Structural Analysis of Portfolio Risk Using. Beta Impulse Response Functions. April Abstract

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Structural Analysis of Portfolio Risk Using. Beta Impulse Response Functions. April Abstract"

Transcription

1 Structural Analysis of Portfolio Risk Using Beta Impulse Response Functions Christian M. Hafner Helmut Herwartz April 1998 Abstract We estimate the data generating process of daily excess returns of 20 major German stocks in a CAPM framework with time varying betas. Our sample spans a 23 year period from 1974 to An asymmetric dependence of volatility on lagged innovations is taken into account. We introduce beta impulse response functions to shed light on the structural implications of systematic risk associated with competing volatility models. The dependence of beta on news is characterized with respect to dierent sources (asset specic vs. market general news). The empirical results suggest that negative news emerging from the market involve a stronger impact on beta relative to positive news. Concerning rm specic news the opposite relation is found for the majority of the analysed data sets. Keywords: CAPM Multivariate GARCH{Models, asymmetry, impulse response analysis, Institut fur Statistik und Okonometrie and Sonderforschungsbereich 373, Wirtschaftswissenschaftliche Fakultat, Humboldt{Universitat zu Berlin, Spandauer Str. 1, D Berlin, Germany. hafner@wiwi.hu-berlin.de or helmut@wiwi.hu-berlin.de. Financial support by the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft is gratefully acknowledged. We thank two anonymous referees and Rolf Tschernig for helpful suggestions. 0

2 1 Introduction As a standard model in nance theory, the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) as invented by Sharpe (1964) and Lintner (1965) has been subject of many empirical tests and applications. One of the principal achievements was the distinction between systematic and unsystematic risk, where only the latter can be diversied away. Portfolio managers were thus enabled to consider as risk of one asset its beta, and the remaining unsystematic risk diminished in his broad portfolio. Thus, the beta of one asset was the standard measure of the asset's contribution to portfolio risk and, once calculated, this was not recalculated frequently. However, the success of the ARCH models (Engle (1982)) in describing stock market volatility suggested to allow for time-varying betas. This was rst investigated by Bollerslev, Engle and Wooldridge (1988, BEW hereafter), who established a link between bivariate GARCH models and the CAPM. BEW analyse quarterly data, but it should be noted that ARCH-eects have very often been shown to be stronger for shorter periods, weekly or daily data. In this paper, we will concentrate on the German stock market for a long time period (1974 to 1996) with daily observations. We thus deal with a huge data set (22 time series of 5748 observations each { a total of observations). On the one hand, this is a potential to detect and exploit typical structures in multivariate time series, on the other hand it challenges the computing power when complex multivariate models are applied. Our main topic is the following question: how sensitive are time-varying betas with respect to independent innovations to the system? These innovations can be rm-specic news or news that is relevant in general. By specifying models that allow for asymmetric volatility impacts, we investigate the issue whether good news (rm-specic or marketgeneral) has the same impact as bad news. Our ndings suggest that there is distinct asymmetry for the impact of shocks on the prediction of betas. Both positive and negative rm-specic innovations tend to increase systematic risk. The reverse tends to hold for market-general news, which for the majority of the analysed series had a decreasing eect on the betas. The overall variability of the betas is large on a daily frequency. This suggests that portfolio managers should revise their beta `estimates' daily and should adjust their beta forecasts given news on that day. This can be easily performed with the tool of impulse response functions, adapted to the analysis of time-varying betas in this paper. It is based on the development of volatility impulse reponse functions by Hafner and Herwartz (1997). The outline of the paper is as follows. Section 2 reviews the theory of the CAPM with time-varying betas. Section 3 deals with multivariate GARCH models and presents models allowing for asymmetry. In Section 4, beta impulse response functions (BIRF) are dened. Section 5 reports the results from estimating dierent multivariate GARCH 1

3 models and presents the resulting BIRF. Section 6 concludes. 2 The CAPM with Time{varying Betas Within the CAPM the return on an asset (r i ) corrected for a riskfree rate (r f ) is linearly related to the excess return on the so{called market portfolio (r m? r f ) covering all traded assets. The covariance between the asset's return and the return on the market portfolio ( im ) and the variance of market returns ( 2 m) govern this linear relationship: r i = r f + im (r m? r f ) m 2 = r f + i (r m? r f ): (1) The quantity i = im = 2 m has become popular as the asset's `beta' which is thought of as a measure for the undiversiable risk associated with a specic asset. Returns on assets having a beta larger than one are more aected by market movements relative to assets with a beta less than one and thus are relatively more risky. A model such as (1) is easily transformed into an econometric regression model explaining excess asset returns in period t, i.e. r i;t = + i r m;t + u t (2) In (2) r i;t and r m;t denote the excess returns, r i;t? r f;t and r m;t? r f;t respectively. The error term u t captures eects stemming from unsystematic risk associated with asset i. Note that the inclusion of a constant term is not implied by the economic model in (1). The static model in (1) is usually tested by checking whiteness of estimated residuals obtained from (2) and a formal test of the hypothesis H 0 : = 0. In its static form the CAPM implies time invariance of the involved variances and covariances and thus of `beta'. However, from an economic viewpoint one may imagine that these quantities vary through time. BEW and Hall, Miles and Taylor (1989) provide a time series framework allowing for time dependence of the relevant quantities. Let t?1 denote the set of information which is available up to time t? 1. Assuming E[r f;t j t?1] = r f;t?1 a time dependent version of (1) is obtained as (see Mills (1993), pp.192{194): E[r i;t j t?1] = r f;t?1 + i;t (E[r m;t j t?1]? r f;t?1 ); (3) with i;t = Cov(r i;t ; r m;t j t?1)=var(r m;t j t?1): (4) An econometric model corresponding to (3) is not immediately available since the expected excess return on the market portfolio is not observed. One means to overcome 2

4 this diculty is to assume that the so{called market{price of risk is invariant through time, i.e. E[r m;t j t?1]? r f;t?1 = : (5) Var(r m;t j t?1) Dening " i;t = r i;t? E[r i;t j t?1] and " m;t = r m;t? E[r m;t j t?1] one obtains from substituting (5) and (4) into (3) and r i;t = r f;t?1 + Cov(r i;t ; r m;t j t?1) + " i;t r m;t = r f;t?1 + Var(r m;t j t?1) + " m;t from (5). A candidate model to estimate conditional variances and covariances of " t = (" i;t ; " m;t ) 0 t = E[" t " 0 t j t?1] = 2 i;t im;t im;t 2 m;t is the bivariate GARCH model which is briey outlined in Section 3. Stacking excess returns into a two dimensional vector r t = (r i;t? r f;t?1 ; r m;t? r f;t?1 ) 0 one obtains a multivariate GARCH in Mean (GARCH{M) model (see e.g. Engle, Lilien and Robins (1987)): r t = g + im;t 2 m;t 1 A 1 A + "t : (6) As already mentioned for the static model in (2) the inclusion of a vector of constants g = (g 1 ; g 2 ) 0 does not directly follow from the economic model in (3). Time varying betas for asset i are obtained from ( t ) as: i;t = im;t : m;t 2 The rst equation of (6) contains time dependent risk premia for asset i, g 1 + im;t. Note that = 0 implies a constant risk premium for the asset of interest. 3 Multivariate GARCH Models { Specication, Identication, and Estimation The generalization of univariate ARCH{type models of conditional heteroskedasticity (see e.g. Engle (1982), Bollerslev (1986)) to the multivariate case is more or less straightforward. An N-dimensional random vector " t = (" 1;t ; : : : ; " N;t ) 0 may be written as " t = 1=2 t t (7) 3

5 where t denotes an i:i:d: random vector with mean zero and covariance matrix equal to the identity matrix I N. If t is specied as GARCH, then (7) is a strong GARCH model in the sense of Drost and Nijman (1993). We employ this strong GARCH form, because we will later dene news to appear in the i:i:d: innovation vector t. Given information up to time t? 1, the elements of t are completely determined by their own history t?i ; i = 1; : : : ; p and lagged observations " t?i ; i = 1; : : : ; q. Let vech(:) denote the operator that stacks the lower fraction of an N N{matrix into an N(N + 1)=2 dimensional vector. To make the dynamics of t explicit, the multivariate GARCH(p; q) model may be given as follows: vech( t ) = c + qx A i vech(" t?i px " 0 ) + t?i i=1 i=1 G i vech( t?i ): (8) In (8), A i and G i denote parameter matrices each containing (N(N + 1)=2) 2 parameters. The vector c accounts for time invariant variance components and contains N(N + 1)=2 coecients. Oering a very general structure of multivariate interdependence the vec{ model may easily suer from overparametrization in econometric practice. As given in (8), the multivariate GARCH(1,1) model contains already 21 parameters for a bivariate series (N = 2) under study. To improve the econometric tractability of the model (8), BEW advocate the diagonal model in which the matrices A i and G i are assumed to be diagonal such that the (k; l){ element in t depends linearly on the respective elements of the matrices " t?i " 0 t?i and t?i. Within the framework of the diagonal model the price paid for parsimony is the a priori exclusion of potentially important cross dynamics for the dependence of t on t?1. Engle and Kroner (1995) discuss the following model named after Baba, Engle, Kraft and Kroner (1990): t = C 0 0 C 0 + KX qx k=1 i=1 A 0 ki " t?i" 0 t?i A ki + KX px k=1 i=1 G 0 ki t?i G ki : (9) In (9), C 0 is an upper triangular matrix and A ki and G ki are N N parameter matrices. Even in the simplest case of K = 1, the so{called BEKK representation given in (9) allows for direct dependence of the conditional variance of one variable on the history of other variables within the system. In addition, (9) always yields positive denite covariance matrices without imposing further parameter restrictions. Engle and Kroner (1995) discuss the specication given in (9) in detail. For the present analysis we take K = 1 and concentrate on the GARCH(1,1) model. In this case the assumption that the upper left elements of A 11 and G 11 are greater than zero is sucient for the model parameters to be identied. From empirical analysis the so{called leverage eect has become a stylized fact of the conditional variance of stock market returns (see e.g. Black (1976)). It states that 4

