z gives d 2 f y z = f xx g xx dx 2 f y f y + 2 f xy g xy dxdy + f yy g yy g y g y g y = (f xx λg xx ) dx (f xy λg xy ) dxdy + (f yy λg yy ) dy 2 = Z xx dx 2 + 2Z xy dxdy + Z yy dy 2 where Z xx = f xx λg xx, Z xy = f xy λg xy, and Z yy = f yy λg yy are from partially di erentiating the derivatives in (7) and (8). Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

17 Second-Order Conditions For a constrained extremum problem, the SO necessary and su cient conditions are still determined by the SO total di erential d 2 z for dx and dy satisfying dg = g x dx + g y dy = 0. Theorem (SO su cient conditions) For maximum of z : d 2 z negative de nite, subject to dg = 0. For minimum of z : d 2 z positive de nite, subject to dg = 0. Theorem (SO necessary conditions) For maximum of z : d 2 z negative semide nite, subject to dg = 0. For minimum of z : d 2 z positive semide nite, subject to dg = 0. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

18 The Bordered Hessian As in the case of free extremum, it is possible to express the SO su cient condition in determinantal form. In the constrained-extremum case we will use what is known a bordered Hessian. Let s rst analyze the conditions for the sign de niteness of a two-variable quadratic form, subject to a linear constraint: q = au 2 + 2huv + bv 2 subject to αu + βv = 0 (33) Since the constraint means that v = (α/β) u, q = aβ 2 2hαβ + bα 2 u 2 which means that q is positive (negative) de nite i aβ 2 2hαβ + bα 2 > 0(< 0). β 2, (34) Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

19 (Conti.) It so happens that the following symmetric determinant 0 α β α a h β h b = aβ2 2hαβ + bα 2. (35) Consequently, we can state that q is positive de nite subject to αu + βv = 0 negative de nite 0 α β i α a h < 0 β h b =. (36) > 0 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

20 (Conti.) Note that the determinant used in this criterion is nothing but the discriminant of the original quadratic form a h h b, with a border placed on top and a similar border on the left: The border is merely composed of two coe cients α and β from the constraint, plus a zero in the principal diagonal. When applied to the quadratic form d 2 z, the (plain) discriminant consists of the Hessian Z xx Z xy Z xy Z yy. Given the constraint g x dx + g y dy = 0, d 2 z is positive de nite negative de nite s.t. dg = 0 i 0 g x g y g x Z xx Z xy g y Z xy Z yy {z } jhj = < 0 > 0 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

21 Example: Consumer s Utility Maximization Problem max u (x 1, x 2 ) = x 1 x 2 subject to x 1 + x 2 = B. (37) 1 + r Step1: The Lagrange function is x 2 Z = L (x 1, x 2, λ) = u (x 1, x 2 ) + λ B x 1. (38) 1 + r Step 2: The FOCs are Z λ = B x x 2 1 = 0, (39) 1 + r Z = x 2 λ = 0, (40) x 1 Z λ = x 1 = 0, (41) x r which can be used to solve for optimal level of x1 = B/2 and = B (1 + r) /2. x 2 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

22 (Conti.) Next, we should check the SO su cient condition for a maximum. The bordered Hessian for this problem is r H = r 1 0 = 2 > 0. (42) 1 + r Thus the SO su cient condition is satis ed for a maximum. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

23 -Variable Case When the optimization problem takes the form: max min fx 1,,x n g fx 1,,x n g z = f (x 1,, x n ), subject to: g(x 1,, x n ) = c, (43) the Lagrange function is Z = f (x 1,, x n ) + λ [c g(x 1,, x n )], (44) and dx 1,, dx n satisfy the relation: dg = g 1 dx g n dx n = 0. (45) which implies that the bordered Hessian is H 0 g 1 g n g 1 Z 11 Z 1n =.... g n Z n1 Z nn Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

24 (Conti.) its bordered leading principal minors are 0 g 1 g 2 H 2 = g 1 Z 11 Z 12 g 2 Z 21 Z 22, 0 g 1 g 2 g 3 H 3 = g 1 Z 11 Z 12 Z 13 g 2 Z 21 Z 22 Z 23, g 3 Z 31 Z 32 Z 33, H = H n Theorem (Conditions for Maximum) (1) FO necessary condition: Z λ = Z 1 = = Z n = 0. (2) SO su cient condition: H2 > 0, H3 < 0., ( 1) n Hn > 0. Theorem (Conditions for Minimum) (1) FO necessary condition: Z λ = Z 1 = = Z n = 0. (2) SO su cient condition: H 2 < 0, H 3 < 0., H n < 0. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

25 Quasiconcavity and Quasiconvexity For an unconstrained optimization problem (a free extremum problem), the concavity (convexity) of the objective function guarantees the existence of absolute maximum (absolute minimum). For a constrained optimization problem, we will show that the quasiconcavity (quasiconvexity) of the objective function guarantees the existence of absolute maximum (absolute minimum). Quasiconcavity (quasiconvexity), like concavity (convexity), can be either strict or nonstrict. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

26 De nition A function is quasiconcave (quasiconvex) i for any pair of distinct points u and v in the convex domain of f, and for 0 < θ < 1, f (v) f (u) implies that f (θu + (1 θ) v) f (u) (f (θu + (1 θ) v) f (v)). (46) Further, if the weak inequality ( ) is replaced by the strict inequality < ( > ), f is said to be strictly quasiconcave (strictly quasiconvex). Fact Quasiconcavity (quasiconvexity) is a weaker condition than concavity (convexity). Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

27 Theorem (Negative of a function) If f (x) is quasiconcave (strictly quasiconcave), then (strictly quasiconvex). f (x) is quasiconvex Proof. Use the fact that multiplying an inequality by inequality. 1 reverses the sense of Theorem (Concavity vs. quasiconcavity) Any (strictly) concave (convex) function is (strictly) quasiconcave (quasiconvex) function, but the converse is not true. Proof. Using the de nitions of concavity and quasiconcavity to prove. f (θu + (1 θ) v) θf (u) + (1 θ) f (v) f (u) (because we assume that f (v) f (u)) Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

28 Theorem (Linear function) If f (x) is linear, then it is quasiconcave as well as quasiconvex. Proof. Using the fact that if f (x) is linear, then it is concave as well as convex. Fact Unlike concave (convex) functions, a sum of two quasiconcave (quasiconvex) functions is not necessarily quasiconcave (quasiconvex). Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

29 Sometimes it is easier to check quasiconcavity and quasiconvexity by the following alternative de nitions. We rst introduce the concept of convex sets. De nition If, for any two points in set S, the line segment connecting these two points lies entirely in S, then S is said to be a convex set. A corresponding algebraic de nition is: A set S is convex i for any two points u 2 S and v 2 S, and for every scalar θ 2 [0, 1], it is true that w = θu + (1 θ) v 2 S. Note that u and v can be in the space with any dimension. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

30 Fact To qualify as a convex set, the set of points must contain no holes, and its boundary must not be indented anywhere. See Figure 11.8 in the book. Fact Note that convex sets and convex functions are distinct concepts. In describing a function, the word convex speci es how a curve or surface bends itself-it must form a valley. But in describing a set, the word speci es how the points in the set are packed together - they must not allow any holes and the boundary must not be indented. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

31 De nition A function f (x), where x is a vector of variables, is quasiconcave (quasiconvex) i for any constant k, the set S = fxjf (x) kg (S = fxjf (x) kg) is convex. See Figure 12.5 (a), (b), and (c). The three functions in Figure 12.5 contain concave as well as convex segments and hence are neither concave or convex. But the function in Fig 12.5 (a) is quasiconcave because for any value of k, the set S is convex. The function in Fig 12.5 (b) is quasiconvex because for any value of k, the set S is convex. The monotonic function in Fig 12.5 (b) is quasiconcave as well as quasiconvex because both S and S are convex. Hence, given that S is convex, we can only conclude that the function f is quasiconcave, but not necessarily concave. Examples: (1) Z = x 2 (x 0) is quasiconvex as well as quasiconcave since both S and S are convex. (2) Z = (x a) 2 + (y b) 2 is quasiconvex since S is convex. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

