Cooperative and Noncooperative R&D in Duopoly with Spillovers and Upstream Input Providers

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Cooperative and Noncooperative R&D in Duopoly with Spillovers and Upstream Input Providers"

Transcription

1 Cooperative and Noncooperative R&D in Duopoly with Spillovers and Upstream Input Providers LINFENG CHEN ZIJUN LUO RONG ZHU January 11, 2016 Abstract This paper extends the model in d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988) to include upstream input providers. We show that, for a sufficiently large number of input providers, noncooperative R&D investments are higher vis-à-vis cooperative R&D for any level of spillovers. This contrasts the finding in the literature that cooperative R&D investments are higher with high spillovers. Such result comes as not a surprise in our model because unit cost of production increases as the number of upstream firms goes up. Consequently, both cooperative R&D and noncooperative R&D decline, but the former declines faster than the latter. Keywords: Noncooperative R&D; Input providers; Duopoly JEL Classification Numbers: D2; L5; O3 School of Economics and Finance, University of Hong Kong. mylinfeng@gmail.com. Department of Economics and International Business, Sam Houston State University. Contact information: 237C Smith-Hutson Business Building, Sam Houston State University, Huntsville, TX luozijun@shsu.edu. National Institute of Labour Studies, Flinders University, Australia. rong.zhu@flinders.edu.au.

2 Cooperative and Noncooperative R&D in Duopoly with Spillovers and Upstream Input Providers Abstract This paper extends the model in d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988) to include upstream input providers. We show that, for a sufficiently large number of input providers, noncooperative R&D investments are higher vis-à-vis cooperative R&D for any level of spillovers. This contrasts the finding in the literature that cooperative R&D investments are higher with high spillovers. Such result comes as not a surprise in our model because unit cost of production increases as the number of upstream firms goes up. Consequently, both cooperative R&D and noncooperative R&D decline, but the former declines faster than the latter. Keywords: Noncooperative R&D; Input providers; Duopoly JEL Classification Numbers: D2; L5; O3

3 1 Introduction Research and Development (R&D) is one of the most vital and intriguing functions of successful modern enterprises. Among topics concerning R&D, one that interests economists the most is arguably the efficiency of cooperative R&D. By cooperative R&D, we refer to the circumstances in which firms, or divisions within the same firm, coordinate in their decisions on R&D investments and efforts, while their interactions in the product market may or may not be competitive. 1 This contrasts the case of a fully noncooperative game where firms make both R&D and output/pricing decisions independently. In their seminal work, d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988) 2 provide the framework that enables generations of economists to analyze the outcomes, efficiency, and welfare implications of cooperative R&D versus noncooperative R&D. 3 They provide a rational explanation to cooperative R&D by introducing a symmetrical spillovers between the two firms engaged in competition in their model. They find that cooperative R&D is more efficient in terms of reducing costs and enhancing welfare compared to noncooperative R&D when the spillovers are sufficiently high (higher than 1/2 in their paper). Our paper follows closely the analytical framework in d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988) but with the addition of upstream input providers. We believe the presence of upstream input providers to be important for at least two reasons. First, in cases where cooperative R&D occurs among firms who are competing in the product market, such as the examples mentioned in footnote 1, shared upstream input providers is often a common characteristic. For example, the well-known 1 The automobile industry and the electronic industry provide some of the best examples of cooperative R&D. For instance, in 2005, BMW, DaimlerChrysler, and General Motors signed an agreement to jointly develop a two-mode hybrid drive system (Bourreau and Doğan, 2010). In 2013, DaimlerChrysler, Ford, and Nissan allied to innovate the fuel-cell systems (Bourreau et al., 2014). In 2005, Sony and Samsung collaborated to innovate LCD panels (Bourreau et al., 2014). Other examples of inter-firm cooperative R&D include Texaco and Chevron, Apple and Dell, Texas Instruments and AMD, and Burlington Northern Santa Fe and Union Pacific (Duso et al., 2014). In addition, different models of the same automaker, ipad versus iphone, to name a few, can be considered examples of intra-firm cooperative R&D. 2 Readers are reminded of the 1990 erratum (d Aspremont and Jacquemin, 1990) and comment (Henriques, 1990) on the original publication. 3 Notable earlier efforts were made by Dasgupta and Stiglitz (1980); Brander and Spencer (1983); Spencer and Brander (1983); Spence (1984), and Katz (1986), to name a few. 2

4 Taiwanese manufacturer Foxconn supplies parts for BlackBerry, iphone/ipad, Amazon Kindle, Sony Playstation, Microsoft Xbox, and Wii U, some of which are close competitors. Second, for the special case of intra-firm R&D in multi-product firms, 4 it is inevitable to have shared upstream input providers. Our model of R&D cooperation and competition with upstream input providers is thus suited for the analysis of both inter-firm and intra-firm R&D. 5 Similar to d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988), we consider two duopolists who engage in cost-reducing R&D investments that have symmetrical spillovers, before competing in the product market in a Cournot model. For the upstream input providers, we make three assumptions. First, we hypothesize that competition among these upstream firms are of the Bertrand fashion. In other words, the upstream input providers simultaneously make their pricing decisions. Second, we assume one unit of output produced by the downstream duopolists requires one unit of input from each of the symmetrical upstream input providers. In addition, no vertical spillovers between upstream and downstream firms are possible. 6 Unlike d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988), whose conclusion is that R&D investments are higher in the cooperative R&D equilibrium as long as the spillovers are sufficiently high, we find that, given any level of spillovers, the noncooperative game results in higher R&D investments and consequently higher output levels when the number of upstream input providers are sufficiently large. The reason is that input costs that need to be paid to the upstream firms restrain the freedom in the output decisions of the downstream firms. In this case, the high output level resulted from cooperative R&D in the original framework is no longer the optimum. As the number of upstream input providers goes up, 7 the marginal revenue from both noncooperative and cooperative games goes down resulting in lower levels of R&D investments and outputs in both cases. However, the latter declines faster than the former, leading to a reversal of the results in d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988) when sufficiently large number of upstream input providers are present. 4 See Lin and Zhou (2013) for an analysis of R&D in multiproduct firms. 5 In this paper, only homogeneous product is considered. Products produced by the same firm are naturally differentiated although sometimes may be highly substitutable and have only small difference in their mark-ups. 6 Ishii (2004) considers the possibility of vertical spillovers in addition to horizontal spillovers. 7 For example, when firms need to produce more sophisticated products. 3

5 While our model fills the gap in the literature by considering upstream input providers, it is instructive to review related papers that contributed important insights to the literature, especially those extend and confirm the basic result of d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988). 8 Kamien et al. (1992) extend the model in a number of ways, but most notably they consider an alternative form of spillovers. In d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988), spillovers occur after R&D are realized and hence one firm s higher level of R&D reduces the production costs of the other firm. However, Kamien et al. (1992) assume spillovers to occur during R&D so that one firm s higher R&D expenditure lowers the other firm s expenditure of investing in R&D, which ultimately reduces production costs through a concave function of R&D expenditure. While the interpretation is different, they still find that, for sufficiently high spillovers, R&D investments under cooperation exceeds those in the noncooperative equilibrium. Suzumura (1992), on the other hand, extends d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988) to the case of oligopoly. The most important contribution of Suzumura (1992) is his consideration of the second-best welfare analysis, although the welfare implications are the same qualitatively regardless of the first-best outcome or the second-best outcome. Suzumura (1992) also finds that when there is no spillovers among the oligopolists, levels of R&D investments could exceed social optimum of both the first- and second-best outcomes. Instead of cost-reducing R&D, Motta (1992) considers quality-improving R&D with spillovers and finds that high spillovers still lead to high R&D investments. In Atallah (2005), spillovers are asymmetric, meaning that the spillover from one firm to the other is not the same as the other way around. Atallah (2005) finds that when the average spillover rate is greater than 1/2, R&D investments are higher in the cooperative equilibrium. Cellini and Lambertini (2009) extend the original model in d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988) to a dynamic model and find that the result that the cooperative game yields higher R&D investments with high spillovers still holds in the 8 d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988) have generated a mega size of literature. While we only review the ones that are most relevant to the current paper, a number of papers that have made important contributions to the literature on cooperative R&D investment with spillovers are also worth mentioning. See, for example, De Bondt and Veugelers (1991); Choi (1993); Combs (1993); Ziss (1994); Yi (1996); Amir and Wooders (1999); Petit and Tolwinski (1999); Amir (2000); Cabral (2000); Tesoriere (2008); Kesavayuth and Zikos (2012) and Dawid et al. (2013). For empirical evidence, see recent contributions in Cassiman and Veugelers (2002) and Duso et al. (2014). 4

