Risk Measures. A. Shapiro School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, Georgia , USA ICSP 2016

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Risk Measures. A. Shapiro School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, Georgia , USA ICSP 2016"

Transcription

1 Risk Measures A. Shapiro School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, Georgia , USA ICSP 2016

2 Min-max (distributionally robust) approach to stochastic programming Min x X { } f(x) := sup E µ [F (x, ω)], µ M where X R n, F : R n Ω R and M is a set of probability measures (distributions) on the sample space (Ω, F). Optimization of mean-risk models: Min ρ[f x(ω)], x X where ρ : Z R is a mean-risk function, Z is a (linear) space of allowable functions Z(ω) and F x ( ) = F (x, ) Z for all x X. 1

3 Axiomatic approach (coherent measures of risk), by Artzner, Delbaen, Eber, Heath (1999): (A1) Convexity: ρ(αz 1 + (1 α)z 2 ) αρ(z 1 ) + (1 α)ρ(z 2 ) for all Z 1, Z 2 Z and α [0, 1]. (A2) Monotonicity: If Z 1, Z 2 Z and Z 2 Z 1, then ρ(z 2 ) ρ(z 1 ). (A3) Translation Equivariance: If a R and Z Z, then ρ(z + a) = ρ(z) + a. (A4) Positive Homogeneity: ρ(αz) = αρ(z), Z Z, α > 0. If ρ satisfies (A1)-(A3), it is said that ρ is a convex risk measure. 2

4 Space Z := L p (Ω, F, P ), where P is a (reference) probability measure on (Ω, F) and p [1, ). That is, Z is the space of random variables Z(ω) having finite p-th order moment. Space Z is paired with its dual space Z = L q (Ω, F, P ), where 1/p+1/q = 1, and the scalar product (bilinear form) ζ, Z := ζ(ω)z(ω)dp (ω), ζ Ω Z, Z Z. We also consider space Z := L (Ω, F, P ), of essentially bounded (measurable) functions Z : Ω R, paired with space L 1 (Ω, F, P ). Theorem 1 (i) If ρ : Z R satisfies axioms (A1) (convexity) and (A2) (monotonicity), then ρ( ) is continuous in the norm topology of the space Z = L p (Ω, F, P ), p [1, ]. (ii) If ρ : Z R, p [1, ), is proper, satisfies axioms (A1) - (A3) and its domain {Z Z : ρ(z) < + } has nonempty interior, then ρ is finite valued and continuous on Z. 3

5 Dual representation of risk functions By Fenchel-Moreau theorem if ρ : Z R is convex (assumption (A1)) and lower semicontinuous, then where ρ(z) = sup ζ A { ζ, Z ρ (ζ)}, ρ (ζ) := sup Z Z { ζ, Z ρ(z)}, A := dom(ρ ) = {ζ Z : ρ (ζ) < + }. It is possible to show that condition (A2) (monotonicity) holds iff ζ 0 for every ζ A. Condition (A3) (translation equivariance) holds iff Ω ζdp = 1 for every ζ A. If ρ is positively homogeneous, then ρ (ζ) = 0 for every ζ A. 4

6 If conditions (A1) (A4) hold, then A is a set of density functions and ρ(z) = sup µ Q E µ [Z], where Q = {µ : dµ = ζdp, ζ A} is a set of absolutely continuous with respect to P probability measures. Consequently, problem Min x X ρ[f (x, ω)] can be represented as a min-max problem. 5

7 Average Value-at-Risk (also called Conditional Value-at-Risk) { AV@R α (Z) := inf t + α 1 } E[Z t] + t R Note that the minimum in the above is attained at t = HZ 1 (1 α), where H Z(t) := Pr(Z t) is the cdf of Z and Indeed HZ 1 (1 α) = V@R α(z) = inf{t : H Z (t) 1 α}. (t+α 1 E[Z t] + ) t = 1 + α 1 E { } [Z t]+ t 1 + α 1 Pr(Z t) = 1 + α 1 (1 H Z (t)). = 6

8 Also α (Z) = 1 α 1 1 α H 1 Z (t)dt. If H Z (z) is continuous at z = H 1 (1 α), then Z AV@R α (Z) = E [ Z Z H 1 Z (1 α)]. Note that AV@R α (Z) HZ 1 (1 α), and the following inequalities are equivalent V@R α (Z γ) 0, V@R α (Z) γ 0, HZ 1 1 α H Z(γ), Pr(Z γ) 1 α, Pr(Z > γ) α. 7

9 The risk measure ρ(z) = AV@R α (Z) is coherent. It is natural to take here Z = L 1 (Ω, F, P ) and Z = L (Ω, F, P ). The dual representation holds with A = { ζ Z : 0 ζ(ω) α 1 a.e. ω Ω, Ω ζ(ω)dp (ω) = 1}. Note that as α 0, AV@R α (Z) converges to ess sup Z(ω) := inf { sup ω Ω Z (ω) : Z (ω) = Z(ω) a.e. ω Ω }. So AV@R 0 ( ) should be defined on the space Z = L (Ω, F, P ). 8

10 Example Mean-variance risk function (c > 0): ρ(z) := E[Z] + c Var[Z], Z Z := L 2 (Ω, F, P ). Dual representation: ρ(z) = sup ζ Z, E[ζ]=1 { ζ, Z (4c) 1 Var[ζ] }. Satisfies (A1) and (A3), does not satisfy (A2) and (A4). Example Mean-upper-semideviation risk function of order p [1, + ), Z Z := L p (Ω, F, P ), c 0 and ρ(z) := E[Z] + c ( E { [Z E[Z]] p +}) 1/p. Here ρ satisfies (A1),(A3),(A4), and also (A2) (monotonicity) if c 1. The max-representation ρ(z) = sup ζ A Ω Z(ω)ζ(ω)dP (ω) holds with A = {ζ : ζ = 1 + h Ω hdp, h q c, h 0}. 9

11 It is said that a risk measure ρ : X R is law invariant, with respect to the reference distribution P, if for any distributionally equivalent Z, Z Z (i.e., Pr(Z t) = Pr(Z t) for all t R), it follows that ρ(z) = ρ(z ). That is, law invariant risk measure ρ(z) is a function of the cdf H Z of random variable Z. It is said that a probability space (Ω, F, P ) is standard if Ω = [0, 1] equipped with its Borel sigma algebra F and uniform probability measure P. Standard probability space is atomless. Two random variables Z and Z defined on the standard probability space are distributionally equivalent iff there exists a measure preserving transformation T : Ω Ω such that Z (ω) = Z(T (ω)). In particular Z(ω) is distributionally equivalent to HZ 1 (ω) = inf{t : H Z (t) ω}. (A measurable T : Ω Ω is measure preserving if it is one-to-one, onto and P (T (A)) = P (A) for any A F.) 10

12 We say that σ : [0, 1) R + is a spectral function if σ( ) is right side continuous, monotonically nondecreasing and such that 1 0 σ(t)dt = 1. Note that any spectral function is a probability density function. Let (Ω, F, P ) be the standard probability space, Z = L p (Ω, F, P ) and ρ : Z R be a law invariant coherent risk measure. It has the dual representation ρ(z) = sup ζ A 1 0 ζ(t)z(t)dt, Z Z. Note that ρ is law invariant iff the set A invariant with respect to measure-preserving transformations. Since Z D HZ 1, by law invariance of ρ we have ρ(z) = ρ(hz 1 ). 11

13 We say that a set Υ Z of spectral functions is a generating set of ρ if If Υ = {σ} is a singleton, 1 ρ(z) = sup σ Υ 0 σ(t)h 1 Z (t)dt, Z Z. 1 ρ(z) = 0 σ(t)h 1 Z (t)dt, Z Z. is said to be a spectral risk measure. It is said that ζ A is an exposed point of A if there exists Z Z such that Ω ζzdp attains its maximum over ζ A at the unique point ζ. In a sense minimal generating set is given by the intersection of the set of exposed points of A with the set of spectral functions. 12

14 Note that 1 α (Z) = 1 1 α 1 α H 1 Z (t)dt. is spectral risk measure with spectral function σ = 1 1 α 1 [α,1]. A convex combination ρ(z) := λ 1 AV@R 1 α1 (Z) λ m AV@R 1 αm (Z), of Average Value-at Risk measures is also spectral risk measure with spectral function σ = m i=1 λ i (1 α i ) 1 1 [αi,1]. 13

15 For a probability measure (distribution) µ on the interval [0, 1) consider spectral function t σ(t) := (1 0 α) 1 dµ(α), t [0, 1). This equation defines a mapping σ = Tµ from the set of probability measures on [0, 1) to the set of spectral functions. The mapping T is one-to-one and onto and its inverse is (T 1 σ)(α) = (1 α)σ(α) + For σ = Tµ we have σ(t)h 1 (t)dt = (1 α) t 0 α H 1 (t)dtdµ(α) = α 0 σ(t)dt, α [0, 1). (1) 0 (1 α) 1 H 1 (t)dµ(α)dt = 1 0 AV@R 1 α(h)dµ(α). 14

16 This leads to the Kusuoka representation ρ(z) = sup µ M 1 0 AV@R 1 α(z)dµ(α), where M is a set of probability measures on [0,1) given by M = T 1 (Υ). For example, consider the absolute semideviation risk measure { [Z ] } ρ(z) := E[Z] + ce E[Z], c [0, 1]. Its (minimal) Kusuoka representation is ρ(z) = sup {(1 cα)av@r 1 (Z) + cαav@r α (Z)}. α (0,1) + 15

