MULTI-PARAMETER MODELS OF INNOVATION DIFFUSION ON COMPLEX NETWORKS

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "MULTI-PARAMETER MODELS OF INNOVATION DIFFUSION ON COMPLEX NETWORKS"

Transcription

1 SIAM J. APPLIED DYNAMICAL SYSTEMS Vol. xx, pp. x c xxxx Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics x x MULTI-PARAMETER MODELS OF INNOVATION DIFFUSION ON COMPLEX NETWORKS N. J. McCullen, A. M. Rucklidge, C. S. E. Bale, T. J. Foxon, and W. F. Gale Abstract. A model, applicable to a range of innovation diffusion applications with a strong peer to peer component, is developed and studied, along with methods for its investigation and analysis. A particular application is to individual households deciding whether to install an energy efficiency measure in their home. The model represents these individuals as nodes on a network, each with a variable representing their current state of adoption of the innovation. The motivation to adopt is composed of three terms, representing personal preference, an average of each individual s network neighbours states and a system average, which is a measure of the current social trend. The adoption state of a node changes if a weighted linear combination of these factors exceeds some threshold. Numerical simulations have been carried out, computing the average uptake after a sufficient number of time-steps over many randomisations at all model parameter values, on various network topologies, including random (Erdős Rényi), small world (Watts Strogatz) and (Newman s) highly clustered, community-based networks. An analytical and probabilistic approach has been developed to account for the observed behaviour, which explains the results of the numerical calculations. Key words. Innovation diffusion, networks, threshold models, uptake of energy efficiency measures. AMS subject classifications , 91F99 1. Introduction. Social phenomena, such as the spread of a technological or behavioural innovation through communities, can be modelled as dynamical processes on networks [17, 1, 9, 7, 8, 6]. Our model, introduced in 2, builds on previous threshold diffusion models (e.g. [27, 20, 8]) by incorporating sociologically realistic factors, yet remains simple enough for mathematical insights to be developed. An example of a particular application of this model is to the adoption of innovations related to energy behaviours and technologies by individual households. These innovations are often not directly visible to an adopter s peers but communication of the benefits of adoption may occur through interaction between individuals. The decision to adopt is therefore based on multiple factors, taking into account not only individual preferences, but also whether or not an individual s social circle has adopted the innovation. As such, the spread of the innovation will be influenced by the network of social contacts between individuals, including both social peers and wider social trends. Models have been developed along these lines [5], splitting the influence on individual decision-making between various social factors, and show interesting dynamics looking at the balance of these influences. The real topologies of interpersonal networks are not known exactly and are constantly changing, further adding to the uncertainty in models of social phenomena. Given these challenges, useful models and methods are required that can assess the likely outcomes of particular scenarios, such as Department of Applied Mathematics, University of Leeds. Now at: Research unit for Energy and the Design of Environments, University of Bath. Energy Research Institute, University of Leeds. School of Earth and Environment, University of Leeds. This work was funded under the EPSRC Energy Challenges for Complexity Science panel, grant EP/G059780/1. 1

2 2 N. J. MCCULLEN, A. M. RUCKLIDGE, C. S. E. BALE, T. J. FOXON AND W. F. GALE the effect of an intervention to persuade population to adopt an innovation, without being excessively sensitive to particular choices of parameter values of the model or the precise structure of the network. Here, we present numerical investigations of the model, studying its behaviour statistically, as well as presenting mathematical analysis that gives a deeper understanding of the observed uptake of the innovation over the network using probabilistic arguments. The numerical methods used in 3 take the ensemble averages of simulation outcomes over many realisations, each with different conditions, such as the initial seed of adopters or the precise details of the network structure. This is carried out over a range of parameter values and on different types of network topology in order to study both the stability of the model with respect to minor variations and the sensitivity to structural details of the models used. These methods can, therefore, be applied to various dynamical models on a variety of networks to assess likely differences in outcomes for alternative scenarios in a statistical sense, rather than relying on individual predictions. We take the applied dynamical systems approach of looking for lines in parameter space where the behaviour of the dynamical process changes. Mathematical analysis is presented in 4 explaining observations for the simulation results in certain simplified cases. Specifically, assuming that all individuals are homogeneous in their model parameters, we can use probabilistic arguments for the conditions of the neighbourhoods of the individuals required to trigger uptake, and calculate the likelihood of success given a choice of parameters on certain types of networks. We have found that the likelihood of success, defined as adoption by the majority of individuals, depends strongly on both the choice of model parameters and the topology of the network. Two particularly important factors are found to be the node degree, i.e., the number of connections of the nodes with their neighbours, and the network s transitivity, which is the degree of clustering related to the correlation between the neighbourhoods of connected individuals. This makes it possible to assess what changes to the model would result in an increased probability of success, and how this can be interpreted in terms of policy decisions intent on maximising adoption in the real world. 2. Modelling social behaviour as dynamical systems on networks. A system of N individuals (or groups such as households) can be represented by N nodes on a network. Possible interactions linking individuals are represented by the edges on the network. The network topology can be represented in the adjacency matrix A, an N 2 matrix with entries: { 1 if node j influences i, A ij = 0 otherwise. (2.1) Information or influence is passed along these edges, which could also be given weights to show the relative probability or strength of the interaction. In this work all influences are taken to be of equal weight and symmetric in both directions. States are assigned to the nodes, describing the properties of the individuals, and deterministic or probabilistic equations or rules can be used to describe the evolution of these states over time A multi-parameter model for innovation uptake. The following model describes the purchase or adoption of a single innovation (not considering competition between similar

3 MULTI-PARAMETER MODELS OF INNOVATION DIFFUSION ON COMPLEX NETWORKS 3 items) but could apply equally well to the spread of any property over a network, such as a rumour or behaviour. The model used in this work assigns each node i with a binary variable representing their current state, x i = 1, 0, indicating whether or not the individual has adopted the innovation. The nodes in state x = 1 are referred to as activated nodes. The initial state is a fixed proportion of activated nodes, randomly distributed across the network. The decision to invest in the innovation is determined by the perceived usefulness, or utility, to the individual (which can include subjective judgements). When this utility outweighs the barriers to adoption (including financial costs), the individual i adopts the innovation, so x i changes from 0 to 1. As this is a one-way process, unlike voter models [7], the state at the next time-step is determined by: 1 if x i (t) = 1, x i (t + 1) = 1 if x i (t) = 0 and u i (t) > θ i, 0 otherwise, (2.2) where θ i is the threshold and t is time. All nodes are updated synchronously at each timestep in the current work. The total utility u i is a combination of both personal and social benefit [9]. The personal benefit p i is a measure of the perceived intrinsic benefit to the individual of acquiring the innovation. The social benefit can be split into both the direct influence from an individual s peer group and the (possibly indirect) influence from society in general [25], which could be affected by the desire to fit in with the social norm on different levels. Thus our utility model has three factors that can be given relative weightings α i, β i and γ i, with α i + β i + γ i = 1. The total utility is, therefore, given by: u i (t) = α i p i + β i s i (t) + γ i m(t), (2.3) where s i is the average of x within a node s network neighbourhood: s i (t) = 1 N A ij x j (t), (2.4) k i and the degree of node i is k i = N j=1 A ij. The mainstream social norm m is the average of x over the entire population: j m(t) = 1 N N x i (t). (2.5) i This can be made equivalent to previous threshold diffusion models such as [27] by setting = (0, 1, 0). We define m 0 = m(t = 0) to be the initial fraction of adopters. For the rest of the discussion we make the simplifying assumption that all nodes take the same values of α, β, γ, p and θ, so that only the value of s i (t) differs between the nodes, which corresponds to the network effects.

4 4 N. J. MCCULLEN, A. M. RUCKLIDGE, C. S. E. BALE, T. J. FOXON AND W. F. GALE 2.2. Modelling social networks. For these investigations we connected the nodes using several network models. Erdős Rényi random graphs [12], where edges are connected with a probability p e between pairs of nodes, were investigated for their analytical simplicity, due to the lack of correlations between neighbourhoods of nodes, allowing probabilistic arguments to be used [16]. The Watts Strogatz scheme [28], where n-nearest-neighbour lattices have edges removed and reassigned according to a probability p r, allowing interpolation between regular (possibly highly clustered) topologies and random networks, were also investigated, as they are frequently studied and provide a simple way to vary the clustering (transitivity) of the system. Empirical studies have shown that real-world networks are often organised in communities of sub-networks [23], which are more densely connected internally than to the rest of the network, and models exist showing mechanisms that can result in the formation of such communities [21]. Community based models, such as Newman s highly clustered networks [22], can better represent real-world social interactions in a number of ways. Here, links between nodes are assigned via their association with G groups each, which are randomly chosen from a set of W groups in total. Association with two or more groups per node is necessary for the network to be fully connected and total transmission to be possible. Nodes are linked to L other nodes within each group, so the total number of groups W and resulting number of members of each group M = GN/W provides a means of varying the clustering while keeping other network parameters fixed. These networks also have locally higher clustering between members of a group than out to the rest of the network. For these models it would also be possible to include some geographical information to the nodes and groups in the network (c.f. Hamill and Gilbert s Social Circles model [19]), as discussed further in 5. Networks with scale-free degree distributions are also widely used in the literature, such as the Barabási Albert (preferential attachment) model. Such degree distributions exist when considering the complete peer-networks of individuals, including both strong and weak links. However, in the application motivating this research, where individuals recommend a certain innovation to their peers, it is reasonable to assume that people discuss financial matters and share recommendations with only a core group of associates, allowing us to ignore the more numerous weaker links. It has previously been shown that adoption decisions are influenced via the strongest links in the network, rather than all weak ties [29]. This is backed up by a survey we conducted on residents of the city of Leeds, where individuals reported limited communications on issues of energy and saving money with their peers [4]. We show how including such links would affect our results, due to the skewed nature of the fat-tail of the degree distributions. 3. Numerical methods. In order to investigate the diffusion dynamics of the system, we performed simulations on various networks, using a synchronous updating rule for the states of the nodes. Given a particular network, initial set of adopters and parameter values (α, β, γ, p, θ), we ask whether or not the innovation succeeds, that is, do most individuals adopt the innovation. Aside from the challenges inherent in modelling the complex factors affecting behaviour, as well as in quantifying models from social data, dynamical processes on complex networks themselves often exhibit dependence on the starting conditions, such as which nodes are chosen as the initial seed. To illustrate the sensitivity to the precise starting

