Multivariate Regime Switching Model with Flexible. Threshold Variable: With an Application to Returns. from a Portfolio of U.S.

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Multivariate Regime Switching Model with Flexible. Threshold Variable: With an Application to Returns. from a Portfolio of U.S."

Transcription

1 Multivariate Regime Switching Model with Flexible Threshold Variable: With an Application to Returns from a Portfolio of U.S. Stocks Daniele Massacci Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance January 16, 2014 Abstract This paper proposes a novel multivariate regime switching model that allows the threshold variable to be a linear combination of covariates with unknown coef- cients. The paper considers least squares estimation of the model and provides a suitable algorithm; and it proposes a test for the number of regimes based on theoretical results from multivariate statistics. Finite sample results from Monte Carlo analysis strengthen the methodological contribution of the paper. An application to asset pricing in stock markets with a focus on portfolio allocation illustrates the This paper greatly bene ts from comments and suggestions from Massimo Guidolin. I am very grateful to Hashem Pesaran for letting me visit the Center for Applied Financial Economics (CAFE), USC, and for providing me with the data I used in this work. Valuable insights from a conversation with Marco Lippi are acknowledged. Errors and omissions are my own responsibility. Financial support from the Associazione Borsisti Marco Fanno and from UniCredit and Universities Foundation is gratefully acknowledged. Address correspondence to Daniele Massacci, EIEF, Via Sallustiana 62, Roma, Italy. Tel.: dm355@cantab.net. 1

2 usefulness of the proposed model for applied work. JEL classi cation: C32, C58, G12. Keywords: Multivariate Threshold Model, Flexible Threshold Variable, Stock Returns, Asset Pricing. 2

3 1 Introduction There now exists substantial empirical evidence that the data generating processes of many economic and nancial variables are well approximated by time series econometric models displaying a nite number of regimes: these models can either be univariate or multivariate, depending on the purpose of the analysis or the nature of the data (or both). A rst approach requires estimation and model selection in the presence of structural instabilities: for example, Paye and Timmermann (2006) follow Bai and Perron (1998) and document the presence of structural instabilities in models for ex post predictability of stock returns. When the underlying assumption is that "history repeats", regime switching models become a useful tool for empirical investigation (see Timmermann, 2008). Markov-Switching models as proposed in Hamilton (1989) assume that regime changes are driven by a latent variable: applications include Guidolin and Timmermann (2006a) to the term structure of risk, Ang et al. (2008) to interest rates, and Henkel et al. (2011) to stock returns. Under transition models, the prevailing regime depends on an observable variable, and the transition itself can be either smooth (see Terasvirta, 1994) or stepwise (see Tsay 1989; 1998), the latter generating threshold models: Audrino and Medeiros (2011) highlight the importance of smooth regimes in modelling interest rates; and Potter (1995) and Pesaran and Potter (1997) employ threshold models to investigate the dynamics of U.S. output. The focus of this paper is on transition models. An important component of these models is the variable that drives the dynamics between regimes. Common practice is to a priori choose a single observable variable such as the appropriately lagged dependent variable (see Tong, 1978; Terasvirta, 1994) or a more general exogenous covariate (see Hansen, 2000): this strategy would lead to model misspeci cation should the chosen 3

4 variable be di erent from the true one or should the regimes be driven by more than one covariate. Within the univariate framework, several studies have proposed exible parameterisations for the variable that determines the regime. Under smooth transition dynamics, Medeiros and Veiga (2003; 2005) and Becker and Osborn (2012) model the transition variable as an average of lagged values of the dependent variable. In threshold models, Seo and Linton (2007) propose a exible speci cation for the threshold variable based on a linear combination of exogenous covariates with unknown coe cients; and Massacci (2013a) modi es Seo and Linton s (2007) model to allow for a di erent identi cation strategy 1. The aforementioned contributions relate to univariate models and suitable extensions to multivariate counterparts are called for: this would be valuable for empirical work since "the search for an appropriate threshold variable [...] in an application needs a careful investigation," as stated in Tsay (1998) 2. This paper focuses on the class of threshold models and it extends to a multivariate framework the exible parameterisation for the threshold variable advanced in Seo and Linton (2007). The paper makes a number of methodological and empirical contributions. From a methodological standpoint, it explicitly addresses the issues of identi cation and estimation: it derives su cient conditions for the former to be achieved; and it provides an algorithm for the latter to be performed. It proposes a test for the number of regimes to be applied to the model: following Luukkonen et al. (1988), the test is speci ed in variable addition form and it is constructed by utilising results from multivariate statistics (see Anderson, 1984). Finally, in order to illustrate the potential empirical usefulness of the theoretical framework, the paper provides an empirical application to an asset pricing exercise in stock markets with a focus on portfolio allocation. 1 More discussion on this point is provided in Section See Tsay (1998), p

5 The rest of the paper is organised as follows: Section 2 introduces the model; Section 3 deals with the issues of identi cation and estimation; Section 4 develops a test to determine the number of regimes; Section 5 performs a Monte Carlo analysis; Section 6 provides an application to stock returns; nally, Section 7 concludes. 2 Model This paper introduces the model y t = (X t 1 + u 1t ) I ( 0 q t ) + (X t 2 + u 2t ) I ( 0 q t > ) ; t = 1; : : : ; T; (1) where I () is the indicator function; y t (y 1t ; : : : ; y Nt ) 0 2 Y R N is the N 1 vector of dependent variables; X t I N x 0 t is a N N (K x + 1) matrix, with x t 2 X R Kx+1 being a (K x + 1)1 vector of K x explanatory variables (which may include lagged values of y t ) and the intercept, denoting the Kronecker product, and I N being the N N identity matrix; the threshold variable 0 q t is a linear combination of the elements of the K q 1 vector of random variables q t (q 1t ; : : : ; q Nt ) 0 2 Q R Kq with coe cients 0; collected in the K q 1 vector of parameters 1 ; : : : ; Kq is the threshold value; 1 and 2 are N (K x + 1) 1 vectors de ned as j 0 j1; 0 j2; : : : ; jn 0 0 for j = 1; 2, where ji is of dimension (K x + 1) 1, for i = 1; : : : ; N; u 1t and u 2t are N 1 vectors of error terms such that E (u jt jx t ; q t ) = 0; E u jt u 0 jt jx t ; q t = j ; j = 1; 2; (2) where 1 and 2 are N N positive de nite matrices. 5

6 From a statistical standpoint, the model in (1) belongs to the general class of threshold models discussed in Tong (1978): according to the threshold principle introduced in Pearson (1900), the change in regime in the data generating process of y t occurs when the threshold variable 0 q t crosses the unknown threshold value. The model in (1) extends the class of multivariate threshold models proposed in Tsay (1998) by letting the threshold variable 0 q t be a linear combination of the elements of q t : this general speci cation has originally been suggested in Seo and Linton (2007) for univariate threshold models; for identi cation purposes, it has been modi ed in Massacci (2013a), as discussed more into details in Section 3.1 below. The speci cation in (1) and (2) allows for threshold e ects induced both on the conditional mean and the conditional variance of y t : letting vech () denote the half-vectorisation operator, the former and the latter are respectively de ned as 2 1 = ( ) 0 ; : : : ; ( 2N 1N ) ; : : : ; 0 N ; (3) and vech ( 2 ) vech ( 1 ) : (4) Several contributions have proposed exible parameterisations for the transition variable in transition models: Medeiros and Veiga (2003; 2005) and Becker and Osborn (2012) focus on univariate smooth transition models; Seo and Linton (2007) and Massacci (2013a) consider univariate threshold regressions; and Galvao and Marcellino (2012) propose a multivariate model analogous to (1) and (2) where the vector of parameters is assumed to be known a priori and does not have to be estimated. This paper therefore contributes to the literature in nonlinear time series econometrics by introducing a multivariate threshold model in which the threshold variable is a linear combination of the 6

7 elements of a random vector with unknown coe cients: it addresses the methodological issues of identi cation, estimation and testing for the number of regimes; and it provides an application to asset pricing in stock markets with a focus on portfolio allocation. 3 Identi cation and Estimation This section deals with identi cation and estimation of the model in (1) and (2): the former and the latter are addressed in Sections 3.1 and 3.2, respectively. 3.1 Identi cation The model in (1) and (2) is piecewise linear: whereas the linear component within each regime does not pose any identi cation issue, the argument of the indicator function I () needs to be suitably constrained. To this purpose, let L and A be the parameter spaces of and, respectively, with generic elements labelled l and a, respectively. The following de nition is introduced: De nition 3.1 The model in (1) and (2) is said to be identi ed if 0 P [I ( 0 q t ) = I (l 0 q t a)] < 1; 8l 2 L; 8a 2 A: Let denote the Cartesian product operator. According to De nition 3.1, the model in (1) and (2) is identi ed provided that I (l 0 q t a) evaluated at l = and a = is di erent from I (l 0 q t a) in any other point in L A with positive probability. Given De nition 3.1, the vector of parameters ( 0 ; ) 0 is observationally equivalent to (l 0 ; a) 0 = v ( 0 ; ) 0 7

8 for 0 < v < 1: formally, P [I ( 0 q t ) = I (v 0 q t v)] = 1; 80 < v < 1; and the model is not identi ed. Let Kq denote the K q 1 vector of ones. Theorem 3.1 below provides su cient conditions for identi cation: Theorem 3.1 The model in (1) and (2) is identi ed according to De nition 3.1 if at least one of the following two conditions is satis ed: (a) m = c m for at least one m = 1; : : : ; K q, where c m is a known constant such that c m 6= 0; (b) 0 Kq = c, where c is a known constant such that c 6= 0. Proof of Theorem 3.1. See Appendix A. Theorem 3.1 provides su cient conditions for identi cation of the model in (1) and (2): condition (a) is more general than the one in Seo and Linton (2007), which imposes c m = 1 for one m = 1; : : : ; K q ; and condition (b) extends Theorem 3.1 in Massacci (2013a) by allowing for c 6= 0 rather than c > 0. Condition (b) will be used in the Monte Carlo analysis and in the empirical application in Sections 5 and 6, respectively. 3.2 Least Squares Estimation This section looks at estimation of the model in (1) and (2): the least squares estimator and the related proposed algorithm are illustrated in Sections and 3.2.2, respectively. 8

