Search Frictions and Wage Dispersion

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Search Frictions and Wage Dispersion"

Transcription

1 Search Frictions and Wage Dispersion Marcus Hagedorn University of Zurich Iourii Manovskii University of Pennsylvania VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE October 23, 2010 Abstract We propose a way to measure the contribution of search frictions to the level of wage dispersion observed in the data. Using the data from the 1979 cohort of the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth we find that the variance of match qualities between workers and employers accounts for about 6% of the variance of log wages. Our method relies on a minimal set of assumptions, the main among them is that match quality is constant over the duration of a job. We show that this assumption can be verified empirically and is supported by the data. We would like to thank Andreas Hornstein and conference participants at the 2010 NBER Summer Institute, Macro and Micro Labor Models conference at the Laboratory for Aggregate Economics and Finance at the University of California Santa Barbara, Labor Market Dynamics and Growth conference at the University of Aarhus, and 2010 Cologne Workshop on Macroeconomics for their comments. Support from the National Science Foundation Grant No. SES and the Research Priority Program on Finance and Financial Markets of the University of Zurich is gratefully acknowledged. Institute for Empirical Research (IEW), University of Zurich, Mühlebachstrasse 86, CH-8008 Zürich, Switzerland. hagedorn@iew.uzh.ch. Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania, 160 McNeil Building, 3718 Locust Walk, Philadelphia, PA, USA. manovski@econ.upenn.edu.

2 1 Introduction A robust finding in countless empirical studies is that over a half of the observed wage variation cannot be accounted for by the observable worker characteristics. Yet, understanding the reasons for why observationally similar workers are paid differently is crucial for understanding the functioning of the labor market. One possibility is that workers who look the same in the data available to an econometrician are actually different in their productivities and these productivity differences are reflected in wages. Moreover, workers productivity may evolve over the life-cycle and while the usual worker characteristics used in empirical work, such as age, gender, education, etc. may proxy relatively well for workers average productivities, they may not be flexible enough to describe the evolution of these productivities. Alternatively, it is possible that observationally equivalent workers are the same in terms of their productivity and the differences in their wages reflect luck in locating productive job matches (Mortensen (2005) articulates this view). One line of research (e.g., Butters (1977), Burdett and Judd (1983), Mortensen (1991), Burdett and Mortensen (1998)) has determined conditions under which dispersion in wage policy is the only equilibrium outcome in the labor market with search frictions even if all employers and employees are identical in their productivity. In another class of models with labor market search (e.g., Dimond (1982), Mortensen (1982), Pissarides (1985, 2000), Mortensen and Pissarides (1994)) workers and firms bargain over match surplus implied by search frictions and this implies wage dispersion given productivity dispersion across worker-employer matches. The objective of this paper is to assess empirically the contribution of search frictions to wage dispersion. Our approach is as follows. Suppose individual wages depend on general human capital accumulated with labor market experience and transferable across employers, employer-specific human capital accumulated with firm tenure, the quality of the match between the worker and the firm, and idiosyncratic worker productivity that contains a fixed and transitory components. Suppose we could obtain unbiased estimates of the returns to tenure, experience, and individual fixed effects (we discuss our approach below) and subtract their contribution from wages. The resulting residual wages contain only the match 2

