Mathematical Economics Part 2

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Mathematical Economics Part 2"

Transcription

1 An Introduction to Mathematical Economics Part Loglinear Publishing Michael Sampson

2 Copyright 00 Michael Sampson. Loglinear Publications: Terms of Use This document is distributed "AS IS" and with no warranties of any kind, whether express or implied. Until November, 00 you are hereby given permission to print one () and only one hardcopy version free of charge from the electronic version of this document (i.e., the pdf file) provided that:. The printed version is for your personal use only.. You make no further copies from the hardcopy version. In particular no photocopies, electronic copies or any other form of reproduction. 3. You agree not to ever sell the hardcopy version to anyone else. 4. You agree that if you ever give the hardcopy version to anyone else that this page, in particular the Copyright Notice and the Terms of Use are included and the person to whom the copy is given accepts these Terms of Use. Until November, 00 you are hereby given permission to make (and if you wish sell) an unlimited number of copies on paper only from the electronic version (i.e., the pdf file) of this document or from a printed copy of the electronic version of this document provided that:. You agree to pay a royalty of either $3.00 Canadian or $.00 US per copy to the author within 60 days of making the copies or to destroy any copies after 60 days for which you have not paid the royalty of $3.00 Canadian or $.00 US per copy. Payment can be made either by cheque or money order and should be sent to the author at: Professor Michael Sampson Department of Economics Concordia University 455 de Maisonneuve Blvd W. Montreal, Quebec Canada, H3G M8. If you intend to make five or more copies, or if you can reasonably expect that five or more copies of the text will be made then you agree to notify the author before making any copies by at: sampson@loglinear.com or by fax at You agree to include on each paper copy of this document and at the same page number as this page on the electronic version of the document: ) the above Copyright Notice, ) the URL: and the address sampson@loglinear.com. You may then if you wish remove this Terms of Use from the paper copies you make.

3 Contents 0. Preface... vi Total Di erentials. EndogenousandExogenousVariables.... StructuralandReducedFormsofaModel..... TheStructuralFormofaModel..... TheReducedFormofaModel ImplicitandExplicitFunctions CalculatingDerivatives TotalDi erentialsforbeginners A Recipe for Calculating dy dx TotalDi erentialsforintermediates A Recipe j Example:ASimpleLinearFunction Example Example 3: The Bivariate Normal Density Example4:LabourDemand TotalDi erentialsforexperts SystemsofImplicitFunctions A Recipe j Example Example : Supply and Demand I Example 3: Supply and Demand II Example 4: The IS=LM Model TotalDi erentialsandoptimization AGeneralDiscussion A Quick Derivation of the Main Principle Pro tmaximization ConstrainedOptimization Utility Maximization CostMinimization i

4 CONTENTS ii The Envelope Theorem 38. UnconstrainedOptimization Pro t Maximization in the Short-Run I EnvelopeTheoremI Pro t Maximization in the Short-Run II Pro tmaximizationinthelong-run EnvelopeTheoremII ARecipeforUnconstrainedOptimization ThePro tfunction HomogeneousFunctions ConcavityandConvexity Concavity, Convexity and Homogeneity of f (x) PropertiesofthePro tfunction SomeSymmetryResults ConstrainedOptimization Envelope Theorem III: Constrained Optimization A Recipe for Constrained Optimization Concavity, Convexity and Homogeneity of f (x) CostMinimization PropertiesoftheCostFunction Utility Maximization ExpenditureMinimization Integration and Random Variables Introduction DiscreteSummation De nitions Example : P n i= ax i Example : P n i= (ax i + by i ) Example 3: P n i= (ax i + b) Example 4: P n i= (ax i + b) Example 5: P n i= Xi ¹X = ManipulatingtheSigmaNotation Example : P n i= (ax i + by i ) Example : P n i= (ax i + b) Xi X ¹ 3..0 Example 3: P n i= Integration The Fundamental Theorem of Integral Calculus Example : R 0 x dx Example : R 5 0 e x dx IntegrationbyParts Example : R 4 0 xe x dx Example : (n) IntegrationasSummation R b a dx asalinearoperator... 89

5 CONTENTS iii Example : R b a (cf (x)+dg (x)) dx Example : R b a (f (x)+d) dx RandomVariables Introduction DiscreteRandomVariables TheBernoulliDistribution TheBinomialDistribution ThePoissonDistribution ContinuousRandomVariables TheUniformDistribution TheStandardNormalDistribution TheNormalDistribution TheChi-SquaredDistribution The Student s t Distribution: The F Distribution: ExpectedValues E [X] fordiscreterandomvariables Example:DieRoll Example:BinomialDistribution E [X] for Continuous Random Variables Example : The Uniform Distribution TheStandardNormalDistribution E []asalinearoperator The Rules for E h [] Example : E (3X +4Y ) i... h Example : E (3X +4) i Example 3: X» N ¹; ¾ Variances De nition SomeResultsforVariances Example:DieRoll Example:UniformDistribution Example 3: The Normal Distribution Covariances De nitions Independence ResultsforCovariances LinearCombinationsofRandomVariables Linear Combinations of Two Random Variables TheCapitalAssetPricingModel(CAPM) AnExample Sums of Uncorrelated Random Variables AnExample...7

6 CONTENTS iv TheSampleMean The Mean and Variance of the Binomial Distribution The Linear Regression Model for Beginners Linear Combinations of Correlated Random Variables TheLinearRegressionModelforExperts Dynamics Introduction Trigonometry DegreesandRadians The Functions cos (x) and sin (x) The Functions tan (x) and arctan (x) ComplexNumbers Introduction ArithmeticwithComplexNumbers Complexconjugates: TheAbsoluteValueofaComplexNumber The Argument of a Complex Number The Polar Form of a Complex Number DeMoivre stheorem Euler sformula When does (a + bi) n! 0 as n!? First-OrderLinearDi erenceequations De nition Example Stability AMacroeconomicExample TheCob-WebModel Second-OrderLinearDi erenceequations The Behavior of Y t withcomplexroots ExampleRealRootsandStable ExampleRealRootsandUnstable Example3ComplexRootsandStable Example 4 Complex Roots and Unstable AMacroeconomicExample First-Order Di erential Equations De nitions The Case where b = The Case where b 6= Example: Example Second-OrderDi erentialequations Solution Stability with Real Roots

7 CONTENTS v Stability with Complex Roots Example:StablewithRealRoots Example : Unstable with Real Roots Example 3: Stable with Complex Roots Example4:UnstablewithComplexRoots...79

8 CONTENTS vi 0. Preface Thanks go to my Economics 36 students from the Winter 999 and Winter 000 semesters for working so hard on the rst and second versions of these lecture notes. I would in particular like to thank Tamarha Louis-Charles, Dana Al-Aghbar, Christopher Martin and Samnang Om for pointing out many typos and errors.

9 Chapter Total Di erentials. Endogenous and Exogenous Variables In economics we mostly work with mathematical models. By their very nature these models contain variables which can be divided into two classes: ) endogenous variables and ) exogenous variables. Endogenous variables (from Greek, endo: within and genous: born hence born or generated from within the model) are those variables which the model attempts to explain. In a supply and demand model, for example, both the equilibrium price P and quantity Q are determined by the model, that is at the intersection of the supply and demand curves. They are therefore endogenous variables. Exogenous variables (from Greek, exo: from outside, hence generated from outside the model) are those variables whose determination the model says nothing about, but which nevertheless in uence the endogenous variables. An example of an exogenous variable in a supply and demand model would be the weather. Bad weather shifts the supply curve of say oranges to the left causing P to go up and Q to go down. Weather therefore in uences P and Q but P and Q do not (presumably) in uence the weather. A supply and demand model says nothing about how the weather is determined. Often policy variables such as taxes, government expenditure or the money supply are exogenous variables. Mathematically you can think of the exogenous variables as the x 0 s or the independent variables, while endogenous variables are the dependent variables or the y 0 s: Typically in economics we do not use x 0 s and y 0 s in our notation and so you willoftenneedtothink carefully about what are the exogenous variables and what are the endogenous variables in any particular model.