17 Statistical properties of risk measures Let ρ : Z R be a law invariant risk measure. Recall that we can consider it as a function ρ(h) of cdf H = H Z. Now let Z 1,..., Z N be an iid sample of the random variable Z. Then we can estimate ρ(h) by replacing H with the empirical cdf (empirical measure) Ĥ N = N 1 N j=1 δ(z j ). For example, for ρ = AV@R 1 α we have { ρ(ĥ N ) = inf t R = inf t R t α E Ĥ [Z t] N + t + 1 (1 α)n N j=1 } [Z j t] + An optimal solution of the above problem is t = Z (k), where Z (1)... Z (N) are the respective order statistics and k is the smallest integer αn. In particular if N < (1 α) 1, then k = N. In that case ρ(ĥ N ) = t = max 1 j N Z j.. 16

18 Law of Large Numbers for risk measures Theorem 2 Let ρ : Z R be a real valued law invariant convex risk measure and Ĥ N be the empirical cdf associated with an iid sample of Z Z. Then ρ(ĥ N ) converges to ρ(z) w.p.1 as N. What about rate of convergence? Consider θ := AV@R 1 α (Z) and its sample estimate ˆθ N based oh iid sample of size N. We have that ˆθ N θ w.p.1 as N. Central Limit Theorem: N 1/2(ˆθ N θ ) converges in distribution to normal N (0, σ 2 ), where σ 2 = (1 α) 2 Var ( [Z t ) ] + with t = HZ 1 (α), provided this quantile is unique. 17

19 Moreover E[ˆθ N ] < θ and E[ˆθ N ] θ α = 2Nh(t ) + o(n 1 ), where h(t ) = H Z (t )/ t is the corresponding density, provided it exists and h(t ) 0. Example. Consider the exponential distribution H(z) = 1 e z, z 0. Then H 1 (α) = log(1 α) 1 and θ = 1 + log(1 α) 1. For N < (1 α) 1, Pr ( ˆθ N θ ε ) = 1 [1 e 1 ε (1 α)] N. Suppose that N is equal to the integer part of (1 α) 1. Then lim inf α 1 Pr (ˆθ N θ + ε ) 1 e e 1 ε.

20 We also need a type of uniform LLN. Consider a random function F (x, ξ) depending on random vector ξ = ξ(ω), and a law invariant convex risk measure ρ : Z R. Suppose that: For every x R n the random variable F x (ξ) = F (x, ξ) belongs to the space Z. Consider the composite function φ(x) = ρ(f x ). Let ξ j, j = 1,..., N, be an iid sample of random vector ξ, and Ĥ xn be the empirical cdf associated with the sample F (x, ξ 1 ),..., F (x, ξ N ). Then ˆφ N (x) = ρ(ĥ xn ) is a sample estimate of φ(x). 19

21 The problem Min {φ(x) = ρ(f x)} x X Can be approximated by the problem Min x X ˆφ N (x). Theorem 3 Suppose that: (i) F x Z for all x R n, (ii) for a.e. ξ the function F (, ξ) is convex, (iii) ρ : Z R is law invariant and convex. Then the composite functions φ : R n R and ˆφ N : R n R are convex and ˆφ N ( ) converges to φ( ) w.p.1 uniformly on any compact set C R n. 20

22 Two-stage risk averse stochastic programs. First stage problem Min ρ(f x(ω)), x X where F x (ω) = F (x, ω) is given by the optimal value of the second stage problem: Min g(x, y, ω), y G(x,ω) where g : R n R m Ω R is a random lower semicontinuous function and G : R n Ω R m is a closed valued measurable multifunction. For example, g(x, y, ω) := c T x + q(ω) T y and G(x, ω) := { y R m : T (ω)x + W (ω)y b(ω) }. 21

23 Interchangeability principle for risk measures Let ρ : Z R be a convex risk measure and G y (ω) = G(y, ω) be such that inf y Y G y (ω) Z, Y R m. Then ρ ( inf G y(ω) y Y ) = inf y( ) Y ρ( G(y(ω), ω) ). By the interchangeability principle the two stage problem can be written in the following equivalent form Min x X, y( ) ρ[g(x, y(ω), ω)] subject to y(ω) G(x, ω) a.e. ω Ω. How this can be extended to a dynamic process (multistage programming)? 22

24 With every law invariant risk measure ρ(z) we can associate the respective conditional risk measure, denoted ρ(z Y ) or ρ Y (Z), conditional on random variable Y, by employing conditional distribution of Z given Y. Note that ρ(z Y ) is a function of Y and we can consider the composite risk measure ρ(ρ(z Y )). For example, for ρ(z) := E[Z] and ρ(z Y ) = E[Z Y ] we have E[E[Z Y ]] = E[Z]. If Z and Y are independent, then ρ Y (Z) = ρ(z). 23

25 Examples With the mean-upper-semideviation risk measure we can associate its conditional version ρ Y (Z) = E Y [Z] + c ( E Y { [Z E Y [Z]] p +}) 1/p. Conditional version of the Average Value-at-Risk: AV@R α Y (Z) = inf E { Y t + α 1 } [Z t] +. t R The minimum in the above is attained at t = { (1 α)-quantile of the conditional distribution of Z given Y }. Of course, t is a function of Y here. 24

26 Risk neutral multistage stochastic programming. Let ξ 1,..., ξ T be random data process, with ξ 1 being deterministic. Denote ξ [t] := (ξ 1,..., ξ t ). Nested formulation of multistage stochastic programming problem: [ Min F 1 (x 1 ) + E ξ1 inf F 2(x 2, ξ 2 ) +... x 1 X 1 [ x 2 X 2 (x 1,ξ 2 ) +E ξ[t inf F 2] T 1(x T 1, ξ T 1 ) x T 1 X T (x T 2,ξ T 1 ) +E ξ[t [ inf F 1] T (x T, ξ T )] ]]. x T X T (x T 1,ξ T ) Here F t : R n t R d t R are real valued functions and X t : R n t 1 R d t R n t, t = 2,..., T, are multifunctions. 25

27 For example F t (x t, ξ t ) := c T t x t, X t (x t 1, ξ t ) := {x t 1 : B t x t 1 + A t x t b t }, t = 2,..., T, X 1 := {x 1 : A 1 x 1 b 1 }, with ξ t = (c t, A t, B t, b t ), corresponds to linear multistage stochastic programming. Note that E[Z] = E ξ1 [E ξ[2] [ E ξ[t 1] [Z] ]]. 26

28 This decomposition property of the expectation operator and interchangeability of the expectation and minimization operators allows to write the nested formulation in the equivalent form ( ) ] Min E[ F 1 (x 1 ) + F 2 (x 2 (ξ [2] ), ξ 2 ) + + F T xt (ξ [T ] ), ξ T x 1,x 2 ( ),...,x T ( ) s.t. x 1 X 1, x t (ξ [t] ) X t (x t 1 (ξ [t 1] ), ξ t ), t = 2,..., T. The optimization is performed over (nonanticipative) policies x 1, x 2 (ξ [2] ),..., x T (ξ [T ] ) satisfying the feasibility constraints, and the feasibility constraints should be satisfied for almost every (a.e.) realization of the random data, i.e., they should hold with probability one (w.p.1). 27

29 Dynamic Programming Equations. For the last period T we have Q T (x T 1, ξ T ) := inf F T (x T, ξ T ), x T X T (x T 1,ξ T ) Q T (x T 1, ξ [T 1] ) := E ξ[t 1] [Q T (x T 1, ξ T )], and for t = T 1,..., 2, where Q t ( xt 1, ξ [t] ) = inf x t X t (x t 1,ξ t ) { Ft (x t, ξ t ) + Q t+1 ( xt, ξ [t] ) }, Q t+1 ( xt, ξ [t] ) := E ξ[t] { Qt+1 ( xt, ξ [t+1] )}. Finally, at the first stage we solve the problem Min x1 X 1 F 1 (x 1 ) + E[Q 2 (x 1, ξ 2 )]. 28

30 It is said that the data process is stagewise independent if random vector ξ t+1 is independent of ξ [t] = (ξ 1,..., ξ t ), t = 1,..., T 1. In case of stagewise independence, by induction in t = T,..., it is possible to show that cost-to-go functions Q t (x t 1 ) do not depend on the data process. The dynamic programming equations take the form where Q t ( xt 1, ξ t ) = { } inf Ft (x t, ξ t ) + Q t+1 (x t ), x t X t (x t 1,ξ t ) Q t+1 (x t ) = E { Q t+1 ( xt, ξ t+1 )}. 29

31 Risk averse multistage programming. Nested formulation of risk averse multistage programming problem: [ Min F 1 (x 1 ) + ρ ξ1 inf F 2(x 2, ξ 2 ) +... x 1 X 1 [ x 2 X 2 (x 1,ξ 2 ) +ρ ξ[t inf F 2] T 1(x T 1, ξ T 1 ) x T 1 X T (x T 2,ξ T 1 ) +ρ ξ[t [ inf F 1] T (x T, ξ T )] ]], x T X T (x T 1,ξ T ) where ρ ξ[t] ( ), t = 1,..., T 1, are conditional law invariant coherent (convex) risk measures. For example ρ ξ[t] ( ) := λe ξ[t] [ ] + (1 λ)av@r α ξ[t] [ ] is a convex combination of the conditional expectation and conditional Average Value-at-risk measure. 30

32 We can write the risk averse multistage programming problem as Min ρ [ ( ) ] F 1 (x 1 ) + F 2 (x 2 (ξ [2] ), ξ 2 ) + + F T xt (ξ [T ] ), ξ T x 1,x 2 ( ),...,x T ( ) where s.t. x 1 X 1, x t (ξ [t] ) X t (x t 1 (ξ [t 1] ), ξ t ), t = 2,..., T, ρ(z Z T ) = ρ ξ1 ( ρ ξ[2] ( ρ ξ[t 1] (Z Z T ) )) = Z 1 + ρ ξ1 ( Z 2 + ρ ξ[2] ( + ρ ξ[t 1] (Z T ) )) is the corresponding composite risk measure. The optimization is performed over (nonanticipative) policies x 1, x 2 (ξ [2] ),..., x T (ξ [T ] ) satisfying the feasibility constraints. 31