6 the conditional variance of a return series is more aected by bad news (negative lagged innovations) relative to good news (positive lagged innovations). To account for the potential of an asymmetric dependence of multivariate volatility on lagged innovations we adopt generalizations of (9) which may be regarded as multivariate extensions of the asymmetric univariate GARCH model introduced by Glosten, Jagannathan and Runkle (1993). Since negative news might occur in the system through each of the components of " t separately or simultaneously we investigate for the case N = 2 and K = 1 the following specications in addition to the symmetric model given in (9): M1: t = C 0 0 C 0 + A 0 11 " t?1" 0 t?1 A 11 + A 0 21 " t?1" 0 t?1 A 21I "1;t?1<0 + A 0 31 " t?1" 0 t?1 A 31I "2;t?1<0 + G 0 11 t?1g 11 (10) M2: t = C 0 0 C 0 + A 0 11 " t?1" 0 t?1 A 11 + A 0 21 " t?1" 0 t?1 A 21I "1;t?1<0 + G 0 11 t?1 G 11 (11) M3: t = C 0 0 C 0 + A 0 11 " t?1" 0 t?1 A 11 + A 0 31 " t?1" 0 t?1 A 31I "2;t?1<0 + G 0 11 t?1 G 11 (12) M4: t = C 0 0 C 0 + A 0 11 " t?1" 0 t?1 A 11 + G 0 11 t?1g 11 : (13) In (10) to (12), I () denotes an indicator function. The model denoted as M4 is just the symmetric model implied by K = p = q = 1 in (9) and is given above in order to provide a comprehensive list of the empirical models which were under study for the present analysis. Recall that one result of Engle and Kroner (1995) was that for each BEKK model there is a unique equivalent vec representation. Thus, when discussing the properties of M1 to M4, we can also consider the equivalent vec-specication by dening c = (C 0 C 0 ) 0 vec(i N ), A 1 = (A 11 A 11 ) 0, A 2 = (A 21 A 21 ) 0, A 3 = (A 31 A 31 ) 0, and G 1 = (G 11 G 11 ) 0. After eliminating from c, A, 1 A, 2 A, and 3 G 1 those rows and columns that are superuous due to the symmetry of the covariances, one obtains the matrices c, A 1, A 2, A 3, and G 1 as in (8). This transformation is notationally more convenient and is consistent with the next section where we discuss impulse response functions only for the vec-specication. The following proposition provides a result for the covariance stationarity of the model M1. The result applies immediately to M2, M3 and M4 by setting the corresponding matrices A 2 and/or A 3 to zero. Proposition 1 Assume that both components of the error t have a symmetric density around zero. Then the process " t is covariance stationary if and only if all eigenvalues of A 1 + A 2 =2 + A 3 =2 + G 1 (14) have moduli less than one. For the implied unconditional covariance matrix, one obtains Proof: see Appendix. vech() = E[vech(" t " 0 t)] = (I? A 1? A 2 =2? A 3 =2? G 1 )?1 c: (15) 5

7 The elements of the parameter matrices in (10) to (13) are estimated by numerical procedures. Within this study we used the BHHH{algorithm as described e.g. in Judge et al. (1988) to maximize the log{likelihood function assuming normally distributed innovations. For t N(0; I P N ), the contribution of an observation " t to the joint log{ likelihood of the sample (l = l t ) is obtained as: l t =? N 2 ln(2)? 1 2 ln j tj? 1 2 "0 t?1 t " t : (16) If the multivariate distribution of t is other than normal, (16) is the quasi{likelihood function, and estimation is performed by quasi maximum likelihood (QML). To our knowledge the consistency of QML for our general model has not been proven yet, but we conjecture such a result along the lines of Bollerslev and Wooldridge (1992) and Lumsdaine (1996). 4 Beta Impulse Response Functions As already mentioned we will only consider vec GARCH models since every BEKK model can be uniquely transformed into an equivalent vec specication. Consider the GARCH(1,1) model with two threshold components, vech( t ) = c + A 1 vech(" t?1 " 0 t?1) + A 2 vech(" t?1 " 0 t?1)i "1;t?1<0 with unconditional covariance matrix, and + A 3 vech(" t?1 " 0 t?1 )I " 2;t?1<0 + G 1 vech( t?1 ) (17) vech() = (I? A 1? A 2 =2? A 3 =2? G 1 )?1 c: All other restricted models (M2, M3, and M4) can be considered as special cases of (17). Assuming covariance stationarity we can dene an impulse response function for the CAPM beta of individual assets. At t = 0 some independent news is reected by 0, and it is not specied whether the news is `good' or `bad', as indicated by the sign of the individual components, and how important the news is, as indicated by the size. as Hafner and Herwartz (1997) dened the volatility impulse response function (VIRF) V t ( 0 ) = E[vech( t ) j 0 ; 0 ]; (18) where V t ( 0 ) is an N(N + 1)=2 dimensional vector. For example, if N = 2, the rst and third element of V t ( 0 ) represent the impulse response function of the conditional variances of the rst and second variable, respectively, and the second element of V t ( 0 ) is the impulse response function of the conditional covariance. For the condition of the volatility state at time t = 0 we will in the following consider the steady state, i.e. 0 =. 6

8 Of course, other states may be considered as well, but the type of inuence of 0 will not change in principal. An impulse response function for the time-varying betas of asset i, is naturally dened to be i;t = im;t 2 m;t B i;t ( 0 ) = V im;t( 0 ) V m;t ( 0 ) ; (19) where V im;t ( 0 ) represents the VIRF for the conditional covariance of the asset with the market portfolio, and V m;t ( 0 ) corresponds to the conditional variance of the market portfolio. Due to the law of iterated expectations, (19) can also be represented as B i;t ( 0 ) = E[ i;t j 0 ; 0 ], that is, the optimal forecast for beta at time t, given information at time 0. Starting at t = 1, it can be seen that V 1 ( 0 ) = c + A 1 vech( 1= =2 ) + A 2 vech( 1= =2 )I 1;0 <0 + A 3 vech( 1= =2 )I 2;0 <0 + G 1 vech(); (20) and, for t 2, V t ( 0 ) = c + (A 1 + A 2 =2 + A 3 =2 + G 1 )V t?1 ( 0 ): (21) This recursive formula can be implemented eciently. Note that lim t?!1 V t ( 0 ) = (I? A 1? A 2 =2? A 3 =2? G 1 )?1 c; so for non{persistent multivariate GARCH processes V t ( 0 ) naturally approaches the unconditional covariance matrix, and thus B t ( 0 ) approaches the unconditional beta. 5 Empirical Analysis 5.1 Dataset and Estimation Results For the empirical analysis we investigate daily prices for 20 German stocks. The sample period is from January 2, 1974 to December 30, 1996 which amounts to 5748 observations for each series under study. Stock price data were obtained from the Deutsche Kapitalmarktdatenbank, Karlsruhe and SFB 373 (Teilprojekt C1) at Humboldt University Berlin. As the risk free rate a money market rate for deposits with one month time to maturity was chosen. Daily rates were kindly provided by the Deutsche Bundesbank. To represent the evolution of the market portfolio we have chosen the so{called DAFOX series, as provided by the University of Karlsruhe. This index is computed for research purposes and is composed of all stocks traded at the Frankfurt stock exchange. All stock market series were adjusted for payments out of the stock and for changes of their nominal value. As an important intermediate result a univariate investigation of the DAFOX series shows that the market returns within our study are signicantly correlated and their 7