10 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS. Structural and Reduced Forms of a Model.. The Structural Form of a Model When we rst write down an economic model, that is before doing any complicated derivations, it is often the case that the endogenous variables y =[y i ] (say an n vector) and exogenous variables x =[x i ] (say an m vector) are all jumbled and appear on both sides of the = sign as: M (y; x) =N (y; x) : This form of the model is often referred to as the structural form of the model since it is in this form that the basic assumptions (or structure) of the model are most apparent... The Reduced Form of a Model In economics we are often interested in how changes the x 0 s; the exogenous variables a ect the y 0 s; the endogenous variables. For example we might ask how increasing the tax rate t (an exogenous variable) a ects the price P or quantity Q (endogenous variables). It is often hard with the structural form of the model to perform such experiments. The problem is that the y 0 s and x 0 s are all jumbled together. It would instead be more useful to have the reduced form of the model which is: y = h (x) so that y is by itself on the left-hand side and some function of x is on the right-hand side. Given knowledge of the form of h (x) we can consider any number of changes in the x 0 s and then see how the y 0 s change. An Example Suppose y is the number of workers that a rm hires, x is the price of the good that the rm sells, and x is the nominal wage. From a model we nd that the marginal revenue of hiring an extra worker is: while the marginal cost is: M (y; x ;x )=x y N (y; x ;x )=x y : Equating marginal revenue M and marginal cost N we arrive at a structural model: M (y; x ;x )=N (y; x ;x ) or x y = x y :

11 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 3 To get the reduced form we need to get y alone on the left-hand side. In this case this is not hard to do. By a little algebra we nd that: y = h (x ;x )= x : x Suppose x = x =: We then know that y =: Consider three experiments: ) doubling x while keeping x xed, ) doubling x while keeping x xed, and 3) doubling both x and x : We see from the reduced form that the rst experiment results in doubling y to ; the second experiment results in halving y to ; while in the third experiment nothing happens to y:..3 Implicit and Explicit Functions Closely related to the notion of structural and reduced forms are implicit and explicit functions. De nition An implicit function is any function written as: g (y; x) =0: so that both the y 0 s and x 0 s appear jumbled together on the left-hand side and zero is on the right-hand side. Given the structural form of a model it is very easy to rewrite it as an implicit function. Thus from the structural form M (y; x) =N (y;x) we can nd the implicit function g (y;x) as: g (y; x) =M (y; x) N (y; x) =0: Using the example of: M (y; x ;x )=x y and N (y; x ;x )=x y we have: g (y; x ;x )=x y x y =0: De nition An explicit function unscrambles the y 0 s and x 0 s so that y is alone on the left-hand side as: y = h (x) : Thus an explicit function and the reduced form are essentially the same thing. Given an explicit function or reduced form it is always possible to write it as an implicit function as: g (y; x) =y h (x) =0: However, it is often impossible to nd an explicit function or the reduced form from an implicit function or structural model.

12 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 4 For example given the implicit function: g (y; x) =y ln (y) ln (x) =0;x> there is no way of getting y alone on the left-hand side. The best we could do is: or y ln (y) =ln(x) y y = x: Nevertheless, g (y; x) = y ln (y) ln (x) = 0 is a perfectly respectable function. We can for example show that it is increasing and concave. We could even plot it as shown below..8.6 y x g (y; x) =y ln (y) ln (x) =0for x>..4 Calculating Derivatives In economics we are often interested in calculating the partial j which tells us the relationship between the j th exogenous variable and the i th endogenous variable when all other exogenous variables are held constant. This corresponds to the experiment of keeping all other exogenous variables except x j constant, changing x j by a small amount and seeing how much y j changes. De nition j > 0 then a positive relationship exists between x i and y j ; that is, an increase (decrease) in x j will result in an increase (decrease) in y i : De nition j < 0 then a negative relationship exists between x i and y j ; that is, an increase (decrease) in x j will result in an decrease (increase ) in y i :

13 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 5 In the example above where we found that y = h (x ;x )= x x we > 0; = (x ) < 0: Thus there is a positive relationship between x and y and a negative relationship between x and y: Since it is often not possible to nd the reduced form of the model, that is, we often cannot unscramble the model enough to get it where y appears alone on the left-hand side and h (x) appears on the right-hand side, we cannot always j in the usual manner. Fortunately, no matter how jumbled up the structural form of the model or the implicit function, it is still possible j indirectly using total di erentials. In what follows we will learn this technique starting with the simplest cases and building up to the more general. We begin with beginners total di erentials where there is one exogenous variable x and one endogenous variable y: We then move on to intermediate total di erentials where there are many exogenous variables but still only one endogenous variable. Finally we move on to advanced total di erentials where there are both many endogenous and exogenous variables..3 Total Di erentials for Beginners Suppose we are given an implicit function: g (y; x) =0 where both y and x are scalars so that there is one endogenous variable y and one exogenous variable x: Under one condition this de nes an explicit function: y = h (x) : The reason we know this is the Implicit Function Theorem that: which states Theorem 5 Implicit Function Theorem I: The explicit function h (x) is guaranteed to exist as long (y; x) 6= The problem then is to calculate: dy dx = h0 (x) : We do this by taking the total di erential of g (y; x) which is:

14 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 6 De nition 6 The total di erential is de ned (y; x) (y; x) dx The total di erential can be used to calculate dy dx using the following recipe:.3. A Recipe for Calculating dy dx Step. If it is not already clear to you, identify the endogenous variable y and the exogenous variable x in your model. Step. If the structural model is not written as an implicit function of the form g (y; x) =0; rewriteitsothatitisinthisform. Step 3. Take the partial derivative of g (y; x) with respect to y and call this a: Thus: : Verify that a 6= 0which insures that the explicit function exists by the Implicit Function Theorem. Multiply a by dy to get: a dy: Step 4. Take the partial derivative of g (y; x) with respect to x and call this b: Thus: : Multiply b by dx to get: b dx: Step 5. Add the results of steps 3 and 4 together and set them equal to zero to get the total di erential: a dy + b dx =0: Step 6. Solvefortheratio dy dx to get: dy dx = b a or alternatively using the de nition of a and b dy dx Note that if a =0this ratio would be unde ned. Example : A Simple Linear Function Let us begin with an easy structural model written 3Q 4R =9: where Q is say the quantity of apples produced in an orchard and R is the amount of rainfall.

15 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 7 Applying Step in the recipe Q is the endogenous variable and R is the exogenous variable. This follows from the common sense notion that while rainfall might a ect apple production, apple production is unlikely to a ect rainfall. Applying Step we can write this as an implicit function by putting the 9 on the other side of the equal sign to get: since: g (Q; R) =3Q 4R 9=0: From steps 3; 4 and 5; the total di erential for g (Q; R) is: a (Q; 3dQ 4dR =0 (Q; = 4: Note that a =36= 0and so the explicit function exists by the Implicit Function Theorem. Solving for dq dr from the total di erential it then follows that: dq dr = 4 3 : This is the same answer we would get from working with the explicit form of the function or the reduced form. We obtain this by solving g (Q; R) = 3Q 4R 9=0for Q to obtain: from which it easily follows that: Example Consider the implicit function: Q = 4 3 R +3 dq dr = 4 3 : g (y; x) =ln(y)+ x + ln (¼) =0: This can be written explicitly or as a reduced form as: y = h (x) = p e x ¼ which is the standard normal density. From h (x) we can directly calculate h 0 (x) as: dy dx = x p e x = xy: ¼ {z } =y

16 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 8 Let us obtain now attempt to obtain the derivative via the total di erential. Using Steps 3, 4, and 5 we obtain y and b = x so that the total di erential is: dy + xdx =0: y Solving for dy dx we then get: dy dx = xy: Example 3 Suppose we were given a structural equation of the form: y y = x: Here from the notation y is the endogenous variable and x is the exogenous variable. From Step ; by taking the ln ( ) of both sides we can write this as an implicit function: g (y; x) =y ln (y) ln (x) =0 which we have already seen cannot be written as an explicit function y = h (x) : From Steps 3; 4 and 5 the total di erential of g (y; x) is: since: Solving for dy dx : a (y; ( + ln (y)) dy dx =0: x =+ln(y) ;b= dy dx = x ( + ln (y)) (y; = x : We can use this result to show that 0 < dy dx < for x>and hence a positive relationship exists between x and y: This follows since: x>=) ln (y) y =ln(x) > 0 implies that y>since if y<then ln (y) < 0: Therefore from x> and ( + ln (y)) > we have x>=) 0 < dy dx = x ( + ln (y)) < : Note that we could have just as correctly used g (y; x) =y y x =0; that is there are many di erent correct ways of writing down an implicit function.

17 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 9 As an exercise di erentiate this one more time with respect to x and show that: d µ y dx = x ( + ln (y)) x + dy < 0 y ( + ln (y)) dx so that the function is concave as the plot above illustrates. Example 4: The Demand for Labour in the Short-Run Suppose a rm facing a short-run production function Q = f (L) where f 0 (L) > 0 and f 00 (L) < 0 and where Q is output and L is the amount of labour. If w = W P is the real wage then the rm will chose that L which satis es: f 0 (L )=w: Here w is the exogenous variable and L is the endogenous variable. We can write this structural form of the model as an implicit function as: g (L ;w)=f 0 (L ) w =0: This de nes the labour demand function or the explicit function or the reduced form as: since The total di erential is: a (L L = L (w) : f 00 (L ) dl dw =0 = f 00 (L ) (L = : Note that a<0 and so the explicit function exists. Note that the coe cient on dl is negative since the diminishing marginal product of labour implies that: f 00 (L ) < 0. Solving for the ratio dl dw we nd that: dl dw = f 00 (L ) < 0 and so the labour demand curve is downward sloping..4 Total Di erentials for Intermediates Consider now an implicit function were there are m exogenous variables x ;x ;:::x m (which we may write as an m vector x) and one endogenous variable y. The implicit function is now written as: g (y; x ;x ;:::x m )=0

