Railroads and American Economic Growth: New Data and Theory

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Railroads and American Economic Growth: New Data and Theory"

Transcription

1 Railroads and American Economic Growth: New Data and Theory Dave Donaldson MIT and NBER Richard Hornbeck Harvard and NBER Draft Version: September 2011 Preliminary and Incomplete Abstract This paper examines the impact of railroads on American economic growth. Drawing on general equilibrium trade theory, changes in counties market access captures the aggregate impact of local changes in railroads. Using a new spatial network of freight transportation routes, we calculate county-to-county lowest transportation costs and counties implied market access. As railroads expanded from 1870 to 1890, changes in market access are capitalized in land values with an estimated elasticity of The computed decline in market access from removing all railroads in 1890 is estimated to reduce GNP by 6.3%, roughly double estimates by Fogel (1964). Without railroads, the total value of US agricultural land would have been lower by 73%. Fogel s proposed extention of the canal network would have only mitigated 8% of the loss from removing railroads. For helpful comments and suggestions, we thank seminar participants at Harvard. We are grateful to Jeremy Atack and coauthors for sharing data from their research. Irene Chen, Manning Ding, Jan Kozak, and Rui Wang provided excellent research assistance.

2 During the 19th century, railroads spread throughout a growing United States as the economy rose to global prominence. Railroads became the dominant form of freight transportation; areas around railroad lines prospered and preferential rates could allow particular companies to dominate sectors. The early historical literature often presumed that railroads were indispensable to the United States economy or, at least, very influential in US economic growth. Understanding the development of the American economy is shaped by an understanding of the impact of railroads and, more generally, the impact of market integration. In Railroads and American Economic Growth, Fogel (1964) transformed the academic literature on railroads impact by using a social savings methodology to focus attention on counterfactuals: in the absence of railroads, freight transportation by rivers and canals would have been only slightly more expensive in most areas. Small differences in freight rates can make-or-break individual firms or induce areas to thrive at the expense of others, but the aggregate impact on economic growth may be small. Fogel s social savings methodology has been widely applied and continues to influence the evaluation of transportation infrastructure improvements. However, many scholars have discussed limitations of the social savings methodology (reviewed in Fogel 1979). 1 One alternative approach is to create a computational general equilibrium (CGE) model, with the explicit inclusion of multiple regions separated by a transportation technology (e.g., Williamson 1974; Herrendorf et al. 2009). Increasingly, econometric studies have exploited local variation in railroad construction and county-level data on population, output, or land values (Haines and Margo 2008; Atack and Margo 2010; Atack et al. 2010; Atack et al. 2011). Similar methods have been used to estimate the impact of railroads in modern China (Banerjee et al. 2010) or highways in the United States (Baum-Snow 2007; Michaels 2008). Given plausibly random variation in the location of transportation routes, these studies estimate the relative impact of transportation infrastructure. General equilibrium effects limit the aggregate interpretation of such estimates, however, because railroads may displace activity from one area to another with little aggregate impact. Railroads are inherently a network technology, and local changes in the network affect all other areas on the network and areas off the network. This paper introduces a new methodology for estimating the aggregate impact of transportation improvements, drawing on recent advances in trade theory and spatial databases to estimate the impact of railroads on the American economy. Following Fogel s analysis, we focus on the aggregate impact of railroad freight transportation on the agricultural sector in Drawing on general equilibrium trade theory, counties market access aggre- 1 For example, the methodology ignores the possibility of increasing returns, market power, or other market imperfections (David 1969). 1

3 gates the local impacts and geographic spillover impacts of railroads. 2 Building on empirical work by Atack et al., we construct a GIS network database to calculate county-to-county transportation costs and analyze county-level variation in market access. As railroads expanded from 1870 to 1890, changes in market access are capitalized in land values with an estimated elasticity of County market access is influenced by changes elsewhere in the railroad network; indeed, the estimated elasticity is robust to controlling for a county s own railroads. We then compare the observed impact of railroads against two counterfactual scenarios in In the first scenario, eliminating railroads lowers the total value of US agricultural land by 73% and generates an annual economic loss of 6.3% of GNP, roughly double Fogel s estimate. In the second scenario, replacing railroads with extended canals generates an annual economic loss of 5.8% of GNP, mitigating only 8% of the loss from eliminating railroads. Contrary to Fogel s expectations, the proposed extension of the canal network is estimated to be a poor substitute for the railroad network. In contrast to canals, railroads provided direct routes to many trading partners, and dramatically lowered distances of expensive wagon transportation. As a comparison, we extend a lesser-known component of Fogel s methodology using recent improvements in county-level data and spatial computational analysis. We calculate the value of agricultural land within different-sized thin buffers around railroads and rivers. Through algebraic manipulation, eliminating railroads is estimated to impose a 4% annual cost and replacing railroads with canal extensions is estimated to impose a 1% annual cost. These estimates are expected to understate the cost of eliminating railroads and, in particular, overstate the benefit of canal extensions. By comparison, the market access methodology results appear of reasonable magnitude. In the United States and around the world, transportation infrastructure is attracting tremendous resources as a popular initiative to increase economic growth. This paper develops and implements a new methodology for measuring the aggregate impacts of transportation infrastructure. The estimates suggest a large role for market integration in economic development. Further, as the trade literature makes progress on tractable general equilibrium models, this empirical setting provides an opportunity to test these models empirical insights using a direct shock to trade costs and land value data. While the market access data are drawn from a newly constructed network database, this data collection process can be replicated in other settings. 2 In related work, Redding and Sturm (2007) use a similar model to estimate the impact on population from changes in market access following the division and reunification of Germany. Donaldson (2010) estimates the impact of railroads on price dispersion, trade flows and real income in colonial India, using a different model to calculate overall gains from trade. 2

4 I Constructing a New Dataset on the Historical US Transportation Network The data are drawn from a newly-constructed geographic information system (GIS) network database on the location of railroads in 1870 and 1890 and the location of other transportation methods. 3 This network database, i.e., Google Maps for the 19th century, allows the calculation of lowest freight transportation costs between any two counties. For 1870 and 1890, we calculate counties market access: a weighted sum of transportation costs suggested by a general equilibrium trade model. We also calculate counties market access under counterfactual scenarios, such as eliminating railroads or constructing Fogel s hypothetical expansion of the canal network in lieu of railroads. The database considers three methods of freight transportation: railroads, boats, and wagons. Railroad and boat freight rates were similar per ton-mile in 1890, so the key advantage to railroads was their wider geographic dispersion. Railroads mainly affected transportation costs by reducing the required lengths of expensive wagon transportation and by providing more-direct transportation routes. Faced with a number of data challenges, the network construction compromises in other areas and focuses on the location of railways and waterways and the implied distances of wagon transportation. I.A Transportation Cost Parameters We use Fogel s transportation cost parameters, which are reasonable choices and enable closer comparison between the methodologies results. One strong assumption is that freight rates per ton-mile are constant throughout the country, which only partly reflects data limitations. Local freight rates are likely endogenous to local economic activity and market power, so there are advantages to using average national rates. Fogel s analysis uses freight rates in 1890, and we maintain these rates in Thus, measured changes in trade costs and market access are determined by variation in the location of transportation routes rather than prices. Using Fogel s parameters, railway rates are set at 0.63 cents per ton-mile and waterway rates are set at 0.49 cents per ton-mile. 4 Transshipment costs 50 cents per ton, incurred whenever transferring goods to/from a railroad car, river boat, canal barge, or ocean liner. 5 Wagon transportation costs 23.1 cents per ton-mile, defined as the straight line distance 3 We are grateful to Jeremy Atack and co-authors for providing initial GIS maps of railways. 4 Rates reflect an output-weighted average of rates for transporting grain and meat. Waterway rates include insurance charges for lost cargo (0.025 cents), inventory and storage costs for slower transport and non-navigable winter months (0.194 cents), and the social cost of public waterway investment (0.073 cents). Waterway or railway rates are not allowed to vary by direction. 5 Fogel considers transshipment charges as a sub-category of water rates, but our modeling of transshipment points allows for a unified treatment of Fogel s interregional and intraregional scenarios. Fogel s sources record higher railroad freight costs per ton-mile for shorter routes, but approximately reflect a 100 cent fixed fee and a 0.63 cent fee per mile. 3

