Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions"

Transcription

1 Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions Vadim Marmer University of British Columbia Artyom Shneyerov y CIREQ, CIRANO, and Concordia University, Montreal August 30, 200 Abstract We propose a quantile-based nonparametric approach to inference on the probability density function (PDF) of the private values in rst-price sealedbid auctions with independent private values. Our method of inference is based on a fully nonparametric kernel-based estimator of the quantiles and PDF of observable bids. Our estimator attains the optimal rate of Guerre et al. (2000), and is also asymptotically normal with the appropriate choice of the bandwidth. JEL Classi cation: C4, D44 Keywords: First-price auctions, independent private values, nonparametric estimation, kernel estimation, quantiles, optimal reserve price Introduction Following the seminal article of Guerre et al. (2000), GPV hereafter, there has been an enormous interest in nonparametric approaches to auctions. By removing the Department of Economics, University of British Columbia, East Mall, Vancouver, BC, Canada V6T Z. vadim.marmer@ubc.ca y Department of Economics, Concordia University, 455 de Maisonneuve Blvd. West, Montreal, QC, Canada H3G M8. achneero@alcor.concordia.ca See a recent survey by Athey and Haile (2007).

2 need to impose tight functional form assumptions, the nonparametric approach provides a more exible framework for estimation and inference. Moreover, the sample sizes available for auction data can be su ciently large to make the nonparametric approach empirically feasible. 2 This paper contributes to this literature by providing a fully nonparametric framework for making inferences on the density of bidders valuations f (v). The need to estimate the density of valuations arises in a number of economic applications, as for example the problem of estimating a revenue-maximizing reserve price. 3 As a starting point, we brie y discuss the estimator proposed in GPV. For the purpose of introduction, we adopt a simpli ed framework. Consider a random, i.i.d. sample b il of bids in rst-price auctions each of which has n risk-neutral bidders; l indexes auctions and i = ; : : : ; n indexes bids in a given auction. GPV assume independent private values (IPV). In equilibrium, the bids are related to the valuations via the equilibrium bidding strategy B: b il = B (v il ). GPV show that the inverse bidding strategy is identi ed directly from the observed distribution of bids: v = (b) b + G (b) n g (b) ; () where G (b) is the cumulative distribution function (CDF) of bids in an auction with n bidders, and g (b) is the corresponding density. GPV propose to use nonparametric estimators ^G and ^g. When b = b il, the left-hand side of () will then give what GPV call the pseudo-values ^v il = ^ (b il ). The CDF F (v) is estimated as the empirical CDF, and the PDF f (v) is estimated by the method of kernels, both using ^v il as observations. GPV show that, with the appropriate choice of the bandwidth, their estimator converges to the true value at the optimal rate (in the minimax sense; Khasminskii (979)). However, the asymptotic distribution of this estimator is as yet unknown, possibly because both steps of the GPV method are nonparametric with estimated values ^v il entering the second stage. 2 For example, List et al. (2004) study bidder collusion in timber auctions using thousands of auctions conducted in the Province of British Columbia, Canada. Samples of similar size are also available for highway procurement auctions in the United States (e.g., Krasnokutskaya (2009)). 3 Several previous articles have studied that problem, see Paarsch (997), Haile and Tamer (2003), and Li et al. (2003). In the supplement to this paper, we discuss how the approach developed here can be used for construction of con dence sets for the optimal reserve price. The supplement is available as Marmer and Shneyerov (200) from the UBC working papers series and the authors web-sites. 2

3 The estimator ^f (v) proposed in this paper avoids the use of pseudo-values. It builds instead on the insight of Haile et al. (2003). 4 They show that the quantiles of the distribution of valuations can be expressed in terms of the quantiles, PDF, and CDF of bids. We show below that this relation can be used for estimation of f (v). Consider the -th quantile of valuations Q () and the -th quantile of bids q (). The latter can be easily estimated from the sample by a variety of methods available in the literature. As for the quantile of valuations, since the inverse bidding strategy (b) is monotone, equation () implies that Q () is related to q () as follows: Q () = q () + (n ) g (q ()) ; (2) providing a way to estimate Q () by a plug-in method. The CDF F (v) can then be recovered by inverting the quantile function, F (v) = Q (v). Our estimator ^f (v) is based on a simple idea that by di erentiating the quantile function we can recover the density: Q 0 () = =f (Q ()), and therefore f (v) = =Q 0 (F (v)). Taking the derivative in (2) and using the fact that q 0 () = =g (q ()), we obtain, after some algebra, our basic formula: n f (v) = n g (q (F (v))) n F (v) g 0 (q (F (v))) : (3) g 3 (q (F (v))) Note that all the quantities on the right-hand side, i.e. g (b), g 0 (b), q (), F (v) = Q (v) can be estimated nonparametrically, for example, using kernel-based methods. Once this is done, we can plug them in (3) to obtain our nonparametric estimator. The expression in (3) can be also derived using the following relationship between the CDF of values and the CDF of bids: F (v) = G (B (v)) : Applying the change of variable argument to the above identity, one obtains f (v) = g (B (v)) B 0 (v) = g (B (v)) = 0 (B (v)) 4 The focus of Haile et al. (2003) is a test of common values. Their model is therefore di erent from the IPV model, and requires an estimator that is di erent from the one in GPV. See also Li et al. (2002). 3

4 = n n g (B (v)) n F (v) g 0 (B (v)) : g 3 (B (v)) Note however, that from the estimation perspective, the quantile-based formula appears to be more convenient, since the bidding strategy function B involves integration of F (see equation (4) below). Furthermore, replacing B (v) with appropriate quantiles has no e ect on the asymptotic distribution of the estimator. Our framework results in the estimator of f (v) that is both consistent and asymptotically normal, with an asymptotic variance that can be easily estimated. Moreover, we show that, with an appropriate choice of the bandwidth sequence, the proposed estimator attains the minimax rate of GPV. In a Monte Carlo experiment, we compare nite sample biases and mean squared errors of our quantile-based estimator with that of the GPV s estimator. Our conclusion is that neither estimator strictly dominates the other. The GPV estimator is more e cient when the PDF of valuations has a positive derivative at the point of estimation and the number of bidders tends to be large. On the other hand, the quantile-based estimator is more e cient when the PDF of valuations has a negative derivative and the number of bidders is small. The Monte Carlo results suggest that the proposed estimator will be more useful when there are su ciently many independent auctions with a small number of bidders. 5 The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the basic setup. Similarly to GPV, we allow the number of bidders to vary from auctions to auction, and also allow auction-speci c covariates. Section 3 presents our main results. Section 4 discusses the bootstrap-based approach to inference on the PDF of valuations. In Section 5, we extend our framework to the case of auctions with binding reserve price. We report Monte Carlo results in Section 6. Section 7 concludes. The proofs of the main results are given in the Appendix. The supplement to this paper contains the proof of the bootstrap result in Section 4, some additional Monte Carlo results, as well as an illustration of how the approach developed here can be applied for conducting inference on the optimal reserve price. 5 We thank a referee for pointing this out. 4

5 2 De nitions The econometrician observes a random sample f(b il ; x l ; n l ) : l = ; : : : ; L; i = ; : : : n l g, where b il is the equilibrium bid of risk-neutral bidder i submitted in auction l with n l bidders, and x l is the vector of auction-speci c covariates for auction l. The corresponding unobservable valuations of the object are given by fv il : l = ; : : : ; L; i = ; : : : n l g. We make the following assumption similar to Assumptions A and A2 of GPV (see also footnote 4 in their paper). Assumption (a) f(n l ; x l ) : l = ; : : : ; Lg are i.i.d. (b) The marginal PDF of x l, ', is strictly positive and continuous on its compact support X R d, and admits up to R 2 continuous derivatives on its interior. (c) The distribution of n l conditional on x l is denoted by (njx) and has support N = fn; : : : ; ng for all x 2 X, n 2. (d) fv il : l = ; : : : ; L; i = ; : : : ; n l g are i.i.d. and independent of the number of bidders conditional on x l with the PDF f (vjx) and CDF F (vjx). (e) f (jx) is strictly positive and bounded away from zero and admits up to R continuous derivatives on its support, a compact interval [v (x) ; v (x)] R + for all x 2 X ; f(vj) admits up to R continuous partial derivatives on Interior (X ) for all v 2 [v (x) ; v (x)]. (f) For all n 2 N, (nj) is strictly positive and admits up to R continuous derivatives on the interior of X. Under Assumption (c), the equilibrium bids are determined by Z vil b il = v il (F (v il jx l )) n (F (ujx l )) n du; (4) v (see, for example, GPV). Let g (bjn; x) and G (bjn; x) be the PDF and CDF of b il, conditional on both x l = x and the number of bidders n l = n. Since b il is a function of v il, x l, and F (jx l ), the bids fb il g are also i.i.d. conditional on (n l ; x l ). Furthermore, by Proposition (i) and (iv) of GPV, for all n = n; : : : ; n and x 2 X, g (jn; x) has the compact support b (n; x) ; b (n; x) for some b (n; x) < b (n; x), and g (jn; ) admits up to R continuous bounded partial derivatives. 5

6 The -th quantile of F (vjx) is de ned as Q (jx) = F (jx) inf v fv : F (vjx) g : The -th quantile of G, q (jn; x) = G (jn; x) ; is de ned similarly. The quantiles of the distributions F (vjx) and G (bjn; x) are related through the following conditional version of equation (2): Q (jx) = q (jn; x) + (n ) g (q (jn; x) jn; x) : (5) Note that the expression on the left-hand side does not depend on n, since by Assumption (d) and as it is usually assumed in the literature, the distribution of valuations is the same regardless of the number of bidders. The true distribution of the valuations is unknown to the econometrician. Our objective is to construct a valid asymptotic inference procedure for the unknown f using the data on observable bids. Di erentiating (5) with respect to, we obtain the following equation relating the PDF of valuations with functionals of the distribution of the = = f (Q (jx) jx) n n g (q (jn; x) jn; x) g () (q (jn; x) jn; x) (n ) g 3 (q (jn; x) jn; x) ; (6) where g (k) (bjn; x) k g (bjn; x) =@b k. Substituting = F (vjx) in equation (6) and using the identity Q (F (vjx) jx) = v, we obtain the following equation that represents the PDF of valuations in terms of the quantiles, PDF and derivative of PDF of bids: f (vjx) = n n g (q (F (vjx) jn; x) jn; x) n F (vjx) g () (q (F (vjx) jn; x) jn; x) : (7) g 3 (q (F (vjx) jn; x) jn; x) Note that the overidentifying restriction of the model is that f (vjx) is the same for all n. 6