3 quality term and the individual productivity realization (and, perhaps, the measurement error). We are interested in the variance of match qualities. It can be computed as the difference between the variance of residual wages and the variance of the individual productivity process. Assuming that match quality is constant on a job, the latter can be directly computed as the weighted average variance of wages within jobs (constant match quality does not affect the within-job wage variance). Applying this decomposition to the data from the U.S. National Longitudinal Survey of Youth we obtain that the variance of match qualities equals 0.016, or about 6% of the variance of log wages in the data. This approach to assessing the role of search frictions is quite simple and yet quite general because it does not require any assumptions on, e.g., the distributions of wages or idiosyncratic productivity process, and it does not require us to take a stand on the value of parameters that are difficult to measure, such as the flow utility of unemployed workers. The only assumptions that this approach requires is that match quality is constant on a job and that wages reflect this match quality. To assess whether the assumption that match quality is constant on the job is appropriate we consider the wage growth of workers who remain in the same match between two consecutive periods. If match quality is stochastic, workers who received negative innovations to their match quality are more likely to leave for other jobs. Thus, the sample of wage stayers is selected in favor of workers with positive innovations to their match quality. The strength of this selection effect depends on ease of locating alternative employers for workers with negative innovations. The probability of receiving an outside offer depends positively on the observed labor market tightness in most search models. Thus, if match quality is stochastic, wage growth of job stayers should depend positively on labor market tightness. We show that this is not the case in the data, implying that the model with constant match quality is a better description of the labor market (constant match quality does not affect the wage growth of job stayers and the selection effect is absent). This argument extends to models where the match quality is constant but is learned over time. Due to the same selection mechanism such models imply that wage growth of job stayers should be increasing in the probability of receiving an offer and we do not observe this in the data. 3

4 Second, the models featuring commitment power of workers or firms imply that various forms of contracts my de-couple wages from the match quality. For example, the models of Postel-Vinay and Robin (2002) and Cahuc, Postel-Vinay, and Robin (2006) feature onthe-job search, just as our benchmark model, but also feature commitment of firms to matching outside offers received by the worker. In such models wages increase on the job when a worker receives an outside offer. Thus, the wage growth on the job is once again a function of the probability of receiving an outside offer. As we already discussed above, the data suggest that the wage growth is independent of the probability to receive an offer implying the lack of evidence for the importance of offer matching contracts in determining wages. Finally, it is possible that the match quality is stochastic but firms smooth the fluctuations in the remuneration of wages. We show that such insurance contracts leave our conclusions unaffected. In particular, in this paper we are only interested in decomposing the observed volatility of wages and not in measuring the amount of inefficiency that might be due to search frictions. Thus, the mechanism that translates differences in productivity into differences in wages (e.g., spot wages or insurance contracts) is not relevant for our analysis. In an important related recent contribution, Hornstein, Krusell, and Violante (2009) study the ability of search models to generate frictional wage dispersion. They argue that the structure of the search model implies tight restrictions between the amount of wage dispersion the model can generate and the magnitude of labor market flows that can be directly measured. Their argument is strongest in models where workers cannot search on the job. In particular, they show that substantial wage dispersion due to search frictions is inconsistent with the observations that unemployment durations are very short in U.S. data. Given the plausible range of values for the disutility of being unemployed, short unemployment durations directly imply that the option value of waiting for a good offer is small. Their approach is less powerful if workers are able to search on the job. And indeed, jobto-job flows are large in the data suggesting that this is an important restriction. 1 If on-the- 1 Based on the monthly Current Population Survey (CPS) data, Fallick and Fleischman (2004), for 4

5 job search is as efficient as search while unemployed, the duration of unemployment contains little information about the distribution of potential match qualities because unemployed workers take the first draw that dominates the value of non-market activity and continue searching while employed. More generally, the more efficient is on-the-job search, the less informative is the duration of unemployment for the distribution of matches. There is some information contained in the frequency of observed job-to job moves but how this translates into the probability to receive offer is strongly model-dependent. As a result, Hornstein, Krusell, and Violante (2009) show that the observed job-to job moves imply fairly wide bounds on the extent of wage dispersion that may be attributed to search frictions. For example, wage dispersion is relatively small in the model of Burdett and Mortensen (1998) on the one hand and large in the models of Postel-Vinay and Robin (2002) and Cahuc, Postel-Vinay, and Robin (2006) on the other hand. We view our approach as complementary to that of Hornstein, Krusell, and Violante (2009). While they study how much dispersion a search model is capable of generating, our objective is to assess how much dispersion is due to the variance of match qualities in the data. In this sense, our analysis provides a simple way to empirically discipline search models. If the model satisfies the assumptions underlying our analysis, we provide a target of how much dispersion in match qualities it should be generating. If the model does not satisfy our assumptions it nevertheless has to be consistent with the finding that the wage growth of job stayers is independent of the job finding rate. The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we present a theoretical framework underlying our analysis. In Section 3 we develop our method to measure the dispersion of match qualities. We proceed in two steps. First, we construct residual wages by subtracting the contribution of tenure, experience, and individual fixed effects from wages. Various approaches can be employed to estimate these components of wages depending on the assumptions one is willing to make on the nature of the search process. The method we use relies on extending the approach in Abraham and Farber (1987), Altonji and Shakotko example, estimate that in the U.S. about 2.7% of employed workers move job-to-job every month. Moscarini and Thomsson (2007) show that a different treatment of missing observations in monthly CPS data raises this estimate to 3.2%. 5

