CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS AS BANACH-LATTICE VALUED MAPPINGS

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS AS BANACH-LATTICE VALUED MAPPINGS"

Transcription

1 CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS AS BANACH-LATTICE VALUED MAPPINGS RAIMUND KOVACEVIC Department of Statistics and Decision Support Systems, University of Vienna, Vienna, Austria Abstract. Conditional acceptability mappings quantify the desirability of random variables e.g. modeling nancial returns by accounting for available non-trivial information. They are dened as mappings from spaces L p Ω, F, µ to spaces L p Ω, F 1, µ, where the σ algebras F 1 F describe the available information. Moreover, such mappings have to be concave, translationequivariant and monotonically increasing. Based on the order completeness of L p Ω, F, µ-spaces, we will dene and analyze superdierentials and concave conjugates for conditional acceptability mappings. In contrast to most of the existing literature, special emphasis is placed on applicability to arbitrary Banach lattices L p Ω, F, µ and L p Ω, F 1, µ with 1 p p. In particular, it will be possible to consider mappings with p < in a straightforward manner. Furthermore, the above results are used to show properties of such multiperiod acceptability functionals that are based on conditional acceptability mappings, in particular, SEC-functionals and additive acceptability compositions. Finally, a chain rule for superdierentials is derived and used to characterize the conjugates of additive acceptability compositions and SECfunctional. 1. Introduction A probability functional is an extended real valued function dened on a set of random variables, which are dened on some probability space Ω, F, P. If a functional is interpreted in the sense of higher values being preferable to lower values we call it a monotonic or acceptability-type [7] functional. Such functionals can be used to judge the desirability of random nancial payments. Acceptability functionals are monotonic functionals with additional properties: Denition 1.1. A probability functional A : L p Ω, F, P R = R is called an acceptability functional, if the following properties hold for all random variables X, Y L p Ω, F, P: A1 Monotonicity. X Y AX AY. A2 Translation Equivariance. AX + c = AX + c for all constants c. A3 Concavity. A λ X + 1 λ Y λ A X + 1 λ A Y for all λ [0, 1]. The domain of a probability functional A is dened as the set dom A = X L p Ω, F, P : AY >. Funded by FWF. 1

2 CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS 2 We allow p [1, ], but point out that p = might be a very optimistic assumption, particularly in some areas of empirical nance. From the Fenchel-Moreau-Rockafellar Theorem [9], Theorem 5, it follows that concave upper semicontinuous functionals can be represented as 1.1 A X = inf L qω,f,µ E X A +, where 1 p + 1 q = 1 and A+ = inf X LpΩ,F,µ E X A X is the concave or Fenchel-Moreau conjugate of the functional A. This representation is called supergradient representation and is very useful for analyzing properties of concave functionals. A simple but useful example is the average value at risk also called tail value at risk, conditional value at risk or expected shortfall. For a random variable X with distribution function G, it is dened as 1.2 α X = 1 G 1 x dx. α 0 This functional is a positive homogeneous acceptability functional and it is well known that its conjugate representation is given by ˆ α 1.3 α X = min E X : E = 1, 0 1 α. 2. Conditional Acceptability Mappings A natural generalization of acceptability functionals are conditional acceptability mappings. Such mappings valuate the acceptability of a random variable relative to additional nontrivial information. A typical example would be the valuation of a random variable at a future point in time: More information will be available, currently it is unknown which state of the system will actually be reached. Literature agrees on how to dene such mappings. However, there are dierent views about how to analyze them, and particularly their conjugate mappings. An important part of literature concentrates, based on the notion of coherent risk measures, on mappings from L -spaces into L -spaces with the additional requirement of positive homogeneity e.g. [2]. Detlefsen in [3] drops the assumption of positive homogeneity but retains the usage of bounded random variables. Pug and Römisch in [7] drop both assumptions but use an indirect denition of conjugate mappings. In the present work, which is a short version of [4], we want to give a general theory of conditional acceptability mappings as possibly nonhomogeneous mappings between L p -spaces for p 1. We regard such mappings as Banach lattice valued mappings, based on the adequate partial order a.s. and use this concept to dene and analyze supergradients and concave conjugate mappings in a straightforward way. Compared with [3] our approach will be more general, while compared with [7] it will be more straightforward and explicit, in particular regarding the used L p -spaces Basic Denitions. Again we consider random variables X L p Ω, F 1, P that can be interpreted as uncertain nancial payments at the end of a time period. For technical reasons we augment any used L p -space with the value. Denition 2.1. For any space L p Ω, F, P, the related extended space is given by L p Ω, F, P = L p Ω, F, P.

3 CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS 3 Remark. The set represents the functions with a.s. constant value. Denition 2.2. Conditional probability mappings are mappings A F 1 : L p Ω, F, P L p Ω, F 1, P with F 1 F and 1 p p. In addition we assume A F 1 =. In the rst instance, we are interested in monotonic mappings, particularly in the conditional counterparts of acceptability functionals. Denition 2.3. A conditional monotonic mapping is a conditional probability mapping such that CA1 Monotonicity. X Y a.s. AX F 1 AY F 1 a.s. holds for all random variables X, Y L p Ω, F, P. A conditional acceptability mapping is a conditional monotonic mapping that fullls the following additional assumptions for all X, Y L p Ω, F, P. CA2 Predictable Translation Equivariance. AX +X 1 F 1 = AX F 1 +X 1 holds a.s. for every X 1 L p Ω, F 1, P. CA3 Concavity. A λ X + 1 λ Y F 1 λ A X F λ A Y F 1 holds a.s. for λ [0, 1]. Sometimes we will shortly write A 1 := A F 1. In this setup, the σ algebra F can be interpreted as the information available at the end of a future time period and F 1 as the information available at its beginning. If F 1 is the trivial σ algebra, Ω, conditional mappings are reduced to unconditional probability functionals. Denition 2.4. The domain of a conditional acceptability mapping A is given by dom A = X L p Ω, F, P : AX F 1. This means that AY F 1 is either in L p Ω, F 1, P or it is a.s. Implicitly, we restrict our analysis to proper mappings, because our denition of extended spaces does not include the value +. Complementary to the conditions CA1-CA3 and dependent on the application, further properties can be required: A conditional mapping A is called positively homogeneous if A λ X F 1 = λ A X F 1 for any positive λ and X L p Ω, F, P. It is called centered at zero if A 0 F 1 = Conjugate Representations of Acceptability Mappings. Generalizing the denition of conditional expectation, Pug and Römisch use a trick from probability theory and derive a representation theorem for conditional acceptability mappings Theorem in [7]: For any u.s.c. conditional acceptability mapping A Y F 1 and for every Y L p Ω, F, µ and B F 1, the conjugate functional of the restricted expectation E A Y F 1 1 B can be written as E A Y F 1 1 B = inf E Y A B : 0, E F 1 = 1 B, L qω,f,µ where A B = inf E Y E A Y F 1 1 B. Y L pω,f,µ This meets the concerns for measurability and allows to use the full duality theory for real valued functionals. However, such a representation is an implicit one, which sometimes makes the reasoning more complicated.

4 CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS 4 If we want to dene concave conjugates for conditional acceptability mappings directly in the style of equation 1.1, we have to consider the fact that the values of such mappings are random variables. Three basic questions have to be answered: 1 What kind of partial order should be used to dene supergradients and conjugates? 2 Is the inmum with respect to this order suciently compatible with the L p -spaces and their norms? In particular: Is the resulting lattice order complete? 3 What type of continuous linear mappings should be used to generalize the expectation E X in equation 1.1? The rst question has already been answered implicitly in the preceding subsection: Every inequality is understood in the almost sure sense. The inmum of a set of random variables with respect to this ordering can be dened in straightforward manner: Denition 2.5. Let V = L p Ω, F, P be a random space and a.s. the almost sure order. A random variable X 0 V is the inmum of a nonempty subset A V, if a X 0 is a lower bound of the set A, i.e. Y X 0 a.s. for any Y A b Y for all Y A implies X 0 a.s. If V = L p Ω, F, P, then X 0 must hold in addition. We denote the inmum of a set A L p Ω, F, P by inf A. It will be clear from the context, whether the notation inf means the inmum of a set of real numbers or the inmum of a set of random variables. As pointed out before, the almost sure order is only a partial order. Therefore, the question arises, whether the inmum in this case is a reasonable concept. At least, order completeness has to be required. Fortunately this request is fullled for L p Ω, F, P-spaces. Recall that Riesz spaces vector lattices are ordered vector spaces V, that are also lattices, which means that any pair of elements v V has an inmum supremum in V. Furthermore, a subset A V is called order bounded from below if there is a vector v V that is dominated by each element of A. Denition 2.6. A Riesz space V is order complete Dedekind complete if every nonempty subset A V that is order bounded from below has an inmum. If the space V is dened as an extended space V = V of a Riesz space V with v for any v V, we call the extended space V order complete, if V is order complete. It is a well known fact that L p Ω, F, P-spaces are Riesz spaces for 0 p. Moreover, if 1 p they are Banach lattices in addition e.g. [1], Theorem 13.5, because they possess lattice norms and are Cauchy-complete. Finally, because p-norms are order continuous norms for 1 p <, it can be shown [1], Theorem 13.7 that L p Ω, F, P-spaces are order complete Banach Lattices for 1 p. We will not go into these details here, but refer to the Appendix, where an alternative proof for the order completeness of L p Ω, F, P-spaces with 1 p is presented. Regarding the third question above, it obviously would be natural to use some kind of conditional expectation E X F 1. Such mappings with X L p Ω, F, P

