On the Conformity of Business Cycles Across EU Countries

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "On the Conformity of Business Cycles Across EU Countries"

Transcription

1 On the Conformity of Business Cycles Across EU Countries Jesper Gregers Linaa University of Copenhagen and EPRU First Version: July 2002 This Version: September 2004 Abstract This paper analyses the conformity of the European business cycles. While previous papers have searched for the existence of synchronous business cycles in the euro-zone, this paper takes the synchronization as given and instead focuses on the growth pattern over the business cycle and deepness of the business cycles. Three interesting results emerge: First, the growth pattern appears to be almost identical across countries with the exception of the UK and Denmark. Second, the business cycle can best be characterized as consisting of two phases. Third, the deepness of the EU business cycle appears to be homogenous across countries. This result challenges Friedman s ceiling hypothesis. Keywords: Business Cycles, European Union, Monetary Policy JEL Classifications: E32, E52 Thanks to Michael Artis, Thomas Lehman Jensen, Katarina Juselius, Claus Thustrup Kreiner and Torben Mark Pedersen for useful comments on issues dealt with in the paper. Thanks also to Mark Watson for providing me with the GAUSS version of the Bry-Boschan algorithm making it much easier for me to implement this in MATLAB. Address for correspondence: Jesper Linaa, Institute of Economics, University of Copenhagen, Studiestraede 6, 1455 Copenhagen K, jesper.linaa@econ.ku.dk, phone: , fax: The activities of EPRU (Economic Policy Research Unit) are financed by a grant from The Danish National Research Foundation.

2 1 Introduction Several papers have analysed whether the turning points of the European business cycles occur at the same point in time. Obviously, this is an important question in consideration to the possibility of the ECB of successfully conducting a single monetary policy in the euro-zone. The overall conclusion to this question is confirmative; synchronicity is present in the European business cycles, eg Artis et al. (1997, 1999), Artis and Zhang (1997). However, there are matters not treated in these analyses. Roughly speaking, one can claim that while the timing of turning points in business cycles is important for the timing of interest rate changes decided by the ECB, the evolvement of the business cycles between the turning points, including the amplitude of the business cycle, is of importance when the ECB is to choose the magnitude of these interest rate changes. Thus, this paper provides a first attempt to analyse these matters; specifically, industrial production and unemployment is analysed. As a starting point the paper adopts the characterisation of the business cycle as proposed by Burns and Mitchell (1946), which is assuming that business cycles consist of eight different phases. This makes the analysis tractable and at the same time the approach is a natural extension of the work provided by Artis et al. (1997) that relies on the Bry and Boschan (1971) (BB, hereafter) algorithm to identify turning points. First, it is tested whether the growth rates in the various stages of the business cycles are significantly different from the corresponding EU aggregate. Afterwards, light is shed on the depth of the business cycle, where depth is defined as troughs being further below trend than peaks are above trend, following the work of Sichel (1993). Despite the simple descriptive approach, which might be characterised measurement without theory, the analysis comes up with a number of interesting conclusions: First, industrial production appears to show a high degree of conformity across countries with regards to the growth pattern. Second, the same degree of conformity cannot be observed when the analysis is done for the labour market. 1

3 More specifically, the developments in the British and Danish labour markets appear to stand out from the EU aggregate. Third, testing whether it is appropriate to distinguish between eight phases reveals that for most countries it is sufficient to consider just two phases, viz. a contraction and an expansion phase. Following this road, however, yields the same conclusion; no great differences with regards to the growth pattern of industrial production, but again the cyclical development of unemployment in the UK and Denmark differs from the European pattern. Turning the focus to the depth of the business cycle, not many signs of deep business cycles in any country are found. This result is interesting, however, since it challenges the ceiling hypothesis suggested by Friedman (1969) and the results obtained by Goodwin and Sweeney (1993). The ceiling hypothesis predicts that growth in real output shows peaks that are relatively homogenous over time due to capacity constraints (the ceiling), while the magnitude of troughs should be very volatile. Given this hypothesis we should expect to find business cycles that go further below trend during contractions than they rise above trend during expansions. But in fact we do not. Linking the present analysis up with existing literature, this paper can be seen as a natural extension of Artis et al. (1997) in which the authors propose business cycle turning points for the G7 and a number of European countries. That paper finds evidence supporting the existence of a core group of European countries that have synchronous business cycles. Hence, the present paper can be seen as accepting the conclusion of Artis et al. (1997) and hence it takes the implied synchronicity of the business cycles as given. Other papers strongly related to the present analysis are Artis et al. (1999), Artis and Zhang (1997) as well as Krolzig and Toro (2001). The main purpose of these papers is to determine whether there is a common European business cycle, but in the sense of synchronicity. Artis et al. (1999) use regime switching models to identify the common cycle in Europe and obtain results in favour of a common cycle. Artis and Zhang (1997) conclude that the establishment of the ERM has created a higher degree of business cycle conformity, while Artis et al. (1997) establish turning 2

4 points in industrial production and use a binary measure to obtain the conclusion that a core group of European countries related to each other exists, but that the UK, Spain and Luxembourg stand out of this group. The present paper therefore contributes to the existing literature in the following areas: First, it goes a step further into the analyses of Artis et al. (1997, 1999) and Artis and Zhang (1997) and investigates the behaviour of the business cycle between the turning points taking the synchronization as given. Second, data for unemployment are used and it is shown that matters are not the same if labour market data are taken into account. Third, evidence that the ceiling hypothesis does not hold for the European industrial sector and labour market is provided. Finally, it contributes to the literature since it provides testable conclusions. Most results in this strand of the literature relies on more subjective results based on whether a given correlation coefficient is considered high or low. The rest of the paper goes as follows: In Section 2 the methodology is described, data is presented in Section 3 and Section 4 presents the findings. Section 5 concludes. 2 Methodology Two features of the European business cycles are examined. First, the growth patterns of the business cycles in the various EU member countries are characterised and compared. The comparison is done to the reference business cycle which is chosen to be the EU-15 aggregate. Second, it is examined whether the severity of contractions differs across countries. For this purpose, we rely on the measure of deepness also used by Sichel (1993). Hence, we employ the coefficient of skewness to analyse this. The first part relies on the classical measure of the business cycle, that is business cycles identified in non-detrended time series. Filtering time series always give rise to much scepticism and in order to avoid this, it is natural not to detrend data when it is not strictly necessary. In the latter part, however, it is necessary to 3

5 detrend data. The measure of skewness that will be employed for this operation is not defined for non-stationary time series. Therefore, the modern definition that regards business cycles as being movements around a trend is employed in the latter part. 2.1 Pattern of the European business cycles In order to characterise the growth pattern of a given business cycle, turning points of the corresponding time series must be identified. Official US peaks and troughs are determined by the NBER Business Cycle Dating Committee. The methodology behind this follows the (Burns and Mitchell, 1946, p. 144) definition in the sense that business cycles are not determined from the development in a single time series. However, the NBER only dates the US turning points. For this reason, the literature has used a number of different definitions in order to identify turning points for other countries. In an attempt to stay close to the NBER when choosing the turning points Bry and Boschan (1971), who developed an algorithm aimed at mimicking the peak and trough dates found by the NBER, are followed. In short, the algorithm is a mechanical way of determining turning points in highly smoothed time series, but it breaks with the NBER and Burns and Mitchell (1946) methodology since it relies on a single time series. Here a slightly modified version of this algorithm is used to find troughs and peaks in industrial production and unemployment in the various countries. 1,2 This way of picking the peaks and troughs can be criticised as being measurement without theory, but on the other hand, the way of picking the turning points can be argued to be more robust and transparent, e.g. Harding and Pagan (2002, 2003) compared to, for example, regime swithing models in the 1 See Appendix A for an overview of details on the Bry & Boschan methodology. The algorithm is modified since here each phase is restricted to having a length of at least 6 months instead of the usual 5 months. If a phase, e.g. a contraction, consisting of only 5 months is observed, there would not be enough observations for reserving two observations for Phase 1, one observation for Phase 2, Phase 3 and Phase 4 each, and one observation for Phase 5 this requires at least 6 observations. Remember that the two months surrounding a turning point are included in that particular phase, cf. Figure 1. 2 The algorithm is written in MATLAB and can be obtained from the author upon request. 4

6 spirit of Hamilton (1989). 3 Having found the troughs and peaks of the time series, it is straightforward to split the business cycles into sub-phases in accordance with Burns and Mitchell (1946, p. 144). More specifically, the three months centred on a peak are denoted as Phase 1, while the three months centred on a trough are denoted Phase 5. Phase 2, Phase 3 and Phase 4 are phases of equal length covering the time from Phase 1 to Phase 5, while Phase 6, Phase 7 and Phase 8 cover the time from Phase 5 to Phase 1. 4 Basically, Balke and Wynne (1995) apply the same technique in a different context when analyzing whether an RBC model is capable of mimicking symmetries of the US business cycle by estimating average growth rates in each phase. This approach is followed in order to obtain estimates of the average growth rates in each phase using phase dummies. Chow tests are employed to compare growth rates in the different phases with the reference business cycle. That is, for each country, i, the model below is estimated. µ µ µ µ γeu XEU 0 βeu εeu = + γ i 0 X i β i ε i Here γ EU and γ i are vectors containing the monthly growth rates of industrial productionintheeuandincountryi, X i is a (n i 8) matrix containing dummy variables describing which phase the corresponding growth rate belongs to, n i is the number of observations for country i, andε i is the error term. The OLS estimates of β EU and β i will be identical to the average growth rates in the corresponding phase. However, OLS must be applied with caution; error terms are likely to be serially correlated and standard inferences cannot be made since standard deviations are incorrectly computed by standard formulas. In order to correct the standard 3 A discussion of this issue between James D. Hamilton and Don Harding & Adrian Pagan is to be found in Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 27 (9), 2003, pp Symmetry is imposed in the sense that the length of Phase 2 is required to equal the length of Phase 4. Similarly Phase 6 and Phase 8 are required to be of equal length. Therefore the length of Phase 3 (Phase 7) may differ by 1 month from Phase 2 and Phase 4 (Phase 6 and Phase 8). This happens if the duration measured in months of an expansion/contraction phase divided by three is not an integer. 5 (1)