18 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 0 which determines the explicit function: y = h (x ;x ;:::x m ) as long as the Implicit Function Theorem is satis ed which states that: Theorem 7 Implicit Function Theorem II: The explicit function y = h (x ;x ;:::x m ) is guaranteed to exist as long as We wish to (y; x ;x ;:::x @x j 6= 0: in order to determine how a change in the j th exogenous variable x j will a ect the endogenous variable y. To do this from the implicit function g (y; x) =0we calculate the total di erential de ned by: De nition 8 The total di erential of g (y; x) =0is given by: a dy + b dx + b dx + + b m dx m =0 where a; b ;b ;:::b m are de ned below in the following recipe:.4. A Recipe j We proceed as follows: Step. If it is not already clear to you, identify the endogenous variable y and the exogenous variables x ;x ;:::x m in your model. Step. Write the structural form of the model as an implicit function of the form: g (y; x ;x ;:::x m )=0: This generally means just collecting all terms on the left-hand side of the structural model and setting them equal to zero. Step 3. Take the partial derivative of g (y; x) with respect to y and call this a: Make sure that a 6= 0so that the explicit function exists by the Implicit Function Theorem. Multiply a by dy to get: a dy: Step 4. Take the partial derivative of g (y; x) with respect to x and call this b : Multiply b by dx to get b dx : Repeat this for x ;x 3 ;:::x m and add them together to get: b dx + b x + + b m dx m :

19 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS Step 5. Add the results of steps 3 and 4 together and set them equal to zero to get the total di erential: a dy + b dx + b x + + b m dx m =0: Step 6. To get the j set all dx 0 s equal to zero except dx j ; and then replacing the remaining d 0 s in the total di erential 0 s: Thus we set dy dx j j and dx i =0for i 6= j in the total di erential to get: Now solve for j : a@y + b j = b j @y.4. Example : A Simple Linear Function Consider the structural model: 3Q 4R 7S =9 where Q is the production of apples, R is rainfall and S is the amount of sunshine. Following Step, Q is the endogenous variable and R and S are the exogenous variables. The structural model can be re-written as an implicit function as: g (Q; R; S) =3Q 4R 7S 9=0: Following Steps 3, 4 and 5 the total di erential is since 3dQ 4dR 7S =0 a (Q; R; (Q; R; S) =3;b = b (Q; R; S) = Suppose we wish : Following step 6 rst set dr =0and then replace the remaining d 0 s 0 s so that: dq and ds We then obtain: 3@Q 7@S =0: :

20 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS Solving for = 7 3 : In this example we could also from the reduced form. From 3Q 4R 7S 9=0you can arrive at the reduced form (or explicit function) as: Q = h (R; S) = 4 3 R S +3 from which it is trivial = 7 3 :.4.3 Example Consider the implicit function: g (y; x ;x )=x y x y =0: We have already seen that this has a reduced form: y = h (x ;x )= x x from which it is easy @x : Let us nd these partial derivatives from the implicit function. The total di erential is: ³ x y 3 + x y dy + y dx y dx =0 since: a = g (y; x ;x b = g (y; x ;x = y b = g (y; x ;x = y : = x y 3 x y set dx =0and replace the remaining d 0 s 0 s so that dy and dx : We then obtain: ³ x y 3 + x + =0:

21 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 3 Solving for @x = y ³ x y 3 + x y As an exercise use the reduced form y = x x to prove that the above is equal to x : set dx =0and replace the remaining d 0 s 0 s to obtain: yields: : ³ x y 3 + x @x = y ³ x y 3 + x y As an exercise use the reduced form y = x is equal to x (x ) : < 0: to prove that the above expression.4.4 Example 3: The Bivariate Normal Density Consider the implicit function: g (y; x ;x )=ln(y)+ x + x +ln(¼) =0 from which we can nd the explicit function: y = h (x ;x )= ¼ e (x +x ) : This is the bivariate standard normal which is plotted below: w x y = h (x ;x )= ¼ e (x +x )

22 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 4 If we start from the explicit function we can = x ¼ e (x ¼ e (x +x ) = x y +x ) = x y: If instead we calculate the total di erential we nd that: y dy + x dx + x dx =0 since a (y; x ;x ) y ; b (y; x ;x ) = x ;b (y; x ;x ) = to obtain: set dy dx and dx =0in the total di erential + =0 so that solving for we = x to obtain: set dy dx and dx =0in the total di erential + =0 so that solving for we = x Example 4: Labour Demand Suppose a rm facing a short-run production function Q = f (L) where Q is output and L is the amount of labour. With price P and nominal wage W, pro ts ¼ as a function of L are given by: ¼ (L) =Pf (L) WL:

23 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 5 The pro t maximizing L then satis es the rst-order condition: ¼ 0 (L )=0=Pf 0 (L ) W with second-order condition: Pf 00 (L ) < 0: Here P and W are the exogenous variables and L is the endogenous variable. Note that the rst-order condition gives us the appropriate implicit function: g (L ;W;P)=Pf 0 (L ) W =0: This de nes the labour demand function or the explicit function or reduced form as: L = L (W; P ) : From the implicit function g (L ;W;P)=0the total di erential is: Pf 00 (L ) dl dw + f 0 (L ) dp =0 since a (L = Pf 00 (L ) ;b (L ;W;P) = b (L ;W;P) = f 0 (L ) Note that the coe cient on dl is negative from the second-order condition; that is a = Pf 00 (L ) < 0. set dp =0in the total di erential and replace the remaining d 0 s 0 s so that dl and dw to get: Pf 00 =0 or Pf 00 (L Dividing both sides and (W; P = Pf 00 (L (W; P )) < 0 and so the labour demand curve is downward sloping. set dw =0in the total di erential and replace the remaining d 0 s 0 s so that dl and dp to get: Pf 00 (L + f 0 (L =0: Solving we = f 0 (L ) Pf 00 (L ) > 0 since f 0 (L ) > 0 (the marginal product of labour is positive) and Pf 00 (L ) < 0 from the second-order conditions.

24 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 6.5 Total Di erentials for Experts.5. Systems of Implicit Functions Suppose we have a model where there are n endogenous variables: y ;y ; y 3 ;:::y n and m exogenous variables x ;x ;:::x m : We can write this more compactly by letting y =[y i ] be an n vector of the endogenous variables and x =[x i ] an m vector of exogenous variables. Suppose you are given n implicit functions: g i (y; x) =0; for i =; ;:::n: This de nes n reduced form or explicit functions given by: y i = h i (x) ; for i =; ;:::n as long as the Implicit Function Theorem is satis ed which states that: Theorem 9 Implicit Function Theorem III: The explicit functions y i = h i (x ;x ;:::x m ) for i =; ;:::n are guaranteed to exist as long as where: A = 6 (y;x) (y;x) det [A] 6= (y;x) n n(y;x) n For example suppose that we have a structural model where apple production Q and honey production Q are related to the amount of rainfall R; sunshine S and temperature T as: 3Q +Q +3S +5T = R 7 Q Q +6R 3T = S +4: Here Q and Q are the endogenous variables and R; S; and T are the exogenous variables. Note that we have two equations and two endogenous variables. This can then be written as two implicit functions as: : g (Q ;Q ;R;S;T) = 3Q +Q R +3S +5T +7=0 g (Q ;Q ;R;S;T) = Q Q +6R +S 3T 4=0: Here: " @g (y;x) # = 3

25 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 7 and 3 det = 8 6= 0 and so the explicit functions: Q = h (R; S; T) Q = h (R; S; T) are guaranteed to exist by the Implicit Function Theorem. We might therefore want ; that is how sunshine a ects honey production. In general we might want j ; in order to determine the nature of the relationship between the j th exogenous variable x j and the i th endogenous variable y i : We do this by calculating the total di erential de ned as De nition 0 The total di erential of g i (y; x) =0for i =; ;:::n is de ned as: Ady + Bdx =0 where: dy = 6 4 dy dy. dy n ;dx= 6 4 dx dx. dx m and A is the n n matrix de ned above and B is an n m matrix given (y;x) m n m The recipe for calculating the total di erential and j is as follows:.5. A Recipe for j Step. Identifythen endogenous variables y ;y ;:::y n and the m exogenous variables x ;x ;:::x m ; in your model.