6 steady state equilibrium. In a recent paper, Bourreau and Verdier (2014) extend the horizon to two-sided markets and find that the threshold level of spillovers that leads to higher cooperative R&D investments is related to the extent of externalities in a two-sided market. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 lays out our model as well as solutions to the noncooperative, cooperative, and collusive equilibria. Section 3 compares the results from the aforementioned equilibria. Section 4 computes the first- and second-best welfare outcomes, before ranking equilibrium levels of R&D investments, outputs, and social welfares in all cases considered. The last section concludes. 2 The Model We consider a model with n( 1) symmetrical upstream input providers and two downstream production firms. The two downstream firms are assumed to be identical. They both invest in cost-reducing R&D, before competing in the output market in the Cournot fashion. The timing of the game is as follows. In the first period, the two firms make R&D investment decisions simultaneously. In the second period, all upstream input providers make pricing decisions simultaneously. In the third and final period, the two downstream firms compete in the Cournot model by choosing profit-maximizing output levels. The game is solved backwardly. Formally, the unit cost of downstream firm i (for i = 1, 2) consists of three components: a constant marginal cost of production that is equal to c; a cost-reduction due to R&D and spillover from the other firm that is equal to x i + sx j (j i); and costs of inputs. For the cost-reducing R&D, x i and x j are investments by own and other firms, with s (0, 1) measuring the size of the spillovers. The cost of R&D is assumed to be a quadratic function of the investment level, x i, and is given by 1 2 rx2 i with r > 0. For costs of inputs, we assume one unit of final output needs one unit of input from all upstream providers, so that the cost of inputs per unit of output is n k=1 w k where w k is the price of input from provider k, to be determined in the second period of the game. 5

7 In summary, unit cost of downstream firm i is equal to n w k + c x i sx j k=1 The inverse market demand is assumed to be a linear function: p = a b (q 1 + q 2 ) ; where q 1 and q 2 are output levels of the two downstream firms and the usual assumptions a > 0 and b > 0 are applied. To ensure positive values for solutions of R&D investments and output levels in all cases, we need the following assumptions throughout the paper: Assumption 1. a c nf > 0. Assumption 2. 2br (1 + s) 2 > 0. In Assumption 1, f is the marginal cost of the upstream input providers. The assumption states that the market, measured by a, needs to be large enough. Assumption 2, on the other hand, will hold true when the cost of R&D (r) is sufficiently high. In this paper, we consider three different scenarios of R&D decision-making, the same as those in d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988). The first scenario is a full noncooperative game, in which the two downstream firms compete noncooperatively in both outputs and R&D investments. In the second scenario, the two downstream firms cooperate in R&D investment but still compete in the output market noncooperatively. However, we will call this the cooperative game since R&D investment is our main concern. The last scenario is the case of collusion, or symmetrical monopoly, in which the two downstream firms cooperate in both the output market and R&D investment. In addition, the socially optimal levels of R&D investments and outputs are computed and compared against results from the aforementioned scenarios. 6

8 2.1 Noncooperative Equilibrium In the noncooperative game where the two downstream firms make both R&D and output decisions simultaneously and noncooperatively, profit of production firm i is given by ( n ) π i = [a b (q 1 + q 2 )] q i w k + c x i sx j q i 1 2 rx2 i, (1) k=1 for i = 1, 2 and j i. We can solve for the output level of firm i in the Cournot competition as ( ) q i = 1 n a c w k + (2 s) x i + (2s 1) x j 3b k=1 (2) for i = 1, 2 and j i. In the second period, we solve for the input providers optimal pricing strategies. From equation (2), we derive the demand function for an input provider as [ ( q 1 + q 2 = 1 2 a c 3b ) ] n w k + (1 + s) (x 1 + x 2 ). k=1 Assuming that all input providers face the same constant marginal cost f, the profit of input provider m is [ ( π m = 1 2 a c 3b ) ] n w k + (1 + s) (x 1 + x 2 ) (w m f) k=1 for m = 1, 2,..., n. The price that maximizes π m is therefore w m = 2 (a c + f) + (1 + s) (x 1 + x 2 ). (3) 2 + 2n Plugging w m in equation (3) back to the solution in equation (2), we have q i = 1 3b ( 2 (a c nf) n (1 + s) (x1 + x 2 ) 2 + 2n + (2 s) x i + (2s 1) x j ). 7

9 In the first period of the noncooperative game, the two firms maximize their own profits by choosing R&D investment levels independently and simultaneously. Let superscript N denote variables of the noncooperative game, in equilibrium, we have x N i = 1 (a c nf) (4 2s + 3n 3ns) A (4a) qi N = 3 (a c nf) (1 + n) r A (4b) where A = 9br (1 + n) 2 (1 + s) (4 2s + 3n 3ns). The following comparative statics can be derived from equation (4a): 9 x N i a > 0; xn i b c r f s n < 0. The above comparative statics fully describe the responses of R&D investments to exogenous factors in the noncooperative equilibrium. It is shown that R&D investments are higher in the noncooperative equilibrium with a bigger market ( a ), lower costs (c, r, and f), lower spillovers b (s), and fewer upstream input providers (n). 9 The comparative statics with respect to s and n are less straightforward. For s, we have where x N i s c nf) ( = (a A 2 (2 + 3n) 9br (1 + n) 2 ( n 3ns) 2), (2 + 3n) 9br (1 + n) 2 ( n 3ns) 2 > (2 + 3n) 9br (1 + n) 2 (2 + 3n) (1 + s) ( n 3ns) > 0. As a result, xn i s < 0. For n, we have x N i n = 1 [(4 2s + 3n 3ns) Af + 9br (1 + n) (3n 3ns s + 5) (a c nf)] < 0. A2 8

10 2.2 Cooperative Equilibrium In the cooperative game, the two firms maximize joint profit π 1 + π 2 : [ ] n Π = a b(q 1 + q 2 ) w k c (q 1 + q 2 ) + (q 1 + sq 2 )x 1 + (sq 1 + q 2 )x rx rx2 2. (5) k=1 The solutions to the second and third periods of the cooperative game is the same as those of the noncooperative game. Let superscript C denote variables of the cooperative game, in equilibrium, we have x C i = 2 (a c nf)(1 + s) (6a) B qi C = 3 (a c nf)(1 + n)r (6b) B where B = 9br(1 + n) 2 2(1 + s) 2. The following comparative statics can be derived from equation (6a): 10 x N i a > 0; xn i b c r f s > 0; xn i n < 0. The above comparative statics fully describe the responses of R&D investments to exogenous factors in the cooperative equilibrium. It is shown that R&D investments are higher in the noncooperative equilibrium with a bigger market ( a ), lower costs (c, r, and f), higher spillovers b (s), and fewer upstream input providers (n). This set of comparative statics is the same compared to the noncooperative game except for the response to spillovers. 10 The comparative static with respect to n is less straightforward. From equation (6a), we have x C i n = 1 [Bf + 18br(1 + n)(a c nf)] < 0. B2 9

11 2.3 Collusive Equilibrium Let x M (= x M 1 = x M 2 ), q M (= q M 1 +q M 2 ) and π M (= π M 1 +π M 2 ) denote R&D investment, output, and profit under collusion, 11 the profit maximization problem is given by max π M = (a bq M )q M q M ( n ) w k + c q M + (1 + s)x M q M r(x M ) 2, (7) k=1 with optimal output level in the first period as q M = 1 2b ( a c ) n w k + (1 + s)x M. (8) k=1 In the second period, profit of input provider m is π m = 1 2b ( a c with the solution of input prices given by ) n w k + (1 + s)x M (w m f), k=1 w m = a c + f + (1 + s)xm 1 + n. (9) Plugging equations (8) and (9) back to equation (7), we can solve for the optimal R&D investment level in collusion as x M = 1 (a c nf)(1 + s), (10) D where D = 4br(1 + n) 2 (1 + s) 2 > 0. In addition, we have qi M = qm 2 = 1 (a c nf)(1 + n)r. (11) D 11 We consider the same collusive game, or symmetrical monopoly, as in d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988). In other words, in equilibrium, x M 1 = x M 2, q M 1 = q M 2 = 1 2 qm, and π M 1 = π M 2 = 1 2 πm. 10