32 If the function z = f (x 1,, x n ) is twice continuously di erentiable, quasiconcavity and quasiconvexity can be checked by the rst and second partial derivatives of the function. De ne a bordered determinant as follows: B 0 f 1 f n f 1 f 11 f 1n =... f n f n1 f nn (47) Note that the determinant B is di erent from the bordered Hessian H : Unlike H, the border in B is composed of the rst derivatives of the function f rather than the constraint function g. Hence, if B satis es the SO su cient condition for strict quasiconcavity (will be speci ed below), H must also satisfy the SO su cient condition for constrained maximization problem. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

33 (Conti.) We can de ne successive principal minors of B as follows: B 1 = 0 f 1 f 1 f 11, 0 f 1 f 2 B 2 = f 1 f 11 f 12 f 2 f 21 f 22,, B n = B (48) A su cient condition for f to be quasiconcave on the nonnegative domain is that B 1 < 0, B 2 > 0,, ( 1) n B n > 0. (49) For quasiconvexity, the corresponding condition is that B 1 < 0, B 2 < 0,, B n < 0. (50) A necessary condition for f to be quasiconcave on the nonnegative domain is that B 1 0, B 2 0,, ( 1) n B n 0. (51) For quasiconvexity, the corresponding condition is that B 1 0, B 2 0,, B n 0. (52) Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

34 Example: Consider z = f (x 1, x 2 ) = x 1 x 2, since f 1 = x 2, f 2 = x 1, f 11 = f 22 = 0, f 12 = f 21 = 1, the relevant principal minors are B1 = 0 x 2 x 2 0 = x 2 2 0, B2 = 0 x 2 x 1 x x Thus, z = x 1 x 2 is quasiconcave on the nonnegative domain. = 2x 1x 2 0. (53) Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

35 Example: Show that z = f (x, y) = x a y b (x > 0, y > 0, a, b 2 (0, 1)) is quasiconcave. Since f x = ax a 1 y b, f y = bx a y b 1, f xx = a (a 1) x a 2 y b, f yy = b (b 1) x a y b 2, f xy = f yx = abx a 1 y b 1, B 1 = B 2 = 0 f x f x 0 ax = a 1 y b 2 < 0, (54) 0 f x f y f x f xx f xy f y f yx f yy = 2ab (a + b) x 3a 2 y 3b 2 > 0, (55) which means that the function is quasiconcave. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

36 (Conti.) In this case, the condition for concavity can be expressed as f xx f yy fxy 2 = ha (a 1) x a 2 y bi h b (b 1) x a y b 2i habx a 1 y b 1i 2 (56) = ab (a 1) (b 1) x 2a 2 y 2b 2 a 2 b 2 x 2a 2 y 2b 2 = ab [1 a b] x 2a 2 y 2b 2 (57) and this expression is positive (as required for concavity) for 1 a b > 0 =) a + b < 1. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

37 Fact When the function in the constraint is linear, that is, g(x 1,, x n ) = a 1 x a n x n = c, the bordered determinant B and the bordered Hessian H have the following relationship: B = λ 2 H. (58) Hence, in the linear constraint case, the two bordered determinants always have the same sign at the stationary point. Fact (Relative vs. absolute extreme) If a function is quasiconcave (quasiconvex), by the same reasons for concave (convex) functions, its relative maximum (relative minimum) is an absolute maximum (absolute minimum). Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

38 Utility Maximization and Consumer Demand Consider the following two-commodity consumer optimization problem: max u (x, y) (u x > 0, u y > 0) (59) subject to the budget constraint where P x, P y, and B are given exogenously. The Lagrange function is then P x x + P y y = B (60) Z = u (x, y) + λ (B P x x P y y). (61) Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

39 The FOCs are From the last two equations, we have Z λ = B P x x P y y = 0 (62) Z x = u x λp x = 0 (63) Z y = u y λp y = 0. (64) u x u y = P x P y, (65) where u x u y = MRS xy is called the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) of x for y. Thus, we have the well-known equality: MRS xy = P x P y which is the necessary condition for the interior optimal solution. See the gure of the indi erence curve. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

40 If the bordered Hessian is positive, i.e., 0 P x P y P x u xx u xy P y u yx u yy = 2P x P y u xy Py 2 u xx Px 2 u yy > 0, in which all elements are evaluated at the optimum, then the stationary value of u is maximum. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

41 Static Optimization with Inequality Constraints So far we have considered optimization problem with equality constraints. Now we shall consider constraints that may be satis ed as inequailities in the solution. Consider the simple optimization problem with inequality constraints: max f (x, y) subject to g (x, y) c. (66) fx,y g2s We seek the largest value attained by f (x, y) in the admissible or feasible set S of all pairs (x, y) satisfying g (x, y) c. Note that problems where one wants to minimize f (x, y) subject to fx, yg 2 S can be handled by instead studying the problem of maximizing f (x, y) subject to fx, yg 2 S. This problem can be solved by using an extended Lagrangian multiplier method introduced above, and it involves examining the stationary points of f in the interior of the feasible set S and the behavior of f on the boundary of S. This new method is originally proposed by two Princeton mathematicians: H. W. Kuhn and A.W. Tucker. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

42 Theorem (Recipe for solving the optimization problem with inequality constraints.) A. Associate a Lagrange multiplier λ with the constraint g (x, y) c, and de ne the Lagrangian function as follows Z = L(x, y) = f (x, y) + λ[c g(x, y)]. (67) B. Equate the partial derivatives of Z w.r.t. x and y to zeros: f x λg x = 0, f y λg y = 0. (68) C. Introduce the complementary slackness condition D. Require (x, y) to satisfy the constraint λ 0 and λ[c g(x, y)] = 0. (69) g (x, y) c (70) Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

43 (Conti.) Step C (the complementary slackness condition) is tricky. It requires that λ is nonnegative and moreover that λ = 0 if g (x, y) < c. Thus, if λ > 0, we must have g (x, y) = c. Note that the Lagrange multiplier λ can be interpreted as a price (it is called the shadow price) associated with increasing the right-hand side c of the resource constraint g (x, y) c by 1 unit. With this interpretation, prices are nonnegative, and if the resource constraint is not binding because g (x, y) < c at the optimum, the price associated with increasing by one unit is 0. It is possible to have both λ = 0 and g (x, y) = c. The two inequalities are complementary in the sense that at most one can be slack, that is, at most one can hold with inequality. Equivalently, at least one must be an equality. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

44 (Conti.) Conditions (68) and (69) are called the Kuhn-Tucker conditions. Note that they are necessary conditions for the above problem. Note that with an inequality constraint, one will have Z λ = c g(x, y) > 0 at an optimum if the constraint holds with inequality at that point. For this reason, we wouldn t di erentiate the Lagrangian w.r.t. λ. Example: Consider the following problem max fx,y g2s f (x, y) = x 2 + y 2 + y 1 (71) The Lagrange function is subject to : g (x, y) = x 2 + y 2 1. (72) Z = x 2 + y 2 + y 1 + λ 1 x 2 + y 2. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

45 The Trial-and-Error Approach to Search Optimal Solutions (Conti.) The FOCs are then The complementary slackness condition is Z x = 2x 2λx = 0 (73) Z y = 2y + 1 2λy = 0. (74) λ 0 and λ 1 x 2 + y 2 = 0. (75) we want to nd all pairs (x, y) that satisfy these conditions for some suitable value of λ. Begin by looking at (73). This condition implies that 2x (1 λ) = 0. There are two possibilities: λ = 1 or x = 0. If λ = 1, then (74) implies that 1 = 0, a contradiction. Hence, x = 0. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

46 (Conti.) Since x = 0, Suppose that x 2 + y 2 = 1, we have y = 1. We try y = 1 rst. Substituting y = 1 into (74) implies that λ = 3/2 and (75) is satis ed. Hence, (x, y) = (0, 1) with λ = 3/2 is a candidate for optimality. Similarly, if y = 1, λ = 1/2 and (75) is also satis ed. Hence, (x, y) = (0, 1) with λ = 1/2 is also a candidate for optimality. Finally, consider the case where x = 0 and x 2 + y 2 < 1. In this case, (75) implies that λ = 0 and (74) implies y = 1/2. Hence, (x, y) = (0, 1/2) with λ = 0 is also a candidate for optimality. We then conclude that there are 3 candidates for optimality: f (0, 1) = 1, f (0, 1) = 1, f (0, 1/2) = 5/4. Because we want to maximize a continuous function over a closed bounded set, by the Extreme value theorem there is a solution to the problem. Thus, (x, y) = (0, 1) solved the maximization problem. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