9 conditional variance shows a dierent impact of volatility to negative lagged innovations relative to positive ones which is signicant at the 10 % level. Due to signicant autocorrelation of at least one series involved in bivariate modelling we adopt a vector autoregressive model of order one, VAR(1), to investigate the dynamics of bivariate excess return series in the light of the CAPM given in Section 2. Using the econometric programme EVIEWS the following univariate threshold GARCH(1,1) model is obtained for the rst dierences of the logarithm of the DAFOX series (p{values in parentheses): r m;t = 3:52e-04 (:0008) ^ 2 t = 8:25e-07 (:0000) + 0:1378 r m;t?1 + ^e t ; ^e t j t?1 (0; ^ 2 t ); (:0000) + 0:0459 ^e 2 + 0:0591 t?1 ^e 2 t?1 I^e t?1<0 + 0:9182 ^ 2 t?1 (22) (:0379) (:0795) (:0000) The value of the log{likelihood function obtained for this model is Restricting the model in (22) to be symmetric in the variance equation one obtains a value of the log{likelihood function of and assuming the mean of r m;t to be uncorrelated with r m;t?1 one obtains a maximum of the log{likelihood function of Without relying too much on formal test procedures (see e.g. p-values in (22)), both types of restrictions obviously imply a considerable loss in accuracy of t. Further diagnostic checking of standardized residuals (^ t = ^e t =^ t ) obtained from (22) reveals that the GARCH(1,1){ model is sucient to cope with heteroskedasticity. ARCH LM(1) and LM(5) tests (see e.g. Engle (1982)) for ^ t yield p{values of 0.86 and 0.99 respectively. However, the normality hypothesis is clearly rejected for the sequence of standardized errors. Using the Jarque{Bera statistic (see e.g. Lutkepohl (1991)) the obtained p{value is The multivariate GARCH-M models outlined in (6) and (10) to (13) were estimated using numerical procedures written in GAUSS 3.2. It turned out that a few extreme outliers in the bivariate data sets had strong eects on the results of the optimization procedure. In order to reduce the dependence of our results on these outlying observations we trimmed the bivariate series. Let # i denote the empirical standard deviation of a return series in question. For a given return series each observation having an absolute value which was greater than 4# i was set to be equal to 2# i by preserving the sign of the respective observation. Depending on the data set it turned out that between 30 and 40 return observations were regarded as outliers. Relative to the sample size this amounts to 0.5% to 0.7% trimmed observations for each series under study. Without trimming the return series the obtained maximum values of the log{likelihood function were about 1000 points lower relative to a sample with trimmed observations and irrespective of the data set under study. In addition, it turned out that checking estimated residuals for autocorrelation became very dicult without trimming. Portmanteau type statistics became rather large for all data sets under study making a meaningful choice of a candidate VAR-order almost impossible. Note that the adopted trimming procedure is `weak' in the sense that observations which are large in absolute value remain large (2# i ) after 8

10 trimming. To account for conditional heteroskedasticity all multivariate models M1 to M4 given in Section 3 were employed alternatively. In addition, all CAPM{specications were estimated assuming constant risk{premia ( = 0) or time varying risk{premia as given in (6). Thus, we considered eight time series models per data set. Estimation results characterizing the relative performance of the empirical models are provided in Table 1. In order to keep the results readable we do not provide detailed estimates because of the large number of empirical models under study. Table 1 reports the log{likelihood values obtained for the most general model allowing for time dependent risk premia and for two complementary sources of asymmetry of volatility (M1 with unrestricted). The other entries indicate 2 times the dierence of the log{likelihood function of a specic model relative to the general model. Note that under normality these dierences provide the likelihood{ratio (LR) statistic to test simultaneously the zero restrictions implied by the `smaller' model. In addition, these results also provide implicitly test statistics for the restrictions implied by the specication M4 relative to M2 and M3. Asymptotically this statistic follows a 2 (q){distribution where q denotes the number of excess parameters in the general model relative to the model under the null{ hypothesis. Since the necessary assumptions for validity of the asymptotic distribution are possibly not met within the present application we do not interpret our results as formal tests. However, Table 1 provides informal insights into shortcomings of specic restrictions which are hardly met by the data. To indicate possible misspecication of the empirical model we also compute the multivariate Portmanteau{statistic (see e.g. Lutkepohl (1991)) which is obtained from empirical autocorrelations of the estimated error sequences ^" t of order 1 to 10 (Q(10)). Under the hypothesis that the underlying true autocorrelations are zero, Q(10) follows asymptotically a 2 {distribution with 36 degrees of freedom. However, with respect to the necessary assumptions to achieve validity of the asymptotic distribution the same argument as given above applies. The 95% (99%) critical value for the 2 (36) distribution is (58.56). It turned out that the obtained Q(10){statistics did not depend very much on the empirical model which was tted to a specic data set. To economize on space we do not provide Portmanteau statistics for each model under study but the observed range of the 8 Q(10){statistics obtained for each data set. These results are also given in Table 1. Compared with the critical values of the portmanteau statistic all empirical models appear to suer from signicant residual autocorrelation. However, a closer inspection of the estimated residuals reveals that the multivariate correlation measures are spoilt by only a few (say 10) outlying estimates. Therefore an augmentation of the empirical model with further lagged vector returns is regarded as inconvenient. On the other hand reducing the vector autoregressive order to the VAR(0) case would yield values of the 9

11 Q(10){statistics that are about three times higher relative to the VAR(1) case. Taking this argument into account and remembering the univariate properties for the DAFOX return series we adopt the VAR(1){model. With respect to the empirical issue of time varying risk premia we obtain for a few data sets weak evidence in favour of signicance of ^. The values of the log{likelihood function of empirical models specied with and without are always very close. Assuming the relevant LR{test statistic to follow a 2 (1)-distribution some tests for = 0 are signicant e.g. at the 10% signicance level. However, apart from looking at formal test{statistics one observes that for a number of data sets the estimated values of are relatively close to each other for dierent specications of the variance equation. Complementary to a comparison of the implied values of the log{likelihood functions one might interpret `similar' estimates for as evidence in favour of time varying risk{premia. Along these lines we found evidence supporting time varying risk{premia for 10 data sets under study. Since estimates for are essential for the interpretation of the CAPM (time dependent vs. time invariant risk premia) we also provide the obtained estimates for this parameter in Table 1. A few estimation results are obtained irrespective of the time series under study. A symmetric specication of the multivariate GARCH{model is clearly outperformed by the three remaining devices for specifying conditional volatility. Relative to the most general model the smallest LR{statistic is 43.4 (RWE) and for 10 data sets the respective statistic exceeds 100. Taking a log{likelihood dierence of 10 as an informal criterion to discriminate between variance specications one favours a restricted asymmetric model relative to the general model M1 in 9 cases under study. For ve (four) of these data sets asymmetry is best treated using innovations in asset returns (market returns), i.e. model specications M2 (M3) outperform M3 (M2). The most general variance model yields a value of the log{likelihood function which is about 17 points higher relative to the second best model in case of the THYSSEN series. Together with the MAN data set (16 points) these cases indicate the strongest improvement of the log{likelihood function obtained from the general model. For the preferred models, Table 2 reports the implied unconditional correlation, which is dened as = 12 = p The smallest correlation is found for PREUSSAG ( = 0:547), the largest for SIEMENS ( = 0:843). Also, the implied unconditional betas () as well as the two largest eigenvalues of the matrix (14) are reported. For all assets the obtained eigenvalues imply covariance stationarity, since all of them are smaller than one. Also we nd high persistence in the sense that the largest eigenvalues are very close to one. Across the assets, the unconditional beta varies strongly with a minimum for LINDE ( = 0:912) and a maximum for VOLKSWAGEN ( = 1:493). The estimated conditional betas also vary strongly over time, as can be seen in Figure 5. Obviously, the variability 10

12 of the betas for HOECHST is much higher than for SIEMENS, which can be interpreted as a higher second order risk. 5.2 BIRF for the estimated models Based on the estimation results reported in the previous section we calculated the BIRF as dened in Section 4 for each data set. To keep the presentation comprehensible, we selected four assets that can be considered as representative, and present the BIRF plots for these assets. Since we preferred dierent models for dierent assets, we selected BAYER (M1), SIEMENS (M2) and HOECHST (M3). Additionally, we plot the BIRF for all models for MANNESMANN. There are two possible ways of plotting B t ( 0 ): (1) to x t and plot B t ( 0 ) versus the two components of 0, and (2), to x one component of 0 to a constant (zero) and plot B t ( 0 ) versus the other component and time. In Figure 1 the BIRF are given for BAYER, where the upper two plots were obtained by the rst method by setting t = 5 (one week, left plot) and t = 20 (four weeks, right plot). The lower two plots are the BIRF for the second method, where the left plot visualizes the impact of an independent innovation to the asset, i;0, xing the market's innovation to zero. Analogously, the lower right plot visualizes the impact of an innovation to the market, setting the asset's innovation to zero. For the time horizon, a maximum period of 50 trading days (ten weeks) was chosen. This pattern is kept for Figure 2 (SIEMENS) and Figure 3 (HOECHST). First, a general result was that the BIRF tend to be convex in the direction of the asset's innovation, keeping the market's innovation xed, and concave the other way around. The only exception was DAIMLER, where the BIRF was convex in both dimensions. The concavity with respect to the market innovation can be explained by the following. The larger the innovation to the market, the larger also the volatility prediction for the market. Thus, the contribution of a single asset to market risk, as measured by its beta, decreases. On the other hand, an asset-specic innovation creates specic uncertainty, and its own variance and covariance with the market portfolio tend to increase. As a consequence, its contribution to market risk will have a higher price. This general fact is well represented by almost all return series analysed. Next, we will investigate the dierence between the impact of `good news' and `bad news' on the systematic risk. Consider rst BAYER (Figure 1). Obviously, a positive rm-specic innovation has a higher impact on the beta as a negative one of the same size. This observation held for the majority of the analysed series, with some exceptions being COMMERZBANK, DRESDNER BANK and MANNESMANN. The asymmetry is even more distinct for SIEMENS (Figure 2). It should be noted that the leverage eect predicts a higher impact of negative shocks on volatility, so the signs are reverted. Apparently rm-specic news may have a dierent type of impact on volatility and on systematic 11