9 3.2.1 Least Squares Estimator The model in (1) and (2) is estimated by least squares by suitably extending the theory developed in Tsay (1998). To this purpose, de ne I 1t (l; a) I (l 0 q t a) ; I 2t (l; a) I (l 0 q t > a) ; 8l 2 L; 8a 2 A; and P T j (l; a) T I jt (l; a) ; j = 1; 2; 8l 2 L; 8a 2 A: t=1 For given l and a, the least squares estimators for 1 and 2, and for 1 and 2, are T P 1 T P ^ j (l; a) = I jt (l; a) X 0 tx t I jt (l; a) X 0 ty t ; j = 1; 2; 8l 2 L; 8a 2 A; t=1 t=1 and ^ j (l; a) = TP t=1 h i h i 0 I jt (l; a) y t X t^j (l; a) y t X t^j (l; a) ; j = 1; 2; 8l 2 L; 8a 2 A; T j (l; a) (K x + 1) respectively. De ne S (l; a) 2 P j=1 h i S j (l; a) ; S j (l; a) [T j (l; a) (K x + 1)] tr ^ j (l; a) ; j = 1; 2; 8l 2 L; 8a 2 A; where tr () denotes the trace operator; the estimator for ( 0 ; ) 0 is then de ned as ^0 ; ^ 0 arg min (l 0 ;a) 0 2(LA) S (l; a) : 9

10 Finally, the least squares estimators for 1, 2, 1 and 2 are de ned as ^ j ^ j ^; ^ ; ^ j ^ j ^; ^ ; j = 1; 2: Let a:s:! and d! denote almost sure convergence and convergence in distribution, respectively. Under conditions analogous to those imposed in Assumption 1 in Tsay (1998), as T! 1 it follows that ^0 ; ^ 0 a:s:! ( 0 ; ) 0 ; ^j a:s:! j ; ^ j a:s:! j ; j = 1; 2; and h T j ^; ^ i 1/2 ^j j d! N (0; j j ) ; j = 1; 2 : the (K x + 1) (K x + 1) matrix j is de ned as j fe [I jt (; ) x t x 0 t]g 1 ; j = 1; 2; and it is estimated as ^j h i 1 P T T j ^; ^ I jt ^; ^ x t x 0 t t=1 1 a:s:! j ; j = 1; 2: Estimation Algorithm From a computational standpoint, this paper extends Massacci (2013a) and proposes a two-step algorithm to rst estimate ( 0 ; ) 0 and then 1, 2, 1 and 2 : the algorithm rst estimates ( 0 ; ) 0 by constructing an objective function de ned on the parameter space L A of ( 0 ; ) 0 only; it then estimates 1, 2, 1 and 2 given the estimator for 10

11 ( 0 ; ) 0 obtained in the rst step. The proposed algorithm is implemented as follows: 0 1. De ne the set L L 1 L Kq with generic point l l 1 ; : : : ; l Kq 2 L such that l m 2 L m, for m = 1; : : : ; K q : L can be constructed according to economic arguments such as those put forward in Section 6. For l 2 L, de ne the set A (l) with generic element a (l) 2 A (l): as in Tong and Lim (1980), Tsay (1989) and Kapetanios (2000), the elements of A (l) are given quantiles of the empirical distribution function of l 0 q t. For all l 2 L and a (l) 2 A (l), consider T P 1 T P ^ j [l; a (l)] = I jt [l; a (l)] X 0 tx t I jt [l; a (l)] X 0 ty t ; j = 1; 2; t=1 t=1 and ^ j [l; a (l)] = TP t=1 n I jt [l; a (l)] y t o hn X t^j [l; a (l)] y t T j [l; a (l)] (K x + 1) oi 0 X t^j [l; a (l)] ; j = 1; 2; and de ne S [l; a (l)] 2 P j=1 o S j [l; a (l)] ; S j [l; a (l)] ft j [l; a (l)] (K x + 1)g tr n^ j [l; a (l)] ; j = 1; 2 : the least squares estimator for ( 0 ; ) 0 is then obtained as ^0 ; ^ 0 = arg min [l 0 ;a(l)] 0 2LA(l) S [l; a (l)] : 2. Given ^0 ; ^ 0, the estimators for 1, 2, 1 and 2 are obtained as in Section

12 4 Testing for the Number of Regimes This section deals with the problem of testing for the number of regimes in the model in (1) and (2): it provides an introduction to the problem in Section 4.1 and it proposes a formal testing procedure in Section Preliminary Discussion A question that naturally arises is whether regimes are actually present in the data generating process of the variables of interest: in order to provide an answer, a formal testing procedure has to be developed. The model in (1) and (2) reduces to y t = X t + u t ; E (u t jx t ; q t ) = 0; E (u t u 0 t jx t ; q t ) = ; t = 1; : : : ; T; under the single-regime null hypothesis H 0 : ( 1 = 2 = ) \ ( 1 = 2 = ), and the parameters vector ( 0 ; ) 0 no longer is identi ed: this is an example of the Davies problem, rst addressed in Davies (1977; 1987). As compared to the framework considered in Tsay (1998), the set of unidenti ed parameters includes the vector of parameters, as well as the threshold value. Several solutions to the Davies problem exist for threshold models: Hansen (1996) develops statistical tests based on empirical process theory; Petruccelli and Davies (1986) and Tsay (1989; 1998) transform threshold regressions into changepoint models by using arranged regressions; and Luukkonen et al. (1988) treat threshold models as limiting cases of logistic smooth transition models and construct variable addition tests by applying Taylor approximations of suitable order to the transition function. In order to construct a test for the number of regimes, this paper suitably extends the 12

13 procedure advanced in Luukkonen et al. (1988) to the model of interest. To this purpose, de ne the logistic function F (z) [1 + exp ( z)] 1 ; z 2 R; (5) and consider the model y t = (X t 1 + u 1t ) f1 F [h ( 0 q t )]g + (X t 2 + u 2t ) F [h ( 0 q t )] ; h > 0; t = 1; : : : ; T; (6) where u 1t and u 2t are de ned as in (2). The model in (5) and (6) extends the univariate set up considered in Medeiros and Veiga (2003; 2005) and Becker and Osborn (2012) by introducing a multivariate logistic smooth transition model with exible transition variable, which nests (1) as a limiting case as h! 1. The speci cation for the conditional mean of y t in (6) is equivalent to y t = X t 1 + X t F [h ( 0 q t )] + u t ; h > 0; t = 1; : : : ; T; (7) where is de ned in (3) and u t u 1t f1 F [h ( 0 q t )]g + u 2t F [h ( 0 q t )] : the single-regime null hypothesis is then stated as H 0 : h = 0. Following Luukkonen et al. (1988), a test for the single-regime null hypothesis can be constructed as a variable addition test by applying a Taylor approximation of suitable order to the transition function F (): as in Harvill and Ray (1999), this results in a multivariate extension of 13

14 Tsay s (1986) univariate test. 4.2 Testing Procedure The rst-order Taylor approximation of the function F (z) in (5) about z = 0 is F (z) ' z; (8) 4 and application of (8) to (7) leads to the auxiliary model 1 y t = X t 1 + X t h (0 q t ) + t = X t h hx t 0 q t + t : (9) Notice that x 0 t i 0 q t = vec (x 0 t i 0 q t ) = (q 0 t x 0 t) vec i 0 ; i = 1; : : : ; N; where vec () denotes the vectorisation operator and de ne 1 = h h0 1 ; : : : ; 0 1N N 4 h0 N ( 0 11; : : : ; 0 1N) 0 0 ; (10) h vec 1 0 ; : : : ; vec N 0 0 ( 0 21; : : : ; 0 2N) 0 ; (11) and Z t I N (q 0 t x 0 t) ; 14

15 where 1 is an N (K x + 1) 1 vector, 2 is a N [K q (K x + 1)] 1 vector, Z t is a N N [K q (K x + 1)] matrix, and i and i are de ned in (3) for i = 1; : : : ; N: the model in (9) is then equivalent to y t = X t 1 + Z t 2 + t ; (12) and the test for the number of regimes is obtained by testing the null hypothesis H 0 : 2 = 0 against the alternative H 1 : 2 6= 0. The test for the number of regimes can be equivalently implemented as follows. De ne the N 1 vector of residuals under the null hypothesis of linearity as ~ t y t X t ~ 1 ; t = 1; : : : ; T; where ~ 1 is the least squares estimator of 1 from (12) under H 0 : 2 = 0. Construct the auxiliary regression ~ t X t 1 + Z t 2 + w t ; t = 1; : : : ; T; with N 1 vector of residuals ^w t. De ne the total sum of squares SST, the errors sum of squares SSE, and the Wilks lambda statistic as SST T P t=1 ~ t ~ 0 t; SSE T P t=1 ^w t ^w 0 t; det (SSE) det (SST) ; respectively, where det () denotes the determinant operator. As T! 1, the test statistic LM = gd b 1 1/2 F [NK NK q (K x + 1) 1/2 q (K x + 1) ; gd b] (13) 15

16 under the single-regime null hypothesis 3, where b NK q (K x + 1) 2 1; d " N 2 K 2 q (K x + 1) 2 4 N 2 + K 2 q (K x + 1) 2 5 # 1/2 ; g T (K x + 1) 1 2 [N + K q (K x + 1) + 1] : When the dimensionality of the model is N = 2, the LM test statistic de ned in (13) reduces to 4 LM = T (K x + 1) K q (K x + 1) 1 K q (K x + 1) 1 1/2 1/2 F f2k q (K x + 1) ; 2 [T (K x + 1) K q (K x + 1) 1]g : (14) The power of the proposed test deserves some discussion. The asymptotic distribution of the LM statistic in (13) is derived under the null hypothesis of no threshold e ect in the conditional mean and variance of y t : the test has then power when the threshold e ect is induced only on the conditional second moment, namely when = 0 and 6= 0, where and are de ned in (3) and (4), respectively. Following Luukkonen et al. (1988), the test deserves special attention when 6= 0 and = 0: as proved in Appendix B, when P (q t = Sx t ) = 1 where S is a K q (K x + 1) matrix of coe cients (i.e., when each element of q t is a linear combination of the elements of x t ), the test does not have power against the alternative that the threshold e ect is induced only on the intercept in all equations in the system or in a subset of them; since this case is not relevant for the empirical analysis in Section 6, this paper does not address the problem and leaves it to future research 5. 3 See Anderson (1984), Section 8:5:4. 4 See Anderson (1984), p. 305, Theorem 8:4:6. 5 As in Luukkonen et al. (1988), the problem is solved by using higher order expansions of the function 16