5 CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS 5 and L q Ω, F, P with 1 p + 1 q = 1 clearly are linear and continuous as mappings into L 1 Ω, F 1, P. However, if we want to cover mappings into L p Ω, F, P with 1 < p p we have to restrict the set of feasible. Proposition 2.7. For 1 p <, 1 p p the conditional expectations X E X F 1 with arguments X L p Ω, F, P and dual variable L s Ω, F, P L q Ω, F, P are linear, continuous and map into L p Ω, F, P, if s p p p p. For mappings L p Ω, F, P L p Ω, F, P with p = the conditional expectations above have these properties, if L p Ω, F, P. Proof. It is clear that the conditional expectation X E X F 1 is linear. Moreover, are dual variables such that X E X F 1 maps into L p Ω, F, P, if L q Ω, F, P Y : X Y L p Ω, F 1, P, X L p Ω, F 1, P. This means that X must be p -integrable. For s = p p p p, which is equivalent to 1 p + 1 s = 1 p, the generalized Hölder inequality 2.1 X p X p s can be used. As X is p-integrable by assumption, this means that X will be p integrable if is s-integrable. To ensure continuity as a mapping into L p Ω, F, P, assume now that X n converges to X in the p-norm, which means that X n X p 0, as n. Because is a convex function we can apply Jensen's inequality and get 2.2 E X n X F p X n X p From this using again the generalized Hölder inequality 2.1 we can conclude E X n X F p X n X p s. If is s-integrable and X n converges to X in the p-norm, it follows that E X n F converges to E X F. Example. For mappings L p Ω, F, P L 1 Ω, F 1, P the variables can be from the natural dual space L q Ω, F, P because q = s holds in this cases. Until now the main focus in literature was on mappings L p Ω, F, P L p Ω, F 1, P, in particular p =. From Proposition 2.7 we see that the dual variables must be from L Ω, F, P in this case. This is a strong restriction and coincides with the natural dual only for the case p = 1. With this preparations, we dene superdierentials and conjugates. We use the principles of convex analysis for partially ordered vector spaces, essentially following the approach of Papageorgiou in [6]. Denition 2.8. The topological superdierential of a proper concave conditional mapping A F 1 : L p Ω, F, P L p Ω, F 1, P at X 0 L p Ω, F, P is given by the set A X 0 F 1 = = L s Ω, F, P : A X F 1 A X 0 F 1 + E X X 0 F 1, X doma, where 1 p + 1 s = 1 p. The elements of superdierentials are called supergradients.

6 CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS 6 The superdierential will be nonempty for a broad range of concave mappings, at least in the interior of their domains. Proposition 2.9. If a concave mapping A F 1 : L p Ω, F, P L p Ω, F 1, P is continuous at some point X 0 doma then A X F 1 for all X int doma. Proof. L p -spaces are metric spaces hence they are normal spaces. Using this fact as a premise we can apply Lemma 3.2 from [6]. Proposition A conditional acceptability mapping A : L p Ω, F, P L p Ω, F 1, P is continuous if it is locally bounded at some element X 0 L p Ω, F, P. Proof. See [5], Theorem 4. Next, we dene concave conjugates for conditional mappings. Based on our considerations about the inmum, this can be done in a straightforward manner. Denition The concave conjugate of a mapping is given by a mapping with 1 p + 1 s = 1 p : A + F 1 = A F 1 : L p Ω, F, P L p Ω, F 1, P A + : L s Ω, F, P L p Ω, F 1, P inf E X F 1 A X F 1. X L pω,f,p The concave biconjugate is a mapping, A ++ : L p Ω, F, P L p Ω, F 1, P dened by A ++ X F 1 = inf L sω,f,p E X F1 A + F 1. Like in the case of unconditional functionals, it is possible to characterize mappings that are equal to their own biconjugate. The following proposition is based on the existence of supergradients. Denition A conditional mapping A F 1 with closed domain is called upper semicontinuous u.s.c. at X 0, if and only if for every ε > 0 a.s. there exists a neighborhood U of X 0 such that A X F 1 A X 0 F 1 + ε a.s. for all X U, or if A X 0 F 1 = +. A mapping A F 1 is called lower semicontinuous l.s.c. at a point X 0 if A F 1 is u.s.c. at the point X 0. Remark. If a mapping A F 1 is nite, l.s.c. and u.s.c. at a point X 0 then it is continuous at this point [6], Theorem Proposition Let A F 1 be a proper, concave mapping. Then for all X L p Ω, F, P, L s Ω, F, P with 1 p + 1 s = 1 p the inequality 2.3 A X F 1 E X F 1 A + F 1, holds a.s..

7 CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS 7 Moreover, if A X 0 F 1 then the equation 2.4 A X 0 F 1 = A ++ X 0 F 1 holds a.s., and A F 1 is u.s.c. at X 0. In this case the inmum inf E X F 1 A + F 1 : doma + is attained and 2.5 A X F 1 = E X F 1 A + F 1 a.s. A X F 1. If in addition A is continuous at some point inside doma, equation 2.4 holds for each point in int doma. Proof. The inequality follows directly from the denition of the conjugate: A + F 1 := inf E X F 1 A X F 1 it follows that X A + F 1 E X F 1 A X F 1 a.s. or A X F 1 E X F 1 A + F 1. The second assertion follows from Theorem 5.8 in [6]. The a.s. equation A X F 1 = E X F 1 A + F 1 holds if and only if A X F 1 + E Y F 1 A Y F 1 E X F 1 holds a.s. for any Y L p Ω, F, P. a First assume A X F 1 = E X F 1 A + F 1 a.s.. Using the denition of the conjugate mapping we have A X F 1 + E Y F 1 A Y F 1 A X F 1 + inf E Y F 1 A Y F 1 Using the above assumption we get for any Y. = A X F 1 + A + F 1. A X F 1 + E Y F 1 A Y F 1 E X F 1 b For the other direction assume A X F 1 + E Y F 1 A Y F 1 E X F 1 a.s.. Remember that this inequality should hold for all Y - which means that E Y F 1 A Y F 1 has a lower bound. Then the inmum exists and it follows that or A X F 1 + inf E Y F 1 A Y F 1 E X F 1 A X F 1 + A + F 1 E X F 1 Together with inequality 2.3 the equation A X F 1 + A + F 1 = E X F 1 can be concluded. Moreover, holds, if and only if A X F 1 + E Y F 1 A Y F 1 E X F 1 A Y F 1 A X F 1 + E Y X F 1, which means A X F 1, is true. Together with inequality 2.3, the last inequality yields equation 2.5. The statement about continuity follows from Proposition 2.9. As

8 CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS 8 For conditional acceptability functionals we can give an even sharper characterization: Proposition Assume that the conditions of Proposition 2.9 or Proposition 2.10 are fullled. Then a concave conditional mapping A F 1 : L p Ω, F, P L p Ω, F 1, P is an acceptability mapping if and only if a dual representation A X F 1 = inf L sω,f,p E X F1 A + F 1 : 0; E F 1 = 1 a.s., holds for each point in int doma. The set represents additional constraints on, restricting e.g. the conjugate A + to be nite. Proof. By Proposition 2.13 and because A is concave and continuous at some point in doma for each point in int doma we have : A X F 1 = inf E X F1 A + F 1 = E X F 1 A + F 1 where is a supergradient. If E F 1 = 1 a.s. and F 1 -measurable X 1, it is possible to infer A X + X 1 F 1 = E X + X 1 F 1 A + F 1 = E X F 1 + E X 1 F 1 A + F 1 = E X F 1 + X 1 E F 1 A + F 1 = E X F 1 + X 1 A + F 1 = A X F 1 + X 1. On the other hand let E F 1 1 on a set S with positive probability. Then we can conclude A X F 1 + X 1 = E X F 1 + X 1 A + F 1 E X F 1 + X 1 E F 1 A + F 1 = A X + X 1 F 1 on this set. This would contradict the assumption of predictable translation equivariance. Assume now that 0 holds a.s. and let Y 0 a.s.. Then, for any random variable X we have X + Y X. Because Y and both are nonnegative it follows that E Y F 1 0. Using Proposition 2.13, we infer A X + Y F 1 = E X + Y F 1 A + F 1 = E X F 1 + E Y F 1 A + F 1 E X F 1 A + F 1 inf E X F1 A + F 1 = A X F 1.