13 risk. Of course, this type of asymmetry can not be found for HOECHST (Figure 3), since for this series we selected the asset-symmetric model (M3). Now consider a market-relevant innovation, with rm-specic news set to zero. For BAYER (Figure 1) and HOECHST (Figure 3) we detect a similar type of asymmetry: good news to the market tends to decrease systematic risk of the individual assets more than bad news of the same size. This was also a typical result for all market-asymmetric models. It may be explained by a higher conditional covariance for negative shocks to the market than for positive ones. Again, note that for the market-symmetric model applied to SIEMENS (Figure 2) this asymmetry cannot be found. Next, we compare the BIRF implied by the estimation of four dierent models to MANNESMANN, see Figure 4. Recall from Table 1 that for this data set the double asymmetric model M1 had a much higher likelihood than the restricted models. It can be seen that the principal shape of the BIRF is similar, but that the restriction to symmetry has to be paid with less reliable predictions especially at the boundaries. For example, the symmetric model M4 predicts a drop of the beta to 1.2 over the next week when there is a positive rm-specic innovation of two standard deviations and a negative marketrelevant news of the same size. The double-asymmetric model M1, on the other hand, predicts only a small drop to about Finally, we look at the persistence of shocks to the betas. Recall from Table 2 that the two assets with largest eigenvalues are RWE and COMMERZBANK. The BIRF of these assets (not shown) converge extremely slowly to their unconditional betas. As for the combination of two independent shocks, there is still some moderate variability in the betas for most of the assets after 20 days (upper right plots of Figure 1 to 3). For HOECHST and BAYER, market-relevant news appears to have some inuence even after 50 days whereas rm-specic news has disappeared. The inverse is true for SIEMENS. The general conclusion is that portfolio management should consider the sensitivity of time-varying betas with respect to rm-specic and market-general news. In particular, good and bad news appear to have dierent impact not only on volatility, but also on the betas for many assets. This should be taken into account by using appropriate models such as the threshold GARCH model. 6 Conclusions We employ bivariate GARCH in Mean time series models in order to explain excess returns of 20 major German stocks in the light of the CAPM. Using daily data we allow for autocorrelation via a VAR(1) framework and to cope with asymmetry of conditional variances we introduce, estimate and evaluate competing threshold model specications. Asymmetry is found to be `signicant' in the sense that a symmetric bivariate volatility model involves considerable loss in accuracy of t. We provide only weak evidence in 12

14 favour of time depending (i.e. daily varying) risk premia for one half of the data sets under study. For the remaining series the hypothesis of constant risk premia is supported. To facilitate structural analysis of the estimated volatility specications we introduce beta impulse response functions. The estimated BIRF are used to indicate the dependence of one asset's beta on independent news appearing at some xed point in time. Dependence on such news is characterized through time and with respect to its possible sources, i.e. general market vs. asset specic news. The implications of competing specications of asymmetry are discussed with respect to some indicative examples. Within the CAPM framework, beta indicates asset specic systematic risk. We nd that for almost all series under study beta is aected dierently by positive and negative news. For news generated by the market beta is higher in the sequel of bad news relative to good ones. With respect to news emerging from the asset we nd the inverse relationship, i.e. beta is more aected by good news. As mentioned, the interpretation of the estimated BIRF depends on the volatility model under study. Taking general and asset specic innovations as complementary sources of asymmetry the most general volatility model is found to yield superior volatility estimates for 11 data sets. Our results are of interest for time series econometricians as well as for portfolio management in practice. Appendix Proof of Proposition 1: Let t = vech(" t " 0 t). Due to the symmetry of the distribution of 1;t and 2;t, we have E t?1 [ t I "1;t <0] = E t?1 [ t I "2;t <0] = 1 2 E t?1[ t ]; where E t [] is short for E[ j t]. The proof proceeds along the lines of the proof of Proposition 2.7 of Engle and Kroner (1995). Succesively plugging in conditional expectations, one arrives at E t? [ t ] = (I + Z + : : : + Z?2 )c + Z?1 1X i=1 G i?1 f( t?i? +1 ) with Z = A 1 + A 2 =2 + A 3 =2 + G and f( t ) = c + A 1 t + A 2 t I "1;t <0 + A 3 t I "2;t <0. The matrix Z converges to the zero matrix for! 1 if and only if all the eigenvalues of Z have modulus less than one, in which case E t? [ t ] converges in probability (as! 1) to (I? Z)?1 c. Q.E.D. 13

15 References Baba, Y., R.F. Engle, D.F. Kraft, K.F. Kroner (1990), Multivariate simultaneous generalized ARCH, mimeo, Department of Economics, University of California, San Diego. Black, F. (1976), Studies in stock price volatility changes, Proceedings of the 1976 Meeting of the Business and Economics Statistics Section, American Statistical Association, 177{181. Bollerslev, T. (1986), Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity, Journal of Econometrics 31, 307{327. Bollerslev, T., R.F. Engle, J.M. Wooldridge (1988), A capital asset pricing model with time varying covariances, Journal of Political Economy 96, 116{131. Bollerslev, T., J.M. Wooldridge (1992), Quasi{maximum likelihood estimation and inference in dynamic models with time{varying covariances, Econometric Reviews 11, 143{172. Drost, F., T. Nijman (1993), Temporal aggregation of GARCH processes, Econometrica 50, Engle, R. (1982), Autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity with estimates of the variance of U.K. ination, Econometrica 50, 987{1008. Engle, R.F., K.F. Kroner (1995), Multivariate simultaneous generalized ARCH, Econometric Theory 11, 122{150. Engle, R.F., D.M. Lilien, R.P. Robins (1987), Estimating time varying risk premia in the term structure: The ARCH-M model, Econometrica 55, 391{407. Glosten, L.R., R. Jagannathan, D.E. Runkle (1993), On the relation between the expected value and the volatility of the nominal excess return on stocks, Journal of Finance 48, 1779{1801. Hafner, C.M., H. Herwartz (1997), Structural analysis of multivariate GARCH models using impulse response functions, mimeo, Humboldt{Universitat zu Berlin, Germany. Hall, S.G., D.K. Miles, M.P. Taylor (1989), Modelling asset prices with time{varying betas, Manchester School 57, 340{356. Judge, G.G., R.C. Hill, W.E. Griths, H. Lutkepohl, T.C. Lee (1988), Introduction to the Theory and Practice of Econometrics, Wiley, New York. 14

16 Lintner, J. (1965), The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets, Review of Economis and Statistics 47, 13{37. Lutkepohl, H. (1991), Introduction to Multiple Time Series Analysis, Springer Verlag, Berlin. Lumsdaine, R.L. (1996), Consistency and asymptotic normality of the quasi maximum likelihood estimator in IGARCH(1,1) and covariance stationary GARCH(1,1) models, Econometrica 64, 575{596. Mills, T.C. (1993), The Econometric Modelling of Financial Time Series, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Sharpe, W.F. (1964),Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk, Journal of Finance 19, 425{

17 1 M1 2 M2 1 M2 2 M3 1 M3 2 M4 1 M4 2 Q(10) M1 ^ 2 lo 2lo ^ 2 lo 2lo ^ 2 lo 2lo ^ 2 lo min - max lo ALLIANZ BASF BAYER BMW COMMERZBANK BENZ DAIMLER DEGUSSA BANK DEUTSCHE BANK DRESDNER HOECHST KARSTADT LINDE MAN MANNESMANN PREUSSAG RWE SCHERING SIEMENS THYSSEN VOLKSWAGEN 1: Estimation and diagnostic results for alternative variance specications M1 to M4. Subscripts 1 and 2 indicate the inclusion and Table of from the econometric model respectively. "lo" is short for log{likelihood and 2lo is the LR{statistic relative to the most exclusion 16 general model. Q(10) is the multivariate Portmanteau statistic. Preferred Models are indicated with an asterisk.