17 5 Monte Carlo Analysis This section assesses the nite sample properties of the least squares estimator and of the test for the number of regimes in relation to the model proposed in this paper: the Monte Carlo design and the results are illustrated in Sections 5.1 and 5.2, respectively. 5.1 Design The Monte Carlo experiment addresses the issues of estimation and inference on the number of regimes, and the speci c designs are presented in Sections and 5.1.2, respectively Estimation The Data Generating Process (DGP) is y r it = ( 1i1 + x r t 1i2 + u r 1it) I [q r 1t + (1 ) q r 2t ] + [ 2i1 + x r t 2i2 + u r 2it] I [q r 1t + (1 ) q r 2t > ] ; i = 1; 2; t = 1; : : : ; T; (15) where r = 1; : : : ; R, r refers to the replication, T is the sample size, and R is the total number of replications. The experiment is run in Ox 7:01 (see Doornik, 2012). The sample sizes T are equal to T = 125; 250; 500; The number of replications is equal to R = The seed of the random number generator is equal to 1. The restrictions 111 = 112 = 121 = 122 = 1 and 211 = 212 = 221 = 222 = 2 are imposed: the same threshold e ect is induced on the intercept and on the slope coe cient in both equations and it is equal to ( 2 1 ). The scalar parameters 1, 2 and are xed throughout the replications. F (z) in (5). 17

18 Three features of the model are controlled for: (i) the value of that assigns the weights to q1t r and q2t r in (15); (ii) the magnitude of the threshold e ect ; (iii) the proportion of observations of q1t r + (1 ) q2t r below. The variables x r t, q1t r and q2t r in (15) are generated as x r t = x (1 x ) + x x r t 1 + (1 2 x) 1/2 r xt; t = 49; : : : ; 0; : : : ; T; x 50 = x ; and q r mt = q 1 q + q q r m;t q 1/2 r qmt; t = 49; : : : ; 0; : : : ; T; q r m; 50 = q ; m = 1; 2; where x, x, q and q are xed in repeated samples, with x N (1; 1), x U (0:05; 0:95) and q U (0:05; 0:95), while the choice of q is described below. The shocks r xt, r q 1 t and r q 2 t are generated as r xt = xqf r t + r xt 2 xq + 1 1/2 ; r q mt = xqf r t + r q mt 2 xq + 1 1/2 t = 49; : : : ; 0; : : : ; T; m = 1; 2; where f r t IIDN (0; 1), r xt IIDN (0; 1), r q 1 t IIDN (0; 1), r q 2 t IIDN (0; 1) and xq = 1: in this way, E (x r t ) = x ; E (q r 1t) = E (q r 2t) = q ; Var (x r t) = Var (q r 1t) = Var (q r 2t) = 1; and Corr (x r t ; q r 1t) = Corr (x r t ; q r 2t) = Var (q r 1t; q r 2t) = 0:5: In order to reduce the e ect induced by the initial values x 50 = x, q r 1; 50 = q and 18

19 q r 2; 50 = q, the rst 50 observations in the DGP for x r t, q r 1t and q r 2t are discarded. The shocks u r 11t, u r 21t, u r 12t and u r 22t in (15) are generated as u r jit = uf r t + r u i t ( 2 u + 1) 1/2 j; i; j = 1; 2; t = 1; : : : ; T; where r u i t IIDN (0; 1), and u, 2 1 and 2 2 are xed in repeated samples with u = 1, 2 1 = 1 and 2 2 = 2: in this way, Var u r j1t = Var u r j2t = 2 j ; Corr u r j1t; u r j2t = 0:5; j = 1; 2; and the threshold e ect induced on the conditional second moment de ned in (4) is equal to = (1; 0:5; 1) 0. Two values for in (15) are considered, namely = 0:10; 0:50. In order to control for the threshold e ect on the slope coe cients, ( 2 1 ) is set equal to = 0:25; 1:00; 1:75: given 1 = 1, 2 is assigned the values 2 = 1:25; 2:00; 2:75, respectively. In order to control for the proportion of observations of q r 1t + (1 ) q r 2t lying below, the latter is set equal to = 2. It follows that P [q1t r + (1 ) q2t r ] 8 q1t r + (1 ) q2t r E (q1t) r + (1 ) E (q2t) r >< 2 Var (q = P 1t) r + (1 ) 2 Var (q2t) r + 2 (1 ) Cov (q1t; r q2t) r 1/2 E (q r >: 1t) + (1 ) E (q2t) r 2 Var (q1t) r + (1 ) 2 Var (q2t) r + 2 (1 ) Cov (q1t; r q2t) r 1/2 " # = x ; 1/2 9 >= >; where () denotes the cumulative distribution function of a random variable with a standard normal distribution; the analytical expression for x is then obtained in closed 19

20 form as x = 1 () /2 : Five values for are considered, namely = 0:15; 0:30; 0:50; 0:70; 0:85. The parameters of the model in (15) are estimated by means of the procedure discussed in Section In order to estimate, the set of points L is a priori de ned as L f0:00; 0:10; 0:20; 0:30; 0:40; 0:50; 0:60; 0:70; 0:80; 0:90; 1:00g ; for l 2 L, the set A (l) is made of 19 equally spaced quantiles of the empirical distribution function of lq r 1t + (1 l) q r 2t, namely 5%; 10%; 15%; : : : ; 85%; 90%; 95%, and the true value = 2. The focus is on estimation of 111, 112, and in (15). The estimators are assessed by computing bias and RMSE. In the case of 111, these are de ned as bias = 1 R RP r=1 r 1 2; ^r ; RMSE = ^r 111 R 111 respectively, where ^ r 111 denotes the estimate of 111 obtained from the r th replication; analogous de nitions hold in the case of 112, and. In the case of 111 and 112, the size of the tests for the null hypotheses H 0 : 111 = 1 and H 0 : 112 = 1 obtained from the relevant t-statistics at 5% signi cance level are also reported Inference on the Number of Regimes In order to assess the size of the proposed test for the number of regimes, the DGP is y r it = i1 + x r t i2 + u r it; i = 1; 2; t = 1; : : : ; T; 20

21 where 11 = 12 = 21 = 22 = = 1; the variable x r t is generated as described in Section 5.1.1; the shocks u r 1t and u r 2t are generated as u r it = uft r + r u i t ; i = 1; 2; t = 1; : : : ; T; ( 2 1/2 u + 1) where r u 1 t IIDN (0; 1), r u 2 t IIDN (0; 1), and u and 2 are xed in repeated samples and set equal to u = 1 and 2 = 1. The power of the test is assessed by using the DGP described in Section Under this set up, the dimensionality of the system is N = 2 and the test statistic is constructed according to (14). 5.2 Results Results from model estimation are shown in Tables 1 4, whereas size and power properties of the test for the number of regimes are summarised in Table 5. Table 1 about here Table 2 about here Table 3 about here Table 4 about here Table 5 about here The bias of the least squares estimators for 111 and 112 (see Tables 1 and 2, respectively) is always of limited magnitude, with the exception of the case in which the threshold e ect is small (i.e., = 0:25), the relevant regime occurs rarely (i.e., = 0:15) and 21

22 the sample size is not large enough to let asymptotic results hold (i.e., T = 125; 250; 500); other conditions being equal, the bias tends to decrease in, T and, while it shows no dependence upon. The RMSE tends to decrease in (with the exception of the case T = 125 and = 0:25), T and, and it is not dependent on. The empirical size of the tests approaches the theoretical value as, T and increase, and it is independent of. Bias and RMSE of the estimators for and (see Tables 3 and 4, respectively) have similar behaviour to those of the estimators for 111 and 112 previously discussed. Finally, the test for the number of regimes (see Table 5) is always correctly sized; as expected, the power of the test monotonically increases in T and. In conclusion, the least squares estimators for 111, 112, and, and the proposed test for the number of regimes have desirable nite sample properties: this paper then provides a valid tool for applied work. 6 Empirical Application This section provides an empirical application of the theory developed in this paper to an asset pricing problem in stock markets with a focus on portfolio allocation: the aim is to show how the proposed model may be used to characterise the degree of crosssectional dependence between returns from portfolios of assets, which plays a key role in diversi cation strategies. In what follows, Section 6.1 provides a description of the data and model speci cation, and Section 6.2 presents the results. 22

23 6.1 Data and Model Speci cation Following Perez-Quiros and Timmermann (2000; 2001), this paper looks at nonlinear dynamics in the joint distribution of U.S. stock returns as related to capitalisation e ects. The vector of dependent variables consists of monthly excess returns (in percentage terms) on size-sorted decile portfolios over the benchmark T -bill rate collected from the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP): the sample period begins in January 1957 and ends in December 2012, a total of 672 observations. Descriptive statistics and correlation matrix for the dependent variables are reported in Table 6. Table 6 about here Two features are worth highlighting: in line with standard asset pricing models, mean and standard deviations decline almost monotonically as one moves from smallest rms to largest rms portfolios; and the correlation between portfolios is higher the closer they are ranked in terms of degree of market capitalisation. Joint analysis of nonlinear dynamics of random variables requires a multivariate system: following Guidolin and Timmermann (2006b), a two-regime system is employed as only stock returns are considered. For i = 1; : : : ; 10, the model for the excess return it at time t is it = ( 1i1 + 1i2 I t 1 + 1i3 Def t 1 + 1i4 Y ield t 1 + u 1it ) I Cli t 2 (1 ) V ol t 1 + ( 2i1 + 2i2 I t 1 + 2i3 Def t 1 + 2i4 Y ield t 1 + u 2it ) I Cli t 2 (1 ) V ol t 1 > : The right-hand side variables consist of monthly observations from Welch and Goyal s 23