9 CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS 9 For the other direction assume now that < 0 on a set S with positive probability, or E Y F 1 < 0 on this set. Then we have A X F 1 = E X F 1 A + F 1 > E X F 1 + E Y F 1 A + F 1 inf E X F1 + E Y F 1 A + F 1 = A X + Y F 1 on the set S. But this would mean that the mapping can not be monotonic. Using the structural anity between conjugate representations for unconditional functionals and conditional mappings, Proposition 2.14 can be used to dene acceptability mappings. If any occurrence of an expectation in the conjugate representation of an acceptability functional is replaced by the appropriate conditional expectation, the result will be a conditional acceptability mapping. Based on equation 1.3, we dene the conditional Average Value at Risk as an example: Denition The conditional average value at risk AV@R is dened as a mapping α F 1 : L p Ω, F, P L p Ω, F 1, P by a generalized LP: α X F 1 = inf E X F 1 : 0 1 α a.s., E F 1 = 1 a.s. The dual variables in this denition are bounded almost surely and therefore, they are in L Ω, F, P. This means that the conditional α is able to map a space L p Ω, F 1, P into itself. Corollary The α is a continuous mapping and its superdierential is a nonempty set for any X L p Ω, F, P. Proof. Because of Proposition 2.7 the α is continuous. Then from Proposition 2.9 nonemptyness of the superdierential follows. 3. Application to Multi-period Functionals For multi-period valuation we consider the following general setup: Time t = 0,..., T is discrete. We restrict ourselves to a nite time horizon T <. F = F 0,..., F T is a ltration with F T = F. Consider now a stochastic process X t t 1,...,T, representing random nancial payos at points in time 1,..., T. Multi-period functionals evaluate the acceptability of such a process in terms of a real number, related to the actual period of decision. Such multi-period functionals can be described as mappings A ; F from product spaces T L pt Ω, F t, P, which are Banach lattices together with T the norm X = E X t pt 1 p t, 1 pt, into the extended real line R. Denition 3.1. We will call a multi-period functional A X; F a multi-period acceptability functional, if it is proper and satises Ω,, F 1 1,..., F 1 T, MA0 Information Monotonicity: If F 1 = F 2 = Ω,, F 2 1,..., F 2 T are ltrations such that F 1 t F 2 t for

10 CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS 10 MA1 all t, then A X; F 1 A X; F 2 for any X dom A T L p Ω, F t, P. Translation Equivariance: For all periods t the equation A X 1,..., X t + c,..., X T ; F = A X 1,..., X t,..., X T ; F + c holds, if c is a real number. MA2 Concavity: The mapping X A X; F is concave. MA3 Monotonicity: X t Y t a.s.for all t implies A X; F A Y ; F Remark. This Denition goes back to [7], where a stronger version of MA1 was used. For concave multi-period functionals A X; F it is possible to dene the concave conjugate A + ; F = inf X, A X; F : X T L p Ω, F t, P. If A X; F is in addition proper and upper semicontinuous, then the Fenchel- Moreau-Rockafellar Theorem [9], Theorem 5 ensures that the functional equals its biconjugate: A X; F = A ++ X; F. The supergradient representation of multi-period acceptability functionals is well known: Proposition 3.2. Let A ; F be an upper semicontinuous multi-period functional satisfying MA1, MA2 and MA3. Then the representation T 3.1 A X; F = inf E X t t A + ; F : t 0; E t = 1 holds for every X T L p Ω, F t, P. Conversely, if A ; F can be represented by a dual representation 3.1 and the conjugate A is proper, then A is proper, upper semicontinuous and satises MA1,MA2 and MA3. Proof. See Theorem 3.21 in [7]. Obviously, there are many ways for constructing multi-period functionals. For example, Pug and Römisch [7] analyze separable functionals, risk functionals of the value-of-information type, compositions of conditional acceptability mappings and polyhedral multi-period acceptability functionals. In the following, we will apply the above results to two special types of multiperiod functionals that can be constructed from conditional mappings, namely additive compositions of acceptability mappings and SEC-functionals Additive Acceptability Compositions. Again we consider stochastic processes X t t 1,...,T, adapted to a ltration F = F 0,..., F T and representing nancial cash ows. It is assumed that F 0 = Ω, is the trivial σ-algebra, hence a mapping A 0 F 0 can be used to represent an unconditional functional. In order to shorten notation we will frequently use the abbreviation A t = A t F t in the following. Conditional expectations will be abbreviated by E F t = E t.

11 CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS 11 Additive compositions will recursively apply conditional acceptability mappings to the values X t. Up to now, conditional probability mappings have been dened as mappings L p Ω, F, P L p Ω, F 1, P. If we want to compose such mappings we have to slightly modify this denition, taking care of the possibility of innite valued arguments: We will understand conditional probability mappings as mappings L p Ω, F, P L p Ω, F 1, P. In addition we have to make sure that the conditional mappings map into the correct spaces. Denition 3.3. Let p be a sequence of real numbers p = p 0 p 1... p T, with 1 p t. We will call a sequence of mappings A t t 0,...,T 1 p integrability adapted if A t 1 maps from L pt Ω, F t, P into L pt 1 Ω, F t 1, P for all t 1,..., T 1. With these agreements it is possible to dene additive monotonic compositions in the following way. Denition 3.4. Let X t t 1,...,T be a stochastic process with X t L pt Ω, F t, P and let A t F t, t = 1,..., T be an integrability adapted sequence of conditional monotonic mappings. An additive monotonic composition is a multi-period probability functional B F which for any X T j=t L pj Ω, F j, P is constructed in the following way: for T 1 and B T 1 X T F T 1 = A T 1 X T F T 1 B t 1 X t F t 1 = A t 1 X t + B t X t+1 F t F t 1 for t < T 1. Then the multiperiod functional B F is given by BX F = B 0 X F. The intermediate mappings B t F T 1 are called nested conditional acceptability mappings. If all of the mappings A t F t are conditional acceptability mappings we call the composition an additive acceptability composition. Remark. For additive acceptability compositions we have B t X t+1 ; F = A t A t+1 A T 1 T k=t+1 X k. Based on the convexity and monotonicity of the constituent conditional mappings it is possible to state a chain rule for additive acceptability mappings. Proposition 3.5. Let A t t 1,...,T 1 be a collection of integrability adapted conditional acceptability functionals with T 2. Given supergradients T A T 1 X T and k A k 1 X k + B X k+1,..., X T

12 CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS 12 for k t 0 + 1,..., T, a supergradient for the nested conditional acceptability functional B t0 ; [A t0,,..., A T 1 ]; F at the base points X t0+1,..., X T is given by a T t-tupel M = M t0+1,..., M T with and M t0+1 t0+1 M k+1 = M k k+1 for t 0 < k T 1. In the case of t 0 = 0, a supergradient for the additive acceptability composition BX F is given by the recursion and M 1 1 for 0 < k T 1. M k+1 = M k k+1 Proof. We use backward induction to prove the result: For t = T 1 the equation CA T 1 X T ; [A T 1 ] = A T 1 X T holds and T is a supergradient. Let the Proposition be true for all t t 0. Then, a supergradient for the nested mapping CA t0 Y t0+1,..., Y T ; [A t0,...,a T 1 ] is given by M t0+1,..., M T. That means: CA t0 X t0+1 + Y t0+1,..., X T + Y T CA t0 X t0+1,..., X T +E t0 Yt0+1 t Et0 YT T T 1... t0+1. Using monotonicity we have for t 0 1: CA t0 1 X t0 + Y t0, X t0+1 + Y t0+1,..., X T + Y T = = A t0 1 X t0 + Y t0 + CA t0 X t0+1 + Y t0+1,..., X T + Y T T k A t0 1 X t0 + CA t0 X t0+1,..., X T + Y t0 + E t0 Y k k=t 0+1 j=t 0+1 j As t0 is a supergradient of A t0 1 at X t0 + CA t0 X t0+1,..., X T it follows that CA t0 1 X t0 + Y t0, X t0+1 + Y t0+1,..., X T + Y T A t0 1 X t0 + CA t0 X t0+1,..., X T + [ + E t0 1 t0 Y t0 + E t0 Yt0+1 t Et0 Y T T t=t 0+1 t ] = = CA t0 1 X t0, X t0+1,..., X T +E t9 1 Yt0 t0 +Et0 1 Yt0+1 t0+1 t E t0 1 YT T T 1... t0+1 t0 The mappings A t F t are integrability adapted and the t are supergradients, hence the conditional expectations E X t t F t 1 are also pt 1 -integrable by Proposition 2.7. This means that all the conditional expectations involved in each nesting-step are p t -integrable. Because we made no restriction on T it is shown that M = M t0,..., M T as dened above is a supergradient for CA t for any t T.