5 between two points. 6 Due to the wide dispersion in travel costs by method, the key features of the transportation network concern the required length of wagon transportation and the number of transshipment points. I.B Transportation Network Construction The first step is obtaining digitized maps of constructed railroads in 1870 and We are grateful to Jeremy Atack and co-authors for providing these initial GIS railroad files. 7 These railroad files were originally constructed to define mileage of railroad track by county and year; by contrast, for our purposes, railroad lines must connect exactly such that GIS software recognizes travel is possible along a continuous line. We use GIS topology tools to ensure exact connections between all railroad line segments. 8 To minimize measurement error in changes, we create a cleaned 1890 railroad file and modify that file to create a version for 1870 that omits lines constructed between 1870 and Figure 1 maps the railroad network in 1870 and The second step adds locations of navigable rivers and canals. We follow Fogel s definition and mapping of navigable waterways, and build on a preliminary file provided by Atack. We enhanced the Fogel-Atack map to follow natural river bends, as the relative straightness of railroads contributes to travel cost differences. Overlapping waterways and railways do not connect by default; instead, we create connections among waterways and railways to allow for fixed transshipment costs. We also include the locations of hypothetical canals, whose construction Fogel argued was feasible and would have largely substituted for railroads. Figure 2 maps the waterway network, and Figure 3 maps the combined waterway network and railroad network in 1870 and The third step allows for travel over two-dimensional space (lakes, oceans, unmapped land). The network allows for travel along line routes, but space between lines is undefined and travel is either costless or impossible. 9 We create waterways that saturate oceans and lakes with a large number of possible routes. For over-land routes, we create wagon connections from every county centroid to every other county centroid within 300km. 10 The fourth step connects individual counties to the transportation network. We define av- 6 This rate reflects a cost of 16.5 cents per mile traveled and Fogel s adjustment factor of 1.4 between the shortest straight line distance and miles traveled. 7 First, year-specific railroad atlas scans from the Library of Congress are georeferenced to US county borders. Second, railroad lines are hand-traced in GIS software to create a digital map of railroad line locations. 8 For example, digitized railroad lines often contain small internal gaps. In addition, by default, two crossing railroad lines are equivalent to a highway overpass without a connection. Correcting all such cases has little effect on total track mileage by county, but can have large impacts on calculated lowest-cost routes. 9 The analysis could use rasters that allow for travel costs for each map pixel, but it would be unable to reflect transshipment costs: a string of railroad pixels will intersect a string of river pixels. 10 Note that wagon rates adjust straight line distance to reflect average travel distance. 4

6 erage travel costs between counties by calculating the travel cost between county centroids. County centroids must be connected to the network of railways and waterways; otherwise, lowest-cost travel calculations assume that freight first travels (freely) to the closest railway or waterway. We create wagon connections between each county centroid and each nearby type of transportation route in each relevant direction. The fifth step refines the centroid connections to reflect the importance of wagon distances to overall travel costs. Consider that when railroads travel through a county, the centroid s nearest distance to a railroad no longer reflects the average distance from county points to a railroad. Fogel recognized the importance of modeling this distance and his ideal solution was to break each county into small grids and take the average of nearest distances from each grid to a railroad. Due to technical limitations, Fogel approximated this average distance using one-third of the distance from the farthest point in a county to a railroad. We use GIS software to create 200 random points in each county, calculate the distance from each point to the nearest railroad, and take the average of these nearest distances. We adjust the cost of travel along each centroid connection to within-county railroads to reflect that county s average travel cost to a railroad. We repeat this process for rivers, canals, and Fogel s proposed canals. This process allows the analysis to exploit precise variation on the intensive margin of county access to railways and waterways. I.C Transportation Route Cost Calculations We use the completed network dataset to calculate the lowest cost route between each pair of counties, i.e., 5 million calculations. The lowest cost routes are calculated under four scenarios: (1) transportation costs with 1870 railroads, (2) transportation costs with 1890 railroads, (3) transportation costs with no railroads, and (4) transportation costs with no railroads and Fogel s extended canals. All scenarios include transportation by river/canal/lake/ocean and over-land wagon routes. The observed travel paths are consistent with intuitive travel patterns. Ultimately, calculated travel costs are not intended to most accurately reflect actual travel costs (for which partial data are available); rather, calculated travel costs are a proxy for differences over space and time in transportation costs due to the availability of nearby railways and waterways. I.D County-level Census Data County-level data are drawn from the US Censuses of Agriculture and Population (Haines 2005). The main variables of interest are total population and the total value of agricultural land. We adjust data from 1870 to reflect 1890 county boundaries (Hornbeck 2010). Unsettled counties with missing data are assumed to have zero population and zero land value, as all areas contribute to the calculation of market access. The empirical analysis excludes 5

7 counties with zero land value, and explores robustness to excluding all counties West of Texas. II A Distance Buffer Approach to Valuing Railroads Using only the location of railways and waterways, an initial empirical exercise extends Fogel s lesser-known approach to valuing the impact of railroads in Fogel s best-known approach involves multiplying the quantity of transported agricultural goods by the difference in transportation costs with railroads and without railroads. This method is applied to inter-regional trade between major hubs and some intra-regional trade. One limitation in applying this method to all intra-regional trade is that waterway and wagon transportation costs would be higher than product values in some railroad-serviced areas. As an alternative, Fogel excludes all areas more than 40 miles from a navigable waterway and calculates the economic loss as the value of agricultural land in these areas. Fogel s alternative method of calculating economic loss is based on a Ricardian model: land values capitalize economic rents, which depend on transportation costs to markets. Railroads and waterways are much cheaper than wagons 40 miles of wagon transportation is equivalent to miles of transportation by rail or waterway so distance to a railroad or waterway is a decent proxy for transportation costs. Fogel makes a stark assumption that farmland is worth its full amount within 40 miles and is worth zero beyond 40 miles, when wagon costs exceed average product prices. We extend this Ricardian method to a full evaluation of railroads, exploiting GIS software and county-level data. For 1890, we calculate the share of each county that is 0-5 miles, 5-10 miles,..., miles, and more than 40 miles from a railroad or river/canal/lake/ocean. We also calculate the share of each county in each distance bin under two counterfactual scenarios: (1) no railroads and (2) no railroads and canal extensions. Figure 4 maps 40-mile buffers for each scenario, which illustrates the intuition in Fogel s original analysis. Panel A is shaded to reflect the area of land within 40 miles of a railroad or waterway. Panel B is shaded to reflect the area of land within 40 miles of a waterway. Panel C overlays these two maps; the gray area is serviced by a railroad but not by a waterway. Panel D adds Fogel s proposed canal extensions; most of the Midwestern areas become serviced by this expanded waterway network. Figure 5 maps 10-mile buffers for each scenario, which illustrates why Fogel s approach may understate the value of railroads and overstate the value of canal extensions. Panel A is shaded to reflect the area of land within 10 miles of a railroad or waterway; given the high density of railroad construction, most areas remain shaded when compared to panel A of figure 4. In Panel B, however, relatively little area is covered by waterways when compared to panel B of figure 4. Panel C overlays these maps, highlighting the relative advantage 6

8 of railroads at closer distances. Panel D adds the canal extensions, which are relatively ineffective at covering areas serviced by railroads. Calculating the economic impact of railroads involves algebraic manipulation in two steps. First, we inflate observed land values to reflect lands implied true value if it were next to a transportation route. Second, we calculate the implied lost land value from changing observed transportation routes to each counterfactual scenario. First, assume a continuous depreciation in land values as nearest distance to a railway or waterway increases from 0 to 40 miles. For each county i, the implied per-acre true land value or T ruelv i is a function of the observed land value or ObservedLV i and the share of county i in each distance bin αi d : (1) T ruelv i = ObservedLV i α α α Second, we calculate the share of each county i in each distance bin βi d from only a river/canal/lake/ocean. The implied lost land value from removing railroads is: (2) Loss NoRR = T ruelv i [(β 0 5 i α 0 5 ) (β5 10 i α 5 10 ) (β35 40 i α ) ] Similarly, we calculate the share of each county i in each distance bin γi d from a proposed canal extension or a river/canal/lake/ocean. The implied lost land value from replacing railroads with extended canals is: (3) Loss Canals = T ruelv i [(γ 0 5 i α 0 5 ) (γ5 10 i α 5 10 ) (γ35 40 i α ) ] This method estimates that removing railroads in 1890 would decrease land values by $6 billion, generating an annual loss of $480 million using Fogel s preferred rate of return. By comparison, Fogel estimates annual intra-regional losses of $248 million to $337 million, and annual inter-regional losses of $73 million. 11 If land values are not inflated to true values, skipping step one above, the estimated annual loss is $420 million. This method estimates that replacing railroads with canal extensions in 1890 would still generate an annual loss of $128 million. In this approach, canal extensions largely mitigate the loss of railroads because extended canals reach near otherwise unserved areas. Canal extensions only provide indirect routes to destinations, however, so a methodology based on trade costs should estimate lower value from canal extensions. The subsequent analysis focuses on county-to-county trade costs because, ultimately, rail- 11 From the 40-mile buffer loss alone, Fogel estimates an annual loss of $154 million. 7

9 ways and waterways matter for where they provide transportation. The full trade model simplifies to a county-level regression that maintains this earlier Ricardian intuition: low trade costs and high market access are capitalized in higher land values. The model is identified from changes in market access over time, and we use these parameters to estimate the economic cost from eliminating railroads or replacing railroads with canal extensions. III A Market Access Approach to Valuing Railroads We formalize a model of trade among US counties that specifies how goods prices and factor prices and hence living standards respond to changing trade costs. The model contains thousands of counties, each with interacting goods markets and factor markets, that generate positive and negative spillovers on other counties. Remarkably, under a set of assumptions that are standard among modern quantitative trade models, all of these spillovers collapse into a single sufficient statistic represented by a county s market access. The model generates a regression equation that we take to the data; in particular, the model implies a simple relationship between county agricultural land values and county market access (appropriately defined). The model s simplifications and abstractions are stark, but these assumptions are rewarded with analytical insight and empirical predictions. 12 In the end, regressing county land values on a weighted sum of trade costs with other counties (i.e., market access ) also has a completely atheoretical appeal. III.A A Model of Trade Among US Counties The economy consists of many trading counties, each indexed by o if the origin of a trade and by d if the destination. Some counties are rural (o R) and some are urban (o U). Tastes: Economic agents have Cobb-Douglas preferences over two commodity groups: agricultural goods (weight γ) and manufactured goods (weight 1 γ). The commodity groups are composed of many differentiated goods varieties (indexed by j), and tastes over these varieties take a CES form (with elasticities σ A and σ M ). 13 An agent living in county 12 These modeling assumptions are used in the fields of international trade and economic geography, and reflect recent best-practice to gain traction in general equilibrium spatial settings with many regions and commodities. 13 It is important to note that the elasticities of substitution within each commodity group are not restricted; these could be very high if agricultural varieties are relatively similar. Anderson et al. (1992) provide an attractive microfoundation of aggregate-level CES preferences. If individual agents desire only one variety of the agricultural good (their ideal variety ) and agents ideal varieties are distributed in a Logit fashion, then aggregate consumption data from a population of many such agents behaves as though all agents have CES preferences over all varieties (where in such an interpretation σ indexes the inverse of the dispersion of agents ideal varieties). 8