24 (2008) updated dataset 6, augmented by the composite leading indicator. The predictors I t 1, Def t 1 and Y ield t 1 are one-month lagged values of the 3 month Treasury Bill Secondary Market rate, the default premium measured as the di erence between the yields on BAA and AAA-rated corporate bonds, and the dividend yield, respectively, all multiplied by 100: these are all consistent with the model employed in Perez-Quiroz and Timmermann (2001). The variables Cli t 2 and V ol t 1 are standardised values for the year-on-year log-di erence in the composite leading indicator and for the stock variance (computed as sum of squared daily returns on the S&P 500), respectively 7 : the choice of the former and the latter as variables driving the regimes follows arguments put forward in Perez-Quiroz and Timmermann (2000) and Massacci (2013b), respectively; and the linear combination Cli t 2 (1 ) V ol t 1 is motivated by the fact that volatility increases during recessions (see Schwert, 1989). The event Cli t 2 (1 ) V ol t 1 (Cli t 2 (1 ) V ol t 1 > ) then identi es a regime with low (high) growth rate in the composite leading indicator and high (low) volatility in the stock market. In order to empirically assess the contribution of the paper, the model is estimated for = 0, = 1 and 2 [0; 1]: the threshold variable is then equal to V ol t 1, Cli t 2, and a convex linear combination of the two, respectively. The analysis is conducted in Ox 7:01 (see Doornik, 2012). For 2 [0; 1], the algorithm suggested in Section is used: and are estimated by searching over L f0:00; 0:01; 0:02; : : : ; 0:98; 0:99; 1:00g and over A (l) made of the f15%; 16%; 17%; : : : ; 83%; 84%; 85%g quantiles of the empirical distribution function of lcli t 2 (1 l) V ol t 1, for l 2 L. For = 0 and = 1, the search for is made over the f15%; 16%; 17%; : : : ; 83%; 84%; 85%g quantiles of (1 l) V ol t 1 6 The dataset is kindly made available online at 7 The variable Cli t 2 is lagged by two periods because macroeconomic indicators are not available in real time. Both Cli t 2 and V ol t 1 are standardised variables for two reasons: to prevent any of them dominating the indicator function I (); and to ensure that Cli t 2 (1 ) V ol t 1 is a pure number. 24

25 and Cli t 2, respectively. It is important to stress that a model for the joint distribution of returns from all decile-sorted portfolios has not been previously constructed and estimated: this therefore provides a further contribution of the paper; and it allows to characterise the risk of the whole portfolio in terms of the conditional covariance matrix. 6.2 Results The test proposed in Section 4.2 as applied to the model described in Section 6.1 strongly rejects the null hypothesis of one regime in the joint distribution of excess stock returns from size-sorted decile portfolios and the multivariate threshold system is estimated 8. Results from model estimation are shown in Tables 7 and 8. Table 7 about here Table 8 about here Given the contribution of the paper, it is important to understand how the model with exible threshold variable di ers from those in which either Cli t 2 or V ol t 1 are a priori chosen. To this purpose, Table 7 shows results from estimation of the regime indicator I Cli t 2 (1 ) V ol t 1 and from characterisation of the degree of cross-sectional dependence when is equal to the least squares estimator ^ and under the restrictions = 0 and = 1. The degree of cross-sectional dependence is measured by computing the maximum eigenvalue of the conditional correlation matrix in each regime 9 : this provides valuable information that can be used for asset allocation purposes. 8 The p-value of the test for the number of regimes is equal to 0: See Bailey et al. (2013) and the references therein for an overview of the literature on measuring cross-sectional dependence. 25

26 The features of the estimated regime indicator I Cli t 2 (1 ) V ol t 1 markedly depend on the assumption made about the threshold variable (see Panel A). Under the exible parameterisation proposed in this paper, the least squares estimators for and are equal to ^ = 0:20 and ^ = 0:1878, respectively: the event ^Cli t 2 1 ^ V ol t 1 ^ occurs with a sample frequency equal to 0:5506 and displays a correlation with the NBER recession indicator equal to 0:3716. The estimation results are di erent under the restrictions = 0 and = 1: the estimated threshold values are equal to 0:2720 and 0:1493, respectively; the sample means of the regime indicators are equal to 0:6101 and 0:4196, respectively; and the correlations between the estimated regime indicator and the NBER recession indicator are equal to 0:2337 and 0:4862, respectively. Therefore, consistently with the speci cation of the threshold variable Cli t 2 (1 ) V ol t 1, the numerical results from the exible parameterisation always lie between those obtained by a priori imposing the restrictions : this highlights the relevance of the exible speci cation proposed in this paper, as a priori restrictions on may lead to misleading empirical ndings. In order to get a sense of the economic relevance of the proposed exible model, it is instructive to consider the degree of cross-sectional dependence as measured by the maximum eigenvalue of the conditional correlation matrix in each regime (see Panel B): the higher such a dependence, the less e ective portfolio diversi cation involving only stocks will be, and the more investors will have to search for alternative asset classes to invest in (e.g., bonds). Under the exible model, the maximum eigenvalues under the regimes Cli t 2 (1 ) V ol t 1 and Cli t 2 (1 ) V ol t 1 > are equal to 374:479 and 212:982, respectively: the maximum eigenvalue decreases when shifting from the rst to the second regime, which means that conditional cross-sectional 26

27 dependence is higher in the former than in the latter. The same monotonic relationship is found when the restrictions = 0 and = 1 are a priori imposed: under the regime Cli t 2 (1 ) V ol t 1, the maximum eigenvalues are equal to 396:911 and 348:032, respectively; and to 153:985 and 268:280, respectively, when the event Cli t 2 (1 ) V ol t 1 > occurs. In both regimes, the eigenvalues from the exible model lie between those from the speci cations under the restrictions = 0 and = 1: therefore, a priori restrictions imposed on the indicator function may bias the estimate of portfolio risk (as captured by the conditional second moment), with potential consequences for allocation strategies. Table 8 presents results for the estimated conditional means, standard deviations and correlations from the exible threshold model (see Panels A, B and C, respectively). Given the contribution of the paper in relation to the empirical analysis, the focus of the discussion is on the conditional correlations (see Panel C): consistently with the monotonic relationship found in the maximum eigenvalues, correlations are generally (although not always) higher in the regime Cli t 2 (1 ) V ol t 1 than when the event Cli t 2 (1 ) V ol t 1 > occurs. 7 Conclusions This paper has generalised the class of multivariate threshold regression models considered in Tsay (1998) to let the threshold variable be a linear combination of variables with unknown coe cients: in this way, the potential problem of model misspeci cation is tackled as the threshold variable no longer needs to be a priori selected. The paper has made a number of methodological and empirical contributions. On the methodological side, it has provided su cient conditions for identi cation of the model, 27

28 it has suggested an algorithm to obtain the least squares estimator for the parameters, and it has developed a test for the number of regimes based on results from multivariate statistics: all methodological contributions have been supported by a comprehensive Monte Carlo analysis. The theoretical framework has then been applied to an asset pricing exercise in stock markets with a focus on portfolio allocation: this has illustrated how the proposed model may be used to characterise the degree of cross-sectional dependence between returns from stock portfolios. This work can be extended along several dimensions. One in particular is worth discussing, namely the application of the proposed model to an asset allocation problem: to this purpose, the contribution by Song et al. (2012) would be a useful starting point. Asset allocation problems have been considered within the framework of Markov-Switching (see Guidolin and Timmermann, 2008) and structural break models (see Pettenuzzo and Timmermann, 2011): the multivariate threshold model proposed in this paper would then provide a useful complementary tool. A Proof of Theorem 3.1 In order to prove part (a), without loss of generality assume that 1 = c 1 so that 0 q t = c 1 q 1t + PK q m=2 m q mt : For c 1 = 0 it follows that P " I PK q m=2 m q mt! = I PK q m=2 v m q mt v!# = 1; 80 < v < 1; 28

29 and the condition stated in De nition 3.1 fails to hold. If 0 < c 1 < 1 then " P I q 1t PK q c 1 m=2 m c 1 q mt! = I q 1t v c 1 PK q m=2 v m q mt c 1!# = 1, v = 1; and the condition stated in De nition 3.1 holds: the case 1 < c 1 < 0 is analogous and omitted. This concludes the proof of part (a). In order to prove part (b), since 0 Kq = c then 1 = c P Kq m=2 m and 0 q t = 1 q 1t + PK q m=2 m q mt = cq 1t + PK q m=2 m (q mt q 1t ) : For c = 0 it follows that P ( I " PK q m=2 m (q mt q 1t ) # = I " PK q m=2 v m (q mt q 1t ) v #) = 1; 80 < v < 1; and the condition stated in De nition 3.1 fails to hold. If 0 < c < 1 then ( " P I q 1t c PK q m=2 m c (q mt q 1t ) # = I " q 1t v c PK q m=2 v m c (q mt q 1t ) #) = 1, v = 1; and the condition stated in De nition 3.1 holds: the case 1 < c < 0 is analogous and omitted. This concludes the proof of part (b) and of the theorem. B Power of the Test for the Number of Regimes This appendix proves that under the condition P (q t = Sx t ) = 1 imposed on the system in (1) and (2), the test for the number of regimes proposed in Section 4.2 does not have power against the alternative that the threshold e ect is induced only on the intercept in 29

30 all equations in the system or in a subset of them. To this purpose, write (12) as y it = x 0 t 1i + (q 0 t x 0 t) 2i + it ; i = 1; : : : ; N; t = 1; : : : ; T; (16) where 1i and 2i are de ned in (10) and (11), respectively. Let the K q (K x + 1) matrix S be de ned as S s 1 ; : : : ; s Kq 0 ; sm (s m1 ; _s 0 m) 0 ; m = 1; : : : ; K q ; where s m is a (K x + 1) 1 vector, for m = 1; : : : ; K q ; decompose x t, 1i and 2i as x t (1; _x 0 t) 0 ; and 1i 1i1 ; _ 1i ; 2i 0 2i1; : : : ; 0 2iK q ; 0 2im 2im1 ; _ 2im 0 0 ; m = 1; : : : ; Kq ; where 2im is a (K x + 1) 1 vector. Under the condition 2 0 P (q t = Sx t ) = 1, P q t = 6 B s C A x t = 1, P q t = 7 6 B 5 s 11 ; _s C A 1 _x t 3 1 C A = s 0 K q s Kq1; _s 0 K q 2 0, P q t = 6 B s 11 + _s 0 1 _x t. s Kq1 + _s 0 K q _x t 13 = 1 C7 A5 30