6 (1987), Topel (1991), and Altonji and Williams (2005). 2 In the second step we decompose the residual wage variance into the variance of match qualities and the variance of individual productivities. In Section 4 we discuss several possible generalizations of the benchmark model, including allowing for the stochastic match quality and various forms of contracts determining wages. In Section 5 we describe the data and present the results of the empirical evaluation of the contribution of match qualities, tenure and experience to wages. In Section 6 we calibrate our theoretical model and use it to evaluate the performance of our method in measuring job match qualities and the returns to tenure and seniority. Finally, we conduct counterfactual experiments to study the effects on wage distribution from hypothetically eliminating search frictions. Section 7 concludes. 2 Model with On-the-job search A continuum of risk-neutral workers of measure one participates in the labor market. 3 At a moment in time, each worker can be either employed or unemployed. An unemployed worker faces a probability λ θ of getting a job offer. This probability depends exogenously on a business cycle indicator θ and is increasing in θ. For example, a high level of θ (say, a high level of market tightness or low level of unemployment rate) means that it is easy to find a job, since λ θ is high as well. Employed workers also face a probability q θ of getting a job offer, which also depends monotonically on θ. A worker who accepts the period t offer, starts working immediately for the new employer in period t + 1. The unemployment rate in period t is denoted u t. The business cycle indicator θ t is a stochastic process which is drawn from a stationary distribution. A match between worker i and a job/employer/firm j at date t is characterized by an idiosyncratic productivity level φ ijt. Each time a worker meets a new employer, a new value of φ is drawn, according to a distribution function F with support [φ, φ], density f and 2 In the earlier versions of the paper we followed the more complicated approach in Hagedorn and Manovskii (2010) and reached the same conclusions. 3 Workers thus maximize expected discounted income if the market interest rate r and the discount factor β satisfy 1 1+r = β. If instead the worker is risk averse and markets are complete, then maximizing expected utility and maximizing expected income are also equivalent (Rogerson, Shimer, and Wright (2005)). 6

7 expected value µ φ. A worker switches if and only if the present value of wages (and thus lifetime utility) increases. The level of φ and thus productivity remain unchanged as long as the worker does not switch, φ ijt 1 = φ ijt. 4 The wage in the model is consistent with the standard specifications in empirical literature. 5 The accumulation of firm-specific and general human capital increase wages. Wages increase by e β 1X ijt if total labor market experience equals X ijt reflecting the accumulation of general human capital. Wages also increase by e β 2T ijt if tenure equals T ijt reflecting the accumulation of firm-specific human capital. 6 The wage also has a fixed individual specific component, µ i, a transitory individual spesific component, ɛ it, and a fixed job match specific component, φ ij, and thus equals e β 1X ijt +β 2 T ijt µ i φ ijt ɛ it, (1) so that the log wage equals log(w ijt ) = β 1 X ijt + β 2 T ijt + log(µ i ) + log(φ ijt ) + log(ɛ it ). (2) We abstract from time effects and from nonlinear terms in experience and tenure. Later we will allow for nonlinearity and show that is inconsequential for our results. To model time effects we could add the unemployment rate or labor market tightness in period t to the model. Again this would not change our results since we allow for time dummies in the empirical implementation. An employed worker faces an exogenous probability s of getting separated and becoming unemployed. For every worker who left unemployment in period 0 and has worked continuously since then we first define an employment cycle. Assume that the worker switched employers in periods 1 + S 1, 1 + S 2, S k, so that this worker stayed with his first 4 We show later that assumption describes the data best. 5 E.g., Altonji and Shakotko (1987), Abraham and Farber (1987), and Topel (1991). 6 To be precise, X years of experience increase general human capital by β 1 x and T years of tenure increase firm specific human capital by β 2 T. Note that we assume that all benefits from human capital accrue to workers. For general human capital this seems reasonable as these skills are transferable across employers. For specific human capital we could instead assume that only a fraction χ accrues to workers and that the β 2 = χ β 2, where β 2 is the true return to specific human capital. We could do the same for general human capital. All our results would remain unchanged. 7