7 In this paper, we suggest a nonparametric estimator for the PDF of valuations based on equations (5) and (7). Such an estimator requires nonparametric estimation of the conditional CDF and quantile functions, PDF and its derivative. Let K be a kernel function. We assume that the kernel is compactly supported and of order R. Assumption 2 K is compactly supported on [ ; ], has at least R derivatives on its support, the derivatives are Lipschitz, and R K (u) du =, R u k K (u) du = 0 for k = ; : : : ; R. To save on notation, denote K h (z) = h K z h, and for x = (x ; : : : ; x d ) 0, de ne K h (x) = h d K d Consider the following estimators: ^' (x) = L ^ (njx) = ^G (bjn; x) = x h = Q d h d k= K xk : h LX K h (x l x) ; (8) l= ^' (x) L LX (n l = n) K h (x l x) ; l= ^ (njx) ^' (x) nl ^q (jn; x) = ^G (jn; x) inf b ^g (bjn; x) = ^ (njx) ^' (x) nl LX Xn l (n l = n) (b il b) K h (x l x) ; l= i= n b : ^G o (bjn; x) ; LX Xn l (n l = n) K h (b il b) K h (x l x) ; (9) l= i= 7

8 where (S) is an indicator function of a set S R. 6;7 The derivatives of the density g (bjn; x) are estimated simply by the derivatives of ^g (bjn; x): where ^g (k) (bjn; x) = ( ) k ^ (njx) ^' (x) nl LX Xn l (n l = n) K (k) h (b il b) K h (x l x) ; (0) l= i= K (k) h (u) = u h +k K(k) ; h and K (k) (u) denotes the k-th derivative of K (u). Our approach also requires nonparametric estimation of Q, the conditional quantile function of valuations. An estimator for Q can be constructed using the relationship between Q, q and g given in (5). A similar estimator was proposed by Haile et al. (2003) in a di erent context. In our case, the estimator of Q will be used to construct ^F, an estimator of the conditional CDF of valuations. The CDF F is related to the quantile function Q through F (vjx) = Q (vjx) = sup f : Q (jx) vg ; () 2[0;] and therefore ^F can be obtained by inverting the estimator of the conditional quantile function. However, since an estimator of Q based on (5) involves kernel estimation of the PDF g, it will be inconsistent for the values of that are close to zero and one because of the asymptotic bias in ^g at the boundaries. In particular, such an estimator of Q can exhibit large oscillations for near one by taking on very small values, which due to supremum in (), might proliferate and bring an upward bias into the estimator of F. A solution to this problem that we pursue in this paper is to use a monotone version of the estimator of Q. First, we de ne a preliminary 6 We estimate the CDF of bids by a conditional version of the empirical CDF. In a recent paper, Li and Racine (2008) discuss a smooth estimator of the CDF (and a corresponding quantile estimator) obtained by integrating the kernel PDF estimator. We, however, adopt the non-smooth empirical CDF approach in order for our estimator to be comparable with that of GPV; both estimator can be modi ed by using the smooth conditional CDF estimator. 7 The quantile estimator ^q is constructed by inverting the estimator of the conditional CDF of bids. This approach is similar to that of Matzkin (2003). 8

9 estimator, ^Q p : ^Q p (jn; x) = ^q (jn; x) + (n ) ^g (^q (jn; x) jn; x) : (2) Next, we choose some 0 2 (0; ) su ciently far from 0 and, for example, 0 = =2. We de ne a monotone version of the estimator of Q as follows: ^Q (jn; x) = ( sup t2[ 0 ;] inf t2[; 0 ] ^Q p (tjn; x) ; 0 < ; ^Q p (tjn; x) ; 0 < 0 : The estimator of the conditional CDF of the valuations based on ^Q (jn; x) is then given by (3) n ^F (vjn; x) = sup : ^Q o (jn; x) v : (4) 2[0;] Since ^Q (jn; x) is monotone, ^F is not a ected by ^Qp (jn; x) taking on small values near =. Furthermore, in our framework, inconsistency of ^Q (jn; x) near the boundaries does not pose a problem, since we are interested in estimating F only on a compact inner subset of its support. Using (7), for a given n we propose to estimate f (vjx) by the plug-in method, i.e. by replacing g (bjn; x), q (jn; x), and F (vjx) in (7) with ^g (bjn; x), ^q (jn; x), and ^F (vjn; x). That is our estimator ^f (vjn; x) is given by the reciprocal of n n ^g ^q ^F (vjn; x) jn; x jn; x n ^F (vjn; x) ^g ^q () ^F (vjn; x) jn; x ^g 3 ^q ^F (vjn; x) jn; x jn; x jn; x : (5) While the PDF of valuations does not depend on the number of bidders n, the estimator de ned by (5) does, and therefore we have a number of estimators for f (vjx): ^f (vjn; x), n = n; : : : ; n. The estimators ^f (vjn; x) ; : : : ; ^f (vjn; x) can be averaged to obtain: ^f (vjx) = nx n=n ^w (n; x) ^f (vjn; x) ; (6) 9

10 where the weights ^w (n; x) satisfy nx n=n ^w (n; x) p w (n; x) > 0; w (n; x) = : In the next section, we discuss how to construct optimal weights that minimize the asymptotic variance of ^f (vjx). We also suggest estimating the conditional CDF of v using the average of ^F (vjn; x), n = n; : : : ; n: ^F (vjx) = nx n=n 3 Asymptotic properties ^w (n; x) ^F (vjn; x) : (7) In this section, we discuss uniform consistency and asymptotic normality of the estimator of f proposed in the previous section. The consistency of the estimator of f follows from the uniform consistency of its components. It is well known that kernel estimators can be inconsistent near the boundaries of the support, and therefore we estimate the PDF of valuations at the points that lie away from the boundaries of [v (x) ; v (x)]. The econometrician can choose quantile values and 2 such that 0 < < 2 < ; in order to cut o the boundaries of the support where estimation is problematic. While v (x) and v (x) are unknown, consider instead the following interval of v s for selected and 2 : Remark. ^ (x) = max n=n;:::;n ^Q ( jn; x) ; min n=n;:::;n ^Q ( 2 jn; x) : (8) Since according to Lemma (g) below, ^Q (jn; x) consistently estimates Q (jx) for 2 [ "; 2 + "] and all n = n; :::; n, the boundaries of ^ (x) satisfy max n=n;:::;n ^Q ( jn; x) p Q ( jx) and min n=n;:::;n ^Q ( 2 jn; x) p Q ( 2 jx). Thus, the boundaries of ^ (x) consistently estimate the boundaries of (x) = [Q ( jx) ; Q ( 2 jx)], the interval between the and 2 quantiles of the distribution of bidders valuations. 0

11 We also show in Theorems and 2 below that our estimator of f is uniformly consistent and asymptotically normal when f is estimated at the points from ^ (x). In practice, and 2 can be selected as follows. Since by Assumption 2 the length of the support of K is two, and following the discussion on page 53 of GPV, when there are no covariates one can choose and 2 such that [^q ( jn) ; ^q ( 2 jn)] ^bmin (n) + h; ^b max (n) h for all n 2 N, where ^b min (n) and ^b max (n) denote the minimum and maximum bids respectively in the sample of auctions with n bidders. When there are covariates available and f is estimated conditional on x l = x, one can replace ^b min (n) and ^bmax (n) with the corresponding minimum and maximum bids in the neighborhood of x as de ned on page 54 of GPV. Next, we present a lemma that provides uniform convergence rates for the components of the estimator ^f. In the case of the estimators of g and its derivatives, uniform consistency is established on the following interval. Since the bidding function is monotone, by Proposition 2. of GPV, there is an inner compact interval of the support of the bids distribution, say [b (n; x) ; b 2 (n; x)], 8 such that [q ( jn; x) ; q ( 2 jn; x)] (b (n; x) ; b 2 (n; x)) ; and [b (n; x) ; b 2 (n; x)] b (n; x) ; b (n; x) : (9) Lemma Under Assumptions and 2, for all x 2 Interior (X ) and n 2 N, (a) ^ (njx) =2 Lh (njx) = O d p log L + h R. (b) ^' (x) =2 Lh ' (x) = O d p log L + h R. (c) sup b2[b(n;x); b(n;x)] j ^G (bjn; x) =2 Lh G (bjn; x) j = O d p log L + h R. =2 Lh (d) sup 2["; "] j^q (jn; x) q (jn; x) j = O d p log L + h R, for any 0 < " < =2. 8 The knowledge of b (n; x) and b 2 (n; x) is not required for construction of our estimator.

12 Lh (e) sup 2["; "] (lim t# ^q (tjn; x) ^q (jn; x)) = O d p, for any 0 < " < log(lh d ) =2. (f) sup b2[b (n;x);b 2 (n;x)] j^g (k) (bjn; x) =2 g (k) Lh (bjn; x) j = O d++2k p log L + h R, k = 0; : : : ; R, where [b (n; x) ; b 2 (n; x)] is de ned in (9). (g) sup 2[ "; 2 +"] j ^Q =2 Lh (jn; x) Q (jx) j = O d+ p log L + h R, for some " > 0 such that " > 0 and 2 + " <. (h) sup v2^(x) j ^F (vjn; x) F (vjx) j = O p Lh d+ log L in (8). =2 + h R, where ^ (x) is de ned Remarks.. Parts (a), (b), and (f) of the lemma follow from Lemmas B. and B.2 of Newey (994) which show that kernel estimators of k-order derivatives of smooth functions of d variables are uniformly consistent with the rate (Lh d+2k = log L) =2 +h R, where R is the degree of smoothness. The conditional CDF estimator ^G (jn; x) in part (c) of Lemma is a step function which involves kernel smoothing only with respect to x. It therefore does not t in Newey s framework and his Lemma B. does not apply in that case. However, precisely because there is no kernel smoothing with respect to b, one should expect to see the uniform convergence rate of (Lh d = log L) =2 + h R for ^G (bjn; x). In the proof of part (c) in the Appendix, we verify this claim using the covering numbers results (Pollard, 984, Chapter II). A similar result appears in GPV. In their Lemma B2, they derive the uniform convergence rate for ^G (jn; x) on an expanding subset of b (n; x) ; b (n; x) that does not include the neighborhoods of the boundaries. In our case, uniform convergence of ^G (jn; x) on the entire support b (n; x) ; b (n; x) is useful for establishing the uniform convergence rate of ^q (jn; x). 2. In part (d) of the lemma, we show that the quantile estimator ^q(jn; x) inherits the uniform convergence rate of its corresponding empirical CDF ^G (jn; x). The result is established using the following argument (to save on notation, we will suppress n and x here). Since G(b) is a continuous CDF and by the properties of quantiles (van der Vaart, 998, Lemma 2.), write G(^q()) G(q()) = G(^q()) ^G(^q()) + ^G(^q()). Since g(q ()) is bounded away from zero, an application of the meanvalue theorem implies then that the uniform distance between ^q () and q () can be bounded by the uniform distance between ^G () and G () and the size of the largest jump in ^G() (the later is of order (Lh d ) ). 2