12 The following comparative statics can be derived from equation (10): 12 x N i a > 0; xn i b c r f s n < 0. The above comparative statics fully describe the responses of R&D investments to exogenous factors in the collusive equilibrium. It is shown that R&D investments are higher in the noncooperative equilibrium with a bigger market ( a ), lower costs (c, r, and f), lower spillovers b (s), and fewer input providers (n). This set of comparative statics is the same as that from the noncooperative game. 3 Comparison of Equilibrium Outcomes In this section, we will compare the equilibrium outcomes of the three scenarios considered above. The focus is on the comparison of R&D investments, which we put into propositions. Comparisons of output levels are concluded as corollaries. 3.1 Noncooperative versus Cooperative The equilibrium R&D investment levels in the noncooperative and cooperative games, from equations (4a) and (6a), allow us to establish the following lemma and proposition: Lemma 1. R&D investments are higher in the cooperative equilibrium than in the noncooperative equilibrium (x C i > x N i ) if, and only if, spillovers are sufficiently high (s > 3n+2 3n+4 ). Proposition 1. R&D investments are higher in the noncooperative equilibrium than in the cooperative equilibrium (x N i > x C i ) if, and only if, the number of upstream input providers is sufficiently large (n > 4s 2 3 3s ). 12 The comparative static with respect to n is less straightforward. From equation (10), we have x M n = (1 + s) D 2 [Df + 8br(1 + n)(a c nf)] < 0. 11

13 Proof. Subtracting (6a) from (4a) gives x N i x C i = 1 AB 9br(a c nf)(1 + n)2 (4s 2 3n + 3ns), which implies x N i > x C i 4s 2 3n + 3ns < 0. The solution of s to the reversal of the above inequality (x C i > x N i ) proves Lemma 1, while the solution of n to the above inequality proves Proposition 1. Note that 4s 2 3 3s 5 7 s < 1. In other words, n > 4s 2 3 3s is always satisfied when s < 5 7 holds. 1 if and only if Lemma 1 is similar to the result of d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988), which states that when spillovers are sufficiently large (s > 1 2 in their model), cooperative R&D investments are higher than noncooperative R&D investment. Note that 3n + 2 3n + 4 > 1 2, for any n > 1, which suggests that our model requires higher spillovers for cooperative R&D investment to exceed noncooperative R&D investment. The intuition is that the presence of the input providers makes it less profitable when firms invest more in R&D and also produce more because they need to pay for the costs of upstream inputs. Added to this explanation, Proposition 1 further states that given any size of spillovers, as long as the number of upstream input providers is sufficiently large (n > 4s 2 ), the result in d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988) is reversed. 3 3s To better understand this result, which runs in contrary to d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988) and many of the extensions in the literature, we hypothesize that initially 4s 2 3n+3ns = 0. This implies x N i = x C i and q N i = q C i. Suppose now the number of input providers, n, has increased This may happen when firms need to produce more sophisticated products. 12

14 We have already established in Sections 2.1 and 2.2 that x N i n < 0; xc i n < 0; which indicates that as the number of input providers increases, R&D investment levels in both the noncooperative and cooperative equilibria decrease. However, the rates of decline in the two cases are not the same. From equations (4a) and (6a), we further find that x N i n xc i n = 3 (1 s)(a c nf) (1 + A ) 2(1 + s)2 > 0, (12) A with the inequality sign follows from Assumptions 1 and 2. In addition, the derivation of equation (12) utilizes the condition 4s 2 3n + 3ns = 0, i.e., A = B. According to equation (12), the decline in the cooperative game is faster than that of the noncooperative game with more input providers. In other words, other things being equal, we have x C i n < xn i n < 0. This explains the result in Proposition 1 that x N i > x C i for n > 4s 2 3 3s. In fact, if the production of input is costless, at the limit, R&D investments in the noncooperative equilibrium will be at least as high as R&D investments in the cooperative equilibrium. Formally, we can establish: Corollary 1. When the marginal cost of upstream input providers is zero (f = 0) and the number of input providers approaches infinity (n ), R&D investments in the cooperative equilibrium will never exceed R&D investments in the noncooperative equilibrium (x C i x N i ). Last, comparison of output levels is established in the following corollary: Corollary 2. q N i q C i if and only if x N i x C i. 13

15 Proof. Subtracting (6b) from (4b) gives qi N qi C = 3 (1 + n)(a c nf)(4s 2 3n + 3ns) AB which implies q N i > q C i 4s 2 3n + 3ns < 0, the same condition as the comparison between x N i and x C i. 3.2 Noncooperative versus Collusion Comparing equations (4a) and (10) gives x M x N i = 1 AD br(a c nf)(1 + n)2 (17s 7 12n + 12ns), (13) which allows us to establish the following lemma and proposition: Lemma 2. R&D investments are higher in collusion than in the noncooperative equilibrium (x M > x N i ) if, and only if, spillovers are sufficiently high (s > 12n+7 12n+17 ). Proposition 2. R&D investments are higher in the noncooperative than in collusion (x N i > x M ) if, and only if, the number of upstream input providers is sufficiently large (n > 17s s ). Proof. From equation (13), we have x M < x N i 17s 7 12n + 12ns < 0. The solution of s to the reversal of the above inequality proves Lemma 2, while the solution of n to the above inequality proves Proposition 2. Note that 17s s is less than 5 4s 2, the critical value for 7 3 3s 1 in Section if and only if s 19 29, which Lemma 2 is similar to d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988). They show that, for sufficiently high spillovers (s > 0.41 in their model), R&D investments are higher in the collusive equilibrium 14

16 than in the noncooperative equilibrium. However, similar to the result and intuition in Section 3.1, 14 Proposition 2 suggests that when the number of upstream providers is sufficiently large, with any size of spillovers, R&D investments in the noncooperative equilibrium can exceed those in collusion. Comparison of output levels is given in the following corollary: Corollary 3. Output level is always higher in the noncooperative equilibrium than in collusion (q N i > q M i ). Proof. From equations (4b) and (11), we have q N i q M i = (1 + n)(a c nf)r AD [ 3br(1 + n) 2 2(1 + s) 2 + 3(1 + n)(1 n 2 ) ] > 0, which is positive according to Assumptions 1 and 2. This proves Corollary Cooperative versus Collusion From equations (6a) and (10), we find x M x C i = 1 BD br(a c nf)(1 + n)2 (1 + s) > 0, which allows us to establish the following lemma that is the same as d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988): Lemma 3. R&D investments are always higher in collusion than in the cooperative equilibrium (x M x C i ). Additionally, the comparison of output levels is given in the following corollary: 14 For the comparison between xn i n xm and n, we have x N i n xm n br(1 + n)(4 2s + 3n 3ns)(a c nf) = (1 + s)a 2 (24n 24ns 29s + 19) > 0. 15

17 Corollary 4. Output levels are always higher in the cooperative equilibrium than in collusion (q C i > q M i ). Proof. From equations (6b) and (11), we have q C i q M i = (1 + n)(a c nf) BD ( 3br(1 + n) 2 (1 + s) 2) > 0, which is positive according to Assumptions 1 and 2. This proves Corollary 4. 4 Welfare Analysis In this Section we follow the literature to compare our equilibrium levels of R&D investments and outputs in all three scenarios to the ones that are socially optimum. In other words, we find levels of R&D investments and outputs that maximize social welfare (SW ), which is defined as the sum of consumer surplus (CS) and producer surplus (P S). Such approach constitutes the first-best outcome. In addition, we consider the second-best outcome as proposed by Suzumura (1992). 4.1 Solutions to First- and Second-Best Let x denote the first-best R&D investment level for each firm and q the first-best total output level (q 1 + q 2). In our model, consumer surplus is CS = 1 2 (a p)q = 1 2 [a (a bq )]q = b 2 (q ) 2. (14) Recognizing the fact that once the socially optimal level of R&D is settled in the first period, marginal cost of production is constant in the third period, we have producer surplus to be P S = (p MC)q r(x ) 2 (15) 16

18 where MC = nf + c (1 + s)x. (16) Combining equations (15) and (16) gives P S = [a bq (nf + c (1 + s)x )] q r(x ) 2 =aq b(q ) 2 (nf + c (1 + s)x )q r(x ) 2. (17) Note that equation (16) postulates the fact that equilibrium of the upstream input providers game is such that they all price at marginal cost. This result could be rationalized by the fact that price equals to marginal cost eliminates dead weight loss in the input market that consists of n upstream input providers. Summing equations (14) and (17) gives SW = aq b 2 (q ) 2 (nf + c (1 + s)x )q r(x ) 2. (18) To solve for the socially optimal output level in the last period of the game, we take the derivative of equation (23) with respect to q, set it to zero, and solve for q taken x as given. The socially optimal q can be computed as q = a c nf + (1 + s)x. (19) To solve for the socially optimal level of R&D (x ), we plug equation (19) back to equation (23), then take the derivative of SW with respect to x and set it to zero. The resulting x is x = 1 (a c nf)(1 + s), (20) E where 15 E = 2br (1 + s) This is the equation that Assumption 2 is based upon. 17