8 employer between periods 0 and S 1, with the second employer between period 1 + S 1 and S 2 and with employer i between period 1 + S j 1 and S j. 3 Measuring Wage Dispersion Let T ijt be completed tenure of individual i in job j at time t. We approximate φ k ijt as a function of T ij and error E(δ ij ) = 0: log(φ ijt ) = α 0 (T ) + α 1 T ij + α 2 T 2 ij + δ ijt, where T is tenure in the current job. We allow the mean of φ do change with tenure even after controlling for completed tenure, as we allow α 0 do depend on T. The relationship between φ and completed tenure is just a statistical one. If φ was observable these coefficients could be obtained by an OLS regression in the data. For our theoretical arguments we can nevertheless use this regression. We proceed now in several steps. We first show how using completed tenure T ijt in an empirical wage regression leads to unbiased estimates of tenure and experience. We then show that completed tenure T ijt is positively correlated with match quality. Finally we use the residual wage variance for job stayers and switchers to compute the volatility of φ. 3.1 Step 1: Unbiased Estimates of the Returns to Tenure and Experience We first regress wages at the beginning of the employment cycle on experience at the beginning of the employment cycle (including individual fixed effects). This gives us the true coefficient on experience, β 1. The reason is that experience at the beginning of the employment cycle and match quality are uncorrelated since workers just leave unemployment. 7 In a second step we first subtract the estimated contribution of experience from wages, ŵ = w β 1 X, and regress this residual on tenure, completed tenure (and an individual fixed effect). As shown for example in Abraham and Farber (1987), this results in an unbiased estimate of 7 We allow for such correlation and show how to control for the resulting bias in Appendix I.1. 8

9 β 2. This is easy to see. Conducting OLS is equivalent to first regress wages and tenure on completed tenure and then as a second step regress the residuals from this regression on each other, that is the wage residual on the tenure residual. The tenure residual is equal to the deviation of tenure from its mean in the same job spell and is thus uncorrelated with match quality. As a result the coefficient is unbiased. We thus have estimated unbiased coefficients for β 1 and β Step 2: Completed Tenure and Match Quality Recall that we approximate φ ijt as a function of T ij and error E(δ ij ) = 0: log(φ ijt ) = α 0 (T ) + α 1 T ij + α 2 T 2 ij + δ ijt. We want to show that the covariance (and thus the correlation) of φ and T is positive. For now we do this for the case of no returns on tenure, β 2 = 0. It equals E[(φ E(φ))(T E(T )] = E φ [(φ E(φ))E(T E(T ) φ)]. Note that E(T ) is the unconditional expected duration of a job and that E(T φ) is the expected duration of a job conditional on type φ. Let the probability to receive an offer per period be q, then the probability not to leave until period T for type φ equals T N=0 ( ) T q N (1 q) T N F (φ) N = (1 q + qf (φ)) T N and thus the probability to leave in period T (and not before) equals (1 q + qf (φ)) T 1 q(1 F (φ)). The expected duration conditional on φ thus equals N(1 q + qf (φ)) N 1 q(1 F (φ)) = N=1 which is increasing in φ. The covariance thus equals 1 q(1 F (φ)), E[(φ E(φ))ϕ(φ)], 9