13 3. Arguments similar to those in the previous remark are also used in the proof of part (h) (recall that ^F (jn; x) is de ned as the inverse function of ^Q(jn; x)). The jumps in ^Q (jn; x) depend on those of ^q(jn; x) and are shown to be of order (Lh d = log L) =2 using the results in Deheuvels (984) (see the proof of part (e) of the lemma). As it follows from Lemma, the estimator of the derivative of g (jn; x) has the slowest rate of convergence among all the components of ^f. Consequently, it determines the uniform convergence rate of ^f. Theorem Let ^ (x) be as de ned in (8). Under Assumptions and 2, and for =2 all x 2 Interior (X ), sup v2^(x) ^f (vjx) f (vjx) = Lh d+3 Op log L + h R. Remarks.. The theorem also holds when ^ (x) is replaced by an inner closed subset of [v (x) ; v (x)], as in Theorem 3 of GPV. Estimation of (x) has no e ect on the result of our theorem because the event E L (n; x) = n v 2 ^ o (x) : ^q ^F (vjn; x) jn; x 2 [b (n; x) ; b 2 (n; x)] (20) satis es P (E L (n; x)) as L for all n 2 N and x 2 Interior (X ) by the results in Lemma. 2. One of the implications of theorem is that our estimator achieves the optimal rate of GPV. Consider the following choice of the bandwidth parameter: h = c (L= log L). By choosing so that Lh d+3 = log L =2 and h R are of the same order, one obtains = = (d R) and the rate (L= log L) R=(d+3+2R), which is the same as the optimal rate established in Theorem 3 of GPV. Next, we discuss asymptotic normality of the proposed estimator. We make following assumption. Assumption 3 Lh d+, and Lh d++2k =2 h R 0. The rate of convergence and asymptotic variance of the estimator of f are determined by ^g () (bjn; x), the component with the slowest rate of convergence. Hence, Assumption 3 will be imposed with k = which limits the possible choices of the bandwidth for kernel estimation. For example, if one follows the rule h = cl, then has to be in the interval (= (d R) ; = (d + )). As usual for asymptotic normality, there is some under smoothing relatively to the optimal rate. 3

14 Lemma 2 Let [b (n; x) ; b 2 (n; x)] be as in (9). Then, under Assumptions -3, for all b 2 [b (n; x) ; b 2 (n; x)], x 2 Interior (X ), and n 2 N, (a) Lh d++2k =2 ^g (k) (bjn; x) g (k) (bjn; x) d N (0; V g;k (b; n; x)), where V g;k (b; n; x) = K k g (bjn; x) = (n (njx) ' (x)) ; and K k = R K 2 (u) du d R K (k) (u) 2 du. (b) ^g (k) (bjn ; x) and ^g (k) (bjn 2 ; x) are asymptotically independent for all n 6= n 2, n ; n 2 2 N. Now, we present the main result of the paper. Using the result in (70) in the Appendix, we have the following decomposition: F (vjx) f ^f 2 (vjx) (vjn; x) f (vjx) = (n ) g 3 (q (F (vjx) jn; x) jn; x) ^g () (q (F (vjx) jn; x) jn; x) g () (q (F (vjx) jn; x) jn; x) + o p Lh d+3 =2 : (2) Lemma 2, the de nition of ^f (vjn; x), and the decomposition in (2) lead to the following theorem. Theorem 2 Let ^ (x) be as de ned in (8). Under Assumptions, 2, and 3 with k =, for v 2 ^ (x), x 2 Interior (X ), and n 2 N, Lh d+3 =2 ^f (vjn; x) f (vjx) d N (0; V f (v; n; x)) ; where V f (v; n; x) = K F 2 (vjx) f 4 (vjx) n (n ) 2 (njx) ' (x) g 5 (q (F (vjx) jn; x) jn; x) ; and K is as de ned in Lemma 2. Furthermore, ^f (vjn; x) ; : : : ; ^f (vjn; x) are asymptotically independent. Remarks.. The theorem also holds for xed v s in an inner closed subset of [v (x) ; v (x)]. Estimation of ^(x) has no e ect on the asymptotic distribution of ^f (vjn; x) by the same reason as in Remark after Theorem. 4

15 2. Our approach can be used for estimation of the conditional PDF of values at quantile, f (Q (jx)). In this case, the estimator, say ^f (Q (jx) jn; x), is given by ^f (Q (jx) jn; x) = n n ^g (^q (jn; x) jn; x) n ^g () (^q (jn; x) jn; x) ; ^g 3 (^q (jn; x) jn; x) and Lh d+3 =2 ^f (Q (jx) jn; x) f (Q (jx) jx) d N (0; V f (Q (jx) ; n; x)). By Lemma, the asymptotic variance V f (v; n; x) can be consistently estimated by the plug-in estimator which replaces the unknown F; f; '; ; g, and q in the expression for V f (v; n; x) with their consistent estimators. Using asymptotic independence of ^f (vjn; x) ; : : : ; ^f (vjn; x), the optimal weights for the averaged PDF estimator of f (vjx) in (6) can be obtained by solving a GLStype problem. As usual, the optimal weights are inversely related to the variances V f (v; n; x): ^w (n; x) = = = ^V f (v; n; x) = nx j=n = ^V f (v; j; x) n (n ) 2 ^ (njx) ^g ^q 5 ^F (vjn; x) jn; x )2 ^ (jjx) ^g 5 ^q P n j=n j (j jn; x ^F (vjn; x) jj; x jj; x and the asymptotic variance of the optimal weighted estimator is therefore given by V f (v; x) = K F 2 (vjx) f 4 (vjx) P n n=n n (n )2 (njx) g 5 (q (F (vjx) jn; x) jn; x) : (22) ; In small samples, the accuracy of the normal approximation can be improved by taking into account the variance of the second-order term multiplied by h 2. To make the notation simple, consider the case of a single value n. We can expand the decomposition in (2) to obtain that Lh d+3 =2 ^f (vjx; n) f (vjx) is given by F f 2 (n ) g 3 Lh d+3 =2 ^g () g () 3f + h g 2nf 2 (n ) g 2 Lh d =2 (^g g) + op (h) ; where, F is the conditional CDF evaluated at v, and g, g (), ^g, ^g () are the conditional density (given x and n), its derivative, and their estimators evaluated at 5

16 q (F (vjx) jn; x). According to this decomposition, one can improve the accuracy of the asymptotic approximation in small samples by using the following variance estimator instead of ^V f : 9 ~V f = ^V f + h 2 3 ^f ^g 2n ^f 2 2 ^Vg;0: (n ) ^g 2 Note that the second summand in the expression for ~ V f is O p (h 2 ) and negligible in large samples. 4 Bootstrap The results in the previous section suggest that a con dence interval for f = f (vjx), for some chosen x 2 Interior(X ) and v 2 ^(x), can be constructed using the usual normal approximation. In this section, we discuss an alternative approach based on the bootstrap percentile method. 0 The bootstrap percentile method approximates the distribution of ^f f by that of ^f y ^f, where ^f = ^f(vjx) and ^f y is the bootstrap analogue of ^f computed using bootstrap data resampled from the original data. Note that the distribution of ^f y ^f can be approximated by simulations. To generate bootstrap samples, rst we draw randomly with replacement L auctions from the original sample of auctions f(n l ; x l ) : l = ; : : : ; Lg. In the second step, we draw bids randomly with replacement from the bids data corresponding to each selected auction. Thus, if auction l is selected in the rst step, in the second step we draw n l bids from fb i l : i = ; : : : ; n l g. Let M be the number of bootstrap samples. For each bootstrap sample m = ; : : : ; M, we compute ^f y m, the bootstrap analogue of ^f. Note that ^f y m is computed the same way as ^f but using the data in bootstrap sample m instead of the original data. Let y be the empirical quantile of f ^f m y : m = ; : : : ; Mg. The bootstrap percentile con dence interval is constructed as h i CI BP = y =2 ; y =2 : (23) 9 There is no covariance term because R K (u) K () (u) du = 0. 0 See, for example, Shao and Tu (995) for a general discussion of the bootstrap methods. 6

17 Let H f;l denote the CDF of p Lh d+3 ^f p Lh d+3 ^f y m ^f given the original data: f and H y f;l p H f;l (u) = P Lh d+3 ^f f u ; p H y f;l (u) = P y Lh d+3 ^f y m ^f u ; be the conditional CDF of where P y () denotes the conditional probability given the original sample of auctions f(b l ; : : : ; b nl l; n l ; x l ) : l = ; : : : ; Lg. The asymptotic validity of CI BP is implied by the result of the following theorem. Theorem 3 Suppose that Assumptions, 2, and 3 with k = hold. Then, as L, sup u2r jh f;l (u) H y f;l (u)j p 0. 5 Binding reserve prices We have so far assumed that there is no reserve price. Alternatively, we could have assumed that there is a reserve price, but it is non-binding. However, in real world auctions, sellers often use binding reserve prices to increase their expected revenues, so it is useful to extend our results in this direction. Let r be the reserve price. As in GPV, we assume that only the bidders with v il r submit bids. In this section, we use n l to denote the number of actual observed bidders in auction l. Let n denote the unobserved number of potential bidders. We make the following assumption identical to Assumption A5 in GPV. Assumption 4 (a) The number of potential bidders n 2 is constant. (b) The reserved price r is a possibly unknown deterministic R continuously di erentiable function Res () of the auction characteristics x. (c) The reserve price is binding in the sense that, for some " > 0, v (x) + " Res (x) v (x) " for all x 2 X. In the supplement, we compare the accuracy of the bootstrap percentile method with that of the asymptotic normal approximation in Monte Carlo simulations, and nd that the bootstrap is more accurate. 7

18 Our estimation method easily extends to this environment. Let F (vjx) F (vjx) F (rjx) F (rjx) be the distribution of valuations conditional on participation, and let f (vjx) be its density. Note that the parent density f (vjx) is related to f (vjx) as f (vjx) = ( F (rjx)) f (vjx) : (24) Our estimator for f (vjx) is based on (24): we separately estimate F (rjx) and f (vjx). We estimate F (rjx) as a nonparametric regression exactly as in GPV: 2 ^F (rjx) = ^nlh d^' (x) LX n l K h (x x l ) ; l= where again as in GPV, ^n = max l=;:::;l n l is the estimator of the number of potential bidders n. Note that by standard results, ^n = n + O(L ) (25) and ^F (rjx) = F (rjx) + O p Lh d =2 : (26) We now describe how our approach can be extended to estimation of f (vjx). Let G (bjx) be the CDF of bids conditional on x and on having a valuation above the reserve price, v il r. Let g (bjx) be the corresponding PDF. By the law of total probability, G (bjx) = g (bjx) = nx n=n nx n=n (njx) G (bjn; x) ; (27) (njx) g (bjn; x) : (28) 2 See the third equation on page 550 of GPV. 8