31 the model in (16) becomes y it = x 0 t 1i + (q 0 t x 0 t) 2i + it = (1; _x 0 t) 1i1 ; _ 0 0 i 0 1i + hs 11 + _s 01 _x t ; : : : ; s Kq1 + _s 0Kq _x t (1; _x 0 t) 0 2i1; : : : ; 0 2iK q + it = (1; _x 0 t) 1i1 ; _ 0 0 1i + s 11 + _s 0 1 _x t ; s 11 _x 0 t + _s 0 1 _x t _x 0 t; : : : ; s Kq1 + _s 0 K q _x t ; s Kq1 _x 0 t + _s 0 K q _x t _x 0 t 2i11 ; _ 02i1; : : : ; 2iKq1; _ 0 02iKq + it = 1i1 + _x 0 t _ 1i + PK q m=1 (s m1 + _s 0 m _x t ) 2im1 + PK q m=1 (s m1 + _s 0 m _x t ) _x 0 t _ 2im + it = 1i1 + PK q m=1 s m1 2im1! + _x 0 t " _ 1i + PK q m=1 _s m 2im1 + s m1 _ 2im # + _x 0 t PK q m=1! 0 _s m _ 2im _x t + it : for i = 1; : : : ; N and m = 1; : : : ; K q, 2im1 cannot be separately identi ed from 1i1 and _ 1i, and the test does not have power against the alternative that the threshold e ect is induced only on the intercept in all equations in the system or in a subset of them. References [1] Anderson, T. W. (1984), An Introduction to Multivariate Statistical Analysis, 2nd ed., New York: John Wiley. [2] Ang, A., G. Bekaert, and M.Wei (2008), "The Term Structure of Real Rates and Expected In ation," Journal of Finance, 63 (2),

32 [3] Audrino, F. and M. Medeiros (2011), "Modeling and Forecasting Short-term Interest Rates: The Bene ts of Smooth Regimes, Macroeconomic Variables and Bagging," Journal of Applied Econometrics, 26 (6), [4] Bai, J. and P. Perron (1998), "Estimating and Testing Linear Models with Multiple Structural Changes," Econometrica, 66 (1), [5] Bailey, N., G. Kapetanios and M. H. Pesaran, "Exponent of Cross-Sectional Dependence: Estimation and Inference," mimeo. [6] Becker, R. and D. R. Osborn (2012), "Weighted Smooth Transition Regressions," Journal of Applied Econometrics, 27 (5), [7] Davies, R. B. (1977), "Hypothesis Testing when a Nuisance Parameter Is Present Only under the Alternative", Biometrika, 64 (2), [8] Davies, R. B. (1987), "Hypothesis Testing When a Nuisance Parameter Is Present Only Under the Alternative", Biometrika, 74 (1), [9] Doornik, J. A. (2012), Ox 7: An Object-orientated Matrix Programming Language, London: Timberlake Consultants Press. [10] Galvao, A. B. and M. Marcellino (2012), "The E ect of the Monetary Policy Stance on the Transmission Mechanism," Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics, forthcoming. [11] Guidolin, M. and A. Timmermann (2006a), "Term Structure of Risk under Alternative Econometric Speci cations," Journal of Econometrics, 131 (1 2),

33 [12] Guidolin, M. and A. Timmermann (2006b), "An Econometric Model of Nonlinear Dynamics in the Joint Distribution of Stock and Bond Returns", Journal of Applied Econometrics, 21 (1), [13] Guidolin, M. and A. Timmermann (2008), "International Asset Allocation under Regime Switching, Skew, and Kurtosis Preferences," Review of Financial Studies, 21 (2), [14] Hamilton, J. D. (1989), "A New Approach to the Economic Analysis of Nonstationary Time Series and the Business Cycle," Econometrica, 57 (2), [15] Hansen, B. E. (1996), "Inference When a Nuisance Parameter Is Not Identi ed Under the Null Hypothesis", Econometrica, 64 (2), [16] Hansen, B. E. (2000), "Sample Splitting and Threshold Estimation", Econometrica, 68 (3), [17] Harvill, J. L. and B. K. Ray (1999), "A Note on Tests for Nonlinearity in a Vector Time Series", Biometrika, 86 (3), [18] Henkel, S. J., J. S. Martin and F. Nardari (2011), Time-varying short horizon predictability, Journal of Financial Economics, 99 (3), [19] Kapetanios, G. (2000), "Small Sample Properties of the Conditional Least Squares Estimator in SETAR Models", Economics Letters, 69 (3), [20] Luukkonen, R., P. Saikkonen and T. Teräsvirta (1988), "Testing Linearity Against Smooth Transition Autoregressive Models", Biometrika, 75 (3),

34 [21] Massacci, D. (2013a), "A Switching Model with Flexible Threshold Variable: With an Application to Nonlinear Dynamics in Stock Returns," Economics Letters, 119 (2), [22] Massacci, D. (2013b), "A Two-Regime Threshold Model with Conditional Skewed Student t Distributions for Stock Returns," SSRN elibrary. [23] Medeiros, M. C. and A. Veiga (2003), "Diagnostic Checking in a Flexible Nonlinear Time Series Model," Journal of Time Series Analysis, 24 (4), [24] Medeiros, M. C. and A. Veiga (2005), "A Flexible Coe cient Smooth Transition Time Series Model," IEEE Transactions on Neural Networks, 16 (1), [25] Paye, B. S. and A. Timmermann (2006), "Instability of Return Prediction Models", Journal of Empirical Finance, 13 (3), [26] Pearson, K. (1900), "On the Correlation of Characters not Quantitatively Measurable", Royal Society Philosophical Transactions, Series A, 195, [27] Perez-Quiros, G. and A. Timmermann (2000), "Firm Size and Cyclical Variations in Stock Returns," Journal of Finance, 55 (3), [28] Perez-Quiros, G. and A. Timmermann (2001), "Business Cycle Asymmetries in Stock Returns: Evidence from Higher Order Moments and Conditional Densities," Journal of Econometrics 103 (1 2), [29] Petruccelli, J. D. and N. Davies (1986), "A Portmanteau Test for Self-Exciting Threshold Autoregressive-Type Nonlinearity in Time Series", Biometrika, 73 (3),

35 [30] Pettenuzzo, D. and A. Timmermann (2011), "Predictability of Stock Returns and Asset Allocation under Structural Breaks," Journal of Econometrics, 164 (1), [31] Pesaran, M. H. and S. M. Potter (1997), "A Floor and Ceiling Model of US Output," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 21 (4 5), [32] Potter, S. M. (1995), "A Nonlinear Approach to US GNP," Journal of Applied Econometrics, 10 (2), [33] Seo, M. H. and O. Linton (2007), "A Smoothed Least Squares Estimator for Threshold Regression Models", Journal of Econometrics, 141 (2), [34] Schwert, G. W. (1989), "Why Does Stock Market Volatility Change Over Time?," Journal of Finance, 44 (5), [35] Song, N., T. K. Siu, W. Ching, H. Tong and H. Yang (2012), "Asset Allocation under Threshold Autoregressive Models," Applied Stochastic Models in Business and Industry, 28 (1), [36] Terasvirta, T. (1994), "Speci cation, Estimation and Evaluation of Smooth Transition Autoregressive Models," Journal of the American Statistical Association, 89 (425), [37] Timmermann, A. (2008), "Elusive Return Predictability", International Journal of Forecasting, 24, [38] Tong, H. (1978), "On a Threshold Model", in Pattern Recognition and Signal Processing, ed. by C. H. Chen, Sijtho and Noordho, Amsterdam. 35

36 [39] Tong, H. and K. S. Lim (1980), "Threshold Autoregression, Limit Cycles and Cyclical Data", Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series B (Methodological), 42 (3), [40] Tsay, R. S. (1986), "Nonlinearity Tests for Time Series", Biometrika, 73 (2), [41] Tsay, R. S. (1989), "Testing and Modelling Threshold Autoregressive Processes", Journal of the American Statistical Association, 84 (405), [42] Tsay, R. S. (1998), "Testing and Modelling Multivariate Threshold Models", Journal of the American Statistical Association, 93 (443), [43] Welch, I. and A. Goyal (2008), "A Comprehensive Look at the Empirical Performance of Equity Premium Prediction", Review of Financial Studies, 21 (4),

37 Table 1: Bias, RMSE and Size in the case of the Estimator for 111 = 1 This table presents results from the Monte Carlo analysis of the estimator for 111 = 1. The DGP is y r it = ( 1i1 + x r t 1i2 + u r 1it ) I [qr 1t + (1 ) q r 2t ] + [ 2i1 + x r t 2i2 + u r 2it ] I [qr 1t + (1 ) q r 2t > ] ; i = 1; 2; t = 1; : : : ; T; r = 1; : : : ; 2000; with = 2, 111 = 112 = 121 = 122 = 1 = 1 and 211 = 212 = 221 = 222 = 2 = 1 +. x r t, q r 1t and q r 2t are generated as x r t = x (1 x ) + x x r t x 1/2 r xt ; x 50 = x ; q r mt = q 1 q + q q r m;t q 1/2 r qmt ; q r m; 50 = q ; t = 49; : : : ; 0; : : : ; T; m = 1; 2; with r xt = (f t r + r xt) p p 2, r qmt = f t r + qmt r 2 for m = 1; 2, with x N (1; 1), x U (0:05; 0:95), x = 1 () /2, q U (0:05; 0:95), f t r IIDN (0; 1), r xt IIDN (0; 1), r qmt IIDN (0; 1) for m = 1; 2, and the rst 50 observations discarded. u r 11t, u r 21t, u r 12t and u r 22t are generated as u r jit = f p t r + uit r j 2 for i; j = 1; 2, with r uit IIDN (0; 1), 2 1 = 1 and 2 2 = 2. = 0:10 = 0:50 = 0:25 = 1:00 = 1:75 = 0:25 = 1:00 = 1:75 T Bias RMSE Size Bias RMSE Size Bias RMSE Size Bias RMSE Size Bias RMSE Size Bias RMSE Size

Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts

Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts Contents 1 Motivating Examples 1 1.1 Instrumental variable estimator....................... 1 1.2 Estimating parameters in monetary policy rules.............. 2 1.3 Estimating

More information

GMM estimation of spatial panels

GMM estimation of spatial panels MRA Munich ersonal ReEc Archive GMM estimation of spatial panels Francesco Moscone and Elisa Tosetti Brunel University 7. April 009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/637/ MRA aper No. 637, posted

More information

Markov-Switching Models with Endogenous Explanatory Variables. Chang-Jin Kim 1

Markov-Switching Models with Endogenous Explanatory Variables. Chang-Jin Kim 1 Markov-Switching Models with Endogenous Explanatory Variables by Chang-Jin Kim 1 Dept. of Economics, Korea University and Dept. of Economics, University of Washington First draft: August, 2002 This version:

More information

GMM-based inference in the AR(1) panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails

GMM-based inference in the AR(1) panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails GMM-based inference in the AR() panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails Edith Madsen entre for Applied Microeconometrics (AM) Department of Economics, University of openhagen,

More information

Finite-sample quantiles of the Jarque-Bera test

Finite-sample quantiles of the Jarque-Bera test Finite-sample quantiles of the Jarque-Bera test Steve Lawford Department of Economics and Finance, Brunel University First draft: February 2004. Abstract The nite-sample null distribution of the Jarque-Bera

More information

Tests for Cointegration, Cobreaking and Cotrending in a System of Trending Variables

Tests for Cointegration, Cobreaking and Cotrending in a System of Trending Variables Tests for Cointegration, Cobreaking and Cotrending in a System of Trending Variables Josep Lluís Carrion-i-Silvestre University of Barcelona Dukpa Kim y Korea University May 4, 28 Abstract We consider

More information

R = µ + Bf Arbitrage Pricing Model, APM

R = µ + Bf Arbitrage Pricing Model, APM 4.2 Arbitrage Pricing Model, APM Empirical evidence indicates that the CAPM beta does not completely explain the cross section of expected asset returns. This suggests that additional factors may be required.