5 MULTI-PARAMETER MODELS OF INNOVATION DIFFUSION ON COMPLEX NETWORKS 5 conditions, the simulation results for a particular network and a single choice of parameters are given in Figure 3.1 (a), showing the uptake over 36 time steps for 100 random realisations of the initial seed. In each case, 5% of the nodes are chosen as seed nodes at random and are set to 1, with the rest initialised at 0. It can clearly be seen that while many runs quickly lead to successful adoption, defined as most or all nodes becoming active, there is a clear subset of about 44% of initial conditions that stagnates and does not take over an appreciable proportion of the network. In cases of stagnation the dynamics of the current model become frozen in a small number of time-steps and no more adoption takes place, due to the static nature of the network and deterministic rules used. Uptake fraction (a) timestep (b) Figure 3.1. Simulations of the adoption model on a community based network, with N = 500 nodes linked to others via their shared association with groups. Each node is randomly assigned to G = 2 groups, from a total of W = 100, and is linked with L = 5 other nodes per group. (a) Runs starting from 100 realisations of a 5% level of initial adoption (m 0 = 0.05), with model parameters.1,.8,.1, p = 0.5, θ = The mean uptake over the 100 realisations at time-step 36 is 56%. (b) The mean uptake at values in the β, γ parameter space, with α = 1 β γ. All nodes take the same parameter values as each other. Given that this sensitivity can result in a wide range of uptake levels, we focus on estimating the likelihood of success for a model run, rather than the expected level of success for a particular run. To obtain this the ensemble average uptake over 100 realisations of the choice of seed-nodes is computed for each chosen set of parameter values. The detailed structure of the network is randomised at each set of parameter values. In order to look at the influence of the parameters on the expected uptake, this calculation is repeated over a range of parameter values and plotted in the β, γ parameter space, with 0 β 1, 0 γ 1 and α = 1 β γ. An example plot is shown in Figure 3.1 (b). Two lines can be seen dividing regions of the parameter space where adoption is total (black), where uptake is about 65% (blue) and where it stagnates at levels up to only slightly above the initial seeding level of 5% (yellow). 4. Results and analysis. The procedure described in the previous section was carried out for different network topologies in order to investigate the general behaviour of the model. The results all show distinct regions of either near total success or stagnation, with a few exceptions where there is a region of intermediate probability of success. In this section we present the results of these simulations along with an analysis into the origin of the dividing lines between these regions in parameter space. This is presented first in terms of Erdős Rényi random (ER) networks, and later for other network models.

6 6 N. J. MCCULLEN, A. M. RUCKLIDGE, C. S. E. BALE, T. J. FOXON AND W. F. GALE 4.1. Number of neighbours needed to induce uptake. In order to understand which parameter values are likely to lead to a higher level of adoption, it is important to consider the properties of the nodes local network environment. Each node experiences the same p and m in Equation (2.3), so the only difference between the nodes is s i, the fraction of its neighbours that are active. For any set of parameter values and current adoption level m(t), there is a critical fraction s (t), defined by: s (t) = θ αp γm(t), (4.1) β such that if s i s, the node will adopt the innovation in the next time-step. The required number of active contacts Y i (an integer) is given by: Y i (t) = k i s i (t), (4.2) where denotes the smallest integer. If the actual number of active contacts Y i = j A ij x j (4.3) is at least Yi, then node i will take up the innovation in the next time-step. To simplify matters, we consider first networks where the nodes all have the same (or similar) degree k, defined by: k = 1 A ij. (4.4) N In this case we can define the critical number of active contacts to be Y = ks (t) ( ) θ αp γm(t) = k, (4.5) β and the success or otherwise of the innovation uptake across the network can be understood in terms of Y. If Y = 0, then all nodes immediately adopt the innovation. If Y = 1, then any node connected to one of the initial seed nodes adopts the innovation, and the innovation uptake will be successful in a fully connected network. If Y = 2, then a node must be connected to two active nodes in order to adopt. We show below that for reasonable values of m 0, and for a wide class of networks, this leads to success. The case Y = 3 will also be discussed below. Using α = 1 β γ, Equation (4.5) can be inverted to give: ( ) β = k γ(m(t) p) + p θ kp Y. (4.6) This gives, for different m(t), and for different integers Y, a sequence of lines in the (β, γ) parameter plane. These lines (with m(t) = m 0 ) are overlaid on numerical results in Figure 4.1 for random (ER) networks of different size (N = 500, N = 2000) and different average degree ( k = 6, k = 15). In Figure 4.1(a) (N = 500, k = 6), uptake is successful for most values of (β, γ) to the left of the Y = 2 line. This boundary becomes sharper for N = 2000 and agrees more closely with the theoretical Y = 2 line in Figure 4.1(b). For k = 15, N = 500 (Fig. 4.1(c)), it is the Y = 3 line that separates success from failure. ij

7 MULTI-PARAMETER MODELS OF INNOVATION DIFFUSION ON COMPLEX NETWORKS 7 (a) (b) (c) Figure 4.1. Comparison of simulations of the adoption model on random Erdős Rényi networks. As in all cases θ = 0.25 and p = 0.5. The mean node degree k and network size N values are: (a) k = 6, N = 500; (b) k = 6, N = 2000; (c) k = 15, N = 500. The results of the analysis in 4 are also plotted for Y = 0, 1, 2, 3, 4. The lines of Y in the (β, γ) plane show the upper limits of (β, γ) for each value of the critical number of neighbours Y. For example, two active neighbours are required to trigger adoption to the left of the Y = 2 line but this changes to three on the right side of the line Probability of induced uptake in random networks. We begin by calculating the probability that the condition Y i Y is satisfied. In the current context, where we consider the initial stages of propagation, the initial adopters are few in number and unlikely to be connected in the first instance. On finite size networks this is an important consideration, as it would determine whether the process stagnates in the early stages or has a chance of continuing through other mechanisms, such as via the clustering mechanism outlined in later sections. The assumption of non-overlapping active neighbourhoods is too strong to generalise to later-stages in the process, particularly on highly clustered networks. However, on large random (i.e. unclustered) networks, it will remain valid for several time-steps, as the neighbourhoods are uncorrelated and probabilities of active neighbours independent of one another. So for random networks with independent random assignment of initial conditions, where all nodes have statistically homogeneous local network environment and the same node degree k, the probability of Y neighbours being active is given by a binomial distribution: P(Y Y ) = k n=y ( ) k m n (1 m) (k n). (4.7) n

8 8 N. J. MCCULLEN, A. M. RUCKLIDGE, C. S. E. BALE, T. J. FOXON AND W. F. GALE This is just the probability of at least Y nodes being adopters, from k nodes in the neighbourhood, given that each node has a probability m of being an adopter. Clearly P(Y Y ) is zero if Y > k. For the specific examples in Figure 4.1 the outcomes in the different sectors of the parameter space can be understood using these ideas. If we define Z to be the number of nodes in the whole network whose neighbourhood influences them to adopt, then the probability that at least one further node will be influenced somewhere in the network is P(Z 1) = 1 P(Z = 0), where the probability that no neighbourhoods are influential is P(Z = 0) = (P(Y < Y )) N, and P(Y < Y ) = 1 P(Y Y ) which, using (4.7) gives the expression: P(Z 1) = 1 ( 1 k n=y ( ) ) N k m n (1 m) (k n). (4.8) n This can be seen to be a specific case of equation (1) in papers by Gleeson et al. [15,13], where average uptake levels are solved for the Watts 2002 model [27] (i.e. taking β = 1), on random networks with arbitrary degree distributions. Here we have restricted the analysis to a single node degree, rather than a distribution, for simplicity and to maintain consistency with the results in Equation (4.8) works for the examples used here, which are limited to cases where there is tightly bound node degree, but the more general formulation of Gleeson would most likely give more accurate results for the rates found within the different regions given by the analysis in 4.1. For small m equation (4.8) approximates to: ( ( ) ) k N P(Z 1) 1 1 Y m Y. (4.9) For k = 6, N = 500 and m 0 = 0.05 this gives P(Z 1) 1 for both Y = 1, 2, but for Y = 3, P(Z 1) 0.7. For the Y = 2 case, the probability of a site having an influential neighbourhood is P(Y Y ) and the expected number of nodes satisfying this condition is this probability multiplied by the number of remaining (inactive) nodes N(1 m)p(y Y ) 18, doubling adoption at each time-step. However, in the Y = 3 sector, the probability of any chosen node having the required number of neighbours is P(Y Y ) , resulting in only one expected new active node with a network size N = 500, easily leading to stagnation. The Y = 2 line becomes a sharper dividing line for larger networks (Fig. 4.1 (b)), as finite size fluctuation effects become less important. The value of Y which is the dividing line changes for k = 15 (Fig. 4.1 (c)), where N(1 m)p(y Y = 3) 27, again of the order of the initial seeding level, and so adoption is successful for Y = 3, but fails when Y = Propagation on random networks. In Equation (4.5), Y is a decreasing function of time, since m(t) can only increase. As argued above, if Y = 0 or 1, uptake will be successful. 1 It would be possible to reformulate the results in 4.1 in a similar spirit to Gleeson, but would involve performing a weighted sum over a range of terms of the form of equation 4.5 for every degree in the distribution k i rather than taking the mean value k, greatly reducing the simplicity of the result demonstrated here.