33 If ρ ξ[t] ( ) := E ξ[t] ( ) are conditional expectations, then ρ( ) = E( ). In that case this becomes the risk neutral stochastic programming. If ρ ξ[t] ( ) := ess sup( ) = AV@R 0 ξ[t] ( ), This case corresponds to multistage ro- then ρ( ) = AV@R 0 ( ). bust optimization. Let ρ be a law invariant coherent risk measure. It turns out that only ρ( ) := E( ) and ρ( ) := ess sup( ) risk measures have the decomposition property ρ(ρ Y (Z)) = ρ(z), Z Z. 32

34 Distributionally robust multistage stochastic programming. We can write the risk neutral multistage problem as Min E P [Z π ], (2) π Π where P is the probability distribution of random vector ξ [T ] = (ξ 1,..., ξ T ), Π is a set of policies satisfying the feasibility constraints x 1 X 1, x t (ξ [t] ) X t (x t 1 (ξ [t 1] ), ξ t ), t = 2,..., T 1, and Z π = Z π (ξ [T ] ) is defined as Z π := f 1 (x 1 ) + f 2 (x 2 (ξ [2] ), ξ 2 ) + + f T (x T (ξ [T ] ), ξ T ). 33

35 It looks natural to formulate the following distributionally robust analogue of problem (2). Consider a set M of probability distributions of ξ [T ] supported on a set Ξ R d 1 R d T equipped with its Borel sigma algebra B, and the problem Min sup E Q [Z π ]. (3) π Π Q M However, there is a problem with formulation (3). The expectation operator has the following property (recall that ξ 1 is deterministic) E[Z] = E ξ1 [E ξ[2] [ E ξ[t 1] (Z) ]]. 34

36 For Z = Z(ξ [T ] ) Z and Q M we have that E Q [Z] = E Q [ E Q ξ[2] [ ]] E Q ξ[t [Z], 1] and hence [ [ sup E Q [Z] sup E Q sup E Q ξ[2] Q M Q M Q M sup E Q ξ[t [Z]] ]. (4) Q M 1] In a certain sense the the right hand side of (4) represents the tightest upper bound for the left hand side among all possible coherent and time consistent upper bounds. 35

37 Rectangularity concept. Let Z be a subset of the space Z. We say that a set M of probability measures on (Ξ, B) is a rectangular set, associated with the sets M and Z, if [ [ sup E Q [Z] = sup E Q sup E Q ξ[1] Q M Q M Q M sup E Q ξ[t [Z]] ], Z Z. Q M 1] In particular, if this holds for M = M we say that the set M is rectangular (with respect to Z). 36

38 Theorem 4 Suppose that the right hand side of (4) is finite for all Z Z. Then there exists a bounded set M Z of probability measures which is rectangular with respect to M and Z. Theorem 5 Suppose that the set M is convex bounded and weakly closed, and let M Z be a rectangular set with respect to M and Z such that M M. Then M is rectangular with respect to Z iff M = M. It could be noted that taking weak closure of convex hull of the set M does not change optimal value of the original problem. Therefore the condition for M to be convex and weakly closed is not that restrictive. Of course, if the set Ξ is finite and hence the spaces Z and Z are finite dimensional, then the weak topology is the same as the standard topology of Z. 37

39 The analysis simplifies if we assume that the set M consists of product measures. That is, M := {Q = Q 1 Q T : Q t M t, t = 1,..., T }, where Ξ = Ξ 1 Ξ T and M t is a set of probability measures on (Ξ t, B t ), t = 1,..., T. If we view ξ 1,..., ξ T as a random process having distribution Q M, then this means that random vectors ξ t, t = 1,..., T, are mutually independent with respective marginal distributions Q t M t. For M Q = Q 1 Q T we can write E Q ξ[t 1] [Z] = and hence sup E Q [Z] Q M sup Q 1 M 1 E Q1 Ξ T Z(ξ [T 1], ξ T )dq T (ξ T ) =: E QT ξ [T 1] [Z], [ sup Q 2 M 2 E Q2 ξ [1] [ ] ] sup E QT ξ [Z]. Q T M [T 1] T 38

40 Dynamic Programming Equations. For the last period T we have Q T (x T 1, ξ T ) := inf F T (x T, ξ T ), x T X T (x T 1,ξ T ) Q T (x T 1, ξ [T 1] ) := ρ ξ[t 1] [Q T (x T 1, ξ T )], and for t = T 1,..., 2, where Q t ( xt 1, ξ [t] ) = inf x t X t (x t 1,ξ t ) { Ft (x t, ξ t ) + Q t+1 ( xt, ξ [t] ) }, Q t+1 ( xt, ξ [t] ) := ρ ξ[t] { Qt+1 ( xt, ξ [t+1] )}. Finally, at the first stage we solve the problem Min x1 X 1 F 1 (x 1 ) + ρ ξ1 [Q 2 (x 1, ξ 2 )]. 39

41 In case of stagewise independence, the cost-to-go functions Q t (x t 1 ) do not depend on the data process, and dynamic programming equations take the form ( ) { } Q t xt 1, ξ t = inf Ft (x t, ξ t ) + Q t+1 (x t ), x t X t (x t 1,ξ t ) t = T,..., 2, where Q t+1 ( xt, ξ [t] ) := ρ { Qt+1 ( xt, ξ t+1 )}, with Q T +1 ( ) 0. Finally, at the first stage we solve the problem Min F 1 (x 1 ) + ρ[q 2 (x 1, ξ 2 )]. x 1 X 1 40

42 Time consistency of stochastic programming problems Consider a multiperiod stochastic program Min x 1,x 2 ( ),...,x T ( ) ϱ( F 1 (x 1 ), F 2 (x 2 (ξ [2] ), ξ 2 ),..., F T ( xt (ξ [T ] ), ξ T ) ) s.t. x 1 X 1, x t (ξ [t] ) X t (x t 1 (ξ [t 1] ), ξ t ), t = 2,..., T, where ϱ : Z 1 Z 2 Z T R is a multiperiod risk measure. Is it time consistent? For example is Min AV@R ( ( ) ) α F1 (x 1 ) + + F T xt (ξ [T ] ), ξ T x 1,x 2 ( ),...,x T ( ) s.t. x 1 X 1, x t (ξ [t] ) X t (x t 1 (ξ [t 1] ), ξ t ), t = 2,..., T, time consistent? Note that for α (0, 1), ( AV@R α ( ) AV@R α ξ1 (AV@R α ξ[2] AV@Rα ξ[t ( ) )). 1] 41

43 Principle of conditional optimality. At every state of the system, optimality of our decisions should not depend on scenarios which we already know cannot happen in the future. Let us consider the following example. Let ϱ(z 1,..., Z T ) := Z 1 + Tt=2 AV@R α (Z t ). We can write ϱ(z 1,..., Z T ) := inf E { Z r 2,...,r 1 + ( T T t=2 rt + α 1 )} [Z t r t ] +. The objective function of the corresponding multiperiod optimization problem can be written as F 1 (x 1 ) + T t=2 r t + E T t=2 α 1 [F t (x t, ξ t ) r t ] + with additional variables r = (r 2,..., r T ). The problem can be viewed as a standard multistage stochastic program with (r, x 1 ) being first stage decision variables., 42

44 Dynamic programming equations: the cost-to-go function Q t (x t 1, r t,..., r T, ξ [t] ) is given by the optimal value of the problem Min x t X t (x t 1,ξ t ) α 1 [F t (x t, ξ t ) r t ] + + E ξ[t] [ Qt+1 (x t, r t,..., r T, ξ [t] ) ]. Although it is possible to write dynamic programming equations for this problem, note that decision variables r 2,..., r T are decided at the first stage and their optimal values depend on all scenarios starting at the root node at stage t = 1. Consequently optimal decisions at later stages depend on scenarios other than following a considered node. That is, here the principle of conditional optimality does not hold. 43

45 A well known quotation of Bellman: An optimal policy has the property that whatever the initial state and initial decision are, the remaining decisions must constitute an optimal policy with regard to the state resulting from the first decision. In order to make this precise we have to define what do we mean by saying that an optimal policy remains optimal at every stage of the process conditional on an observed realization of the data process. 44

46 We assume that with the multiperiod problem is associated a sequence of mappings ϱ t,t : Z t Z T Z t, t = 1,..., T. We say that {ϱ t,t } is a sequence of multiperiod mappings if it satisfies the condition of monotonicity: if Z, Z Z t Z T and Z Z, then ϱ t,t (Z) ϱ t,t (Z ). Examples. Conditional expectations: ϱ t,t (Z t,..., Z T ) := E ξ[t] (Z t Z T ). Conditional max-risk measures (recall that AV@R 0 ( ) = ess sup( )): ϱ t,t (Z t,..., Z T ) := AV@R 0 ξ[t] (Z t Z T ). For a law invariant coherent (convex) risk measure ρ( ): ϱ t,t (Z t,..., Z T ) := ρ ξ[t] (Z t Z T ). 45

47 Nested form: ϱ t,t (Z t,..., Z T ) := ρ ξ[t] ( ρ ξ[t 1] (Z t Z T ) ) = Z t + ρ ξ[t] (Z t ρ ξ[t 1] (Z T ) Recall that only conditional expectations and conditional maxrisk measures can be represented in the nested form of coherent risk measures. ) 46

48 For t = 2,..., T, consider problems Min (P t ) : ϱ ( ( ) ) t,t Ft (x t (ξ [t] ), ξ t ),..., F T xt (ξ [T ] ), ξ T x t ( ),...,x T ( ) s.t. x τ (ξ [τ] ) X τ (x τ 1 (ξ [τ 1] ), ξ τ ), τ = t,..., T, conditional on ξ [t] and x t 1. At t = 1 the problem (P 1 ) is Min x 1,x 2 ( ),...,x T ( ) ϱ 1,T ( F1 (x 1 ), F 2 (x 2 (ξ [2] ), ξ 2 ),..., F T ( xt (ξ [T ] ), ξ T ) ) s.t. x 1 X 1, x t (ξ [t] ) X t (x t 1 (ξ [t 1] ), ξ t ), t = 2,..., T, with ϱ 1,T : Z 1 Z 2 Z T R being a multiperiod risk measure. 47