47 Consider the n-variable problem max f (x 1,, x n ) s.t. 8 < : g 1 (x 1,, x n ) c 1 g m (x 1,, x n ) c m (76) Theorem (Recipe for Solving the General Problem with n-variable) A). Write down the Lagrange function L = f (x 1,, x n ) + m j=1 λ j (c j g j (x 1,, x n )) (77) where λ j is the Lagrange multiplier associated with the j th constraint. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

48 Theorem (conti.) B) Equate all the FOCs to 0, for each i = 1,, n : f x i m g j λ j = 0. (78) j=1 x i C) Impose the complementary slackness conditions: λ j 0 ( = 0 if c j g j (x 1,, x n ) > 0), j = 1,, m. (79) D) Require x 1,, x n to satisfy the constraints g j (x 1,, x n ) c j, j = 1,, m. (80) Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

49 Theorem (Kuhn-Tucker Su cient Conditions) Consider (66) and suppose that (x, y ) satis es conditions (68), (69) and (70). If the Lagrange function is concave, then (x, y ) solves the problem. Proof. If (x, y ) satis es the conditions in (68), then (x, y ) is a stationary point of the Lagrangian. Because a stationary point of the concave Lagrangian will maximize the function, we have L(x, y ) = f (x, y ) + λ[c g(x, y )] f (x, y) + λ[c g(x, y)] Rearranging the terms gives f (x, y ) f (x, y) λ[g(x, y ) g(x, y)] (81) Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

50 Proof. (conti.) If c g (x, y ) > 0, then by (69), we have λ = 0, so (81) implies that f (x, y ) f (x, y). On the other hand, if c g(x, y ) = 0, then λ[g(x, y ) g(x, y)] = λ[c g(x, y)]. Here λ 0, and c g(x, y) 0 for all (x, y) satisfying the constraint. Hence, (x, y ) solves problem (66). Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

51 A Special Case: Nonnegativity Conditions on the Variables Many economic variables must be nonnegative by their very nature. It is not di cult to incorporate such constraints in our above formulation. For example, x 0 can be expressed as h (x, y) = x 0, and we introduce an additional Lagrange multiplier to go with it. Consider the problem max f (x, y) subject to g (x, y) c, x 0, y 0. (82) fx,y g2s Note that it can be rewritten as max f (x, y) subject to g (x, y) c, x 0, y 0. (83) fx,y g2s Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

52 (Conti.) The Lagrange function is then Z = L(x, y, λ) = f (x, y) + λ[c g(x, y)] + µ 1 x + µ 2 y. (84) The FOCs are f x λg x + µ 1 = 0 (85) f y λg y + µ 2 = 0 (86) λ 0, λ[c g(x, y)] = 0 (87) µ 1 0, µ 1 x = 0 (88) µ 2 0, µ 2 y = 0, (89) which is equivalent to f x λg x 0 ( = 0 if x > 0) f y λg y 0 ( = 0 if y > 0) λ 0 ( = 0 if c g(x, y) > 0) Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

53 The same idea can obviously be extended to the n-variable problem 8 < g 1 (x 1,, x n ) c 1 max f (x 1,, x n ) s.t., (90) : g m (x 1,, x n ) c m x 1 0,, x n 0. The necessary FOCs for the solution of (90) are that, for each i = 1,, n : f x i m g j λ j j=1 x i 0 ( = 0 if x i > 0) (91) λ j 0 ( = 0 if c j g j (x, y) > 0), j = 1,, (92) m. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

54 Example: The consumer s maximization problem is subject to The Lagrange function is max u = u (x, y) P x x + P y y B (93) c x x + c y y C (94) x 0 (95) y 0 (96) Z = u (x, y) + λ 1 [B (P x x + P y y)] + λ 2 [C (c x x + c y y)] +µ 1 x + µ 2 y Suppose that u (x, y) = xy 2, B = 100, P x = P y = 1, C = 120, c x = 2, and c y = 1. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

55 (Conti.) The Kuhn-Tucker conditions are Z x = y 2 λ 1 2λ 2 0, x 0, xz x = 0. equivalently, y 2 λ 1 2λ 2 0 (= 0 if x > 0) Z y = 2xy λ 1 λ 2 0, y 0, yz y = 0. λ 1 0, λ 1 [100 (x + y)] = 0, 100 (x + y) 0. λ 2 0, λ 2 [120 (2x + y)] = 0, 120 (2x + y) 0. Again, the solution procedure involves a certain amount of trial and error. We can rst choose one of the constraints to be nonbinding and solve for x and y. Once found, use these values to test if the constraint chosen to be nonbinding is violated. If it is, then redo the procedure choosing another constraint to be nonbinding. If violation of the nonbinding constraint occurs again, then we can assume both constraints bind and the solution is determined only by the constraints. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

56 (Conti.) Step 1: Assume that the second constraint is nonbinding in the solution (that is, 120 > 2x + y), so that λ 2 = 0 by complementary slackness. But let x, λ 1, and y be positive so that: Z x = y 2 λ 1 = 0 Z y = 2xy λ 1 = = x + y Solving for x and y yields a trial solution x = , y = But substituting this into the second constraint gives = > 120. In other words, this solution violates the second constraint and must be rejected. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

57 (Conti.) Step 2: Reverse the assumption so that λ 1 = 0 and let x, λ 2, and y be positive so that: Z x = y 2 λ 2 = 0 Z y = 2xy λ 2 = = 2x + y Solving for x and y yields a trial solution x = 20, y = 80 which implies that λ 2 = These solutions together with λ 1 = 0 satisfy all constraints. Thus we accept them as the nal solution to the Kuhn-Tucker conditions. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

58 Example: Quasi-linear Preference Consumer s problem is to choose two commodities to maximize his utility function: u(x, y) = y + a ln (x) (97) subject to px + qy I, (98) x 0 (99) y 0 (100) where a is a given positive constant. p and q are both positive prices. First, we construct the Lagrange function as follows L = y + a ln (x) + λ [I px qy] + +µ 1 x + µ 2 y (101) Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

59 (Conti.) The Kuhn-Tucker conditions can be written as a a λp 0, x 0, λp x = 0 (102) x x 1 λq 0, y 0, (1 λq) y = 0 (103) I px qy 0, λ 0, (I px qy) λ = 0. (104) in which we have 2 3 possibilities of equalities or inequalities because there are two nonnegative variables and one inequality constraint. First, note that the budget constraint must be binding (that is, px + qy = I, all available income must be used up) because the marginal utility is positive: u x (x, y) > 0 and u y (x, y) > 0, that is, consuming more can result in higher levels of utility. Formally, if the BC is not binding, then λ = 0, which means that a x 0 and 1 0, both are contradiction. Now we can reduce the number of possibilities to 4 : x > 0, x = 0, y > 0, y = 0. We can also rule out the possibility that x = 0 and y = 0 because they don t satisfy the BC: px + qy = I > 0. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

60 (Conti.) If x = 0 and y = I /q > 0, the second line in the Kuhn-Tucker conditions means that λ = 1 q and the rst line in the KT conditions implies that p q, which is a contradiction. Intuitively, the initial one unit increase in x will result in positively in nite utility, so zero consumption in x can t be optimal. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

61 (Conti.) If y = 0 and x = I /p > 0, the rst line in the KT conditions implies that a λp = 0 =) λ = a x I. (105) Substituting it into the second line of the KT conditions gives 1 a q 0 =) I aq. I If these parameters (I, a, q) satisfy this condition, then x = I /p and y = 0 is a candidate optimal solution. Finally, if both x and y are positive, the rst two lines in the KT conditions gives a x λp = 0 = 1 λq =) x = aq/p and y = I /q a. (106) Hence, if I > aq (y > 0), then it is also a candidate optimal solution. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