7 deviations the Newey-West covariance estimator is used. When constructing the heteroscedasticity and serial correlation consistent covariance matrix, Sichel (1993) and Newey and West (1987) are followed. This means allowing for a serial correlation up to order six, which results from taking the integer part of the sample size raised to the 1/3 power. On top of this, 15 comparisons are carried out; one between the business cycle in each member country, i, and the total EU-15 business cycle, by testing the hypotheses β j,eu = β j,i for j =1, 2,..., 8 where j is the number of the corresponding phase. 2.2 Deepness of the Business Cycles Measuring the severity of the typical contraction is done by constructing a measure of the deepness of the business cycle using the same method used by Sichel (1993) inhisstudyoftheusbusinesscycle. For this operation the modern definition of the business cycle is employed, and business cycles are considered to be movements around a trend. The reason is that the coefficient of skewness is not defined for non-stationary time series. Therefore the time series are filtered in order to separate the cycle from the trend. To ensure this distinction between a trend component and a cyclical component, the Hodrick-Prescott filter, cf. Hodrick and Prescott (1997), is used. The smoothing parameter is set equal to as suggested by Ravn and Uhlig (2002) when working with monthly observations, and the first and last three years of observations are eliminated due to the end-point problems related to the Hodrick-Prescott filter, cf. Baxter and King (1999) and Cogley and Nason (1995). The Hodrick-Prescott filter has been subject to much criticism, cf. Cogley and Nason (1995). However, it still appears to be widely used in this field of the literature due to the lack of definitively better alternatives, and an obvious advantage of applying this filter is therefore the possibility of comparing results with other studies. For the same reason the possibility of choosing the smoothing parameter in order to minimize the distortion of the filter, cf. Pedersen (2001), is abstained. 6

8 Deviating from commonly accepted values will make it less easy to compare with results obtained in other studies. Following Sichel (1993) the coefficient of skewness is used D (c) = 1 T ΣT t=1 (c t µ c ) 3 σ 3 c (2) where µ c is the mean of c t, σ c is the standard deviation of c t, which is the cyclical componentattimet, andt is the size of the sample. Figure 1 gives examples of three time series. The upper panel shows a time series, where the distance from the mean to the peak value is equal to the distance from the mean to the trough value. The middle panel shows the case where the distance from the mean to the peak is greater than the distance from the mean tothetrough,whiletheoppositecaseisillustratedinthelowerpanel. Thethree examples will provide values of D(c) equal to zero, greater than zero, and less that 7

9 zero. Figure 1 Symmetric, high and deep Business Cycles. Three examples 1 D(c)= D(c)> D(c)< An estimate of D (c) is obtained by regressing z t = (c t µ c ) 3 σ 3 c (3) on a constant. Regressing (3) on a constant reveals the average of {z 1,z 2,...,z T } as the parameter estimate, which is just equal to (2). However, the regression delivers standard deviations of the parameter estimates that can be used when testing hypotheses. Once again serial correlation is expected, and so the Newey- 8

10 West estimator is used. Analogous to (1) the model µ µ µ µ ZEU IEU 0 β d EU ε d = Z i 0 I Zi β d + EU i ε d (4) i is estimated. Z EU and Z i are vectors containing the values of z t,t=1, 2,..., T for the EU and country i, I EU and I i are dummy variables containing ones, while ε d EU and ε d i areerrorterms. AgainthecomparisonisdonebyapplyingtheChowtest, that is, testing the hypotheses that β d E15 = β d i. 3 Data Data for industrial production and unemployment in the EU countries in the period April l979 - December 2002, hereafter 1979:4-2002:12, is used. This beginning of the period is chosen to respect the findings of Artis and Zhang (1997) who conclude that the ERM has promoted the synchronisation of the European business cycles, and that the similarity of European business cycles is to be found in another regime after the introduction of the ERM. Data is drawn from OECD Main Economic Indicators provided by EcoWin, see Appendix B for specific codes and for mnemonics used in this paper. The time series for the EU-15 industrial production is a weighted average of the member countries industrial production, cf. Eurostat (2000). Looking at industrial production instead of GDP has two advantages. First, data for industrial production is released on a monthly basis while GDP is only released on a quarterly basis. Second, policy makers might at least in the short run pay more attention to this figure, since the release of industrial production leads the release of GDP. To some extent GDP figures can be said to contain a large amount of information already known before its release, and monetary policy may very well have been changed ahead of the release. This makes industrial production data interesting in a monetary policy context. The obvious disadvantage by using industrial production instead of GDP is that industrial production only covers the economic conditions in a part of the economy. Furthermore, the share of industrial output relative to overall output has, 9

11 in general, dropped over the last decades and therefore the aggregate business cycle may differ from the industrial cycle to a greater extent than years ago. In Appendix B the reader can verify the differences in growth between these two measures of the business cycle. Converting industrial production into quarterly observations (by averaging), taking logs to industrial production and GDP, differencing and calculating the correlation coefficient results in a correlation of Repeating this procedure, but using fourth differences, results in a correlation coefficient of Ideally, data for employment instead of unemployment should have been used. However, it is not possible to find employment data on a monthly basis for most of the European countries and for this reason unemployment, is used. If there were no supply effects in the labour market, unemployment would simply be the flip side of employment. However, over time the size of the labour force changes and that is not case. At same, unfortunately, it is not possible to find information on the number of persons unemployed in all of the 15 member countries, and no aggregate time series for EU-15 unemployment going back to April 1979 seems to exist. Data for Austria, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Luxembourg, Portugal, Spain, Sweden and UK is available, and EU unemployment is constructed by simply summing over the figures reported in each of these countries. As a last word on the data employed here, it would have been natural to include consumer price measures in the present analysis. However, the upward trend in (seasonally adjusted) consumer prices has been so strong that in most countries not even one full cycle is observed and for that reason this focus is dropped. The analysis is restricted to the members of the EU, which are the 12 countries participating in the EMU s third stage as well as the UK, Sweden and Denmark whohavedecidedtooptout. Itwouldbeobvioustoextendtheanalysistoinclude the Eastern European countries that are to join the EU and who one day even might be members of the euro-zone. However, the data material makes it impossible to include these countries. 10

12 4 Results 4.1 Pattern of the European business cycles After having identified the turning points and splitting the industrial production into the 8 phases the results presented in Table 1 are obtained. Table 1 Industrial production, average growth rates Phase 1 Phase 2 Phase 3 Phase 4 Phase 5 Phase 6 Phase 7 Phase 8 E15 0,10-0,26-0,20-0,30-0,35 0,27 0,26 0,22 (0,18) (0,18) (0,13) (0,11) (0,18) (0,06) (0,06) (0,06) DEU 0,03-0,46-0,19-0,38-0,16 0,34 0,45 0,27 (0,27) (0,14) (0,22) (0,17) (0,23) (0,10) (0,15) (0,11) FRA 0,15-0,19-0,11-0,35-0,07 0,14 0,24 0,20 (0,12) (0,12) (0,38) (0,21) (0,24) (0,08) (0,08) (0,08) ITA 0,13-0,26-0,03-0,31-0,32 0,42 0,42 0,38 (0,26) (0,21) (0,11) (0,12) (0,11) (0,16) (0,12) (0,11) ESP 0,08-0,49-0,23-0,15 0,58 0,19 0,31 0,41 (0,24) (0,23) (0,25) (0,34) (0,50) (0,15) (0,14) (0,12) NLD 0,18 0,14-0,27-0,39 1,09 0,14 0,36 0,05 (0,64) (0,34) (0,30) (0,36) (0,83) (0,19) (0,18) (0,13) BEL 0,84-0,42-0,21-0,30 0,33 0,31 0,35 0,19 (0,36) (0,22) (0,32) (0,26) (0,36) (0,24) (0,17) (0,14) AUT 0,41 0,02-0,24-0,31 0,19 0,29 0,63 0,46 (0,29) (0,24) (0,29) (0,23) (0,23) (0,14) (0,15) (0,17) LUX 1,01-0,29-0,05 0,31-0,42 0,51 0,36 0,47 (0,82) (0,47) (0,25) (0,53) (0,87) (0,26) (0,34) (0,29) FIN 0,67-1,08 0,32-0,34-1,25 0,52 0,38 0,60 (1,12) (0,64) (0,57) (0,34) (0,83) (0,13) (0,17) (0,19) PRT 0,25-0,08-0,62-0,28 1,04 0,54 0,50 0,35 (0,54) (0,25) (0,72) (0,68) (1,02) (0,36) (0,35) (0,21) GRC 0,24 0,03 0,05-0,31-0,26 0,32 0,09 0,42 (0,38) (0,41) (0,29) (0,27) (0,35) (0,17) (0,14) (0,17) GBR 0,05-0,42-0,59-0,07-0,05 0,29 0,25 0,18 (0,19) (0,16) (0,29) (0,22) (0,21) (0,11) (0,07) (0,06) SWE 0,39-0,11-0,21-0,11 0,19 0,59 0,33 0,32 (0,43) (0,60) (0,23) (0,16) (0,45) (0,16) (0,14) (0,16) DNK 0,46-1,38 0,00 0,30-1,47 0,59 0,30 0,49 (0,53) (0,53) (0,81) (0,39) (1,21) (0,31) (0,20) (0,30) It reports estimates of β i for i = EU, GER, FRA, ITA, SPA, NET, BEL, AUT,LUX,FIN,POR,GRE,UK,SWE,DENfrom (1). Examining Table 1 reveals only a few wrong signs in the estimates. This is hardly surprising since the method of dividing the time series into various phases dependent on the relative position of the particular phase to the previous peak (trough) and the next trough (peak) nearly defines the sign of growth. In contrast, the signs of the growth rates in Phase 1 and in Phase 5 are not obvious. Apriorithese should be expected to lie close to zero since these phases cover the period where growth goes from being negative (positive) to being positive (negative). However, remember that these phases include not only the turning points of the time series, but also its 11