49 We say that an optimal policy x 1, x 2 (ξ [2] ),..., x T (ξ [T ] ) of problem (P 1 ) is time consistent if the policy x t (ξ [t] ),..., x T (ξ [T ] ) is optimal for the problem (P t ), t = 2,..., T, conditional on ξ [t] and x t 1 = x t 1 (ξ [t 1] ). For the nested conditional risk measures ϱ t,t (Z t,..., Z T ) = Z t + ρ ξ[t] (Z t ρ ξ[t 1] (Z T ) every optimal policy of (P 1 ) is time consistent. ), (C1) For all 1 τ < θ T and Z, Z Z τ Z T, the conditions Z t = Z t, t = τ,..., θ 1, and ϱ θ,t (Z θ,..., Z T ) ϱ θ,t (Z θ,..., Z T ) imply that ϱ τ,t (Z τ,..., Z T ) ϱ τ,t (Z τ,..., Z T ). 48

50 Proposition 1 Suppose that condition (C1) holds and the multiperiod problem (P 1 ) has unique optimal solution policy x 1, x 2 (ξ [2] ),..., x T (ξ [T ] ). Then the policy x t (ξ [t] ),..., x T (ξ [T ] ) is optimal for the problem (P t ), t = 2,..., T, conditional on ξ [t] and x t 1 = x t 1. In case problem (P 1 ) has more than one optimal solution we need a stronger condition to ensure that an optimal solution of (P 1 ) is conditionally optimal for (P t ), t = 2,..., T : (C1 ) For all 1 τ < θ T and Z, Z Z τ Z T, the conditions Z t = Z t, t = τ,..., θ 1, and ϱ θ,t (Z θ,..., Z T ) ϱ θ,t (Z θ,..., Z T ) imply that ϱ τ,t (Z τ,..., Z T ) ϱ τ,t (Z τ,..., Z T ). 49

51 Consider the following conditions. (C2) For t = 1,..., T, it holds that ϱ t,t (0,..., 0) = 0, and for all (Z 1,..., Z T ) Z and t = 1,..., T 1, it holds that ϱ t,t (Z t, Z t+1,..., Z T ) = Z t + ϱ t,t (0, Z t+1,..., Z T ). (C3) For all 1 τ < θ T and Z Z it holds that ϱ τ,t (Z τ,..., Z θ,..., Z T ) = ϱ τ,θ ( Zτ,..., Z θ 1, ϱ θ,t (Z θ,..., Z T ) ). 50

52 Multiperiod coherent mappings of the nested form satisfy conditions (C1),(C2) and (C3), but not necessarily (C1 ). We have the following relations between these conditions. Proposition 2 Let {ϱ t,t } be a sequence of multiperiod mappings. Then the following holds. (i) Conditions (C1) and (C2) imply condition (C3). (ii) Condition (C3) implies condition (C1). 51

53 It is tempting to impose the following condition on the sequence of multiperiod mappings: For all 1 τ < θ T and Z, Z Z τ Z T, the conditions Z t = Z t, t = τ,..., θ 1, and ϱ τ,t (Z τ,..., Z T ) ϱ τ,t (Z τ,..., Z T ) imply that ϱ θ,t (Z θ,..., Z T ) ϱ θ,t (Z θ,..., Z T ). This condition will impliy the desired property of the sequence of multiperiod mappings. Unfortunately this condition does not hold even for a sequence of conditional expectation mappings ϱ t,t (Z t,..., Z T ) := E ξ[t] [Z t Z T ]. 52

54 Suppose that conditions (C1) and (C2) hold. Then condition (C3) follows, and hence we can write ( ϱ 1,T (Z 1,..., Z T ) = ϱ 1,T 1 Z1,..., Z T 2, ϱ T 1,T (Z T 1, Z T ) ) ( = ϱ 1,T 1 Z1,..., Z T 2, Z T 1 + ϱ T 1,T (0, Z T ) ). By continuing this process backwards we obtain the nested representation of ϱ 1,T : ϱ 1,T (Z 1,..., Z T ) = Z 1 + ρ 2 [Z ρ T 1 [ ZT 1 + ρ T [Z T ] ]], where ρ t+1 : Z t+1 Z t are one step mappings defined as ρ t+1 (Z t+1 ) := ϱ t,t+1 (0, Z t+1 ) = ϱ t,t (0, Z t+1, 0,..., 0). Clearly the mappings ρ t+1 inherit such properties of ϱ t,t as monotonicity, convexity and positive homogeneity. 53

55 Approximate dynamic programming Basic idea is to approximate the cost-to-go functions by a class of computationally manageable functions. Since functions Q t ( ) are convex it is natural to approximate these functions by piecewise linear functions given by maximum of cutting hyperplanes. Stochastic Dual Dynamic Programming (SDDP) method (Pereira and Pinto, 1991). For trial decisions x t, t = 1,..., T 1, at the backward step of the SDDP algorithm, piecewise linear approximations Q t ( ) of the cost-to-go functions Q t ( ) are constructed by solving problems Min x t R n (cj t t )T x t + Q t+1 (x t ) s.t. Bt j x t 1 + A j t x t = b j t, x t 0, j = 1,..., N t, and their duals, going backward in time t = T,..., 1. Denote by v 0 and ˆv N the respective optimal values of the true and SAA problems. 54

56 By construction Therefore the optimal value of Q t ( ) Q t ( ), t = 2,..., T. Min x 1 R n 1 ct 1 x 1 + Q 2 (x 1 ) s.t. A 1 x 1 = b 1, x 1 0 gives a lower bound for the optimal value ˆv N of the SAA problem. We also have that v 0 E[ˆv N ]. Therefore on average ˆv N is also a lower bound for the optimal value of the true problem. 55

57 The approximate cost-to-go functions Q 2,..., Q T and a feasible first stage solution x 1 define a feasible policy. That is for a realization (sample path) ξ 1,..., ξ T of the data process, x t = x t (ξ [t] ) are computed recursively in t = 2,..., T as a solution of Min x t c T t x t + Q t+1 (x t ) s.t. B t x t 1 + A t x t b t. In the forward step of the SDDP algorithm M sample paths (scenarios) are generated and the corresponding x t, t = 2,..., T, are used as trial points in the next iteration of the backward step. It is essential for convergence of this algorithm that at each iteration in the forward step the paths (scenarios) are resampled, i.e., generated independently of the previous iteration. Note that the functions Q 2,..., Q T and x 1 define a feasible policy also for the true problem. 56

58 Convergence of the SDDP algorithm It is possible to show that, under mild regularity conditions, the SDDP algorithm converges as the number of iterations go to infinity. That is, the computed optimal values and generated policies converge w.p.1 to their counterparts of the considered SAA problem. However, the convergence can be very slow and one should take such mathematical proofs very cautiously. Moreover, it should be remembered that the SAA problem is just an approximation of the true problem. It is possible to show that, in a certain probabilistic sense, the SAA problem converges to the true problem as all sample sizes N t, t = 2,..., T, tend to infinity. It was found in our numerical experiments that optimal solutions of the SAA problems started to stabilize for sample sizes of about N t = 100, t = 2,..., T. 57

59 Stopping criteria The policy value E [ Tt=1 c T t x t(ξ [t] ) ] can be estimated in the forward step of the algorithm. That is, let ξ2 i,..., ξi T, i = 1,..., M, be sample paths (scenarios) generated at a current iteration of the forward step, and ϑ i := T t=1 (c i t) T x i t, i = 1,..., M, be the corresponding cost values. Then E[ϑ i ] = E [ Tt=1 c T t x t(ξ [t] i )], and hence ϑ = 1 M M ϑ i i=1 gives an unbiased estimate of the policy value. 58

60 Also ˆσ 2 = 1 M 1 M i=1 (ϑ i ϑ) 2 estimates variance of the sample ϑ 1,..., ϑ M. Hence ϑ + z αˆσ/ M gives an upper bound for the policy value with confidence of about 100(1 α)%. Here z α is the corresponding critical value. At the same time this gives an upper bound for the optimal value of the corresponding multistage problem, SAA or the true problem depending from what data process the random scenarios were generated. Typical example of behavior of the lower and upper bounds produced by the SDDP algorithm for an SAA problem 59

61 8 state variables, 120 stages, 1 cut per iteration 60

62 Theoretical analysis and numerical experiments indicate that computational complexity of the SDDP algorithm grows fast with increase of the number of state variables. Sensitivity to initial conditions Individual stage costs for the risk neutral approach in two cases: all the reservoirs start at 25% or at 75% of the maximum capacity. The yellow curve denotes the 75% initial reservoir level and the dark green denotes the 25% initial level. 61

63 62

64 Variability of SAA problems Table shows the 95% confidence interval for the lower bound and average policy value at iteration 3000 over a sample of 20 SAA problems. Each of the policy value observations was computed using 2000 scenarios. The last 2 columns of the table shows the range divided by the average of the lower bound (where the range is the difference between the maximum and minimum observation) and the standard deviation divided by the average value. This problem has relatively low variability (approx. 4%) for both of the lower bound and the average policy value. 95% C.I. left Average 95% C.I. right range average sdev. average ( 10 9 ) ( 10 9 ) ( 10 9 ) Lower bound % 4.07% Average policy % 4.12% SAA variability for risk neutral SDDP 63