10 o and receiving income Y o experiences indirect utility: (4) V (P o, Y o ) = Y o (P A o ) γ (P M o ) 1 γ, where P A o and P M o are standard CES price indices. 14 Agricultural technology: For simplicity, we assume a stark form of specialization: rural counties produce only agricultural goods and urban counties produce only manufacturing goods. 15 Rural counties use a Cobb-Douglas technology to transform land and labor into agricultural goods varieties. We assume that labor is mobile across space and across sectors, i.e., that farmers have an endogenous outside option to work in other counties or manufacturing. The marginal cost of producing agricultural goods of variety j in county o is: (5) MC A o (j) = (q o) α (w o ) 1 α z A o (j) if o R, where w o is the wage rate, q o is the agricultural land rental rate, and zo A (j) is a Hicksneutral productivity shifter that is exogenous and local to county o. We follow Eaton and Kortum (2002) in modeling these productivity shifters by assuming that each county draws its productivity level, for any given variety j, from a Frechet (or Type II extreme value) distribution: F o (z) = 1 exp( To A z θ A ). 16 This functional form is restrictive, but it has made multiple-region models of comparative advantage tractable since the seminal work of Eaton and Kortum (2002). Finally, we assume perfect competition among producers, following most of the trade literature on relatively homogeneous goods such as agricultural commodities. Manufacturing technology: Urban counties use a Cobb-Douglas technology to transform capital and labor into manufacturing goods varieties, whose marginal cost of production is: (6) MC M o (j) = (w o) β (r o ) 1 β z M o (j) if o U, [ 14 That is, Po A n A 1/(1 σa = (p A 0 c (j)) 1 σ ) [ A dj] and P M n M ] 1/(1 σm o = (p M 0 o (j)) 1 σ ) M dj. Variables n A and n M are the number of varieties available to consumers; as we describe below, the number of varieties is fixed in agriculture and the number is endogenous in the manufacturing sector and adjusts to allow free entry. 15 In future work we aim to subdivide all counties into their rural and urban segments (based on population shares in the Census data). An additional extension could solve for the equilibrium specialization of each county into its rural and urban segments. 16 This distribution captures how productivity differences across counties give incentives to specialize and trade. The parameter To A captures county-specific (log) mean productivity, which corresponds to the county s absolute advantage. The parameter θ A captures, inversely, the (log) standard deviation of productivity, which corresponds to the scope for comparative advantage. A low θ A means county productivity draws are dispersed, creating large incentives to trade on the basis of productivity differences. 9

11 where w o is the same wage rate, r o is the capital rental rate, and zo M (j) is a Hicks-neutral productivity shifter that is exogenous and local to county o. The urban manufacturing sector pays both this marginal cost and a fixed cost of production, f o, paid in the same proportion of factors as marginal costs. We follow Melitz (2003) in assuming a set of potential producers, each with a productivity shifter zo M (j) that is drawn, prior to entry, from a distribution with CDF G o (z). We also follow Chaney (2008), among others, in modeling the distribution G o (z) as a Pareto distribution: G o (z) = 1 (z/to M ) θ M. 17 The parameter To M captures the location of this distribution and θ M captures its dispersion. Following Melitz (2003), firms compete monopolistically with free entry such that all profits are zero. Trade costs: Trading goods is costly. Remote rural locations pay high prices for imported goods and receive low prices for goods they produce, as this is the only way locations can be competitive in distant markets. We model trade costs using a simple and standard iceberg formulation. When a variety is made in county o and sold locally in county o, its price is p k oo(j) in sector k; but when this same variety is made in county o and shipped to county d, it will sell for p k od (j) = τ od k pk oo(j). 18 A proportional trade cost τod k is applied to each unit of the variety shipped. 19 Trade is costly because τod k 1. Our empirical analysis below models as a function of observables, based on the available transportation routes between county τ k od o and county d and how these routes changed over time. Factor mobility: Workers are free to move around the country. Worker utility, as defined in equation (4), will hence be equalized across counties in equilibrium and wages will satisfy: (7) w o = U(P o A ) γ (Po M ) 1 γ, where U is the endogenous level of utility obtained by workers in each county. Land is fixed by county and capital is perfectly mobile. 20 III.B Using the Model to Inform Empirical Work Solving for trade flows the gravity equation: First, we solve for trade flows from each origin county o to each other destination county d in the agricultural sector. Due to perfect competition, the marginal costs of producing each variety are equal to their price. assume that consumers only buy a variety from the cheapest available location. Substituting marginal costs from each supply location o (equation 5) into the demand for agricultural 17 This is a good match for the empirical distribution of firm sizes in most samples (e.g., Axtell 2001). 18 Monopolistically competitive producers in the manufacturing sector have an incentive to segment markets but, with CES preferences and many producers, the same mark-up over marginal cost will be charged by each producer in each market. 19 Melitz (2003) proposed that some trade barriers may be fixed (ie, constant regardless of the quantity shipped). For simplicity we have not included such costs here but they could easily be added in future work. 20 Predictions are equivalent if capital is perfectly immobile, but intermediate cases are difficult to model. We 10

12 varieties in county d, Eaton and Kortum (2002) derive the value of total exports from o to d: 21 (8) (9) where CMA A d i R X A od = χ A T A o (q α o w 1 α o ) θ A (τ A od) θ A (CMA A d ) 1 Y d, T A i (q α i w 1 α i ) θ A (τ A id) θ A. CMA A d refers to consumer market access for agricultural goods in destination market d. Consumer market access is a weighted sum of productivity-adjusted costs of production in each market i that could supply market d, with weights declining in the cost of trading from i to d (i.e., τid A ). From equation (8), county o sends more goods to county d if county o is relatively productive (high To A ) or relatively low cost (low q o or w o ). County o also sends more goods to county d if county d has high total income (high Y d ) or low overall consumer market access (low CMA A d ), meaning that county o faces fewer competitors when selling to market d. A similar expression can be derived for trade in the manufacturing sector. The manufacturing problem is complicated by the presence of free entry, however, Chaney (2008) shows that trade flows again take a gravity equation form: (10) (11) where CMA M d i U X M od = χ M T M o n M o (w β o r 1 β o ) θ M (τ M od ) θ M (CMA M d ) 1 Y d, T M i n M i (w β i r1 β i ) θ M (τ M id ) θ M. The only difference from equation (8) is that manufacturing exports from county o also depend on the endogenous number of varieties available in each location (i.e., n M o ). Equations (8) and (10) are known as a gravity equations, and they govern trade flows in this model. Deriving a gravity equation is dependent on the particular functional form assumptions for tastes and technology; indeed, it is difficult to imagine alternative assumptions that give rise to a gravity equation in these two settings (Arkolakis et al. 2011). The gravity equation is appealing because it dramatically simplifies a complex general equilibrium problem of spatial competition. A more appealing feature of the gravity equation is that it appears to fit data universally (Anderson and van Wincoop 2003, 2004; Combes et al. 2008). Thus, it is difficult to imagine an exercise that models trade among counties in the United States that does not predict trade flows will take the gravity form. Solving for the land rental rate. The absence of systematic data on 19th century trade flows between US counties means that Xod A and XM od are unobservable. However, the gravity equation implies tractable expressions for outcome variables that are observable and important for our purposes, such as the rural land rental rate (q o ). 21 The term χ A is a constant that is comprised of the parameters γ, θ A, and σ A. 11

13 The Cobb-Douglas agricultural technology leaves land a fixed share α of total output Y A so q o L o = αyo A markets clear, so all produced goods are bought (Yo A where L o is the (exogenous) quantity of agricultural land in county o. Goods (12) q 1+αθ A o F MA A o ( ) T A = α o w θ A(1 α) o F MA A o. L o o, = d XA od ). Thus, equation (8) implies: refers to firm market access over agricultural goods in origin o and is defined as: (13) F MA A o γ (τod) A θ A (CMA A d ) 1 Y d. d R,U Firm market access (F MA A o ) is a sum of terms for all destination counties d to which the rural county o tries to sell its agricultural goods. These terms include the size of the destination market (given by total income, Y d ) and the competitiveness of the destination market (given by its CMA A d term). All terms are inversely weighted by the cost of trading with each distant market ((τod A) θ A ). Substituting equation (7) into equation (12) to eliminate the wage, we obtain an expression for the land rental rate in county o: (14) ( ) ( ) ( ) 1 T A ln q o = κ + ln o γ(1 α) + ln(cma A o ) 1 + αθ A L o 1 + αθ ( ) A ( ) (1 γ)(1 α) + ln(cma M 1 o ) + ln(f MA A o ), 1 + αθ A 1 + αθ A where κ is a constant that subsumes model parameters and U. Equation (14) provides a parsimonious guide for empirical work. Equilibrium rural land rental rates (q o ) are log-linear in just three endogenous economic variables: (1) firm market access for agricultural goods that these rural areas produce (F MA A o ), (2) consumer market access to agricultural goods (CMA A o ), and (3) consumer market access to manufacturing goods (CMA M o ). Immobile land in county o will be more valuable if county o has: easy access to large uncompetitive markets (high F MA A o ) or easy access to agricultural goods (high CMA A o ) and manufactured goods (high CMA M o ) that workers value. Equation (14) has two key implications for analyzing the impact of railroads on the development of the American economy. First, all economic forces that make goods and factor markets interdependent across thousands of counties get collapsed into three sufficient statistics, each of which capture a slightly different concept of market access. All cross-county general equilibrium spillover effects of railroads are captured by working with this particular concept of market access. For example, one county receiving a railroad line would, in 12