62 (Conti.) In sum, the optimal solution eventually depends on the values of parameters (I, a, q): x = I /p and y = 0 if I aq. x = aq/p and y = I /q a if I > aq. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

63 The Envelop Theorem for Unconstrained Optimization A maximum-value function is an objective function where the choice variables have been assigned their optimal values. Thus, this function indirectly becomes a function of the parameters only through the parameters e ects on the optimal values of the choice variables, and is also referred to as the indirect objective function. The indirect objective function traces out all the maximum values of the objective functions these parameters vary. Hence, the IOF is an envelop of the set of optimized objective functions generated by varying the parameters. Consider max u = f (x, y, φ) where x and y are choice variables and φ is a parameter. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

64 The FOC necessary conditions: f x (x, y, φ) = f y (x, y, φ) = 0. (107) If the SO conditions are met, these two equations implicitly de ne the solutions x = x (φ) and y = y (φ). Substituting these solutions back into the f gives the IOF (or the maximum value function) Di erentiating V (φ) w.r.t. φ gives V (φ) = f (x (φ), y (φ), φ). (108) dv dφ = f x x φ + f y y φ + f φ = f φ. This result means that at the optimum (f x = f y = 0), as φ varies, with x and y allowed to adjust, dv d φ gives the same result as if x and y are treated as constants (only the direct e ect need to be considered). This is the essence of the Envelop theorem. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

65 The Envelop Theorem for Constrained Optimization The problem becomes max u = f (x, y, φ) s.t. g (x, y, φ) = 0. The Lagrangian is then Z = f (x, y, φ) λg (x, y, φ). The FOCs are Z x = f x λg x = 0 Z y = f y λg y = 0 Z λ = g (x, y, φ) = 0. The optimal solution is then x = x (φ), y = y (φ), λ = λ (φ). Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

66 Substituting these solutions back into the f gives the IOF (or the maximum value function) Di erentiating V (φ) w.r.t. φ gives Further, note that since we have V (φ) = f (x (φ), y (φ), φ). (109) dv dφ = f x x φ + f y y φ + f φ. (110) g (x (φ), y (φ), φ) = 0, x g x φ + g y y φ + g φ = 0. (111) Multiplying λ on both sides and then combining it with the expression gives the Envelop theorem for constrained optimization: of dv d φ dv dφ = (f x λg x ) x φ + (f y λg y ) y φ + f φ λg φ = Zφ. (112) Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

67 which means that this function is homogenous function of degree 0 (j 0 = 1). Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81 Homogeneous Functions De nition A function is said to be homogenous of degree r, if multiplication of each of its independent variables by a constant j will alter the value of the function by the proportion j r, that is, f (jx 1,, jx n ) = j r f (x 1,, x n ). (113) In economics applications, we assume that j is usually taken to be positive. Example Given the function f (x, y, w) = x/y + 2w/3x, if we multiply each variable by j, we get f (jx, jy, jw) = x/y + 2w/3x = j 0 f (x, y, w), (114)

68 De nition Production functions are usually homogeneous functions of degree 1. They are often referred to as linearly homogeneous functions. Assume that the production function has the following form: Q = f (K, L) (115) The mathematical assumption of linear homogeneity would amount to the economic assumption of constant returns to scale (CRTS), because linear homogeneity means that raising all inputs j-fold will always raise the output (value of the function) exactly j-fold also. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

69 Fact Given the LH production function Q, the average production of labor (APL) and of capital (APK) can be expressed as functions of the capital-labor ratio, k = K /L alone. Fact Multiplying each independent variable by a factor j = 1/L and using the property of linear homogeneity, we have APL = Q L = f K L, 1 = f (k, 1) = φ (k). (116) APK = Q K = Q L L K = φ (k) k (117) Therefore, while the production function is homogeneous degree one, both APL and APK are homogenous of degree zero in the K and L. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

70 Fact Given the LH production function Q, the marginal production of labor (MPL) and of capital (MPK) can be expressed as functions of the capital-labor ratio, k = K /L alone. Fact To nd the marginal products, we rewrite the total product as Q = Lφ (k).di erentiating it w.r.t. K and L gives MPK = Q K MPL = Q L = L φ (k) K = φ (k) + L φ (k) L = φ (k) φ 0 (k) k (k) k = Ldφ dk K = φ0 (k) = φ (k) + Lφ 0 (k) K L 2 They are also homogenous of degree zero in the K and L (they remain the same as long as k is held constant. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

71 This theorem says that the value of a LH function can always be expressed as a sum of terms, each of which is one of the independent variables and the FO partial derivative w.r.t. to that variable. Hence, under conditions of CRTS, if each input is paid the amount of its marginal product, the total product will be exhausted by the distributive shares for all the input factors, or the pure economic pro t will be zero. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81 Theorem (Euler s Theorem) If Q = f (K, L) is linearly homogeneous, then Proof. K Q K + L Q L = Q. K Q K + L Q L = K φ 0 (k) + L φ (k) φ 0 (k) k = Lφ (k) = Q.

72 Example (Cobb-Douglas Production Function) One speci c production function is the Cobb-Douglas function: Q = AK α L β (118) where A is a positive constant, α and β are positive fractions. Major features of this production are: (1) It is homogenous of degree (α + β). (2) In the special case of α + β = 1, it is linearly homogeneous. (3) Its isoquants are negatively sloped throughout and strictly convex for positive values of K and L. (4) It is strictly quasiconcave for positive K and L. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

73 Example (Cobb-Douglas Production Function) (conti.) For the special case α + β = 1, Q = AK α L 1 α = ALk α. (119) APL = Q L = Ak α, APK = Q K = Ak α 1. (120) MPK = Q K = Aαk α The Euler theorem can be veri ed as follows: K Q K + L Q L 1, MPL = Q L = A (1 α) k α. (121) = KAαk α 1 + LA (1 α) k α = k α [AαL + A (1 α) L] = ALk α = Q. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

74 Example (CES Production Function) A constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production function is Q = A δk ρ + (1 δ) L ρ 1/ρ (A > 0; 0 < δ < 1; 1 < ρ 6= 0) (122) where δ is the distributive parameter, like α in the CD function, and ρ is the substitution parameter-which has no counterpart in the CD function. First, the CES production function is homogeneous of degree one h jq = A δ (jk ) ρ + (1 δ) (jl) ρi 1/ρ. (123) Second, CD function is a special case of the CES function. When ρ! 0, the CES function approaches the CD function. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

75 Example (CES Production Function) (conti.) Proof. Taking log on both side of the CES production function and then taking the limitation gives ln Q A = lim ρ!0 ln [δk ρ + (1 δ) L ρ ] ρ = lim ρ!0 δk ρ ln K (1 δ) L ρ ln L δk ρ + (1 δ) L ρ = ln Q = AK δ L 1 δ. in which we use the L Hopital s rule. K δ L 1 δ. =) Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

76 Least-Cost Combination of Inputs (Application of the Homogenous PF) Minimizing cost problem: subject to the output constraint min C = ap a + bp b (124) fa,bg Q (a, b) = Q 0 (125) where Q 0, P a, and P b are given exogenously. The marginal products are positive: Q a > 0, Q b > 0. The Lagrangian can be written as Z = ap a + bp b + µ [Q 0 Q (a, b)] (126) Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

77 (Conti.) The FOCs are The last two equation imply that Z µ = Q 0 Q (a, b) = 0 (127) Z a = P a µq a = 0 (128) Z b = P b µq b = 0 (129) P a Q a = P b Q b = µ, (130) which means that at the optimum, the input price marginal product ratio must be the same for each input. This equality can be rewritten as P a = Q a, MRT ab, (131) P b Q b where MRT ab is the marginal rate of technical substitution of a for b. See Figure 12.8 in CW. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

78 (Conti.) Su cient SOC can be used to ensure a minimum cost after the FOCs are met. That is, the problem needs a negative bordered Hessian: H = 0 Q a Q b Q a µq aa µq ab Q b µq ba µq bb = µ Q aaqb 2 2Q ab Q a Q b + Q bb Qa 2 < (132) Note that the curvature of an isoquant is represented by the second derivative: d 2 b da 2 = d db = d da da da h Q aa + Q ab = = 1 Q 3 b Q aa Q 2 b Qa Q b = Qaa + Q ab db da Qb Qba + Q Q 2 b i i Qa Q b Q b hq ba + Q Qa bb Q b Q a Q 2 b 2Q ab Q a Q b + Q bb Qa 2 Hence, the satisfaction of the su cient SOC implies that d 2 b da 2 > 0 because µ > 0 and Q b > 0. That is, the isoquant is strictly convex. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