65 Risk averse approach How to control risk, i.e., to reduce chances of extreme costs, at every stage of the time process. Value-at-Risk of a random outcome (variable) Z at level α (0, 1): V@R α (Z) = inf{t : F Z (t) 1 α}, where F Z (t) = Pr(Z t) is the cdf of Z. That is, V@R α (Z) is the (1 α)-quantile of the distribution of Z. Note that V@R α (Z) c is equivalent to Pr(Z > c) α. Therefore it could be a natural approach to impose constraints (chance constraints) of V@R α (Z) c for Z = cost, chosen constant c and significance level α at every stage of the process. 64

66 There are two problems with such approach. It is difficult to handle chance constraints numerically and could lead to infeasibility problems. Average Value-at-Risk (also called Conditional Value-at-Risk) { AV@R α (Z) = inf t + α 1 } E[Z t] + t R Note that the minimum in the above is attained at t = V@R α (Z). If the cdf F Z (z) is continuous, then AV@R α (Z) = E [ Z Z V@R α (Z) ]. It follows that AV@R α (Z) V@R α (Z). Therefore the constraint AV@R α (Z) c is a conservative approximation of the chance constraint V@R α (Z) c. 65

67 In the problem of minimizing expected cost E[Z] subject to the constraint α (Z) c, we impose an infinite penalty for violating this constraint. This could result in infeasibility of the obtained problem. Instead we can impose a finite penalty and consider problem of minimization of E[Z] + κav@r α (Z) for some constant κ > 0. Note that this is equivalent to minimization of ρ(z), where for λ (0, 1) and κ = ρ(z) = (1 λ)e[z] + λav@r α (Z) λ 1 λ. 66

68 This leads to the following (nested) formulation of risk averse multistage problem. with [ Min c T A 1 x 1 b 1 x 1 + ρ 2 ξ1 inf c T 2 x B 2 x 1 +A 2 x 2 =b 2 x 2 0 [ +ρ T 1 ξ[t inf c T 2] T 1 x T 1 B T 1 x T 2 +A T 1 x T 1 =b T 1 x T 1 0 +ρ T ξ[t 1] [ inf B T x T 1 +A T x T =b T x T 0 c T T x T ] ]], ρ t ξ[t] ( ) := (1 λ)e ξ[t] [ ] + λav@r α ξ[t] ( ) being conditional analogue of ρ( ). 67

69 We can write the risk averse multistage programming problem as Min ρ [ ( ) ] F 1 (x 1 ) + F 2 (x 2 (ξ [2] ), ξ 2 ) + + F T xt (ξ [T ] ), ξ T x 1,x 2 ( ),...,x T ( ) s.t. x 1 X 1, x t (ξ [t] ) X t (x t 1 (ξ [t 1] ), ξ t ), t = 2,..., T, where F t (x t, ξ t ) = c T t x t and X t (x t 1, ξ t ) = {x t : B t x t 1 + A t x t = b t, x t 0}. ρ(z Z T ) = ρ ξ1 ( ρ ξ[2] ( ρ ξ[t 1] (Z Z T ) )) = Z 1 + ρ ξ1 ( Z 2 + ρ ξ[2] ( + ρ ξ[t 1] (Z T ) )) is the corresponding composite risk measure. The optimization is performed over (nonanticipative) policies x 1, x 2 (ξ [2] ),..., x T (ξ [T ] ) satisfying the feasibility constraints. 68

70 With some modifications the SDDP algorithm can be applied to the above multistage problem. Assuming the stagewise independence, the dynamic programming equations for the adaptive risk averse problem take the form Q t ( xt 1, ξ t ) = inf x t R n t t = T,..., 2, where Q T +1 ( ) 0 and { c T t x t +Q t+1 (x t ) : B t x t 1 +A t x t = b t, x t 0 }, Q t+1 (x t ) := ρ t+1 ξ[t] [ Qt+1 ( xt, ξ t+1 )]. Since ξ t+1 is independent of ξ [t], the cost-to-go functions Q t+1 (x t ) do not depend on the data process. In order to apply the backward step of the SDDP algorithm we only need to know how to compute subgradients of the cost-to-go functions. 69

71 The value of this problem corresponds to the total objective ρ(z Z T ) = ρ ξ[1] ( ρ ξ[t 1] (Z Z T ) ) = Z 1 + ρ ξ[1] (Z ρ ξ[t 1] (Z T ) The dynamic programming equations of the risk averse formulation of the SAA program take the form Q j t (x t 1) = inf x t { (c j t ) T x t + Q t+1 (x t ) : B j t x t 1 + A j t x t = b j t, x t 0 }, j = 1,..., N t, t = T,..., 2, and ( Q t+1 (x t ) = ρ Q 1 t+1 (x t),..., Q N t+1 t+1 (x t) with Q T +1 ( ) 0 and the first stage problem Min A 1 x 1 b 1 c T 1 x 1 + ρ ( Q 1 2 (x 1),..., Q N 2 2 (x 1) ). ), ) 70

72 For ρ( ) = (1 λ)e[ ] + λav@r α ( ), and (Z 1,..., Z N ) = ( Q 1 t+1 (x t ),..., Q N t+1 (x t) ) we have that Q t+1 (x t ) = 1 λ N t+1 N t+1 j=1 Z j + λ Z ι + 1 αn t+1 j:z j >Z ι where Z ι is the (1 α)-quantile of Z 1,..., Z Nt+1. N t+1 < (1 α) 1, then Z ι = max{z 1,..., Z Nt+1 }. [ ] Zj Z ι, Note that if A subgradient of Q t+1 (x t ) is given by Q t+1 (x t ) = 1 λ N λ N t+1 j=1 Q ι t+1 (x t) + 1 αn t+1 Q j t+1 (x t) + j:z j >Z ι [ j Q t+1 (x t) Q ι t+1 (x t) ]. 71

73 These formulas allow construction of cuts in the backward step of the SDDP algorithm. In the forward step trial points are generated in the same way as in the risk neutral case. Remarks Unfortunately there is no easy way for evaluating value of the risk objective of generated policies, and hence constructing a corresponding upper bound. Some suggestions were made in the recent literature. However, in larger problems the optimality gap (between the upper and lower bounds) never approaches zero in any realistic time. Therefore stopping criteria based on stabilization of the lower bound (and may be optimal solutions) could be reasonable. Also it should be remembered that there is no intuitive interpretation for the risk objective ρ(cost) of the total cost. Rather the goal is to control risk at every stage of the process. 72

74 73

Risk neutral and risk averse approaches to multistage stochastic programming.

Risk neutral and risk averse approaches to multistage stochastic programming. Risk neutral and risk averse approaches to multistage stochastic programming. A. Shapiro School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, Georgia 30332-0205, USA

More information

Decomposability and time consistency of risk averse multistage programs

Decomposability and time consistency of risk averse multistage programs Decomposability and time consistency of risk averse multistage programs arxiv:1806.01497v1 [math.oc] 5 Jun 2018 A. Shapiro School of Industrial and Systems Engineering Georgia Institute of Technology Atlanta,

More information

Minimax and risk averse multistage stochastic programming

Minimax and risk averse multistage stochastic programming Minimax and risk averse multistage stochastic programming Alexander Shapiro School of Industrial & Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, 765 Ferst Drive, Atlanta, GA 30332. Abstract. In

More information

On Kusuoka Representation of Law Invariant Risk Measures

On Kusuoka Representation of Law Invariant Risk Measures MATHEMATICS OF OPERATIONS RESEARCH Vol. 38, No. 1, February 213, pp. 142 152 ISSN 364-765X (print) ISSN 1526-5471 (online) http://dx.doi.org/1.1287/moor.112.563 213 INFORMS On Kusuoka Representation of

More information

On Kusuoka representation of law invariant risk measures

On Kusuoka representation of law invariant risk measures On Kusuoka representation of law invariant risk measures Alexander Shapiro School of Industrial & Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, 765 Ferst Drive, Atlanta, GA 3332. Abstract. In this

More information

Topics in Stochastic Programming

Topics in Stochastic Programming Topics in Stochastic Programming Alexander Shapiro School of Industrial & Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, 765 Ferst Drive, Atlanta, GA 30332. Contents 1 Introduction 1 2 Two Stage

More information

Operations Research Letters. On a time consistency concept in risk averse multistage stochastic programming

Operations Research Letters. On a time consistency concept in risk averse multistage stochastic programming Operations Research Letters 37 2009 143 147 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Operations Research Letters journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/orl On a time consistency concept in risk averse

More information

Risk-Averse Dynamic Optimization. Andrzej Ruszczyński. Research supported by the NSF award CMMI

Risk-Averse Dynamic Optimization. Andrzej Ruszczyński. Research supported by the NSF award CMMI Research supported by the NSF award CMMI-0965689 Outline 1 Risk-Averse Preferences 2 Coherent Risk Measures 3 Dynamic Risk Measurement 4 Markov Risk Measures 5 Risk-Averse Control Problems 6 Solution Methods

More information

Stochastic Programming Approach to Optimization under Uncertainty

Stochastic Programming Approach to Optimization under Uncertainty Mathematical Programming manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) Alexander Shapiro Stochastic Programming Approach to Optimization under Uncertainty Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract In

More information

Asymptotics of minimax stochastic programs

Asymptotics of minimax stochastic programs Asymptotics of minimax stochastic programs Alexander Shapiro Abstract. We discuss in this paper asymptotics of the sample average approximation (SAA) of the optimal value of a minimax stochastic programming

More information

Upper bound for optimal value of risk averse multistage problems

Upper bound for optimal value of risk averse multistage problems Upper bound for optimal value of risk averse multistage problems Lingquan Ding School of Industrial and Systems Engineering Georgia Institute of Technology Atlanta, GA 30332-0205 Alexander Shapiro School

More information

Risk averse stochastic programming: time consistency and optimal stopping

Risk averse stochastic programming: time consistency and optimal stopping Risk averse stochastic programming: time consistency and optimal stopping A. Pichler Fakultät für Mathematik Technische Universität Chemnitz D 09111 Chemnitz, Germany A. Shapiro School of Industrial and