13 CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS 13 It should be noted that supergradients of additive acceptability compositions form a martingale: Corollary 3.6. Let A t t 1,...,T be a collection of u.s.c. integrability adapted conditional acceptability mappings. Then the process M t t t0+1,...,t of the supergradients dened in Proposition 3.5 is a martingale. Proof. From Proposition 2.14 we know that E t F t 1 = 1 holds because of predictable translation equivariance. Moreover, as the process M t is adapted to F t, the random variable M t 1 is F t 1 -measurable. Therefore holds. E M t F t 1 = E M t 1 t F t 1 = Wt 1 E t F t 1 = Mt 1 So far we have characterized the supergradients of additive acceptability compositions. Using this martingale representation and Proposition 2.14 it is also possible to calculate the dual representation of compositions by using the concave conjugates of the constituent conditional mappings. Proposition 3.7. Let CA 0 be an additive acceptability composition constructed by a sequence A t t=0,...,t of conditional acceptability mappings with concave conjugates A t X F t = Et X t+1 t A + t t+1 : t+1 0; E t t+1 = 1, t t. inf t+1 L st Ω,F,P Under the assumptions of Theorem 3.5 the acceptability composition CA 0 can be represented by 3.2 CA 0 X 1, X 2,..., X T = T with inf 1,..., T T E X t M t A E A + t t+1 M t : = t : M 1 = 1 ; M t+1 = M t t; ; t 0; E t F t 1 = 1, t t. Proof. Theorem 2.14 can be used to replace the conditional mappings A t by their concave conjugates in a recursive manner. In this way the assertion can be proved by backward induction. Here is one step: First note that 3.3 A t 1 Y t = inf t Et 1 Y t t A + t 1 t : t 0; E t 1 t = 1 holds by Theorem Using 2.2 we get for a two period additive acceptability compositions: A T 2 X T 1 + A T 1 X T = inf E T 2 [X T 1 + A T 1 X T ] T 1 A + T 2 T 1 T 1 [ = inf E ] T 2 X T 1 + inf E T 1 X T T A + T 1 T 1 T T 1 A + T 2 T 1 T = inf T 1 E T 2 X T 1 T 1 + E T 2 inf E T 1 X T T A + T 1 T T 1 A + T 2 T 1 T

14 CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS 14 Let now T be a supergradient of A T 1 X T. Then this supergradient must also be minimizer of E T 1 X T T F T 1 A + T 1 T by Theorem Because of [ monotonicity all the t are nonnegative and hence T is also a minimizer of ET 1 X T T A + T 1 T ] T 1. Therefore we can interchange inmum and conditional expectation. This is possible because the inmum in the conjugate representation mapping must be attained if the superdierential is not empty - which is the case, since - by assumption - we know the supergradients. A T 2 X T 1 + A T 1 X T = ] = inf E T 2 X T 1 T 1 + inf E T 2 [E T 1 X T T A + T 1 T 1 T T ] = inf E T 2 X T 1 T 1 + E T 2 [E T 1 X T T A + T 1, T 1 T T T 1 A + T 2 T 1 T 1 A + T 2 T 1 = inf E T 2 X T 1 T 1 + E T 2 X T T T 1 E T 2 A + T 1, T 1 T T 1 A + T 2 T 1 T All the inma must be understood with respect to the constraints T 0 E T F 1 = 1 and T 1 0 E T 1 F 1 = 1. Iterating this step and dening the variable M t as M 1 = 1 and M t+1 = M t t+1 we get the statement of the theorem. In the light of Proposition 3.5 and Corollary 3.6 the M t are martingales and constitute a supergradient of the composition. So the equation CA 0 X 1, X 2,..., X T = T inf 1,..., T E X t M t A T 1 E A + t t+1 M t : basically gives the conjugate representation of the composition and the mapping A T E A + t t+1 M t is the related conjugate mapping CA + 0. It is possible to restate Proposition 3.7 in a way, such that only the supergradients M t are used: Corollary 3.8. Under the assumptions of Proposition 3.5, and with ψm t, M t+1 = sup E A + t t+1 M t : Mt+1 = M t t+1, t+1 t, the supergradient representation of an acceptability composition is given t+1 by CA 0 X 1, X 2,..., X T = T inf M 1,M 2,...,M T E X t M t A + 0 M 1 T 1 ψm t, M t+1 : M t M with M = M t M t 0; E M t F t 1 = M t 1. Based on the results on supergradients and concave conjugates of additive acceptability compositions, we can outline the properties of such mappings in the following way:,

15 CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS 15 Proposition 3.9. An acceptability composition is a proper, u.s.c. concave MA2, monotonic MA3 multi-period probability functional that is also translation equivariant MA1. Proof. Properness and upper semicontinuity follows from 3.2. As a composition of monotonic concave mappings the multiperiod functional must be concave itself. It is also monotonic because of M t 0 a.s. for all t. From M 0 = 1 and E M t F t 1 = M t 1 we can infer the equation E M t = 1, which, by Proposition 3.2, is the criterion for weak translation equivariance. Proof. An alternative proof for MA1', MA2 and MA3, which is independent of the dual representation 3.2 is given in [7], Theorem Example Based on Proposition 3.8 the nested average value at risk - constructed by composing conditional α s for the later periods with an unconditional α for the rst period - has the following representation: α X; F = T E X t M t : 0 M t 1 α M t 1, E M t F t 1 = M t 1, M 0 = 1 inf M 1,M 2,...,M T 4. Separable Expected Conditional Functionals Another approach for dening multi-period functionals consists in applying singleperiod functionals to the random variables X t of the process and summing up the results: T A X; F = A [t] X t Such multi-period functionals are called separable functionals. If the constituent single-period functionals are concave, the resulting separable functional will be also concave MA2. In addition, separable functionals are weakly translationequivariant MA1' and monotonic MA3 if this is also true for all their constituents. Unfortunately, it is not automatically guaranteed that separable functionals are information monotonic for arbitrary single period acceptability functionals. That means that generally such multi-period functionals are not acceptability functionals without additional measures to assure this property. For example, sums of expectations or sums of as well as sums of other typical single-period functionals are not information monotonic. Nevertheless, there is an approach for dening separable functionals that account for information in the right way: it is characterized by taking sums of expectations of conditional acceptability mappings. Such functionals are called separable expected conditional SEC, [7], p 145. Denition 4.1. SEC-functional A multi-period acceptability functional is called separable expected conditional SEC if it is of the form T A X; F = E A [t] X t F t 1,

16 CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS 16 where the A [t] F t 1 are conditional u.s.c. acceptability mappings. The most important and best known SEC-functional is the multi-period average T value at risk [8] E α X t F t 1. SEC-functionals are separable functionals and hence they fulll MA1', MA2 and MA3. It is well known that SEC-functionals based on conditional versions of distortion functionals AX = 0,1] αx dmα are information monotonic [7], Proposition 3.9. A multi-period functional A is separable if and only if its dual is separable, and it is SEC if and only if its dual is SEC Proposition 3.27 in [7]. That means that the concave conjugate of any SEC-functional can be represented in the form T A ; F = E A [t] t F t 1. Building on the chain-rule given in Proposition 3.5, we can characterize the supergradients of SEC-functionals: Proposition 4.2. Let A X; F = T E A [t] X t F t 1 be a SEC-functional and = 1,..., T a vector of supergradients of the constituent conditional acceptability mappings A [t]. Then is also a supergradient of the SEC-functional. Proof. Each summand E A [t] X t F t 1 can be interpreted as an acceptability composition, with no action between the beginning and period t. The conjugate of the expectation equals zero at one and is unbounded elsewhere. Therefore, the supergradient of the expectation must be one almost sure. Supergradients for the conditional acceptability mappings A [t] are given by t. Applying Proposition 3.5, we see that for each t the product t 1 = t must be a supergradient of the associated acceptability composition E A [t] X t F t 1, which means that E A [t] X t + Y t F t 1 E A [t] X t F t 1 + E Y t t. or Summing over all t we get T T E A [t] X t + Y t F t 1 E A [t] X t F t 1 + A X + Y ; F A X; F + T E Y t t. T E Y t t, This shows that is a supergradient for the whole SEC-functional. Appendix Proposition. Let S = X ϑ : ϑ Θ be an arbitrary set of nonnegative functions from L p Ω, F, P with p 1. Then this set has an almost sure inmum X L p Ω, F, P.