9 MULTI-PARAMETER MODELS OF INNOVATION DIFFUSION ON COMPLEX NETWORKS 9 In this section, we estimate the likelihood that Y will decrease from a larger initial value to 1, and how long this will take. The expected number of nodes that will become adopters in this time-step is the number of nodes that have not adopted the technology, N(1 m), multiplied by this probability. The overall fraction of active nodes will therefore increase by: m = (1 m)p(y Y ), (4.10) giving the updated value of m(t + 1) as a function of the current value f(m(t)): m(t + 1) = m(t) + (1 m(t))p(y Y ) f(m(t)). (4.11) Y is also a function of m but, being an integer, can only take discrete values, so f(m) is discontinuous when Y changes. This gives a macroscopic, system level, version of the microscopic (individual) dynamics given by Equation (2.2). The functions in (4.11) and (4.10) are shown in Figure 4.2 for some example parameter values. In Figure 4.2 (a) and (c) we have Y > k = 6 for m < 0.1, so 1 k=6, β=0.1, γ=0.9 1 k=6, β=0.5, γ= f(m) f(m) (a) m (b) m (c) m k=6, β=0.1, γ= e-05 1e-06 1e m (d) m k=6, β=0.5, γ= e-05 1e-06 1e m Figure 4.2. Plots of Eqn. (4.11), for k = 6, (a).1,.9 and (b).5,.2, and Eqn. (4.10) at the same values in (c) and (d) (on a log scale). In (a) and (c) Y > k for small m so there is no further uptake, and in (b) and (d) Y = 2 for small m so uptake is disproportionately slow for small levels of seeding. The diagonal is drawn for comparison in (a) and (b), while in (d) the fit to the initial slope is given. m = 0 in this range, and starting at an initial seed level of m 0 = 0.05 will lead to stagnation.

10 10 N. J. MCCULLEN, A. M. RUCKLIDGE, C. S. E. BALE, T. J. FOXON AND W. F. GALE If m 0 0.2, m is quite large and success will come quickly. In contrast, in Figure 4.2 (b) and (d), Y = 2 for small m, and uptake can only happen if the network size N is large enough to allow further nodes to be influenced. For small values of the initial adoption m 1 the following approximation can be made: ( ) k P(Y Y ) m Y m Y, (4.12) ( ) θ αp with Y k for small enough m. If Y > 1 then the super-linear power of m β results in very small returns for small initial seeding, and it takes a time on the order of m 1 Y 0 for a successful outcome, for small m Structured networks. The approach above works for random networks, where independence of neighbourhoods can be assumed, and for randomly distributed initial seeds. For networks with high clustering, where the clustering coefficient or transitivity [26, page 243], defined as ( ) 3 #(triangles) c =, (4.13) #(length 2 paths) is close to 1, this is not the case. This difference is demonstrated in the numerical simulations shown in Figure 4.3. For these results the Watts Strogatz scheme was used to rewire a highly clustered one dimensional lattice, where nodes are initially laid out in a ring and linked to their six nearest neighbours. Due to the large number of triangles, this network has a high transitivity c = 0.6, indicating a 60% probability that any two neighbours of a node are also neighbours of each other. For comparison, a completely random (ER) network of this size and edge density would have c = The probability of rewiring is p r, and for small values of p r where there is still significant clustering, the results show successful uptake in around 50% of cases in the Y = 3 sector, with either successful or stagnated adoption for Y values below or above this, respectively. This behaviour for Y = 3 would not be expected in random networks at these values, where the random probability of any particular neighbourhood triggering an adoption P(Y Y ) 0.002, resulting in only a single expected further uptake per realisation. This would result in very slow uptake or stagnation on finite networks, which is indeed what happens for large p r, where c is small and the network is again more random in structure (Fig. 4.3 (d)). The enhanced success of uptake in these cases is due to the clustered structure favouring continuing propagation from any influential neighbourhood. In clustered networks, any neighbour j of a newly activated node i is likely to also be a neighbour of the nodes that influenced i to adopt, and so j has an enhanced chance of itself becoming an adopter. If a suitable neighbourhood is present under these circumstances, one uptake will then trigger another in an adjacent position due to this overlap of neighbourhoods (see Fig. 4.4). If clustering is sufficient that there is overlap between neighbourhoods for a sizeable portion of the whole network, then it can take only a single critical neighbourhood to induce a successful uptake for the system. The 50% chance of success seen in Figure 4.3 (a) in the Y = 3 sector then represents the chance of randomly seeding a group of nodes in such a way as to trigger this process. The probability given by (4.8), of at least one node in a random system having a

11 MULTI-PARAMETER MODELS OF INNOVATION DIFFUSION ON COMPLEX NETWORKS 11 (a) (b) (c) (d) Figure 4.3. Results on Watts Strogatz networks with nodes initially connected to their six nearest neighbours on a one dimensional lattice and different rewiring probabilities p r, resulting in different transitivity c: (a) p r = 0, c = 0.6; (b) p r = 0.01, c = 0.57; (c) p r = 0.02, c = 0.53; (d) p r = 0.05, c = Model parameters are p = 0.5 and θ = 0.25, with N = 500. Edges were swapped in pairs to preserve the node degree k = 6. critical neighbourhood, yields P(Z 1) 0.67 for k = 6, Y = 3 and N = 500. Equation (4.8) is strictly valid only for independent neighbourhoods, and hence gives too high a value in this case, where neighbourhoods overlap, but a quantitatively accurate expression would require a far more intensive calculation of the different combinations of the initial seed for the whole system. However, the current method is accurate enough to give qualitatively correct predictions. The propagation via overlapping neighbourhoods is a percolation phenomenon, similar to that seen in other studies [22], but percolating on hyper-edges connecting hyper-nodes, rather than via single links. Here, a hyper-node is a complete sub-graph of Y + 1 nodes, or a (Y + 1)-clique. Two hyper-nodes are connected if the two (Y + 1)-cliques have Y nodes in common. The implication is that if a hyper-node becomes active, then every hyper-node to which it is connected will also become active in the next time-step. This is shown in Figure 4.4, for propagation via 4-cliques where Y = 3, with a single uptake triggering others via their overlapping neighbourhoods. Threshold models on clustered networks are discussed at length in Chapter 19 of Easley and Kleinberg s Networks, Crowds, and Markets [11] (including some useful references to the economics literature), motivated by coordination game models of micro-economic cooperation between individuals.

12 12 N. J. MCCULLEN, A. M. RUCKLIDGE, C. S. E. BALE, T. J. FOXON AND W. F. GALE To demonstrate the transition between cluster-enabled propagation and stagnation, the ensemble uptake within the Y = 3 sector of Figure 4.3 (after 36 time-steps) is shown in Figure 4.5, plotted as a function of both p r and c. The regular (un-rewired) network has a clustering coefficient c = 0.6, which decreases smoothly with increasing rewiring probability. If the node degree is held constant by rewiring edges in pairs (Fig. 4.5 (a)) then the average uptake after 36 time-steps fits well with the function m(36) = σ exp(εc), with fitting parameters σ = and ε = This is not the case if edges are rewired one at a time (Fig. 4.5 (b)), where the node degree becomes distributed. In this case the uptake peaks at around 5% rewiring (c 0.5), similar to other models showing a peak in the level of adoption at certain node degrees [1]. A further example is shown in Figure 4.6 for a community based, random clustered network [22], where the clustering can be varied by associating N individual nodes each via G groups of varying sizes M. The total number of communities W and number of connections L per individual in each community (here L = 5) determines the size and density of the communities and hence the amount of clustering. In Figure 4.6 (d) the dependence of c on W is shown alongside the mean uptake after 36 time-steps, averaged over 1000 realisations for each W. Similar results can be seen as in the previous case, with increased clustering resulting in an increased likelihood of successful uptake, despite the low number of influential neighbourhoods. However, these expected values are only valid when averaging over different (a) (b) (c) (d) Figure 4.4. An example of uptake propagation via clustering, in a network where nodes require three active neighbours to become active themselves. The sequence of uptakes is shown in (a) (d), starting from a single node influenced by three of its neighbours, which then induces further uptake via 3-member overlap of 4-cliques.