18 eig. eig. ALLIANZ KARSTADT BASF LINDE BAYER MAN BMW MANNESMANN COMMERZBANK PREUSSAG DAIMLER BENZ RWE DEGUSSA SCHERING DEUTSCHE BANK SIEMENS DRESDNER BANK THYSSEN HOECHST VOLKSWAGEN Table 2: Estimates of the implied unconditional correlation (), unconditional beta () and the two largest eigenvalues of the `preferred' GARCH{specication (eig.) 17

19 i;0 m;0 i;0 m;0 i;0 t m;0 t Figure 1: BIRF estimates for BAYER (upper panel: B 5 ( 0 ) (left) and B 20 ( 0 ) (right) with respect to asset specic ( i;0 ) and general market innovations ( m;0 ); lower panel: B t ( 0 ) versus time). 18

20 i;0 m;0 i;0 m;0 i;0 t m;0 t Figure 2: BIRF estimates for SIEMENS (upper panel: B 5 ( 0 ) (left) and B 20 ( 0 ) (right) with respect to asset specic ( i;0 ) and general market innovations ( m;0 ); lower panel: B t ( 0 ) versus time). 19

21 i;0 m;0 i;0 m;0 i;0 t m;0 t Figure 3: BIRF estimates for HOECHST (upper panel: B 5 ( 0 ) (left) and B 20 ( 0 ) (right) with respect to asset specic ( i;0 ) and general market innovations ( m;0 ); lower panel: B t ( 0 ) versus time). 20

22 i;0 m;0 i;0 m;0 m;0 m;0 i;0 i;0 Figure 4: BIRF estimates for MANNESMANN (B 5 ( 0 ) obtained for volatility models M1 (upper left), M2 (upper right), M3 (lower left), M4 (lower right) with respect to asset specic ( i;0 ) and general market innovations ( m;0 )). 21

23 y y y y BAYER x SIEMENS x HOECHST x MANNESMANN x Figure 5: The estimated betas for BAYER, SIEMENS, HOECHST, and MANNESMANN (from top to bottom) for the preferred models. The time axis covers the estimation period 1974 to

Multivariate GARCH models.

Multivariate GARCH models. Multivariate GARCH models. Financial market volatility moves together over time across assets and markets. Recognizing this commonality through a multivariate modeling framework leads to obvious gains

More information

Financial Econometrics Lecture 6: Testing the CAPM model

Financial Econometrics Lecture 6: Testing the CAPM model Financial Econometrics Lecture 6: Testing the CAPM model Richard G. Pierse 1 Introduction The capital asset pricing model has some strong implications which are testable. The restrictions that can be tested

More information

A Non-Parametric Approach of Heteroskedasticity Robust Estimation of Vector-Autoregressive (VAR) Models

A Non-Parametric Approach of Heteroskedasticity Robust Estimation of Vector-Autoregressive (VAR) Models Journal of Finance and Investment Analysis, vol.1, no.1, 2012, 55-67 ISSN: 2241-0988 (print version), 2241-0996 (online) International Scientific Press, 2012 A Non-Parametric Approach of Heteroskedasticity

More information

Lecture 8: Multivariate GARCH and Conditional Correlation Models

Lecture 8: Multivariate GARCH and Conditional Correlation Models Lecture 8: Multivariate GARCH and Conditional Correlation Models Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20192 Financial Econometrics Winter/Spring 2018 Overview Three issues in multivariate modelling of CH covariances

More information

R = µ + Bf Arbitrage Pricing Model, APM

R = µ + Bf Arbitrage Pricing Model, APM 4.2 Arbitrage Pricing Model, APM Empirical evidence indicates that the CAPM beta does not completely explain the cross section of expected asset returns. This suggests that additional factors may be required.

More information

MEASURING THE CORRELATION OF SHOCKS BETWEEN THE UK AND THE CORE OF EUROPE

MEASURING THE CORRELATION OF SHOCKS BETWEEN THE UK AND THE CORE OF EUROPE Measuring the Correlation of Shocks Between the UK and the Core of Europe 2 MEASURING THE CORRELATION OF SHOCKS BETWEEN THE UK AND THE CORE OF EUROPE Abstract S.G.HALL * B. YHAP ** This paper considers

More information

GARCH Models. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. December Rossi GARCH Financial Econometrics / 50

GARCH Models. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. December Rossi GARCH Financial Econometrics / 50 GARCH Models Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia December 013 Rossi GARCH Financial Econometrics - 013 1 / 50 Outline 1 Stylized Facts ARCH model: definition 3 GARCH model 4 EGARCH 5 Asymmetric Models 6

More information

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1 Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1 John C. Chao April 25, 2017 1 These notes are based in large part on Chapter 16 of Stock and Watson (2011). They are for instructional purposes

More information

Ross (1976) introduced the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) as an alternative to the CAPM.

Ross (1976) introduced the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) as an alternative to the CAPM. 4.2 Arbitrage Pricing Model, APM Empirical evidence indicates that the CAPM beta does not completely explain the cross section of expected asset returns. This suggests that additional factors may be required.

More information

Volatility. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University

Volatility. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University Volatility Gerald P. Dwyer Clemson University February 2016 Outline 1 Volatility Characteristics of Time Series Heteroskedasticity Simpler Estimation Strategies Exponentially Weighted Moving Average Use

More information

The Size and Power of Four Tests for Detecting Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity in the Presence of Serial Correlation

The Size and Power of Four Tests for Detecting Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity in the Presence of Serial Correlation The Size and Power of Four s for Detecting Conditional Heteroskedasticity in the Presence of Serial Correlation A. Stan Hurn Department of Economics Unversity of Melbourne Australia and A. David McDonald

More information

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, SAN DIEGO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, SAN DIEGO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS 89-57R UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, SAN DIEGO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MULTIVARIATE SIMULTANEOUS GENERALIZED ARCH BY ROBERT F. ENGLE AND KENNETH F. KRONER DISCUSSION PAPER 89-57R JULY 1993 Multivariate Simultaneous

More information

Lecture 6: Univariate Volatility Modelling: ARCH and GARCH Models

Lecture 6: Univariate Volatility Modelling: ARCH and GARCH Models Lecture 6: Univariate Volatility Modelling: ARCH and GARCH Models Prof. Massimo Guidolin 019 Financial Econometrics Winter/Spring 018 Overview ARCH models and their limitations Generalized ARCH models

More information

ECONOMICS 7200 MODERN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Econometric Theory and Applications

ECONOMICS 7200 MODERN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Econometric Theory and Applications ECONOMICS 7200 MODERN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Econometric Theory and Applications Yongmiao Hong Department of Economics & Department of Statistical Sciences Cornell University Spring 2019 Time and uncertainty

More information

Analytical derivates of the APARCH model

Analytical derivates of the APARCH model Analytical derivates of the APARCH model Sébastien Laurent Forthcoming in Computational Economics October 24, 2003 Abstract his paper derives analytical expressions for the score of the APARCH model of

More information

APPLIED TIME SERIES ECONOMETRICS

APPLIED TIME SERIES ECONOMETRICS APPLIED TIME SERIES ECONOMETRICS Edited by HELMUT LÜTKEPOHL European University Institute, Florence MARKUS KRÄTZIG Humboldt University, Berlin CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS Contents Preface Notation and Abbreviations

More information

Diagnostic Test for GARCH Models Based on Absolute Residual Autocorrelations

Diagnostic Test for GARCH Models Based on Absolute Residual Autocorrelations Diagnostic Test for GARCH Models Based on Absolute Residual Autocorrelations Farhat Iqbal Department of Statistics, University of Balochistan Quetta-Pakistan farhatiqb@gmail.com Abstract In this paper

More information

1 Phelix spot and futures returns: descriptive statistics

1 Phelix spot and futures returns: descriptive statistics MULTIVARIATE VOLATILITY MODELING OF ELECTRICITY FUTURES: ONLINE APPENDIX Luc Bauwens 1, Christian Hafner 2, and Diane Pierret 3 October 13, 2011 1 Phelix spot and futures returns: descriptive statistics

More information

Inference in VARs with Conditional Heteroskedasticity of Unknown Form

Inference in VARs with Conditional Heteroskedasticity of Unknown Form Inference in VARs with Conditional Heteroskedasticity of Unknown Form Ralf Brüggemann a Carsten Jentsch b Carsten Trenkler c University of Konstanz University of Mannheim University of Mannheim IAB Nuremberg

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN 0819-64 ISBN 0 7340 616 1 THE UNIVERSITY OF MELBOURNE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPER NUMBER 959 FEBRUARY 006 TESTING FOR RATE-DEPENDENCE AND ASYMMETRY IN INFLATION UNCERTAINTY: EVIDENCE FROM

More information

The Bond Pricing Implications of Rating-Based Capital Requirements. Internet Appendix. This Version: December Abstract

The Bond Pricing Implications of Rating-Based Capital Requirements. Internet Appendix. This Version: December Abstract The Bond Pricing Implications of Rating-Based Capital Requirements Internet Appendix This Version: December 2017 Abstract This Internet Appendix examines the robustness of our main results and presents

More information

A Bootstrap Test for Causality with Endogenous Lag Length Choice. - theory and application in finance

A Bootstrap Test for Causality with Endogenous Lag Length Choice. - theory and application in finance CESIS Electronic Working Paper Series Paper No. 223 A Bootstrap Test for Causality with Endogenous Lag Length Choice - theory and application in finance R. Scott Hacker and Abdulnasser Hatemi-J April 200

More information

1 Introduction Impulse responses are standard tools in vector autoregressive (VAR) analyses. In this context an economic system of interest is describ