10 1 where ϕ(φ) = E(T ), which is increasing in φ. Define Ψ( ˆφ) = ˆφ ϕ(φ)dφ. It then q(1 F (φ)) holds that the covariance equals (partial integration) φ since Ψ(φ) = Ψ(φ) = 0 and thus Ψ(ˆφ) 0. φ Ψ(φ)dφ > 0. φ 3.3 Step 3: Volatility of φ In this section we measure the volatility of match quality φ. The basic idea is to compare the volatility of wages of job stayers and switchers. As match quality is constant on the job and changes only if the worker changes jobs (because of search frictions), the difference in these volatilities is attributed to changes in φ and thus to search frictions. We first define the wage residual, subtracting the returns to tenure and experience as well as the fixed effect from wages: log w it = log w it β 1 X it β 2 T it log(µ i ) = log(φ k ijt) + log(ɛ it ). Behavior of Wages within Jobs We start by looking at what happens within jobs. Let v ij be the variance of wages in job j, n ij - the number of observations in job j, and N = ij (nij 1) - the total number of observations minus the number of jobs. A consistent estimate of the within-job wage variance (Raab (1981)) is: V ar(log ɛ it ) = ij n ij N vij. The variance of φ Once we know the variance of ɛ, it is easy to compute the variance of φ by subtracting the variance of ɛ from the variance of the wage residual w it : V ar(log(φ)) = V ar(log( w)) V ar(log(log ɛ)). 10

11 4 Extensions In this section we discuss several possible generalizations of the benchmark model. In each case we demonstrate whether and how our analysis needs to be modified. We first allow for the possibility that match quality is not constant during a job as we assumed so far but that it instead follows a stochastic process even during a job. We show that the data do not support this generalization and that the data are best described by a constant match quality. Second, we consider what type of contracts are (not) supported by the data and whether our analysis needs to be modified. Again we find that existing models are either not supported by the data or/and would not change our results. Finally we allow for occupational specific human capital (Kambourov and Manovskii (2009)). 4.1 Stochastic Match Quality Suppose that (demeaned) match quality evolves as log(φ ijt ) = ˆφ + ρ(log(φ ijt 1 ) ˆφ) + e ijt, (3) where ρ [0, 1] and e ijt is the period t innovation. A constant φ is a special case for ρ = 1 and a zero volatility of e. The match quality is approximated through an OLS regression as log(φ ijt ) = α 0 (T ) + α1t j ij + α2t j 2 ij + η ijt, Since we now allow the match quality to evolve over time, the α 0 depends on tenure T. The mean of match quality with tenure T equals E T (α 1 T ij + α 2 T 2 ij) + α 0 (T ), since η ijt has mean zero. We allow for a T -dependent variable α 0 since the mean of match quality can evolve over the job. Let us take a closer look at how match quality evolves over time during the job. The mean can change because the process is autoregressive if ρ < 1 and because workers with high realizations of e tend to stay and workers with low realizations of e tend to leave the 11