14 principle, affect other counties: counties that remain without a railroad, counties that previously had a railroad, counties that traded with the new railroad county, counties that can now trade with the new railroad county, and so on. Even if railroad assignment is random, control counties are affected and a regression of land rents on railroad access will confound these effects and be biased. However, a regression of land rents on market access will be free of this bias because, according to the model, all counties market access variables will adjust with changes in the railroad network. The second key implication of equation (14) is that access to markets matters for county prosperity, as opposed to access to railroads or waterways. Market access can increase or decrease due to events far beyond county borders: any changes in the transportation network or changes in other counties market size. Thus, the empirical estimation is not identified solely from particular counties gaining railroad access; rather, county market access changes due to factors independent of decisions to extend railroads into particular locations. The model suggests several instrumental variable strategies, which we explore below. III.C From Theory to an Empirical Specification Equation (14) provides a useful approach for empirical work, though three obstacles prevent its direct empirical implementation. We discuss proposed solutions to these challenges, many of which are preliminary and can be improved upon in future work. First, the Census of Agriculture contains data on land values rather than land rental rates. 22 We use land values as a proxy for land rental rates. 23 Second, the technology term To A in equation (14) is not directly observable in our setting. 24 One plausible assumption is that this term is constant over time, or at least that changes in county agricultural technology are orthogonal to changes in market access. Because technology (T A o ) enters log-linearly in equation (14), we control for this term using county fixed effects. We also attempt to control for technological change that may be correlated with changes in market access through the use of state-year fixed effects, and year effects interacted with cubic polynomials in each county s latitude and longitude. Third, the three market access terms (F MA o, CMA A o, CMA M o ) are also not directly ob- 22 The Census reports the value of agricultural land and buildings. In some years the Census reports separate values for land and buildings, and land values are the largest share of this combined measure. 23 In particular, we assume that V o = qo δ, where V o is the land value and δ is the interest rate or discount rate relevant to those who own agricultural land. This assumes that agents face a fixed interest rate or discount rate and expect zero serial correlation in market access over time. We are exploring relaxing this assumption by allowing for forward-looking agents with different expectations for changes in market access. The analysis benefits from debates and uncertainty over the future paths of railroad construction, as well as uncertainty over changes in market sizes. 24 Following Eaton and Kortun (2002) and a large body of work since, a typical method for estimating the technology terms T A o and T M o uses the relationship between these terms and the exporter fixed effect in a gravity equation. Due to the lack of trade data in our setting, this method is unavailable to us. 13

15 servable because each contains variables that are unobserved in our setting (e.g., the wage w d, the capital rental rate r d, and the technology terms Td A and T d M ). We are exploring calibrating these terms to population data (as in Redding and Sturm 2007); for now, we proxy for F MA o, CMA A o, and CMA M o Harris (1954). 25 with one simplified market access term (MA o ) inspired by Harris originally defined a concept of market potential, based on the number and magnitude of markets available at low trade costs. This market potential term (MP H ot ) effectively equals d =o (τ odt A ) 1 Xdt A, where XA dt is a proxy for total demand at location d, such as population or the value of agricultural land. That is, market potential is the sum of all other market sizes (X A dt ) down-weighted by inverse trade costs (weights are 1/τ A odt ). We extend the Harris formula in two respects. First, in our model, trade costs do not diminish effective market sizes inversely; rather, they do so to the power of θ A and typical estimates of θ A (discussed below) are significantly greater than one. Second, the F MA A o formula in equation (13) implies that market size should be deflated by the competitiveness of that market (CMA A d ). Intuitively, a large market d is more appealing to exporters in county o if market d is served by fewer other counties (and, thus, prices are high in market d). The same is true for CMA A o and CMA M o : access to a large market d is more appealing to consumers in market o if market d supplies fewer other counties (and, thus, sells goods for low prices). To incorporate these multilateral effects, we divide market sizes (X A dt ) by a proxy for county d s competitiveness level (MP H dt = i =d,o (τ A dit ) 1 X A it ). In this way, we condense three unobserved market access terms (F MA o, CMA A o, CMA M o ) into one observed market access term: (15) MA ot = d =o (τ A odt ) θ A X A dt i =d,o (τ A dit ) θ A X A it. This combined market access term is more ad hoc than the three terms that follow directly from the model. 26 However, we find the assumption plausible that a farmer s market access is positively correlated with the farmer having lower trade costs with: (1) larger populations demanding the farmer s goods, (2) larger populations that have fewer other sources for acquiring the farmer s goods, (3) larger populations producing the farmer s demanded goods, and (4) larger populations that have fewer other destinations to sell the farmer s demanded goods. 25 Note that collapsing CMA A o, CMA M o, and F MA A o into one market access variable removes the model s distinction between urban and rural counties (and between agricultural and manufacturing sectors). This simplification removes the scope for analyzing cross-county specification into sectors and analyzing separate effects on urban and rural counties. 26 Formally, MA ot can be shown to approximate CMA A ot, CMA M ot and F MA A ot as the location of manufacturing and agriculture in the vicinity of county o becomes more and more similar. 14

16 These four forces are embodied in (15). The term MA ot is calculated for each county in 1870 and 1890 using the GIS-computed county-to-county lowest cost transportation route. 27 Summarizing the above discussion, we regress land values in county o and year t on a county fixed effect (α o ), state-by-year fixed effects (α st ), a cubic polynomial in county latitude and longitude interacted with year effects (f(x o, y o )γ t ), and log market access (MA ot ): (16) ln V ot = α o + α st + f(x o, y o )γ t + β ln(ma ot ) + ε ot. The sample is a balanced panel of 2,161 counties with land value data in 1870 and Standard errors are clustered at the state level to adjust for heteroskedasticity and withinstate correlation over time. III.D Empirical Results Table 1 presents results from estimating equation (16). Column 1 reports the estimated impact of market access on land values, when defining market access based on other counties population (X A dt = L dt in equation (15)). Column 2 repeats this regression, defining market access based on other counties land value. In columns 1 and 2, market access is estimated to have an economically large and statistically significant impact on county land values. The elasticity between land values and market access is (column 1) or (column 2), indicating that our preliminary results are insensitive to the variable chosen to capture size of each county market. This similarity in results is reassuring, as neither proxy matches total demand in other counties (Xdt A in the model). 28 There is substantial variation in market access across the country, and the baseline estimates may be influenced by outliers: frontier counties whose market access and land values both increased dramatically. Column 3 weights the regression by 1870 county populations. Column 4 excludes areas West of Texas. The estimated elasticities decline to 1.2 and 1; unsurprisingly smaller if market access is more influential on land values in less-dense agriculture-exporting counties. Estimated coefficients of imply a large elasticity between land values and market access, but in the range one might expect using the approximation of our model discussed above. A coefficient of 1.05 is predicted by plausible parameter values As described below, we follow Donaldson (2010) and use a value of θ A = 3.8 in constructing MA ot. 28 The full model predicts a log-linear relationship between land values and market access. Consistent with this theoretical relationship, when including a fourth-degree polynomial in the log of market access, the coefficient on the linear term remains similar and the higher-order terms are( jointly) insignificant α The coefficient on market access in Equation (16) should satisfy β = 1+αθ A under the model approximation discussed above. The parameter α is the land share in agricultural production, which Caselli 15