1 Introduction Impulse responses are standard tools in vector autoregressive (VAR) analyses. In this context an economic system of interest is describ March 18, 1999 Comparison of Bootstrap Condence Intervals for Impulse Responses of German Monetary Systems 1 Alexander Benkwitz, Helmut Lutkepohl Humboldt-Universitat Institut fur Statistik und Okonometrie

More information

the US, Germany and Japan University of Basel Abstract

the US, Germany and Japan University of Basel   Abstract A multivariate GARCH-M model for exchange rates in the US, Germany and Japan Wolfgang Polasek and Lei Ren Institute of Statistics and Econometrics University of Basel Holbeinstrasse 12, 4051 Basel, Switzerland

More information

A Guide to Modern Econometric:

A Guide to Modern Econometric: A Guide to Modern Econometric: 4th edition Marno Verbeek Rotterdam School of Management, Erasmus University, Rotterdam B 379887 )WILEY A John Wiley & Sons, Ltd., Publication Contents Preface xiii 1 Introduction

More information

Regression Analysis. y t = β 1 x t1 + β 2 x t2 + β k x tk + ϵ t, t = 1,..., T,

Regression Analysis. y t = β 1 x t1 + β 2 x t2 + β k x tk + ϵ t, t = 1,..., T, Regression Analysis The multiple linear regression model with k explanatory variables assumes that the tth observation of the dependent or endogenous variable y t is described by the linear relationship

More information

Properties of Estimates of Daily GARCH Parameters. Based on Intra-day Observations. John W. Galbraith and Victoria Zinde-Walsh

Properties of Estimates of Daily GARCH Parameters. Based on Intra-day Observations. John W. Galbraith and Victoria Zinde-Walsh 3.. Properties of Estimates of Daily GARCH Parameters Based on Intra-day Observations John W. Galbraith and Victoria Zinde-Walsh Department of Economics McGill University 855 Sherbrooke St. West Montreal,

More information

Financial Econometrics Return Predictability

Financial Econometrics Return Predictability Financial Econometrics Return Predictability Eric Zivot March 30, 2011 Lecture Outline Market Efficiency The Forms of the Random Walk Hypothesis Testing the Random Walk Hypothesis Reading FMUND, chapter

More information

A simple graphical method to explore tail-dependence in stock-return pairs

A simple graphical method to explore tail-dependence in stock-return pairs A simple graphical method to explore tail-dependence in stock-return pairs Klaus Abberger, University of Konstanz, Germany Abstract: For a bivariate data set the dependence structure can not only be measured

More information

Technical Appendix-3-Regime asymmetric STAR modeling and exchange rate reversion

Technical Appendix-3-Regime asymmetric STAR modeling and exchange rate reversion Technical Appendix-3-Regime asymmetric STAR modeling and exchange rate reversion Mario Cerrato*, Hyunsok Kim* and Ronald MacDonald** 1 University of Glasgow, Department of Economics, Adam Smith building.

More information

Time Series Modeling of Financial Data. Prof. Daniel P. Palomar

Time Series Modeling of Financial Data. Prof. Daniel P. Palomar Time Series Modeling of Financial Data Prof. Daniel P. Palomar The Hong Kong University of Science and Technology (HKUST) MAFS6010R- Portfolio Optimization with R MSc in Financial Mathematics Fall 2018-19,

More information

ECON3327: Financial Econometrics, Spring 2016

ECON3327: Financial Econometrics, Spring 2016 ECON3327: Financial Econometrics, Spring 2016 Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics (5th ed, 2012) Chapter 11: OLS with time series data Stationary and weakly dependent time series The notion of a stationary

More information

Department of Economics, UCSB UC Santa Barbara

Department of Economics, UCSB UC Santa Barbara Department of Economics, UCSB UC Santa Barbara Title: Past trend versus future expectation: test of exchange rate volatility Author: Sengupta, Jati K., University of California, Santa Barbara Sfeir, Raymond,

More information

Intro VEC and BEKK Example Factor Models Cond Var and Cor Application Ref 4. MGARCH

Intro VEC and BEKK Example Factor Models Cond Var and Cor Application Ref 4. MGARCH ntro VEC and BEKK Example Factor Models Cond Var and Cor Application Ref 4. MGARCH JEM 140: Quantitative Multivariate Finance ES, Charles University, Prague Summer 2018 JEM 140 () 4. MGARCH Summer 2018

More information

Arma-Arch Modeling Of The Returns Of First Bank Of Nigeria

Arma-Arch Modeling Of The Returns Of First Bank Of Nigeria Arma-Arch Modeling Of The Returns Of First Bank Of Nigeria Emmanuel Alphonsus Akpan Imoh Udo Moffat Department of Mathematics and Statistics University of Uyo, Nigeria Ntiedo Bassey Ekpo Department of

More information

Multivariate Time Series: VAR(p) Processes and Models

Multivariate Time Series: VAR(p) Processes and Models Multivariate Time Series: VAR(p) Processes and Models A VAR(p) model, for p > 0 is X t = φ 0 + Φ 1 X t 1 + + Φ p X t p + A t, where X t, φ 0, and X t i are k-vectors, Φ 1,..., Φ p are k k matrices, with

More information

Multivariate Time Series Analysis and Its Applications [Tsay (2005), chapter 8]

Multivariate Time Series Analysis and Its Applications [Tsay (2005), chapter 8] 1 Multivariate Time Series Analysis and Its Applications [Tsay (2005), chapter 8] Insights: Price movements in one market can spread easily and instantly to another market [economic globalization and internet

More information

Determining and Forecasting High-Frequency Value-at-Risk by Using Lévy Processes

Determining and Forecasting High-Frequency Value-at-Risk by Using Lévy Processes Determining and Forecasting High-Frequency Value-at-Risk by Using Lévy Processes W ei Sun 1, Svetlozar Rachev 1,2, F rank J. F abozzi 3 1 Institute of Statistics and Mathematical Economics, University

More information

Projektpartner. Sonderforschungsbereich 386, Paper 163 (1999) Online unter:

Projektpartner. Sonderforschungsbereich 386, Paper 163 (1999) Online unter: Toutenburg, Shalabh: Estimation of Regression Coefficients Subject to Exact Linear Restrictions when some Observations are Missing and Balanced Loss Function is Used Sonderforschungsbereich 386, Paper

More information

Generalized Autoregressive Score Models

Generalized Autoregressive Score Models Generalized Autoregressive Score Models by: Drew Creal, Siem Jan Koopman, André Lucas To capture the dynamic behavior of univariate and multivariate time series processes, we can allow parameters to be

More information

A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED

A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED by W. Robert Reed Department of Economics and Finance University of Canterbury, New Zealand Email: bob.reed@canterbury.ac.nz

More information

Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework

Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework Online Appendix to the paper Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework October 5, 2015 Part I: Maturity specific shocks in affine and equilibrium models This Appendix present

More information

TESTING FOR CO-INTEGRATION

TESTING FOR CO-INTEGRATION Bo Sjö 2010-12-05 TESTING FOR CO-INTEGRATION To be used in combination with Sjö (2008) Testing for Unit Roots and Cointegration A Guide. Instructions: Use the Johansen method to test for Purchasing Power

More information

Normal Probability Plot Probability Probability

Normal Probability Plot Probability Probability Modelling multivariate returns Stefano Herzel Department ofeconomics, University of Perugia 1 Catalin Starica Department of Mathematical Statistics, Chalmers University of Technology Reha Tutuncu Department

More information

1. Introduction The Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedastic (ARCH) class of models introduced by Engle (1982) is widely used to capture the tempora

1. Introduction The Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedastic (ARCH) class of models introduced by Engle (1982) is widely used to capture the tempora GARCH for Irregularly Spaced Financial Data: The ACD-GARCH Model Eric Ghysels 1 Pennsylvania State University, Department of Economics 523 Kern Graduate Building University Park, PA 16802-3305, U.S.A.

More information

Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 3

Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 3 Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 3 Pairs Trading by Cointegration Haksun Li haksun.li@numericalmethod.com www.numericalmethod.com Outline Distance method Cointegration Stationarity

More information

This note introduces some key concepts in time series econometrics. First, we

This note introduces some key concepts in time series econometrics. First, we INTRODUCTION TO TIME SERIES Econometrics 2 Heino Bohn Nielsen September, 2005 This note introduces some key concepts in time series econometrics. First, we present by means of examples some characteristic

More information

Notes on Time Series Modeling

Notes on Time Series Modeling Notes on Time Series Modeling Garey Ramey University of California, San Diego January 17 1 Stationary processes De nition A stochastic process is any set of random variables y t indexed by t T : fy t g

More information

Stock index returns density prediction using GARCH models: Frequentist or Bayesian estimation?