13 MULTI-PARAMETER MODELS OF INNOVATION DIFFUSION ON COMPLEX NETWORKS c 0.4 _ m(36) (a) p m(36) r _ (b) c Figure 4.5. Uptake on Watts Strogatz rewired 6-neighbour rings, after 36 time-steps, against both rewiring probability p r and clustering c. (a) Runs starting from 1000 random initial conditions with m 0 = 0.05, α = 0.1,.45,.45, p = 0.5, θ = 0.25, randomising the network on each realisation. Edges are rewired in pairs to preserve the node degree k = 6. Dashed blue lines show the data in Fig. 4.3, with p r = 0, 0.01, 0.02, 0.05 and c = 0.6, 0.57, 0.53, 0.45, respectively. The fitted red curve is the function σ exp(εc), with σ = , ε = (b) For comparison, the same system is used but with edges rewired individually between 0 < p r < 0.5, showing the effect of allowing distribution of the node degree with p r. A peak in the uptake appears at c 0.5. network realisations as well as initial adopters. For many networks it was found that uptake was almost never achieved for most choices of initial adopters, which we believe to be related to the connectedness of cliques of size Y + 1. However, an interesting observation is the strong functional dependence of the expected success on the transitivity, which fits to about 1% accuracy to the function: m(36) = 1 σ exp( εc), (4.14) with fitting parameters σ = 0.86, ε = This relationship was also found for different values of within the Y = 3 sector, with different coefficients in (4.14). This suggests that it is possible to obtain an analytical expression for these systems, and should motivate further research. The phenomenon of connectedness via more highly connected clusters than single edges is known as k-clique percolation, and results exist deriving this result for random (ER) networks [10, 24]. However, to understand the results in Figure 4.6 analytically would require results for the expected connected (Y + 1)-clique percolation component size distribution as a function of the clustering coefficient. Some progress has been made in this direction, with numerical results existing for cascades of various models, such as Watts threshold model [27] on clustered random networks like the Newman model [18]. Additionally analytical results have also been derived for expected connected component sizes for single bond percolation on clustered networks [14]. However, obtaining the required results for k-clique percolation components remains an open and difficult problem. These results imply that, in cases where several network neighbours are required to influence adoption, greater levels of system-wide adoption can be achieved in more highly clustered networks, in agreement with earlier results on similar systems [8]. Therefore, innovations in systems with more communication between overlapping groups of individuals will be more

14 14 N. J. MCCULLEN, A. M. RUCKLIDGE, C. S. E. BALE, T. J. FOXON AND W. F. GALE (a) (b) 0.32 c (c) (d) W 0.4 _ m(36) Figure 4.6. Same as Figs. 4.3 and 4.5 but for a community-based, Newman random clustered, network model. The network size N = 500, so for each number of groups W there are M members, on average, resulting in a measured transitivity c: (a) W = 20, M = 25, c = (b) W = 40, M = 12.5, c = (c) W = 100, M = 5, c = 0.2 (d) Clustering as a function of W versus uptake for.1,.8,.1 within the Y = 3 sector. The fitted red line is the empirical function m(36) = 1 σ exp( εc), with σ = 0.86, ε = likely to succeed than if such overlap were not present Scale-free networks. In the current model and analysis we have so far only considered networks with node degrees that are distributed close to the mean value. This is mainly due so the nature of the recommendation network being restricted to a close group of associates. However, it is possible to apply the multi-parameter model used here to networks with broader degree distributions, in order to compare the results and their generalisability. In such cases the fat-tails of the degree distribution strongly violate the requirement of our analysis (in 4.1) that k be meaningful and represent most of the nodes in the network. The result of this is demonstrated in Figure 4.7 using Barabasí Albert networks, showing how the division between the regions of the parameter space becomes less clear than in the case of near-constant degree. In such cases the analysis presented here would not be applicable, and would require a more sophisticated approach. 5. Conclusions. We have introduced a three parameter model for the diffusion of innovations by individuals connected by a network of peer to peer influences, and methods for the investigation and analysis of such models. This model has particular application to technologies with varying degrees of visibility, such as energy efficiency installations in households.

15 MULTI-PARAMETER MODELS OF INNOVATION DIFFUSION ON COMPLEX NETWORKS 15 Y * = 6 Y * = 8 (a) (b) Figure 4.7. Results on a scale-free Barabasí Albert network. The division between regions of the parameter space is less clearly defined and no longer linear, due to the broad degree distribution of the nodes. Numerical simulations have been carried out, computing the average uptake of an innovation over many realisations, to account for the sensitivity of network diffusion processes. This was carried out at a range of model parameter values, on various network topologies and initial conditions. It has been found that the expected level of adoption depends strongly on the topology of the network and the Y sector that the (β, γ) parameters are in. The node degree and the network s transitivity, related to the correlation between the neighbourhoods of connected individuals, were found to be of particular importance. An analytical and probabilistic approach has been developed to account for the observed behaviour. In the current work we have introduced the model, along with methods for investigating it and similar models, in its most tractable form. The analysis explains the results of the numerical calculations well in the case of randomly connected networks, and provides useful insight in the case of networks with clustering. The study and the model here are limited to homogeneous nodes with the same parameters and equal weights. The analysis of the model also made use of the assumption of a near-constant node degree, and so do not carry over simply to scale-free networks. In this work we argued that communication on innovation adoption is restricted to a select few contacts, therefore excluding wide degree distributions. An alternative would be to assume that individuals are influenced by a number rather than fraction of their network neighbours, which is independent of k. The dynamical adoption model can be made to account for the various archetypes discussed in the social science literature by assigning individuals to different groups. Individuals in different categories can be assigned different α i, β i and γ i values, depending on their personality, for example with technology enthusiasts having high α values, social followers having high β, and cautious individuals having a high γ. In subsequent work we have extended the model to cases involving inhomogeneous nodes with distributions of parameters, weights and degrees, in order to study the sensitivity of the results to such factors [3]. The model provides a basis to simulate the behaviour seen in the real world. For example, it can form the basis for computational investigations comparing different interventions by a government agency to try to improve the level of uptake of innovations relating to energy efficiency. These could be represented in the model by varying the initial seeding for different

16 16 N. J. MCCULLEN, A. M. RUCKLIDGE, C. S. E. BALE, T. J. FOXON AND W. F. GALE roll-out strategies, or network structure for different word-of-mouth marketing campaigns. By identifying intervention strategies that have a high probability of achieving successful uptake of the technology, the model could allow government to make informed decisions of whether to go ahead with interventions and if so, how. Such interventions are the subject of subsequent research by the authors [2] based on enhancing uptake, either by altering the parameters of the model or the network structure, in ways that have real-world interpretations. In a similar way the effect of marketing could also be considered in a more general context. Such advertising would be an active attempt to promote, or enhance the perception of the utility through one or more of the parameters or variables. This could be included as either a nonlinear function of m(t) (currently a linear global (all all) feedback from the system norm to the individuals) or another term that effectively increases u. Related models have used an external driver taking this role, in addition to the feed-back from other nodes [5], and this feature could easily be incorporated into our model. Additionally, the current model currently only considers a single innovation, but it would also be interesting to include features of competition between competing products in future developments. Future studies could also modify the community-based network models to provide more flexibility and realistic features in a number of ways. Some positional information can be ascribed to the nodes and some or all of the groups, preferentially attaching individuals to communities that are geographically closer, in a similar way to Hamill and Gilbert s Social Circles model [19]. In cases where none (or only one) of the groups have geographic information they again reduce to the Newman scheme. These groups could be classified into different categories, for example some could have a fixed membership number to allow variation of the clustering between groups and represent different types of group interaction (e.g., social or workplace groups). For other types there could be no geographical element, introducing long-range connections into the network, as may be the case for workplaces. The model could also be given a stochastic element, either on the transfer of information along links (e.g. as in [5]), or by allowing a distribution of time-step values, as well as non-synchronous updating, and introducing a probabilistic, rather than deterministic, uptake once the utility exceeds its threshold. A further feature of interest is that of non-static network topologies. Although the networks in the short time-scales investigated here have been assumed static, it is interesting to consider what effect dynamic networks would have on the adoption process. In our subsequent modelling work we have investigated cases where links are added to existing networks as the diffusion process is ongoing [2]. Depending on the nature of the dynamics of the network re-structuring, there is potential for the added mixing to enhance uptake in these cases. As well as the application of the diffusion of (energy) innovations that were used as a basis for this model, the methods discussed in this paper can also be applied to multi-parameter models of different systems with similar features, and provide a framework for the investigation of many real-world systems. Acknowledgements. The authors thank Mason Porter for some very useful discussions of this problem from the perspective of mean-field and probability approaches. The authors are also grateful for the considered and thoughtful comments and suggestions of the referees, which have been very helpful in improving the manuscript and providing food for thought.