19 Plugging x back to equation (19) gives each firm s socially optimal output level as qi = 1 2 q = 1 (a c nf)r. (21) E Suzumura (1992) argues that the first-best welfare analysis may not be appropriate in the cases of R&D because the second-stage quantity game lies beyond the regulatory power of the nonomnipotent government (pp.1314). Following his suggestion, we also calculate the second-best R&D investment level, which we denote as x, and the second-best firm output level, which we denote as q i. The second-best R&D and output levels are x = 1 (a c nf)(4 + 6n)(1 + s); F (22a) q i = 3 (a c nf)(1 + n)r; F (22b) where F = 9br(1 + n) 2 (4 + 6n)(1 + s) Comparing R&D Investments A comparison among R&D investment levels, from equations (4a), (6a), (10), (20), and (22a), allows us to establish the following proposition: Proposition 3. The complete ranking of all R&D investment levels in our model is: (i) x > x > x M x C i x N i if and only if s 3n+2 for any given n; 3n+4 n 4s 2 for any given s; 3 3s (ii) x > x > x N i x M x C i if and only if s 12n+7 for any given n; 12n+17 n 17s 7 for any given s; 12 12s (iii) x > x > x M > x N i > x C i if and only if 18

20 12n+7 < s < 3n+2 for any given n; 12n+17 3n+4 4s 2 < n < 17s 7 for any given s; 3 3s 12 12s Proof. The conditions for comparisons among x N i, x C i, and x M are followed from Lemmas 1-3, and Propositions 1 and 2. In addition, from equations (4a), (6a), (10), (20), and (22a), we get x x = br EF (a c nf)(1 + 3n)2 (1 + s) > 0; x x N i x x C i = 27br AF (a c nf)(1 + n)2 (n + 2s + 3ns) > 0; = 18br BF (a c nf)(1 + n)2 (1 + 3n)(1 + s) > 0; x x M = br DF (a c nf)(1 + n)2 (7 + 24n)(1 + s) > 0. These together prove Proposition 3. We draw two important conclusions from Proposition 3. First, when either spillovers are sufficiently high (s 3n+2 4s 2 ) or the number of input providers is sufficiently small (n ), 3n+4 3 3s that is, in cases (i), more cooperations and coordination between the two downstream production firms leads to higher levels of R&D investments, as x > x > x M x C i x N i is the resulted ranking. Second, although noncooperative R&D investment level does not exceed that of social optimum, it overshoots the cases of both cooperative and collusive equilibria when either spillovers are sufficiently low (s 12n+7 17s 7 ) or the number of input providers is sufficiently large (n ). 12n s The result arisen from sufficiently low spillovers is similar to Suzumura (1992). 4.3 Comparing Output Levels Comparison among output levels, from equations (4b), (6b), (11), (21), and (22b), leads to the following proposition: Proposition 4. The complete ranking of output levels in our model is: (i) q i > q i > q C i q N i > q M i if and only if s 3n+2 for any given n; 3n+4 19

21 n 4s 2 for any given s; 3 3s (ii) q i > q i > q N i > q C i > q M i if and only if s < 3n+2 for any given n; 3n+4 n > 4s 2 for any given s. 3 3s Proof. The conditions for comparisons among q N i, q C i, and q M are followed from Corollaries 2-4, and Propositions 1 and 2. In addition, from equations (4b), (6b), (11), (21), and (22b), we get q i q i = q i q N i q i q C i r EF (a c nf)(1 + 3n) [ 3br(1 + n) (1 + s) 2] > 0; = 9r (a c nf)(1 + n)(1 + s)(n + 2s + 3ns) > 0; BF = 6r AF (a c nf)(1 + n)(1 + 3n)(1 + s)2 > 0; q i q M i = r DF (a c nf)(1 + n) [ (3 + 12s)br(1 + n) 2 + (1 + 6n 3s)(1 + s) 2] > 0. These together prove Proposition 4. The ranking of output levels is similar to the ranking of R&D investments with one exception: output levels in the collusive equilibrium are always the lowest among all cases. This is to be expected because firms work as a joint/symmetrical monopoly in collusion. With higher market power, they produce lower combined levels of outputs. 4.4 Comparing Social Welfares Finally, we compute values of social welfares as 16 SW (4 + 6n) = (a c nf) 2 r, F (23a) SW N = [18br(1 + n)2 (2 + 3n) (4 2s + 3n 3ns) 2 ] (a c nf) 2 r, A 2 (23b) SW C = [18br(1 + n)2 (2 + 3n) 4(1 + s) 2 ] B 2 (a c nf) 2 r, (23c) SW M = [2br(1 + n)2 (3 + 4n) (1 + s) 2 ] D 2 (a c nf) 2 r. (23d) 16 Note that we have ignored SW because by definition SW is the maximum possible welfare. 20

22 A comparison among these values allow us to establish the following proposition: Proposition 5. The complete ranking of social welfares in our model is: (i) SW > SW > SW C SW N > SW M if and only if s 3n+2 for any given n; 3n+4 n 4s 2 for any given s; 3 3s (ii) SW > SW > SW N > SW C > SW M if and only if s < 3n+2 for any given n; 3n+4 n > 4s 2 for any given s. 3 3s Proof. First, we note that SW N = SW C if and only if 4 2s + 3n 3ns = 2(1 + s). In other words, SW N SW C if and only if x N i x C i or q N i q C i. Second, taking the difference between SW C and SW M gives SW C SW M = (1 + n)2 (a c nf) 2 br 2 B 2 D ( 2 2(12n + 5) [ (1 + s) 2 3br(1 + n) 2] 2 [ + (1 + n)(1 + s) 2 5br(1 + n) 2(1 + s) 2]) > 0, where the inequality sign is derived according to Assumption 2. Third, proof of SW N > SW M is presented in the Appendix. Lastly, we find SW SW N = 1 A 2 F SW SW C = 1 B 2 F [ 81(1 + n) 2 (2s + n + 3ns) 2 (a c nf) 2 br 2] > 0; [ 36(1 + n) 2 (1 + 3n) 2 (1 + s) 2 (a c nf) 2 br 2] > 0. These together prove Proposition 5. Taken together, Propositions 3, 4, and 5 show that, for the three cases of R&D considered in this paper, both R&D investments and output levels are under-supplied compared to social optimum of either first- or second-best. Consequently, the social welfares from these three cases are below the social optimal levels. The comparison among results of second-best, noncooperative 21

23 game, and cooperative game is interesting. Our calculations indicate that full competition, as in the case of the noncooperative game, does not automatically lead to social optimum. On the other hand, even the cooperative game in which firms coordinate in their R&D decisions is sub-optimal compared to the second-best outcome. Keep in mind that the second-best outcome has already recognized the fact that the last period of the game will be Cournot competition, as proposed by Suzumura (1992). Together, the welfare conclusions from these propositions indicate that stronger government intervention and coordination efforts in R&D investments may be beneficial. 5 Concluding Remarks Since the seminal work of d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988), many extensions have shown that with sufficiently high spillovers, R&D investments in the cooperative equilibrium are higher than those in the noncooperative equilibrium. With the addition of upstream input providers, we demonstrate in this paper that the aforementioned result can reverse, so long as the number of upstream input providers is sufficiently large. We show that the presence of the input providers has changed the decision making of the downstream firms. Given any level of spillovers, as the number of input providers goes up, the marginal revenue from more R&D investment and more output decreases at a faster rate in the cooperative game than in the noncooperative game. As a result, when the number of input providers is sufficiently high, firms invest more in R&D in the noncooperative equilibrium compared to the cooperative equilibrium. Consequently, the downstream firms also produce more output in the noncooperative equilibrium. We believe the contribution in this paper is important because as manufactured goods become more sophisticated, more components and/or steps are needed to finish a product. More sophisticated products will call for more upstream input providers. The connection between R&D spillovers and upstream input providers is also natural. When a new technology is being introduced as the outcome of cost-reducing R&D, a firm may look for new input providers who have the ability to handle the new technology, or it may teach its current input providers the new procedure. Both 22