13 two surrounding observations, and if these are not numerically equally large, the estimate should differ from zero. Furthermore, growth in the turning point will, in general, not be zero. Another conclusion to be drawn from Table 1 is that for the bigger countries almost no growth rates in any phase differs significantly from the EU-15 business cycle. 5 This is hardly surprising neither since the EU-15 industrial production by definition is a weighted average of industrial production in the individual member countries. In a monetary policy context this is, however, the problem in a nutshell; when attaching the largest weights to the largest countries before aggregating and using this aggregate for designing monetary policy, the risk of ignoring the economic development in the smaller countries arises. This was the subject of much debate over the years before the launch of the EMU s third stage and still is. Of course, the risk cannot be rejected from this analysis since industrial production is just one measure of the conformity of the business cycles, and at the same time it is a rather volatile one. However, it indicates that the European industry has a relatively high level of conformity. The most significant deviations from the EU-15 industrial cycle are found in the Austrian Phase 7 and the Danish Phase 2 these deviations can be found at the 5% level of significance. At the 10% level of significance, however, a number of phases stand out. Phase 5 (the trough) shows significant deviations in Spain, the Netherlands, Belgium and Austria, while Phase 6 stands out in Finland and Denmark. Furthermore, Phase 1 stands out in Belgium and Phase 8 stands out in Finland. It appears that the significant deviations are concentrated around the trough. That is when business cycles go from being contractive to expansive. The results indicate that this phase of the cycle is not as conform across countries as the remaining part of the cycle. Drawing special attention to the three countries not participating in the third stage of the EMU the UK, Sweden and Denmark the analysis does not reveal 5 Probabilities of F-tests can be found in appendix D. 12

14 much information pointing towards any circumstances that would make an entry into the third stage harder than for any other participating countries as far as the industrial growth pattern is concerned. As the most extreme case, Denmark differs in two phases when allowing for a 10 percent significance level. The Swedish and British cycles do not differ in any phase. For the British case, however, is worth noting that Artis et al. (1997) and Artis and Zhang (1997) find that peaks and troughs in the British cycle are not highly synchronised with the peaks and troughs in the core countries. But since, the present analysis has taken this synchronization as given and solely focuses on the underlying growth pattern, the results obtained here do not contradict any conclusions in the above mentioned studies. Drawing attention to the corresponding results for unemployment as presented in Table 2, it appears that the labour markets in the EU seem to differ a lot more across countries than the output from the industrial sector does. In particular, the UK seems to differ substantially from the EU. All phases but Phase 1, Phase 5 and Phase 6 differ at the 1% level of significance and indicate that the conformity between the British and the EU-15 business cycle is a poor one when talking about the labour market. At the 1% significance level France also turns out to differ in two phases, 6 and 7, while Germany differsinphase8. Atthe10%significance level it is worth noting that the three EU-15 member countries not participating in the third stage, the UK, Sweden and Denmark, are the countries with the most phases that differ. Sweden and Denmark each have three phases to differ. The results obtained so far have shown that industrial output differs relatively less across the EU member countries than the labour markets do. However, industrial production is a highly volatile figure and it might be worth testing whether the apparent high degree of conformity in the industrial cycles is a result of a real conformity or whether it is a result of a misspecification of the model by allowing for too many phases that are not found to be significantly different from each other. 13

15 Table 2 Unemployment, average growth rates Phase 1 Phase 2 Phase 3 Phase 4 Phase 5 Phase 6 Phase 7 Phase 8 E15 0,15-0,32-0,59-0,58-0,25 1,78 0,78 0,35 (0,12) (0,13) (0,13) (0,10) (0,10) (0,24) (0,14) (0,15) DEU 0,11-0,55-0,52-1,05-0,20 1,36 1,35 1,27 (0,16) (0,30) (0,10) (0,31) (0,20) (0,33) (0,53) (0,31) FRA 0,29-0,36-0,52-0,78-0,17 0,64 0,18 0,42 (0,12) (0,05) (0,26) (0,28) (0,15) (0,17) (0,13) (0,19) IRL 0,14-0,57-0,77-1,06-0,23 1,66 1,13 0,41 (0,18) (0,13) (0,20) (0,33) (0,28) (0,36) (0,20) (0,10) ESP -0,03-0,72-0,77-0,41-0,22 1,21 1,10 0,65 (0,08) (0,07) (0,15) (0,13) (0,11) (0,13) (0,33) (0,25) AUT 0,87-0,86-0,24-0,91-0,21 2,17 0,45 0,94 (0,47) (0,17) (0,30) (0,27) (0,26) (0,62) (0,29) (0,22) LUX 0,92-0,79 0,10-0,79 1,42 1,92 2,36 0,97 (0,47) (0,31) (0,54) (0,35) (1,11) (0,46) (0,42) (0,23) FIN -1,00-0,42-0,86-1,11-0,54 2,90 2,31 1,70 (1,22) (0,42) (0,41) (0,35) (0,54) (1,22) (1,13) (0,60) PRT -1,52-0,47-0,80-0,36 0,09 1,15 0,57 0,81 (1,51) (0,30) (0,19) (0,24) (0,21) (0,19) (0,31) (0,20) GBR 0,55-1,37-1,91-1,57 0,01 3,08 2,12 1,17 (0,39) (0,19) (0,12) (0,25) (0,26) (0,58) (0,42) (0,08) SWE 2,97-0,85-0,68 0,07-4,41 1,90 3,56 2,56 (1,71) (0,44) (0,57) (0,99) (2,15) (0,89) (0,82) (0,98) DNK -0,09-0,91-1,03-1,00 0,00 1,61 0,63 0,60 (0,50) (0,28) (0,20) (0,21) (0,28) (0,62) (0,19) (0,16) Standard deviations in parantheses Different from EU-15 growth at a 10 percentage significance level 5 percentage significance level 1 percentage significance level Therefore, the cycles are collapsed into just two phases; contractions (Phase 1) and expansions (Phase 2). With regards to industrial production, it can be seen that collapsing the 8 phases into just 2 phases only appears to be a problem for Denmark, cf. Appendix E. For Denmark it is found that at the 2% level of significanceitisnot appropriate to distinguish between just two phases. With regards to unemployment, this two-phase distinction is seen not to be appropriate for the EU because of the developments in Phase 6, Phase 7 and Phase 8 in Ireland, Austria, Luxembourg and the UK. However, when redefining the phases for industrial production, the same operation for unemployment is nevertheless performed. The results found in Table 3 do not reveal much new information compared to the results obtained in 14

16 Table 1. Table 3 Industrial Production and Unemployment, average growth rates Industrial production Unemployment Phase 1 Phase 2 Phase 1 Phase 2 EU (0.08) (0.04) (0.08) (0.17) GER (0.10) (0.07) (0.14) (0.23) FRA (0.09) (0.04) (0.14) (0.11) ITA (0.08) (0.07) - - SPA (0.14) (0.07) (0.08) (0.26) NET (0.17) (0.09) - - BEL (0.12) (0.10) - - AUT (0.12) (0.08) (0.18) (0.27) LUX (0.25) (0.16) (0.25) (0.23) FIN (0.27) (0.10) (0.20) (0.60) POR (0.20) (0.18) (0.16) (0.14) GRE (0.16) (0.09) - - UK (0.10) (0.05) (0.24) (0.47) SWE (0.19) (0.09) (0.44) (0.66) DEN (0.26) (0.14) (0.14) (0.22) IRE (0.15) (0.18) Standard deviations in parantheses Different from EU-15 growth at the 10 percent significance level 5 percent significance level 1 percent significance level It still shows a great deal of conformity in the European industrial cycle. Looking at unemployment, the UK still stands out from the EU. Both phases differ significantly from the EU aggregate. Furthermore, the contraction phase in Denmark and the expansion phases in France and Luxembourg differ at the 1% significance level. 4.2 Deepness of the Business Cycles Table 4 shows the results of estimating (2) for industrial production and unemployment. It appears that no coefficient is computed to be significantly different from the corresponding coefficient of the EU-15. Nor are any coefficients significantly different from zero. 15

17 Table 4 Coefficient of skewness Industrial production Unemployment EU (0.02) (0.02) GER (0.07) (0.05) FRA (0.02) (0.00) ITA (0.04) - SPA (0.08) (0.01) NET (0.05) - BEL (0.05) - AUT (0.04) (0.03) LUX (0.24) (0.06) FIN (0.25) (0.98) POR (0.14) (0.05) GRE (0.11) - UK (0.02) (0.21) SWE (0.13) (0.69) DEN (0.23) (0.02) IRE (0.01) Standard deviations in parantheses Different from EU-15 growth at the 10 percent significance level 5 percent significance level 1 percent significance level This latter result is interesting since it challenges the ceiling hypothesis suggested by Friedman (1969) and examined for a number of countries by Goodwin and Sweeney (1993). The ceiling hypothesis suggests that at times the economy is to be found at the limit of its capacity (the ceiling) with no further, or at least very modest, possibilities of increasing production. In these periods production is determined by the supply side of the economy. Most of the time, however, the economy is away from its potential output ceiling due to demand disturbances, but equilibrating forces and expansionary economic policy push the economy back. This is also the explanation for the Friedman (1969) result that the magnitude of an expansion is related to the magnitude of the preceding contraction, but that contractions are unrelated to the preceding expansions. As shown by Friedman (1993) a feature of the data in the ceiling case will be that if one considers real output in growth rates, one should expect to find peaks of the series that are relatively homogenous while 16