19 The estimators ^G (bjx) and ^g (bjx) then can be constructed by the plug-in method using our previously derived estimators ^n, ^ (njx), ^G (bjn; x), and ^g (bjn; x). 3 With ^G (bjx) and ^g (bjx) in hand, we estimate the density f (vjx) by following exactly the same steps as in the case without reserve price. Since the inverse bidding strategy under a binding reserve price is given by (bjx) = b + n the valuation quantile for the participants becomes ( F (rjx)) G (bjx) + F (rjx) ; ( F (rjx)) g (bjx) Q (jx) = q (jx) + ( F (rjx)) + F (rjx) n ( F (rjx)) g (q (jx) jx) ; (29) where Q (jx) is the quantile function of F (vjx). Let ^Q p (jx) be the plug-in estimator of Q (jx) based on (29), ^Q (jx) be its monotone version as in (3), and ^F (vjx) be the corresponding estimator of the CDF F (vjx) as in (4). The estimator ^f (vjx) is derived parallel to (5), as the reciprocal of + ^F (rjx) ^n ^g ^q ^F (vjx) jx jx ^F (rjx) ^F (vjx) ^g () ^q ^F (vjx) jx jx : ^n ^g ^q 3 ^F (vjx) jx jx Similarly to ^ (x) in Section 3, de ne ^ (x) = h ^Q ( jx) ; ^Q ( 2 jx)i, where 0 < < 2 < are chosen by the econometrician. Note that by construction, v > Res (x) with probability approaching one for all v 2 ^ (x). As before, the asymptotics of ^f (vjx) are driven by ^g (), the term with the slowest convergence rate. All the steps in our previous results routinely transfer to this setting. 4 In particular, we have an exact analogue to Lemma, and parallel to (2), the delta-method expansion for the 3 Assumption 4(a) implies that G (bjx) does not depend on n. Note that in the present setting, n l are draws from the Binomial dostribution, n l jx Binomial (n; F (rjx)), and (njx) are the corresponding Binomial probabilities. 4 Since we pick the inner quantiles 0 < < 2 <, we only use the bid observations su ciently far from the boundary b (n; x) = r. We therefore do not need to transform the bids as in GPV to avoid the singularity of g (bjx) when b # r. 9

20 estimator ^f (vjx) for v 2 ^ (x) takes the form ^f (vjx) f (vjx) = ( F (rjx)) F (vjx) f 2 (vjx) (n ) g 3 (q (F (vjx) jx) jx) ^g () (q (F (vjx) jx) jx) g () (q (F (vjx) jx) jx) + o p Lh d+3 =2 : The estimator ^f (vjx) therefore satis es Lh d+ =2 ^f (vjx) f (vjx) d N (0; V f (v; x)) ; (30) for v 2 ^ (x). The asymptotic variance is given by V f (v; x) = (n where from (28), The asymptotic variance V f F (vjx) f 2 2 (vjx) V ) g 3 (q (F g; (q (F (vjx) jx) ; x) ; (vjx) jx) jx) V g; (b; x) = nx n= (njx) 2 V g; (b; n; x) : can be consistently estimated by the plug-in method. From (24), the estimator of f (vjx) for v 2 ^ (x) is given by ^f (vjx) ^F (rjx) ^f (vjx) ; Combining (30) and (26), we have the following asymptotic normality result. Theorem 4 Under Assumptions, 2, 3 with k =, and 4, for v 2 ^ (x) and x 2 Interior (X ), Lh d+ =2 ^f (vjx) f (vjx) d N (0; V f (v; x)) ; where V f (v; x) = ( F (rjx)) 2 V f (v; x). 6 Monte Carlo experiments In this section, we compare the nite sample performance of our estimator with that of the GPV s estimator in terms of bias and mean squared error (MSE). We consider the 20

21 case with no covariates (d = 0). The true CDF of valuations used in our simulations is given by 8 >< 0; v < 0; F (v) = v >: ; 0 v ; ; v > ; where > 0. Such a choice of F is convenient because the corresponding bidding strategy is easy to compute: B (v) = (3) v: (32) (n ) + In our simulations, we consider the values = =2;, and 2. When =, the distribution of valuations is uniform over the interval [0; ], = =2 corresponds to the case of a downward-sloping PDF of valuations, and = 2 corresponds to the upward-sloping PDF. We report the results for v = 0:4; 0:5; 0:6, and the number of bidders n = 3 and 5. The number of auctions L is chosen so that the total number of observations in a simulated sample, nl, is the same for all values of n. In this case, the di erences in simulations results observed across n cannot be attributed to varying sample size. We set nl = Each Monte Carlo experiment has 0 3 replications. Similarly to GPV, we use the tri-weight kernel function for the kernel estimators, and the normal rule-of-thumb bandwidth in estimation of g: h = :06^ b (nl) =5 ; where ^ b is the estimated standard deviation of bids. The MSE optimal bandwidth for derivative estimation is of order L =7 (Pagan and Ullah, 999, Page 56). Therefore, for estimation of g () we use the following bandwidth: h 2 = :06^ b (nl) =7 : In each Monte Carlo replication, we generate randomly nl valuations fv i : i = ; : : : ; nlg from the CDF in (3), and then compute the corresponding bids according to (32). The computation of the quantile-based estimator ^f (v) involves several steps. First, we estimate the quantile function of bids q (). Let b () ; : : : ; b (nl) i denote the ordered sample of bids. We set ^q nl = b(i). Second, we estimate 2

22 the PDF of bids g (b) using (9). To construct our estimator, g needs to be estimated at all points ^q i n nl : i = ; : : : ; nl. Given the estimates ^g, we compute o i ^Qp nl : i = ; : : : ; nl using (2), its monotone version according to (3), and ^F (v) according to (4). Let dxe denote the nearest integer greater than or equal dnl ^F (v)e to x; we compute ^q ^F (v) as ^q. Next, we compute ^g ^q nl ^F (v) and ^g ^q () ^F (v) using (9) and (0) respectively, and ^f (v) as the reciprocal of (5). To compute the GPV s estimator of f (v), in the rst step we compute the pseudovaluations ^v il according to equation (), with G and g replaced by their estimators. In the second step, we estimate f (v) by the kernel method from the sample f^v il g obtained in the rst-step. To avoid the boundary bias e ect, GPV suggest trimming of the observations that are too close to the estimated boundary of the support. Note that no explicit trimming is necessary for our estimator, since implicit trimming occurs from our use of quantiles instead of pseudo-valuations. 5 In their simulations, GPV use the bandwidths of order (nl) =5 in the rst and second steps of estimation. We found, however, that using a bandwidth of order (nl) =7 in the second step signi cantly improves the performance of their estimator in terms of bias and MSE. To compute the GPV s estimator, we therefore use h as the rst step bandwidth (for estimation of G and g), and h 2 at the second step. Similarly to the quantile-based estimator, the GPV s estimator is implemented with the tri-weight kernel. The results are reported in Table. In most cases, the GPV s estimator has a smaller bias. This can be due to the fact that the GPV s estimator is obtained by kernel smoothing of the data, while the quantile-based estimator is a nonlinear function of the estimated CDF, PDF and its derivative. In terms of MSE, however, there is no clear winner, and the relative e ciency of the estimators depends on the underlying distribution of the valuations and the number of bidders in the auction. The GPV s estimator is more e cient when the number of bidders is relatively large and PDF has a positive slope. On the other hand, our estimator is more attractive when the number of bidders is small and the PDF has a negative slope. 6 5 In our simulations, we found that trimming has no e ect on the estimator of GPV: essentially the same estimates were obtained with and without trimming. 6 Additional results, including the simulations for n = 2; 4; 6, and 7, are reported in the supplement. 22

23 7 Concluding remarks In this paper, we have assumed that the bidders are risk-neutral. It would be important to extend our method to the case of risk-averse bidders. Guerre et al. (2009) consider nonparametric identi cation of a rst-price auction with risk-averse bidders each of whom has an unknown utility function U (), and nd that exclusion restrictions are necessary to achieve the identi cation of model primitives. They show that under risk aversion, the bids and valuations are linked as v = (bjn) b + G (bjn) ; n g (bjn) where () is the inverse of U () =U 0 (). 7 Consequently, the quantiles of bids and valuations are now linked as Q (jn) = (q (jn) jn). Assuming that the variation in n is exogenous, the valuation quantiles Q (jn) do not depend on n. Guerre et al. (2009) show that () (and hence U ()) is identi able through this restriction, and in the concluding section of their paper, discuss some strategies for the nonparametric estimation of. At this point, it is not known whether these approaches can lead to a consistent estimator ^. However, when such an estimator becomes available, it might be possible to extend the approach of our paper to accommodate risk aversion. Such an extension is left for future work. Acknowledgements We thank Donald Andrews, Herman Bierens, Chuan Goh, Christian Gourieroux, Bruce Hansen, Sung Jae Jun, Roger Koenker, Guido Kuersteiner, Isabelle Perrigne, Joris Pinkse, James Powell, Je rey Racine, Yixiao Sun, Quang Vuong, two anonymous referees and the guest editors for helpful comments. Pai Xu provided excellent research assistance. The rst author gratefully acknowledges the research support of the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada under grant number A preliminary version of the paper was completed when the second author was visiting the Center for Mathematical Studies in Economics and Management Science at Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern University. Its warm hospitality is gratefully acknowledged. 7 See their equation (4) on page

24 Appendix of proofs Proof of Lemma. For part (c), de ne G 0 (b; n; x) = n (njx) G (bjn; x) ' (x) ; and its estimator ^G 0 (b; n; x) = L LX Xn l (n l = n) (b il b) K h (x l x) : (33) l= i= Next, E ^G Xn l 0 (b; n; x) = E (n l = n) K h (x l x) (b il b) i= = ne ( (n l = n) (b il b) K h (x l x)) = ne ( (njx l ) G (bjn; x l ) K h (x Z l x)) = n (nju) G (bjn; u) K h (u x) ' (u) du Z = G 0 (b; n; x + hu) K d (u) du: By Assumption (e) and Proposition (iii) of GPV, G (bjn; ) admits up to R continuous bounded derivatives. Then, as in the proof of Lemma B.2 of Newey (994), there exists a constant c > 0 such that G 0 (b; n; x) E ^G 0 (b; n; x) Z vec ch R jk d (u)j kuk R du D R x G 0 (b; n; x) ; where kk denotes the Euclidean norm and D R x G 0 denotes the R-th partial derivative of G 0 with respect to x. It follows then that sup b2[b(n;x); b(n;x)] G 0 (b; n; x) E ^G 0 (b; n; x) = O h R : (34) 24

25 Next, we show that sup j ^G 0 (b; n; x) E ^G Lh 0 d =2 (b; n; x) j = O p : (35) b2[b(n;x); b(n;x)] log L We follow the approach of Pollard (984). Fix n 2 N and x 2 Interior (X ), and consider a class of functions Z indexed by h and b, with a representative function Xn l z l (b; n; x) = (n l = n) (b il b) h d K h (x l x) : i= By the result in Pollard (984) (Problem 28), the class Z has polynomial discrimination. Theorem 37 in Pollard (984) (see also Example 38) implies that for any sequences L, L such that L 2 L 2 L = log L and Ez2 l (b; n; x) 2 L, L 2 L sup b2[b(n;x); b(n;x)] j L LX z l (b; n; x) Ez l (b; n; x) j 0 (36) l= almost surely. We claim that this implies the result in (35). The proof is by contradiction. Suppose not. Then there exist a sequence L and a subsequence of L such that along this subsequence, sup j ^G 0 (b; n; x) b2[b(n;x); b(n;x)] E ^G Lh 0 d =2 (b; n; x) j L : (37) log L on a set of events 0 with a positive probability measure. Now if we let 2 L = h d and L = ( Lhd ) =2 =2 log L L, then the de nition of z implies that, along the subsequence on a set of events 0, = = L 2 L Lh d log L Lh d log L sup b2[b(n;x); b(n;x)] j L LX z l (b; n; x) l= =2 =2 L h d sup =2 =2 L b2[b(n;x); b(n;x)] j L Ez l (b; n; x) j LX z l (b; n; x) l= sup j ^G 0 (b; n; x) b2[b(n;x); b(n;x)] E ^G 0 (b; n; x) j Ez l (b; n; x) j 25