24 cases cause spillovers horizontally among downstream production firms, as an input provider can serve multiple downstream production firms. Since our model builds on the framework of d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988), it can potentially be applied to extensions of d Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988) considered in the literature. We believe the results derived in the current paper will continue to hold because the logic in the decision-makings of the downstream firms will continue to be valid. References Amir, R. (2000). Modelling Imperfectly Appropriable R&D via Spillovers. International Journal of Industrial Organization 18, Amir, R. and J. Wooders (1999). Effects of One-Way Spillovers on Market Shares, Industry Price, Welfare, and R&D Cooperation. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 8, Atallah, G. (2005). R&D Cooperation with Asymmetric Spillovers. Canadian Journal of Economics 38, Bourreau, M. and P. Doğan (2010). Cooperation in Product Development and Process R&D between Competitors. International Journal of Industrial Organization 28, Bourreau, M., P. Doğan, and M. Manant (2014, July). Size of RJVs with partial cooperation in product development. Institute for Advanced Study, School of Social Science, Economics Working Papers. Bourreau, M. and M. Verdier (2014). Cooperative and Noncooperative R&D in Two-Sided Markets. Review of Network Economics 13, Brander, J. A. and B. J. Spencer (1983). Strategic Commitment with R&D: The Symmetric Case. Bell Journal of Economics 14, Cabral, L. M. B. (2000). R&D Cooperation and Product Market Competition. International Journal of Industrial Organization 18, Cassiman, B. and R. Veugelers (2002). R&D Cooperation and Spillovers: Some Empirical Evidence from Belgium. American Economic Review 92, Cellini, R. and L. Lambertini (2009). Dynamic R&D with Spillovers: Competition vs Cooperation. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 33, Choi, J. P. (1993). Cooperative R&D with Product Market Competition. International Journal of Industrial Organization 11,

25 Combs, K. L. (1993). The Role of Information Sharing in Cooperative Research and Development. International Journal of Industrial Organization 11, Dasgupta, P. and J. Stiglitz (1980). Industrial Structure and the Nature of Innovative Activity. Economic Journal 90, d Aspremont, C. and A. Jacquemin (1988). Cooperative and Noncooperative R&D in Duopoly with Spillovers. American Economic Review 78, d Aspremont, C. and A. Jacquemin (1990). Cooperative and Noncooperative R&D in Duopoly with Spillovers: Erratum. American Economic Review 80, Dawid, H., M. Kopel, and P. Kort (2013). R&D Competition versus R&D cooperation in Oligopolistic Markets with Evolving Structure. International Journal of Industrial Organization 31, De Bondt, R. and R. Veugelers (1991). Strategic Investments with Spillovers. European Journal of Political Economy 7, Duso, T., L.-H. Röller, and J. Seldeslachts (2014). Collusion through Joint R&D: An Empirical Assessment. Review of Economics and Statistics 96, Henriques, I. (1990). Cooperative and Noncooperative R&D in Duopoly with Spillovers: Comment. American Economic Review 80, Ishii, A. (2004). Cooperative R&D between Vertically Related Firms with Spillovers. International Journal of Industrial Organization 22, Kamien, M. I., E. Muller, and I. Zang (1992). Research Joint Ventures and R&D Cartels. American Economic Review 82, Katz, M. L. (1986). An Analysis of Cooperative Research and Development. RAND Journal of Economics 17, Kesavayuth, D. and V. Zikos (2012). Economic Modelling 29, Upstream and Downstream Horizontal R&D Networks. Lin, P. and W. Zhou (2013). The Effects of Competition on the R&D Portfolios of Multiproduct Firms. International Journal of Industrial Organization 31, Motta, M. (1992). Cooperative R&D and Vertical Product Differentiation. International Journal of Industrial Organization 10, Petit, M. L. and B. Tolwinski (1999). R&D Cooperation or Competition? European Economic Review 43, Spence, M. (1984). Cost Reduction, Competition, and Industry Performance. Econometrica 52,

26 Spencer, B. J. and J. A. Brander (1983). International R&D Rivalry and Industrial Strategy. Review of Economic Studies 50, Suzumura, K. (1992). Cooperative and Noncooperative R&D in an Oligopoly with Spillovers. American Economic Review 82, Tesoriere, A. (2008). Endogenous R&D Symmetry in Linear Duopoly with One-way Spillovers. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 66, Yi, S.-S. (1996). The Welfare Effects of Cooperative R&D in Oligopoly with Spillovers. Review of Industrial Organization 11, Ziss, S. (1994). Strategic R&D with Spillovers, Collusion and Welfare. Journal of Industrial Economics 42, Appendix This appendix provides detailed proof of the result that SW N SW M > 0 in Proposition 5. From equations (23b) and (23d), we find where SW N SW M = (1 + n)2 (a c nf) 2 br 2 A 2 D 2 (Z 1 + Z 2 + Z 3 + Z 4 + Z 5 ), Z 1 =954bnr ( bn 3 r s 2) + 288bn 4 r(2s + 1)(1 s), Z 2 =90b 2 r b 2 n 5 r 2 br ( 31 58s + 487s 2) + 4 ( 20s 2 + s 1 ) (1 + s) 2, Z 3 =n ( b 2 r 2 6 (1 s) (29 13s) (s + 1) 2 br ( 3535s 2 346s 425 )), Z 4 =12n ( 3 138b 2 r 2 6 (1 + s) 2 (s + 1) 2 br ( 199s 2 48s 55 )), Z 5 =2n ( 288b 2 r 2 br ( 628s 2 58s 11 ) + 2 ( 25s s 20 ) (1 + s) 2). With Assumption 1, it can be verified that Z 1 > 0, Z 2 (br) > 0, Z 3 (br) > 0, Z 4 (br) > 0, Z 5 (br) > 0. For Z 2 to Z 5, replacing br with (1+s)2 2 results in Z 2 >90b 2 r b 2 r 2 br ( 31 58s + 487s 2) + 4 ( 20s 2 + s 1 ) (1 + s) 2, ( ) (1 + s) 2 2 ( ) (1 + s) 2 (31 >306 ) 58s + 487s ( 20s 2 + s 1 ) (1 + s) =3 (1 + s) 2 ( s 29s 2) > 0. 25

27 ( ) Z 3 >n 2 (1 + s) ( ) 6 (1 s) (29 13s) (s + 1) 2 (1 + s) 2 (3535s 2 346s 425 ), 2 2 = 1 2 (1 + ( s) s 2989s 2) > 0. ( ) Z 4 >12n 3 (1 + s) ( ) 6 (1 + s) 2 (s + 1) 2 (1 + s) 2 (199s 2 48s 55 ), 2 2 = (1 + s) 2 ( s 71s 2) > 0. ( ) (1 + s) Z 5 > ( ) (1 + s) 2 (628s 2 58s 11 ) + 2 ( 25s s 20 ) (1 + s) 2, 2 2 = 3 2 (1 + s)2 ( s 128s 2) > 0. All the inequality signs above utilize Assumption 1 and the fact that 0 < s < 1. Together these prove that SW N SW M > 0. 26

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 16-1, 231 253 (2015) Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * Hongkun Ma School of Economics, Shandong University,

More information

Faculty Research Working Papers Series

Faculty Research Working Papers Series Faculty Research Working Papers Series Cooperation in Product Development and Process R&D between Competitors Marc Bourreau ENST and CREST-LEI (France) Pinar Dogan John F. Kennedy School of Government

More information

Oligopoly Notes. Simona Montagnana

Oligopoly Notes. Simona Montagnana Oligopoly Notes Simona Montagnana Question 1. Write down a homogeneous good duopoly model of quantity competition. Using your model, explain the following: (a) the reaction function of the Stackelberg

More information

Environmental R&D with Permits Trading

Environmental R&D with Permits Trading Environmental R&D with Permits Trading Gamal Atallah Department of Economics, University of Ottawa Jianqiao Liu Environment Canada April 2012 Corresponding author: Gamal Atallah, Associate Professor, Department

More information

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of... This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of... John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 1 / 1 We will cover the following topics: with Sequential Moves

More information

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

Answer Key: Problem Set 3 Answer Key: Problem Set Econ 409 018 Fall Question 1 a This is a standard monopoly problem; using MR = a 4Q, let MR = MC and solve: Q M = a c 4, P M = a + c, πm = (a c) 8 The Lerner index is then L M P

More information

Advanced Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomics Advanced Microeconomics Leonardo Felli EC441: Room D.106, Z.332, D.109 Lecture 8 bis: 24 November 2004 Monopoly Consider now the pricing behavior of a profit maximizing monopolist: a firm that is the only