More information

Time inconsistency of optimal policies of distributionally robust inventory models

Time inconsistency of optimal policies of distributionally robust inventory models Time inconsistency of optimal policies of distributionally robust inventory models Alexander Shapiro Linwei Xin Abstract In this paper, we investigate optimal policies of distributionally robust (risk

More information

CONVERGENCE ANALYSIS OF SAMPLING-BASED DECOMPOSITION METHODS FOR RISK-AVERSE MULTISTAGE STOCHASTIC CONVEX PROGRAMS

CONVERGENCE ANALYSIS OF SAMPLING-BASED DECOMPOSITION METHODS FOR RISK-AVERSE MULTISTAGE STOCHASTIC CONVEX PROGRAMS CONVERGENCE ANALYSIS OF SAMPLING-BASED DECOMPOSITION METHODS FOR RISK-AVERSE MULTISTAGE STOCHASTIC CONVEX PROGRAMS VINCENT GUIGUES Abstract. We consider a class of sampling-based decomposition methods

More information

Inverse Stochastic Dominance Constraints Duality and Methods

Inverse Stochastic Dominance Constraints Duality and Methods Duality and Methods Darinka Dentcheva 1 Andrzej Ruszczyński 2 1 Stevens Institute of Technology Hoboken, New Jersey, USA 2 Rutgers University Piscataway, New Jersey, USA Research supported by NSF awards

More information

Complexity of two and multi-stage stochastic programming problems

Complexity of two and multi-stage stochastic programming problems Complexity of two and multi-stage stochastic programming problems A. Shapiro School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, Georgia 30332-0205, USA The concept

More information

Process-Based Risk Measures for Observable and Partially Observable Discrete-Time Controlled Systems

Process-Based Risk Measures for Observable and Partially Observable Discrete-Time Controlled Systems Process-Based Risk Measures for Observable and Partially Observable Discrete-Time Controlled Systems Jingnan Fan Andrzej Ruszczyński November 5, 2014; revised April 15, 2015 Abstract For controlled discrete-time

More information

Bounds on Risk-averse Mixed-integer Multi-stage Stochastic Programming Problems with Mean-CVaR

Bounds on Risk-averse Mixed-integer Multi-stage Stochastic Programming Problems with Mean-CVaR Bounds on Risk-averse Mixed-integer Multi-stage Stochastic Programming Problems with Mean-CVaR Ali rfan Mahmuto ullar, Özlem Çavu³, and M. Selim Aktürk Department of Industrial Engineering, Bilkent University,

More information

On duality theory of conic linear problems

On duality theory of conic linear problems On duality theory of conic linear problems Alexander Shapiro School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, Georgia 3332-25, USA e-mail: ashapiro@isye.gatech.edu

More information

MIDAS: A Mixed Integer Dynamic Approximation Scheme

MIDAS: A Mixed Integer Dynamic Approximation Scheme MIDAS: A Mixed Integer Dynamic Approximation Scheme Andy Philpott, Faisal Wahid, Frédéric Bonnans May 7, 2016 Abstract Mixed Integer Dynamic Approximation Scheme (MIDAS) is a new sampling-based algorithm

More information

Random sets. Distributions, capacities and their applications. Ilya Molchanov. University of Bern, Switzerland

Random sets. Distributions, capacities and their applications. Ilya Molchanov. University of Bern, Switzerland Random sets Distributions, capacities and their applications Ilya Molchanov University of Bern, Switzerland Molchanov Random sets - Lecture 1. Winter School Sandbjerg, Jan 2007 1 E = R d ) Definitions

More information

Regularized optimization techniques for multistage stochastic programming

Regularized optimization techniques for multistage stochastic programming Regularized optimization techniques for multistage stochastic programming Felipe Beltrán 1, Welington de Oliveira 2, Guilherme Fredo 1, Erlon Finardi 1 1 UFSC/LabPlan Universidade Federal de Santa Catarina

More information

Coherent risk measures

Coherent risk measures Coherent risk measures Foivos Xanthos Ryerson University, Department of Mathematics Toµɛας Mαθηµατ ικὼν, E.M.Π, 11 Noɛµβρὶoυ 2015 Research interests Financial Mathematics, Mathematical Economics, Functional

More information

School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, Georgia , USA

School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, Georgia , USA 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 DISTRIBUTIONALLY ROBUST STOCHASTIC PROGRAMMING ALEXANDER SHAPIRO School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, Georgia

More information

Robust Optimal Control Using Conditional Risk Mappings in Infinite Horizon

Robust Optimal Control Using Conditional Risk Mappings in Infinite Horizon Robust Optimal Control Using Conditional Risk Mappings in Infinite Horizon Kerem Uğurlu Monday 9 th April, 2018 Department of Applied Mathematics, University of Washington, Seattle, WA 98195 e-mail: keremu@uw.edu

More information

Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University

Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University TIME CONSISTENT RISK AVERSE DYNAMIC DECISION MODELS: AN ECONOMIC INTERPRETATION Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University brudloff@princeton.edu Alexandre Street

More information

ELEMENTS OF PROBABILITY THEORY

ELEMENTS OF PROBABILITY THEORY ELEMENTS OF PROBABILITY THEORY Elements of Probability Theory A collection of subsets of a set Ω is called a σ algebra if it contains Ω and is closed under the operations of taking complements and countable

More information

3 (Due ). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure?

3 (Due ). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure? MA 645-4A (Real Analysis), Dr. Chernov Homework assignment 1 (Due ). Show that the open disk x 2 + y 2 < 1 is a countable union of planar elementary sets. Show that the closed disk x 2 + y 2 1 is a countable

More information

Multistage stochastic programs: Time-consistency, time-inconsistency and martingale bounds

Multistage stochastic programs: Time-consistency, time-inconsistency and martingale bounds Multistage stochastic programs: Time-consistency, time-inconsistency and martingale bounds Georg Ch. Pflug, joint work with Raimund Kovacevic and Alois Pichler April 2016 The time-consistency problem Many

More information

arxiv: v2 [math.oc] 18 Nov 2017

arxiv: v2 [math.oc] 18 Nov 2017 DASC: A DECOMPOSITION ALGORITHM FOR MULTISTAGE STOCHASTIC PROGRAMS WITH STRONGLY CONVEX COST FUNCTIONS arxiv:1711.04650v2 [math.oc] 18 Nov 2017 Vincent Guigues School of Applied Mathematics, FGV Praia

More information

Stability of optimization problems with stochastic dominance constraints

Stability of optimization problems with stochastic dominance constraints Stability of optimization problems with stochastic dominance constraints D. Dentcheva and W. Römisch Stevens Institute of Technology, Hoboken Humboldt-University Berlin www.math.hu-berlin.de/~romisch SIAM

More information

Stochastic Dual Dynamic Programming with CVaR Risk Constraints Applied to Hydrothermal Scheduling. ICSP 2013 Bergamo, July 8-12, 2012

Stochastic Dual Dynamic Programming with CVaR Risk Constraints Applied to Hydrothermal Scheduling. ICSP 2013 Bergamo, July 8-12, 2012 Stochastic Dual Dynamic Programming with CVaR Risk Constraints Applied to Hydrothermal Scheduling Luiz Carlos da Costa Junior Mario V. F. Pereira Sérgio Granville Nora Campodónico Marcia Helena Costa Fampa

More information

CVaR and Examples of Deviation Risk Measures

CVaR and Examples of Deviation Risk Measures CVaR and Examples of Deviation Risk Measures Jakub Černý Department of Probability and Mathematical Statistics Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance November 10, 2014 1 / 25 Contents CVaR - Dual

More information

Stochastic Optimization with Risk Measures

Stochastic Optimization with Risk Measures Stochastic Optimization with Risk Measures IMA New Directions Short Course on Mathematical Optimization Jim Luedtke Department of Industrial and Systems Engineering University of Wisconsin-Madison August

More information

On a class of minimax stochastic programs

On a class of minimax stochastic programs On a class of minimax stochastic programs Alexander Shapiro and Shabbir Ahmed School of Industrial & Systems Engineering Georgia Institute of Technology 765 Ferst Drive, Atlanta, GA 30332. August 29, 2003

More information

The L-Shaped Method. Operations Research. Anthony Papavasiliou 1 / 44

The L-Shaped Method. Operations Research. Anthony Papavasiliou 1 / 44 1 / 44 The L-Shaped Method Operations Research Anthony Papavasiliou Contents 2 / 44 1 The L-Shaped Method [ 5.1 of BL] 2 Optimality Cuts [ 5.1a of BL] 3 Feasibility Cuts [ 5.1b of BL] 4 Proof of Convergence

More information

Time Consistent Decisions and Temporal Decomposition of Coherent Risk Functionals

Time Consistent Decisions and Temporal Decomposition of Coherent Risk Functionals Time Consistent Decisions and Temporal Decomposition of Coherent Risk Functionals Georg Ch. Pflug, Alois Pichler June 16, 15 Abstract In management and planning it is commonplace for additional information

More information

Weak convergence and Brownian Motion. (telegram style notes) P.J.C. Spreij

Weak convergence and Brownian Motion. (telegram style notes) P.J.C. Spreij Weak convergence and Brownian Motion (telegram style notes) P.J.C. Spreij this version: December 8, 2006 1 The space C[0, ) In this section we summarize some facts concerning the space C[0, ) of real

More information

Scenario decomposition of risk-averse two stage stochastic programming problems

Scenario decomposition of risk-averse two stage stochastic programming problems R u t c o r Research R e p o r t Scenario decomposition of risk-averse two stage stochastic programming problems Ricardo A Collado a Dávid Papp b Andrzej Ruszczyński c RRR 2-2012, January 2012 RUTCOR Rutgers

More information

The Subdifferential of Convex Deviation Measures and Risk Functions

The Subdifferential of Convex Deviation Measures and Risk Functions The Subdifferential of Convex Deviation Measures and Risk Functions Nicole Lorenz Gert Wanka In this paper we give subdifferential formulas of some convex deviation measures using their conjugate functions

More information

CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS AS BANACH-LATTICE VALUED MAPPINGS

CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS AS BANACH-LATTICE VALUED MAPPINGS CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS AS BANACH-LATTICE VALUED MAPPINGS RAIMUND KOVACEVIC Department of Statistics and Decision Support Systems, University of Vienna, Vienna, Austria Abstract. Conditional

More information

Semi-infinite programming, duality, discretization and optimality conditions

Semi-infinite programming, duality, discretization and optimality conditions Semi-infinite programming, duality, discretization and optimality conditions Alexander Shapiro School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, Georgia 30332-0205,

More information

Random Locations of Periodic Stationary Processes

Random Locations of Periodic Stationary Processes Random Locations of Periodic Stationary Processes Yi Shen Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Waterloo Joint work with Jie Shen and Ruodu Wang May 3, 2016 The Fields Institute

More information

2 (Bonus). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure?