26 Lh d log L = =2 L ; =2 =2 Lh d =2 L L log L where the inequality follows by (37), a contradiction to (36). This establishes (35), so that (34), (35) and the triangle inequality together imply that sup j ^G Lh 0 (b; n; x) G 0 d =2 (b; n; x) j = O p + h R : (38) b2[b(n;x); b(n;x)] log L To complete the proof, recall that from the de nitions of G 0 (b; n; x) and ^G 0 (b; n; x), G (bjn; x) = G0 (b; n; x) (njx) ' (x) and ^G (bjn; x) = ^G 0 (b; n; x) ^ (njx) ^' (x) ; so that by the mean-value theorem, ^G (bjn; x) G (bjn; x) is bounded by G ~ (n; x) ~' (x) ; ~ 0 (b; n; x) G ~ 2 (n; x) ~' (x) ; ~ 0 (b; n; x) ~ (n; x) ~' 2 (x) ^G0 (b; n; x) G 0 (b; n; x) ; ^ (njx) (njx) ; ^' (x) ' (x) ; (39) where ~G 0 G 0 ; ~ ; ~' ' ^G0 G 0 ; ^ ; ^' '. Further, by Assumption (b) and (c) and the results in parts (a) and (b) of the lemma, with the probability approaching one ~ and ~' are bounded away from zero. The desired result follows from (38), (39) and parts (a) and (b) of the lemma. For part (d) of the lemma, since ^G (jn; x) is monotone by construction, n P (^q ("jn; x) b (n; x)) = P inf b : ^G o (bjn; x) " b = P ^G (b (n; x) jn; x) " = o () ; b (n; x) where the last equality is by the result in part (c). Similarly, P ^q ( "jn; x) b (n; x) = P ^G b (n; x) jn; x " 26

27 = o () : Hence, for all x 2 Interior (X ) and n 2 N, b (n; x) < ^q ("jn; x) < ^q ( "jn; x) < b (n; x) with probability approaching one. Since the distribution G (bjn; x) is continuous in b, G (q (jn; x) jn; x) =, and for 2 ["; "], we can write the identity G (^q (jn; x) jn; x) G (q (jn; x) jn; x) = G (^q (jn; x) jn; x) : (40) Next, we have that with probability one, 0 ^G (^q (jn; x) jn; x) (sup u2r K(u)) d ; where (4) N (n; x) LX Xn l N (n; x) = (n l = n) (K h (x l x) > 0) : (42) l= i= The rst inequality in (4) is by Lemma 2.(ii) of van der Vaart (998). The second inequality in (4) holds (with probability one) because ^G(jn; x) is a weighted empirical CDF of a continuous random variable ( ^G(jn; x) is a step function, b il is continuously distributed, and therefore with probability one, the size of each step of ^G(jn; x) is inversely related to the number of observations with non-zero weights used in its construction). Let B h (x) = u 2 R d : K h (u By a similar argument, we have Further, x) > 0. We have EN (n; x) = P (n l = n; K h (x l x) > 0) nl Z = nl (nju) ' (u) du B h (x) Z nl sup ' (x) x2x du B h (x) : (43) Z EN (n; x) nl inf (njx) inf ' (x) du : (44) x2x x2x B h (x) V ar (N (n; x)) P (n l = n; K h (x l x) > 0) nl = O Lh d : (45) 27

28 It follows now by Assumptions (b),(f) and from (43)-(45) that there is a constant c n;x > 0 such that N (n; x) = EN (n; x) + O p = Lh d c n;x + O p Lh d =2 Lh d =2 : (46) By the results in parts (a) and (b) and (46), ^G (^q (jn; x) jn; x) = + O p Lh d (47) uniformly over. Combining (40) and (47), and applying the mean-value theorem to the left-hand side of (40), we obtain ^q (jn; x) q (jn; x) = = G (^q (jn; x) jn; x) ^G (^q (jn; x) jn; x) g (eq (jn; x) jn; x) + O p Lh d ; (48) where eq lies between ^q and q for all (; n; x). By Proposition (ii) of GPV, g (bjn; x) > c g > 0 for all b 2 b (n; x) ; b (n; x), and the result in part (d) follows from (48) and part (c) of the lemma. Next, we prove part (e) of the lemma. Let N (n; x) be as de ned in (42). Consider the ordered sub-sample of bids b () : : : b (N(n;x)) with n l = n and K h (x l x) > 0. Then, 0 lim t# ^q (tjn; x) ^q (jn; x) max j=2;:::;n(n;x) By the results of Deheuvels (984), max j=2;:::;n b (j) b (j ) = Op The result of part (e) follows from (49) and (46). b (j) b (j ) : N (n; x) : (49) log N (n; x) To prove part (f), note that by Assumption (e) and Proposition (iv) of GPV, g (jn; ) admits up to R continuous bounded partial derivatives. Let g (k) 0 (b; n; x) = (njx) g (k) (bjn; x) ' (x) ; (50) 28

29 and de ne ^g (k) 0 (b; n; x) = nl LX Xn l (n l = n) K (k) h (b il b) K h (x l x) : (5) l= i= We can write the estimator ^g (bjn; x) as ^g (bjn; x) = ^g 0 (b; n; x) =(^ (njx) ^' (x)), so that ^g (k) (bjn; x) = ^g (k) 0 (b; n; x) =(^ (njx) ^' (x)). By Lemma B.3 of Newey (994), the estimator ^g (k) 0 (b; n; x) is uniformly consistent in b over [b (n; x) ; b 2 (n; x)]. By the results in parts (a) and (b), the estimators ^ (njx) and ^' (x) converge at the rate faster than that of ^g (k) 0 (b; n; x). The desired result follows by the same argument as in the proof of part (c), equation (39). For part (g), let c g be as in the proof of part (d) of the lemma. First, we consider the preliminary estimator, ^Qp (jn; x). We have that ^Q p (jn; x) Q (jx) is bounded by j^g (^q (jn; x) jn; x) g (q (jn; x) jn; x)j j^q (jn; x) q (jn; x)j + ^g (^q (jn; x) jn; x) c g jg (^q (jn; x) jn; x) g (q (jn; x) jn; x)j j^q (jn; x) q (jn; x)j + ^g (^q (jn; x) jn; x) c g j^g (^q (jn; x) jn; x) g (^q (jn; x) jn; x)j + ^g (^q (jn; x) jn; x) c g + sup b2[b (n;x);b 2 (n;x)] g () (bjn; x) j^q (jn; x) q (jn; x)j ^g (^q (jn; x) jn; x) c g j^g (^q (jn; x) jn; x) g (^q (jn; x) jn; x)j + : (52) ^g (^q (jn; x) jn; x) c g By continuity of the distributions, we can pick " > 0 small enough so that q ( "jn; x) > b (n; x) and q ( 2 + "jn; x) < b 2 (n; x) : De ne E L (n; x) = f^q ( "jn; x) b (n; x) ; ^q ( 2 + "jn; x) b 2 (n; x)g : By the result in part (d), P (EL c (n; x)) = o (). Hence, it follows from part (f) of the lemma that the estimator ^g (^q (jn; x) jn; x) is bounded away from zero with probability approaching one. Consequently, by Assumption (e) and part (d) of the 29

30 lemma that the rst summand on the right-hand side of (52) is O p ( L ) uniformly over [ P "; 2 + "], where L = Lh d++2k = log L =2 + h R. Next, sup L j^g (^q (jn; x) jn; x) g (^q (jn; x) jn; x)j > M 2[ "; 2 +"] P sup L j^g (^q (jn; x) jn; x) g (^q (jn; x) jn; x)j > M; E L (n; x) 2[ "; 2 +"] +P (E c L (n; x)) P sup L j^g (bjn; x) g (bjn; x)j > M + o () : (53) b2[b (n;x);b 2 (n;x)] It follows from part (f) of the lemma and (53) that sup j ^Q Lh p d+ =2 (jn; x) Q (jx) j = O p + h R : (54) 2[ "; 2 +"] log L Further, by construction, ^Q (jn; x) ^Qp (jn; x) 0 for 0. We can choose 0 2 [ ; 2 ]. Since ^Q p (jn; x) is left-continuous, there exists 0 2 [ 0 ; ] such that ^Q p ( 0 jn; x) = sup t2[ 0 ;] ^Q p (tjn; x). Since Q (jx) is nondecreasing, ^Q (jn; x) ^Qp (jn; x) = ^Q p ( 0 jn; x) ^Qp (jn; x) ^Q p ( 0 jn; x) Q ( 0 jx) + Q (jx) ^Qp (jn; x) ^Qp (tjn; x) Q (tjx) + Q (jx) ^Qp (jn; x) sup t2[ 0 ;] 2 sup 2[ "; 2 +"] = O p Lh d+ log L ^Q p (jn; x) =2 + h R Q (jx) where the last result follows from (54). Using a similar argument for < 0, we conclude that sup 2[ "; 2 +"] ^Q (jn; x) ; ^Qp Lh d+ =2 (jx) = O p + h R : (55) log L 30

31 The result of part (g) follows from (54) and (55). Lastly, we prove part (h). Let " be as in part(g). By Lemma 2.(ii) of van der Vaart (998), ^F ^Q (jn; x) jn; x, where the inequality becomes strict only at the points of discontinuity, and therefore ^F ^Q ( jn; x) jn; x > " for all n. Further, since ^Q (jn; x) is non-decreasing, P ^F ^Q ( 2 jn; x) jn; x = P sup ; t2[0;] < 2 + " n t : ^Q (tjn; x) ^Q o ( 2 jn; x) < 2 + " P ^Q ( 2 jn; x) < ^Q ( 2 + "jn; x) where the last result is by part (g) of the lemma and because Q( 2 jx) < Q ( 2 + "jx). Thus, for all v 2 ^ (x), ^F (vjn; x) 2 [ "; 2 + "] (56) with probability approaching one. Therefore, using the same argument as in part (g), equation (53), it is su cient to consider only v 2 ^ (x) such that ^F (vjn; x) 2 [ "; 2 + "]. Since by Assumption (f), Q (jx) is continuously di erentiable on [ "; 2 + "], for such v s by the mean-value theorem we have that, Q ^F (vjn; x) jx v = Q ^F (vjn; x) jx = f (Q (~ (v; n; x) jn; x) jx) Q (F (vjx)) ^F (vjn; x) F (vjx) ; (57) where ~ (v; n; x) is between ^F (vjn; x) and F (vjx). By Lemma 2.(iv) of van der Vaart (998), ^Q ^F (vjn; x) jn; x v, and equality can fail only at the points of discontinuity of ^Q. Hence, sup v v2^(x) ^Q ^F (vjn; x) jn; x sup lim ^Q (tjn; x) ^Q (jn; x) 2[ "; 2 +"] t# 3

Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions

Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions Vadim Marmer University of British Columbia Artyom Shneyerov CIREQ, CIRANO, and Concordia University, Montreal May 16, 2013 Abstract We propose

More information

Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions

Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions Vadim Marmer and Artyom Shneyerov University of British Columbia October 2006 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/5899/

More information

Supplement to Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions

Supplement to Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions Supplement to Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions Vadim Marmer University of British Columbia Artyom Shneyerov CIRANO, CIREQ, and Concordia University August 30, 2010 Abstract

More information

Nonparametric Identi cation and Estimation of Truncated Regression Models with Heteroskedasticity

Nonparametric Identi cation and Estimation of Truncated Regression Models with Heteroskedasticity Nonparametric Identi cation and Estimation of Truncated Regression Models with Heteroskedasticity Songnian Chen a, Xun Lu a, Xianbo Zhou b and Yahong Zhou c a Department of Economics, Hong Kong University

More information

A Shape Constrained Estimator of Bidding Function of First-Price Sealed-Bid Auctions

A Shape Constrained Estimator of Bidding Function of First-Price Sealed-Bid Auctions A Shape Constrained Estimator of Bidding Function of First-Price Sealed-Bid Auctions Yu Yvette Zhang Abstract This paper is concerned with economic analysis of first-price sealed-bid auctions with risk

More information

SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER. Donald W. K. Andrews. August 2011

SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER. Donald W. K. Andrews. August 2011 SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER By Donald W. K. Andrews August 2011 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1815 COWLES FOUNDATION FOR RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS

More information

Equilibria in Second Price Auctions with Participation Costs

Equilibria in Second Price Auctions with Participation Costs Equilibria in Second Price Auctions with Participation Costs Guofu Tan and Okan Yilankaya January 2005 Abstract We investigate equilibria of sealed-bid second price auctions with bidder participation costs

More information

Robust Con dence Intervals in Nonlinear Regression under Weak Identi cation

Robust Con dence Intervals in Nonlinear Regression under Weak Identi cation Robust Con dence Intervals in Nonlinear Regression under Weak Identi cation Xu Cheng y Department of Economics Yale University First Draft: August, 27 This Version: December 28 Abstract In this paper,

More information

Rank Estimation of Partially Linear Index Models

Rank Estimation of Partially Linear Index Models Rank Estimation of Partially Linear Index Models Jason Abrevaya University of Texas at Austin Youngki Shin University of Western Ontario October 2008 Preliminary Do not distribute Abstract We consider

More information

GMM-based inference in the AR(1) panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails

GMM-based inference in the AR(1) panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails GMM-based inference in the AR() panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails Edith Madsen entre for Applied Microeconometrics (AM) Department of Economics, University of openhagen,

More information

Supplemental Material 1 for On Optimal Inference in the Linear IV Model

Supplemental Material 1 for On Optimal Inference in the Linear IV Model Supplemental Material 1 for On Optimal Inference in the Linear IV Model Donald W. K. Andrews Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics Yale University Vadim Marmer Vancouver School of Economics University

More information

Simple Estimators for Monotone Index Models

Simple Estimators for Monotone Index Models Simple Estimators for Monotone Index Models Hyungtaik Ahn Dongguk University, Hidehiko Ichimura University College London, James L. Powell University of California, Berkeley (powell@econ.berkeley.edu)

More information

Identification and Estimation of Bidders Risk Aversion in. First-Price Auctions

Identification and Estimation of Bidders Risk Aversion in. First-Price Auctions Identification and Estimation of Bidders Risk Aversion in First-Price Auctions Isabelle Perrigne Pennsylvania State University Department of Economics University Park, PA 16802 Phone: (814) 863-2157, Fax:

More information

SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER. Donald W. K. Andrews. August 2011 Revised March 2012

SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER. Donald W. K. Andrews. August 2011 Revised March 2012 SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER By Donald W. K. Andrews August 2011 Revised March 2012 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1815R COWLES FOUNDATION FOR

More information

LECTURE 12 UNIT ROOT, WEAK CONVERGENCE, FUNCTIONAL CLT

LECTURE 12 UNIT ROOT, WEAK CONVERGENCE, FUNCTIONAL CLT MARCH 29, 26 LECTURE 2 UNIT ROOT, WEAK CONVERGENCE, FUNCTIONAL CLT (Davidson (2), Chapter 4; Phillips Lectures on Unit Roots, Cointegration and Nonstationarity; White (999), Chapter 7) Unit root processes

More information

Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts

Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts Contents 1 Motivating Examples 1 1.1 Instrumental variable estimator....................... 1 1.2 Estimating parameters in monetary policy rules.............. 2 1.3 Estimating

More information

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design 1. Public Good Provision Imagine that you and your colleagues want to buy a co ee machine for your o ce. Suppose that some of you may

More information

NONPARAMETRIC IDENTIFICATION AND SEMI-NONPARAMETRIC ESTIMATION OF FIRST-PRICE AUCTIONS

NONPARAMETRIC IDENTIFICATION AND SEMI-NONPARAMETRIC ESTIMATION OF FIRST-PRICE AUCTIONS The Pennsylvania State University The Graduate School Department of Economics NONPARAMETRIC IDENTIFICATION AND SEMI-NONPARAMETRIC ESTIMATION OF FIRST-PRICE AUCTIONS A Thesis in Economics by Hosin Song

More information

ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401S) University of Toronto. Department of Economics. Winter 2014 Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria

ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401S) University of Toronto. Department of Economics. Winter 2014 Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401S) University of Toronto. Department of Economics. Winter 2014 Instructor: Victor guirregabiria SOLUTION TO FINL EXM Monday, pril 14, 2014. From 9:00am-12:00pm (3 hours) INSTRUCTIONS:

More information

Stochastic Demand and Revealed Preference

Stochastic Demand and Revealed Preference Stochastic Demand and Revealed Preference Richard Blundell Dennis Kristensen Rosa Matzkin UCL & IFS, Columbia and UCLA November 2010 Blundell, Kristensen and Matzkin ( ) Stochastic Demand November 2010

More information

Simple Estimators for Semiparametric Multinomial Choice Models

Simple Estimators for Semiparametric Multinomial Choice Models Simple Estimators for Semiparametric Multinomial Choice Models James L. Powell and Paul A. Ruud University of California, Berkeley March 2008 Preliminary and Incomplete Comments Welcome Abstract This paper

More information

Measuring robustness

Measuring robustness Measuring robustness 1 Introduction While in the classical approach to statistics one aims at estimates which have desirable properties at an exactly speci ed model, the aim of robust methods is loosely

More information

Control Functions in Nonseparable Simultaneous Equations Models 1

Control Functions in Nonseparable Simultaneous Equations Models 1 Control Functions in Nonseparable Simultaneous Equations Models 1 Richard Blundell 2 UCL & IFS and Rosa L. Matzkin 3 UCLA June 2013 Abstract The control function approach (Heckman and Robb (1985)) in a

More information

Nonparametric Tests for Common Values In First-Price Sealed-Bid Auctions

Nonparametric Tests for Common Values In First-Price Sealed-Bid Auctions Nonparametric Tests for Common Values In First-Price Sealed-Bid Auctions Philip A. Haile Han Hong Matthew Shum September 24, 2003 preliminary Abstract Wedeveloptestsforcommonvaluesatrst-price sealed-bid

More information

GMM estimation of spatial panels

GMM estimation of spatial panels MRA Munich ersonal ReEc Archive GMM estimation of spatial panels Francesco Moscone and Elisa Tosetti Brunel University 7. April 009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/637/ MRA aper No. 637, posted

More information

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics Yulei Luo SEF of HKU January 14, 2009 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) MME January 14, 2009 1 / 44 Comparative Statics and The Concept of Derivative Comparative Statics

More information

University of Toronto

University of Toronto A Limit Result for the Prior Predictive by Michael Evans Department of Statistics University of Toronto and Gun Ho Jang Department of Statistics University of Toronto Technical Report No. 1004 April 15,

More information

Estimating First-Price Auctions with Unknown Number of Bidders: A Misclassification Approach

Estimating First-Price Auctions with Unknown Number of Bidders: A Misclassification Approach Estimating First-Price Auctions with Unknown Number of Bidders: A Misclassification Approach Yingyao Hu and Matthew Shum Dept. of Economics, Johns Hopkins University October 29, 27 Incomplete: Please do

More information

Consistency and Asymptotic Normality for Equilibrium Models with Partially Observed Outcome Variables

Consistency and Asymptotic Normality for Equilibrium Models with Partially Observed Outcome Variables Consistency and Asymptotic Normality for Equilibrium Models with Partially Observed Outcome Variables Nathan H. Miller Georgetown University Matthew Osborne University of Toronto November 25, 2013 Abstract

More information

Introduction: structural econometrics. Jean-Marc Robin

Introduction: structural econometrics. Jean-Marc Robin Introduction: structural econometrics Jean-Marc Robin Abstract 1. Descriptive vs structural models 2. Correlation is not causality a. Simultaneity b. Heterogeneity c. Selectivity Descriptive models Consider

More information

NONPARAMETRIC ESTIMATION OF DUTCH AND FIRST-PRICE, SEALED-BID AUCTION MODELS WITH ASYMMETRIC BIDDERS

NONPARAMETRIC ESTIMATION OF DUTCH AND FIRST-PRICE, SEALED-BID AUCTION MODELS WITH ASYMMETRIC BIDDERS NONPARAMETRIC ESTIMATION OF DUTCH AND FIRST-PRICE, SEALED-BID AUCTION MODELS WITH ASYMMETRIC BIDDERS Bjarne Brendstrup Department of Economics University of Aarhus Harry J. Paarsch Department of Economics

More information

Nonparametric Trending Regression with Cross-Sectional Dependence

Nonparametric Trending Regression with Cross-Sectional Dependence Nonparametric Trending Regression with Cross-Sectional Dependence Peter M. Robinson London School of Economics January 5, 00 Abstract Panel data, whose series length T is large but whose cross-section

More information

Likelihood Ratio Based Test for the Exogeneity and the Relevance of Instrumental Variables

Likelihood Ratio Based Test for the Exogeneity and the Relevance of Instrumental Variables Likelihood Ratio Based est for the Exogeneity and the Relevance of Instrumental Variables Dukpa Kim y Yoonseok Lee z September [under revision] Abstract his paper develops a test for the exogeneity and

More information

Economics 620, Lecture 19: Introduction to Nonparametric and Semiparametric Estimation

Economics 620, Lecture 19: Introduction to Nonparametric and Semiparametric Estimation Economics 620, Lecture 19: Introduction to Nonparametric and Semiparametric Estimation Nicholas M. Kiefer Cornell University Professor N. M. Kiefer (Cornell University) Lecture 19: Nonparametric Analysis

More information

Identification and Estimation of Auction Models with Unobserved Heterogeneity

Identification and Estimation of Auction Models with Unobserved Heterogeneity Review of Economic Studies 2011 78, 293 327 The Author 2011. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of The Review of Economic Studies Limited. doi: 10.1093/restud/rdq004 Identification and Estimation

More information

Nonparametric Identi cation of a Binary Random Factor in Cross Section Data

Nonparametric Identi cation of a Binary Random Factor in Cross Section Data Nonparametric Identi cation of a Binary Random Factor in Cross Section Data Yingying Dong and Arthur Lewbel California State University Fullerton and Boston College Original January 2009, revised March

More information

7 Semiparametric Methods and Partially Linear Regression

7 Semiparametric Methods and Partially Linear Regression 7 Semiparametric Metods and Partially Linear Regression 7. Overview A model is called semiparametric if it is described by and were is nite-dimensional (e.g. parametric) and is in nite-dimensional (nonparametric).