26 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 8 Step. If the structural model is not written as a system of implicit functions write them in the form: g (y ;y ;:::y n ;x ;x ;:::x m ) = 0; g (y ;y ;:::y n ;x ;x ;:::x m ) = 0;. g n (y ;y ;:::y n ;x ;x ;:::x m ) = 0; Note you should have as many implicit functions as endogenous variables! Step 3. Take the partial derivative of the rst implicit function g (y; x) =0 with respect to y. Call this a so that : Multiply a by dy to get a dy : Continue this with the remaining endogenous variables y ;y 3 ;:::y n and add the results together to obtain: a dy + a dy + + a n dy n : Note that a j is the coe cient on dy j in the rst implicit function. Step 4. Take the partial derivative of g (y; x) with respect to x and call this b : Multiply b by dx to get b dx : Repeat for x ;x ;:::x m to get: b dx + b dx + + b m dx m : Step 5. Add the results of steps 3 and 4 together and set them equal to zero. This gives you the total di erential for the rst implicit function. a dy + a dy + + a n dy n + b dx + b dx + + b m dx m =0 Now repeat this for the second implicit function to get: a dy + a dy + + a n dy n + b dx + b dx + + b m dx m =0 so that a j and b j. Keep doing this for all n implicit equations to obtain n total di erentials: a dy + a dy + + a n dy n + b dx + b dx + + b m dx m = 0 a dy + a dy + + a n dy n + b dx + b dx + + b m dx m = 0. a n dy + a n dy + + a nn dy n + b n dx + b n dx + + b nm dx m = 0 so that a j and b j are the coe cients on dy j and dx j in the i th total di erential: Thus there are n total di erentials, one for each implicit equation. Step 6. j from the total di erential set all dx 0 s equal to zero except dx j and replace all remaining d 0 s 0 s to obtain:

27 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS a n + b j = a n + b j = 0. a + a + + a n + b j = 0: Now put the terms j on the right-hand side to get: a n = b j a n = b j. a + a + + a n = b j or: 6 4 a a a n a a a n a n a n a nn @y n = 6 4 b j b j. b nj 3 7 j: Divide both sides by the j and re-write this in matrix j = b j and b j are n column vectors given j = @x j and b j = 6 4 Note that b j is the j th column of the matrix B: To solve j use Cramer s rule to i = det [A i ( b j j det [A] where A i ( b j ) is the matrix you obtain by replacing the i th column of A with the vector b j : b j b j. b nj :

28 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS Example Given the apple/honey production example above, we have two linear implicit equations: g (Q ;Q ;R;S;T) = 3Q +Q R +3S +5T +7=0 g (Q ;Q ;R;S;T) = Q Q +6R +S 3T 4=0: Suppose we wish : Using Total Di erentials Following steps 3; 4; and 5 we have: a =3;a =; = =3;b =5 so that the total di erential for g (Q ;Q ;R;S;T) is: Similarly since: 3dQ +dq dr +3dS +5dT =0: a =;a =;b = 3 the total di erential for g (Q ;Q ;R;S;T) is: dq dq +6dR +ds 3dT =0: Putting these two total di erentials together and we have: 3dQ +dq dr +3dS +5dT = 0 dq dq +6dR +ds 3dT = 0: from the total di erential set dr = dt =0and replace the remaining d 0 s 0 s so that ds dq and dq to obtain: 3@Q +@Q +3@S +@S = 0 or in matrix =

29 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS Dividing both sides we then = 3 Solving by Cramer s rule then yields: 3 = = : det Similar if we wish set ds = dt =0in the total di erential and replace the remaining d 0 s 0 s so that dr dq and dq : We therefore obtain: : 3@Q +6@R = 0 or in matrix = Dividing both sides @R = 6 Solving by Cramer s rule then = 6 3 det = : From the Reduced Form Since the structural model is linear, we can easily nd the reduced form using matrix algebra. We thus have from the implicit functions: 3 Q R 3 S =0: Q T :

30 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS so that: Q Q 3 = = R 3 S 5 + T R S T : Writing these out we get the reduced form: Q = h (R; S; T) = R 5 4 S T 3 4 so that: Q = h (R; S; T) = 5 R S 7 4 T = 3 8 :.5.4 Example : Supply and Demand I First consider a demand and supply model given by: Q d = D (P ) Q s = S (P ) Q s = Q d = Q D 0 (P ) < 0 (the demand curve) S 0 (P ) > 0 (the supply curve) (the equilibrium condition). Here there are no exogenous variables, the rst equation says that the demand curve slopes downward, the second that the supply curve slopes upward and the third that in equilibrium supply equals demand. We can re-write this as two implicit functions with two endogenous variables Q and P as: g (Q; P ) = Q D (P )=0 g (Q; P ) = Q S (P )=0: At this stage there are no exogenous variables. Let us now introduce two exogenous variables: a tax T H paid by households and a tax T F paid by rms so that the model becomes: Q d = D (P + T H ) ; Q s = S (P T F ) ; Q s = Q d = Q:

31 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 3 or as implicit functions: g (Q; P; T H ;T F ) = Q D (P + T H )=0 g (Q; P; T H ;T F ) = Q S (P T F )=0: This determines the equilibrium quantity Q and price P as functions of T H and T F as: To simplify the notation de ne: Q = h (T H ;T F ) P = h (T H ;T F ) : D P D 0 (P + T H ) S P S 0 (P T F ) : To nd the e ect of the tax T H on the endogenous variables P and Q; we calculate the total di erential which is: since: dq D P dp D P dt H = 0 dq S P dp + S P dt F = 0 and: a = a = D P b H = D P b F =0 a ;TF = a = S P b H =0 b F = S P : H set dt F =0and replace all the remaining d 0 s in the total di erential 0 s to D D H = S = 0 or S = DP H : Dividing both sides H we obtain: H H # = DP 0

32 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 4 so that from Cramer H = = DP D det P 0 S P DP det S P D P S P < 0 S P + D P so that the tax on households reduces the equilibrium quantity..5.5 Example 3: Supply and Demand II There are of course many more variables than taxes which shift demand and supply curves. Let a be any variable which shifts the demand curve to the right and b any variable which shifts the supply curve to the right. We can write a more general supply and demand model as: Q d = D (P; a) Q s = S (P; b) Q s = Q d = Q: < 0 > 0 > 0 > 0 For example if a = T H and b = T F and D (P; a) =D (P + T H ) and S (P; b) = S (P T F ) then we would have the previous supply and demand model. Here the exogenous variables are a and b and the endogenous variables are Q and P: Written as a system of implicit equations we have: The total di erential is then: g (Q; P; a; b) = Q D (P; a) =0 g (Q; P; a; b) = Q S (P; b) =0: dq D P dp D a da +0db = 0 dq S P dp +0da S b db = 0: Suppose we want to see what happens if the demand curve shifts to the right while the supply curve stays xed. Set db and dp so that from the total di erential: DP = Da 0

33 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 5 so that using Cramer s rule: Da D det 0 S P D = a S P = > DP S det P + D P S P Da 0 D = a = > DP S det P + D P S P Thus anything which shifts the demand curve to the right increases Q and P: Verify this using a diagram!.5.6 Example 4: The IS=LM Model The Goods and Services Market In the IS/LM model the goods and services market is described by: c d = c (y) ; 0 <c 0 (y) < ; i d = i (r) ;i 0 (r) < 0 g d = g o y d = c d + i d + g d y = y d where c d is consumption demand (with c 0 (y) the marginal propensity to consume), i d is investment demand (which depends negatively on the rate of interest), g d is government expenditure y d is aggregate demand and y is GNP: Here government expenditure is exogenous and equal to some constant g o (the o subscript here is used to denote exogenous variables) while all other variables are endogenous, i.e., c, i; y and r: In equilibrium we require that y = y d = c (y)+i (r)+g o so that: y = c (y)+i (r)+g o which is the structural form of the IS curve. We can write this as an implicit function as: g (y; r; g o ;m s o)=y c (y) i (r) g o =0 where y and r are the endogenous variables and g o and (the not yet introduced exogenous money supply) m s o are the exogenous variables. The total di erential for the IS curve is then: ( c 0 (y)) dy i 0 (r) dr dg o +0dm s o =0:

34 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 6 TheSlopeoftheISCurve Let us now show that the IS curve is downward sloping. The IS curve is all r; y combinations which satisfy this implicit function for xed values of g o and m s o: We can therefore think of y as the independent or exogenous variable and r as the dependent variable or endogenous variable and take the total di erential with dg o = dm s o =0to obtain: ( c 0 (y)) dy i 0 (r) dr =0: dr Solving for the slope of the IS curve given by: dy we obtain: dr dy = c0 (y) i 0 < 0 (r) since c 0 (y) > 0 and i 0 (r) < 0: Thus the IS curve is downward sloping. The Money Market The money market is described by: m d = k (y)+l(r);k 0 (y) > 0; l 0 (r) < 0 m s = m s o where k (y) is the transactions demand for money, l (r) is the speculative demand for money, which depends negatively on r; and m s o is the exogenous supply of money. In equilibrium: m s = m d so that we have: m s o = k (y)+l(r) which is the structural form of the LM curve. We can write the LM curve as an implicit function as: g (y; r; g o ;m s o )=k(y)+l(r) ms o =0: This has a total di erential given by: k 0 (y) dy + l 0 (r) dr +0dg o dm s o =0: TheSlopeoftheLMCurve Let us now show that the LM curve is downward sloping. The LM curve is all r; y combinations which satisfy this implicit function for xed values of g o and m s o: We can therefore think of y as the independent or exogenous variable and r as the dependent variable or endogenous variable and take the total di erential with dg o = dm s o =0to obtain: k 0 (y) dy + l 0 (r) dr =0 and solve for dr dy ; the slope of the LM curve as: dr dy = k0 (y) l 0 (r) > 0