2 (Bonus). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure? MA 645-4A (Real Analysis), Dr. Chernov Homework assignment 1 (Due 9/5). Prove that every countable set A is measurable and µ(a) = 0. 2 (Bonus). Let A consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is

More information

arxiv: v3 [math.oc] 25 Apr 2018

arxiv: v3 [math.oc] 25 Apr 2018 Problem-driven scenario generation: an analytical approach for stochastic programs with tail risk measure Jamie Fairbrother *, Amanda Turner *, and Stein W. Wallace ** * STOR-i Centre for Doctoral Training,

More information

Revisiting some results on the sample complexity of multistage stochastic programs and some extensions

Revisiting some results on the sample complexity of multistage stochastic programs and some extensions Revisiting some results on the sample complexity of multistage stochastic programs and some extensions M.M.C.R. Reaiche IMPA, Rio de Janeiro, RJ, Brazil March 17, 2016 Abstract In this work we present

More information

1 Stochastic Dynamic Programming

1 Stochastic Dynamic Programming 1 Stochastic Dynamic Programming Formally, a stochastic dynamic program has the same components as a deterministic one; the only modification is to the state transition equation. When events in the future

More information

Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem

Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem 56 Chapter 7 Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem Recall that C(X) is not a normed linear space when X is not compact. On the other hand we could use semi

More information

Dual representations of risk measures

Dual representations of risk measures May 7, 2005 The variance and similar pure risk measures The standard deviation and similar pure risk measures The lower semi-variance and similar pure risk measures The lower semi-standard deviation and

More information

Semidefinite and Second Order Cone Programming Seminar Fall 2012 Project: Robust Optimization and its Application of Robust Portfolio Optimization

Semidefinite and Second Order Cone Programming Seminar Fall 2012 Project: Robust Optimization and its Application of Robust Portfolio Optimization Semidefinite and Second Order Cone Programming Seminar Fall 2012 Project: Robust Optimization and its Application of Robust Portfolio Optimization Instructor: Farid Alizadeh Author: Ai Kagawa 12/12/2012

More information

University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming

University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists 1 of 63 University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming Peter J. Hammond Autumn 2013, revised 2014 University of

More information

Resource Allocation for Contingency Planning: An Inexact Bundle Method for Stochastic Optimization

Resource Allocation for Contingency Planning: An Inexact Bundle Method for Stochastic Optimization Resource Allocation for Contingency Planning: An Inexact Bundle Method for Stochastic Optimization Ricardo A. Collado, Somayeh Moazeni* School of Business, Stevens Institute of Technology, Hoboken, NJ

More information

Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process

Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process Lecture 17: Brownian motion as a Markov process 1 of 14 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 2015 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process Brownian motion is

More information

MIDAS: A Mixed Integer Dynamic Approximation Scheme

MIDAS: A Mixed Integer Dynamic Approximation Scheme MIDAS: A Mixed Integer Dynamic Approximation Scheme Andy Philpott, Faisal Wahid, Frédéric Bonnans June 16, 2016 Abstract Mixed Integer Dynamic Approximation Scheme (MIDAS) is a new sampling-based algorithm

More information

Stochastic Dual Dynamic Integer Programming

Stochastic Dual Dynamic Integer Programming Stochastic Dual Dynamic Integer Programming Jikai Zou Shabbir Ahmed Xu Andy Sun December 26, 2017 Abstract Multistage stochastic integer programming (MSIP) combines the difficulty of uncertainty, dynamics,

More information

4. Conditional risk measures and their robust representation

4. Conditional risk measures and their robust representation 4. Conditional risk measures and their robust representation We consider a discrete-time information structure given by a filtration (F t ) t=0,...,t on our probability space (Ω, F, P ). The time horizon

More information

Aliprantis, Border: Infinite-dimensional Analysis A Hitchhiker s Guide

Aliprantis, Border: Infinite-dimensional Analysis A Hitchhiker s Guide aliprantis.tex May 10, 2011 Aliprantis, Border: Infinite-dimensional Analysis A Hitchhiker s Guide Notes from [AB2]. 1 Odds and Ends 2 Topology 2.1 Topological spaces Example. (2.2) A semimetric = triangle

More information

Lecture 5: The Bellman Equation

Lecture 5: The Bellman Equation Lecture 5: The Bellman Equation Florian Scheuer 1 Plan Prove properties of the Bellman equation (In particular, existence and uniqueness of solution) Use this to prove properties of the solution Think

More information

On the convergence of sequences of random variables: A primer

On the convergence of sequences of random variables: A primer BCAM May 2012 1 On the convergence of sequences of random variables: A primer Armand M. Makowski ECE & ISR/HyNet University of Maryland at College Park armand@isr.umd.edu BCAM May 2012 2 A sequence a :

More information

Acceptability functionals, risk capital functionals and risk deviation functionals: Primal and dual properties for one-and multiperiod models

Acceptability functionals, risk capital functionals and risk deviation functionals: Primal and dual properties for one-and multiperiod models Acceptability functionals, risk capital functionals and risk deviation functionals: Primal and dual properties for one-and multiperiod models 11.5.2005 Preliminary remark: risk measures risk functionals

More information

Introduction to Stochastic Optimization Part 4: Multi-stage decision

Introduction to Stochastic Optimization Part 4: Multi-stage decision Introduction to Stochastic Optimization Part 4: Multi-stage decision problems April 23, 29 The problem ξ = (ξ,..., ξ T ) a multivariate time series process (e.g. future interest rates, future asset prices,

More information

Revisiting some results on the complexity of multistage stochastic programs and some extensions

Revisiting some results on the complexity of multistage stochastic programs and some extensions Revisiting some results on the complexity of multistage stochastic programs and some extensions M.M.C.R. Reaiche IMPA, Rio de Janeiro, RJ, Brazil October 30, 2015 Abstract In this work we present explicit

More information

Statistics 612: L p spaces, metrics on spaces of probabilites, and connections to estimation

Statistics 612: L p spaces, metrics on spaces of probabilites, and connections to estimation Statistics 62: L p spaces, metrics on spaces of probabilites, and connections to estimation Moulinath Banerjee December 6, 2006 L p spaces and Hilbert spaces We first formally define L p spaces. Consider

More information

Local strong convexity and local Lipschitz continuity of the gradient of convex functions

Local strong convexity and local Lipschitz continuity of the gradient of convex functions Local strong convexity and local Lipschitz continuity of the gradient of convex functions R. Goebel and R.T. Rockafellar May 23, 2007 Abstract. Given a pair of convex conjugate functions f and f, we investigate

More information

(1) Consider the space S consisting of all continuous real-valued functions on the closed interval [0, 1]. For f, g S, define

(1) Consider the space S consisting of all continuous real-valued functions on the closed interval [0, 1]. For f, g S, define Homework, Real Analysis I, Fall, 2010. (1) Consider the space S consisting of all continuous real-valued functions on the closed interval [0, 1]. For f, g S, define ρ(f, g) = 1 0 f(x) g(x) dx. Show that

More information

Lecture 1. Stochastic Optimization: Introduction. January 8, 2018

Lecture 1. Stochastic Optimization: Introduction. January 8, 2018 Lecture 1 Stochastic Optimization: Introduction January 8, 2018 Optimization Concerned with mininmization/maximization of mathematical functions Often subject to constraints Euler (1707-1783): Nothing

More information

Risk Measures in non-dominated Models

Risk Measures in non-dominated Models Purpose: Study Risk Measures taking into account the model uncertainty in mathematical finance. Plan 1 Non-dominated Models Model Uncertainty Fundamental topological Properties 2 Risk Measures on L p (c)

More information

Scenario decomposition of risk-averse multistage stochastic programming problems a

Scenario decomposition of risk-averse multistage stochastic programming problems a R u t c o r Research R e p o r t Scenario decomposition of risk-averse multistage stochastic programming problems a Ricardo A. Collado b Dávid Papp c Andrzej Ruszczyński d RRR 13-2010, September 30, 2010

More information

Stochastic Shortest Path Problems

Stochastic Shortest Path Problems Chapter 8 Stochastic Shortest Path Problems 1 In this chapter, we study a stochastic version of the shortest path problem of chapter 2, where only probabilities of transitions along different arcs can

More information

Fundamentals in Optimal Investments. Lecture I

Fundamentals in Optimal Investments. Lecture I Fundamentals in Optimal Investments Lecture I + 1 Portfolio choice Portfolio allocations and their ordering Performance indices Fundamentals in optimal portfolio choice Expected utility theory and its

More information

Real Analysis Math 131AH Rudin, Chapter #1. Dominique Abdi

Real Analysis Math 131AH Rudin, Chapter #1. Dominique Abdi Real Analysis Math 3AH Rudin, Chapter # Dominique Abdi.. If r is rational (r 0) and x is irrational, prove that r + x and rx are irrational. Solution. Assume the contrary, that r+x and rx are rational.