18 the troughs are extremely volatile. Hence we should expect to find deep business cycles. Goodwin and Sweeney (1993) find strong support for the ceiling hypothesis, while the present study does not, since it finds no evidence pointing towards deep business cycles. Before jumping to any conclusions in relation to the results of Goodwin and Sweeney (1993), though, one must note that the techniques for obtaining the result are not identical. The present approach involves no model, but simply relies on the coefficient of skewness, while Goodwin and Sweeney (1993) rely on the possibility of identifying an asymmetric error for efficiency in using factors when producing output. However, the studies also differ inthewaythatthe cyclicalcomponent isiden- tified. Goodwin and Sweeney (1993) rely on annual growth rates in GDP, while the present paper has so far relied on a Hodrick-Prescott measure of the cycle. Therefore, annual growth rates for industrial production as well as annual growth rates in thenumberofunemployedarecalculated,andthesameoperationsareperformed with these measures. However, this does not change the result that no coefficient is significantly different from zero. The results of this estimation are to be found in Appendix F. The results obtained here therefore question the robustness of the results obtained by Goodwin and Sweeney (1993). 5 Concluding remarks The analysis carried out involves dating the turning points of the European business cycle defined as the development in industrial production and in the number of unemployed. Once the turning points are determined the business cycles are split into sub phases in accordance with Burns and Mitchell (1946). Growth rates in these phases are compared and tested against the corresponding EU-15 measure. The analysis does not point towards much idiosyncrasy across countries with regards to industrial production, but apparently the dynamics on the British and Danish labour market do not follow the dynamics of the EU-15 labour market. The 17

19 reason why labour market dynamics are different in the UK and Denmark is very likely to be explained by the strictness of employment protection. According to OECD (1994, Table 6.5) employment protection in the EU was lowest in Denmark and third lowest in the UK. This finding seems highly consistent with the results here, saying that recessions measured by rising unemployment are significantly more severe in the UK and Denmark than in the EU. At the same time, however, unemployment also drops more sharply in these countries once the economy again expands. This is exactly what should be expected in a labour market with fewer frictions. This observation might be a good reason to involve the labour market when analysing the conformity of the European business cycle. Data for industrial production that indicates that the business cycle has a relatively high degree of conformity might give the wrong impression; it is always possible for a producer to slow down production in times of low demand, but the possibilities for producers to adjust the capacity over time are not identical. There are two reasons for this; first, the unemployment rate varies substantially across countries and labour hoarding arguments might be an issue in some countries while not in others. Second, the institutional setup might differ in a way that makes it a very expensive act to dismiss workers in some countries, while it can be done at almost no cost in other countries. The analysis also focuses on the depth of the typical recession in the European countries. Two conclusions emerge from this. First, no evidence on any countries having deeper business cycles than the EU-15 is found. Second, no evidence of any countries having business cycles that drop further below trend during contractions than they rise above trend during expansions is found. This latter result contradicts the Friedman (1969) ceiling hypothesis and the results obtained by Goodwin and Sweeney (1993). Gaining further knowledge about the similarity of the European business cycles is an important topic for future research. In order to satisfy monetary policy needs of all its member countries at the same time, the ECB must face relatively similar European business cycles. With regards to the implications for monetary policy 18

20 one must be careful, though; although we should expect that conformity of business cycles across the counties in the euro-zone is fundamental for the ECB to conduct an appropriate monetary policy for all countries, one must keep in mind that monetary transmissions differ from country to country due to, eg. the institutional setup in that particular country. Therefore an output gap of a given size might not imply the same price pressure in two different countries. Two extensions of the present work seem obvious. First, since the primary target of the ECB is to keep inflation below 2% in the medium term, more attention should be paid to similarity of the movements in consumer prices. However, for the present analysis, identifying classical turning points in consumer prices is an impossible task due to a very strong non-reversing upward drift in prices. No full cycle is found for a number of countries. Second, data for the Eastern European countries should be included since the enlargement of the EU is also very likely to lead to an enlargement of the EMU members group in the years to come. 19

21 6 Appendix A The Bry and Boschan (1971) algorithm PROCEDURE FOR PROGRAMMED DETERMINATION OF TURNING POINTS I. Determination of extremes and substitution of values. II. Determination of cycles in 12-month moving average (extremes replaced). A. Identification of points higher (or lower) than 5 months on either side. B. Enforcement of alternation of turns by selecting highest of multiple peaks (or lowest of multiple troughs). III. Determination of corresponding turns in Spencer curve (extremes replaced). A. Identification of highest (or lowest) value within ± 5 months of selected turn in 12-month moving average. B. Enforcement of minimum cycle duration of 15 months by eliminating lower peaks and higher troughs of shorter cycles. IV. Determination of corresponding turns in short-term moving average of 3 to 6 months, depending on MCD (months of cyclical dominance). A. Identification of highest (or lowest) value within ±5 months of selected turn in Spencer curve. V. Determination of corresponding turns in unsmoothed series. A. Identification of highest (or lowest) value within ±4 months, or MCD term, whichever is larger, of selected turn in short-term moving average. B. Elimination of turns within 6 months of beginning and end of series. C. Elimination of peaks (or troughs) at both ends of series which are lower (or higher) than values closer to end. D. Elimination of cycles whose duration is less than 15 months E. Elimination of phases whose duration is less than 5 months VI. Statement of final turning points. Source: Bry & Boschan (1971, Table 1, pp. 21). Requirement V.E is modified in this study: Instead of requiring a given phase to have a length of at least 5 months, in this study it is required to have a length of at least 6 months. If a phase, i.e. a contraction, consisting of only 5 months is observed, there would not be enough observations for reserving two observations for Phase 1, one observation each for Phase 2, Phase 3 and Phase 4, and one observation for Phase 5 this would require at least 6 observations. Remember that the two months surrounding a turning point are included in that particular 20

22 phase, cf. Figure 1. B Data sources All data are from the OECD Main Economic Indicators database provided by EcoWin Industrial production Country Code AUT Austria aut_prpein01_ixobsam.v BEL Belgium bel_prpein01_ixobsam.v DEN Denmark dnk_prpemn01_ixobsam.v FIN Finland fin_prpein01_ixobsam.v FRA France fra_prpein01_ixobsam.v GER Germany deu_prpein01_ixobsam.v GRE Greece grc_prpein01_ixobsam.v IRE Ireland irl_prpein01_ixobsam.v Country Code ITA Italy ita_prpein01_ixobsam.v LUX Luxembourg lux_prpein01_ixobsam.v NET Netherlands nld_prpein01_ixobsam.v POR Portugal prt_prpein01_ixobsam.v SPA Spain esp_prpein01_ixobsam.v SWE Sweden swe_prpein01_ixobsam.v UK UK gbr_prpein01_ixobsam.v EU EU-15 e15_prpein01_ixobsam.v 21

23 Notes Unemployment Country Code AUT Austria aut_unlvrg01_stsam.v DEN Denmark dnk_unlvrg01_stsam.v FIN Finland fin_unlvsu01_stsam.v FRA France fra_unlvrg01_stsam.v GER Germany deu_unlvrg01_stsam.v* West Germany deu_unlvrg01_stsam.v IRE Ireland irl_unlvrg01_stsam.v Country Code LUX Luxembourg lux_unlvrg01_stsam.v POR Portugal prt_unlvrg01_stsam.v* SPA Spain esp_unlvrg01_stsam.v SWE Sweden swe_unlvsu01_stsam.v UK UK gbr_unlvrg01_stsam.v *) Series for unemployment in Germany and Portugal were not seasonally adjusted. This was done by the X11 (multiplicative) module in EcoWin. 22

24 B.1 Industrial Production and GDP First differences GDP Industrial Production Fourth differences GDP Industrial Production

25 C Turning Points C.1 Industrial production Month EU GER FRA ITA SPA NET BEL AUT LUX GRE FIN POR UK SWE DEN IRE 1979:10 Peak 1979:11 Peak 1979:12 Peak Peak Peak Peak 1980:3 Peak Peak 1980:4 Peak 1980:9 Trough 1980:10 Trough 1980:11 Trough Trough 1980:12 Trough Trough 1981:4 Trough 1981:5 Trough 1981:7 Trough Peak 1981:8 Peak 1981:10 Peak 1981:12 Peak 1982:1 Peak 1982:2 Peak 1982:4 Peak 1982:7 Trough 1982:8 Trough Trough 1982:11 Trough Trough Trough Trough 1982:12 Trough Trough 1983:1 Trough 1983:5 Trough Trough 1984:1 Peak 1984:8 Trough 1985:1 Peak 1985:9 Peak 1985:11 Peak 1986:3 Trough Peak 1986:4 Peak Trough 1986:7 Peak 1986:8 Peak 1986:11 Trough 1987:1 Trough Peak Trough 1987:6 Trough 1987:10 Trough 1988:4 Trough 1988:12 Peak 1989:7 Peak Peak Peak 1989:8 Trough 1989:12 Peak 1990:2 Peak 1990:4 Peak 1990:6 Peak Peak 1990:8 Peak 1990:12 Peak 1991:1 Peak 1991:3 Trough 1991:6 Trough 1991:8 Trough 1991:12 Peak Peak 1992:2 Peak 1992:6 Peak 1992:12 Trough 1993:4 Trough 1993:5 Trough 1993:6 Trough 1993:7 Trough Trough Trough Trough 1993:8 Trough Trough 1993:10 Trough 1993:11 Trough 1994:12 Peak 1995:5 Peak 1995:6 Peak 1995:8 Peak 1995:10 Trough 1995:12 Peak 1996:1 Trough 1996:2 Trough 1996:5 Trough 1996:12 Trough 1997:10 Peak 1998:6 Peak 1998:7 Peak Peak 1998:12 Trough 1999:2 Trough Trough Trough 1999:6 Peak 1999:8 Peak 2000:4 Trough 2000:6 Peak 2000:10 Trough 2000:11 Peak Peak Peak Peak 2000:12 Peak Peak Peak Peak Peak 2001:2 Peak 2001:9 Trough Trough 2001:10 Trough 2001:11 Trough Trough Trough 2001:12 Trough Trough 2002:1 Trough 2002:2 Trough 2002:3 Peak 2002:4 Peak Peak 2002:5 Peak 2002:6 Peak 24