More information

Research and Development

Research and Development Chapter 9. March 7, 2011 Firms spend substantial amounts on. For instance ( expenditure to output sales): aerospace (23%), o ce machines and computers (18%), electronics (10%) and drugs (9%). is classi

More information

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 Bertrand Model of Price Competition Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 ҧ Bertrand Model of Price Competition Consider: An industry with two firms, 1 and 2, selling a homogeneous product Firms face market

More information

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship Journal of Game Theory 2017 6(2): 38-42 DOI: 10.5923/j.jgt.20170602.02 Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship Aika Monden Graduate School

More information

Basics of Game Theory

Basics of Game Theory Basics of Game Theory Giacomo Bacci and Luca Sanguinetti Department of Information Engineering University of Pisa, Pisa, Italy {giacomo.bacci,luca.sanguinetti}@iet.unipi.it April - May, 2010 G. Bacci and

More information

Free Entry and Social Inefficiency under Vertical Oligopoly: Revisited

Free Entry and Social Inefficiency under Vertical Oligopoly: Revisited Free Entry and Social Inefficiency under Vertical Oligopoly: Revisited Hiroshi Kurata a, Takao Ohkawa b, Makoto Okamura c a Department of Economics, Tohoku Gakuin University, Japan b Department of Economics,

More information

Oligopoly. Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009

Oligopoly. Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009 Oligopoly Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009 1 Oligopoly A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. An oligopoly is an industry

More information

Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly

Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo June 8, 2010 Abstract I investigate an asymmetric duopoly where

More information

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October 23 2011 1 Scores The exam was long. I know this. Final grades will definitely be curved. Here is a rough

More information

Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot

Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot Class Note: There are supplemental readings, including Werden (008) Unilateral Competitive Effects of Horizontal Mergers I: Basic Concepts and Models, that

More information

Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network

Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network Effects Adriana Gama Mario Samano September 7, 218 Abstract We establish an important difference between Cournot oligopolies with and without positive

More information

Modeling of Chaotic Behavior in the Economic Model

Modeling of Chaotic Behavior in the Economic Model Chaotic Modeling and Simulation (CMSIM) 3: 9-98, 06 Modeling of Chaotic Behavior in the Economic Model Volodymyr Rusyn, Oleksandr Savko Department of Radiotechnics and Information Security, Yuriy Fedkovych

More information

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Hiroaki Ino Institute of Intellectual Property and Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo [Preliminary

More information

Katz and Shapiro (1985)

Katz and Shapiro (1985) Katz and Shapiro (1985) 1 The paper studies the compatibility choice of competing firms in industries with network externalities. Also investigated are the social vs. private incentives of compatibility

More information

A Note on Cost Reducing Alliances in Vertically Differentiated Oligopoly. Abstract

A Note on Cost Reducing Alliances in Vertically Differentiated Oligopoly. Abstract A Note on Cost Reducing Alliances in Vertically Differentiated Oligopoly Frédéric DEROÏAN FORUM Abstract In a vertically differentiated oligopoly, firms raise cost reducing alliances before competing with

More information

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games University of Manchester, UK November 25, 2010 Introduction Suppose we make a finite set of observations T = {1,..., m}, m 1, of a perfectly homogeneous-good oligopoly market. There is a finite number

More information

Managerial delegation in multimarket oligopoly

Managerial delegation in multimarket oligopoly Managerial delegation in multimarket oligopoly Arup Bose Barnali Gupta Statistics and Mathematics Unit Department of Economics Indian Statistical Institute Miami University, Ohio INDIA USA bosearu@gmail.com

More information

Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!?

Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!? Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!? Mathias Erlei Clausthal University of Technology Julius-Albert-Str. 2, 38678 Clausthal-Zellerfeld, Germany email: m.erlei@tu-clausthal.de Abstract This

More information

Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition

Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition Luca Lambertini Alessandro Tampieri Quaderni - Working Paper DSE N 750 Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Di erentiated

More information

On Competitive and Welfare Effects of Cross-Holdings with Product Differentiation

On Competitive and Welfare Effects of Cross-Holdings with Product Differentiation On Competitive and Welfare Effects of Cross-Holdings with Product Differentiation Teng Wang October 2, 2017 Abstract Competitive implications of cross-holdings have been extensively analyzed in the literature.

More information

Partial Privatization under Multimarket Price Competition

Partial Privatization under Multimarket Price Competition MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Partial Privatization under Multimarket Price Competition Taku Masuda and Susumu Sato Graduate School of Economics, The University of Tokyo, Graduate School of Economics,

More information

Green Technology and Optimal Emissions Taxation

Green Technology and Optimal Emissions Taxation Green Technology and Optimal Emissions Taxation Stuart McDonald School of Economics The Universty of Queensland s.mcdonald@uq.edu.au Joanna Poyago-Theotoky School of Economics, La Trobe University Rimini

More information

A Model of Endogenous Cross-Holdings in Oligopoly

A Model of Endogenous Cross-Holdings in Oligopoly A Model of Endogenous Cross-Holdings in Oligopoly Cheng-Zhong Qin, Shengping Zhang, and Dandan Zhu February 6, 2012 Abstract A network approach is proposed to analyze endogenous cross-holdings and their

More information

Green Technology and Optimal Emissions Taxation

Green Technology and Optimal Emissions Taxation La Trobe University From the SelectedWorks of Joanna Poyago-Theotoky March, 2014 Green Technology and Optimal Emissions Taxation Stuart McDonald, The University of Queensland Joanna Poyago-Theotoky, La

More information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers September 6, 016 ONLINE APPENDIX In this Appendix we present in full additional results and extensions which are only mentioned in the paper. In the exposition

More information

Emissions abatement R&D Dynamic Competition in Supply Schedules

Emissions abatement R&D Dynamic Competition in Supply Schedules Emissions abatement R&D Dynamic Competition in Supply Schedules Flavio M. Menezes School of Economics The University of Queensland Brisbane, QLD, 4072 Australia Phone +61 7 33656340 email: f.menezes@uq.edu.au

More information

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with Increasing Returns to Scale Abhijit Sengupta and Yair Tauman February 6, 24 Abstract We consider a Cournot Oligopoly market of firms possessing increasing

More information

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing Jianwei Huang & Lin Gao Network Communications and Economics Lab (NCEL) Information Engineering Department The Chinese University of Hong Kong Huang

More information

University of Kent. Department of Economics Discussion Papers

University of Kent. Department of Economics Discussion Papers University of Kent Department of Economics Discussion Papers R&D Spillovers, Concentration and Market Performance. Anna Stepanova February 2009 KDPE 0901 R&D Spillovers, Concentration and Market Performance.

More information

Collaborative Network Formation in Spatial Oligopolies

Collaborative Network Formation in Spatial Oligopolies Collaborative Network Formation in Spatial Oligopolies 1 Shaun Lichter, Terry Friesz, and Christopher Griffin arxiv:1108.4114v1 [math.oc] 20 Aug 2011 Abstract Recently, it has been shown that networks

More information

Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership

Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership Kazuhiko Kato and Leonard F.S. Wang December 29, 2012 Abstract The paper compares an emission tax and an emission quota in a

More information

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Yongmin Chen and David Sappington University of Colorado and University of Florida February 2016 1 / 32 1. Introduction Patent policy: patent protection

More information

International R&D Collaboration Networks

International R&D Collaboration Networks International R&D Collaboration Networks Huasheng Song CORE, Université catholique de Louvain. Vincent Vannetelbosch FNRS and CORE, Université catholique de Louvain. May 2005 Abstract We reconsider Goyal

More information

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly Daisuke Hirata Graduate School of Economics, University of Tokyo March 2008 Abstract This paper investigates a simultaneous move capacity constrained price competition

More information

On the relation between Sion s minimax theorem and existence of Nash equilibrium in asymmetric multi-players zero-sum game with only one alien

On the relation between Sion s minimax theorem and existence of Nash equilibrium in asymmetric multi-players zero-sum game with only one alien arxiv:10607253v1 [econem] 17 Jun 201 On the relation between Sion s i theorem and existence of Nash equilibrium in asymmetric multi-players zero-sum game with only one alien Atsuhiro Satoh Faculty of Economics

More information

Green Technology and Optimal Emissions Taxation

Green Technology and Optimal Emissions Taxation Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Working Papers 6-2014 Green Technology and Optimal Emissions Taxation Stuart McDonald School of Economics, The Universty of Queensland Joanna Poyago-Theotoky School of Economics,

More information

Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) -

Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) - Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) - What is the old empirical IO? The old empirical IO refers to studies that tried to draw inferences about the relationship

More information

Market Power. Economics II: Microeconomics. December Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39

Market Power. Economics II: Microeconomics. December Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39 Market Power Economics II: Microeconomics VŠE Praha December 2009 Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39 Microeconomics Consumers: Firms: People. Households. Monopoly. Oligopoly Now Perfect Competition.