17 CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS 17 Proof. Let A be the directed set of nite subsets of Θ and dene a decreasing net X α α A with the following elements: 4.1 X α = inf X ϑ1,..., X ϑk, for α = ϑ 1,..., ϑ k. Furthermore, dene s α = X α dp for each X α and observe that s α must be bounded below, because X α is bounded below. This means that s = inf s α must exist. Select now a sequence α n n N with α n α n+1 such that s αn s. By 4.1, this sequence of sets induces a decreasing sequence X αn n N of random variables in S. Moreover, the set S was assumed to be bounded below by zero and to contain integrable random variables. Hence, because of X αn 0 X αn dp we can use monotoneˆconvergence to conclude that there exists an X L 1 Ω, F, P with X αn C and X dp = lim n Xαn dp = s. X is the inmum of X αn n N and must also be a lower bound for A, hence also for S: Assume that some X α is not dominated by X. Because of the ordered structure of X αn n N A this means that X α X a.s. and X α ω Xω must hold on some set with positive probability. But this would imply X α dp < X dp = s, which contradicts the fact that s = inf Xα dp. On the other hand X must be the largest lower bound: If any Y exists with Y X a.s. and Y ω > Xω on some set with positive probability then Y dp > X dp = s follows, which means that Y can not be a lower bound of A. We can also conclude that X L p Ω, F, P, because S contains only p-integrable functions X ϑ, which means that 0 X X ϑ and hence p-integrability of X must hold for any ϑ Θ. References [1] C. D. Aliprantis and K. C. Border. Innite Dimensional Analysis - A Hitchhiker's Guide. Springer, 3d edition, [2] P. Artzner, F. Delbaen, D. Heath, and H. Ku. Coherent multiperiod risk adjusted values and bellman's principle. Annals of Operations Research, 1521:522, [3] K. Detlefsen and G. Scandolo. Conditional and dynamic convex risk measures. Finance and Stochastics, 9:539561, [4] R. Kovacevic. Conditional Acceptability mappings: Convex Analysis in Banach Lattices. Dissertation, University of Vienna, [5] K. Nikodem. Continuity properties of convex-type set-valued mappings. Journal of Inequalities in Pure and Applied Mathematics, 43:Article [6] N. S. Papageorgiou. Nonsmooth analysis on partially ordered vector spaces: Part 1 - convex case. Pacic Journal of Mathematics, 1072:403458, [7] G. Pug and W. Römisch. Modeling, Measuring and Managing Risk. World Scientic, August [8] G. Pug and A. Ruszczy«ski. Measuring risk for income streams. Computational Optimization and Applications, 32:161178, [9] R. Rockafellar. Conjugate duality and optimization. In CBMS-NSF Regional Conference Series in Applied Mathematics, volume 16. SIAM, Philadelphia, 1974.

CONDITIONAL RISK AND ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS AS BANACH-LATTICE VALUED MAPPINGS

CONDITIONAL RISK AND ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS AS BANACH-LATTICE VALUED MAPPINGS CONDITIONAL RISK AND ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS AS BANACH-LATTICE VALUED MAPPINGS RAIMUND KOVACEVIC Abstract. Conditional risk and acceptability mappings quantify the desirability of random variables e.g.

More information

On Kusuoka Representation of Law Invariant Risk Measures

On Kusuoka Representation of Law Invariant Risk Measures MATHEMATICS OF OPERATIONS RESEARCH Vol. 38, No. 1, February 213, pp. 142 152 ISSN 364-765X (print) ISSN 1526-5471 (online) http://dx.doi.org/1.1287/moor.112.563 213 INFORMS On Kusuoka Representation of

More information

The Subdifferential of Convex Deviation Measures and Risk Functions

The Subdifferential of Convex Deviation Measures and Risk Functions The Subdifferential of Convex Deviation Measures and Risk Functions Nicole Lorenz Gert Wanka In this paper we give subdifferential formulas of some convex deviation measures using their conjugate functions

More information

Valuation and Pricing of Electricity Delivery Contracts The Producer s View

Valuation and Pricing of Electricity Delivery Contracts The Producer s View SWM ORCOS Valuation and Pricing of Electricity Delivery Contracts The Producer s View Raimund M. Kovacevic Research Report 2015-04 February, 2015 Operations Research and Control Systems Institute of Statistics

More information

Some Properties of the Augmented Lagrangian in Cone Constrained Optimization

Some Properties of the Augmented Lagrangian in Cone Constrained Optimization MATHEMATICS OF OPERATIONS RESEARCH Vol. 29, No. 3, August 2004, pp. 479 491 issn 0364-765X eissn 1526-5471 04 2903 0479 informs doi 10.1287/moor.1040.0103 2004 INFORMS Some Properties of the Augmented

More information

Lectures for the Course on Foundations of Mathematical Finance

Lectures for the Course on Foundations of Mathematical Finance Definitions and properties of Lectures for the Course on Foundations of Mathematical Finance First Part: Convex Marco Frittelli Milano University The Fields Institute, Toronto, April 2010 Definitions and

More information

On duality theory of conic linear problems

On duality theory of conic linear problems On duality theory of conic linear problems Alexander Shapiro School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, Georgia 3332-25, USA e-mail: ashapiro@isye.gatech.edu

More information

Translative Sets and Functions and their Applications to Risk Measure Theory and Nonlinear Separation

Translative Sets and Functions and their Applications to Risk Measure Theory and Nonlinear Separation Translative Sets and Functions and their Applications to Risk Measure Theory and Nonlinear Separation Andreas H. Hamel Abstract Recently defined concepts such as nonlinear separation functionals due to

More information

The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1

The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1 The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1 Damir Filipović Gregor Svindland 3 November 2008 Abstract In this paper we establish a one-to-one correspondence between lawinvariant

More information

Risk-Averse Dynamic Optimization. Andrzej Ruszczyński. Research supported by the NSF award CMMI

Risk-Averse Dynamic Optimization. Andrzej Ruszczyński. Research supported by the NSF award CMMI Research supported by the NSF award CMMI-0965689 Outline 1 Risk-Averse Preferences 2 Coherent Risk Measures 3 Dynamic Risk Measurement 4 Markov Risk Measures 5 Risk-Averse Control Problems 6 Solution Methods

More information

Decomposability and time consistency of risk averse multistage programs

Decomposability and time consistency of risk averse multistage programs Decomposability and time consistency of risk averse multistage programs arxiv:1806.01497v1 [math.oc] 5 Jun 2018 A. Shapiro School of Industrial and Systems Engineering Georgia Institute of Technology Atlanta,

More information

Semicontinuous functions and convexity

Semicontinuous functions and convexity Semicontinuous functions and convexity Jordan Bell jordan.bell@gmail.com Department of Mathematics, University of Toronto April 3, 2014 1 Lattices If (A, ) is a partially ordered set and S is a subset

More information

Functional Analysis. Franck Sueur Metric spaces Definitions Completeness Compactness Separability...

Functional Analysis. Franck Sueur Metric spaces Definitions Completeness Compactness Separability... Functional Analysis Franck Sueur 2018-2019 Contents 1 Metric spaces 1 1.1 Definitions........................................ 1 1.2 Completeness...................................... 3 1.3 Compactness......................................

More information

Integral Jensen inequality

Integral Jensen inequality Integral Jensen inequality Let us consider a convex set R d, and a convex function f : (, + ]. For any x,..., x n and λ,..., λ n with n λ i =, we have () f( n λ ix i ) n λ if(x i ). For a R d, let δ a

More information

Operations Research Letters. On a time consistency concept in risk averse multistage stochastic programming

Operations Research Letters. On a time consistency concept in risk averse multistage stochastic programming Operations Research Letters 37 2009 143 147 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Operations Research Letters journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/orl On a time consistency concept in risk averse

More information

Bounds on Risk-averse Mixed-integer Multi-stage Stochastic Programming Problems with Mean-CVaR

Bounds on Risk-averse Mixed-integer Multi-stage Stochastic Programming Problems with Mean-CVaR Bounds on Risk-averse Mixed-integer Multi-stage Stochastic Programming Problems with Mean-CVaR Ali rfan Mahmuto ullar, Özlem Çavu³, and M. Selim Aktürk Department of Industrial Engineering, Bilkent University,

More information

Multistage stochastic programs: Time-consistency, time-inconsistency and martingale bounds

Multistage stochastic programs: Time-consistency, time-inconsistency and martingale bounds Multistage stochastic programs: Time-consistency, time-inconsistency and martingale bounds Georg Ch. Pflug, joint work with Raimund Kovacevic and Alois Pichler April 2016 The time-consistency problem Many

More information

Journal of Mathematical Economics. Coherent risk measures in general economic models and price bubbles

Journal of Mathematical Economics. Coherent risk measures in general economic models and price bubbles Journal of Mathematical Economics ( ) Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect Journal of Mathematical Economics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jmateco Coherent risk measures in general

More information

Lecture 5. Theorems of Alternatives and Self-Dual Embedding

Lecture 5. Theorems of Alternatives and Self-Dual Embedding IE 8534 1 Lecture 5. Theorems of Alternatives and Self-Dual Embedding IE 8534 2 A system of linear equations may not have a solution. It is well known that either Ax = c has a solution, or A T y = 0, c

More information

Acceptability functionals, risk capital functionals and risk deviation functionals: Primal and dual properties for one-and multiperiod models

Acceptability functionals, risk capital functionals and risk deviation functionals: Primal and dual properties for one-and multiperiod models Acceptability functionals, risk capital functionals and risk deviation functionals: Primal and dual properties for one-and multiperiod models 11.5.2005 Preliminary remark: risk measures risk functionals

More information

Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces

Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces Bernhard Schmitzer October 19, 2017 1 Convex non-smooth optimization with proximal operators Remark 1.1 (Motivation). Convex optimization: easier to solve,

More information

Local strong convexity and local Lipschitz continuity of the gradient of convex functions

Local strong convexity and local Lipschitz continuity of the gradient of convex functions Local strong convexity and local Lipschitz continuity of the gradient of convex functions R. Goebel and R.T. Rockafellar May 23, 2007 Abstract. Given a pair of convex conjugate functions f and f, we investigate

More information

On Semicontinuity of Convex-valued Multifunctions and Cesari s Property (Q)