79 Now assume that Q = Aa α b β. The optimum implies that P a P b = Q a Q b = αb βa b =) a = β P a = a constant α P b See Figure The expansion path serves to describe the least-cost combinations required to produce varying levels of Q 0 and is the locus of the points of tangency. In the above case, the EP is a straight line. Note that any homogenous production can give rise to a linear EP. A more general class of functions, known as homothetic functions, can produce linear EPs too. De nition Homotheticity can arise from a composite function in the form where Q (a, b) is homogenous of degree r. H = h (Q (a, b)) h 0 (Q) 6= 0 (133) Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

80 (Conti.) Note that H (a, b) is in general not homogenous in a and b. Nonetheless, the EPs of it are linear: Slope of H isoquant = = h0 (Q) Q a H b h 0 = (Q) Q b = Slope of Q isoquant H a Q a Q b = constant for any given b a given the linearity of the EPs of Q. Check two examples: H = Q 2 (H is also a homogenous function) and H = exp (Q) (H is not a homogenous function). Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

81 What is the e ect of the change in the exogenous input price ratio P a P b on the optimal ratio b a? We introduce a concept the elasticity of substitution: relative change in σ = relative change in b a Pa P b = d b a / d Pa P b / b a Pa P b = d b a /d Pa P b, b a / Pa P b (134) the larger the σ, the greater the substitution between the two inputs. If b a is considered as a function of P a P b, then σ will be the ratio of a marginal function to an average function. For the CD function, b a = β α P a P b, which means that σ = 1. (135) For the CES function introduced above, Q L = P L =) K δ 1/(1+ρ) 1/(1+ρ) Q K P K L = PL =) σ = 1 1 δ P K 1 + ρ. Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) ME September 9, / 81

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics ECON2285: Mathematical Economics Yulei Luo Economics, HKU September 17, 2018 Luo, Y. (Economics, HKU) ME September 17, 2018 1 / 46 Static Optimization and Extreme Values In this topic, we will study goal

More information

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics Yulei Luo SEF of HKU January 14, 2009 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) MME January 14, 2009 1 / 44 Comparative Statics and The Concept of Derivative Comparative Statics

More information

Tutorial 3: Optimisation

Tutorial 3: Optimisation Tutorial : Optimisation ECO411F 011 1. Find and classify the extrema of the cubic cost function C = C (Q) = Q 5Q +.. Find and classify the extreme values of the following functions (a) y = x 1 + x x 1x

More information

Lecture Notes for Chapter 12

Lecture Notes for Chapter 12 Lecture Notes for Chapter 12 Kevin Wainwright April 26, 2014 1 Constrained Optimization Consider the following Utility Max problem: Max x 1, x 2 U = U(x 1, x 2 ) (1) Subject to: Re-write Eq. 2 B = P 1

More information

The Kuhn-Tucker Problem

The Kuhn-Tucker Problem Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 8: Nonlinear Programming - The Kuhn-Tucker Problem Note 8 is based on de la Fuente (2000, Ch. 7) and Simon and Blume (1994, Ch. 18 and 19). The Kuhn-Tucker

More information

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

September Math Course: First Order Derivative September Math Course: First Order Derivative Arina Nikandrova Functions Function y = f (x), where x is either be a scalar or a vector of several variables (x,..., x n ), can be thought of as a rule which

More information

z = f (x; y) f (x ; y ) f (x; y) f (x; y )

z = f (x; y) f (x ; y ) f (x; y) f (x; y ) BEEM0 Optimization Techiniques for Economists Lecture Week 4 Dieter Balkenborg Departments of Economics University of Exeter Since the fabric of the universe is most perfect, and is the work of a most

More information

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics Yulei Luo SEF of HKU January 12, 2009 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) MME January 12, 2009 1 / 35 Course Outline Economics: The study of the choices people (consumers,

More information

Constrained optimization.

Constrained optimization. ams/econ 11b supplementary notes ucsc Constrained optimization. c 2016, Yonatan Katznelson 1. Constraints In many of the optimization problems that arise in economics, there are restrictions on the values

More information

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution)

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution) Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution) 1. Checking properties of the Cobb-Douglas utility function. Consider the utility function u(x) Y n i1 x i i ; where x denotes a vector of n di erent goods x 2 R n +,

More information

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Lecture Notes. Course Outline

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Lecture Notes. Course Outline LONDON SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS Professor Leonardo Felli Department of Economics S.478; x7525 EC400 20010/11 Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Lecture Notes Course Outline Lecture 1: Tools for

More information

Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 5: Optimization Kuhn-Tucker conditions for problems with inequality constraints 1

Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 5: Optimization Kuhn-Tucker conditions for problems with inequality constraints 1 Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 5: Optimization Kuhn-Tucker conditions for problems with inequality constraints 1 Session: 15 Aug 2015 (Mon), 10:00am 1:00pm I. Optimization with

More information

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1 Microeconomics, Block I Part 1 Piero Gottardi EUI Sept. 26, 2016 Piero Gottardi (EUI) Microeconomics, Block I Part 1 Sept. 26, 2016 1 / 53 Choice Theory Set of alternatives: X, with generic elements x,

More information

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions. a11 a 12. x 2

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions. a11 a 12. x 2 LONDON SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS Professor Leonardo Felli Department of Economics S.478; x7525 EC400 2010/11 Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions 1. Show that the general

More information

1 Objective. 2 Constrained optimization. 2.1 Utility maximization. Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics

1 Objective. 2 Constrained optimization. 2.1 Utility maximization. Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics BEE020 { Basic Mathematical Economics Week 2, Lecture Thursday 2.0.0 Constrained optimization Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics University of Exeter Objective We give the \ rst order conditions"

More information

Econ Slides from Lecture 14

Econ Slides from Lecture 14 Econ 205 Sobel Econ 205 - Slides from Lecture 14 Joel Sobel September 10, 2010 Theorem ( Lagrange Multipliers ) Theorem If x solves max f (x) subject to G(x) = 0 then there exists λ such that Df (x ) =

More information

BEEM103 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER. BUSINESS School. January 2009 Mock Exam, Part A. OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions

BEEM103 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER. BUSINESS School. January 2009 Mock Exam, Part A. OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions BEEM03 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER BUSINESS School January 009 Mock Exam, Part A OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions Duration : TWO HOURS The paper has 3 parts. Your marks on the rst part will be

More information

ECON 186 Class Notes: Optimization Part 2

ECON 186 Class Notes: Optimization Part 2 ECON 186 Class Notes: Optimization Part 2 Jijian Fan Jijian Fan ECON 186 1 / 26 Hessians The Hessian matrix is a matrix of all partial derivatives of a function. Given the function f (x 1,x 2,...,x n ),

More information

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7 Mathematical Foundations -- Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization An intuitive approach First Order Conditions (FOC) 7 Constraint qualifications 9 Formal statement of the FOC for a maximum

More information

Microeconomic Theory-I Washington State University Midterm Exam #1 - Answer key. Fall 2016

Microeconomic Theory-I Washington State University Midterm Exam #1 - Answer key. Fall 2016 Microeconomic Theory-I Washington State University Midterm Exam # - Answer key Fall 06. [Checking properties of preference relations]. Consider the following preference relation de ned in the positive

More information

Microeconomic Theory: Lecture 2 Choice Theory and Consumer Demand

Microeconomic Theory: Lecture 2 Choice Theory and Consumer Demand Microeconomic Theory: Lecture 2 Choice Theory and Consumer Demand Summer Semester, 2014 De nitions and Axioms Binary Relations I Examples: taller than, friend of, loves, hates, etc. I Abstract formulation:

More information

a = (a 1; :::a i )

a = (a 1; :::a  i ) 1 Pro t maximization Behavioral assumption: an optimal set of actions is characterized by the conditions: max R(a 1 ; a ; :::a n ) C(a 1 ; a ; :::a n ) a = (a 1; :::a n) @R(a ) @a i = @C(a ) @a i The rm