17 MULTI-PARAMETER MODELS OF INNOVATION DIFFUSION ON COMPLEX NETWORKS 17 REFERENCES [1] F. Alkemade and C. Castaldi, Strategies for the diffusion of innovations on social networks, Computational Economics, 25 (2005), pp [2] C. S. E. Bale, N. J. McCullen, T. J. Foxon, A. M. Rucklidge, and W. F. Gale, Harnessing social networks for promoting adoption of energy technologies in the domestic sector. submitted January 2012 as part of Complexity Science in the Real World Network Conference. [3], Modelling diffusion of energy innovations on a social network and integration of real-world data, Energy Policy. submitted December [4], Local authority interventions in the domestic sector and the role of social networks: a case study from the city of leeds., UKERC conference. Energy and People: Futures, complexity and challenges, June [5] D.S. Bassett, D.L. Alderson, and J.M. Carlson, Collective decision dynamics in the presence of external drivers, Physical Review E, 86 (2012), p [6] S. Bikhchandani, D. Hirshleifer, and I. Welch, A theory of fads, fashion, custom, and cultural change as informational cascades, Journal of Political Economy, (1992), pp [7] C. Castellano, S. Fortunato, and V. Loreto, Statistical physics of social dynamics, Reviews of Modern Physics, 81 (2009), pp [8] H. Choi, S.H. Kim, and J. Lee, Role of network structure and network effects in diffusion of innovations, Industrial Marketing Management, 39 (2010), pp [9] S. A. Delre, W. Jager, T. H. A. Bijmolt, and M. A. Janssen, Will it spread or not? The effects of social influences and network topology on innovation diffusion, Journal of Product Innovation Management, 27 (2010), pp [10] I. Derényi, G. Palla, and T. Vicsek, Clique percolation in random networks, Physical Review Letters, 94 (2005), p [11] D. Easley and J. Kleinberg, Networks, crowds, and markets, Cambridge Univ Press, [12] P. Erdős and A. Rényi, On the evolution of random graphs, Akad. Kiadó, [13] J.P. Gleeson, Cascades on correlated and modular random networks, Physical Review E, 77 (2008), p [14], Bond percolation on a class of clustered random networks, Physical Review E, 80 (2009), p [15] J.P. Gleeson and D.J. Cahalane, Seed size strongly affects cascades on random networks, Physical Review E, 75 (2007), p [16] J.P. Gleeson, S. Melnik, J.A. Ward, M.A. Porter, and P.J. Mucha, Accuracy of mean-field theory for dynamics on real-world networks, Physical Review E, 85 (2012), p [17] M. Granovetter and R. Soong, Threshold models of diffusion and collective behavior, Journal of Mathematical Sociology, 9 (1983), pp [18] A. Hackett, S. Melnik, and J.P. Gleeson, Cascades on a class of clustered random networks, Physical Review E, 83 (2011), p [19] L. Hamill and N. Gilbert, Social circles: A simple structure for agent-based social network models, Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 12 (2009). [20] E. Lee, J. Lee, and J. Lee, Reconsideration of the winner-take-all hypothesis: Complex networks and local bias, Management Science, (2006), pp [21] P.G. Lind and H.J. Herrmann, New approaches to model and study social networks, New Journal of Physics, 9 (2007), p [22] M.E.J. Newman, Properties of highly clustered networks, Physical Review E, 68 (2003), p [23] G. Palla, I. Derényi, I. Farkas, and T. Vicsek, Uncovering the overlapping community structure of complex networks in nature and society, Nature, 435 (2005), pp [24] G. Palla, I. Derényi, and T. Vicsek, The critical point of k-clique percolation in the erdős rényi graph, Journal of Statistical Physics, 128 (2007), pp [25] T.W. Valente, Social network thresholds in the diffusion of innovations, Social Networks, 18 (1996), pp [26] S. Wasserman and K. Faust, Social network analysis: Methods and applications, vol. 8, Cambridge university press, [27] D.J. Watts, A simple model of global cascades on random networks, Proceedings of the National Academy

18 18 N. J. MCCULLEN, A. M. RUCKLIDGE, C. S. E. BALE, T. J. FOXON AND W. F. GALE of Sciences, 99 (2002), p [28] D.J. Watts and S.H. Strogatz, Collective dynamics of small-world networks, Nature, 393 (1998), pp [29] M.W. Weenig and C.J. Midden, Communication network influences on information diffusion and persuasion., Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 61 (1991), p. 734.

ECS 289 F / MAE 298, Lecture 15 May 20, Diffusion, Cascades and Influence

ECS 289 F / MAE 298, Lecture 15 May 20, Diffusion, Cascades and Influence ECS 289 F / MAE 298, Lecture 15 May 20, 2014 Diffusion, Cascades and Influence Diffusion and cascades in networks (Nodes in one of two states) Viruses (human and computer) contact processes epidemic thresholds

More information

Diffusion of Innovations in Social Networks

Diffusion of Innovations in Social Networks Daron Acemoglu Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Department of Economics, Cambridge, MA, 02139, daron@mit.edu Diffusion of Innovations in Social Networks Asuman Ozdaglar Massachusetts Institute of

More information

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 12: Generalized Random Graphs

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 12: Generalized Random Graphs 6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 12: Generalized Random Graphs 1 Outline Small-world model Growing random networks Power-law degree distributions: Rich-Get-Richer effects Models: Uniform attachment model

More information

Diffusion of Innovation and Influence Maximization

Diffusion of Innovation and Influence Maximization Diffusion of Innovation and Influence Maximization Leonid E. Zhukov School of Data Analysis and Artificial Intelligence Department of Computer Science National Research University Higher School of Economics

More information

Information Cascades in Social Networks via Dynamic System Analyses

Information Cascades in Social Networks via Dynamic System Analyses Information Cascades in Social Networks via Dynamic System Analyses Shao-Lun Huang and Kwang-Cheng Chen Graduate Institute of Communication Engineering, National Taiwan University, Taipei, Taiwan Email:{huangntu,

More information

Growing a Network on a Given Substrate

Growing a Network on a Given Substrate Growing a Network on a Given Substrate 1 Babak Fotouhi and Michael G. Rabbat Department of Electrical and Computer Engineering McGill University, Montréal, Québec, Canada Email: babak.fotouhi@mail.mcgill.ca,

More information

Adventures in random graphs: Models, structures and algorithms

Adventures in random graphs: Models, structures and algorithms BCAM January 2011 1 Adventures in random graphs: Models, structures and algorithms Armand M. Makowski ECE & ISR/HyNet University of Maryland at College Park armand@isr.umd.edu BCAM January 2011 2 Complex

More information

Decision Making and Social Networks

Decision Making and Social Networks Decision Making and Social Networks Lecture 4: Models of Network Growth Umberto Grandi Summer 2013 Overview In the previous lecture: We got acquainted with graphs and networks We saw lots of definitions:

More information

Modeling, Analysis, and Control of Information Propagation in Multi-layer and Multiplex Networks. Osman Yağan

Modeling, Analysis, and Control of Information Propagation in Multi-layer and Multiplex Networks. Osman Yağan Modeling, Analysis, and Control of Information Propagation in Multi-layer and Multiplex Networks Osman Yağan Department of ECE Carnegie Mellon University Joint work with Y. Zhuang and V. Gligor (CMU) Alex

More information

Cascades on Temporal Networks

Cascades on Temporal Networks Cascades on Temporal Networks Georgios Kapros-Anastasiadis St Anne s College University of Oxford A thesis submitted for the degree of M.Sc. in Mathematical Modelling and Scientific Computing September

More information

Deterministic Decentralized Search in Random Graphs

Deterministic Decentralized Search in Random Graphs Deterministic Decentralized Search in Random Graphs Esteban Arcaute 1,, Ning Chen 2,, Ravi Kumar 3, David Liben-Nowell 4,, Mohammad Mahdian 3, Hamid Nazerzadeh 1,, and Ying Xu 1, 1 Stanford University.

More information

Web Structure Mining Nodes, Links and Influence

Web Structure Mining Nodes, Links and Influence Web Structure Mining Nodes, Links and Influence 1 Outline 1. Importance of nodes 1. Centrality 2. Prestige 3. Page Rank 4. Hubs and Authority 5. Metrics comparison 2. Link analysis 3. Influence model 1.

More information

Efficient Network Structures with Separable Heterogeneous Connection Costs

Efficient Network Structures with Separable Heterogeneous Connection Costs Efficient Network Structures with Separable Heterogeneous Connection Costs Babak Heydari a, Mohsen Mosleh a, Kia Dalili b arxiv:1504.06634v3 [q-fin.ec] 11 Dec 2015 a School of Systems and Enterprises,

More information

Opinion Dynamics on Triad Scale Free Network

Opinion Dynamics on Triad Scale Free Network Opinion Dynamics on Triad Scale Free Network Li Qianqian 1 Liu Yijun 1,* Tian Ruya 1,2 Ma Ning 1,2 1 Institute of Policy and Management, Chinese Academy of Sciences, Beijing 100190, China lqqcindy@gmail.com,

More information

Lecture VI Introduction to complex networks. Santo Fortunato

Lecture VI Introduction to complex networks. Santo Fortunato Lecture VI Introduction to complex networks Santo Fortunato Plan of the course I. Networks: definitions, characteristics, basic concepts in graph theory II. III. IV. Real world networks: basic properties

More information

Diffusion of Innovation

Diffusion of Innovation Diffusion of Innovation Leonid E. Zhukov School of Data Analysis and Artificial Intelligence Department of Computer Science National Research University Higher School of Economics Social Network Analysis

More information

How opinion dynamics generates group hierarchies

How opinion dynamics generates group hierarchies Author-produced version of the paper presented at ECCS'0 European Conference on Complex Systems, 3-7 septembre 200 - Lisbonne, Portugal How opinion dynamics generates group hierarchies F. Gargiulo, S.