On Semicontinuity of Convex-valued Multifunctions and Cesari s Property (Q) On Semicontinuity of Convex-valued Multifunctions and Cesari s Property (Q) Andreas Löhne May 2, 2005 (last update: November 22, 2005) Abstract We investigate two types of semicontinuity for set-valued

More information

Subdifferential representation of convex functions: refinements and applications

Subdifferential representation of convex functions: refinements and applications Subdifferential representation of convex functions: refinements and applications Joël Benoist & Aris Daniilidis Abstract Every lower semicontinuous convex function can be represented through its subdifferential

More information

Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University

Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University TIME CONSISTENT RISK AVERSE DYNAMIC DECISION MODELS: AN ECONOMIC INTERPRETATION Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University brudloff@princeton.edu Alexandre Street

More information

Stochastic dominance with imprecise information

Stochastic dominance with imprecise information Stochastic dominance with imprecise information Ignacio Montes, Enrique Miranda, Susana Montes University of Oviedo, Dep. of Statistics and Operations Research. Abstract Stochastic dominance, which is

More information

The local equicontinuity of a maximal monotone operator

The local equicontinuity of a maximal monotone operator arxiv:1410.3328v2 [math.fa] 3 Nov 2014 The local equicontinuity of a maximal monotone operator M.D. Voisei Abstract The local equicontinuity of an operator T : X X with proper Fitzpatrick function ϕ T

More information

WEAK CONVERGENCE OF RESOLVENTS OF MAXIMAL MONOTONE OPERATORS AND MOSCO CONVERGENCE

WEAK CONVERGENCE OF RESOLVENTS OF MAXIMAL MONOTONE OPERATORS AND MOSCO CONVERGENCE Fixed Point Theory, Volume 6, No. 1, 2005, 59-69 http://www.math.ubbcluj.ro/ nodeacj/sfptcj.htm WEAK CONVERGENCE OF RESOLVENTS OF MAXIMAL MONOTONE OPERATORS AND MOSCO CONVERGENCE YASUNORI KIMURA Department

More information

Metric Spaces and Topology

Metric Spaces and Topology Chapter 2 Metric Spaces and Topology From an engineering perspective, the most important way to construct a topology on a set is to define the topology in terms of a metric on the set. This approach underlies

More information

Linear Algebra (part 1) : Vector Spaces (by Evan Dummit, 2017, v. 1.07) 1.1 The Formal Denition of a Vector Space

Linear Algebra (part 1) : Vector Spaces (by Evan Dummit, 2017, v. 1.07) 1.1 The Formal Denition of a Vector Space Linear Algebra (part 1) : Vector Spaces (by Evan Dummit, 2017, v. 1.07) Contents 1 Vector Spaces 1 1.1 The Formal Denition of a Vector Space.................................. 1 1.2 Subspaces...................................................

More information

Self-equilibrated Functions in Dual Vector Spaces: a Boundedness Criterion

Self-equilibrated Functions in Dual Vector Spaces: a Boundedness Criterion Self-equilibrated Functions in Dual Vector Spaces: a Boundedness Criterion Michel Théra LACO, UMR-CNRS 6090, Université de Limoges michel.thera@unilim.fr reporting joint work with E. Ernst and M. Volle

More information

Appendix B Convex analysis

Appendix B Convex analysis This version: 28/02/2014 Appendix B Convex analysis In this appendix we review a few basic notions of convexity and related notions that will be important for us at various times. B.1 The Hausdorff distance

More information

CHAPTER 2: CONVEX SETS AND CONCAVE FUNCTIONS. W. Erwin Diewert January 31, 2008.

CHAPTER 2: CONVEX SETS AND CONCAVE FUNCTIONS. W. Erwin Diewert January 31, 2008. 1 ECONOMICS 594: LECTURE NOTES CHAPTER 2: CONVEX SETS AND CONCAVE FUNCTIONS W. Erwin Diewert January 31, 2008. 1. Introduction Many economic problems have the following structure: (i) a linear function

More information

Dedicated to Michel Théra in honor of his 70th birthday

Dedicated to Michel Théra in honor of his 70th birthday VARIATIONAL GEOMETRIC APPROACH TO GENERALIZED DIFFERENTIAL AND CONJUGATE CALCULI IN CONVEX ANALYSIS B. S. MORDUKHOVICH 1, N. M. NAM 2, R. B. RECTOR 3 and T. TRAN 4. Dedicated to Michel Théra in honor of

More information

Time Consistent Decisions and Temporal Decomposition of Coherent Risk Functionals

Time Consistent Decisions and Temporal Decomposition of Coherent Risk Functionals Time Consistent Decisions and Temporal Decomposition of Coherent Risk Functionals Georg Ch. Pflug, Alois Pichler June 16, 15 Abstract In management and planning it is commonplace for additional information

More information

THE UNIQUE MINIMAL DUAL REPRESENTATION OF A CONVEX FUNCTION

THE UNIQUE MINIMAL DUAL REPRESENTATION OF A CONVEX FUNCTION THE UNIQUE MINIMAL DUAL REPRESENTATION OF A CONVEX FUNCTION HALUK ERGIN AND TODD SARVER Abstract. Suppose (i) X is a separable Banach space, (ii) C is a convex subset of X that is a Baire space (when endowed

More information

A SET OF LECTURE NOTES ON CONVEX OPTIMIZATION WITH SOME APPLICATIONS TO PROBABILITY THEORY INCOMPLETE DRAFT. MAY 06

A SET OF LECTURE NOTES ON CONVEX OPTIMIZATION WITH SOME APPLICATIONS TO PROBABILITY THEORY INCOMPLETE DRAFT. MAY 06 A SET OF LECTURE NOTES ON CONVEX OPTIMIZATION WITH SOME APPLICATIONS TO PROBABILITY THEORY INCOMPLETE DRAFT. MAY 06 CHRISTIAN LÉONARD Contents Preliminaries 1 1. Convexity without topology 1 2. Convexity

More information

Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for unbounded

Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for unbounded Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for unbounded càdlàg processes Patrick Cheridito ORFE Princeton University Princeton, NJ, USA dito@princeton.edu Freddy Delbaen Departement für Mathematik ETH

More information

On Kusuoka representation of law invariant risk measures

On Kusuoka representation of law invariant risk measures On Kusuoka representation of law invariant risk measures Alexander Shapiro School of Industrial & Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, 765 Ferst Drive, Atlanta, GA 3332. Abstract. In this

More information

Aliprantis, Border: Infinite-dimensional Analysis A Hitchhiker s Guide

Aliprantis, Border: Infinite-dimensional Analysis A Hitchhiker s Guide aliprantis.tex May 10, 2011 Aliprantis, Border: Infinite-dimensional Analysis A Hitchhiker s Guide Notes from [AB2]. 1 Odds and Ends 2 Topology 2.1 Topological spaces Example. (2.2) A semimetric = triangle

More information

Duality and optimality conditions in stochastic optimization and mathematical finance

Duality and optimality conditions in stochastic optimization and mathematical finance Duality and optimality conditions in stochastic optimization and mathematical finance Sara Biagini Teemu Pennanen Ari-Pekka Perkkiö April 25, 2015 Abstract This article studies convex duality in stochastic

More information

Real Analysis Math 131AH Rudin, Chapter #1. Dominique Abdi

Real Analysis Math 131AH Rudin, Chapter #1. Dominique Abdi Real Analysis Math 3AH Rudin, Chapter # Dominique Abdi.. If r is rational (r 0) and x is irrational, prove that r + x and rx are irrational. Solution. Assume the contrary, that r+x and rx are rational.

More information

Real Analysis Notes. Thomas Goller

Real Analysis Notes. Thomas Goller Real Analysis Notes Thomas Goller September 4, 2011 Contents 1 Abstract Measure Spaces 2 1.1 Basic Definitions........................... 2 1.2 Measurable Functions........................ 2 1.3 Integration..............................