35 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 7 The IS and LM Curves as Implicit Functions Taken together IS and LM equations determine the structural form of the model with two endogenous variables y and r and two exogenous variables g o and m s o. We can write the IS and LM equations respectively as: g (y; r; g o ;m s o) = y c (y) i (r) g o =0 g (y; r; g o ;m s o ) = k (y)+l(r) ms o =0: These two equations then determine a reduced form: y = f (g o ;m s o) r = f (g o ;m s o ) : We wish to calculate such partial o ; which tells us how responds to changes in government expenditure, which tells us how s o interest rates respond to changes in the money supply. The Total Di erential The total di erential for the IS=LM model is given by: since: ( c 0 (y)) dy i 0 (r) dr dg o = 0 k 0 (y) dy + l 0 (r) dr dm s o = 0 and = c0 (y) = i0 (r) ; b = ; s =0 o = k0 (y) = l0 (r) ; b s = : o The E ect of Changes in Government Expenditure o set dm s o =0and replace the d0 s 0 s to obtain: ( c 0 i o = 0 k 0 + l 0 = 0 or writing this in matrix notation: c 0 (y) i 0 (r) k 0 (y) l = o :

36 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 8 Dividing both sides o we obtain: c 0 (y) " i 0 (r) k 0 (y) l 0 (r) Finally, using Cramer o = = so that simplifying @g o # = 0 i det 0 (r) 0 l 0 (r) c det 0 (y) i 0 (r) k 0 (y) l 0 (r) : l 0 (r) ( c 0 (y)) l 0 (r)+i 0 (r) k 0 (y) ( c 0 (y)) + i0 (r)k 0 (y) l 0 (r) Since 0 <c 0 (y) < it follows that 0 < c 0 (y) < so the rst term in the denominator is positive. The second term: i0 (r)k 0 (y) l 0 (r) represents the crowding out e ect and is also positive since i 0 (r) < 0, l 0 (r) < 0 and k 0 (y) > 0: We therefore o > 0 so that an increase in government expenditure increases GNP: Using Cramer s rule to o we nd that: c det 0 k 0 (y) 0 o c det 0 (y) i 0 (r) k 0 (y) l 0 (r) = k 0 (y) c det 0 (y) i 0 > 0 (r) k 0 (y) l 0 (r) so that an increase in government expenditure increases interest rates. It follows from this that investment falls when government expenditure increases. Using the chain rule we (g o ;m s o )) = i 0 (r (g o ;m s (g o;m s o ) < 0 o since i 0 (r) < 0: The E ect of Changes in the Money Supply Similarly s o set dg o =0and replace the d 0 s 0 s to obtain: ( c 0 i 0 = 0 k 0 + l s o = 0: :

37 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 9 or c 0 (y) i 0 (r) k 0 (y) l 0 s o # = 0 : Using Cramer s rule it follows that : 0 i det 0 l 0 s = o c det 0 (y) i 0 (r) k 0 (y) l 0 (r) > s o c det 0 (y) 0 k 0 (y) = c det 0 (y) i 0 (r) k 0 (y) l 0 (r) < 0 so that an increase in the money supply increases GNP and decreases interest rates. (Verify this!) It follows from this that investment increases when the money supply increases since using the chain rule we have: since i 0 (r) < (g o ;m s s o = i 0 (r (g o ;m s o (g o;m s s o > 0.6 Total Di erentials and Optimization.6. A General Discussion Economics deals with rational behavior, and rational behavior typically means maximizing or minimizing something. For example utility and pro ts get maximized while costs get minimized. Maximization and minimization imply rst-order and second-order conditions. First-order conditions say that some expression of the endogenous and exogenous variables must equal zero and so give directly implicit functions from which we can take total di erentials. Second-order conditions tell us that something about a symmetric matrix, the Hessian H: For example with an unconstrained maximization problem we know that H must be negative de nite while for an unconstrained minimization problem H must be positive de nite. It turns out that when we take the total di erential, the coe cients on the dy 0 s; the exogenous variables, always come from H; the Hessian from the secondorder conditions. This turns out to be invaluable in signing partial derivatives since if we use Cramer s rule det [H] will always appear in the denominator.

38 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS A Quick Derivation of the Main Principle Let y be an n vector and x an m vector of exogenous variables. Suppose that our structural model involves either maximizing or minimizing: f (y; x) : The optimal y; say y will then satisfy the rst-order (y ;x) =0; for i =; i Here y is the vector of endogenous variables and x is the vector of exogenous variables. The rst-order conditions then de ne a set of n implicit functions given by: g i (y (y ;x) =0; for i =; i This determines the reduced form of n equations: y i = y i (x) for i =; ;:::n: From the second-order conditions we have that the f (y ;x) H j is negative de nite for a maximum and positive de nite for a minimum. Taking the total di erential of g (y ;x)=0we nd that: Hdy + Bdx =0 where the n n matrix H and the n m matrix B are given H (y f (y ;x) ;x) = f (y ;x) B j Using Cramer s rule we then nd that as before that i = det [H i ( b j )] j det [H] From the second-order conditions we know that H is either negative de nite for a maximum or positive de nite and for a minimum hence non-singular. Furthermorewecandeterminethesignofdet [H] : For example det [H] > 0 if H is positive de nite. This can be used in j is positive or negative when we use Cramer s rule.

39 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 3 While this derivation has skipped some details and is perhaps hard to follow in the details, the essential point is easy to grasp and is this: When taking the total di erential from an unconstrained optimization problem, the matrix of coe cients on the dy 0 s is identical to the Hessian: H from the second-order conditions. This fact can then be used in signing the partial derivatives j :.6.3 Pro t Maximization Consider the problem of pro t maximizing in the long-run for a perfectly competitive rm with technology Q = F (L; K) where ¼ is pro ts, Q is output, P is price, L is labour, K is capital, W is the nominal wage and R is the rental cost of capital. Pro t are thus given by: ¼ (L; K; P; W; R) =PF (L; K) WL RK: From the rst-order conditions we have: (L ;K ) W = (L ;K ) R = Here L and K are the endogenous variables and P; W and R are the exogenous variables. The rst-order conditions thus de ne two implicit functions: g (L ;K ;P;W;R) = (L ;K ) W g (L ;K ;P;W;R) = (L ;K ) R which determines the reduced form: L = L (P; W; R) K = K (P; W; R) : To simplify the notation let us make the following de nitions: F ;K F ;K F F (L ;K F F (L ;K F F (L ;K The second-order conditions are then that the Hessian H given by: PFLL PF H = LK PF LK PF KK is negative de nite. Therefore: PF LL (L ;K ) < 0; PF KK (L ;K ) < 0 det [H] > 0:

40 CHAPTER. TOTAL DIFFERENTIALS 3 Taking the total di erential we nd that: PF LL dl + PF LK dk + F L dp dw = 0 PF LK dl + PF KK dk + F K dp dr = 0 so that in matrix notation we have: PFLL PF LK dl FL 0 PF LK PF KK dk + F K 0 {z } =H 4 dp dw dr 3 5 = Note that the matrix of coe cients on the vector of dl and dk ; the endogenous variables, is H; the Hessian from the second-order conditions. Suppose now we wish @W : Set dp = dr =0and change the remaining d 0 s 0 s so that dl ;dk ; and dw put the terms on the right-hand side, and divide to obtain: PFLL PF LK = : KK 0 {z =H Using Cramer s rule we nd = PFLK 0 PF KK det [H] = PF KK det [H] < 0 since PF KK < 0 and det [H] > 0 from the second-order conditions. Note how we have used the second-order conditions to show that the long-run labour demand curve is downward sloping. From this we can also show using Cramer s rule = PFLL PF LK 0 = PF LK det [H] det [H] which can be either positive or negative depending on the sign of F LK : Suppose now @R : From the total di erential we can show that: PFLL 0 = PF LK PF KK @R 0 PFLK det PF KK det [H] PFLL 0 PF LK det [H] = PF LK det [H] = PF LL det [H] < 0: 0 0 :

Workbook. Michael Sampson. An Introduction to. Mathematical Economics Part 1 Q 2 Q 1. Loglinear Publishing

Workbook. Michael Sampson. An Introduction to. Mathematical Economics Part 1 Q 2 Q 1. Loglinear Publishing Workbook An Introduction to Mathematical Economics Part U Q Loglinear Publishing Q Michael Sampson Copyright 00 Michael Sampson. Loglinear Publications: http://www.loglinear.com Email: mail@loglinear.com.

More information

z = f (x; y) f (x ; y ) f (x; y) f (x; y )

z = f (x; y) f (x ; y ) f (x; y) f (x; y ) BEEM0 Optimization Techiniques for Economists Lecture Week 4 Dieter Balkenborg Departments of Economics University of Exeter Since the fabric of the universe is most perfect, and is the work of a most

More information

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics Yulei Luo SEF of HKU January 14, 2009 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) MME January 14, 2009 1 / 44 Comparative Statics and The Concept of Derivative Comparative Statics

More information

BEE1024 Mathematics for Economists

BEE1024 Mathematics for Economists BEE1024 Mathematics for Economists Dieter and Jack Rogers and Juliette Stephenson Department of Economics, University of Exeter February 1st 2007 1 Objective 2 Isoquants 3 Objective. The lecture should

More information

MTAEA Implicit Functions

MTAEA Implicit Functions School of Economics, Australian National University February 12, 2010 Implicit Functions and Their Derivatives Up till now we have only worked with functions in which the endogenous variables are explicit

More information

z = f (x; y) = x 3 3x 2 y x 2 3

z = f (x; y) = x 3 3x 2 y x 2 3 BEE Mathematics for Economists Week, ecture Thursday..7 Functions in two variables Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics University of Exeter Objective This lecture has the purpose to make you familiar

More information

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics ECON2285: Mathematical Economics Yulei Luo Economics, HKU September 17, 2018 Luo, Y. (Economics, HKU) ME September 17, 2018 1 / 46 Static Optimization and Extreme Values In this topic, we will study goal

More information

Tutorial 2: Comparative Statics

Tutorial 2: Comparative Statics Tutorial 2: Comparative Statics ECO42F 20 Derivatives and Rules of Differentiation For each of the functions below: (a) Find the difference quotient. (b) Find the derivative dx. (c) Find f (4) and f (3)..