More information

Spatial and Temporal Behaviors in a Modified Evolution Model Based on Small World Network

Spatial and Temporal Behaviors in a Modified Evolution Model Based on Small World Network Commun. Theor. Phys. (Beijing, China) 42 (2004) pp. 242 246 c International Academic Publishers Vol. 42, No. 2, August 15, 2004 Spatial and Temporal Behaviors in a Modified Evolution Model Based on Small

More information

Rate of Convergence of Learning in Social Networks

Rate of Convergence of Learning in Social Networks Rate of Convergence of Learning in Social Networks Ilan Lobel, Daron Acemoglu, Munther Dahleh and Asuman Ozdaglar Massachusetts Institute of Technology Cambridge, MA Abstract We study the rate of convergence

More information

Evolving network with different edges

Evolving network with different edges Evolving network with different edges Jie Sun, 1,2 Yizhi Ge, 1,3 and Sheng Li 1, * 1 Department of Physics, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, Shanghai, China 2 Department of Mathematics and Computer Science,

More information

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.dis-nn] 18 Feb 2004 Diego Garlaschelli a,b and Maria I. Loffredo b,c

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.dis-nn] 18 Feb 2004 Diego Garlaschelli a,b and Maria I. Loffredo b,c Wealth Dynamics on Complex Networks arxiv:cond-mat/0402466v1 [cond-mat.dis-nn] 18 Feb 2004 Diego Garlaschelli a,b and Maria I. Loffredo b,c a Dipartimento di Fisica, Università di Siena, Via Roma 56, 53100

More information

The Beginning of Graph Theory. Theory and Applications of Complex Networks. Eulerian paths. Graph Theory. Class Three. College of the Atlantic

The Beginning of Graph Theory. Theory and Applications of Complex Networks. Eulerian paths. Graph Theory. Class Three. College of the Atlantic Theory and Applications of Complex Networs 1 Theory and Applications of Complex Networs 2 Theory and Applications of Complex Networs Class Three The Beginning of Graph Theory Leonhard Euler wonders, can

More information

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 7: Search on Networks: Navigation and Web Search

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 7: Search on Networks: Navigation and Web Search 6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 7: Search on Networks: Navigation and Web Search Daron Acemoglu and Asu Ozdaglar MIT September 30, 2009 1 Networks: Lecture 7 Outline Navigation (or decentralized search)

More information

1 Complex Networks - A Brief Overview

1 Complex Networks - A Brief Overview Power-law Degree Distributions 1 Complex Networks - A Brief Overview Complex networks occur in many social, technological and scientific settings. Examples of complex networks include World Wide Web, Internet,

More information

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.dis-nn] 4 May 2000

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.dis-nn] 4 May 2000 Topology of evolving networks: local events and universality arxiv:cond-mat/0005085v1 [cond-mat.dis-nn] 4 May 2000 Réka Albert and Albert-László Barabási Department of Physics, University of Notre-Dame,

More information

Maximizing the Spread of Influence through a Social Network. David Kempe, Jon Kleinberg, Éva Tardos SIGKDD 03

Maximizing the Spread of Influence through a Social Network. David Kempe, Jon Kleinberg, Éva Tardos SIGKDD 03 Maximizing the Spread of Influence through a Social Network David Kempe, Jon Kleinberg, Éva Tardos SIGKDD 03 Influence and Social Networks Economics, sociology, political science, etc. all have studied

More information

ECS 253 / MAE 253, Lecture 15 May 17, I. Probability generating function recap

ECS 253 / MAE 253, Lecture 15 May 17, I. Probability generating function recap ECS 253 / MAE 253, Lecture 15 May 17, 2016 I. Probability generating function recap Part I. Ensemble approaches A. Master equations (Random graph evolution, cluster aggregation) B. Network configuration

More information

Analysis of Variance and Co-variance. By Manza Ramesh

Analysis of Variance and Co-variance. By Manza Ramesh Analysis of Variance and Co-variance By Manza Ramesh Contents Analysis of Variance (ANOVA) What is ANOVA? The Basic Principle of ANOVA ANOVA Technique Setting up Analysis of Variance Table Short-cut Method

More information

Nonlinear Dynamical Behavior in BS Evolution Model Based on Small-World Network Added with Nonlinear Preference

Nonlinear Dynamical Behavior in BS Evolution Model Based on Small-World Network Added with Nonlinear Preference Commun. Theor. Phys. (Beijing, China) 48 (2007) pp. 137 142 c International Academic Publishers Vol. 48, No. 1, July 15, 2007 Nonlinear Dynamical Behavior in BS Evolution Model Based on Small-World Network

More information

Complex networks: an introduction

Complex networks: an introduction Alain Barrat Complex networks: an introduction CPT, Marseille, France ISI, Turin, Italy http://www.cpt.univ-mrs.fr/~barrat http://cxnets.googlepages.com Plan of the lecture I. INTRODUCTION II. I. Networks:

More information

Preliminary Results on Social Learning with Partial Observations

Preliminary Results on Social Learning with Partial Observations Preliminary Results on Social Learning with Partial Observations Ilan Lobel, Daron Acemoglu, Munther Dahleh and Asuman Ozdaglar ABSTRACT We study a model of social learning with partial observations from

More information

Online Social Networks and Media. Opinion formation on social networks

Online Social Networks and Media. Opinion formation on social networks Online Social Networks and Media Opinion formation on social networks Diffusion of items So far we have assumed that what is being diffused in the network is some discrete item: E.g., a virus, a product,

More information

Power Laws & Rich Get Richer

Power Laws & Rich Get Richer Power Laws & Rich Get Richer CMSC 498J: Social Media Computing Department of Computer Science University of Maryland Spring 2015 Hadi Amiri hadi@umd.edu Lecture Topics Popularity as a Network Phenomenon

More information

1 Mechanistic and generative models of network structure

1 Mechanistic and generative models of network structure 1 Mechanistic and generative models of network structure There are many models of network structure, and these largely can be divided into two classes: mechanistic models and generative or probabilistic

More information

Network models: dynamical growth and small world

Network models: dynamical growth and small world Network models: dynamical growth and small world Leonid E. Zhukov School of Data Analysis and Artificial Intelligence Department of Computer Science National Research University Higher School of Economics

More information

Modeling Strategic Information Sharing in Indian Villages

Modeling Strategic Information Sharing in Indian Villages Modeling Strategic Information Sharing in Indian Villages Jeff Jacobs jjacobs3@stanford.edu Arun Chandrasekhar arungc@stanford.edu Emily Breza Columbia University ebreza@columbia.edu December 3, 203 Matthew

More information

Complex networks and evolutionary games

Complex networks and evolutionary games Volume 2 Complex networks and evolutionary games Michael Kirley Department of Computer Science and Software Engineering The University of Melbourne, Victoria, Australia Email: mkirley@cs.mu.oz.au Abstract

More information

Efficient routing in Poisson small-world networks

Efficient routing in Poisson small-world networks Efficient routing in Poisson small-world networks M. Draief and A. Ganesh Abstract In recent work, Jon Kleinberg considered a small-world network model consisting of a d-dimensional lattice augmented with

More information

A LINE GRAPH as a model of a social network

A LINE GRAPH as a model of a social network A LINE GRAPH as a model of a social networ Małgorzata Krawczy, Lev Muchni, Anna Mańa-Krasoń, Krzysztof Kułaowsi AGH Kraów Stern School of Business of NY University outline - ideas, definitions, milestones

More information

Predicting AGI: What can we say when we know so little?

Predicting AGI: What can we say when we know so little? Predicting AGI: What can we say when we know so little? Fallenstein, Benja Mennen, Alex December 2, 2013 (Working Paper) 1 Time to taxi Our situation now looks fairly similar to our situation 20 years

More information

On Resolution Limit of the Modularity in Community Detection

On Resolution Limit of the Modularity in Community Detection The Ninth International Symposium on Operations Research and Its Applications (ISORA 10) Chengdu-Jiuzhaigou, China, August 19 23, 2010 Copyright 2010 ORSC & APORC, pp. 492 499 On Resolution imit of the

More information

Communities Via Laplacian Matrices. Degree, Adjacency, and Laplacian Matrices Eigenvectors of Laplacian Matrices

Communities Via Laplacian Matrices. Degree, Adjacency, and Laplacian Matrices Eigenvectors of Laplacian Matrices Communities Via Laplacian Matrices Degree, Adjacency, and Laplacian Matrices Eigenvectors of Laplacian Matrices The Laplacian Approach As with betweenness approach, we want to divide a social graph into

More information

Oriented majority-vote model in social dynamics

Oriented majority-vote model in social dynamics Author: Facultat de Física, Universitat de Barcelona, Diagonal 645, 08028 Barcelona, Spain. Advisor: M. Ángeles Serrano Mass events ruled by collective behaviour are present in our society every day. Some

More information

A Random Dot Product Model for Weighted Networks arxiv: v1 [stat.ap] 8 Nov 2016

A Random Dot Product Model for Weighted Networks arxiv: v1 [stat.ap] 8 Nov 2016 A Random Dot Product Model for Weighted Networks arxiv:1611.02530v1 [stat.ap] 8 Nov 2016 Daryl R. DeFord 1 Daniel N. Rockmore 1,2,3 1 Department of Mathematics, Dartmouth College, Hanover, NH, USA 03755

More information

SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION

SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION Social diversity promotes the emergence of cooperation in public goods games Francisco C. Santos 1, Marta D. Santos & Jorge M. Pacheco 1 IRIDIA, Computer and Decision Engineering Department, Université

More information

ECS 253 / MAE 253, Lecture 13 May 15, Diffusion, Cascades and Influence Mathematical models & generating functions

ECS 253 / MAE 253, Lecture 13 May 15, Diffusion, Cascades and Influence Mathematical models & generating functions ECS 253 / MAE 253, Lecture 13 May 15, 2018 Diffusion, Cascades and Influence Mathematical models & generating functions Last week: spatial flows and game theory on networks Optimal location of facilities