More information

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models Fall 22 Contents Introduction 2. An illustrative example........................... 2.2 Discussion...................................

More information

Regression: Ordinary Least Squares

Regression: Ordinary Least Squares Regression: Ordinary Least Squares Mark Hendricks Autumn 2017 FINM Intro: Regression Outline Regression OLS Mathematics Linear Projection Hendricks, Autumn 2017 FINM Intro: Regression: Lecture 2/32 Regression

More information

Comparing Nested Predictive Regression Models with Persistent Predictors

Comparing Nested Predictive Regression Models with Persistent Predictors Comparing Nested Predictive Regression Models with Persistent Predictors Yan Ge y and ae-hwy Lee z November 29, 24 Abstract his paper is an extension of Clark and McCracken (CM 2, 25, 29) and Clark and

More information

ECONOMETRICS FIELD EXAM Michigan State University May 9, 2008

ECONOMETRICS FIELD EXAM Michigan State University May 9, 2008 ECONOMETRICS FIELD EXAM Michigan State University May 9, 2008 Instructions: Answer all four (4) questions. Point totals for each question are given in parenthesis; there are 00 points possible. Within

More information

ECONOMICS 7200 MODERN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Econometric Theory and Applications

ECONOMICS 7200 MODERN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Econometric Theory and Applications ECONOMICS 7200 MODERN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Econometric Theory and Applications Yongmiao Hong Department of Economics & Department of Statistical Sciences Cornell University Spring 2019 Time and uncertainty

More information

Problem set 1 - Solutions

Problem set 1 - Solutions EMPIRICAL FINANCE AND FINANCIAL ECONOMETRICS - MODULE (8448) Problem set 1 - Solutions Exercise 1 -Solutions 1. The correct answer is (a). In fact, the process generating daily prices is usually assumed

More information

Evaluating Value-at-Risk models via Quantile Regression

Evaluating Value-at-Risk models via Quantile Regression Evaluating Value-at-Risk models via Quantile Regression Luiz Renato Lima (University of Tennessee, Knoxville) Wagner Gaglianone, Oliver Linton, Daniel Smith. NASM-2009 05/31/2009 Motivation Recent nancial

More information

Ross (1976) introduced the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) as an alternative to the CAPM.

Ross (1976) introduced the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) as an alternative to the CAPM. 4.2 Arbitrage Pricing Model, APM Empirical evidence indicates that the CAPM beta does not completely explain the cross section of expected asset returns. This suggests that additional factors may be required.

More information

Combining Macroeconomic Models for Prediction

Combining Macroeconomic Models for Prediction Combining Macroeconomic Models for Prediction John Geweke University of Technology Sydney 15th Australasian Macro Workshop April 8, 2010 Outline 1 Optimal prediction pools 2 Models and data 3 Optimal pools

More information

Technical Appendix-3-Regime asymmetric STAR modeling and exchange rate reversion

Technical Appendix-3-Regime asymmetric STAR modeling and exchange rate reversion Technical Appendix-3-Regime asymmetric STAR modeling and exchange rate reversion Mario Cerrato*, Hyunsok Kim* and Ronald MacDonald** 1 University of Glasgow, Department of Economics, Adam Smith building.

More information

On the Power of Tests for Regime Switching

On the Power of Tests for Regime Switching On the Power of Tests for Regime Switching joint work with Drew Carter and Ben Hansen Douglas G. Steigerwald UC Santa Barbara May 2015 D. Steigerwald (UCSB) Regime Switching May 2015 1 / 42 Motivating

More information

Testing for Regime Switching: A Comment

Testing for Regime Switching: A Comment Testing for Regime Switching: A Comment Andrew V. Carter Department of Statistics University of California, Santa Barbara Douglas G. Steigerwald Department of Economics University of California Santa Barbara

More information

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1 Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1 John C. Chao April 25, 2017 1 These notes are based in large part on Chapter 16 of Stock and Watson (2011). They are for instructional purposes

More information

Inference about Clustering and Parametric. Assumptions in Covariance Matrix Estimation

Inference about Clustering and Parametric. Assumptions in Covariance Matrix Estimation Inference about Clustering and Parametric Assumptions in Covariance Matrix Estimation Mikko Packalen y Tony Wirjanto z 26 November 2010 Abstract Selecting an estimator for the variance covariance matrix

More information

University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series

University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series Predicting Stock Returns and Volatility Using Consumption-Aggregate Wealth Ratios: A Nonlinear Approach Stelios Bekiros IPAG Business

More information

On GMM Estimation and Inference with Bootstrap Bias-Correction in Linear Panel Data Models

On GMM Estimation and Inference with Bootstrap Bias-Correction in Linear Panel Data Models On GMM Estimation and Inference with Bootstrap Bias-Correction in Linear Panel Data Models Takashi Yamagata y Department of Economics and Related Studies, University of York, Heslington, York, UK January

More information

Economics 241B Estimation with Instruments

Economics 241B Estimation with Instruments Economics 241B Estimation with Instruments Measurement Error Measurement error is de ned as the error resulting from the measurement of a variable. At some level, every variable is measured with error.

More information

ECONOMICS SERIES SWP 2009/11 A New Unit Root Tes t with Two Structural Breaks in Level and S lope at Unknown Time

ECONOMICS SERIES SWP 2009/11 A New Unit Root Tes t with Two Structural Breaks in Level and S lope at Unknown Time Faculty of Business and Law School of Accounting, Economics and Finance ECONOMICS SERIES SWP 2009/11 A New Unit Root Test with Two Structural Breaks in Level and Slope at Unknown Time Paresh Kumar Narayan

More information

Time Series Models and Inference. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley

Time Series Models and Inference. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Time Series Models and Inference James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Overview In contrast to the classical linear regression model, in which the components of the

More information

Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods

Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods Robert V. Breunig Centre for Economic Policy Research, Research School of Social Sciences and School of

More information

Econometric modeling of the relationship among macroeconomic variables of Thailand: Smooth transition autoregressive regression model

Econometric modeling of the relationship among macroeconomic variables of Thailand: Smooth transition autoregressive regression model The Empirical Econometrics and Quantitative Economics Letters ISSN 2286 7147 EEQEL all rights reserved Volume 1, Number 4 (December 2012), pp. 21 38. Econometric modeling of the relationship among macroeconomic

More information

Notes on Time Series Modeling

Notes on Time Series Modeling Notes on Time Series Modeling Garey Ramey University of California, San Diego January 17 1 Stationary processes De nition A stochastic process is any set of random variables y t indexed by t T : fy t g

More information

Instead of using all the sample observations for estimation, the suggested procedure is to divide the data set

Instead of using all the sample observations for estimation, the suggested procedure is to divide the data set Chow forecast test: Instead of using all the sample observations for estimation, the suggested procedure is to divide the data set of N sample observations into N 1 observations to be used for estimation

More information

ECONOMET RICS P RELIM EXAM August 24, 2010 Department of Economics, Michigan State University

ECONOMET RICS P RELIM EXAM August 24, 2010 Department of Economics, Michigan State University ECONOMET RICS P RELIM EXAM August 24, 2010 Department of Economics, Michigan State University Instructions: Answer all four (4) questions. Be sure to show your work or provide su cient justi cation for

More information

Using all observations when forecasting under structural breaks

Using all observations when forecasting under structural breaks Using all observations when forecasting under structural breaks Stanislav Anatolyev New Economic School Victor Kitov Moscow State University December 2007 Abstract We extend the idea of the trade-off window

More information

Chapter 2. GMM: Estimating Rational Expectations Models

Chapter 2. GMM: Estimating Rational Expectations Models Chapter 2. GMM: Estimating Rational Expectations Models Contents 1 Introduction 1 2 Step 1: Solve the model and obtain Euler equations 2 3 Step 2: Formulate moment restrictions 3 4 Step 3: Estimation and

More information

Estimating the Number of Common Factors in Serially Dependent Approximate Factor Models

Estimating the Number of Common Factors in Serially Dependent Approximate Factor Models Estimating the Number of Common Factors in Serially Dependent Approximate Factor Models Ryan Greenaway-McGrevy y Bureau of Economic Analysis Chirok Han Korea University February 7, 202 Donggyu Sul University

More information

11. Bootstrap Methods

11. Bootstrap Methods 11. Bootstrap Methods c A. Colin Cameron & Pravin K. Trivedi 2006 These transparencies were prepared in 20043. They can be used as an adjunct to Chapter 11 of our subsequent book Microeconometrics: Methods

More information

When is a copula constant? A test for changing relationships

When is a copula constant? A test for changing relationships When is a copula constant? A test for changing relationships Fabio Busetti and Andrew Harvey Bank of Italy and University of Cambridge November 2007 usetti and Harvey (Bank of Italy and University of Cambridge)

More information

2. Multivariate ARMA

2. Multivariate ARMA 2. Multivariate ARMA JEM 140: Quantitative Multivariate Finance IES, Charles University, Prague Summer 2018 JEM 140 () 2. Multivariate ARMA Summer 2018 1 / 19 Multivariate AR I Let r t = (r 1t,..., r kt