17 III.E Economic Impact of Eliminating Railroads and/or Extending Canals The estimated relationship between market access and land values can be used to estimate the aggregate economic impact associated with counterfactual scenarios. In particular, we consider two scenarios: (1) eliminating all railroads in 1890, and (2) replacing all railroads in 1890 with Fogel s proposed canal extensions. First, consider the economic impact if no railroads existed in We calculate the resulting market access of each county in 1890, using computed county-to-county freight costs in a spatial network that excludes all railroads. We find that market access falls by 63%, on average, when all railroads are eliminated. By comparison, the average county increase in market access from 1870 to 1890 was 50%; thus, the counterfactual fall in market access is not substantially out of sample. 30 County land value falls by log points for every log point decline in market access (from column 1), and the implied percent decline in land value is multiplied by county land value in Summing over all counties, eliminating railroads in 1890 would have decreased the total value of US agricultural land by 73% or $9.5 billion (1890 dollars). The implied annual economic loss is $751 million (6.3% of GNP) using Fogel s preferred rate of return. 31 Second, consider the economic impact of replacing all railroads with an extended canal network in Fogel (1964) proposes an extended canal network that may have largely substituted for railroads; indeed, the distance buffer calculations suggested that extended canals mostly substituted for railroads. Our market access methodology suggests that canal extensions were not as effective, as county market access declines on average by 57%. Replacing railroads with extended canals generates an annual economic loss of $692 million (5.8% of GNP). When the benefits of railroads are measured more accurately reflecting the wide dispersal of railroad lines and direct connections to markets the 1890 railroad network generates benefits that far exceed the potential gains from feasible improvements in canals. III.F Endogeneity of Railroad Construction and Changes in Market Access The baseline analysis has developed the necessary theory and data to regress land values on market access; further work can improve identification of this regression. Changes in county market access may be correlated with unobserved determinants of county land values, though the preliminary regressions do control for county and state-by-year fixed effects and and Coleman (2001) take to be 0.19 based on Census data. The parameter θ A is known as the trade elasticity. Donaldson (2010) estimates a value of 3.8 in colonial Indian agriculture and Simonovska and Waugh (2011) estimate a value of 4.5 in modern OECD manufacturing. Using α = 0.19 and θ A = 3.8 we obtain β = Our specification is an approximation to the ideal model, but we find this encouraging. 30 Note also that the impact of market access was estimated to be approximately linear. 31 For an elasticity of (from column 3), the annual economic loss is $679 million (5.7% of GNP). The estimated economic loss declines less than linearly in the estimated elasticity. 16

18 year-specific polynomial controls for county latitude and longitude. County market access depends on three terms: costs of trading with other counties ((τodt A ) θ A ), market sizes in other counties (Xdt A ), and the competitiveness of other counties (( i =d,o XA it (τdit A ) θ A )). Plausible exogenous variation in any of these three terms can be used to identify the impact of market access on land values. Thus, the identification problem has more potential solutions than a direct impact evaluation of railroad placement. In the first term, county railroad construction is unlikely to be randomly assigned (conditional on the controls). One approach may be to replicate identification strategies by Atack et al. to use some exogenous variation in railroad placement, or adapt methods used by Baum-Snow (2007) and Michaels (2008). Alternatively, we can exploit the larger impact of nationwide railroad expansion on counties with worse access to waterways; in practice, counties (non)access to waterways can instrument for improved market access from 1870 to In the second term, changes in other counties population is less likely to be correlated with a county s own land values (conditional on the controls). We can instrument for changes in market access with changes in other counties population; in particular, we can control for changes in nearby counties population and define the instrument based on changes in population for the county s initial trading partners. Alternatively, we can exploit market size variation in the impact of trade cost declines: among counties that experience large declines in trade costs, some become able to trade with larger markets. In the third term, changes in other counties access to other counties is less likely to be correlated with a county s own land values (conditional on the controls). These multilateral competitiveness terms are determined by factors twice-removed from a county: if a county s trading partner gains access to other markets, it decreases that county s effective market access. We can instrument for changes in county market access with (inverse) changes in the county s trading partners access to other markets (not including itself). In practice, some of these instrumental variables strategies will have stronger or weaker predictive power, but comparing results across specifications should be informative. As an initial empirical exercise, we focus on variation in county market access that is orthogonal to that particular county s railroad access. Table 2, column 1 reports the baseline estimate for comparison. Table 2, column 2, reports the estimated impact on land values from a county having any railroad track, conditional on county fixed effects, state-by-year fixed effects, and year-specific cubic polynomials in latitude and longitude. A county containing any railroad track is associated with a log point increase in land values, though county railroad construction may be endogenous and jointly determined with land values. The estimated impact of market access is remarkably robust to controlling for whether a county has any railroad track (Table 2, column 3). Once controlling for market access, the 17

19 estimated impact of any railroad track is no longer substantial or statistically significant. These estimates are similar when also controlling for the length of railroad track by county (Table 2, column 4). 32 Thus, county market access is correlated with railroad track, but the estimated impact of market access is robust to exploiting variation in market access that is independent of that county s railroad construction and associated endogeneity bias. IV Conclusion (To Come) 32 The coefficient on market access is also robust to controlling for high-order polynomials of railroad track length. 18

20 References Anderson, S. P., A. de Palma, and J. Thisse (1992): Discrete Choice Theory of Product Differentiation. MIT Press, Cambridge. Anderson, J. and E. van Wincoop (2003): Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle, American Economic Review, 93(1), pp Anderson, J. and E. van Wincoop (2004): Trade Costs, Journal of Economic Literature XLII(3), pp Arkolakis, C., A. Costinot, and A. Rodríguez-Clare (2011): New Trade Models, Same Old Gains?, American Economic Review, forthcoming. Atack, J., F. Bateman, M. Haines and R.A. Margo (2010): Did Railroads Induce or Follow Economic Growth? Urbanization and Population Growth in the American Midwest, , Social Science History, 34(2), pp Atack, J., M. Haines and R.A. Margo (2011): Railroads and the Rise of the Factory: Evidence for the United States, , in P. Rhode, J. Rosenbloom, D. Weiman, eds. Economic Evolution and Revolutions in Historical Time. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press. Atack, J. and R.A. Margo (2010): "The Impact of Access to Rail Transportation on Agricultural Improvement: The American Midwest as a Test Case, ," BU Mimeo, March. Axtell, R. (2001): Zipf Distribution of U.S. Firm Sizes, Science, 293(5536), pp Baum-Snow, N. (2007), "Did Highways Cause Suburbanization?," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(2), pp Caselli, F. and W. Coleman II (2001): The U.S. Structural Transformation and Regional Convergence: A Reinterpretation, The Journal of Political Economy, 109(3), pp Chaney, T. (2008): Distorted Gravity: The Intensive and Extensive Margins of International Trade, American Economic Review, 98(4), pp Combes, P-P., T. Mayer and J-F. Thisse (2008): Economic Geography: the Integration of Regions and Nations, Princeton: Princeton University Press. 19

21 David, P. (1969): Transport Innovation and Economic Growth: Professor Fogel on and off the Rails, The Economic History Review, 22(3), pp Donaldson, D. (2010): Railroads of the Raj: Estimating the Impact of Transportation Infrastructure, revisions requested at The American Economic Review. Eaton, J. and S. Kortum (2002): Technology, Geography and Trade, Econometrica, 70(5), pp Fogel, R. W. (1964): Railroads and American Economic Growth: Essays in Economic History, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore. Fogel, R. W. (1979): Notes on the Social Saving Controversy, Journal of Economic History, 39, pp Haines, M. (2005): Historical, Demographic, Economic, and Social Data: US, , ICPSR. Haines, M. and R.A. Margo (2008): Railroads and Local Economic Development: The United States in the 1850s, in J. Rosenbloom, ed., Quantitative Economic History: The Good of Counting, pp London: Routledge. Harris, C. (1954): The Market as a Factor in the Localization of Industry in the United States, Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 64, pp Herrendorf, B. J.A. Schmitz Jr. and A.Teixeira (2009): "Transportation and Development: Insights from the U.S., ," Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report Hornbeck, R. (2010): Barbed Wire: Property Rights and Agricultural Development, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125, pp Melitz, M. (2003): The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity, Econometrica, 71, pp Michaels, G. (2008): "The Effect of Trade on the Demand for Skill: Evidence from the Interstate Highway System," The Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(4), pp Redding, S. and D. Sturm (2007): The Cost of Remoteness: Evidence from German Division and Reunification, American Economic Review, 98(5), pp

22 Simonovska, I. and M. Waugh (2011): Elasticity of Trade: Estimates and Evidence, Unpublished Manuscript, UC Davis and NYU. Williamson, J.G. (1974): Late Nineteenth-Century American Development: a General Equilibrium History, New York: Cambridge University Press. 21

23 Figure 1. Railroad Network in 1870 and 1890 A. Railroads in 1870 B. Railroads in 1890 Notes: Railroad lines are traced in GIS from georeferenced railroad Atlase images in 1870 and

24 Figure 2. Waterway Network A. Navigable Rivers B. Navigable Rivers and Canals C. Navigable Rivers, Canals, Lakes, and Coastal Routes D. All Navigable Waterways and Proposed Canal Extensions Notes: Navigable rivers, canals, and proposed canal extensions are traced in GIS, as defined by Fogel (1964). Lakes and coasts are saturated with waterways. 23

25 Figure 3. Available Waterways and Railroads, by Year A. Waterways and 1870 Railroads B. Waterways and 1890 Railroads Notes: Railroads are as defined in Figure 1. Waterways are as defined in Figure 2C. 24

26 Figure mile Buffers around Railroads, Waterways, and Proposed Canal Extensions A. Railroads in 1890 B. Waterways C. Railroads, overlaid with Waterways D. Railroads, overlaid with Proposed Canals, then Waterways Notes: Using GIS software, 40-mile buffers are drawn around railroads, waterways, and proposed canal extensions. 25

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory)

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory) 14.581 MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory) Dave Donaldson Spring 2011 Introduction to Gravity Models Recall that in this course we have so far seen a wide range of trade models:

More information

Entrepôts and Economic Geography

Entrepôts and Economic Geography Entrepôts and Economic Geography Hugh Montag & Heyu Xiong 6/2/17 Motivation What explains the uneven distribution of economic activities across space? A large empirical literature has emphasized the significance