More information

Inverse Stochastic Dominance Constraints Duality and Methods

Inverse Stochastic Dominance Constraints Duality and Methods Duality and Methods Darinka Dentcheva 1 Andrzej Ruszczyński 2 1 Stevens Institute of Technology Hoboken, New Jersey, USA 2 Rutgers University Piscataway, New Jersey, USA Research supported by NSF awards

More information

Subdifferentiability and the Duality Gap

Subdifferentiability and the Duality Gap Subdifferentiability and the Duality Gap Neil E. Gretsky (neg@math.ucr.edu) Department of Mathematics, University of California, Riverside Joseph M. Ostroy (ostroy@econ.ucla.edu) Department of Economics,

More information

Introduction to Stochastic Optimization Part 4: Multi-stage decision

Introduction to Stochastic Optimization Part 4: Multi-stage decision Introduction to Stochastic Optimization Part 4: Multi-stage decision problems April 23, 29 The problem ξ = (ξ,..., ξ T ) a multivariate time series process (e.g. future interest rates, future asset prices,

More information

Monetary Risk Measures and Generalized Prices Relevant to Set-Valued Risk Measures

Monetary Risk Measures and Generalized Prices Relevant to Set-Valued Risk Measures Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 8, 2014, no. 109, 5439-5447 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/10.12988/ams.2014.43176 Monetary Risk Measures and Generalized Prices Relevant to Set-Valued

More information

A Note on the Swiss Solvency Test Risk Measure

A Note on the Swiss Solvency Test Risk Measure A Note on the Swiss Solvency Test Risk Measure Damir Filipović and Nicolas Vogelpoth Vienna Institute of Finance Nordbergstrasse 15 A-1090 Vienna, Austria first version: 16 August 2006, this version: 16

More information

1 Stochastic Dynamic Programming

1 Stochastic Dynamic Programming 1 Stochastic Dynamic Programming Formally, a stochastic dynamic program has the same components as a deterministic one; the only modification is to the state transition equation. When events in the future

More information

Convex Optimization Notes

Convex Optimization Notes Convex Optimization Notes Jonathan Siegel January 2017 1 Convex Analysis This section is devoted to the study of convex functions f : B R {+ } and convex sets U B, for B a Banach space. The case of B =

More information

Midterm 1. Every element of the set of functions is continuous

Midterm 1. Every element of the set of functions is continuous Econ 200 Mathematics for Economists Midterm Question.- Consider the set of functions F C(0, ) dened by { } F = f C(0, ) f(x) = ax b, a A R and b B R That is, F is a subset of the set of continuous functions

More information

Part III. 10 Topological Space Basics. Topological Spaces

Part III. 10 Topological Space Basics. Topological Spaces Part III 10 Topological Space Basics Topological Spaces Using the metric space results above as motivation we will axiomatize the notion of being an open set to more general settings. Definition 10.1.

More information

Contents: 1. Minimization. 2. The theorem of Lions-Stampacchia for variational inequalities. 3. Γ -Convergence. 4. Duality mapping.

Contents: 1. Minimization. 2. The theorem of Lions-Stampacchia for variational inequalities. 3. Γ -Convergence. 4. Duality mapping. Minimization Contents: 1. Minimization. 2. The theorem of Lions-Stampacchia for variational inequalities. 3. Γ -Convergence. 4. Duality mapping. 1 Minimization A Topological Result. Let S be a topological

More information

Continuity of convex functions in normed spaces

Continuity of convex functions in normed spaces Continuity of convex functions in normed spaces In this chapter, we consider continuity properties of real-valued convex functions defined on open convex sets in normed spaces. Recall that every infinitedimensional

More information

2. Dual space is essential for the concept of gradient which, in turn, leads to the variational analysis of Lagrange multipliers.

2. Dual space is essential for the concept of gradient which, in turn, leads to the variational analysis of Lagrange multipliers. Chapter 3 Duality in Banach Space Modern optimization theory largely centers around the interplay of a normed vector space and its corresponding dual. The notion of duality is important for the following

More information

16 1 Basic Facts from Functional Analysis and Banach Lattices

16 1 Basic Facts from Functional Analysis and Banach Lattices 16 1 Basic Facts from Functional Analysis and Banach Lattices 1.2.3 Banach Steinhaus Theorem Another fundamental theorem of functional analysis is the Banach Steinhaus theorem, or the Uniform Boundedness

More information

On convex risk measures on L p -spaces

On convex risk measures on L p -spaces MMOR manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) On convex risk measures on L p -spaces M. Kaina and L. Rüschendorf University of Freiburg, Department of Mathematical Stochastics, Eckerstr. 1, 79104

More information

Convex analysis and profit/cost/support functions

Convex analysis and profit/cost/support functions Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Convex analysis and profit/cost/support functions KC Border October 2004 Revised January 2009 Let A be a subset of R m Convex analysts may give one of two

More information

Introduction to Real Analysis Alternative Chapter 1

Introduction to Real Analysis Alternative Chapter 1 Christopher Heil Introduction to Real Analysis Alternative Chapter 1 A Primer on Norms and Banach Spaces Last Updated: March 10, 2018 c 2018 by Christopher Heil Chapter 1 A Primer on Norms and Banach Spaces

More information

Garrett: `Bernstein's analytic continuation of complex powers' 2 Let f be a polynomial in x 1 ; : : : ; x n with real coecients. For complex s, let f

Garrett: `Bernstein's analytic continuation of complex powers' 2 Let f be a polynomial in x 1 ; : : : ; x n with real coecients. For complex s, let f 1 Bernstein's analytic continuation of complex powers c1995, Paul Garrett, garrettmath.umn.edu version January 27, 1998 Analytic continuation of distributions Statement of the theorems on analytic continuation

More information

Fast Bellman Iteration: An Application of Legendre-Fenchel Duality to Deterministic Dynamic Programming in Discrete Time

Fast Bellman Iteration: An Application of Legendre-Fenchel Duality to Deterministic Dynamic Programming in Discrete Time Fast Bellman Iteration: An Application of Legendre-Fenchel Duality to Deterministic Dynamic Programming in Discrete Time Ronaldo Carpio Takashi Kamihigashi February 8, 2016 Abstract We propose an algorithm,

More information

Fast Bellman Iteration: An Application of Legendre-Fenchel Duality to Infinite-Horizon Dynamic Programming in Discrete Time

Fast Bellman Iteration: An Application of Legendre-Fenchel Duality to Infinite-Horizon Dynamic Programming in Discrete Time Fast Bellman Iteration: An Application of Legendre-Fenchel Duality to Infinite-Horizon Dynamic Programming in Discrete Time Ronaldo Carpio Takashi Kamihigashi March 17, 2015 Abstract We propose an algorithm,

More information

Convergent Iterative Algorithms in the 2-inner Product Space R n

Convergent Iterative Algorithms in the 2-inner Product Space R n Int. J. Open Problems Compt. Math., Vol. 6, No. 4, December 2013 ISSN 1998-6262; Copyright c ICSRS Publication, 2013 www.i-csrs.org Convergent Iterative Algorithms in the 2-inner Product Space R n Iqbal

More information

A SHORT INTRODUCTION TO BANACH LATTICES AND

A SHORT INTRODUCTION TO BANACH LATTICES AND CHAPTER A SHORT INTRODUCTION TO BANACH LATTICES AND POSITIVE OPERATORS In tis capter we give a brief introduction to Banac lattices and positive operators. Most results of tis capter can be found, e.g.,

More information

On duality gap in linear conic problems

On duality gap in linear conic problems On duality gap in linear conic problems C. Zălinescu Abstract In their paper Duality of linear conic problems A. Shapiro and A. Nemirovski considered two possible properties (A) and (B) for dual linear

More information

A new approach for stochastic ordering of risks

A new approach for stochastic ordering of risks A new approach for stochastic ordering of risks Liang Hong, PhD, FSA Department of Mathematics Robert Morris University Presented at 2014 Actuarial Research Conference UC Santa Barbara July 16, 2014 Liang

More information

Problem Set 2: Solutions Math 201A: Fall 2016

Problem Set 2: Solutions Math 201A: Fall 2016 Problem Set 2: s Math 201A: Fall 2016 Problem 1. (a) Prove that a closed subset of a complete metric space is complete. (b) Prove that a closed subset of a compact metric space is compact. (c) Prove that

More information

Lecture 5: The Bellman Equation

Lecture 5: The Bellman Equation Lecture 5: The Bellman Equation Florian Scheuer 1 Plan Prove properties of the Bellman equation (In particular, existence and uniqueness of solution) Use this to prove properties of the solution Think

More information

Introduction and Preliminaries

Introduction and Preliminaries Chapter 1 Introduction and Preliminaries This chapter serves two purposes. The first purpose is to prepare the readers for the more systematic development in later chapters of methods of real analysis

More information

Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem

Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem 56 Chapter 7 Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem Recall that C(X) is not a normed linear space when X is not compact. On the other hand we could use semi

More information

(convex combination!). Use convexity of f and multiply by the common denominator to get. Interchanging the role of x and y, we obtain that f is ( 2M ε

(convex combination!). Use convexity of f and multiply by the common denominator to get. Interchanging the role of x and y, we obtain that f is ( 2M ε 1. Continuity of convex functions in normed spaces In this chapter, we consider continuity properties of real-valued convex functions defined on open convex sets in normed spaces. Recall that every infinitedimensional

More information

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY Elementary properties of convex functions

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY Elementary properties of convex functions Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Ec 181 KC Border Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY 2018 2019 Topic 6: Convex functions I 6.1 Elementary properties of convex functions We may occasionally

More information

Convergence of generalized entropy minimizers in sequences of convex problems

Convergence of generalized entropy minimizers in sequences of convex problems Proceedings IEEE ISIT 206, Barcelona, Spain, 2609 263 Convergence of generalized entropy minimizers in sequences of convex problems Imre Csiszár A Rényi Institute of Mathematics Hungarian Academy of Sciences

More information

ON GAP FUNCTIONS OF VARIATIONAL INEQUALITY IN A BANACH SPACE. Sangho Kum and Gue Myung Lee. 1. Introduction

ON GAP FUNCTIONS OF VARIATIONAL INEQUALITY IN A BANACH SPACE. Sangho Kum and Gue Myung Lee. 1. Introduction J. Korean Math. Soc. 38 (2001), No. 3, pp. 683 695 ON GAP FUNCTIONS OF VARIATIONAL INEQUALITY IN A BANACH SPACE Sangho Kum and Gue Myung Lee Abstract. In this paper we are concerned with theoretical properties

More information

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory Winter 2018

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory Winter 2018 Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Ec 181 KC Border Convex Analysis and Economic Theory Winter 2018 Supplement A: Mathematical background A.1 Extended real numbers The extended real number

More information

HILBERT SPACES AND THE RADON-NIKODYM THEOREM. where the bar in the first equation denotes complex conjugation. In either case, for any x V define

HILBERT SPACES AND THE RADON-NIKODYM THEOREM. where the bar in the first equation denotes complex conjugation. In either case, for any x V define HILBERT SPACES AND THE RADON-NIKODYM THEOREM STEVEN P. LALLEY 1. DEFINITIONS Definition 1. A real inner product space is a real vector space V together with a symmetric, bilinear, positive-definite mapping,

More information

Convexity in R n. The following lemma will be needed in a while. Lemma 1 Let x E, u R n. If τ I(x, u), τ 0, define. f(x + τu) f(x). τ.