More information

Economics 241B Review of Limit Theorems for Sequences of Random Variables

Economics 241B Review of Limit Theorems for Sequences of Random Variables Economics 241B Review of Limit Theorems for Sequences of Random Variables Convergence in Distribution The previous de nitions of convergence focus on the outcome sequences of a random variable. Convergence

More information

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics ECON2285: Mathematical Economics Yulei Luo Economics, HKU September 17, 2018 Luo, Y. (Economics, HKU) ME September 17, 2018 1 / 46 Static Optimization and Extreme Values In this topic, we will study goal

More information

Inference about Clustering and Parametric. Assumptions in Covariance Matrix Estimation

Inference about Clustering and Parametric. Assumptions in Covariance Matrix Estimation Inference about Clustering and Parametric Assumptions in Covariance Matrix Estimation Mikko Packalen y Tony Wirjanto z 26 November 2010 Abstract Selecting an estimator for the variance covariance matrix

More information

Near convexity, metric convexity, and convexity

Near convexity, metric convexity, and convexity Near convexity, metric convexity, and convexity Fred Richman Florida Atlantic University Boca Raton, FL 33431 28 February 2005 Abstract It is shown that a subset of a uniformly convex normed space is nearly

More information

A Conditional-Heteroskedasticity-Robust Con dence Interval for the Autoregressive Parameter

A Conditional-Heteroskedasticity-Robust Con dence Interval for the Autoregressive Parameter A Conditional-Heteroskedasticity-Robust Con dence Interval for the Autoregressive Parameter Donald W. K. Andrews Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics Yale University Patrik Guggenberger Department

More information

ESTIMATION AND INFERENCE WITH WEAK, SEMI-STRONG, AND STRONG IDENTIFICATION. Donald W. K. Andrews and Xu Cheng. October 2010 Revised July 2011

ESTIMATION AND INFERENCE WITH WEAK, SEMI-STRONG, AND STRONG IDENTIFICATION. Donald W. K. Andrews and Xu Cheng. October 2010 Revised July 2011 ESTIMATION AND INFERENCE WITH WEAK, SEMI-STRONG, AND STRONG IDENTIFICATION By Donald W. K. Andrews and Xu Cheng October 1 Revised July 11 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1773R COWLES FOUNDATION

More information

Volume 30, Issue 3. Monotone comparative statics with separable objective functions. Christian Ewerhart University of Zurich

Volume 30, Issue 3. Monotone comparative statics with separable objective functions. Christian Ewerhart University of Zurich Volume 30, Issue 3 Monotone comparative statics with separable objective functions Christian Ewerhart University of Zurich Abstract The Milgrom-Shannon single crossing property is essential for monotone

More information

Mean-Variance Utility

Mean-Variance Utility Mean-Variance Utility Yutaka Nakamura University of Tsukuba Graduate School of Systems and Information Engineering Division of Social Systems and Management -- Tennnoudai, Tsukuba, Ibaraki 305-8573, Japan

More information

Estimation and Inference with Weak, Semi-strong, and Strong Identi cation

Estimation and Inference with Weak, Semi-strong, and Strong Identi cation Estimation and Inference with Weak, Semi-strong, and Strong Identi cation Donald W. K. Andrews Cowles Foundation Yale University Xu Cheng Department of Economics University of Pennsylvania This Version:

More information

Implementation with Interdependent Valuations Preliminary and Incomplete

Implementation with Interdependent Valuations Preliminary and Incomplete Implementation with Interdependent Valuations Preliminary and Incomplete Richard P. McLean Rutgers University Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania April 1, 004 1. Introduction There is a large

More information

Applications of Subsampling, Hybrid, and Size-Correction Methods

Applications of Subsampling, Hybrid, and Size-Correction Methods Applications of Subsampling, Hybrid, and Size-Correction Methods Donald W. K. Andrews Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics Yale University Patrik Guggenberger Department of Economics UCLA November

More information

Identification and Testing in Ascending Auctions with Unobserved Heterogeneity

Identification and Testing in Ascending Auctions with Unobserved Heterogeneity Identification and Testing in Ascending Auctions with Unobserved Heterogeneity Andrés Aradillas-ópez, Amit Gandhi, Daniel Quint July 22, 2010 Abstract This paper empirically studies the consequences of

More information

Estimation of a Local-Aggregate Network Model with. Sampled Networks

Estimation of a Local-Aggregate Network Model with. Sampled Networks Estimation of a Local-Aggregate Network Model with Sampled Networks Xiaodong Liu y Department of Economics, University of Colorado, Boulder, CO 80309, USA August, 2012 Abstract This paper considers the

More information

CAE Working Paper # Fixed-b Asymptotic Approximation of the Sampling Behavior of Nonparametric Spectral Density Estimators

CAE Working Paper # Fixed-b Asymptotic Approximation of the Sampling Behavior of Nonparametric Spectral Density Estimators CAE Working Paper #06-04 Fixed-b Asymptotic Approximation of the Sampling Behavior of Nonparametric Spectral Density Estimators by Nigar Hashimzade and Timothy Vogelsang January 2006. Fixed-b Asymptotic

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INFERENCE OF BIDDERS RISK ATTITUDES IN ASCENDING AUCTIONS WITH ENDOGENOUS ENTRY. Hanming Fang Xun Tang

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INFERENCE OF BIDDERS RISK ATTITUDES IN ASCENDING AUCTIONS WITH ENDOGENOUS ENTRY. Hanming Fang Xun Tang NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INFERENCE OF BIDDERS RISK ATTITUDES IN ASCENDING AUCTIONS WITH ENDOGENOUS ENTRY Hanming Fang Xun Tang Working Paper 19435 http://www.nber.org/papers/w19435 NATIONAL BUREAU OF

More information

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours. University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring 2012 EC941: Game Theory Prof. Francesco Squintani Final Exam Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours. 1. Consider

More information

Replacing Sample Trimming with Boundary Correction in. Nonparametric Estimation of First-Price Auctions

Replacing Sample Trimming with Boundary Correction in. Nonparametric Estimation of First-Price Auctions Replacing Sample Trimming with Boundary Correction in Nonparametric Estimation of First-Price Auctions Brent R. Hickman Timothy P. Hubbard December 8, 3 Abstract Two-step nonparametric estimators have

More information

Non-parametric Identi cation and Testable Implications of the Roy Model

Non-parametric Identi cation and Testable Implications of the Roy Model Non-parametric Identi cation and Testable Implications of the Roy Model Francisco J. Buera Northwestern University January 26 Abstract This paper studies non-parametric identi cation and the testable implications

More information

1 Games in Normal Form (Strategic Form)

1 Games in Normal Form (Strategic Form) Games in Normal Form (Strategic Form) A Game in Normal (strategic) Form consists of three components. A set of players. For each player, a set of strategies (called actions in textbook). The interpretation

More information

Estimation and Inference with Weak Identi cation

Estimation and Inference with Weak Identi cation Estimation and Inference with Weak Identi cation Donald W. K. Andrews Cowles Foundation Yale University Xu Cheng Department of Economics University of Pennsylvania First Draft: August, 2007 Revised: March

More information

ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401S) University of Toronto. Department of Economics. Spring 2013 Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria

ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401S) University of Toronto. Department of Economics. Spring 2013 Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401S) University of Toronto. Department of Economics. Spring 2013 Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria SOLUTION TO FINAL EXAM Friday, April 12, 2013. From 9:00-12:00 (3 hours) INSTRUCTIONS:

More information

Lecture Notes on Game Theory

Lecture Notes on Game Theory Lecture Notes on Game Theory Levent Koçkesen 1 Bayesian Games So far we have assumed that all players had perfect information regarding the elements of a game. These are called games with complete information.

More information

An E cient Auction. (First version: October 1998) April 2001

An E cient Auction. (First version: October 1998) April 2001 An E cient Auction Motty Perry The Hebrew University of Jerusalem and Penn State University and Philip J. Reny Department of Economics University of Chicago (First version: October 1998) April 2001 Abstract

More information

Introduction to Nonparametric and Semiparametric Estimation. Good when there are lots of data and very little prior information on functional form.

Introduction to Nonparametric and Semiparametric Estimation. Good when there are lots of data and very little prior information on functional form. 1 Introduction to Nonparametric and Semiparametric Estimation Good when there are lots of data and very little prior information on functional form. Examples: y = f(x) + " (nonparametric) y = z 0 + f(x)

More information

Notes on Asymptotic Theory: Convergence in Probability and Distribution Introduction to Econometric Theory Econ. 770

Notes on Asymptotic Theory: Convergence in Probability and Distribution Introduction to Econometric Theory Econ. 770 Notes on Asymptotic Theory: Convergence in Probability and Distribution Introduction to Econometric Theory Econ. 770 Jonathan B. Hill Dept. of Economics University of North Carolina - Chapel Hill November

More information

Identi cation of Positive Treatment E ects in. Randomized Experiments with Non-Compliance

Identi cation of Positive Treatment E ects in. Randomized Experiments with Non-Compliance Identi cation of Positive Treatment E ects in Randomized Experiments with Non-Compliance Aleksey Tetenov y February 18, 2012 Abstract I derive sharp nonparametric lower bounds on some parameters of the

More information

Averaging Estimators for Regressions with a Possible Structural Break

Averaging Estimators for Regressions with a Possible Structural Break Averaging Estimators for Regressions with a Possible Structural Break Bruce E. Hansen University of Wisconsin y www.ssc.wisc.edu/~bhansen September 2007 Preliminary Abstract This paper investigates selection

More information

Minimum Wages and Excessive E ort Supply

Minimum Wages and Excessive E ort Supply Minimum Wages and Excessive E ort Supply Matthias Kräkel y Anja Schöttner z Abstract It is well-known that, in static models, minimum wages generate positive worker rents and, consequently, ine ciently