More information

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models Dave Donaldson (MIT) CEMMAP MC July 2018 1 All material based on earlier courses taught

More information

Gravity Models and the Armington Assumption

Gravity Models and the Armington Assumption Gravity Models and the Armington Assumption Background Economists love the elegance and completeness of physics, and what could be more elegant than Newton s Law of Universal Gravity? To recap: The gravitational

More information

Cities in Bad Shape: Urban Geometry in India

Cities in Bad Shape: Urban Geometry in India Cities in Bad Shape: Urban Geometry in India Mariaflavia Harari MIT IGC Cities Research Group Conference 21 May 2015 Introduction Why Study City Shape A wide range of factors determine intra-urban commuting

More information

Chapter 4. Explanation of the Model. Satoru Kumagai Inter-disciplinary Studies, IDE-JETRO, Japan

Chapter 4. Explanation of the Model. Satoru Kumagai Inter-disciplinary Studies, IDE-JETRO, Japan Chapter 4 Explanation of the Model Satoru Kumagai Inter-disciplinary Studies, IDE-JETRO, Japan Toshitaka Gokan Inter-disciplinary Studies, IDE-JETRO, Japan Ikumo Isono Bangkok Research Center, IDE-JETRO,

More information

The challenge of globalization for Finland and its regions: The new economic geography perspective

The challenge of globalization for Finland and its regions: The new economic geography perspective The challenge of globalization for Finland and its regions: The new economic geography perspective Prepared within the framework of study Finland in the Global Economy, Prime Minister s Office, Helsinki

More information

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory)

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory) 14.581 International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory) 14.581 Week 9 Spring 2013 14.581 (Week 9) Gravity Models (Theory) Spring 2013 1 / 44 Today s Plan 1 The Simplest Gravity Model: Armington

More information

Eaton Kortum Model (2002)

Eaton Kortum Model (2002) Eaton Kortum Model (2002) Seyed Ali Madanizadeh Sharif U. of Tech. November 20, 2015 Seyed Ali Madanizadeh (Sharif U. of Tech.) Eaton Kortum Model (2002) November 20, 2015 1 / 41 Introduction Eaton and

More information

Internation1al Trade

Internation1al Trade 4.58 International Trade Class notes on 4/8/203 The Armington Model. Equilibrium Labor endowments L i for i = ; :::n CES utility ) CES price index P = i= (w i ij ) P j n Bilateral trade ows follow gravity

More information

Use Eaton Kortum model to look at very cool data

Use Eaton Kortum model to look at very cool data Railroads of the Raj Dave Donaldson, MIT Impact of transportation on: Prices Welfare Use Eaton Kortum model to look at very cool data Background about RR in India 1860 1870 1880 1890 1900 1910 1920 1930

More information

International Trade 31E00500

International Trade 31E00500 International Trade 31E00500 Lecture 6: Intra-industry trade and Gravity modelling Saara Tamminen 1 1 VATT Institute of Economic Research, Finland Winter 2016 Tamminen (VATT) Lecture 6 21.1.2016 1 / 53

More information

The Geography of Development: Evaluating Migration Restrictions and Coastal Flooding

The Geography of Development: Evaluating Migration Restrictions and Coastal Flooding The Geography of Development: Evaluating Migration Restrictions and Coastal Flooding Klaus Desmet SMU Dávid Krisztián Nagy Princeton University Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Princeton University World Bank, February

More information

Trade, Inequality and Costly Redistribution

Trade, Inequality and Costly Redistribution Trade, Inequality and Costly Redistribution Pol Antràs Alonso de Gortari Oleg Itskhoki Harvard Harvard Princeton ILO Symposium September 2015 1 / 30 Introduction International trade raises real income

More information

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation Daron Acemoglu MIT September 19, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition and Innovation September 19, 2011. 1 / 51 Competition and Innovation

More information

Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies:

Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies: Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies: Explorations with a Dynamic General Equilibrium Model of Labor Earnings based on Heckman, Lochner and Taber, Review of Economic

More information

More on Roy Model of Self-Selection

More on Roy Model of Self-Selection V. J. Hotz Rev. May 26, 2007 More on Roy Model of Self-Selection Results drawn on Heckman and Sedlacek JPE, 1985 and Heckman and Honoré, Econometrica, 1986. Two-sector model in which: Agents are income

More information

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms Andrew Bernard, Tuck and NBER Stephen e Redding, LSE and CEPR Peter Schott, Yale and NBER 1 Introduction How do economies respond when opening to trade? Classical

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t ) 6. Economic growth Let us recall the main facts on growth examined in the first chapter and add some additional ones. (1) Real output (per-worker) roughly grows at a constant rate (i.e. labor productivity

More information

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition, Policy and Technological Progress

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition, Policy and Technological Progress 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition, Policy and Technological Progress Daron Acemoglu MIT September 15, 2016. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 15, 2016.

More information

Measuring the Gains from Trade: They are Large!

Measuring the Gains from Trade: They are Large! Measuring the Gains from Trade: They are Large! Andrés Rodríguez-Clare (UC Berkeley and NBER) May 12, 2012 Ultimate Goal Quantify effects of trade policy changes Instrumental Question How large are GT?

More information

Changes in Transportation Infrastructure and Commuting Patterns in U.S. Metropolitan Areas,

Changes in Transportation Infrastructure and Commuting Patterns in U.S. Metropolitan Areas, Changes in Transportation Infrastructure and Commuting Patterns in U.S. Metropolitan Areas, 1960-2000 Nathaniel Baum-Snow Department of Economics Box B Brown University Providence, RI 02912 Nathaniel_Baum-Snow@brown.edu

More information

International Trade. Lecture 4: the extensive margin of trade. Thomas Chaney. Sciences Po. Thomas Chaney (Sciences Po) International Trade 1 / 17

International Trade. Lecture 4: the extensive margin of trade. Thomas Chaney. Sciences Po. Thomas Chaney (Sciences Po) International Trade 1 / 17 International Trade ecture 4: the extensive margin of trade Thomas Chaney Sciences Po Thomas Chaney (Sciences Po) International Trade / 7 Target of the paper Explain the observed role of the extensive

More information

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Government Purchases and Endogenous Growth Consider the following endogenous growth model with government purchases (G) in continuous time. Government purchases enhance production, and the production

More information

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model New Notes on the Solow Growth Model Roberto Chang September 2009 1 The Model The firstingredientofadynamicmodelisthedescriptionofthetimehorizon. In the original Solow model, time is continuous and the

More information

Cities in Bad Shape: Urban Geometry in India

Cities in Bad Shape: Urban Geometry in India Cities in Bad Shape: Urban Geometry in India Mariaflavia Harari presented by Federico Curci September 15, 2015 Harari Cities in Bad Shape September 15, 2015 1 / 19 Research question Estimate effect of

More information

Modeling firms locational choice

Modeling firms locational choice Modeling firms locational choice Giulio Bottazzi DIMETIC School Pécs, 05 July 2010 Agglomeration derive from some form of externality. Drivers of agglomeration can be of two types: pecuniary and non-pecuniary.

More information

Economic Development and the Spatial Allocation of Labor: Evidence From Indonesia. Gharad Bryan (LSE) Melanie Morten (Stanford) May 19, 2015

Economic Development and the Spatial Allocation of Labor: Evidence From Indonesia. Gharad Bryan (LSE) Melanie Morten (Stanford) May 19, 2015 Economic Development and the Spatial Allocation of Labor: Evidence From Indonesia Gharad Bryan (LSE) Melanie Morten (Stanford) May 19, 2015 Gains from Spatial Reallocation of Labor? Remove observables

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT November 28, 2017. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 9 November 28, 2017. 1 / 41 First-Generation Models

More information

Estimating the effect of exchange rate changes on total exports

Estimating the effect of exchange rate changes on total exports Estimating the effect of exchange rate changes on total exports Thierry Mayer (Science Po) and Walter Steingress (Banque de France) 12th CompNet Conference Prague 2016 Motivation Real Effective Exchange

More information

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. Ph.D. Core Exam -- Macroeconomics 5 January 2015 -- 8:00 am to 3:00 pm Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. A1 (required): Ending Quantitative Easing Now that the U.S.