26 C.2 Unemployment Month EU GER FRA SPA AUT LUX FIN POR UK SWE DEN 1979:10 Peak Peak Trough 1979:11 Trough 1979:12 Trough Trough 1980:5 Trough Trough 1980:6 Trough 1982:11 Trough 1983:4 Peak 1983:6 Peak Peak 1983:7 Peak 1984:1 Trough 1984:2 Peak 1985:1 Trough 1985:5 Peak 1986:7 Peak Peak 1986:10 Trough 1986:11 Trough 1987:3 Peak Peak Peak 1987:12 Peak Peak 1988:3 Peak 1989:3 Trough 1989:6 Trough 1990:1 Trough 1990:5 Trough Trough 1990:9 Trough Trough 1991:1 Trough 1991:5 Trough 1992:7 Trough 1992:12 Peak 1993:6 Peak 1993:7 Peak 1994:1 Peak 1994:2 Peak 1994:4 Peak 1994:5 Peak Peak Peak 1994:12 Trough 1995:2 Trough 1995:7 Trough 1995:8 Trough 1996:3 Peak 1996:4 Peak 1996:12 Trough Peak 1997:5 Peak 1997:6 Peak 1998:2 Peak 1998:6 Peak 2000:4 Trough 2000:9 Trough 2000:11 Trough Peak 2001:2 Trough 2001:5 Trough Trough Trough 2001:7 Trough 2001:8 Trough 2002:3 Trough 25

27 D Testing whether growth phases and coefficients of deepness are equal to the corresponding values for EU-15 D.1 Pattern of the European business cycles - 8 Phases Probabilities of F-values for tests of growth beingequaltoeu-15growth Industrial production Phase 1 Phase 2 Phase 3 Phase 4 Phase 5 Phase 6 Phase 7 Phase 8 EU GER FRA ITA SPA NET BEL AUT LUX FIN POR GRE UK SWE DEN Unemployment Phase 1 Phase 2 Phase 3 Phase 4 Phase 5 Phase 6 Phase 7 Phase 8 EU GER FRA ITA SPA NET BEL AUT LUX FIN POR GRE UK SWE DEN

28 D.2 Pattern of the European business cycles - 2 Phases Probabilities for F-values for tests of growth beingequaltoeu-15growth Industrial production D.3 coefficient of skewness Phase 1 Phase 2 P(Ph.1=Ph.2) EU 0.00 GER FRA ITA SPA NET BEL AUT LUX FIN POR GRE UK SWE DEN Unemployment Phase 1 Phase 2 P(Ph.1=Ph.2) EU 0.00 GER FRA SPA AUT LUX FIN POR UK SWE DEN IRE Probabilities of F-values for tests of deepness being equal to EU-15 deepness Industrial production Unemployment EU GER FRA ITA SPA NET BEL AUT LUX FIN POR GRE UK SWE DEN IRE

29 E Specification tests Probabilities that expansion and contraction phases can be collapsed into one phase Industrial production P(Ph.2=Ph.3=Ph.4) P(Ph.6=Ph.7=Ph.8) EU GER FRA ITA SPA NET BEL AUT LUX FIN POR GRE UK SWE DEN Unemployment P(Ph.2=Ph.3=Ph.4) P(Ph.6=Ph.7=Ph.8) EU GER FRA IRE SPA AUT LUX FIN POR UK SWE DEN Probabilities whether Phase 1 is different from Phase 2 Industrial production Unemployment EU GER FRA ITA 0.00 SPA NET 0.06 BEL 0.02 AUT LUX FIN POR GRE 0.17 UK SWE DEN IRE

30 F Coefficient of skewness based on year-on-year growth rates Industrial production Unemployment EU (0.01) (0.02) GER (0.06) (0.06) FRA (0.01) (0.01) ITA (0.03) - SPA (0.05) (0.01) NET (0.02) - BEL (0.04) - AUT (0.03) (0.08) LUX (0.29) (0.04) FIN (0.15) (1.00) POR (0.08) (0.06) GRE (0.07) - UK (0.05) (0.17) SWE (0.10) (0.36) DEN (0.20) (0.07) IRE (0.02) Standard deviations in parantheses Different from EU-15 growth at the 10 percent significance level 5 percent significance level 1 percent significance level 29

31 References Artis, M., H.-M. K. Krolzig, and J. Toro (1999). The european business cycle. EUI Working Paper ECO 99 (24). Artis, M. J., Z. G. Kontolemis, and D. R. Osborn (1997). Business cycles for g7 and european countries. Journal of Business 70 (2). Artis, M. J. and W. Zhang (1997). International business cycles and the erm: Is there a european business cycle? International Journal of Finance and Economics 2 (1), Balke, N. and M. A. Wynne (1995). Recessions and recoveries in real business cycle models. Economic Inquiry 33 (4), Baxter, M. and R. G. King (1999). Measuring business cycles approximate bandpass filters for economic time series. Review of Economics and Statistics 81 (4), Bry, G. and C. Boschan (1971). Cyclical Analysis of Time Series: Selected Procedures and Computer Programs. New York and London: Columbia University Press. National Bureau of Economic Research, Technical Paper 20. Burns,A.F.andW.C.Mitchell(1946). Measuring Business Cycles. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, Studies in Business Cycles. Cogley, T. and J. M. Nason (1995). Effects of the hodrick-prescott filter on trend and difference stationary time series: Implications for business cycle research. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 19(1-2), Eurostat (2000). A new presentation to meet users needs. Eurostat News Letter 38/2000. Friedman, M. (1969). Monetary Studies of the National Bureau in "The Optimum Quantity of Money", chap. 12. Chicago:MACMILLAN. 30

Business Cycle Dating Committee of the Centre for Economic Policy Research. 1. The CEPR Business Cycle Dating Committee

Business Cycle Dating Committee of the Centre for Economic Policy Research. 1. The CEPR Business Cycle Dating Committee Business Cycle Dating Committee of the Centre for Economic Policy Research Michael Artis Fabio Canova Jordi Gali Francesco Giavazzi Richard Portes (President, CEPR) Lucrezia Reichlin (Chair) Harald Uhlig

More information

The Changing Nature of Gender Selection into Employment: Europe over the Great Recession

The Changing Nature of Gender Selection into Employment: Europe over the Great Recession The Changing Nature of Gender Selection into Employment: Europe over the Great Recession Juan J. Dolado 1 Cecilia Garcia-Peñalosa 2 Linas Tarasonis 2 1 European University Institute 2 Aix-Marseille School

More information

Chapter 9.D Services Trade Data

Chapter 9.D Services Trade Data Chapter 9.D Services Trade Data Arjan Lejour, Nico van Leeuwen and Robert A. McDougall 9.D.1 Introduction This paper has two aims. First of all, it presents CPB s contribution of bilateral services trade

More information

The Information Content of Capacity Utilisation Rates for Output Gap Estimates

The Information Content of Capacity Utilisation Rates for Output Gap Estimates The Information Content of Capacity Utilisation Rates for Output Gap Estimates Michael Graff and Jan-Egbert Sturm 15 November 2010 Overview Introduction and motivation Data Output gap data: OECD Economic

More information

Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods

Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods Robert V. Breunig Centre for Economic Policy Research, Research School of Social Sciences and School of

More information

Output correlation and EMU: evidence from European countries

Output correlation and EMU: evidence from European countries 1 Output correlation and EMU: evidence from European countries Kazuyuki Inagaki Graduate School of Economics, Kobe University, Rokkodai, Nada-ku, Kobe, 657-8501, Japan. Abstract This paper examines the

More information

Detrending and nancial cycle facts across G7 countries: Mind a spurious medium term! Yves S. Schüler. 2nd November 2017, Athens

Detrending and nancial cycle facts across G7 countries: Mind a spurious medium term! Yves S. Schüler. 2nd November 2017, Athens Detrending and nancial cycle facts across G7 countries: Mind a spurious medium term! Yves S. Schüler Deutsche Bundesbank, Research Centre 2nd November 217, Athens Disclaimer: The views expressed in this

More information

FORECAST ERRORS IN PRICES AND WAGES: THE EXPERIENCE WITH THREE PROGRAMME COUNTRIES

FORECAST ERRORS IN PRICES AND WAGES: THE EXPERIENCE WITH THREE PROGRAMME COUNTRIES Escola de Economia e Gestão Universidade do Minho e NIPE fjveiga@eeg.uminho.pt FORECAST ERRORS IN PRICES AND WAGES: THE EXPERIENCE WITH THREE PROGRAMME COUNTRIES ABSTRACT This paper evaluates the accuracy

More information

Lecture 9: Location Effects, Economic Geography and Regional Policy

Lecture 9: Location Effects, Economic Geography and Regional Policy Lecture 9: Location Effects, Economic Geography and Regional Policy G. Di Bartolomeo Index, EU-25 = 100 < 30 30-50 50-75 75-100 100-125 >= 125 Canarias (E) Guadeloupe Martinique RÈunion (F) (F) (F) Guyane

More information

Lecture 1: Facts To Be Explained

Lecture 1: Facts To Be Explained ECONG205 MRes Applied Job Search Models Lecture 1: Facts To Be Explained Fabien Postel-Vinay Department of Economics, University College London. 1 / 31 WAGE DISPERSION 2 / 31 The Sources of Wage Dispersion

More information

Business Cycle Synchronisation in Europe: Core vs. Periphery

Business Cycle Synchronisation in Europe: Core vs. Periphery Business Cycle Synchronisation in Europe: Core vs. Periphery Ansgar Belke, Clemens Domnick, Daniel Gros 23.09.2016 Differences in Economic Activity: I unemployment rate 5 10 15 20 1995q1 2000q1 2005q1

More information

A nonparametric test for path dependence in discrete panel data

A nonparametric test for path dependence in discrete panel data A nonparametric test for path dependence in discrete panel data Maximilian Kasy Department of Economics, University of California - Los Angeles, 8283 Bunche Hall, Mail Stop: 147703, Los Angeles, CA 90095,

More information

NON-LINEARITIES AND HYSTERESIS IN OECD UNEMPLOYMENT *

NON-LINEARITIES AND HYSTERESIS IN OECD UNEMPLOYMENT * A R TIGO RBEE Revista Brasileira de Economia de Empresas Brazilian Journal of Business Economics Vol. 2 - nº 3 Setembro - Dezembro 2002 p. 23-30 NON-LINEARITIES AND HYSTERESIS IN OECD UNEMPLOYMENT * Miguel