More information

A Non-Parametric Approach of Heteroskedasticity Robust Estimation of Vector-Autoregressive (VAR) Models

A Non-Parametric Approach of Heteroskedasticity Robust Estimation of Vector-Autoregressive (VAR) Models Journal of Finance and Investment Analysis, vol.1, no.1, 2012, 55-67 ISSN: 2241-0988 (print version), 2241-0996 (online) International Scientific Press, 2012 A Non-Parametric Approach of Heteroskedasticity

More information

The Instability of Correlations: Measurement and the Implications for Market Risk

The Instability of Correlations: Measurement and the Implications for Market Risk The Instability of Correlations: Measurement and the Implications for Market Risk Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20254 Advanced Quantitative Methods for Asset Pricing and Structuring Winter/Spring 2018 Threshold

More information

1 A Non-technical Introduction to Regression

1 A Non-technical Introduction to Regression 1 A Non-technical Introduction to Regression Chapters 1 and Chapter 2 of the textbook are reviews of material you should know from your previous study (e.g. in your second year course). They cover, in

More information

Bootstrapping the Grainger Causality Test With Integrated Data

Bootstrapping the Grainger Causality Test With Integrated Data Bootstrapping the Grainger Causality Test With Integrated Data Richard Ti n University of Reading July 26, 2006 Abstract A Monte-carlo experiment is conducted to investigate the small sample performance

More information

Panel cointegration rank testing with cross-section dependence

Panel cointegration rank testing with cross-section dependence Panel cointegration rank testing with cross-section dependence Josep Lluís Carrion-i-Silvestre y Laura Surdeanu z September 2007 Abstract In this paper we propose a test statistic to determine the cointegration

More information

Bayesian Inference for a Threshold Autoregression with a Unit Root

Bayesian Inference for a Threshold Autoregression with a Unit Root Bayesian Inference for a Threshold Autoregression with a Unit Root Penelope Smith Melbourne Institute The University of Melbourne Parkville, VIC 3010 September 1, 2005 Abstract A Bayesian approach to distinguishing

More information

Discussion Paper Series

Discussion Paper Series INSTITUTO TECNOLÓGICO AUTÓNOMO DE MÉXICO CENTRO DE INVESTIGACIÓN ECONÓMICA Discussion Paper Series Size Corrected Power for Bootstrap Tests Manuel A. Domínguez and Ignacio N. Lobato Instituto Tecnológico

More information

x i = 1 yi 2 = 55 with N = 30. Use the above sample information to answer all the following questions. Show explicitly all formulas and calculations.

x i = 1 yi 2 = 55 with N = 30. Use the above sample information to answer all the following questions. Show explicitly all formulas and calculations. Exercises for the course of Econometrics Introduction 1. () A researcher is using data for a sample of 30 observations to investigate the relationship between some dependent variable y i and independent

More information

On Econometric Analysis of Structural Systems with Permanent and Transitory Shocks and Exogenous Variables

On Econometric Analysis of Structural Systems with Permanent and Transitory Shocks and Exogenous Variables On Econometric Analysis of Structural Systems with Permanent and Transitory Shocks and Exogenous Variables Adrian Pagan School of Economics and Finance, Queensland University of Technology M. Hashem Pesaran

More information

University of Kent Department of Economics Discussion Papers

University of Kent Department of Economics Discussion Papers University of Kent Department of Economics Discussion Papers Testing for Granger (non-) Causality in a Time Varying Coefficient VAR Model Dimitris K. Christopoulos and Miguel León-Ledesma January 28 KDPE

More information

A New Approach to Robust Inference in Cointegration

A New Approach to Robust Inference in Cointegration A New Approach to Robust Inference in Cointegration Sainan Jin Guanghua School of Management, Peking University Peter C. B. Phillips Cowles Foundation, Yale University, University of Auckland & University

More information

(Y jz) t (XjZ) 0 t = S yx S yz S 1. S yx:z = T 1. etc. 2. Next solve the eigenvalue problem. js xx:z S xy:z S 1

(Y jz) t (XjZ) 0 t = S yx S yz S 1. S yx:z = T 1. etc. 2. Next solve the eigenvalue problem. js xx:z S xy:z S 1 Abstract Reduced Rank Regression The reduced rank regression model is a multivariate regression model with a coe cient matrix with reduced rank. The reduced rank regression algorithm is an estimation procedure,

More information

Testing the null of cointegration with structural breaks

Testing the null of cointegration with structural breaks Testing the null of cointegration with structural breaks Josep Lluís Carrion-i-Silvestre Anàlisi Quantitativa Regional Parc Cientí c de Barcelona Andreu Sansó Departament of Economics Universitat de les

More information

Online Appendix to: Marijuana on Main Street? Estimating Demand in Markets with Limited Access

Online Appendix to: Marijuana on Main Street? Estimating Demand in Markets with Limited Access Online Appendix to: Marijuana on Main Street? Estating Demand in Markets with Lited Access By Liana Jacobi and Michelle Sovinsky This appendix provides details on the estation methodology for various speci

More information

Learning in Real Time: Theory and Empirical Evidence from the Term Structure of Survey Forecasts

Learning in Real Time: Theory and Empirical Evidence from the Term Structure of Survey Forecasts Learning in Real Time: Theory and Empirical Evidence from the Term Structure of Survey Forecasts Andrew Patton and Allan Timmermann Oxford and UC-San Diego November 2007 Motivation Uncertainty about macroeconomic

More information

GMM based inference for panel data models

GMM based inference for panel data models GMM based inference for panel data models Maurice J.G. Bun and Frank Kleibergen y this version: 24 February 2010 JEL-code: C13; C23 Keywords: dynamic panel data model, Generalized Method of Moments, weak

More information

Convergence of prices and rates of in ation

Convergence of prices and rates of in ation Convergence of prices and rates of in ation Fabio Busetti, Silvia Fabiani y, Andrew Harvey z May 18, 2006 Abstract We consider how unit root and stationarity tests can be used to study the convergence

More information

Wild Bootstrap Tests for Autocorrelation in Vector Autoregressive Models

Wild Bootstrap Tests for Autocorrelation in Vector Autoregressive Models MEDDELANDEN FRÅN SVENSKA HANDELSHÖGSKOLAN HANKEN SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPERS 562 Niklas Ahlgren and Paul Catani Wild Bootstrap Tests for Autocorrelation in Vector Autoregressive Models 2012 Wild

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE COLLEGE OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CANTERBURY CHRISTCHURCH, NEW ZEALAND

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE COLLEGE OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CANTERBURY CHRISTCHURCH, NEW ZEALAND DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE COLLEGE OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CANTERBURY CHRISTCHURCH, NEW ZEALAND Testing For Unit Roots With Cointegrated Data NOTE: This paper is a revision of

More information

Functional Coefficient Models for Nonstationary Time Series Data

Functional Coefficient Models for Nonstationary Time Series Data Functional Coefficient Models for Nonstationary Time Series Data Zongwu Cai Department of Mathematics & Statistics and Department of Economics, University of North Carolina at Charlotte, USA Wang Yanan

More information

Simple Estimators for Semiparametric Multinomial Choice Models

Simple Estimators for Semiparametric Multinomial Choice Models Simple Estimators for Semiparametric Multinomial Choice Models James L. Powell and Paul A. Ruud University of California, Berkeley March 2008 Preliminary and Incomplete Comments Welcome Abstract This paper

More information

Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence

Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence Parametric Inference on Strong Dependence Peter M. Robinson London School of Economics Based on joint work with Javier Hualde: Javier Hualde and Peter M. Robinson: Gaussian Pseudo-Maximum Likelihood Estimation

More information

1 Regression with Time Series Variables

1 Regression with Time Series Variables 1 Regression with Time Series Variables With time series regression, Y might not only depend on X, but also lags of Y and lags of X Autoregressive Distributed lag (or ADL(p; q)) model has these features:

More information

Lecture 5: Unit Roots, Cointegration and Error Correction Models The Spurious Regression Problem

Lecture 5: Unit Roots, Cointegration and Error Correction Models The Spurious Regression Problem Lecture 5: Unit Roots, Cointegration and Error Correction Models The Spurious Regression Problem Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20192 Financial Econometrics Winter/Spring 2018 Overview Defining cointegration Vector

More information

Likelihood Ratio Based Test for the Exogeneity and the Relevance of Instrumental Variables

Likelihood Ratio Based Test for the Exogeneity and the Relevance of Instrumental Variables Likelihood Ratio Based est for the Exogeneity and the Relevance of Instrumental Variables Dukpa Kim y Yoonseok Lee z September [under revision] Abstract his paper develops a test for the exogeneity and

More information

GMM Estimation with Noncausal Instruments

GMM Estimation with Noncausal Instruments ömmföäflsäafaäsflassflassflas ffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffff Discussion Papers GMM Estimation with Noncausal Instruments Markku Lanne University of Helsinki, RUESG and HECER and Pentti Saikkonen

More information

ARIMA Models. Richard G. Pierse

ARIMA Models. Richard G. Pierse ARIMA Models Richard G. Pierse 1 Introduction Time Series Analysis looks at the properties of time series from a purely statistical point of view. No attempt is made to relate variables using a priori

More information

Testing for Unit Roots with Cointegrated Data

Testing for Unit Roots with Cointegrated Data Discussion Paper No. 2015-57 August 19, 2015 http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers/2015-57 Testing for Unit Roots with Cointegrated Data W. Robert Reed Abstract This paper demonstrates

More information

Financial Econometrics

Financial Econometrics Financial Econometrics Nonlinear time series analysis Gerald P. Dwyer Trinity College, Dublin January 2016 Outline 1 Nonlinearity Does nonlinearity matter? Nonlinear models Tests for nonlinearity Forecasting

More information

Economics Introduction to Econometrics - Fall 2007 Final Exam - Answers

Economics Introduction to Econometrics - Fall 2007 Final Exam - Answers Student Name: Economics 4818 - Introduction to Econometrics - Fall 2007 Final Exam - Answers SHOW ALL WORK! Evaluation: Problems: 3, 4C, 5C and 5F are worth 4 points. All other questions are worth 3 points.