More information

1 Objective. 2 Constrained optimization. 2.1 Utility maximization. Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics

1 Objective. 2 Constrained optimization. 2.1 Utility maximization. Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics BEE020 { Basic Mathematical Economics Week 2, Lecture Thursday 2.0.0 Constrained optimization Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics University of Exeter Objective We give the \ rst order conditions"

More information

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4 Solow Growth Model Michael Bar February 28, 208 Contents Introduction 2. Some facts about modern growth........................ 3.2 Questions..................................... 4 2 The Solow Model 5

More information

Sometimes the domains X and Z will be the same, so this might be written:

Sometimes the domains X and Z will be the same, so this might be written: II. MULTIVARIATE CALCULUS The first lecture covered functions where a single input goes in, and a single output comes out. Most economic applications aren t so simple. In most cases, a number of variables

More information

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics Yulei Luo SEF of HKU January 12, 2009 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) MME January 12, 2009 1 / 35 Course Outline Economics: The study of the choices people (consumers,

More information

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I 14.454 - Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I 04/02/2011 Due: Monday 4/11/2011 1 Question 1 - Kocherlakota (2000) Take an economy with a representative, in nitely-lived consumer. The consumer owns a technology

More information

Chapter 4. Maximum Theorem, Implicit Function Theorem and Envelope Theorem

Chapter 4. Maximum Theorem, Implicit Function Theorem and Envelope Theorem Chapter 4. Maximum Theorem, Implicit Function Theorem and Envelope Theorem This chapter will cover three key theorems: the maximum theorem (or the theorem of maximum), the implicit function theorem, and

More information

AY Term 1 Examination November 2013 ECON205 INTERMEDIATE MATHEMATICS FOR ECONOMICS

AY Term 1 Examination November 2013 ECON205 INTERMEDIATE MATHEMATICS FOR ECONOMICS AY203-4 Term Examination November 203 ECON205 INTERMEDIATE MATHEMATICS FOR ECONOMICS INSTRUCTIONS TO CANDIDATES The time allowed for this examination paper is TWO hours 2 This examination paper contains

More information

Lecture Notes for Chapter 12

Lecture Notes for Chapter 12 Lecture Notes for Chapter 12 Kevin Wainwright April 26, 2014 1 Constrained Optimization Consider the following Utility Max problem: Max x 1, x 2 U = U(x 1, x 2 ) (1) Subject to: Re-write Eq. 2 B = P 1

More information

Econ Review Set 2 - Answers

Econ Review Set 2 - Answers Econ 4808 Review Set 2 - Answers EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS 1. De ne the concept of equilibrium within the con nes of an economic model. Provide an example of an economic equilibrium. Economic models contain

More information

Chapter 4 Differentiation

Chapter 4 Differentiation Chapter 4 Differentiation 08 Section 4. The derivative of a function Practice Problems (a) (b) (c) 3 8 3 ( ) 4 3 5 4 ( ) 5 3 3 0 0 49 ( ) 50 Using a calculator, the values of the cube function, correct

More information

Implicit Function Theorem: One Equation

Implicit Function Theorem: One Equation Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 3: The Implicit Function Theorem Note 3 is based on postol (975, h 3), de la Fuente (2, h5) and Simon and Blume (994, h 5) This note discusses the

More information

Answer Key for M. A. Economics Entrance Examination 2017 (Main version)

Answer Key for M. A. Economics Entrance Examination 2017 (Main version) Answer Key for M. A. Economics Entrance Examination 2017 (Main version) July 4, 2017 1. Person A lexicographically prefers good x to good y, i.e., when comparing two bundles of x and y, she strictly prefers

More information

Solutions to Problem Set 4 Macro II (14.452)

Solutions to Problem Set 4 Macro II (14.452) Solutions to Problem Set 4 Macro II (14.452) Francisco A. Gallego 05/11 1 Money as a Factor of Production (Dornbusch and Frenkel, 1973) The shortcut used by Dornbusch and Frenkel to introduce money in

More information

ECON 255 Introduction to Mathematical Economics

ECON 255 Introduction to Mathematical Economics Page 1 of 5 FINAL EXAMINATION Winter 2017 Introduction to Mathematical Economics April 20, 2017 TIME ALLOWED: 3 HOURS NUMBER IN THE LIST: STUDENT NUMBER: NAME: SIGNATURE: INSTRUCTIONS 1. This examination

More information

Partial Differentiation

Partial Differentiation CHAPTER 7 Partial Differentiation From the previous two chapters we know how to differentiate functions of one variable But many functions in economics depend on several variables: output depends on both

More information

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory 2 Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory 2.1. The Keynesian Consumption Function 2.2. The Complete Keynesian Model 2.3. The Keynesian-Cross Model 2.4. The IS-LM Model 2.5. The Keynesian AD-AS Model 2.6. Conclusion

More information

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010 Session 4: Jean November 2010 I So far, focused on real economy. Real quantities consumed, produced, invested. No money, no nominal in uences. I Now, introduce nominal dimension in the economy. First and

More information

ECON501 - Vector Di erentiation Simon Grant

ECON501 - Vector Di erentiation Simon Grant ECON01 - Vector Di erentiation Simon Grant October 00 Abstract Notes on vector di erentiation and some simple economic applications and examples 1 Functions of One Variable g : R! R derivative (slope)

More information

DEPARTMENT OF MANAGEMENT AND ECONOMICS Royal Military College of Canada. ECE Modelling in Economics Instructor: Lenin Arango-Castillo

DEPARTMENT OF MANAGEMENT AND ECONOMICS Royal Military College of Canada. ECE Modelling in Economics Instructor: Lenin Arango-Castillo Page 1 of 5 DEPARTMENT OF MANAGEMENT AND ECONOMICS Royal Military College of Canada ECE 256 - Modelling in Economics Instructor: Lenin Arango-Castillo Final Examination 13:00-16:00, December 11, 2017 INSTRUCTIONS

More information

Nonlinear Programming (NLP)

Nonlinear Programming (NLP) Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 6: Nonlinear Programming - Unconstrained Optimization Note 6 is based on de la Fuente (2000, Ch. 7), Madden (1986, Ch. 3 and 5) and Simon and Blume

More information

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3) MakØk3, Fall 2 (blok 2) Business cycles and monetary stabilization policies Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen Lecture 3, November 3: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter

More information

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

September Math Course: First Order Derivative September Math Course: First Order Derivative Arina Nikandrova Functions Function y = f (x), where x is either be a scalar or a vector of several variables (x,..., x n ), can be thought of as a rule which

More information

a = (a 1; :::a i )

a = (a 1; :::a  i ) 1 Pro t maximization Behavioral assumption: an optimal set of actions is characterized by the conditions: max R(a 1 ; a ; :::a n ) C(a 1 ; a ; :::a n ) a = (a 1; :::a n) @R(a ) @a i = @C(a ) @a i The rm

More information

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 2: Dynamics in Aggregate Demand and Supply

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 2: Dynamics in Aggregate Demand and Supply Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics: Chapter 2 1 Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 2: Dynamics in Aggregate Demand and Supply Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics:

More information

Tutorial 1: Linear Algebra

Tutorial 1: Linear Algebra Tutorial : Linear Algebra ECOF. Suppose p + x q, y r If x y, find p, q, r.. Which of the following sets of vectors are linearly dependent? [ ] [ ] [ ] (a),, (b),, (c),, 9 (d) 9,,. Let Find A [ ], B [ ]

More information

BEEM103 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER. BUSINESS School. January 2009 Mock Exam, Part A. OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions

BEEM103 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER. BUSINESS School. January 2009 Mock Exam, Part A. OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions BEEM03 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER BUSINESS School January 009 Mock Exam, Part A OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions Duration : TWO HOURS The paper has 3 parts. Your marks on the rst part will be

More information

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Labor Economics, 14.661. Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Daron Acemoglu MIT December 6, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Sequential Search December 6, 2011. 1 / 43 Introduction Introduction

More information

Lecture 1: The Classical Optimal Growth Model

Lecture 1: The Classical Optimal Growth Model Lecture 1: The Classical Optimal Growth Model This lecture introduces the classical optimal economic growth problem. Solving the problem will require a dynamic optimisation technique: a simple calculus

More information

A Summary of Economic Methodology

A Summary of Economic Methodology A Summary of Economic Methodology I. The Methodology of Theoretical Economics All economic analysis begins with theory, based in part on intuitive insights that naturally spring from certain stylized facts,