More information

TIGER: Tracking Indexes for the Global Economic Recovery By Eswar Prasad and Karim Foda

TIGER: Tracking Indexes for the Global Economic Recovery By Eswar Prasad and Karim Foda TIGER: Tracking Indexes for the Global Economic Recovery By Eswar Prasad and Karim Foda Technical Appendix Methodology In our analysis, we employ a statistical procedure called Principal Compon Analysis

More information

Shortfalls of Panel Unit Root Testing. Jack Strauss Saint Louis University. And. Taner Yigit Bilkent University. Abstract

Shortfalls of Panel Unit Root Testing. Jack Strauss Saint Louis University. And. Taner Yigit Bilkent University. Abstract Shortfalls of Panel Unit Root Testing Jack Strauss Saint Louis University And Taner Yigit Bilkent University Abstract This paper shows that (i) magnitude and variation of contemporaneous correlation are

More information

Modelling structural change using broken sticks

Modelling structural change using broken sticks Modelling structural change using broken sticks Paul White, Don J. Webber and Angela Helvin Department of Mathematics and Statistics, University of the West of England, Bristol, UK Department of Economics,

More information

Threshold effects in Okun s Law: a panel data analysis. Abstract

Threshold effects in Okun s Law: a panel data analysis. Abstract Threshold effects in Okun s Law: a panel data analysis Julien Fouquau ESC Rouen and LEO Abstract Our approach involves the use of switching regime models, to take account of the structural asymmetry and

More information

Euro-indicators Working Group

Euro-indicators Working Group Euro-indicators Working Group Luxembourg, 9 th & 10 th June 2011 Item 9.3 of the Agenda Towards an early warning system for the Euro area By Gian Luigi Mazzi Doc 308/11 Introduction Clear picture of economic

More information

Finance and Synchronization

Finance and Synchronization Finance and Synchronization A. Cesa-Bianchi 1 J. Imbs 2 J. Saleheen 3 1 Bank of England & Centre for Macroeconomics 2 Paris School of Economics (CNRS), and CEPR 3 Bank of England ECB/BoE/IMF Workshop Global

More information

This time it is different! Or not? Discounting past data when predicting the future

This time it is different! Or not? Discounting past data when predicting the future This time it is different! Or not? Discounting past data when predicting the future Philip Hans Franses Eva Janssens Econometric Institute Erasmus School of Economics EI2017-25 Abstract We employ a simple

More information

Will it float? The New Keynesian Phillips curve tested on OECD panel data

Will it float? The New Keynesian Phillips curve tested on OECD panel data Phillips curve Roger Bjørnstad 1 2 1 Research Department Statistics Norway 2 Department of Economics University of Oslo 31 October 2006 Outline Outline Outline Outline Outline The debatable The hybrid

More information

Multivariate Markov Switching With Weighted Regime Determination: Giving France More Weight than Finland

Multivariate Markov Switching With Weighted Regime Determination: Giving France More Weight than Finland Multivariate Markov Switching With Weighted Regime Determination: Giving France More Weight than Finland November 2006 Michael Dueker Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis P.O. Box 442, St. Louis, MO 63166

More information

TIGER: Tracking Indexes for the Global Economic Recovery By Eswar Prasad, Karim Foda, and Ethan Wu

TIGER: Tracking Indexes for the Global Economic Recovery By Eswar Prasad, Karim Foda, and Ethan Wu TIGER: Tracking Indexes for the Global Economic Recovery By Eswar Prasad, Karim Foda, and Ethan Wu Technical Appendix Methodology In our analysis, we employ a statistical procedure called Principal Component

More information

ESPON evidence on European cities and metropolitan areas

ESPON evidence on European cities and metropolitan areas BEST METROPOLISES Final Conference 18 April 2013, Warsaw ESPON evidence on European cities and metropolitan areas Michaela Gensheimer Structure of Intervention Content Part I: What is the ESPON 2013 Programme?

More information

Searching for the Output Gap: Economic Variable or Statistical Illusion? Mark W. Longbrake* J. Huston McCulloch

Searching for the Output Gap: Economic Variable or Statistical Illusion? Mark W. Longbrake* J. Huston McCulloch Draft Draft Searching for the Output Gap: Economic Variable or Statistical Illusion? Mark W. Longbrake* The Ohio State University J. Huston McCulloch The Ohio State University August, 2007 Abstract This

More information

Warwick Business School Forecasting System. Summary. Ana Galvao, Anthony Garratt and James Mitchell November, 2014

Warwick Business School Forecasting System. Summary. Ana Galvao, Anthony Garratt and James Mitchell November, 2014 Warwick Business School Forecasting System Summary Ana Galvao, Anthony Garratt and James Mitchell November, 21 The main objective of the Warwick Business School Forecasting System is to provide competitive

More information

This note introduces some key concepts in time series econometrics. First, we

This note introduces some key concepts in time series econometrics. First, we INTRODUCTION TO TIME SERIES Econometrics 2 Heino Bohn Nielsen September, 2005 This note introduces some key concepts in time series econometrics. First, we present by means of examples some characteristic

More information

How Well Are Recessions and Recoveries Forecast? Prakash Loungani, Herman Stekler and Natalia Tamirisa

How Well Are Recessions and Recoveries Forecast? Prakash Loungani, Herman Stekler and Natalia Tamirisa How Well Are Recessions and Recoveries Forecast? Prakash Loungani, Herman Stekler and Natalia Tamirisa 1 Outline Focus of the study Data Dispersion and forecast errors during turning points Testing efficiency

More information

Is it the How or the When that Matters in Fiscal Adjustments?

Is it the How or the When that Matters in Fiscal Adjustments? Is it the How or the When that Matters in Fiscal Adjustments? Alberto Alesina, Gualtiero Azzalini, Carlo Favero, Francesco Giavazzi, Armando Miano IGIER, Bocconi University November 2016 1 / 41 Question

More information

economic growth is not conducive to a country s overall economic performance and, additionally,

economic growth is not conducive to a country s overall economic performance and, additionally, WEB APPENDIX: EXAMINING THE CROSS-NATIONAL AND LONGITUDINAL VARIATION IN ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE USING FUZZY-SETS APPENDIX REASONING BEHIND THE BREAKPOINTS FOR THE SETS ECONOMIC GROWTH, EMPLOYMENT AND DEBT

More information

A Comparison of Business Cycle Regime Nowcasting Performance between Real-time and Revised Data. By Arabinda Basistha (West Virginia University)

A Comparison of Business Cycle Regime Nowcasting Performance between Real-time and Revised Data. By Arabinda Basistha (West Virginia University) A Comparison of Business Cycle Regime Nowcasting Performance between Real-time and Revised Data By Arabinda Basistha (West Virginia University) This version: 2.7.8 Markov-switching models used for nowcasting

More information

Inflation Targeting as a Tool To Control Unemployment

Inflation Targeting as a Tool To Control Unemployment Inflation Targeting as a Tool To Control Unemployment - Using the Phillips Curve to study its effectiveness - Manchit Mahajan Subhashish Bhadra St. Stephen s College Delhi University Abstract An Inflation

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES ISSN 47-0498 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES CLASSICAL AND MODERN BUSINESS CYCLE MEASUREMENT: THE EUROPEAN CASE Hans-Martin Krolzig and Juan Toro Number 60 January 200 Manor Road Building,

More information

Exploring the World of Growth and Development

Exploring the World of Growth and Development Exploring the World of Growth and Development Ping Wang Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis January 2018 1 Data source: Acemoglus (2009), Aghion-Howitt (2009), Jones (1998, 2015)

More information

Timely detection of turning points: Should I use the seasonally adjusted or trend estimates? G P A P

Timely detection of turning points: Should I use the seasonally adjusted or trend estimates? G P A P D I E S 2 0 0 6 E D I T I O N O R K E ISSN 1725-4825 R S A N D S T U Timely detection of turning points: Should I use the seasonally adjusted or trend estimates? G P A P Conference on seasonality, seasonal

More information

Parity Reversion of Absolute Purchasing Power Parity Zhi-bai ZHANG 1,a,* and Zhi-cun BIAN 2,b

Parity Reversion of Absolute Purchasing Power Parity Zhi-bai ZHANG 1,a,* and Zhi-cun BIAN 2,b 2016 3 rd International Conference on Economics and Management (ICEM 2016) ISBN: 978-1-60595-368-7 Parity Reversion of Absolute Purchasing Power Parity Zhi-bai ZHANG 1,a,* and Zhi-cun BIAN 2,b 1,2 School

More information

Sustainability of balancing item of balance of payment for OECD countries: evidence from Fourier Unit Root Tests

Sustainability of balancing item of balance of payment for OECD countries: evidence from Fourier Unit Root Tests Theoretical and Applied Economics FFet al Volume XXII (2015), No. 3(604), Autumn, pp. 93-100 Sustainability of balancing item of balance of payment for OECD countries: evidence from Fourier Unit Root Tests

More information

Euro-indicators Working Group

Euro-indicators Working Group Euro-indicators Working Group Luxembourg, 9 th & 10 th June 2011 Item 9.4 of the Agenda New developments in EuroMIND estimates Rosa Ruggeri Cannata Doc 309/11 What is EuroMIND? EuroMIND is a Monthly INDicator

More information

Purchasing Power Parity and the European Single Currency: Some New Evidence

Purchasing Power Parity and the European Single Currency: Some New Evidence Christidou-Panagiotidis, 309-323 Purchasing Power Parity and the European Single Currency: Some New Evidence Maria Christidou Theodore Panagiotidis Abstract The effect of the single currency on the Purchasing

More information

Testing for Regime Switching in Singaporean Business Cycles

Testing for Regime Switching in Singaporean Business Cycles Testing for Regime Switching in Singaporean Business Cycles Robert Breunig School of Economics Faculty of Economics and Commerce Australian National University and Alison Stegman Research School of Pacific

More information

Periklis. Gogas. Tel: +27. Working May 2017

Periklis. Gogas. Tel: +27. Working May 2017 University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series Macroeconomicc Uncertainty, Growth and Inflation in the Eurozone: A Causal Approach Vasilios Plakandaras Democritus University of Thrace