More information

Inference of Bidders Risk Attitudes in Ascending Auctions with Endogenous Entry

Inference of Bidders Risk Attitudes in Ascending Auctions with Endogenous Entry Inference of Bidders Risk Attitudes in Ascending Auctions with Endogenous Entry Hanming Fang y Xun Tang z First Version: May 28, 20. This Version: Feb 8, 203 Abstract Bidders risk attitudes have key implications

More information

Computation Of Asymptotic Distribution. For Semiparametric GMM Estimators. Hidehiko Ichimura. Graduate School of Public Policy

Computation Of Asymptotic Distribution. For Semiparametric GMM Estimators. Hidehiko Ichimura. Graduate School of Public Policy Computation Of Asymptotic Distribution For Semiparametric GMM Estimators Hidehiko Ichimura Graduate School of Public Policy and Graduate School of Economics University of Tokyo A Conference in honor of

More information

A CONDITIONAL-HETEROSKEDASTICITY-ROBUST CONFIDENCE INTERVAL FOR THE AUTOREGRESSIVE PARAMETER. Donald W.K. Andrews and Patrik Guggenberger

A CONDITIONAL-HETEROSKEDASTICITY-ROBUST CONFIDENCE INTERVAL FOR THE AUTOREGRESSIVE PARAMETER. Donald W.K. Andrews and Patrik Guggenberger A CONDITIONAL-HETEROSKEDASTICITY-ROBUST CONFIDENCE INTERVAL FOR THE AUTOREGRESSIVE PARAMETER By Donald W.K. Andrews and Patrik Guggenberger August 2011 Revised December 2012 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION

More information

The Kuhn-Tucker Problem

The Kuhn-Tucker Problem Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 8: Nonlinear Programming - The Kuhn-Tucker Problem Note 8 is based on de la Fuente (2000, Ch. 7) and Simon and Blume (1994, Ch. 18 and 19). The Kuhn-Tucker

More information

Economics Bulletin, 2012, Vol. 32 No. 1 pp Introduction. 2. The preliminaries

Economics Bulletin, 2012, Vol. 32 No. 1 pp Introduction. 2. The preliminaries 1. Introduction In this paper we reconsider the problem of axiomatizing scoring rules. Early results on this problem are due to Smith (1973) and Young (1975). They characterized social welfare and social

More information

Auctions. data better than the typical data set in industrial organization. auction game is relatively simple, well-specified rules.

Auctions. data better than the typical data set in industrial organization. auction game is relatively simple, well-specified rules. Auctions Introduction of Hendricks and Porter. subject, they argue To sell interest in the auctions are prevalent data better than the typical data set in industrial organization auction game is relatively

More information

Identi cation and Estimation of Semiparametric Two Step Models

Identi cation and Estimation of Semiparametric Two Step Models Identi cation and Estimation of Semiparametric Two Step Models Juan Carlos Escanciano y Indiana University David Jacho-Chávez z Indiana University Arthur Lewbel x Boston College original May 2010, revised

More information

How to Attain Minimax Risk with Applications to Distribution-Free Nonparametric Estimation and Testing 1

How to Attain Minimax Risk with Applications to Distribution-Free Nonparametric Estimation and Testing 1 How to Attain Minimax Risk with Applications to Distribution-Free Nonparametric Estimation and Testing 1 Karl H. Schlag 2 March 12, 2007 ( rst version May 12, 2006) 1 The author would like to thank Dean

More information

Notes on Time Series Modeling

Notes on Time Series Modeling Notes on Time Series Modeling Garey Ramey University of California, San Diego January 17 1 Stationary processes De nition A stochastic process is any set of random variables y t indexed by t T : fy t g

More information

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models Fall 22 Contents Introduction 2. An illustrative example........................... 2.2 Discussion...................................

More information

Smooth simultaneous confidence bands for cumulative distribution functions

Smooth simultaneous confidence bands for cumulative distribution functions Journal of Nonparametric Statistics, 2013 Vol. 25, No. 2, 395 407, http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10485252.2012.759219 Smooth simultaneous confidence bands for cumulative distribution functions Jiangyan Wang

More information

Testing for Regime Switching: A Comment

Testing for Regime Switching: A Comment Testing for Regime Switching: A Comment Andrew V. Carter Department of Statistics University of California, Santa Barbara Douglas G. Steigerwald Department of Economics University of California Santa Barbara

More information

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1 Microeconomics, Block I Part 1 Piero Gottardi EUI Sept. 26, 2016 Piero Gottardi (EUI) Microeconomics, Block I Part 1 Sept. 26, 2016 1 / 53 Choice Theory Set of alternatives: X, with generic elements x,

More information

Nonparametric Identification and Estimation of a Transformation Model

Nonparametric Identification and Estimation of a Transformation Model Nonparametric and of a Transformation Model Hidehiko Ichimura and Sokbae Lee University of Tokyo and Seoul National University 15 February, 2012 Outline 1. The Model and Motivation 2. 3. Consistency 4.

More information

Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence

Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence Peter M. Robinson London School of Economics Based on joint work with Javier Hualde: Javier Hualde and Peter M. Robinson: Gaussian Pseudo-Maximum Likelihood Estimation

More information

Characterization of equilibrium in pay-as-bid auctions for multiple units

Characterization of equilibrium in pay-as-bid auctions for multiple units Economic Theory (2006) 29: 197 211 DOI 10.1007/s00199-005-0009-y RESEARCH ARTICLE Indranil Chakraborty Characterization of equilibrium in pay-as-bid auctions for multiple units Received: 26 April 2004

More information

When is it really justifiable to ignore explanatory variable endogeneity in a regression model?

When is it really justifiable to ignore explanatory variable endogeneity in a regression model? Discussion Paper: 2015/05 When is it really justifiable to ignore explanatory variable endogeneity in a regression model? Jan F. Kiviet www.ase.uva.nl/uva-econometrics Amsterdam School of Economics Roetersstraat

More information

Appendix for "O shoring in a Ricardian World"

Appendix for O shoring in a Ricardian World Appendix for "O shoring in a Ricardian World" This Appendix presents the proofs of Propositions - 6 and the derivations of the results in Section IV. Proof of Proposition We want to show that Tm L m T

More information

Analogy Principle. Asymptotic Theory Part II. James J. Heckman University of Chicago. Econ 312 This draft, April 5, 2006

Analogy Principle. Asymptotic Theory Part II. James J. Heckman University of Chicago. Econ 312 This draft, April 5, 2006 Analogy Principle Asymptotic Theory Part II James J. Heckman University of Chicago Econ 312 This draft, April 5, 2006 Consider four methods: 1. Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE) 2. (Nonlinear) Least

More information

Simultaneous Choice Models: The Sandwich Approach to Nonparametric Analysis

Simultaneous Choice Models: The Sandwich Approach to Nonparametric Analysis Simultaneous Choice Models: The Sandwich Approach to Nonparametric Analysis Natalia Lazzati y November 09, 2013 Abstract We study collective choice models from a revealed preference approach given limited

More information

The Relation Between Variance and Information Rent in Auctions

The Relation Between Variance and Information Rent in Auctions The Relation Between Variance and Information Rent in Auctions Brett Katzman Kennesaw State University Jesse A. Schwartz z Kennesaw State University First Copy: June 2006 Revised Copy: March 2009 Julian

More information

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill remium Ariel Burstein UCLA and NBER Jonathan Vogel Columbia and NBER April 22 Abstract In this Addendum we set up a perfectly competitive version

More information

11. Bootstrap Methods

11. Bootstrap Methods 11. Bootstrap Methods c A. Colin Cameron & Pravin K. Trivedi 2006 These transparencies were prepared in 20043. They can be used as an adjunct to Chapter 11 of our subsequent book Microeconometrics: Methods

More information

Time Series Models and Inference. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley

Time Series Models and Inference. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Time Series Models and Inference James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Overview In contrast to the classical linear regression model, in which the components of the

More information

Nonparametric Estimation of Wages and Labor Force Participation

Nonparametric Estimation of Wages and Labor Force Participation Nonparametric Estimation of Wages Labor Force Participation John Pepper University of Virginia Steven Stern University of Virginia May 5, 000 Preliminary Draft - Comments Welcome Abstract. Model Let y

More information

An E cient Auction. (First version: October 1998) October 2000

An E cient Auction. (First version: October 1998) October 2000 An E cient Auction Motty Perry The Hebrew University of Jerusalem and Penn State University and Philip J. Reny Department of Economics University of Chicago (First version: October 1998) October 2000 Abstract

More information

Nonlinear Programming (NLP)

Nonlinear Programming (NLP) Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 6: Nonlinear Programming - Unconstrained Optimization Note 6 is based on de la Fuente (2000, Ch. 7), Madden (1986, Ch. 3 and 5) and Simon and Blume

More information

Optimal Design and ρ-concavity

Optimal Design and ρ-concavity Institute for Empirical Research in Economics University of Zurich Working Paper Series ISSN 44-0459 Working Paper No. 409 Optimal Design and ρ-concavity Christian Ewerhart May 0 Optimal design and -concavity*

More information

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam #2 - Answer Key

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam #2 - Answer Key EconS 50 - Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam # - Answer Key 1. Revenue comparison in two auction formats. Consider a sealed-bid auction with bidders. Every bidder i privately observes his valuation

More information

Generalized Jackknife Estimators of Weighted Average Derivatives. Matias D. Cattaneo. Department of Economics, University of Michigan

Generalized Jackknife Estimators of Weighted Average Derivatives. Matias D. Cattaneo. Department of Economics, University of Michigan Generalized Jackknife Estimators of Weighted Average Derivatives Matias D. Cattaneo Department of Economics, University of Michigan Richard K. Crump Federal Reserve Bank of New York Michael Jansson Department

More information

Chapter 2. Dynamic panel data models

Chapter 2. Dynamic panel data models Chapter 2. Dynamic panel data models School of Economics and Management - University of Geneva Christophe Hurlin, Université of Orléans University of Orléans April 2018 C. Hurlin (University of Orléans)

More information

E cient Regressions via Optimally Combining Quantile Information

E cient Regressions via Optimally Combining Quantile Information E cient Regressions via Optimally Combining Quantile Information Zhibiao Zhao Penn State University Zhijie Xiao Boston College Abstract We develop a generally applicable framework for constructing e cient

More information

A test of the conditional independence assumption in sample selection models

A test of the conditional independence assumption in sample selection models A test of the conditional independence assumption in sample selection models Martin Huber, Blaise Melly First draft: December 2006, Last changes: September 2012 Abstract: Identi cation in most sample selection

More information

Approximately Most Powerful Tests for Moment Inequalities

Approximately Most Powerful Tests for Moment Inequalities Approximately Most Powerful Tests for Moment Inequalities Richard C. Chiburis Department of Economics, Princeton University September 26, 2008 Abstract The existing literature on testing moment inequalities

More information

Estimation and Inference of Linear Trend Slope Ratios

Estimation and Inference of Linear Trend Slope Ratios Estimation and Inference of Linear rend Slope Ratios imothy J. Vogelsang and Nasreen Nawaz Department of Economics, Michigan State University October 4 Abstract We focus on the estimation of the ratio

More information