More information

Game Theory, Population Dynamics, Social Aggregation. Daniele Vilone (CSDC - Firenze) Namur

Game Theory, Population Dynamics, Social Aggregation. Daniele Vilone (CSDC - Firenze) Namur Game Theory, Population Dynamics, Social Aggregation Daniele Vilone (CSDC - Firenze) Namur - 18.12.2008 Summary Introduction ( GT ) General concepts of Game Theory Game Theory and Social Dynamics Application:

More information

Modeling of Growing Networks with Directional Attachment and Communities

Modeling of Growing Networks with Directional Attachment and Communities Modeling of Growing Networks with Directional Attachment and Communities Masahiro KIMURA, Kazumi SAITO, Naonori UEDA NTT Communication Science Laboratories 2-4 Hikaridai, Seika-cho, Kyoto 619-0237, Japan

More information

CENTRAL OR POLARIZED PATTERNS IN COLLECTIVE ACTIONS

CENTRAL OR POLARIZED PATTERNS IN COLLECTIVE ACTIONS 1 IMITATION, LEARNING, AND COMMUNICATION: CENTRAL OR POLARIZED PATTERNS IN COLLECTIVE ACTIONS Ping Chen I.Prigogine Center for Studies in Statistical Mechanics and Complex Systems and IC2 Institute University

More information

Year 9 plan Victorian Curriculum: Humanities Semester Two (Geography/Economics and Business)

Year 9 plan Victorian Curriculum: Humanities Semester Two (Geography/Economics and Business) Year 9 plan Victorian Curriculum: Humanities Semester Two (Geography/Economics and Business) Implementation year: School name: Kyabram P-12 College Prepared By: Rowena Morris Identify Curriculum Curriculum

More information

Data Mining and Analysis: Fundamental Concepts and Algorithms

Data Mining and Analysis: Fundamental Concepts and Algorithms Data Mining and Analysis: Fundamental Concepts and Algorithms dataminingbook.info Mohammed J. Zaki 1 Wagner Meira Jr. 2 1 Department of Computer Science Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute, Troy, NY, USA

More information

ECS 289 / MAE 298, Lecture 7 April 22, Percolation and Epidemiology on Networks, Part 2 Searching on networks

ECS 289 / MAE 298, Lecture 7 April 22, Percolation and Epidemiology on Networks, Part 2 Searching on networks ECS 289 / MAE 298, Lecture 7 April 22, 2014 Percolation and Epidemiology on Networks, Part 2 Searching on networks 28 project pitches turned in Announcements We are compiling them into one file to share

More information

Chaos, Complexity, and Inference (36-462)

Chaos, Complexity, and Inference (36-462) Chaos, Complexity, and Inference (36-462) Lecture 21: More Networks: Models and Origin Myths Cosma Shalizi 31 March 2009 New Assignment: Implement Butterfly Mode in R Real Agenda: Models of Networks, with

More information

Mathematical analysis of the primary network effect

Mathematical analysis of the primary network effect Noname manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) Mathematical analysis of the primary network effect Etienne Emmrich 1, Joachim Kaldasch 1 TU Berlin, Institut für Mathematik, Straße des 17. Juni

More information

ESSENTIAL CONCEPTS AND SKILL SETS OF THE IOWA CORE CURRICULUM

ESSENTIAL CONCEPTS AND SKILL SETS OF THE IOWA CORE CURRICULUM ESSENTIAL CONCEPTS AND SKILL SETS OF THE IOWA CORE CURRICULUM SOCIAL STUDIES PROVIDED BY THE IOWA DEPARTMENT OF EDUCATION INTRODUCTION Social studies is the integrated study of the social sciences and

More information

Chaos, Complexity, and Inference (36-462)

Chaos, Complexity, and Inference (36-462) Chaos, Complexity, and Inference (36-462) Lecture 21 Cosma Shalizi 3 April 2008 Models of Networks, with Origin Myths Erdős-Rényi Encore Erdős-Rényi with Node Types Watts-Strogatz Small World Graphs Exponential-Family

More information

Complex Networks, Course 303A, Spring, Prof. Peter Dodds

Complex Networks, Course 303A, Spring, Prof. Peter Dodds Complex Networks, Course 303A, Spring, 2009 Prof. Peter Dodds Department of Mathematics & Statistics University of Vermont Licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 3.0 License.

More information

Efficient Network Structures with Separable Heterogeneous Connection Costs

Efficient Network Structures with Separable Heterogeneous Connection Costs MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Efficient Network Structures with Separable Heterogeneous Connection Costs Babak Heydari and Mohsen Mosleh and Kia Dalili School of Systems and Enterprises, Stevens Institute

More information

Networks as vectors of their motif frequencies and 2-norm distance as a measure of similarity

Networks as vectors of their motif frequencies and 2-norm distance as a measure of similarity Networks as vectors of their motif frequencies and 2-norm distance as a measure of similarity CS322 Project Writeup Semih Salihoglu Stanford University 353 Serra Street Stanford, CA semih@stanford.edu

More information

A simple agricultural land use model implemented using Geographical Vector Agents (GVA)

A simple agricultural land use model implemented using Geographical Vector Agents (GVA) A simple agricultural land use model implemented using Geographical Vector Agents (GVA) A. B. Moore 1, Y. Hammam 2, P. A. Whigham 2 1 School of Surveying / 2 Department of Information Science, University

More information

A Threshold Model of Social Contagion Process for Evacuation Decision Making

A Threshold Model of Social Contagion Process for Evacuation Decision Making A Threshold Model of Social Contagion Process for Evacuation Decision Making Samiul Hasan 1 Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN 47907, USA Satish Ukkusuri 2, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN 47907,

More information

arxiv: v2 [physics.soc-ph] 22 Nov 2015

arxiv: v2 [physics.soc-ph] 22 Nov 2015 Effects of local and global network connectivity on synergistic epidemics David Broder-Rodgers Selwyn College and Cavendish Laboratory, University of Cambridge, Cambridge, UK Francisco J. Pérez-Reche Institute

More information

CS224W: Social and Information Network Analysis Jure Leskovec, Stanford University

CS224W: Social and Information Network Analysis Jure Leskovec, Stanford University CS224W: Social and Information Network Analysis Jure Leskovec, Stanford University http://cs224w.stanford.edu 10/24/2012 Jure Leskovec, Stanford CS224W: Social and Information Network Analysis, http://cs224w.stanford.edu

More information

Holme and Newman (2006) Evolving voter model. Extreme Cases. Community sizes N =3200, M =6400, γ =10. Our model: continuous time. Finite size scaling

Holme and Newman (2006) Evolving voter model. Extreme Cases. Community sizes N =3200, M =6400, γ =10. Our model: continuous time. Finite size scaling Evolving voter model Rick Durrett 1, James Gleeson 5, Alun Lloyd 4, Peter Mucha 3, Bill Shi 3, David Sivakoff 1, Josh Socolar 2,andChris Varghese 2 1. Duke Math, 2. Duke Physics, 3. UNC Math, 4. NC State

More information

Spectral Analysis of Directed Complex Networks. Tetsuro Murai

Spectral Analysis of Directed Complex Networks. Tetsuro Murai MASTER THESIS Spectral Analysis of Directed Complex Networks Tetsuro Murai Department of Physics, Graduate School of Science and Engineering, Aoyama Gakuin University Supervisors: Naomichi Hatano and Kenn

More information

Measuring the shape of degree distributions

Measuring the shape of degree distributions Measuring the shape of degree distributions Dr Jennifer Badham Visiting Fellow SEIT, UNSW Canberra research@criticalconnections.com.au Overview Context What does shape mean for degree distribution Why

More information

Agent based modelling of technological diffusion and network influence

Agent based modelling of technological diffusion and network influence Agent based modelling of technological diffusion and network influence May 4, 23 Martino Tran, D.Phil.(Oxon) Senior Researcher, Environmental Change Institute, University of Oxford Outline Outline. Study

More information

Structural Uncertainty in Health Economic Decision Models

Structural Uncertainty in Health Economic Decision Models Structural Uncertainty in Health Economic Decision Models Mark Strong 1, Hazel Pilgrim 1, Jeremy Oakley 2, Jim Chilcott 1 December 2009 1. School of Health and Related Research, University of Sheffield,

More information

Cost and Preference in Recommender Systems Junhua Chen LESS IS MORE

Cost and Preference in Recommender Systems Junhua Chen LESS IS MORE Cost and Preference in Recommender Systems Junhua Chen, Big Data Research Center, UESTC Email:junmshao@uestc.edu.cn http://staff.uestc.edu.cn/shaojunming Abstract In many recommender systems (RS), user

More information

arxiv: v4 [cond-mat.dis-nn] 16 May 2011

arxiv: v4 [cond-mat.dis-nn] 16 May 2011 Direct, physically-motivated derivation of the contagion condition for spreading processes on generalized random networks arxiv:1101.5591v4 [cond-mat.dis-nn] 16 May 2011 Peter Sheridan Dodds, 1,2, Kameron

More information

The Spatial Perspective

The Spatial Perspective Department of Geography University of California at Santa Barbara GEOGRAPHY 5 MIDTERM REVIEW SHEET The Spatial Perspective - Review all of chapter 1 carefully except for Box 1.B (but do review Box 1.A

More information

The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers

The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers joint work with Frederic Murphy Climate Policy and Long Term Decisions-Investment and R&D, Bocconi University, Milan,