Stock index returns density prediction using GARCH models: Frequentist or Bayesian estimation? MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Stock index returns density prediction using GARCH models: Frequentist or Bayesian estimation? Ardia, David; Lennart, Hoogerheide and Nienke, Corré aeris CAPITAL AG,

More information

Revisiting the returns-volume relationship: Time variation, alternative measures and the nancial crisis

Revisiting the returns-volume relationship: Time variation, alternative measures and the nancial crisis *Manuscript Click here to view linked References Revisiting the returns-volume relationship: Time variation, alternative measures and the nancial crisis Steve Cook ; y and Duncan Watson z September 20,

More information

New Introduction to Multiple Time Series Analysis

New Introduction to Multiple Time Series Analysis Helmut Lütkepohl New Introduction to Multiple Time Series Analysis With 49 Figures and 36 Tables Springer Contents 1 Introduction 1 1.1 Objectives of Analyzing Multiple Time Series 1 1.2 Some Basics 2

More information

Thomas J. Fisher. Research Statement. Preliminary Results

Thomas J. Fisher. Research Statement. Preliminary Results Thomas J. Fisher Research Statement Preliminary Results Many applications of modern statistics involve a large number of measurements and can be considered in a linear algebra framework. In many of these

More information

MFE Financial Econometrics 2018 Final Exam Model Solutions

MFE Financial Econometrics 2018 Final Exam Model Solutions MFE Financial Econometrics 2018 Final Exam Model Solutions Tuesday 12 th March, 2019 1. If (X, ε) N (0, I 2 ) what is the distribution of Y = µ + β X + ε? Y N ( µ, β 2 + 1 ) 2. What is the Cramer-Rao lower

More information

Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods

Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods Robert V. Breunig Centre for Economic Policy Research, Research School of Social Sciences and School of

More information

JOURNAL OF MANAGEMENT SCIENCES IN CHINA. R t. t = 0 + R t - 1, R t - 2, ARCH. j 0, j = 1,2,, p

JOURNAL OF MANAGEMENT SCIENCES IN CHINA. R t. t = 0 + R t - 1, R t - 2, ARCH. j 0, j = 1,2,, p 6 2 2003 4 JOURNAL OF MANAGEMENT SCIENCES IN CHINA Vol 6 No 2 Apr 2003 GARCH ( 300072) : ARCH GARCH GARCH GARCH : ; GARCH ; ; :F830 :A :1007-9807 (2003) 02-0068 - 06 0 2 t = 0 + 2 i t - i = 0 +( L) 2 t

More information

Revisiting linear and non-linear methodologies for time series prediction - application to ESTSP 08 competition data

Revisiting linear and non-linear methodologies for time series prediction - application to ESTSP 08 competition data Revisiting linear and non-linear methodologies for time series - application to ESTSP 08 competition data Madalina Olteanu Universite Paris 1 - SAMOS CES 90 Rue de Tolbiac, 75013 Paris - France Abstract.

More information

The GARCH Analysis of YU EBAO Annual Yields Weiwei Guo1,a

The GARCH Analysis of YU EBAO Annual Yields Weiwei Guo1,a 2nd Workshop on Advanced Research and Technology in Industry Applications (WARTIA 2016) The GARCH Analysis of YU EBAO Annual Yields Weiwei Guo1,a 1 Longdong University,Qingyang,Gansu province,745000 a

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN 0819-2642 ISBN 0 7340 2601 3 THE UNIVERSITY OF MELBOURNE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPER NUMBER 945 AUGUST 2005 TESTING FOR ASYMMETRY IN INTEREST RATE VOLATILITY IN THE PRESENCE OF A NEGLECTED

More information

Bootstrap tests of multiple inequality restrictions on variance ratios

Bootstrap tests of multiple inequality restrictions on variance ratios Economics Letters 91 (2006) 343 348 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Bootstrap tests of multiple inequality restrictions on variance ratios Jeff Fleming a, Chris Kirby b, *, Barbara Ostdiek a a Jones Graduate

More information

Network Connectivity and Systematic Risk

Network Connectivity and Systematic Risk Network Connectivity and Systematic Risk Monica Billio 1 Massimiliano Caporin 2 Roberto Panzica 3 Loriana Pelizzon 1,3 1 University Ca Foscari Venezia (Italy) 2 University of Padova (Italy) 3 Goethe University

More information

Title. Description. var intro Introduction to vector autoregressive models

Title. Description. var intro Introduction to vector autoregressive models Title var intro Introduction to vector autoregressive models Description Stata has a suite of commands for fitting, forecasting, interpreting, and performing inference on vector autoregressive (VAR) models

More information

Financial Econometrics

Financial Econometrics Financial Econometrics Multivariate Time Series Analysis: VAR Gerald P. Dwyer Trinity College, Dublin January 2013 GPD (TCD) VAR 01/13 1 / 25 Structural equations Suppose have simultaneous system for supply

More information

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models Fall 22 Contents Introduction 2. An illustrative example........................... 2.2 Discussion...................................

More information

Lecture 9: Markov Switching Models

Lecture 9: Markov Switching Models Lecture 9: Markov Switching Models Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20192 Financial Econometrics Winter/Spring 2018 Overview Defining a Markov Switching VAR model Structure and mechanics of Markov Switching: from

More information

Heteroskedasticity in Time Series

Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Figure: Time Series of Daily NYSE Returns. 206 / 285 Key Fact 1: Stock Returns are Approximately Serially Uncorrelated Figure: Correlogram of Daily Stock Market Returns.

More information

GMM-based inference in the AR(1) panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails

GMM-based inference in the AR(1) panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails GMM-based inference in the AR() panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails Edith Madsen entre for Applied Microeconometrics (AM) Department of Economics, University of openhagen,

More information

Web Appendix to Multivariate High-Frequency-Based Volatility (HEAVY) Models

Web Appendix to Multivariate High-Frequency-Based Volatility (HEAVY) Models Web Appendix to Multivariate High-Frequency-Based Volatility (HEAVY) Models Diaa Noureldin Department of Economics, University of Oxford, & Oxford-Man Institute, Eagle House, Walton Well Road, Oxford OX

More information

Nonsense Regressions due to Neglected Time-varying Means

Nonsense Regressions due to Neglected Time-varying Means Nonsense Regressions due to Neglected Time-varying Means Uwe Hassler Free University of Berlin Institute of Statistics and Econometrics Boltzmannstr. 20 D-14195 Berlin Germany email: uwe@wiwiss.fu-berlin.de

More information

Combining Macroeconomic Models for Prediction

Combining Macroeconomic Models for Prediction Combining Macroeconomic Models for Prediction John Geweke University of Technology Sydney 15th Australasian Macro Workshop April 8, 2010 Outline 1 Optimal prediction pools 2 Models and data 3 Optimal pools

More information

International Monetary Policy Spillovers

International Monetary Policy Spillovers International Monetary Policy Spillovers Dennis Nsafoah Department of Economics University of Calgary Canada November 1, 2017 1 Abstract This paper uses monthly data (from January 1997 to April 2017) to

More information

ECONOMETRIC REVIEWS, 5(1), (1986) MODELING THE PERSISTENCE OF CONDITIONAL VARIANCES: A COMMENT

ECONOMETRIC REVIEWS, 5(1), (1986) MODELING THE PERSISTENCE OF CONDITIONAL VARIANCES: A COMMENT ECONOMETRIC REVIEWS, 5(1), 51-56 (1986) MODELING THE PERSISTENCE OF CONDITIONAL VARIANCES: A COMMENT Professors Engle and Bollerslev have delivered an excellent blend of "forest" and "trees"; their important

More information

Economics 472. Lecture 10. where we will refer to y t as a m-vector of endogenous variables, x t as a q-vector of exogenous variables,

Economics 472. Lecture 10. where we will refer to y t as a m-vector of endogenous variables, x t as a q-vector of exogenous variables, University of Illinois Fall 998 Department of Economics Roger Koenker Economics 472 Lecture Introduction to Dynamic Simultaneous Equation Models In this lecture we will introduce some simple dynamic simultaneous

More information

Discussion of Bootstrap prediction intervals for linear, nonlinear, and nonparametric autoregressions, by Li Pan and Dimitris Politis

Discussion of Bootstrap prediction intervals for linear, nonlinear, and nonparametric autoregressions, by Li Pan and Dimitris Politis Discussion of Bootstrap prediction intervals for linear, nonlinear, and nonparametric autoregressions, by Li Pan and Dimitris Politis Sílvia Gonçalves and Benoit Perron Département de sciences économiques,

More information

Calculation of maximum entropy densities with application to income distribution

Calculation of maximum entropy densities with application to income distribution Journal of Econometrics 115 (2003) 347 354 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Calculation of maximum entropy densities with application to income distribution Ximing Wu Department of Agricultural and Resource

More information

MODELLING TIME SERIES WITH CONDITIONAL HETEROSCEDASTICITY

MODELLING TIME SERIES WITH CONDITIONAL HETEROSCEDASTICITY MODELLING TIME SERIES WITH CONDITIONAL HETEROSCEDASTICITY The simple ARCH Model Eva Rubliková Ekonomická univerzita Bratislava Manuela Magalhães Hill Department of Quantitative Methods, INSTITUTO SUPERIOR

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE COLLEGE OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CANTERBURY CHRISTCHURCH, NEW ZEALAND

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE COLLEGE OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CANTERBURY CHRISTCHURCH, NEW ZEALAND DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE COLLEGE OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CANTERBURY CHRISTCHURCH, NEW ZEALAND Discussion of Principal Volatility Component Analysis by Yu-Pin Hu and Ruey Tsay