Convexity in R n. The following lemma will be needed in a while. Lemma 1 Let x E, u R n. If τ I(x, u), τ 0, define. f(x + τu) f(x). τ. Convexity in R n Let E be a convex subset of R n. A function f : E (, ] is convex iff f(tx + (1 t)y) (1 t)f(x) + tf(y) x, y E, t [0, 1]. A similar definition holds in any vector space. A topology is needed

More information

Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for bounded

Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for bounded Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for bounded càdlàg processes Patrick Cheridito ORFE Princeton University Princeton, NJ, USA dito@princeton.edu Freddy Delbaen Departement für Mathematik ETH Zürich

More information

BASICS OF CONVEX ANALYSIS

BASICS OF CONVEX ANALYSIS BASICS OF CONVEX ANALYSIS MARKUS GRASMAIR 1. Main Definitions We start with providing the central definitions of convex functions and convex sets. Definition 1. A function f : R n R + } is called convex,

More information

Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences. Supergradients. KC Border Fall 2001 v ::15.45

Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences. Supergradients. KC Border Fall 2001 v ::15.45 Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Supergradients KC Border Fall 2001 1 The supergradient of a concave function There is a useful way to characterize the concavity of differentiable functions.

More information

Vector Space Basics. 1 Abstract Vector Spaces. 1. (commutativity of vector addition) u + v = v + u. 2. (associativity of vector addition)

Vector Space Basics. 1 Abstract Vector Spaces. 1. (commutativity of vector addition) u + v = v + u. 2. (associativity of vector addition) Vector Space Basics (Remark: these notes are highly formal and may be a useful reference to some students however I am also posting Ray Heitmann's notes to Canvas for students interested in a direct computational

More information

2 Statement of the problem and assumptions

2 Statement of the problem and assumptions Mathematical Notes, 25, vol. 78, no. 4, pp. 466 48. Existence Theorem for Optimal Control Problems on an Infinite Time Interval A.V. Dmitruk and N.V. Kuz kina We consider an optimal control problem on

More information

Elements of Convex Optimization Theory

Elements of Convex Optimization Theory Elements of Convex Optimization Theory Costis Skiadas August 2015 This is a revised and extended version of Appendix A of Skiadas (2009), providing a self-contained overview of elements of convex optimization

More information

Fundamental Inequalities, Convergence and the Optional Stopping Theorem for Continuous-Time Martingales

Fundamental Inequalities, Convergence and the Optional Stopping Theorem for Continuous-Time Martingales Fundamental Inequalities, Convergence and the Optional Stopping Theorem for Continuous-Time Martingales Prakash Balachandran Department of Mathematics Duke University April 2, 2008 1 Review of Discrete-Time

More information

Conjugate duality in stochastic optimization

Conjugate duality in stochastic optimization Ari-Pekka Perkkiö, Institute of Mathematics, Aalto University Ph.D. instructor/joint work with Teemu Pennanen, Institute of Mathematics, Aalto University March 15th 2010 1 / 13 We study convex problems.

More information

3.1 Basic properties of real numbers - continuation Inmum and supremum of a set of real numbers

3.1 Basic properties of real numbers - continuation Inmum and supremum of a set of real numbers Chapter 3 Real numbers The notion of real number was introduced in section 1.3 where the axiomatic denition of the set of all real numbers was done and some basic properties of the set of all real numbers

More information

Extreme points of compact convex sets

Extreme points of compact convex sets Extreme points of compact convex sets In this chapter, we are going to show that compact convex sets are determined by a proper subset, the set of its extreme points. Let us start with the main definition.

More information

APPENDIX C: Measure Theoretic Issues

APPENDIX C: Measure Theoretic Issues APPENDIX C: Measure Theoretic Issues A general theory of stochastic dynamic programming must deal with the formidable mathematical questions that arise from the presence of uncountable probability spaces.

More information

Economics 204 Summer/Fall 2011 Lecture 5 Friday July 29, 2011

Economics 204 Summer/Fall 2011 Lecture 5 Friday July 29, 2011 Economics 204 Summer/Fall 2011 Lecture 5 Friday July 29, 2011 Section 2.6 (cont.) Properties of Real Functions Here we first study properties of functions from R to R, making use of the additional structure

More information

LECTURE 15: COMPLETENESS AND CONVEXITY

LECTURE 15: COMPLETENESS AND CONVEXITY LECTURE 15: COMPLETENESS AND CONVEXITY 1. The Hopf-Rinow Theorem Recall that a Riemannian manifold (M, g) is called geodesically complete if the maximal defining interval of any geodesic is R. On the other

More information

Sequential Pareto Subdifferential Sum Rule And Sequential Effi ciency

Sequential Pareto Subdifferential Sum Rule And Sequential Effi ciency Applied Mathematics E-Notes, 16(2016), 133-143 c ISSN 1607-2510 Available free at mirror sites of http://www.math.nthu.edu.tw/ amen/ Sequential Pareto Subdifferential Sum Rule And Sequential Effi ciency

More information

An introduction to some aspects of functional analysis

An introduction to some aspects of functional analysis An introduction to some aspects of functional analysis Stephen Semmes Rice University Abstract These informal notes deal with some very basic objects in functional analysis, including norms and seminorms

More information

JUHA KINNUNEN. Harmonic Analysis

JUHA KINNUNEN. Harmonic Analysis JUHA KINNUNEN Harmonic Analysis Department of Mathematics and Systems Analysis, Aalto University 27 Contents Calderón-Zygmund decomposition. Dyadic subcubes of a cube.........................2 Dyadic cubes

More information

Coherent risk measures

Coherent risk measures Coherent risk measures Foivos Xanthos Ryerson University, Department of Mathematics Toµɛας Mαθηµατ ικὼν, E.M.Π, 11 Noɛµβρὶoυ 2015 Research interests Financial Mathematics, Mathematical Economics, Functional

More information

Fast Bellman Iteration: An Application of Legendre-Fenchel Duality to Infinite-Horizon Dynamic Programming in Discrete Time

Fast Bellman Iteration: An Application of Legendre-Fenchel Duality to Infinite-Horizon Dynamic Programming in Discrete Time Fast Bellman Iteration: An Application of Legendre-Fenchel Duality to Infinite-Horizon Dynamic Programming in Discrete Time Ronaldo Carpio Takashi Kamihigashi March 10, 2015 Abstract We propose an algorithm,

More information

Fast Bellman Iteration: An Application of Legendre-Fenchel Duality to a Class of Deterministic Dynamic Programming Problems in Discrete Time

Fast Bellman Iteration: An Application of Legendre-Fenchel Duality to a Class of Deterministic Dynamic Programming Problems in Discrete Time Fast Bellman Iteration: An Application of Legendre-Fenchel Duality to a Class of Deterministic Dynamic Programming Problems in Discrete Time Ronaldo Carpio Takashi Kamihigashi July 30, 2016 Abstract We

More information

5 Measure theory II. (or. lim. Prove the proposition. 5. For fixed F A and φ M define the restriction of φ on F by writing.

5 Measure theory II. (or. lim. Prove the proposition. 5. For fixed F A and φ M define the restriction of φ on F by writing. 5 Measure theory II 1. Charges (signed measures). Let (Ω, A) be a σ -algebra. A map φ: A R is called a charge, (or signed measure or σ -additive set function) if φ = φ(a j ) (5.1) A j for any disjoint

More information

Dynamic risk measures. Robust representation and examples

Dynamic risk measures. Robust representation and examples VU University Amsterdam Faculty of Sciences Jagiellonian University Faculty of Mathematics and Computer Science Joint Master of Science Programme Dorota Kopycka Student no. 1824821 VU, WMiI/69/04/05 UJ

More information

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Tim Leung 1, Qingshuo Song 2, and Jie Yang 3 1 Columbia University, New York, USA; leung@ieor.columbia.edu 2 City

More information

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint that the ON PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION UNDER \DRAWDOWN" CONSTRAINTS JAKSA CVITANIC IOANNIS KARATZAS y March 6, 994 Abstract We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the wealth

More information