More information

KINETICS OF SOCIAL CONTAGION. János Kertész Central European University. SNU, June

KINETICS OF SOCIAL CONTAGION. János Kertész Central European University. SNU, June KINETICS OF SOCIAL CONTAGION János Kertész Central European University SNU, June 1 2016 Theory: Zhongyuan Ruan, Gerardo Iniguez, Marton Karsai, JK: Kinetics of social contagion Phys. Rev. Lett. 115, 218702

More information

SMALL-WORLD NAVIGABILITY. Alexandru Seminar in Distributed Computing

SMALL-WORLD NAVIGABILITY. Alexandru Seminar in Distributed Computing SMALL-WORLD NAVIGABILITY Talk about a small world 2 Zurich, CH Hunedoara, RO From cliché to social networks 3 Milgram s Experiment and The Small World Hypothesis Omaha, NE Boston, MA Wichita, KS Human

More information

1. Introductory Examples

1. Introductory Examples 1. Introductory Examples We introduce the concept of the deterministic and stochastic simulation methods. Two problems are provided to explain the methods: the percolation problem, providing an example

More information

CS224W: Analysis of Networks Jure Leskovec, Stanford University

CS224W: Analysis of Networks Jure Leskovec, Stanford University CS224W: Analysis of Networks Jure Leskovec, Stanford University http://cs224w.stanford.edu 10/30/17 Jure Leskovec, Stanford CS224W: Social and Information Network Analysis, http://cs224w.stanford.edu 2

More information

Network models: random graphs

Network models: random graphs Network models: random graphs Leonid E. Zhukov School of Data Analysis and Artificial Intelligence Department of Computer Science National Research University Higher School of Economics Structural Analysis

More information

Derogation Criteria for the Requirements for Generators Network Code

Derogation Criteria for the Requirements for Generators Network Code Derogation Criteria for the Requirements for Generators Network Code Decision Paper Reference: CER/17/084 Date Published: 13/04/2017 Closing Date: 0 Executive Summary Commission Regulation (EU) 2016/631

More information

Chapter 2 Chaos theory and its relationship to complexity

Chapter 2 Chaos theory and its relationship to complexity Chapter 2 Chaos theory and its relationship to complexity David Kernick This chapter introduces chaos theory and the concept of non-linearity. It highlights the importance of reiteration and the system

More information

GOVERNMENT MAPPING WORKSHOP RECOVER Edmonton s Urban Wellness Plan Mapping Workshop December 4, 2017

GOVERNMENT MAPPING WORKSHOP RECOVER Edmonton s Urban Wellness Plan Mapping Workshop December 4, 2017 GOVERNMENT MAPPING WORKSHOP 12.4.17 RECOVER Edmonton s Urban Wellness Plan Mapping Workshop December 4, 2017 In July of 2017, City Council directed administration to develop RECOVER, Edmonton s Urban Wellness

More information

Modern Urban and Regional Economics

Modern Urban and Regional Economics Modern Urban and Regional Economics SECOND EDITION Philip McCann OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS Contents List of figures List of tables Introduction xii xiv xvii Part I Urban and Regional Economic Models and

More information

Social Networks. Chapter 9

Social Networks. Chapter 9 Chapter 9 Social Networks Distributed computing is applicable in various contexts. This lecture exemplarily studies one of these contexts, social networks, an area of study whose origins date back a century.

More information

El Botellón: Modeling the Movement of Crowds in a City

El Botellón: Modeling the Movement of Crowds in a City El Botellón: Modeling the Movement of Crowds in a City Jonathan E. Rowe Rocio Gomez School of Computer Science, University of Birmingham, Birmingham B15 2TT, United Kingdom A simulation of crowd movement

More information

Measurements and Data Analysis

Measurements and Data Analysis Measurements and Data Analysis 1 Introduction The central point in experimental physical science is the measurement of physical quantities. Experience has shown that all measurements, no matter how carefully

More information

Spatial Epidemic Modelling in Social Networks

Spatial Epidemic Modelling in Social Networks Spatial Epidemic Modelling in Social Networks Joana Margarida Simoes Centre for Advanced Spatial Analysis, University College of London, UK Abstract. The spread of infectious diseases is highly influenced

More information

A Modified Earthquake Model Based on Generalized Barabási Albert Scale-Free

A Modified Earthquake Model Based on Generalized Barabási Albert Scale-Free Commun. Theor. Phys. (Beijing, China) 46 (2006) pp. 1011 1016 c International Academic Publishers Vol. 46, No. 6, December 15, 2006 A Modified Earthquake Model Based on Generalized Barabási Albert Scale-Free

More information

r10_summary.qxd :19 Page 245 ABOUT THE BOOK

r10_summary.qxd :19 Page 245 ABOUT THE BOOK r10_summary.qxd 2011-08-28 21:19 Page 245 ABOUT THE BOOK The main strategic aim of most concepts of rural development is to improve the quality of life of rural residents through providing appropriate

More information

networks in molecular biology Wolfgang Huber

networks in molecular biology Wolfgang Huber networks in molecular biology Wolfgang Huber networks in molecular biology Regulatory networks: components = gene products interactions = regulation of transcription, translation, phosphorylation... Metabolic

More information

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.other] 4 Aug 2004

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 [cond-mat.other] 4 Aug 2004 Conservation laws for the voter model in complex networks arxiv:cond-mat/0408101v1 [cond-mat.other] 4 Aug 2004 Krzysztof Suchecki, 1,2 Víctor M. Eguíluz, 1 and Maxi San Miguel 1 1 Instituto Mediterráneo

More information

Multiplexity in networks

Multiplexity in networks Multiplexity in networs Kwang-Il Goh Department of Physics Korea University Thans to: Kyu-Min Lee, Byungjoon Min, Won-u Cho, Jung Yeol Kim, Jeehye Choi, In-moo Kim, Charlie Brummitt (UC Davis), NRF Korea

More information

KINETICS OF COMPLEX SOCIAL CONTAGION. János Kertész Central European University. Pohang, May 27, 2016

KINETICS OF COMPLEX SOCIAL CONTAGION. János Kertész Central European University. Pohang, May 27, 2016 KINETICS OF COMPLEX SOCIAL CONTAGION János Kertész Central European University Pohang, May 27, 2016 Theory: Zhongyuan Ruan, Gerardo Iniguez, Marton Karsai, JK: Kinetics of social contagion Phys. Rev. Lett.

More information

arxiv:cond-mat/ v2 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 7 Jan 2000

arxiv:cond-mat/ v2 [cond-mat.stat-mech] 7 Jan 2000 Epidemics and percolation in small-world networks Cristopher Moore 1,2 and M. E. J. Newman 1 1 Santa Fe Institute, 1399 Hyde Park Road, Santa Fe, New Mexico 87501 2 Departments of Computer Science and

More information

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206)

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206) Theory Field Exam Summer 2011 Instructions You must complete two of the four areas (the areas being (I) contract theory, (II) game theory A, (III) game theory B, and (IV) psychology & economics). Be sure

More information

Modelling self-organizing networks

Modelling self-organizing networks Paweł Department of Mathematics, Ryerson University, Toronto, ON Cargese Fall School on Random Graphs (September 2015) Outline 1 Introduction 2 Spatial Preferred Attachment (SPA) Model 3 Future work Multidisciplinary

More information

models: A markov chain approach

models: A markov chain approach School of Economics and Management TECHNICAL UNIVERSITY OF LISBON Department of Economics Carlos Pestana Barros & Nicolas Peypoch Sven Banish, Ricardo Lima & Tanya Araújo Aggregation A Comparative Analysis

More information

Distributed Optimization. Song Chong EE, KAIST

Distributed Optimization. Song Chong EE, KAIST Distributed Optimization Song Chong EE, KAIST songchong@kaist.edu Dynamic Programming for Path Planning A path-planning problem consists of a weighted directed graph with a set of n nodes N, directed links

More information

Cascading Failures in Power Grids - Analysis and Algorithms

Cascading Failures in Power Grids - Analysis and Algorithms Cascading Failures in Power Grids - Analysis and Algorithms Saleh Soltan 1, Dorian Mazaruic 2, Gil Zussman 1 1 Electrical Engineering, Columbia University 2 INRIA Sophia Antipolis Cascading Failures in

More information

CHOOSING THE RIGHT SAMPLING TECHNIQUE FOR YOUR RESEARCH. Awanis Ku Ishak, PhD SBM

CHOOSING THE RIGHT SAMPLING TECHNIQUE FOR YOUR RESEARCH. Awanis Ku Ishak, PhD SBM CHOOSING THE RIGHT SAMPLING TECHNIQUE FOR YOUR RESEARCH Awanis Ku Ishak, PhD SBM Sampling The process of selecting a number of individuals for a study in such a way that the individuals represent the larger

More information

Bayesian Social Learning with Random Decision Making in Sequential Systems

Bayesian Social Learning with Random Decision Making in Sequential Systems Bayesian Social Learning with Random Decision Making in Sequential Systems Yunlong Wang supervised by Petar M. Djurić Department of Electrical and Computer Engineering Stony Brook University Stony Brook,

More information

The role of predictive uncertainty in the operational management of reservoirs

The role of predictive uncertainty in the operational management of reservoirs 118 Evolving Water Resources Systems: Understanding, Predicting and Managing Water Society Interactions Proceedings of ICWRS014, Bologna, Italy, June 014 (IAHS Publ. 364, 014). The role of predictive uncertainty

More information