More information

Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization

Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization Yulei Luo Economics, HKU November 13, 2017 Luo, Y. (Economics, HKU) ECON0703: ME November 13, 2017 1 / 43 The Nature of Optimal Control In static optimization,

More information

Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis

Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis 1 Convex sets Both convex sets and functions have general importance in economic theory, not only in optimization. Given two points x; y 2 R n and 2 [0; 1]; the weighted

More information

Nonlinear Programming (NLP)

Nonlinear Programming (NLP) Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 6: Nonlinear Programming - Unconstrained Optimization Note 6 is based on de la Fuente (2000, Ch. 7), Madden (1986, Ch. 3 and 5) and Simon and Blume

More information

Final Exam - Math Camp August 27, 2014

Final Exam - Math Camp August 27, 2014 Final Exam - Math Camp August 27, 2014 You will have three hours to complete this exam. Please write your solution to question one in blue book 1 and your solutions to the subsequent questions in blue

More information

Mathematical Economics: Lecture 16

Mathematical Economics: Lecture 16 Mathematical Economics: Lecture 16 Yu Ren WISE, Xiamen University November 26, 2012 Outline 1 Chapter 21: Concave and Quasiconcave Functions New Section Chapter 21: Concave and Quasiconcave Functions Concave

More information

Constrained Optimization

Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization Joshua Wilde, revised by Isabel Tecu, Takeshi Suzuki and María José Boccardi August 13, 2013 1 General Problem Consider the following general constrained optimization problem:

More information

EconS Microeconomic Theory I Recitation #5 - Production Theory-I 1

EconS Microeconomic Theory I Recitation #5 - Production Theory-I 1 EconS 50 - Microeconomic Theory I Recitation #5 - Production Theory-I Exercise. Exercise 5.B.2 (MWG): Suppose that f () is the production function associated with a single-output technology, and let Y

More information

The general programming problem is the nonlinear programming problem where a given function is maximized subject to a set of inequality constraints.

The general programming problem is the nonlinear programming problem where a given function is maximized subject to a set of inequality constraints. 1 Optimization Mathematical programming refers to the basic mathematical problem of finding a maximum to a function, f, subject to some constraints. 1 In other words, the objective is to find a point,

More information

Maximum Value Functions and the Envelope Theorem

Maximum Value Functions and the Envelope Theorem Lecture Notes for ECON 40 Kevin Wainwright Maximum Value Functions and the Envelope Theorem A maximum (or minimum) value function is an objective function where the choice variables have been assigned

More information

Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer November Theory 1, 2015 (Jehle and 1 / Reny, 32

Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer November Theory 1, 2015 (Jehle and 1 / Reny, 32 Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer Theory (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 1) Tsun-Feng Chiang* *School of Economics, Henan University, Kaifeng, China November 1, 2015 Week 7: The Consumer

More information

Mathematical Economics. Lecture Notes (in extracts)

Mathematical Economics. Lecture Notes (in extracts) Prof. Dr. Frank Werner Faculty of Mathematics Institute of Mathematical Optimization (IMO) http://math.uni-magdeburg.de/ werner/math-ec-new.html Mathematical Economics Lecture Notes (in extracts) Winter

More information

Calculus and optimization

Calculus and optimization Calculus an optimization These notes essentially correspon to mathematical appenix 2 in the text. 1 Functions of a single variable Now that we have e ne functions we turn our attention to calculus. A function

More information

OPTIMIZATION THEORY IN A NUTSHELL Daniel McFadden, 1990, 2003

OPTIMIZATION THEORY IN A NUTSHELL Daniel McFadden, 1990, 2003 OPTIMIZATION THEORY IN A NUTSHELL Daniel McFadden, 1990, 2003 UNCONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION 1. Consider the problem of maximizing a function f:ú n 6 ú within a set A f ú n. Typically, A might be all of ú

More information

Review of Optimization Methods

Review of Optimization Methods Review of Optimization Methods Prof. Manuela Pedio 20550 Quantitative Methods for Finance August 2018 Outline of the Course Lectures 1 and 2 (3 hours, in class): Linear and non-linear functions on Limits,

More information

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics ECON2285: Mathematical Economics Yulei Luo FBE, HKU September 2, 2018 Luo, Y. (FBE, HKU) ME September 2, 2018 1 / 35 Course Outline Economics: The study of the choices people (consumers, firm managers,

More information

ECON 582: Dynamic Programming (Chapter 6, Acemoglu) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

ECON 582: Dynamic Programming (Chapter 6, Acemoglu) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko ECON 582: Dynamic Programming (Chapter 6, Acemoglu) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko Indirect Utility Recall: static consumer theory; J goods, p j is the price of good j (j = 1; : : : ; J), c j is consumption

More information

How to Characterize Solutions to Constrained Optimization Problems

How to Characterize Solutions to Constrained Optimization Problems How to Characterize Solutions to Constrained Optimization Problems Michael Peters September 25, 2005 1 Introduction A common technique for characterizing maximum and minimum points in math is to use first

More information

DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION

DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION UNIVERSITY OF MARYLAND: ECON 600. Alternative Methods of Discrete Time Intertemporal Optimization We will start by solving a discrete time intertemporal

More information

Tutorial 2: Comparative Statics

Tutorial 2: Comparative Statics Tutorial 2: Comparative Statics ECO42F 20 Derivatives and Rules of Differentiation For each of the functions below: (a) Find the difference quotient. (b) Find the derivative dx. (c) Find f (4) and f (3)..

More information

CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES. Likewise, we may define the higher order derivatives. f(x, y, z) = xy 2 + e zx. y = 2xy.

CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES. Likewise, we may define the higher order derivatives. f(x, y, z) = xy 2 + e zx. y = 2xy. April 15, 2009 CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES In this chapter D denotes an open subset of R n. 1. Introduction Definition 1.1. Given a function f : D R we define the second partial derivatives as

More information

Nonlinear Programming and the Kuhn-Tucker Conditions

Nonlinear Programming and the Kuhn-Tucker Conditions Nonlinear Programming and the Kuhn-Tucker Conditions The Kuhn-Tucker (KT) conditions are first-order conditions for constrained optimization problems, a generalization of the first-order conditions we

More information

Optimization. A first course on mathematics for economists

Optimization. A first course on mathematics for economists Optimization. A first course on mathematics for economists Xavier Martinez-Giralt Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona xavier.martinez.giralt@uab.eu II.3 Static optimization - Non-Linear programming OPT p.1/45

More information

Implicit Function Theorem: One Equation

Implicit Function Theorem: One Equation Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 3: The Implicit Function Theorem Note 3 is based on postol (975, h 3), de la Fuente (2, h5) and Simon and Blume (994, h 5) This note discusses the

More information

II. An Application of Derivatives: Optimization

II. An Application of Derivatives: Optimization Anne Sibert Autumn 2013 II. An Application of Derivatives: Optimization In this section we consider an important application of derivatives: finding the minimum and maximum points. This has important applications

More information

Chapter 4. Maximum Theorem, Implicit Function Theorem and Envelope Theorem

Chapter 4. Maximum Theorem, Implicit Function Theorem and Envelope Theorem Chapter 4. Maximum Theorem, Implicit Function Theorem and Envelope Theorem This chapter will cover three key theorems: the maximum theorem (or the theorem of maximum), the implicit function theorem, and

More information

Chapter 4 Differentiation

Chapter 4 Differentiation Chapter 4 Differentiation 08 Section 4. The derivative of a function Practice Problems (a) (b) (c) 3 8 3 ( ) 4 3 5 4 ( ) 5 3 3 0 0 49 ( ) 50 Using a calculator, the values of the cube function, correct

More information

Properties of Walrasian Demand

Properties of Walrasian Demand Properties of Walrasian Demand Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 5, September 12 Problem Set 2 is due in Kelly s mailbox by 5pm today Outline 1 Properties of Walrasian Demand 2 Indirect Utility Function 3 Envelope

More information

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 6 October, 2017 Properties of the Profit Function Recall the following property of the profit function π(p, w) = max x p f (x)

More information

Recitation #2 (August 31st, 2018)

Recitation #2 (August 31st, 2018) Recitation #2 (August 1st, 2018) 1. [Checking properties of the Cobb-Douglas utility function.] Consider the utility function u(x) = n i=1 xα i i, where x denotes a vector of n different goods x R n +,

More information

MATH529 Fundamentals of Optimization Constrained Optimization I

MATH529 Fundamentals of Optimization Constrained Optimization I MATH529 Fundamentals of Optimization Constrained Optimization I Marco A. Montes de Oca Mathematical Sciences, University of Delaware, USA 1 / 26 Motivating Example 2 / 26 Motivating Example min cost(b)

More information

ARE211, Fall 2005 CONTENTS. 5. Characteristics of Functions Surjective, Injective and Bijective functions. 5.2.