More information

Generalized Autoregressive Score Models

Generalized Autoregressive Score Models Generalized Autoregressive Score Models by: Drew Creal, Siem Jan Koopman, André Lucas To capture the dynamic behavior of univariate and multivariate time series processes, we can allow parameters to be

More information

Cointegration and the joint con rmation hypothesis

Cointegration and the joint con rmation hypothesis Cointegration and the joint con rmation hypothesis VASCO J. GABRIEL Department of Economics, Birkbeck College, UK University of Minho, Portugal October 2001 Abstract Recent papers by Charemza and Syczewska

More information

A Bootstrap Test for Causality with Endogenous Lag Length Choice. - theory and application in finance

A Bootstrap Test for Causality with Endogenous Lag Length Choice. - theory and application in finance CESIS Electronic Working Paper Series Paper No. 223 A Bootstrap Test for Causality with Endogenous Lag Length Choice - theory and application in finance R. Scott Hacker and Abdulnasser Hatemi-J April 200

More information

Nonparametric Identi cation and Estimation of Truncated Regression Models with Heteroskedasticity

Nonparametric Identi cation and Estimation of Truncated Regression Models with Heteroskedasticity Nonparametric Identi cation and Estimation of Truncated Regression Models with Heteroskedasticity Songnian Chen a, Xun Lu a, Xianbo Zhou b and Yahong Zhou c a Department of Economics, Hong Kong University

More information

Subsets Tests in GMM without assuming identi cation

Subsets Tests in GMM without assuming identi cation Subsets Tests in GMM without assuming identi cation Frank Kleibergen Brown University and University of Amsterdam Sophocles Mavroeidis y Brown University sophocles_mavroeidis@brown.edu Preliminary: please

More information

Multivariate GARCH models.

Multivariate GARCH models. Multivariate GARCH models. Financial market volatility moves together over time across assets and markets. Recognizing this commonality through a multivariate modeling framework leads to obvious gains

More information

General comments Linear vs Non-Linear Univariate vs Multivariate

General comments Linear vs Non-Linear Univariate vs Multivariate Comments on : Forecasting UK GDP growth, inflation and interest rates under structural change: A comparison of models with time-varying parameters by A. Barnett, H. Mumtaz and K. Theodoridis Laurent Ferrara

More information

Testing Weak Convergence Based on HAR Covariance Matrix Estimators

Testing Weak Convergence Based on HAR Covariance Matrix Estimators Testing Weak Convergence Based on HAR Covariance atrix Estimators Jianning Kong y, Peter C. B. Phillips z, Donggyu Sul x August 4, 207 Abstract The weak convergence tests based on heteroskedasticity autocorrelation

More information

May 2, Why do nonlinear models provide poor. macroeconomic forecasts? Graham Elliott (UCSD) Gray Calhoun (Iowa State) Motivating Problem

May 2, Why do nonlinear models provide poor. macroeconomic forecasts? Graham Elliott (UCSD) Gray Calhoun (Iowa State) Motivating Problem (UCSD) Gray with May 2, 2012 The with (a) Typical comments about future of forecasting imply a large role for. (b) Many studies show a limited role in providing forecasts from. (c) Reviews of forecasting

More information

The linear regression model: functional form and structural breaks

The linear regression model: functional form and structural breaks The linear regression model: functional form and structural breaks Ragnar Nymoen Department of Economics, UiO 16 January 2009 Overview Dynamic models A little bit more about dynamics Extending inference

More information

International Symposium on Mathematical Sciences & Computing Research (ismsc) 2015 (ismsc 15)

International Symposium on Mathematical Sciences & Computing Research (ismsc) 2015 (ismsc 15) Model Performance Between Linear Vector Autoregressive and Markov Switching Vector Autoregressive Models on Modelling Structural Change in Time Series Data Phoong Seuk Wai Department of Economics Facultyof

More information

A formal statistical test for the number of factors in. the approximate factor models

A formal statistical test for the number of factors in. the approximate factor models A formal statistical test for the number of factors in the approximate factor models Alexei Onatski Economics Department, Columbia University September 26, 2006 Abstract In this paper we study i.i.d. sequences

More information

MC3: Econometric Theory and Methods. Course Notes 4

MC3: Econometric Theory and Methods. Course Notes 4 University College London Department of Economics M.Sc. in Economics MC3: Econometric Theory and Methods Course Notes 4 Notes on maximum likelihood methods Andrew Chesher 25/0/2005 Course Notes 4, Andrew

More information

Interpreting Regression Results

Interpreting Regression Results Interpreting Regression Results Carlo Favero Favero () Interpreting Regression Results 1 / 42 Interpreting Regression Results Interpreting regression results is not a simple exercise. We propose to split

More information

Chapter 2. Dynamic panel data models

Chapter 2. Dynamic panel data models Chapter 2. Dynamic panel data models School of Economics and Management - University of Geneva Christophe Hurlin, Université of Orléans University of Orléans April 2018 C. Hurlin (University of Orléans)

More information

Large Panel Data Models with Cross-Sectional Dependence: A Surevey

Large Panel Data Models with Cross-Sectional Dependence: A Surevey Large Panel Data Models with Cross-Sectional Dependence: A Surevey Hashem Pesaran University of Southern California, CAFE, USA, and Trinity College, Cambridge, UK A Course on Panel Data Models, University

More information

Forecasting Canadian GDP: Evaluating Point and Density Forecasts in Real-Time

Forecasting Canadian GDP: Evaluating Point and Density Forecasts in Real-Time Forecasting Canadian GDP: Evaluating Point and Density Forecasts in Real-Time Frédérick Demers Research Department Bank of Canada October 2007 (Preliminary and Incomplete - Do not Quote) Presented at the

More information

A note on nonlinear dynamics in the Spanish term structure of interest rates B

A note on nonlinear dynamics in the Spanish term structure of interest rates B International Review of Economics and Finance 15 (2006) 316 323 www.elsevier.com/locate/iref A note on nonlinear dynamics in the Spanish term structure of interest rates B Vicente EsteveT Departamento

More information

Monitoring Forecasting Performance

Monitoring Forecasting Performance Monitoring Forecasting Performance Identifying when and why return prediction models work Allan Timmermann and Yinchu Zhu University of California, San Diego June 21, 2015 Outline Testing for time-varying

More information

Structural Breaks in Panel Data Models: A New Approach

Structural Breaks in Panel Data Models: A New Approach Structural Breaks in Panel Data Models: A New Approach Wei Liao November 15, 28 Abstract This paper provides a new econometric framework to make inference about structural breaks in panel data models.

More information

News Shocks: Different Effects in Boom and Recession?

News Shocks: Different Effects in Boom and Recession? News Shocks: Different Effects in Boom and Recession? Maria Bolboaca, Sarah Fischer University of Bern Study Center Gerzensee June 7, 5 / Introduction News are defined in the literature as exogenous changes

More information

Department of Economics, UCSB UC Santa Barbara

Department of Economics, UCSB UC Santa Barbara Department of Economics, UCSB UC Santa Barbara Title: Past trend versus future expectation: test of exchange rate volatility Author: Sengupta, Jati K., University of California, Santa Barbara Sfeir, Raymond,

More information

Working Paper SerieS. A Predictability Test for a Small Number of Nested Models. NO 1580 / august 2013

Working Paper SerieS. A Predictability Test for a Small Number of Nested Models. NO 1580 / august 2013 Working Paper SerieS NO 1580 / august 2013 A Predictability Test for a Small Number of Nested Models Eleonora Granziera, Kirstin Hubrich and Hyungsik Roger Moon In 2013 all ECB publications feature a motif

More information

Empirical Asset Pricing and Statistical Power in the Presence of Weak Risk Factors

Empirical Asset Pricing and Statistical Power in the Presence of Weak Risk Factors Empirical Asset Pricing and Statistical Power in the Presence of Weak Risk Factors Craig Burnside y Duke University August 27 Abstract The risk factors in many consumption-based asset pricing models display

More information

Comment on HAC Corrections for Strongly Autocorrelated Time Series by Ulrich K. Müller

Comment on HAC Corrections for Strongly Autocorrelated Time Series by Ulrich K. Müller Comment on HAC Corrections for Strongly Autocorrelated ime Series by Ulrich K. Müller Yixiao Sun Department of Economics, UC San Diego May 2, 24 On the Nearly-optimal est Müller applies the theory of optimal

More information

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3) MakØk3, Fall 2 (blok 2) Business cycles and monetary stabilization policies Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen Lecture 3, November 3: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter

More information

Backtesting Marginal Expected Shortfall and Related Systemic Risk Measures

Backtesting Marginal Expected Shortfall and Related Systemic Risk Measures and Related Systemic Risk Measures Denisa Banulescu, Christophe Hurlin, Jérémy Leymarie, Olivier Scaillet, ACPR Chair "Regulation and Systemic Risk" - March 24, 2016 Systemic risk The recent nancial crisis

More information

Finite sample distributions of nonlinear IV panel unit root tests in the presence of cross-section dependence

Finite sample distributions of nonlinear IV panel unit root tests in the presence of cross-section dependence Finite sample distributions of nonlinear IV panel unit root tests in the presence of cross-section dependence Qi Sun Department of Economics University of Leicester November 9, 2009 Abstract his paper

More information

2014 Preliminary Examination

2014 Preliminary Examination 014 reliminary Examination 1) Standard error consistency and test statistic asymptotic normality in linear models Consider the model for the observable data y t ; x T t n Y = X + U; (1) where is a k 1

More information

Föreläsning /31

Föreläsning /31 1/31 Föreläsning 10 090420 Chapter 13 Econometric Modeling: Model Speci cation and Diagnostic testing 2/31 Types of speci cation errors Consider the following models: Y i = β 1 + β 2 X i + β 3 X 2 i +

More information

CENTRE FOR ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS

CENTRE FOR ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS CENTRE FOR ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS CEA@Cass http://www.cass.city.ac.uk/cea/index.html Cass Business School Faculty of Finance 106 Bunhill Row London EC1Y 8TZ Testing for Instability in Factor Structure of

More information

The Predictive Space or If x predicts y; what does y tell us about x?

The Predictive Space or If x predicts y; what does y tell us about x? The Predictive Space or If x predicts y; what does y tell us about x? Donald Robertson and Stephen Wright y October 28, 202 Abstract A predictive regression for y t and a time series representation of

More information

Panel VAR Models with Spatial Dependence

Panel VAR Models with Spatial Dependence Panel VAR Models with Spatial Dependence Jan Mutl Institute of Advanced Studies Stumpergasse 56 A-6 Vienna Austria mutl@ihs.ac.at January 3, 29 Abstract I consider a panel vector autoregressive (panel

More information