More information

Mixed duopolies with advance production

Mixed duopolies with advance production Mixed duopolies with advance production Tamás László Balogh Department of Economic Analysis and Business Informatics, University of Debrecen and Attila Tasnádi MTA-BCE Lendület Strategic Interactions Research

More information

Pollution Tax and Social Welfare in Oligopoly. Asymmetric Taxation on Identical Polluters

Pollution Tax and Social Welfare in Oligopoly. Asymmetric Taxation on Identical Polluters Pollution Tax and Social Welfare in Oligopoly Asymmetric Taxation on Identical Polluters Satoshi HONMA Abstract We study asymmetric pollution taxation on identical polluting oligopolists engaged in Cournot

More information

INVESTMENT EFFICIENCY AND PRODUCT MARKET COMPETITION

INVESTMENT EFFICIENCY AND PRODUCT MARKET COMPETITION INVESTMENT EFFICIENCY AND PRODUCT MARKET COMPETITION Neal M. Stoughton WU-Vienna University of Economics and Business Kit Pong Wong University of Hong Kong Long Yi Hong Kong Baptist University QUESTION

More information

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS 8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS We have studied competitive markets where there are a large number of rms and each rm takes market prices as given. When a market contain only a few relevant rms, rms may

More information

Retailer s product line choice with manufacturer s multi-channel marketing

Retailer s product line choice with manufacturer s multi-channel marketing Retailer s product line choice with manufacturer s multi-channel marketing Cong Pan Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University pge042pc@student.econ.osaka-u.ac.jp June 15, 2016 Cong Pan (Osaka University)

More information

Regulation, Free-Riding Incentives, and Investment in R&D with Spillovers

Regulation, Free-Riding Incentives, and Investment in R&D with Spillovers Regulation, Free-Riding Incentives, and Investment in R&D with Spillovers John Strandholm, Ana Espinola-Arredondo, and Felix Munoz-Garcia School of Economic Sciences Washington State University Pullman,

More information

Volume 29, Issue 3. Strategic delegation and market competitiveness

Volume 29, Issue 3. Strategic delegation and market competitiveness Volume 29, Issue Strategic delegation and market competitiveness Caterina Colombo Università di Ferrara Alessandra Chirco Università del Salento Marcella Scrimitore Università del Salento Abstract Within

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 More on strategic games and extensive games with perfect information Block 2 Jun 12, 2016 Food for thought LUPI Many players

More information

A Stackelberg Game Model of Dynamic Duopolistic Competition with Sticky Prices. Abstract

A Stackelberg Game Model of Dynamic Duopolistic Competition with Sticky Prices. Abstract A Stackelberg Game Model of Dynamic Duopolistic Competition with Sticky Prices Kenji Fujiwara School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University Abstract We develop the following Stackelberg game model of

More information

R&D Collaboration in Collusive Networks

R&D Collaboration in Collusive Networks R&D Collaboration in Collusive Networks Gizem Korkmaz European University Institute December, 2011 Market Sharing Agreements In recent years, the scope for explicit or implicit market sharing agreements

More information

Relative Profit Maximization and Bertrand Equilibrium with Convex Cost Functions

Relative Profit Maximization and Bertrand Equilibrium with Convex Cost Functions Vol. 8, 2014-34 October 27, 2014 http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2014-34 Relative Profit Maximization and Bertrand Equilibrium with Convex Cost Functions Atsuhiro Satoh and Yasuhito Tanaka

More information

Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly. Abstract Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly Yasuo Sanjo Graduate School of Economics, Nagoya University Abstract We investigate a mixed duopoly market by introducing quality choice

More information

The Impact of Organizer Market Structure on Participant Entry Behavior in a Multi-Tournament Environment

The Impact of Organizer Market Structure on Participant Entry Behavior in a Multi-Tournament Environment The Impact of Organizer Market Structure on Participant Entry Behavior in a Multi-Tournament Environment Timothy Mathews and Soiliou Daw Namoro Abstract. A model of two tournaments, each with a field of

More information

Among the available options: horizontal separation (HS) and vertical separation (VS)

Among the available options: horizontal separation (HS) and vertical separation (VS) Among the available options: horizontal separation (HS) and vertical separation (VS) Horizontal separation (or systems competition per Pittman 2011) Inter-system competition between vertically integrated

More information

Cooperation, R&D Spillovers and Antitrust Policy

Cooperation, R&D Spillovers and Antitrust Policy Cooperation, R&D Spillovers and Antitrust Policy Ángel L. López y Xavier Vives z September 2014 Abstract We consider a model of process (cost-reducing) R&D investments with spillovers in Cournot oligopoly,

More information

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective Alex Possajennikov University of Nottingham January 2012 Abstract Suppose that in aggregative games, in which a player s payoff

More information

EconS Sequential Competition

EconS Sequential Competition EconS 425 - Sequential Competition Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 47 A Warmup 1 x i x j (x

More information

CSR as a bribe to a government

CSR as a bribe to a government CSR as a bribe to a government Taku Masuda 1 Kosuke Hirose 2 PRELIMINARY. ANY COMMENTS APPRECIATED. 1 Introduction The rationale behind partial privatization of public enterprises or social responsibility

More information

Static Models of Oligopoly

Static Models of Oligopoly Static Models of Oligopoly Cournot and Bertrand Models Mateusz Szetela 1 1 Collegium of Economic Analysis Warsaw School of Economics 3 March 2016 Outline 1 Introduction Game Theory and Oligopolies 2 The

More information

Cartel Stability in a Dynamic Oligopoly with Sticky Prices

Cartel Stability in a Dynamic Oligopoly with Sticky Prices Cartel Stability in a Dynamic Oligopoly with Sticky Prices Hassan Benchekroun and Licun Xue y McGill University and CIREQ, Montreal This version: September 2005 Abstract We study the stability of cartels

More information

Game theory lecture 4. September 24, 2012

Game theory lecture 4. September 24, 2012 September 24, 2012 Finding Nash equilibrium Best-response or best-reply functions. We introduced Nash-equilibrium as a profile of actions (an action for each player) such that no player has an incentive

More information

Mergers, investments and demand expansion

Mergers, investments and demand expansion 17 880 December 2017 Mergers, investments and demand expansion Marc Bourreau and Bruno Jullien Mergers, investments and demand expansion Marc Bourreau and Bruno Jullien December 2017 Abstract In this paper,

More information

A theory of recommended price dispersion

A theory of recommended price dispersion A theory of recommended price dispersion Marco Haan Pim Heijnen Martin Obradovits January 3, 017 WORK IN PROGRESS DO NOT CITE Abstract This paper contributes to the theory of recommended retail prices

More information

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games 1/10 Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games May 4, 2014 2/10 Outline 1 Bertrand Market Game 2 Bertrand Paradox 3 Asymmetric Firms 3/10 Bertrand Duopoly Market Game Discontinuous Payoff Functions (1 p

More information

Regulation, Free-Riding Incentives, and Investment in R&D with Spillovers

Regulation, Free-Riding Incentives, and Investment in R&D with Spillovers Regulation, Free-Riding Incentives, and Investment in R&D with Spillovers John C. Strandholm George Dean Johnson, Jr. College of Business and Economics University of South Carolina Upstate Spartanburg,

More information

Revealed Preference Tests of the Cournot Model

Revealed Preference Tests of the Cournot Model Andres Carvajal, Rahul Deb, James Fenske, and John K.-H. Quah Department of Economics University of Toronto Introduction Cournot oligopoly is a canonical noncooperative model of firm competition. In this

More information

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction Susumu Sato July 9, 2018 I study a monopoly regulation in the setting where consumers can engage in demand-reducing investments. I first

More information

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility Toker Doganoglu and Julian Wright July 19, 2005 We would like to thank two anonymous referees and our editor, Simon Anderson, for their very helpful

More information

THE EXISTENCE OF EQUILIBRIUM IN A DIFFERENTIATED DUOPOLY WITH NETWORK EXTERNALITIES*

THE EXISTENCE OF EQUILIBRIUM IN A DIFFERENTIATED DUOPOLY WITH NETWORK EXTERNALITIES* Vol. 56, No. 1, March 005 TE EXISTENCE OF EQUILIBRIUM IN A DIFFERENTIATED DUOPOLY WIT NETWORK EXTERNALITIES* By LUCA LAMBERTINI and RAIMONDELLO ORSINI Università degli Studi di Bologna, Italy The existence

More information

On Competitive and Welfare Effects of Cross-Holdings with Product Differentiation

On Competitive and Welfare Effects of Cross-Holdings with Product Differentiation On Competitive and Welfare Effects of Cross-Holdings with Product Differentiation Teng Wang October 26, 2017 Abstract Competitive implications of cross-holdings have been extensively analyzed in the literature.