More information

When is a copula constant? A test for changing relationships

When is a copula constant? A test for changing relationships When is a copula constant? A test for changing relationships Fabio Busetti and Andrew Harvey Bank of Italy and University of Cambridge November 2007 usetti and Harvey (Bank of Italy and University of Cambridge)

More information

Financial Econometrics

Financial Econometrics Financial Econometrics Nonlinear time series analysis Gerald P. Dwyer Trinity College, Dublin January 2016 Outline 1 Nonlinearity Does nonlinearity matter? Nonlinear models Tests for nonlinearity Forecasting

More information

CONTAGION VERSUS FLIGHT TO QUALITY IN FINANCIAL MARKETS

CONTAGION VERSUS FLIGHT TO QUALITY IN FINANCIAL MARKETS EVA IV, CONTAGION VERSUS FLIGHT TO QUALITY IN FINANCIAL MARKETS Jose Olmo Department of Economics City University, London (joint work with Jesús Gonzalo, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid) 4th Conference

More information

DYNAMIC CONDITIONAL CORRELATIONS FOR ASYMMETRIC PROCESSES

DYNAMIC CONDITIONAL CORRELATIONS FOR ASYMMETRIC PROCESSES J. Japan Statist. Soc. Vol. 41 No. 2 2011 143 157 DYNAMIC CONDITIONAL CORRELATIONS FOR ASYMMETRIC PROCESSES Manabu Asai* and Michael McAleer** *** **** ***** The paper develops a new Dynamic Conditional

More information

Sample Exam Questions for Econometrics

Sample Exam Questions for Econometrics Sample Exam Questions for Econometrics 1 a) What is meant by marginalisation and conditioning in the process of model reduction within the dynamic modelling tradition? (30%) b) Having derived a model for

More information

ECON4515 Finance theory 1 Diderik Lund, 5 May Perold: The CAPM

ECON4515 Finance theory 1 Diderik Lund, 5 May Perold: The CAPM Perold: The CAPM Perold starts with a historical background, the development of portfolio theory and the CAPM. Points out that until 1950 there was no theory to describe the equilibrium determination of

More information

Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme?

Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme? MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme? Kim Hyeongwoo Auburn University April 2009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/17014/ MPRA Paper No. 17014,

More information

Heteroskedasticity-Robust Inference in Finite Samples

Heteroskedasticity-Robust Inference in Finite Samples Heteroskedasticity-Robust Inference in Finite Samples Jerry Hausman and Christopher Palmer Massachusetts Institute of Technology December 011 Abstract Since the advent of heteroskedasticity-robust standard

More information

THE LONG-RUN DETERMINANTS OF MONEY DEMAND IN SLOVAKIA MARTIN LUKÁČIK - ADRIANA LUKÁČIKOVÁ - KAROL SZOMOLÁNYI

THE LONG-RUN DETERMINANTS OF MONEY DEMAND IN SLOVAKIA MARTIN LUKÁČIK - ADRIANA LUKÁČIKOVÁ - KAROL SZOMOLÁNYI 92 Multiple Criteria Decision Making XIII THE LONG-RUN DETERMINANTS OF MONEY DEMAND IN SLOVAKIA MARTIN LUKÁČIK - ADRIANA LUKÁČIKOVÁ - KAROL SZOMOLÁNYI Abstract: The paper verifies the long-run determinants

More information

Impulse Response Analysis. Helmut Lutkepohl and Jorg Breitung. Institut fur Statistik und Okonometrie. Humboldt{Universitat zu Berlin

Impulse Response Analysis. Helmut Lutkepohl and Jorg Breitung. Institut fur Statistik und Okonometrie. Humboldt{Universitat zu Berlin October 16, 1996 Impulse Response Analysis of Vector Autoregressive Processes by Helmut Lutkepohl and Jorg Breitung Institut fur Statistik und Okonometrie Humboldt{Universitat zu Berlin Spandauer Str.

More information

Oil price and macroeconomy in Russia. Abstract

Oil price and macroeconomy in Russia. Abstract Oil price and macroeconomy in Russia Katsuya Ito Fukuoka University Abstract In this note, using the VEC model we attempt to empirically investigate the effects of oil price and monetary shocks on the

More information

Recovering Copulae from Conditional Quantiles

Recovering Copulae from Conditional Quantiles Wolfgang K. Härdle Chen Huang Alexander Ristig Ladislaus von Bortkiewicz Chair of Statistics C.A.S.E. Center for Applied Statistics and Economics HumboldtUniversität zu Berlin http://lvb.wiwi.hu-berlin.de

More information

A simple nonparametric test for structural change in joint tail probabilities SFB 823. Discussion Paper. Walter Krämer, Maarten van Kampen

A simple nonparametric test for structural change in joint tail probabilities SFB 823. Discussion Paper. Walter Krämer, Maarten van Kampen SFB 823 A simple nonparametric test for structural change in joint tail probabilities Discussion Paper Walter Krämer, Maarten van Kampen Nr. 4/2009 A simple nonparametric test for structural change in

More information

Vector Autoregressive Model. Vector Autoregressions II. Estimation of Vector Autoregressions II. Estimation of Vector Autoregressions I.

Vector Autoregressive Model. Vector Autoregressions II. Estimation of Vector Autoregressions II. Estimation of Vector Autoregressions I. Vector Autoregressive Model Vector Autoregressions II Empirical Macroeconomics - Lect 2 Dr. Ana Beatriz Galvao Queen Mary University of London January 2012 A VAR(p) model of the m 1 vector of time series

More information

Estimation of Vector Error Correction Model with GARCH Errors. Koichi Maekawa Hiroshima University of Economics

Estimation of Vector Error Correction Model with GARCH Errors. Koichi Maekawa Hiroshima University of Economics Estimation of Vector Error Correction Model with GARCH Errors Koichi Maekawa Hiroshima University of Economics Kusdhianto Setiawan Hiroshima University of Economics and Gadjah Mada University Abstract

More information

The Instability of Correlations: Measurement and the Implications for Market Risk

The Instability of Correlations: Measurement and the Implications for Market Risk The Instability of Correlations: Measurement and the Implications for Market Risk Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20254 Advanced Quantitative Methods for Asset Pricing and Structuring Winter/Spring 2018 Threshold

More information

Econ671 Factor Models: Principal Components

Econ671 Factor Models: Principal Components Econ671 Factor Models: Principal Components Jun YU April 8, 2016 Jun YU () Econ671 Factor Models: Principal Components April 8, 2016 1 / 59 Factor Models: Principal Components Learning Objectives 1. Show

More information

SFB 823. A simple and focused backtest of value at risk. Discussion Paper. Walter Krämer, Dominik Wied

SFB 823. A simple and focused backtest of value at risk. Discussion Paper. Walter Krämer, Dominik Wied SFB 823 A simple and focused backtest of value at risk Discussion Paper Walter Krämer, Dominik Wied Nr. 17/2015 A simple and focused backtest of value at risk 1 by Walter Krämer and Dominik Wied Fakultät

More information

International Symposium on Mathematical Sciences & Computing Research (ismsc) 2015 (ismsc 15)

International Symposium on Mathematical Sciences & Computing Research (ismsc) 2015 (ismsc 15) Model Performance Between Linear Vector Autoregressive and Markov Switching Vector Autoregressive Models on Modelling Structural Change in Time Series Data Phoong Seuk Wai Department of Economics Facultyof

More information

Specication Search and Stability Analysis. J. del Hoyo. J. Guillermo Llorente 1. This version: May 10, 1999

Specication Search and Stability Analysis. J. del Hoyo. J. Guillermo Llorente 1. This version: May 10, 1999 Specication Search and Stability Analysis J. del Hoyo J. Guillermo Llorente 1 Universidad Autonoma de Madrid This version: May 10, 1999 1 We are grateful for helpful comments to Richard Watt, and seminar

More information

A Test of Cointegration Rank Based Title Component Analysis.

A Test of Cointegration Rank Based Title Component Analysis. A Test of Cointegration Rank Based Title Component Analysis Author(s) Chigira, Hiroaki Citation Issue 2006-01 Date Type Technical Report Text Version publisher URL http://hdl.handle.net/10086/13683 Right

More information

Cointegration Lecture I: Introduction

Cointegration Lecture I: Introduction 1 Cointegration Lecture I: Introduction Julia Giese Nuffield College julia.giese@economics.ox.ac.uk Hilary Term 2008 2 Outline Introduction Estimation of unrestricted VAR Non-stationarity Deterministic

More information

10. Time series regression and forecasting

10. Time series regression and forecasting 10. Time series regression and forecasting Key feature of this section: Analysis of data on a single entity observed at multiple points in time (time series data) Typical research questions: What is the

More information

Cointegration and Error Correction Exercise Class, Econometrics II

Cointegration and Error Correction Exercise Class, Econometrics II u n i v e r s i t y o f c o p e n h a g e n Faculty of Social Sciences Cointegration and Error Correction Exercise Class, Econometrics II Department of Economics March 19, 2017 Slide 1/39 Todays plan!

More information