More information

Importance sampling in scenario generation

Importance sampling in scenario generation Importance sampling in scenario generation Václav Kozmík Faculty of Mathematics and Physics Charles University in Prague September 14, 2013 Introduction Monte Carlo techniques have received significant

More information

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING 15. HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROF. YURI BAKHTIN Instructions. You are allowed to work on solutions in groups, but you are required to write up solutions on your own. Please

More information

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING 218. HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROF. YURI BAKHTIN Instructions. You are allowed to work on solutions in groups, but you are required to write up solutions on your own. Please

More information

c 2004 Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics

c 2004 Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics SIAM J. OPTIM. Vol. 14, No. 4, pp. 1237 1249 c 2004 Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics ON A CLASS OF MINIMAX STOCHASTIC PROGRAMS ALEXANDER SHAPIRO AND SHABBIR AHMED Abstract. For a particular

More information

The L-Shaped Method. Operations Research. Anthony Papavasiliou 1 / 38

The L-Shaped Method. Operations Research. Anthony Papavasiliou 1 / 38 1 / 38 The L-Shaped Method Operations Research Anthony Papavasiliou Contents 2 / 38 1 The L-Shaped Method 2 Example: Capacity Expansion Planning 3 Examples with Optimality Cuts [ 5.1a of BL] 4 Examples

More information

On the Convergence of Adaptive Stochastic Search Methods for Constrained and Multi-Objective Black-Box Global Optimization

On the Convergence of Adaptive Stochastic Search Methods for Constrained and Multi-Objective Black-Box Global Optimization On the Convergence of Adaptive Stochastic Search Methods for Constrained and Multi-Objective Black-Box Global Optimization Rommel G. Regis Citation: R. G. Regis. 2016. On the convergence of adaptive stochastic

More information

2. Dual space is essential for the concept of gradient which, in turn, leads to the variational analysis of Lagrange multipliers.

2. Dual space is essential for the concept of gradient which, in turn, leads to the variational analysis of Lagrange multipliers. Chapter 3 Duality in Banach Space Modern optimization theory largely centers around the interplay of a normed vector space and its corresponding dual. The notion of duality is important for the following

More information

Penalty and Barrier Methods General classical constrained minimization problem minimize f(x) subject to g(x) 0 h(x) =0 Penalty methods are motivated by the desire to use unconstrained optimization techniques

More information

Exercises: Brunn, Minkowski and convex pie

Exercises: Brunn, Minkowski and convex pie Lecture 1 Exercises: Brunn, Minkowski and convex pie Consider the following problem: 1.1 Playing a convex pie Consider the following game with two players - you and me. I am cooking a pie, which should

More information

Notes 1 : Measure-theoretic foundations I

Notes 1 : Measure-theoretic foundations I Notes 1 : Measure-theoretic foundations I Math 733-734: Theory of Probability Lecturer: Sebastien Roch References: [Wil91, Section 1.0-1.8, 2.1-2.3, 3.1-3.11], [Fel68, Sections 7.2, 8.1, 9.6], [Dur10,

More information

Generalized quantiles as risk measures

Generalized quantiles as risk measures Generalized quantiles as risk measures Bellini, Klar, Muller, Rosazza Gianin December 1, 2014 Vorisek Jan Introduction Quantiles q α of a random variable X can be defined as the minimizers of a piecewise

More information

Lagrange Relaxation: Introduction and Applications

Lagrange Relaxation: Introduction and Applications 1 / 23 Lagrange Relaxation: Introduction and Applications Operations Research Anthony Papavasiliou 2 / 23 Contents 1 Context 2 Applications Application in Stochastic Programming Unit Commitment 3 / 23

More information

PROBLEMS. (b) (Polarization Identity) Show that in any inner product space

PROBLEMS. (b) (Polarization Identity) Show that in any inner product space 1 Professor Carl Cowen Math 54600 Fall 09 PROBLEMS 1. (Geometry in Inner Product Spaces) (a) (Parallelogram Law) Show that in any inner product space x + y 2 + x y 2 = 2( x 2 + y 2 ). (b) (Polarization

More information

Financial Optimization ISE 347/447. Lecture 21. Dr. Ted Ralphs

Financial Optimization ISE 347/447. Lecture 21. Dr. Ted Ralphs Financial Optimization ISE 347/447 Lecture 21 Dr. Ted Ralphs ISE 347/447 Lecture 21 1 Reading for This Lecture C&T Chapter 16 ISE 347/447 Lecture 21 2 Formalizing: Random Linear Optimization Consider the

More information

MATHS 730 FC Lecture Notes March 5, Introduction

MATHS 730 FC Lecture Notes March 5, Introduction 1 INTRODUCTION MATHS 730 FC Lecture Notes March 5, 2014 1 Introduction Definition. If A, B are sets and there exists a bijection A B, they have the same cardinality, which we write as A, #A. If there exists

More information

Some Properties of NSFDEs

Some Properties of NSFDEs Chenggui Yuan (Swansea University) Some Properties of NSFDEs 1 / 41 Some Properties of NSFDEs Chenggui Yuan Swansea University Chenggui Yuan (Swansea University) Some Properties of NSFDEs 2 / 41 Outline

More information

II - REAL ANALYSIS. This property gives us a way to extend the notion of content to finite unions of rectangles: we define

II - REAL ANALYSIS. This property gives us a way to extend the notion of content to finite unions of rectangles: we define 1 Measures 1.1 Jordan content in R N II - REAL ANALYSIS Let I be an interval in R. Then its 1-content is defined as c 1 (I) := b a if I is bounded with endpoints a, b. If I is unbounded, we define c 1

More information

REVIEW OF ESSENTIAL MATH 346 TOPICS

REVIEW OF ESSENTIAL MATH 346 TOPICS REVIEW OF ESSENTIAL MATH 346 TOPICS 1. AXIOMATIC STRUCTURE OF R Doğan Çömez The real number system is a complete ordered field, i.e., it is a set R which is endowed with addition and multiplication operations

More information

Some Properties of the Augmented Lagrangian in Cone Constrained Optimization

Some Properties of the Augmented Lagrangian in Cone Constrained Optimization MATHEMATICS OF OPERATIONS RESEARCH Vol. 29, No. 3, August 2004, pp. 479 491 issn 0364-765X eissn 1526-5471 04 2903 0479 informs doi 10.1287/moor.1040.0103 2004 INFORMS Some Properties of the Augmented

More information

Continuous Functions on Metric Spaces

Continuous Functions on Metric Spaces Continuous Functions on Metric Spaces Math 201A, Fall 2016 1 Continuous functions Definition 1. Let (X, d X ) and (Y, d Y ) be metric spaces. A function f : X Y is continuous at a X if for every ɛ > 0

More information

STAT Sample Problem: General Asymptotic Results

STAT Sample Problem: General Asymptotic Results STAT331 1-Sample Problem: General Asymptotic Results In this unit we will consider the 1-sample problem and prove the consistency and asymptotic normality of the Nelson-Aalen estimator of the cumulative

More information

BREGMAN DISTANCES, TOTALLY

BREGMAN DISTANCES, TOTALLY BREGMAN DISTANCES, TOTALLY CONVEX FUNCTIONS AND A METHOD FOR SOLVING OPERATOR EQUATIONS IN BANACH SPACES DAN BUTNARIU AND ELENA RESMERITA January 18, 2005 Abstract The aim of this paper is twofold. First,

More information

Optimal stopping for non-linear expectations Part I

Optimal stopping for non-linear expectations Part I Stochastic Processes and their Applications 121 (2011) 185 211 www.elsevier.com/locate/spa Optimal stopping for non-linear expectations Part I Erhan Bayraktar, Song Yao Department of Mathematics, University

More information

Chapter 1. Preliminaries. The purpose of this chapter is to provide some basic background information. Linear Space. Hilbert Space.

Chapter 1. Preliminaries. The purpose of this chapter is to provide some basic background information. Linear Space. Hilbert Space. Chapter 1 Preliminaries The purpose of this chapter is to provide some basic background information. Linear Space Hilbert Space Basic Principles 1 2 Preliminaries Linear Space The notion of linear space

More information

Stochastic Programming: Basic Theory

Stochastic Programming: Basic Theory Stochastic Programming: Basic Theory John R. Birge John.Birge@ChicagoBooth.edu www.chicagobooth.edu/fac/john.birge JRBirge ICSP, Bergamo, July 2013 1 Goals Provide background on the basics of stochastic

More information

Probability. Lecture Notes. Adolfo J. Rumbos

Probability. Lecture Notes. Adolfo J. Rumbos Probability Lecture Notes Adolfo J. Rumbos October 20, 204 2 Contents Introduction 5. An example from statistical inference................ 5 2 Probability Spaces 9 2. Sample Spaces and σ fields.....................

More information

Stability-based generation of scenario trees for multistage stochastic programs

Stability-based generation of scenario trees for multistage stochastic programs Stability-based generation of scenario trees for multistage stochastic programs H. Heitsch and W. Römisch Humboldt-University Berlin Institute of Mathematics 10099 Berlin, Germany http://www.math.hu-berlin.de/~romisch

More information

Chapter 2 Convex Analysis

Chapter 2 Convex Analysis Chapter 2 Convex Analysis The theory of nonsmooth analysis is based on convex analysis. Thus, we start this chapter by giving basic concepts and results of convexity (for further readings see also [202,

More information

Stability of Stochastic Programming Problems

Stability of Stochastic Programming Problems Stability of Stochastic Programming Problems W. Römisch Humboldt-University Berlin Institute of Mathematics 10099 Berlin, Germany http://www.math.hu-berlin.de/~romisch Page 1 of 35 Spring School Stochastic

More information