ARE211, Fall 2005 CONTENTS. 5. Characteristics of Functions Surjective, Injective and Bijective functions. 5.2. ARE211, Fall 2005 LECTURE #18: THU, NOV 3, 2005 PRINT DATE: NOVEMBER 22, 2005 (COMPSTAT2) CONTENTS 5. Characteristics of Functions. 1 5.1. Surjective, Injective and Bijective functions 1 5.2. Homotheticity

More information

The Kuhn-Tucker and Envelope Theorems

The Kuhn-Tucker and Envelope Theorems The Kuhn-Tucker and Envelope Theorems Peter Ireland EC720.01 - Math for Economists Boston College, Department of Economics Fall 2010 The Kuhn-Tucker and envelope theorems can be used to characterize the

More information

ECON501 - Vector Di erentiation Simon Grant

ECON501 - Vector Di erentiation Simon Grant ECON01 - Vector Di erentiation Simon Grant October 00 Abstract Notes on vector di erentiation and some simple economic applications and examples 1 Functions of One Variable g : R! R derivative (slope)

More information

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice Economics 101 Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice 1 Uncle Léon The canonical model of exchange in economics is sometimes referred to as the Walrasian Model, after the early economist Léon

More information

Econ 101A Problem Set 1 Solution

Econ 101A Problem Set 1 Solution Econ 101A Problem Set 1 Solution Problem 1. Univariate unconstrained maximization. (10 points) Consider the following maximization problem: max x f(x; x 0)=exp( (x x 0 ) 2 ) 1. Write down the first order

More information

Chiang/Wainwright: Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics

Chiang/Wainwright: Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics CHAPTER 12 Eercise 12.2 1. (a) Z = y + (2 2y). The necessary condition is: Z =2 2y =0 Z = y =0 Z y = 2 =0 Thus 2, =1, y 2 yielding z 2. (b) Z = y +4 + (8 y). The necessary condition is: Z =8 y =0 Z = y

More information

Partial Differentiation

Partial Differentiation CHAPTER 7 Partial Differentiation From the previous two chapters we know how to differentiate functions of one variable But many functions in economics depend on several variables: output depends on both

More information

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP Prof. Olivier Bochet Room A.34 Phone 3 63 476 E-mail olivier.bochet@vwi.unibe.ch Webpage http//sta.vwi.unibe.ch/bochet Advanced Microeconomics Fall 2 Lecture Note Choice-Based Approach Price e ects, Wealth

More information

E 600 Chapter 4: Optimization

E 600 Chapter 4: Optimization E 600 Chapter 4: Optimization Simona Helmsmueller August 8, 2018 Goals of this lecture: Every theorem in these slides is important! You should understand, remember and be able to apply each and every one

More information

STATIC LECTURE 4: CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION II - KUHN TUCKER THEORY

STATIC LECTURE 4: CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION II - KUHN TUCKER THEORY STATIC LECTURE 4: CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION II - KUHN TUCKER THEORY UNIVERSITY OF MARYLAND: ECON 600 1. Some Eamples 1 A general problem that arises countless times in economics takes the form: (Verbally):

More information

UNDERGROUND LECTURE NOTES 1: Optimality Conditions for Constrained Optimization Problems

UNDERGROUND LECTURE NOTES 1: Optimality Conditions for Constrained Optimization Problems UNDERGROUND LECTURE NOTES 1: Optimality Conditions for Constrained Optimization Problems Robert M. Freund February 2016 c 2016 Massachusetts Institute of Technology. All rights reserved. 1 1 Introduction

More information

It is convenient to introduce some notation for this type of problems. I will write this as. max u (x 1 ; x 2 ) subj. to. p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 m ;

It is convenient to introduce some notation for this type of problems. I will write this as. max u (x 1 ; x 2 ) subj. to. p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 m ; 4 Calculus Review 4.1 The Utility Maimization Problem As a motivating eample, consider the problem facing a consumer that needs to allocate a given budget over two commodities sold at (linear) prices p

More information

Microeconomics CHAPTER 2. THE FIRM

Microeconomics CHAPTER 2. THE FIRM Chapter The Firm Exercise. Suppose that a unit of output can be produced by any of the following combinations of inputs z = 0: 0:5 ; z 0:3 = 0:. Construct the isouant for =. ; z 3 0:5 = 0:. Assuming constant

More information

Paul Schrimpf. October 17, UBC Economics 526. Constrained optimization. Paul Schrimpf. First order conditions. Second order conditions

Paul Schrimpf. October 17, UBC Economics 526. Constrained optimization. Paul Schrimpf. First order conditions. Second order conditions UBC Economics 526 October 17, 2012 .1.2.3.4 Section 1 . max f (x) s.t. h(x) = c f : R n R, h : R n R m Draw picture of n = 2 and m = 1 At optimum, constraint tangent to level curve of function Rewrite

More information

Lecture 3 - Axioms of Consumer Preference and the Theory of Choice

Lecture 3 - Axioms of Consumer Preference and the Theory of Choice Lecture 3 - Axioms of Consumer Preference and the Theory of Choice David Autor 14.03 Fall 2004 Agenda: 1. Consumer preference theory (a) Notion of utility function (b) Axioms of consumer preference (c)

More information

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 4, September 7 Outline 1 Structural Properties of Utility Functions 1 Local Non Satiation 2 Convexity 3 Quasi-linearity

More information

The Envelope Theorem

The Envelope Theorem The Envelope Theorem In an optimization problem we often want to know how the value of the objective function will change if one or more of the parameter values changes. Let s consider a simple example:

More information

Microeconomic Theory. Microeconomic Theory. Everyday Economics. The Course:

Microeconomic Theory. Microeconomic Theory. Everyday Economics. The Course: The Course: Microeconomic Theory This is the first rigorous course in microeconomic theory This is a course on economic methodology. The main goal is to teach analytical tools that will be useful in other

More information

Week 10: Theory of the Firm (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 3)

Week 10: Theory of the Firm (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 3) Week 10: Theory of the Firm (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 3) Tsun-Feng Chiang* *School of Economics, Henan University, Kaifeng, China November 22, 2015 First Last (shortinst) Short title November 22, 2015 1

More information

Week 4: Calculus and Optimization (Jehle and Reny, Chapter A2)

Week 4: Calculus and Optimization (Jehle and Reny, Chapter A2) Week 4: Calculus and Optimization (Jehle and Reny, Chapter A2) Tsun-Feng Chiang *School of Economics, Henan University, Kaifeng, China September 27, 2015 Microeconomic Theory Week 4: Calculus and Optimization

More information

Notes on Consumer Theory

Notes on Consumer Theory Notes on Consumer Theory Alejandro Saporiti Alejandro Saporiti (Copyright) Consumer Theory 1 / 65 Consumer theory Reference: Jehle and Reny, Advanced Microeconomic Theory, 3rd ed., Pearson 2011: Ch. 1.