More information

Commuting, Migration, and Rural Development

Commuting, Migration, and Rural Development MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Commuting, Migration, and Rural Development Ayele Gelan Socio-economic Research Program, The Macaulay Institute, Aberdeen, UK 003 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/903/

More information

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances Johannes Brumm University of Zurich Georgios Georgiadis European Central Bank Johannes Gräb European Central Bank Fabian Trottner Princeton

More information

Discussion Papers In Economics And Business

Discussion Papers In Economics And Business Discussion Papers In Economics And Business Nonlinear Effects of the Transport Costs on the Wage Inequality Yuichiro Matsumoto Discussion Paper 18-07 Graduate School of Economics and Osaka School of International

More information

International Trade

International Trade 4.58 International Trade Class notes on 5//3 Krugman (JPE, 99) This is an extremely influential paper on a theory of economic geography (8,5 cites). It formalizes, in an extremely simple and clear manner,

More information

Economic Geography of the Long Island Region

Economic Geography of the Long Island Region Geography of Data Economic Geography of the Long Island Region Copyright 2011 AFG 1 The geography of economic activity requires: - the gathering of spatial data - the location of data geographically -

More information

Visitor Flows Model for Queensland a new approach

Visitor Flows Model for Queensland a new approach Visitor Flows Model for Queensland a new approach Jason. van Paassen 1, Mark. Olsen 2 1 Parsons Brinckerhoff Australia Pty Ltd, Brisbane, QLD, Australia 2 Tourism Queensland, Brisbane, QLD, Australia 1

More information

Impact Analysis of Economic Linkages of South Korea with North Korea Using a CGE Model (draft version)

Impact Analysis of Economic Linkages of South Korea with North Korea Using a CGE Model (draft version) Comments Only Impact Analysis of Economic Linkages of South Korea with North Korea Using a CGE Model (draft version) Euijune Kim Professor, Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Development and

More information

A Summary of Economic Methodology

A Summary of Economic Methodology A Summary of Economic Methodology I. The Methodology of Theoretical Economics All economic analysis begins with theory, based in part on intuitive insights that naturally spring from certain stylized facts,

More information

Lecture 19: Common property resources

Lecture 19: Common property resources Lecture 19: Common property resources Economics 336 Economics 336 (Toronto) Lecture 19: Common property resources 1 / 19 Introduction Common property resource: A resource for which no agent has full property

More information

ECO 310: Empirical Industrial Organization Lecture 2 - Estimation of Demand and Supply

ECO 310: Empirical Industrial Organization Lecture 2 - Estimation of Demand and Supply ECO 310: Empirical Industrial Organization Lecture 2 - Estimation of Demand and Supply Dimitri Dimitropoulos Fall 2014 UToronto 1 / 55 References RW Section 3. Wooldridge, J. (2008). Introductory Econometrics:

More information

From Difference to Differential Equations I

From Difference to Differential Equations I From Difference to Differential Equations I Start with a simple difference equation x (t + 1) x (t) = g(x (t)). (30) Now consider the following approximation for any t [0, 1], x (t + t) x (t) t g(x (t)),

More information

Thoughts toward autonomous land development. Introduction

Thoughts toward autonomous land development. Introduction Thoughts toward autonomous land development Spatial Transformation of Regular grid Irrigation Frameworks Bangkok and Cairo A Work in Progress Information based on student workshop June 2009 and earlier

More information

A Harris-Todaro Agent-Based Model to Rural-Urban Migration

A Harris-Todaro Agent-Based Model to Rural-Urban Migration Brazilian Journal of Physics, vol. 36, no. 3A, September, 26 63 A Harris-Todaro Agent-Based Model to Rural-Urban Migration Aquino L. Espíndola, Instituto de Física, Universidade Federal Fluminense 24.21-34,

More information

International Trade and Agglomeration in Asymmetric World: Core-Periphery Approach

International Trade and Agglomeration in Asymmetric World: Core-Periphery Approach Research Motivation Our Results/Contribution International Trade and Agglomeration in Asymmetric World: Core-Periphery Approach Alexander V. Sidorov Sobolev Institute of Mathematics, Novosibirsk, Russia

More information

Clarendon Lectures, Lecture 1 Directed Technical Change: Importance, Issues and Approaches

Clarendon Lectures, Lecture 1 Directed Technical Change: Importance, Issues and Approaches Clarendon Lectures, Lecture 1 Directed Technical Change: Importance, Issues and Approaches Daron Acemoglu October 22, 2007 Introduction New technologies not neutral towards different factors/groups. 1.

More information

Motivation A Figure 1 Figure 2 Table 1 Table 2

Motivation A Figure 1 Figure 2 Table 1 Table 2 Future Work Motivation A Figure 1 Figure 2 Table 1 Table 2 Motivation B Markup Di erences: SOEs vs. POEs Markup Di erences Across Sectors Sectoral Di erences Motivation Key Novelty Model Trade Liberalization,

More information

Roads and the Geography of Economic Activities in Mexico

Roads and the Geography of Economic Activities in Mexico Roads and the Geography of Economic Activities in Mexico Brian Blankespoor Development Data Group, The World Bank Théophile Bougna Development Research Group (DIME), The World Bank Rafael Garduno-Rivera

More information

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam? The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam? Jean Louis Brillet, France For presentation at the LINK 2014 Conference New York, 22nd 24th October, 2014 Advertisement!!! The model uses EViews The

More information

General motivation behind the augmented Solow model

General motivation behind the augmented Solow model General motivation behind the augmented Solow model Empirical analysis suggests that the elasticity of output Y with respect to capital implied by the Solow model (α 0.3) is too low to reconcile the model

More information

Quantifying the effects of NTMs. Xinyi Li Trade Policies Review Division, WTO Secretariat 12 th ARTNeT Capacity Building Workshop December 2016

Quantifying the effects of NTMs. Xinyi Li Trade Policies Review Division, WTO Secretariat 12 th ARTNeT Capacity Building Workshop December 2016 Quantifying the effects of NTMs Xinyi Li Trade Policies Review Division, WTO Secretariat 12 th ARTNeT Capacity Building Workshop December 2016 1 Approaches to quantifying NTMs Chen and Novy (2012) described

More information

General Equilibrium and Welfare

General Equilibrium and Welfare and Welfare Lectures 2 and 3, ECON 4240 Spring 2017 University of Oslo 24.01.2017 and 31.01.2017 1/37 Outline General equilibrium: look at many markets at the same time. Here all prices determined in the

More information

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013) The Ramsey Model (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 213) 1 Introduction The Ramsey model (or neoclassical growth model) is one of the prototype models in dynamic macroeconomics.

More information

Seaport Status, Access, and Regional Development in Indonesia

Seaport Status, Access, and Regional Development in Indonesia Seaport Status, Access, and Regional Development in Indonesia Muhammad Halley Yudhistira Yusuf Sofiyandi Institute for Economic and Social Research (LPEM), Faculty of Economics and Business, University

More information

STATEMENT ON DEVELOPMENT CHALLENGES OF THE LAND- LOCKED LEAST DEVELOPED COUNTRIES AND THEIR PARTICIPATION IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE

STATEMENT ON DEVELOPMENT CHALLENGES OF THE LAND- LOCKED LEAST DEVELOPED COUNTRIES AND THEIR PARTICIPATION IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE STATEMENT ON DEVELOPMENT CHALLENGES OF THE LAND- LOCKED LEAST DEVELOPED COUNTRIES AND THEIR PARTICIPATION IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE Introduction It is widely acknowledged by many that Landlocked Least Developed

More information

Paul Krugman s New Economic Geography: past, present and future. J.-F. Thisse CORE-UCLouvain (Belgium)

Paul Krugman s New Economic Geography: past, present and future. J.-F. Thisse CORE-UCLouvain (Belgium) Paul Krugman s New Economic Geography: past, present and future J.-F. Thisse CORE-UCLouvain (Belgium) Economic geography seeks to explain the riddle of unequal spatial development (at different spatial

More information

arxiv:physics/ v1 [physics.soc-ph] 27 Oct 2005

arxiv:physics/ v1 [physics.soc-ph] 27 Oct 2005 A Harris-Todaro Agent-Based Model to Rural-Urban Migration Aquino L. Espíndola Instituto de Física, Universidade Federal Fluminense 24.21-34, Niterói, RJ, Brazil aquino@if.uff.br arxiv:physics/51248v1

More information

Price Discrimination through Refund Contracts in Airlines

Price Discrimination through Refund Contracts in Airlines Introduction Price Discrimination through Refund Contracts in Airlines Paan Jindapon Department of Economics and Finance The University of Texas - Pan American Department of Economics, Finance and Legal

More information

Gravity Models: Theoretical Foundations and related estimation issues

Gravity Models: Theoretical Foundations and related estimation issues Gravity Models: Theoretical Foundations and related estimation issues ARTNet Capacity Building Workshop for Trade Research Phnom Penh, Cambodia 2-6 June 2008 Outline 1. Theoretical foundations From Tinbergen

More information

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj Macro II (UC3M, MA/PhD Econ) Professor: Matthias Kredler Problem Set 1 Due: 29 April 216 You are encouraged to work in groups; however, every student has to hand in his/her own version of the solution.

More information

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I Name: Students ID: ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I I. Short Questions (21/2 points each) Mark the following statements as True (T) or False (F) and give a brief explanation of your answer in each case. 1. 2.

More information

On Spatial Dynamics. Klaus Desmet Universidad Carlos III. and. Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Princeton University. April 2009

On Spatial Dynamics. Klaus Desmet Universidad Carlos III. and. Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Princeton University. April 2009 On Spatial Dynamics Klaus Desmet Universidad Carlos and Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Princeton University April 2009 Desmet and Rossi-Hansberg () On Spatial Dynamics April 2009 1 / 15 ntroduction Economists

More information

ARTNeT Interactive Gravity Modeling Tool

ARTNeT Interactive Gravity Modeling Tool Evidence-Based Trade Policymaking Capacity Building Programme ARTNeT Interactive Gravity Modeling Tool Witada Anukoonwattaka (PhD) UNESCAP 26 July 2011 Outline Background on gravity model of trade and

More information

Does agglomeration explain regional income inequalities?