More information

Heterogenous Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Behavioral Uncertainty

Heterogenous Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Behavioral Uncertainty Heterogenous Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Behavioral Uncertainty Akio Matsumoto Department of Systems Industrial Engineering Univesity of Arizona, USA Department of Economics Chuo University,

More information

Oligopoly with Hyperbolic Demand: ADifferential Game Approach 1

Oligopoly with Hyperbolic Demand: ADifferential Game Approach 1 Oligopoly with Hyperbolic Demand: ADifferential Game Approach 1 Luca Lambertini Department of Economics, University of Bologna Strada Maggiore 45, 40125 Bologna, Italy Fax: +39-051-2092664; lamberti@spbo.unibo.it;

More information

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

Trade policy III: Export subsidies The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies - wiiw June 25, 2015 Overview Overview 1 1 Under perfect competition lead to welfare loss 2 Effects depending on market structures 1 Subsidies to

More information

Profitability of price and quantity strategies in a duopoly with vertical product differentiation

Profitability of price and quantity strategies in a duopoly with vertical product differentiation Economic Theory 7, 693 700 (200) Profitability of price quantity strategies in a duopoly with vertical product differentiation Yasuhito Tanaka Faculty of Law, Chuo University, 742-, Higashinakano, Hachioji,

More information

A Summary of Economic Methodology

A Summary of Economic Methodology A Summary of Economic Methodology I. The Methodology of Theoretical Economics All economic analysis begins with theory, based in part on intuitive insights that naturally spring from certain stylized facts,

More information

Knowledge Sharing and Competition in a Bio-tech Consortium

Knowledge Sharing and Competition in a Bio-tech Consortium Knowledge Sharing and Competition in a Bio-tech Consortium Hervouet Adrien Trommetter Michel March 17, 2017 Very Preliminary Abstract This article deals with a current research project, namely the Amaizing

More information

Equal treatment and socially optimal R&D in duopoly with one-way spillovers

Equal treatment and socially optimal R&D in duopoly with one-way spillovers Received: 29 August 2017 Accepted: 8 October 2017 DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12280 ARTICLE Equal treatment and socially optimal R&D in duopoly with one-way spillovers Charlène Cosandier 1 Giuseppe De Feo 2 Małgorzata

More information

Optimal Objective Function

Optimal Objective Function Optimal Objective Function Junichi Haraguchi Taku Masuda June 5 017 PRELIMINARY. ANY COMMENTS APPRECIATED. 1 Introduction In a framework of industrial organization we basically assume firms objective is

More information

Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous?

Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous? Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous? Paolo G. Garella University of Bologna 14 July 004 Abstract The present note shows that innocuous Minimum Quality Standards, namely standards that

More information

Price vs. Quantity in Oligopoly Games

Price vs. Quantity in Oligopoly Games Price vs. Quantity in Oligopoly Games Attila Tasnádi Department of Mathematics, Corvinus University of Budapest, H-1093 Budapest, Fővám tér 8, Hungary July 29, 2005. Appeared in the International Journal

More information

ECO 2901 EMPIRICAL INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION

ECO 2901 EMPIRICAL INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION ECO 2901 EMPIRICAL INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION Lecture 7 & 8: Models of Competition in Prices & Quantities Victor Aguirregabiria (University of Toronto) Toronto. Winter 2018 Victor Aguirregabiria () Empirical

More information

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016 Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016 1 Modelling incomplete information So far, we have studied games in which information was complete,

More information

Asymptotic relations in Cournot s game

Asymptotic relations in Cournot s game MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Asymptotic relations in Cournot s game Marco Guerrazzi Departmento of Economics, University of Genoa November 0 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/476/ MPRA Paper

More information

Bertrand-Edgeworth competition with substantial product dierentiation

Bertrand-Edgeworth competition with substantial product dierentiation Bertrand-Edgeworth competition with substantial product dierentiation Robert Somogyi Preliminary version August 21, 2013 Abstract Since Kreps and Scheinkman's seminal article (1983) a large number of papers

More information

The Economics of E-commerce and Technology

The Economics of E-commerce and Technology The Economics of E-commerce and Technology Industry Analysis 1 9/25/16 Industry Profits } In Econ 11, Economic Profits = 0 } In reality, many industries have much higher profits: 2 9/25/16 Industry Analysis

More information

Oligopoly. Firm s Profit Maximization Firm i s profit maximization problem: Static oligopoly model with n firms producing homogenous product.

Oligopoly. Firm s Profit Maximization Firm i s profit maximization problem: Static oligopoly model with n firms producing homogenous product. Oligopoly Static oligopoly model with n firms producing homogenous product. Firm s Profit Maximization Firm i s profit maximization problem: Max qi P(Q)q i C i (q i ) P(Q): inverse demand curve: p = P(Q)

More information

EconS Oligopoly - Part 2

EconS Oligopoly - Part 2 EconS 305 - Oligopoly - Part 2 Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu November 29, 2015 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 32 November 29, 2015 1 / 28 Introduction Last time,

More information

Information Sharing in Private Value Lottery Contest

Information Sharing in Private Value Lottery Contest Information Sharing in Private Value Lottery Contest Zenan Wu Jie Zheng May 4, 207 Abstract We investigate players incentives to disclose information on their private valuations of the prize ahead of a

More information

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 W2005

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 W2005 GS/ECON 500 Answers to Assignment 3 W005 Q. What are the market price, and aggregate quantity sold, in long run equilibrium in a perfectly competitive market f which the demand function has the equation

More information

ABSORPTIVE CAPACITY, R&D SPILLOVERS, AND PUBLIC POLICY* Dermot Leahy University College Dublin. and. J. Peter Neary University of Oxford and CEPR

ABSORPTIVE CAPACITY, R&D SPILLOVERS, AND PUBLIC POLICY* Dermot Leahy University College Dublin. and. J. Peter Neary University of Oxford and CEPR ABSORPTIVE CAPACITY, R&D SPILLOVERS, AND PUBLIC POLICY* Dermot Leahy University College Dublin and J. Peter Neary University of Oxford and CEPR 23 March 2007 Abstract Empirical evidence strongly suggests

More information

Ranking Bertrand, Cournot and Supply Function Equilibria in Oligopoly

Ranking Bertrand, Cournot and Supply Function Equilibria in Oligopoly ISSN 2282-6483 Ranking Bertrand, Cournot and Supply Function Equilibria in Oligopoly Flavio Delbono Luca Lambertini Quaderni - Working Paper DSE N 1000 Ranking Bertrand, Cournot and Supply Function Equilibria

More information

Industrial Organization

Industrial Organization Industrial Organization Lecture Notes Sérgio O. Parreiras Fall, 2017 Outline Mathematical Toolbox Intermediate Microeconomic Theory Revision Perfect Competition Monopoly Oligopoly Mathematical Toolbox

More information

Oligopoly. Oligopoly. Xiang Sun. Wuhan University. March 23 April 6, /149

Oligopoly. Oligopoly. Xiang Sun. Wuhan University. March 23 April 6, /149 Oligopoly Xiang Sun Wuhan University March 23 April 6, 2016 1/149 Outline 1 Introduction 2 Game theory 3 Oligopoly models 4 Cournot competition Two symmetric firms Two asymmetric firms Many symmetric firms

More information

No Information Sharing in Oligopoly: The Case of Price Competition with Cost Uncertainty

No Information Sharing in Oligopoly: The Case of Price Competition with Cost Uncertainty No Information Sharing in Oligopoly: The Case of Price Competition with Cost Uncertainty Stephan O. Hornig and Manfred Stadler* Abstract We show that concealing cost information is a dominant strategy

More information

Informative Advertising with Spillover Effects

Informative Advertising with Spillover Effects Informative Advertising with Spillover Effects Hiroyuki Nakata December 4, 006 Abstract This paper studies the effects of advertising in a Bertrand duopoly model with informative advertising, which is

More information