More information

MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model

MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Autumn 2014 Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 1 / 38 Beyond IS-LM We have reviewed the

More information

Are 'unbiased' forecasts really unbiased? Another look at the Fed forecasts 1

Are 'unbiased' forecasts really unbiased? Another look at the Fed forecasts 1 Are 'unbiased' forecasts really unbiased? Another look at the Fed forecasts 1 Tara M. Sinclair Department of Economics George Washington University Washington DC 20052 tsinc@gwu.edu Fred Joutz Department

More information

RBC Model with Indivisible Labor. Advanced Macroeconomic Theory

RBC Model with Indivisible Labor. Advanced Macroeconomic Theory RBC Model with Indivisible Labor Advanced Macroeconomic Theory 1 Last Class What are business cycles? Using HP- lter to decompose data into trend and cyclical components Business cycle facts Standard RBC

More information

MA Macroeconomics 4. Analysing the IS-MP-PC Model

MA Macroeconomics 4. Analysing the IS-MP-PC Model MA Macroeconomics 4. Analysing the IS-MP-PC Model Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Autumn 2014 Karl Whelan (UCD) Analysing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 1 / 28 Part I Inflation Expectations Karl Whelan

More information

Investment in Austria: a view from the WIFO Investitionstest

Investment in Austria: a view from the WIFO Investitionstest Investment in Austria: a view from the WIFO Investitionstest Werner Hölzl and Gerhard Schwarz Wien 20 März 2017 Introduction Forecasting and nowcasting investment is notoriously difficult It is crucial

More information

Online Appendix of the paper " How does sovereign bond market integration relate to fundamentals and CDS spreads?"

Online Appendix of the paper  How does sovereign bond market integration relate to fundamentals and CDS spreads? Online Appendix of the paper " How does sovereign bond market integration relate to fundamentals and CDS spreads?" Appendix A.1 - Summary statistics for sovereign bond returns Appendix A.2 - Correlations

More information

Stephen G. Hall (University of Leicester) Sérgio Lagoa (ISCTE University Institute of Lisbon) Abstract

Stephen G. Hall (University of Leicester) Sérgio Lagoa (ISCTE University Institute of Lisbon) Abstract Inflation and business cycle convergence in the euro area: Empirical analysis using an unobserved component model Stephen G. Hall (University of Leicester) Sérgio Lagoa (ISCTE University Institute of Lisbon)

More information

A Markov system analysis application on labour market dynamics: The case of Greece

A Markov system analysis application on labour market dynamics: The case of Greece + A Markov system analysis application on labour market dynamics: The case of Greece Maria Symeonaki Glykeria Stamatopoulou This project has received funding from the European Union s Horizon 2020 research

More information

Empirical Project, part 1, ECO 672

Empirical Project, part 1, ECO 672 Empirical Project, part 1, ECO 672 Due Date: see schedule in syllabus Instruction: The empirical project has two parts. This is part 1, which is worth 15 points. You need to work independently on this

More information

The trade dispute between the US and China Who wins? Who loses?

The trade dispute between the US and China Who wins? Who loses? 1 Munich, Jan 10 th, 2019 The trade dispute between the US and China Who wins? Who loses? by Gabriel Felbermayr and Marina Steininger This report offers a brief, quantitative analysis of the potential

More information

Nauro F. Campos and Corrado Macchiarelli Core and periphery in the European Monetary Union: Bayoumi and Eichengreen 25 years later

Nauro F. Campos and Corrado Macchiarelli Core and periphery in the European Monetary Union: Bayoumi and Eichengreen 25 years later Nauro F. Campos and Corrado Macchiarelli Core and periphery in the European Monetary Union: Bayoumi and Eichengreen 25 years later Article (Published version) (Refereed) Original citation: Campos, Nauro

More information

1.2. Structural VARs

1.2. Structural VARs 1. Shocks Nr. 1 1.2. Structural VARs How to identify A 0? A review: Choleski (Cholesky?) decompositions. Short-run restrictions. Inequality restrictions. Long-run restrictions. Then, examples, applications,

More information

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 7: A Closer Look at the Labour Market

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 7: A Closer Look at the Labour Market Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics: Chapter 7 1 Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 7: A Closer Look at the Labour Market Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics:

More information

Estimates of the Sticky-Information Phillips Curve for the USA with the General to Specific Method

Estimates of the Sticky-Information Phillips Curve for the USA with the General to Specific Method MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Estimates of the Sticky-Information Phillips Curve for the USA with the General to Specific Method Antonio Paradiso and B. Bhaskara Rao and Marco Ventura 12. February

More information

Introduction to Macroeconomics

Introduction to Macroeconomics Introduction to Macroeconomics Martin Ellison Nuffi eld College Michaelmas Term 2018 Martin Ellison (Nuffi eld) Introduction Michaelmas Term 2018 1 / 39 Macroeconomics is Dynamic Decisions are taken over

More information

The European regional Human Development and Human Poverty Indices Human Development Index

The European regional Human Development and Human Poverty Indices Human Development Index n 02/2011 The European regional Human Development and Human Poverty Indices Contents 1. Introduction...1 2. The United Nations Development Programme Approach...1 3. Regional Human Development and Poverty

More information

Detecting and predicting recessions

Detecting and predicting recessions ISSN 1977-3331 EWP 2011/012 Euroindicators working papers Detecting and predicting recessions Don Harding This paper was presented at the 6th Eurostat Colloquium on Modern Tools for Business Cycle Analysis:

More information

epub WU Institutional Repository

epub WU Institutional Repository epub WU Institutional Repository Nikolaos Antonakakis and Mina Dragouni and George Filis Tourism and Growth: The Times they are A-changing Article (Draft) (Refereed) Original Citation: Antonakakis, Nikolaos

More information

A Panel Test of Purchasing Power Parity. under the Null of Stationarity.

A Panel Test of Purchasing Power Parity. under the Null of Stationarity. A Panel Test of Purchasing Power Parity under the Null of Stationarity. John Hunter * and Mark Simpson Department of Economics, Brunel University, Uxbridge, Middlesex UB8 3PH Abstract Purchasing Power

More information

Oil price and macroeconomy in Russia. Abstract

Oil price and macroeconomy in Russia. Abstract Oil price and macroeconomy in Russia Katsuya Ito Fukuoka University Abstract In this note, using the VEC model we attempt to empirically investigate the effects of oil price and monetary shocks on the

More information

Lecture 2. Business Cycle Measurement. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD II Semestre 2017 Last updated: August 18, 2017

Lecture 2. Business Cycle Measurement. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD II Semestre 2017 Last updated: August 18, 2017 Lecture 2 Business Cycle Measurement Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD II Semestre 2017 Last updated: August 18, 2017 Universidad de Costa Rica EC3201 - Teoría Macroeconómica 2 Table of contents 1. Introduction

More information

EUROINDICATORS WORKING GROUP THE IMPACT OF THE SEASONAL ADJUSTMENT PROCESS OF BUSINESS TENDENCY SURVEYS ON TURNING POINTS DATING

EUROINDICATORS WORKING GROUP THE IMPACT OF THE SEASONAL ADJUSTMENT PROCESS OF BUSINESS TENDENCY SURVEYS ON TURNING POINTS DATING EUROINDICATORS WORKING GROUP 11 TH MEETING 4 & 5 DECEMBER 2008 EUROSTAT D1 DOC 239/08 THE IMPACT OF THE SEASONAL ADJUSTMENT PROCESS OF BUSINESS TENDENCY SURVEYS ON TURNING POINTS DATING ITEM 6.2 ON THE

More information

Identifying Aggregate Liquidity Shocks with Monetary Policy Shocks: An Application using UK Data

Identifying Aggregate Liquidity Shocks with Monetary Policy Shocks: An Application using UK Data Identifying Aggregate Liquidity Shocks with Monetary Policy Shocks: An Application using UK Data Michael Ellington and Costas Milas Financial Services, Liquidity and Economic Activity Bank of England May

More information

On Enhanced Alternatives for the Hodrick-Prescott Filter

On Enhanced Alternatives for the Hodrick-Prescott Filter On Enhanced Alternatives for the Hodrick-Prescott Filter Marlon Fritz* Thomas Gries Yuanhua Feng Abstract The trend estimation for macroeconomic time series is crucial due to many different model specifications.

More information

Projektbereich B Discussion Paper No. B-393. Katrin Wesche * Aggregation Bias in Estimating. European Money Demand Functions.

Projektbereich B Discussion Paper No. B-393. Katrin Wesche * Aggregation Bias in Estimating. European Money Demand Functions. Projektbereich B Discussion Paper No. B-393 Katrin Wesche * Aggregation Bias in Estimating European Money Demand Functions November 1996 *University of Bonn Institut für Internationale Wirtschaftspolitik

More information

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models 4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models Basic Economic Models In Economics, we use theoretical models to explain the economic processes in the real world. These models de ne a relation

More information

The Determinants of Regional Unemployment in Turkey: A Spatial Panel Data Analysis

The Determinants of Regional Unemployment in Turkey: A Spatial Panel Data Analysis 14 The Determinants of Regional Unemployment in Turkey: A Spatial Panel Data Analysis Burcu TÜRKCAN Utku AKSEKİ Abstract The aim of this study is to analyze spatially the main determinants of regional

More information

Random Matrix Theory and the Failure of Macro-economic Forecasts

Random Matrix Theory and the Failure of Macro-economic Forecasts Random Matrix Theory and the Failure of Macro-economic Forecasts Paul Ormerod (Pormerod@volterra.co.uk) * and Craig Mounfield (Craig.Mounfield@volterra.co.uk) Volterra Consulting Ltd The Old Power Station

More information

Compact guides GISCO. Geographic information system of the Commission

Compact guides GISCO. Geographic information system of the Commission Compact guides GISCO Geographic information system of the Commission What is GISCO? GISCO, the Geographic Information System of the COmmission, is a permanent service of Eurostat that fulfils the requirements

More information

Introduction to Forecasting

Introduction to Forecasting Introduction to Forecasting Introduction to Forecasting Predicting the future Not an exact science but instead consists of a set of statistical tools and techniques that are supported by human judgment

More information

Okun s Law: Fit at 50? Laurence Ball Johns Hopkins University. Daniel Leigh International Monetary Fund. Prakash Loungani International Monetary Fund

Okun s Law: Fit at 50? Laurence Ball Johns Hopkins University. Daniel Leigh International Monetary Fund. Prakash Loungani International Monetary Fund Okun s Law: Fit at 50? Laurence Ball Johns Hopkins University Daniel Leigh International Monetary Fund Prakash Loungani International Monetary Fund Revised, April 2016 Abstract This paper asks how well

More information

Constructing Turning Point Chronologies with Markov Switching Vector Autoregressive Models: the Euro Zone Business Cycle

Constructing Turning Point Chronologies with Markov Switching Vector Autoregressive Models: the Euro Zone Business Cycle Constructing Turning Point Chronologies with Markov Switching Vector Autoregressive Models: the Euro Zone Business Cycle Hans Martin Krolzig Department of Economics and Nuffield College, Oxford University.