More information

i) This is simply an application of Berge s Maximum Theorem, but it is actually not too difficult to prove the result directly.

i) This is simply an application of Berge s Maximum Theorem, but it is actually not too difficult to prove the result directly. Bocconi University PhD in Economics - Microeconomics I Prof. M. Messner Problem Set 3 - Solution Problem 1: i) This is simply an application of Berge s Maximum Theorem, but it is actually not too difficult

More information

Bi-Variate Functions - ACTIVITES

Bi-Variate Functions - ACTIVITES Bi-Variate Functions - ACTIVITES LO1. Students to consolidate basic meaning of bi-variate functions LO2. Students to learn how to confidently use bi-variate functions in economics Students are given the

More information

Advanced Microeconomics I: Consumers, Firms and Markets Chapters 1+2

Advanced Microeconomics I: Consumers, Firms and Markets Chapters 1+2 Advanced Microeconomics I: Consumers, Firms and Markets Chapters 1+2 Prof. Dr. Oliver Gürtler Winter Term 2012/2013 1 Advanced Microeconomics I: Consumers, Firms and Markets Chapters 1+2 JJ N J 1. Introduction

More information

STUDY MATERIALS. (The content of the study material is the same as that of Chapter I of Mathematics for Economic Analysis II of 2011 Admn.

STUDY MATERIALS. (The content of the study material is the same as that of Chapter I of Mathematics for Economic Analysis II of 2011 Admn. STUDY MATERIALS MATHEMATICAL TOOLS FOR ECONOMICS III (The content of the study material is the same as that of Chapter I of Mathematics for Economic Analysis II of 2011 Admn.) & MATHEMATICAL TOOLS FOR

More information

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers The Ohio State University Department of Economics Econ. 805 Winter 00 Prof. James Peck Homework Set Questions and Answers. Consider the following pure exchange economy with two consumers and two goods.

More information

MATHEMATICAL ECONOMICS: OPTIMIZATION. Contents

MATHEMATICAL ECONOMICS: OPTIMIZATION. Contents MATHEMATICAL ECONOMICS: OPTIMIZATION JOÃO LOPES DIAS Contents 1. Introduction 2 1.1. Preliminaries 2 1.2. Optimal points and values 2 1.3. The optimization problems 3 1.4. Existence of optimal points 4

More information

ECON 5111 Mathematical Economics

ECON 5111 Mathematical Economics Test 1 October 1, 2010 1. Construct a truth table for the following statement: [p (p q)] q. 2. A prime number is a natural number that is divisible by 1 and itself only. Let P be the set of all prime numbers

More information

5 Handling Constraints

5 Handling Constraints 5 Handling Constraints Engineering design optimization problems are very rarely unconstrained. Moreover, the constraints that appear in these problems are typically nonlinear. This motivates our interest

More information

g(x,y) = c. For instance (see Figure 1 on the right), consider the optimization problem maximize subject to

g(x,y) = c. For instance (see Figure 1 on the right), consider the optimization problem maximize subject to 1 of 11 11/29/2010 10:39 AM From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia In mathematical optimization, the method of Lagrange multipliers (named after Joseph Louis Lagrange) provides a strategy for finding the

More information

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018 EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 018 Show all your work clearly and make sure you justify all your answers. NAME 1. Consider the market for smart pencil in which only one firm (Superapiz) enjoys a

More information

Optimization Theory. Lectures 4-6

Optimization Theory. Lectures 4-6 Optimization Theory Lectures 4-6 Unconstrained Maximization Problem: Maximize a function f:ú n 6 ú within a set A f ú n. Typically, A is ú n, or the non-negative orthant {x0ú n x$0} Existence of a maximum:

More information

Final Exam Advanced Mathematics for Economics and Finance

Final Exam Advanced Mathematics for Economics and Finance Final Exam Advanced Mathematics for Economics and Finance Dr. Stefanie Flotho Winter Term /5 March 5 General Remarks: ˆ There are four questions in total. ˆ All problems are equally weighed. ˆ This is

More information

Econ Review Set 2 - Answers

Econ Review Set 2 - Answers Econ 4808 Review Set 2 - Answers EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS 1. De ne the concept of equilibrium within the con nes of an economic model. Provide an example of an economic equilibrium. Economic models contain

More information

CHAPTER 1-2: SHADOW PRICES

CHAPTER 1-2: SHADOW PRICES Essential Microeconomics -- CHAPTER -: SHADOW PRICES An intuitive approach: profit maimizing firm with a fied supply of an input Shadow prices 5 Concave maimization problem 7 Constraint qualifications

More information

EconS 301. Math Review. Math Concepts

EconS 301. Math Review. Math Concepts EconS 301 Math Review Math Concepts Functions: Functions describe the relationship between input variables and outputs y f x where x is some input and y is some output. Example: x could number of Bananas

More information

Lecture 4: Optimization. Maximizing a function of a single variable

Lecture 4: Optimization. Maximizing a function of a single variable Lecture 4: Optimization Maximizing or Minimizing a Function of a Single Variable Maximizing or Minimizing a Function of Many Variables Constrained Optimization Maximizing a function of a single variable

More information

Economics 101A (Lecture 3) Stefano DellaVigna

Economics 101A (Lecture 3) Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 3) Stefano DellaVigna January 24, 2017 Outline 1. Implicit Function Theorem 2. Envelope Theorem 3. Convexity and concavity 4. Constrained Maximization 1 Implicit function theorem

More information

In the Ramsey model we maximized the utility U = u[c(t)]e nt e t dt. Now

In the Ramsey model we maximized the utility U = u[c(t)]e nt e t dt. Now PERMANENT INCOME AND OPTIMAL CONSUMPTION On the previous notes we saw how permanent income hypothesis can solve the Consumption Puzzle. Now we use this hypothesis, together with assumption of rational

More information

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 2

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 2 Macroeconomic Theory, Fall 03 SEF, HKU Instructor: Dr. Yulei Luo October 03 Suggested Solutions to Problem Set. 0 points] Consider the following Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model with fiscal policy. First, we

More information

Topic 5: The Difference Equation

Topic 5: The Difference Equation Topic 5: The Difference Equation Yulei Luo Economics, HKU October 30, 2017 Luo, Y. (Economics, HKU) ME October 30, 2017 1 / 42 Discrete-time, Differences, and Difference Equations When time is taken to

More information

Structural and Multidisciplinary Optimization. P. Duysinx and P. Tossings

Structural and Multidisciplinary Optimization. P. Duysinx and P. Tossings Structural and Multidisciplinary Optimization P. Duysinx and P. Tossings 2018-2019 CONTACTS Pierre Duysinx Institut de Mécanique et du Génie Civil (B52/3) Phone number: 04/366.91.94 Email: P.Duysinx@uliege.be

More information

ARE202A, Fall Contents

ARE202A, Fall Contents ARE202A, Fall 2005 LECTURE #2: WED, NOV 6, 2005 PRINT DATE: NOVEMBER 2, 2005 (NPP2) Contents 5. Nonlinear Programming Problems and the Kuhn Tucker conditions (cont) 5.2. Necessary and sucient conditions

More information

The Ramsey Model. Alessandra Pelloni. October TEI Lecture. Alessandra Pelloni (TEI Lecture) Economic Growth October / 61

The Ramsey Model. Alessandra Pelloni. October TEI Lecture. Alessandra Pelloni (TEI Lecture) Economic Growth October / 61 The Ramsey Model Alessandra Pelloni TEI Lecture October 2015 Alessandra Pelloni (TEI Lecture) Economic Growth October 2015 1 / 61 Introduction Introduction Introduction Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model: di ers

More information

CONSTRAINED OPTIMALITY CRITERIA

CONSTRAINED OPTIMALITY CRITERIA 5 CONSTRAINED OPTIMALITY CRITERIA In Chapters 2 and 3, we discussed the necessary and sufficient optimality criteria for unconstrained optimization problems. But most engineering problems involve optimization

More information

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4 Solow Growth Model Michael Bar February 28, 208 Contents Introduction 2. Some facts about modern growth........................ 3.2 Questions..................................... 4 2 The Solow Model 5

More information

MATH2070 Optimisation

MATH2070 Optimisation MATH2070 Optimisation Nonlinear optimisation with constraints Semester 2, 2012 Lecturer: I.W. Guo Lecture slides courtesy of J.R. Wishart Review The full nonlinear optimisation problem with equality constraints

More information

z = f (x; y) = x 3 3x 2 y x 2 3

z = f (x; y) = x 3 3x 2 y x 2 3 BEE Mathematics for Economists Week, ecture Thursday..7 Functions in two variables Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics University of Exeter Objective This lecture has the purpose to make you familiar

More information