Does agglomeration explain regional income inequalities? Does agglomeration explain regional income inequalities? Karen Helene Midelfart Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration and CEPR August 31, 2004 First draft Abstract This paper seeks

More information

TECHNICAL APPENDIX. 7. Agents Decisions in the Cobb-Douglas Case

TECHNICAL APPENDIX. 7. Agents Decisions in the Cobb-Douglas Case TECHNICAL APPENDIX 7 Agents Decisions in the Cobb-Douglas Case A closed form solution for production and trade obtains if we assume that utility is a Cobb-Douglas function of the consumption bundle: u

More information

Spatial Aspects of Trade Liberalization in Colombia: A General Equilibrium Approach. Eduardo Haddad Jaime Bonet Geoffrey Hewings Fernando Perobelli

Spatial Aspects of Trade Liberalization in Colombia: A General Equilibrium Approach. Eduardo Haddad Jaime Bonet Geoffrey Hewings Fernando Perobelli Spatial Aspects of Trade Liberalization in Colombia: A General Equilibrium Approach Eduardo Haddad Jaime Bonet Geoffrey Hewings Fernando Perobelli Outline Motivation The CEER model Simulation results Final

More information

Problem 1 (30 points)

Problem 1 (30 points) Problem (30 points) Prof. Robert King Consider an economy in which there is one period and there are many, identical households. Each household derives utility from consumption (c), leisure (l) and a public

More information

Online Appendix The Growth of Low Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market. By David H. Autor and David Dorn

Online Appendix The Growth of Low Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market. By David H. Autor and David Dorn Online Appendix The Growth of Low Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market By David H. Autor and David Dorn 1 2 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MONTH YEAR I. Online Appendix Tables

More information

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Endogenous Growth with Human Capital Consider the following endogenous growth model with both physical capital (k (t)) and human capital (h (t)) in continuous time. The representative household solves

More information

Among the available options: horizontal separation (HS) and vertical separation (VS)

Among the available options: horizontal separation (HS) and vertical separation (VS) Among the available options: horizontal separation (HS) and vertical separation (VS) Horizontal separation (or systems competition per Pittman 2011) Inter-system competition between vertically integrated

More information

LOCATIONAL PREFERENCES OF FDI FIRMS IN TURKEY

LOCATIONAL PREFERENCES OF FDI FIRMS IN TURKEY LOCATIONAL PREFERENCES OF FDI FIRMS IN TURKEY Prof. Dr. Lale BERKÖZ Assist. Prof. Dr.S. SenceTÜRK I.T.U. Faculty of Architecture Istanbul/TURKEY E-mail: lberkoz@itu.edu.tr INTRODUCTION Foreign direct investment

More information

The E ect of Infrastructure Investment in a Low-Growth Environment

The E ect of Infrastructure Investment in a Low-Growth Environment The E ect of Infrastructure Investment in a Low-Growth Environment Evidence from the Great Depression Miguel Morin and Scott N. Swisher IV, University of Cambridge June 22, 2016 Miguel Morin and Scott

More information

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011 Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano University of Munich July 22, 2011 & 1 / 20 & & 2 / 20 My Bachelor Thesis: Ottaviano et al. (2009) apply the model to study gains from the euro & 3 / 20 Melitz and Ottaviano

More information

BROOKINGS May

BROOKINGS May Appendix 1. Technical Methodology This study combines detailed data on transit systems, demographics, and employment to determine the accessibility of jobs via transit within and across the country s 100

More information

Spatial Competition and the Structure of Retail Markets

Spatial Competition and the Structure of Retail Markets 18 th World IMACS / MODSIM Congress, Cairns, Australia 13-17 July 2009 http://mssanz.org.au/modsim09 Spatial Competition and the Structure of Retail Markets Dr S. Beare, S. Szakiel Concept Economics, Australian

More information

Macroeconomics Field Exam. August 2007

Macroeconomics Field Exam. August 2007 Macroeconomics Field Exam August 2007 Answer all questions in the exam. Suggested times correspond to the questions weights in the exam grade. Make your answers as precise as possible, using graphs, equations,

More information

Trade, Neoclassical Growth and Heterogeneous Firms

Trade, Neoclassical Growth and Heterogeneous Firms Trade, Neoclassical Growth and eterogeneous Firms Julian Emami Namini Department of Economics, University of Duisburg Essen, Campus Essen, Germany Email: emami@vwl.uni essen.de 10th March 2006 Abstract

More information

Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade

Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade Alfonso A. Irarrazabal University of Oslo September 25, 2007 Contents 1 Simple Ricardian Model 3 1.1 Preferences................................. 3 1.2 Technologies.................................

More information

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Paul Pichler and Gerhard Sorger This Version: February 2006 Abstract We study the Ramsey (1928) model under the assumption that households act strategically.

More information

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011 Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano University of Munich July 22, 2011 & 1 / 20 & & 2 / 20 My Bachelor Thesis: Ottaviano et al. (2009) apply the model to study gains from the euro & 3 / 20 Melitz and Ottaviano

More information

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change Chapter 7 Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change 225 Economic Growth: Lecture Notes 7.1 Expanding Product Variety: The Romer Model There are three sectors: one for the final good sector, one

More information

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form: Practice Questions for Mid-Term I Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form: y f(k) = k α ; α (0, 1) (1) where y and k are output per worker and capital per worker respectively.

More information

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill remium Ariel Burstein UCLA and NBER Jonathan Vogel Columbia and NBER April 22 Abstract In this Addendum we set up a perfectly competitive version

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Directed Technological Change

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Directed Technological Change 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Directed Technological Change Daron Acemoglu MIT December 13, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 13 December 13, 2011. 1 / 71 Directed Technological

More information

WHY ARE THERE RICH AND POOR COUNTRIES? SYMMETRY BREAKING IN THE WORLD ECONOMY: A Note

WHY ARE THERE RICH AND POOR COUNTRIES? SYMMETRY BREAKING IN THE WORLD ECONOMY: A Note WHY ARE THERE RICH AND POOR COUNTRIES? SYMMETRY BREAKING IN THE WORLD ECONOMY: A Note Yannis M. Ioannides Department of Economics Tufts University Medford, MA 02155, USA (O): 1 617 627 3294 (F): 1 617

More information

Essays in Economic Geography and Development. Dominick Gabriel Bartelme. A dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the

Essays in Economic Geography and Development. Dominick Gabriel Bartelme. A dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the Essays in Economic Geography and Development by Dominick Gabriel Bartelme A dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Economics in the

More information

Toulouse School of Economics, L3 Macroeconomics 1 Professors Chaney & Portier. Exam

Toulouse School of Economics, L3 Macroeconomics 1 Professors Chaney & Portier. Exam Toulouse School of Economics, 2014-2015 L3 Macroeconomics 1 Professors Chaney & Portier Put the barcode here Exam Instructions: This is a 2h30 hours exam. BE SURE TO PUT THE STICKER ON THE EXAM. There

More information

Economics 312: Urban Land Economics University of Victoria Midterm Examination #1 VERSION 1 SOLUTIONS Spring 2018 Instructor: Martin Farnham

Economics 312: Urban Land Economics University of Victoria Midterm Examination #1 VERSION 1 SOLUTIONS Spring 2018 Instructor: Martin Farnham Economics 312: Urban Land Economics University of Victoria Midterm Examination #1 VERSION 1 SOLUTIONS Spring 2018 Instructor: Martin Farnham Midterm Exam #1 Section 1: Multiple Choice (2 points each) Unless

More information

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions Daniel Němec Faculty of Economics and Administrations Masaryk University Brno, Czech Republic nemecd@econ.muni.cz ESF MU (Brno)

More information

Modern Urban and Regional Economics

Modern Urban and Regional Economics Modern Urban and Regional Economics SECOND EDITION Philip McCann OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS Contents List of figures List of tables Introduction xii xiv xvii Part I Urban and Regional Economic Models and

More information

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton Figure a. Aggregate exchange rate disconnect (levels) 28.5

More information

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2015 1 / 36 Production Economy Last time: studied equilibrium in an endowment economy Now: study equilibrium in an economy

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6 Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO April 10, 017 Administrative Stuff Homework # is due at the end of class. I will post the solutions on the website later today. The midterm

More information

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk Optimal Insurance of Search Risk Mikhail Golosov Yale University and NBER Pricila Maziero University of Pennsylvania Guido Menzio University of Pennsylvania and NBER November 2011 Introduction Search and

More information

Workshop for empirical trade analysis. December 2015 Bangkok, Thailand

Workshop for empirical trade analysis. December 2015 Bangkok, Thailand Workshop for empirical trade analysis December 2015 Bangkok, Thailand Cosimo Beverelli (WTO) Rainer Lanz (WTO) Content a. What is the gravity equation? b. Naïve gravity estimation c. Theoretical foundations

More information

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market Daron Acemoglu MIT September 20, 2016. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Technology and the Labor Market September 20, 2016. 1 / 51 Technology

More information

I-1. The slope of the bid-price function, P{u}, is - t / H. Use Equation (35) to derive general

I-1. The slope of the bid-price function, P{u}, is - t / H. Use Equation (35) to derive general ECN 741, Professor Yinger Exercises Part I. Bid Functions and Density Functions I-1. The slope of the bid-price function, P{u}, is - t / H. Use Equation (35) to derive general expression for the slope

More information

Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection

Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection Eric Bartelsman, John Haltiwanger & Stefano Scarpetta American Economic Review (2013) Presented by Beatriz González January

More information

Structural change in a multi-sector model of the climate and the economy

Structural change in a multi-sector model of the climate and the economy Structural change in a multi-sector model of the climate and the economy Gustav Engström The Beijer Institute of Environmental Economics Stockholm, December 2012 G. Engström (Beijer) Stockholm, December

More information