More information

Andrew Bond 2nd International Workshop on Evaluation of Eurocode 7, Pavia, Italy, April 2010

Andrew Bond 2nd International Workshop on Evaluation of Eurocode 7, Pavia, Italy, April 2010 Andrew Bond Survey procedure Some unexpected results NDPs for slope stability NDPs for shallow foundations NDPs for deep foundations Accidental design situations Conclusions Results of the NDP Survey 2009/10

More information

A. Cuñat 1 R. Zymek 2

A. Cuñat 1 R. Zymek 2 1 2 1 University of Vienna and CESifo, alejandro.cunat@univie.ac.at 2 University of Edinburgh and CESifo, robert.zymek@ed.ac.uk and Outline accounting: quantitative assessment of the contribution of measurable

More information

Stochastic Trends & Economic Fluctuations

Stochastic Trends & Economic Fluctuations Stochastic Trends & Economic Fluctuations King, Plosser, Stock & Watson (AER, 1991) Cesar E. Tamayo Econ508 - Economics - Rutgers November 14, 2011 Cesar E. Tamayo Stochastic Trends & Economic Fluctuations

More information

Inflation Revisited: New Evidence from Modified Unit Root Tests

Inflation Revisited: New Evidence from Modified Unit Root Tests 1 Inflation Revisited: New Evidence from Modified Unit Root Tests Walter Enders and Yu Liu * University of Alabama in Tuscaloosa and University of Texas at El Paso Abstract: We propose a simple modification

More information

JEL classification: E32, C49. Keywords: Business Cycles, Magnitude Dependence, Stabilization Policy.

JEL classification: E32, C49. Keywords: Business Cycles, Magnitude Dependence, Stabilization Policy. INTERNATIONAL EVIDENCE ON BUSINESS CYCLE MAGNITUDE DEPENDENCE DI GUILMI, Corrado * GAFFEO, Edoardo * GALLEGATI, Mauro PALESTRINI, Antonio Abstract Are expansions and recessions more likely to end as their

More information

Approximating fixed-horizon forecasts using fixed-event forecasts

Approximating fixed-horizon forecasts using fixed-event forecasts Approximating fixed-horizon forecasts using fixed-event forecasts Comments by Simon Price Essex Business School June 2016 Redundant disclaimer The views in this presentation are solely those of the presenter

More information

International Economic Geography- Introduction

International Economic Geography- Introduction International Economic Geography- Introduction dr hab. Bart Rokicki Chair of Macroeconomics and Foreign Trade Theory Faculty of Economic Sciences, University of Warsaw Course structure Introduction LocationtheoryI

More information

ORGANISATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT

ORGANISATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT ORGANISATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT Pursuant to Article 1 of the Convention signed in Paris on 14th December 1960, and which came into force on 30th September 1961, the Organisation

More information

Strict and Flexible Inflation Forecast Targets: An Empirical Investigation

Strict and Flexible Inflation Forecast Targets: An Empirical Investigation Strict and Flexible Inflation Forecast Targets: An Empirical Investigation Graham Voss University of Victoria, Canada Glenn Otto University of New South Wales, Australia Inflation Targets Bank of Canada

More information

Comparison of detrending methods

Comparison of detrending methods Comparison of detrending methods Gabrielle Larsson and Tamás Vasi Department of statistics, Uppsala University Supervisor: Daniel Preve June 4, 2012 ABSTRACT This thesis examines the difference between

More information

APPLYING BORDA COUNT METHOD FOR DETERMINING THE BEST WEEE MANAGEMENT IN EUROPE. Maria-Loredana POPESCU 1

APPLYING BORDA COUNT METHOD FOR DETERMINING THE BEST WEEE MANAGEMENT IN EUROPE. Maria-Loredana POPESCU 1 APPLYING BORDA COUNT METHOD FOR DETERMINING THE BEST MANAGEMENT IN EUROPE Maria-Loredana POPESCU 1 ABSTRACT This article presents the Borda Count method and its application for ranking the regarding the

More information

The more, the merrier? Urbanization and regional GDP growth in Europe over the 20th century

The more, the merrier? Urbanization and regional GDP growth in Europe over the 20th century The more, the merrier? Urbanization and regional GDP growth in Europe over the 20th century Kerstin Enflo * Anna Missiaia Joan Rosés Abstract Preliminary draft prepared for the Economic History Society

More information

St. Gallen, Switzerland, August 22-28, 2010

St. Gallen, Switzerland, August 22-28, 2010 Session Number: First Poster Session Time: Monday, August 23, PM Paper Prepared for the 31st General Conference of The International Association for Research in Income and Wealth St. Gallen, Switzerland,

More information

Utilitarianism, Degressive Proportionality and the Constitution of a Federal Assembly

Utilitarianism, Degressive Proportionality and the Constitution of a Federal Assembly 1 Utilitarianism, Degressive Proportionality and the Constitution of a Federal Assembly Luc Bovens and Stephan Hartmann 1 Introduction. A federal assembly consists of a number of representatives for each

More information

EMERGING MARKETS - Lecture 2: Methodology refresher

EMERGING MARKETS - Lecture 2: Methodology refresher EMERGING MARKETS - Lecture 2: Methodology refresher Maria Perrotta April 4, 2013 SITE http://www.hhs.se/site/pages/default.aspx My contact: maria.perrotta@hhs.se Aim of this class There are many different

More information

Extracting information from noisy time series data

Extracting information from noisy time series data Extracting information from noisy time series data Paul Ormerod (Pormerod@volterra.co.uk) Volterra Consulting Ltd Sheen Elms 135c Sheen Lane London SW14 8AE December 2004 1 Abstract A question which is

More information

Volatility. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University

Volatility. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University Volatility Gerald P. Dwyer Clemson University February 2016 Outline 1 Volatility Characteristics of Time Series Heteroskedasticity Simpler Estimation Strategies Exponentially Weighted Moving Average Use

More information

Detecting and forecasting business cycle turning points

Detecting and forecasting business cycle turning points MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Detecting and forecasting business cycle turning points Don Harding 23. September 2008 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/33583/ MPRA Paper No. 33583, posted 22.

More information

Consumption Risk Sharing over the Business Cycle: the Role of Small Firms Access to Credit Markets

Consumption Risk Sharing over the Business Cycle: the Role of Small Firms Access to Credit Markets 1 Consumption Risk Sharing over the Business Cycle: the Role of Small Firms Access to Credit Markets Mathias Hoffmann & Iryna Shcherbakova-Stewen University of Zurich PhD Topics Lecture, 22 Sep 2014 www.econ.uzh.ch/itf

More information

Research Brief December 2018

Research Brief December 2018 Research Brief https://doi.org/10.21799/frbp.rb.2018.dec Battle of the Forecasts: Mean vs. Median as the Survey of Professional Forecasters Consensus Fatima Mboup Ardy L. Wurtzel Battle of the Forecasts:

More information

Exploring the World of Growth and Development

Exploring the World of Growth and Development Exploring the World of Growth and Development Ping Wang Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis January 2018 1 A. The Big Picture 1. Long Term Development of the World Economy Five ancient

More information

Another Look at the Boom and Bust of Financial Bubbles

Another Look at the Boom and Bust of Financial Bubbles ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 16-2, 417 423 (2015) Another Look at the Boom and Bust of Financial Bubbles Andrea Beccarini University of Münster, Department of Economics, Am Stadtgraben 9, 48143, Münster,

More information

Volume 31, Issue 1. Mean-reverting behavior of consumption-income ratio in OECD countries: evidence from SURADF panel unit root tests

Volume 31, Issue 1. Mean-reverting behavior of consumption-income ratio in OECD countries: evidence from SURADF panel unit root tests Volume 3, Issue Mean-reverting behavior of consumption-income ratio in OECD countries: evidence from SURADF panel unit root tests Shu-Yi Liao Department of Applied Economics, National Chung sing University,

More information

International evidence on business cycle magnitude dependence

International evidence on business cycle magnitude dependence International evidence on business cycle magnitude dependence Corrado Di Guilmi, a Edoardo Gaffeo, b, * Mauro Gallegati, a Antonio Palestrini c a Department of Economics, Università Politecnica delle Marche,

More information

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case.

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case. Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case. Ragnar Nymoen Department of Economics, University of Oslo October 20, 2008 1 Ch 17, 19 and 20 in IAM Since our primary concern is to

More information

Scaling invariant distributions of firms exit in OECD countries

Scaling invariant distributions of firms exit in OECD countries Scaling invariant distributions of firms exit in OECD countries Corrado Di Guilmi a Mauro Gallegati a Paul Ormerod b a Department of Economics, University of Ancona, Piaz.le Martelli 8, I-62100 Ancona,

More information

Answer all questions from part I. Answer two question from part II.a, and one question from part II.b.

Answer all questions from part I. Answer two question from part II.a, and one question from part II.b. B203: Quantitative Methods Answer all questions from part I. Answer two question from part II.a, and one question from part II.b. Part I: Compulsory Questions. Answer all questions. Each question carries

More information