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 202 Answer Key to Section 2 Questions Section. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of

More information

Maths for Economists Tutorial 0: Revision of Basic Concepts

Maths for Economists Tutorial 0: Revision of Basic Concepts Maths for Economists Tutorial 0: Revision of Basic Concepts ECO42F 20 In the following paired statements, let p be the first statement and q the second. Indicate for each case whether q is necessary or

More information

ECON 186 Class Notes: Optimization Part 2

ECON 186 Class Notes: Optimization Part 2 ECON 186 Class Notes: Optimization Part 2 Jijian Fan Jijian Fan ECON 186 1 / 26 Hessians The Hessian matrix is a matrix of all partial derivatives of a function. Given the function f (x 1,x 2,...,x n ),

More information

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems Craig Burnside Duke University September 2010 Craig Burnside (Duke University) Competitive Equilibrium September 2010 1 / 32 Competitive Equilibrium and

More information

a11 a A = : a 21 a 22

a11 a A = : a 21 a 22 Matrices The study of linear systems is facilitated by introducing matrices. Matrix theory provides a convenient language and notation to express many of the ideas concisely, and complicated formulas are

More information

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 December 14, 2006 Exercise 1 A Households Households maximise their intertemporal utility function by optimally choosing consumption, savings, and the mix of

More information

Lecture # 1 - Introduction

Lecture # 1 - Introduction Lecture # 1 - Introduction Mathematical vs. Nonmathematical Economics Mathematical Economics is an approach to economic analysis Purpose of any approach: derive a set of conclusions or theorems Di erences:

More information

Lecture 1- The constrained optimization problem

Lecture 1- The constrained optimization problem Lecture 1- The constrained optimization problem The role of optimization in economic theory is important because we assume that individuals are rational. Why constrained optimization? the problem of scarcity.

More information

Differentiation. 1. What is a Derivative? CHAPTER 5

Differentiation. 1. What is a Derivative? CHAPTER 5 CHAPTER 5 Differentiation Differentiation is a technique that enables us to find out how a function changes when its argument changes It is an essential tool in economics If you have done A-level maths,

More information

The Ramsey Model. Alessandra Pelloni. October TEI Lecture. Alessandra Pelloni (TEI Lecture) Economic Growth October / 61

The Ramsey Model. Alessandra Pelloni. October TEI Lecture. Alessandra Pelloni (TEI Lecture) Economic Growth October / 61 The Ramsey Model Alessandra Pelloni TEI Lecture October 2015 Alessandra Pelloni (TEI Lecture) Economic Growth October 2015 1 / 61 Introduction Introduction Introduction Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model: di ers

More information

Notice in equation (1) that the objective function modified by the Lagrangian multiplier times the constraint is relabeled.

Notice in equation (1) that the objective function modified by the Lagrangian multiplier times the constraint is relabeled. 9 Notes 4.DOC Department of Economics A PROBLEM OF CONSTRAINED MAXIMIZATION Consider the problem of keeping bees. Bees provide pollination services and they make honey. For decades economists used the

More information

Business Cycles: The Classical Approach

Business Cycles: The Classical Approach San Francisco State University ECON 302 Business Cycles: The Classical Approach Introduction Michael Bar Recall from the introduction that the output per capita in the U.S. is groing steady, but there

More information

Problem 1 (30 points)

Problem 1 (30 points) Problem (30 points) Prof. Robert King Consider an economy in which there is one period and there are many, identical households. Each household derives utility from consumption (c), leisure (l) and a public

More information

Economics 401 Sample questions 2

Economics 401 Sample questions 2 Economics 401 Sample questions 1. What does it mean to say that preferences fit the Gorman polar form? Do quasilinear preferences fit the Gorman form? Do aggregate demands based on the Gorman form have

More information

Internation1al Trade

Internation1al Trade 14.581 Internation1al Trade Class notes on 3/4/2013 1 Factor Proportion Theory The law of comparative advantage establishes the relationship between relative autarky prices and trade ows But where do relative

More information

Bi-Variate Functions - ACTIVITES

Bi-Variate Functions - ACTIVITES Bi-Variate Functions - ACTIVITES LO1. Students to consolidate basic meaning of bi-variate functions LO2. Students to learn how to confidently use bi-variate functions in economics Students are given the

More information

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP Prof. Olivier Bochet Room A.34 Phone 3 63 476 E-mail olivier.bochet@vwi.unibe.ch Webpage http//sta.vwi.unibe.ch/bochet Advanced Microeconomics Fall 2 Lecture Note Choice-Based Approach Price e ects, Wealth

More information

c 2007 Je rey A. Miron

c 2007 Je rey A. Miron Review of Calculus Tools. c 007 Je rey A. Miron Outline 1. Derivatives. Optimization 3. Partial Derivatives. Optimization again 5. Optimization subject to constraints 1 Derivatives The basic tool we need

More information

ECON Answers Homework #4. = 0 6q q 2 = 0 q 3 9q = 0 q = 12. = 9q 2 108q AC(12) = 3(12) = 500

ECON Answers Homework #4. = 0 6q q 2 = 0 q 3 9q = 0 q = 12. = 9q 2 108q AC(12) = 3(12) = 500 ECON 331 - Answers Homework #4 Exercise 1: (a)(i) The average cost function AC is: AC = T C q = 3q 2 54q + 500 + 2592 q (ii) In order to nd the point where the average cost is minimum, I solve the rst-order

More information

Lecture 6: Contraction mapping, inverse and implicit function theorems

Lecture 6: Contraction mapping, inverse and implicit function theorems Lecture 6: Contraction mapping, inverse and implicit function theorems 1 The contraction mapping theorem De nition 11 Let X be a metric space, with metric d If f : X! X and if there is a number 2 (0; 1)

More information

ECON607 Fall 2010 University of Hawaii Professor Hui He TA: Xiaodong Sun Assignment 2

ECON607 Fall 2010 University of Hawaii Professor Hui He TA: Xiaodong Sun Assignment 2 ECON607 Fall 200 University of Hawaii Professor Hui He TA: Xiaodong Sun Assignment 2 The due date for this assignment is Tuesday, October 2. ( Total points = 50). (Two-sector growth model) Consider the

More information

Some Notes on Adverse Selection

Some Notes on Adverse Selection Some Notes on Adverse Selection John Morgan Haas School of Business and Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Overview This set of lecture notes covers a general model of adverse selection

More information

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. Ph.D. Core Exam -- Macroeconomics 5 January 2015 -- 8:00 am to 3:00 pm Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. A1 (required): Ending Quantitative Easing Now that the U.S.

More information

Econ Slides from Lecture 10

Econ Slides from Lecture 10 Econ 205 Sobel Econ 205 - Slides from Lecture 10 Joel Sobel September 2, 2010 Example Find the tangent plane to {x x 1 x 2 x 2 3 = 6} R3 at x = (2, 5, 2). If you let f (x) = x 1 x 2 x3 2, then this is

More information

Study Skills in Mathematics. Edited by D. Burkhardt and D. Rutherford. Nottingham: Shell Centre for Mathematical Education (Revised edn 1981).

Study Skills in Mathematics. Edited by D. Burkhardt and D. Rutherford. Nottingham: Shell Centre for Mathematical Education (Revised edn 1981). Study Skills in Mathematics. Edited by D. Burkhardt and D. Rutherford. Nottingham: Shell Centre for Mathematical Education (Revised edn 1981). (Copies are available from the Shell Centre for Mathematical

More information

Economic Growth

Economic Growth MIT OpenCourseWare http://ocw.mit.edu 14.452 Economic Growth Fall 2008 For information about citing these materials or our Terms of Use, visit: http://ocw.mit.edu/terms. 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture

More information

Constrained optimization.

Constrained optimization. ams/econ 11b supplementary notes ucsc Constrained optimization. c 2016, Yonatan Katznelson 1. Constraints In many of the optimization problems that arise in economics, there are restrictions on the values

More information

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009 Department of Agricultural Economics PhD Qualifier Examination May 009 Instructions: The exam consists of six questions. You must answer all questions. If you need an assumption to complete a question,

More information

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy Economics 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Kam Yu Winter 2013 Outline 1 Introduction 2 The Basic DGE Closed Economy 3 Golden Rule Solution 4 Optimal Solution The Euler Equation

More information

General Equilibrium and Welfare

General Equilibrium and Welfare and Welfare Lectures 2 and 3, ECON 4240 Spring 2017 University of Oslo 24.01.2017 and 31.01.2017 1/37 Outline General equilibrium: look at many markets at the same time. Here all prices determined in the

More information

Modelling Production

Modelling Production Modelling Production David N. DeJong University of Pittsburgh Econ. 1540, Spring 2010 DND () Production Econ. 1540, Spring 2010 1 / 23 Introduction The production function is the foundation upon which

More information

1 Uncertainty. These notes correspond to chapter 2 of Jehle and Reny.

1 Uncertainty. These notes correspond to chapter 2 of Jehle and Reny. These notes correspond to chapter of Jehle and Reny. Uncertainty Until now we have considered our consumer s making decisions in a world with perfect certainty. However, we can extend the consumer theory

More information

ECON4515 Finance theory 1 Diderik Lund, 5 May Perold: The CAPM

ECON4515 Finance theory 1 Diderik Lund, 5 May Perold: The CAPM Perold: The CAPM Perold starts with a historical background, the development of portfolio theory and the CAPM. Points out that until 1950 there was no theory to describe the equilibrium determination of

More information

Monetary Economics Notes

Monetary Economics Notes Monetary Economics Notes Nicola Viegi 2 University of Pretoria - School of Economics Contents New Keynesian Models. Readings...............................2 Basic New Keynesian Model...................

More information

Midterm Exam 2. October 27, Time: 1 hour, 30 minutes. San Francisco State University ECON 715 Fall Name:

Midterm Exam 2. October 27, Time: 1 hour, 30 minutes. San Francisco State University ECON 715 Fall Name: San Francisco State University Michael Bar ECON 75 Fall 206 Midterm Exam 2 October 27, 206 Time: hour, 30 minutes Name: Instructions:. One double-sided sheet with any content is allowed. 2. Calculators

More information

Economics th April 2011

Economics th April 2011 Economics 401 8th April 2011 Instructions: Answer 7 of the following 9 questions. All questions are of equal weight. Indicate clearly on the first page which questions you want marked. 1. Answer both parts.

More information

Maximum Value Functions and the Envelope Theorem

Maximum Value Functions and the Envelope Theorem Lecture Notes for ECON 40 Kevin Wainwright Maximum Value Functions and the Envelope Theorem A maximum (or minimum) value function is an objective function where the choice variables have been assigned

More information

Test code: ME I/ME II, 2004 Syllabus for ME I. Matrix Algebra: Matrices and Vectors, Matrix Operations, Determinants,

Test code: ME I/ME II, 2004 Syllabus for ME I. Matrix Algebra: Matrices and Vectors, Matrix Operations, Determinants, Test code: ME I/ME II, 004 Syllabus for ME I Matri Algebra: Matrices and Vectors, Matri Operations, Determinants, Nonsingularity, Inversion, Cramer s rule. Calculus: Limits, Continuity, Differentiation

More information

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model Toulouse School of Economics, 2009-2010 Macroeconomics II Franck Portier Homework 1 Problem I An AD-AS Model Let us consider an economy with three agents (a firm, a household and a government) and four

More information

EconS Oligopoly - Part 2

EconS Oligopoly - Part 2 EconS 305 - Oligopoly - Part 2 Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu November 29, 2015 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 32 November 29, 2015 1 / 28 Introduction Last time,

More information

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Equilibrium in a Production Economy Equilibrium in a Production Economy Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2012 Sims (ND) Equilibrium in a Production Economy Fall 2012 1 / 23 Production Economy Last time: studied equilibrium in

More information

Math 1280 Notes 4 Last section revised, 1/31, 9:30 pm.

Math 1280 Notes 4 Last section revised, 1/31, 9:30 pm. 1 competing species Math 1280 Notes 4 Last section revised, 1/31, 9:30 pm. This section and the next deal with the subject of population biology. You will already have seen examples of this. Most calculus

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano Gerzensee, August 27 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand.

More information

It is convenient to introduce some notation for this type of problems. I will write this as. max u (x 1 ; x 2 ) subj. to. p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 m ;

It is convenient to introduce some notation for this type of problems. I will write this as. max u (x 1 ; x 2 ) subj. to. p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 m ; 4 Calculus Review 4.1 The Utility Maimization Problem As a motivating eample, consider the problem facing a consumer that needs to allocate a given budget over two commodities sold at (linear) prices p

More information

The Kuhn-Tucker Problem

The Kuhn-Tucker Problem Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 8: Nonlinear Programming - The Kuhn-Tucker Problem Note 8 is based on de la Fuente (2000, Ch. 7) and Simon and Blume (1994, Ch. 18 and 19). The Kuhn-Tucker

More information

You are permitted to use your own calculator where it has been stamped as approved by the University.

You are permitted to use your own calculator where it has been stamped as approved by the University. ECONOMICS TRIPOS Part I Friday 11 June 004 9 1 Paper 3 Quantitative Methods in Economics This exam comprises four sections. Sections A and B are on Mathematics; Sections C and D are on Statistics. You

More information

MC3: Econometric Theory and Methods. Course Notes 4

MC3: Econometric Theory and Methods. Course Notes 4 University College London Department of Economics M.Sc. in Economics MC3: Econometric Theory and Methods Course Notes 4 Notes on maximum likelihood methods Andrew Chesher 25/0/2005 Course Notes 4, Andrew

More information

Economics 241B Estimation with Instruments

Economics 241B Estimation with Instruments Economics 241B Estimation with Instruments Measurement Error Measurement error is de ned as the error resulting from the measurement of a variable. At some level, every variable is measured with error.

More information

Comparative Statics. Autumn 2018

Comparative Statics. Autumn 2018 Comparative Statics Autumn 2018 What is comparative statics? Contents 1 What is comparative statics? 2 One variable functions Multiple variable functions Vector valued functions Differential and total

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6 Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO April 10, 017 Administrative Stuff Homework # is due at the end of class. I will post the solutions on the website later today. The midterm

More information

Topic 5: The Difference Equation

Topic 5: The Difference Equation Topic 5: The Difference Equation Yulei Luo Economics, HKU October 30, 2017 Luo, Y. (Economics, HKU) ME October 30, 2017 1 / 42 Discrete-time, Differences, and Difference Equations When time is taken to

More information

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models Daron Acemoglu MIT September 12, 2007 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Advanced Growth Lecture 3 September 12, 2007 1 / 40 Introduction

More information

Lecture 3 - Axioms of Consumer Preference and the Theory of Choice

Lecture 3 - Axioms of Consumer Preference and the Theory of Choice Lecture 3 - Axioms of Consumer Preference and the Theory of Choice David Autor 14.03 Fall 2004 Agenda: 1. Consumer preference theory (a) Notion of utility function (b) Axioms of consumer preference (c)

More information

External Economies of Scale and International Trade: Further Analysis

External Economies of Scale and International Trade: Further Analysis External Economies of Scale and International Trade: Further Analysis Kar-yiu Wong 1 University of Washington August 9, 2000 1 Department of Economics, Box 353330, University of Washington, Seattle, WA

More information

Microeconomic theory focuses on a small number of concepts. The most fundamental concept is the notion of opportunity cost.

Microeconomic theory focuses on a small number of concepts. The most fundamental concept is the notion of opportunity cost. Microeconomic theory focuses on a small number of concepts. The most fundamental concept is the notion of opportunity cost. Opportunity Cost (or "Wow, I coulda had a V8!") The underlying idea is derived

More information

Internation1al Trade

Internation1al Trade 4.58 International Trade Class notes on 4/8/203 The Armington Model. Equilibrium Labor endowments L i for i = ; :::n CES utility ) CES price index P = i= (w i ij ) P j n Bilateral trade ows follow gravity

More information

Economics Computation Winter Prof. Garey Ramey. Exercises : 5 ; B = AX = B: 5 ; h 3 1 6

Economics Computation Winter Prof. Garey Ramey. Exercises : 5 ; B = AX = B: 5 ; h 3 1 6 Economics 80 - Computation Winter 01-18 Prof. Garey Ramey Exercises Exercise 1. Consider the following maices: 9 A = 1 8 ; B = 1 1 1 : a. Enter A and B as Matlab variables. b. Calculate the following maices:

More information

Macroeconomics II Dynamic macroeconomics Class 1: Introduction and rst models

Macroeconomics II Dynamic macroeconomics Class 1: Introduction and rst models Macroeconomics II Dynamic macroeconomics Class 1: Introduction and rst models Prof. George McCandless UCEMA Spring 2008 1 Class 1: introduction and rst models What we will do today 1. Organization of course

More information

4.3 - Linear Combinations and Independence of Vectors

4.3 - Linear Combinations and Independence of Vectors - Linear Combinations and Independence of Vectors De nitions, Theorems, and Examples De nition 1 A vector v in a vector space V is called a linear combination of the vectors u 1, u,,u k in V if v can be

More information

CHAPTER 7: TECHNIQUES OF INTEGRATION

CHAPTER 7: TECHNIQUES OF INTEGRATION CHAPTER 7: TECHNIQUES OF INTEGRATION DAVID GLICKENSTEIN. Introduction This semester we will be looking deep into the recesses of calculus. Some of the main topics will be: Integration: we will learn how

More information

The Implicit Function Theorem (IFT): key points

The Implicit Function Theorem (IFT): key points The Implicit Function Theorem (IFT): key points 1 The solution to any economic model can be characterized as the level set (LS) corresponding to zero of some function 1 Model: S = S(p;t), D = D(p), S =

More information

CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES. Likewise, we may define the higher order derivatives. f(x, y, z) = xy 2 + e zx. y = 2xy.

CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES. Likewise, we may define the higher order derivatives. f(x, y, z) = xy 2 + e zx. y = 2xy. April 15, 2009 CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES In this chapter D denotes an open subset of R n. 1. Introduction Definition 1.1. Given a function f : D R we define the second partial derivatives as

More information