12 current job. In particular the difference in match quality, which equals: log(φ ijt ) log(φ ijt 1 ) = α 0 (T ) + α 1 T ijt + α 2 T 2 ijt + η ijt (α 0 (T 1) + α 1 T ijt 1 + α 2 T 2 ijt 1 + η ijt 1 ) = (ρ 1)(α 0 (T 1) + α 1 T ijt 1 + α 2 T 2 ijt 1 ˆφ + η ijt 1 ) + e ijt, does not necessarily has mean zero. The first equality sign just uses the approximation of φ in (4). The second equality replaces log(φ ijt ) first using (3) and then applies the approximation in (4) to log(φ ijt 1 ) only. To understand this first difference in match quality, it is key to understand how e evolves, since e is the only unobservable variable in this equation which is exposed to selection. The expected value of e is subject to selection if the worker receives an offer. If the worker does not receive an offer e is a mean zero variable, say ẽ 2. If however the worker receives an offer and this happens with probability q t, then the decision to stay or switch depends on T and α 0 (T ). Let p(e T, α 0 (T )) be the probability of type e of rejecting an offer conditional on T and α 0 (T ). Conditional on receiving an offer and staying (still in the same job in T as in T 1), the innovation is named ẽ 1, and has mean E t (ẽ 1 ) = e e eh(e) p(e T, α 0(T )) m(t, α 0 (T )) de, where m(t, α 0 (T )) is the probability to reject an offer and h(e) is the density of the innovation ẽ 2. The expected value of e thus equals E t (e t ) = q t E t (ẽ 1 ) + (1 q t )E t (ẽ 2 ). Since E t (ẽ 1 ) > E t (ẽ 2 ) 8, E j (e j ) is increasing in q t. that If we implement an OLS regression of e on q, completed tenure and a dummy, we get e ijt = γ 1 q t + γ 2 (α 1 T ijt + α 2 T 2 ijt) + γ 3 α 0 (T ) + ν ijt, 8 E t (ẽ 1 ) E t (ẽ 2 ) = e pj(e T,α0(T )) ef(e)( e )de. Let Λ(ê, T, α µ(t,α 0(T 1)) 0(T 1)) = ê e f(e)( pj(e T,α0(T 1)) µ(t,α 0(T 1)) 1)de, pj(e T,α0(T 1)) then Λ(e, T, α 0 (T 1)) = Λ(e, T, α 0 (T 1)) = 0. Since 1) is increasing in e, it is negative if µ(t,α 0(T 1)) e < e and positive if e e, for some e. As a result Λ(ê, T, α 0 (T 1)) < 0 so that (FOSD) E j (ẽ 1 ) > E j (ẽ 2 ). 12

13 where γ 1 > 0. The sign of the coefficients γ 2 and γ 3 is somewhat unclear but it is irrelevant anyway. Using this regression equation to replace e in the equation for the difference in φ, log(φ ijt ) log(φ ijt 1 ) = γ 1 q t + (γ 2 + (ρ 1))(α 1 T ijt 1 + α 2 T 2 ijt 1) + (ρ 1 + γ 3 )α 0 (T 1) + (ρ 1)(η ijt 1 ˆφ) + ν ijt, where (ρ 1)(η ijt 1 ˆφ) + ν ijt is just nuisance. The difference in wages equals log(w ijt ) log(w ijt 1 ) = α T ijt + α E ijt + log(φ ijt ) log(φ ijt 1 ), where α T ijt is the tenure dummy for the increase from t 1 to t and α E ijt is the experience dummy for the increase from t 1 to t. Plugging in the equation for φ ijt φ ijt 1 yields: log(w ijt ) log(w ijt 1 ) = α T ijt + α E ijt + γ 1 q t + (γ 2 + (ρ 1))(α T 1 T ijt + α T 2 T 2 ijt) + (ρ 1 + γ 3 )α 0 (T ) + (ρ 1)(η ijt 1 ˆφ) + ν ijt. We thus estimate the difference in wages on the dummies αijt T and αijt, E a quadratic in T and a quadratic in q t. Note that α 0 (T ) is not identified. Instead we estimate α T + (ρ 1 + γ 3 )α 0 (T ), that is the returns to tenure would be biased if ρ 1 or γ 3 0. Note that the coefficient in this regression on q t is the same as in the regression for e. 9 We test whether the estimated coefficients of the terms for T and q t are zero. In this estimation we have to take into account that the wages depend on the business cycle 9 This is a more general result. Suppose we regress y on X 1 and the one-dimensional variable X 2, so that y = γ 1 X 1 + γ 2 X 2. Furthermore we regress X 2 on X 1 and X 3, X 2 = λ 1 X 1 + λ 3 X 3. If we then regress y on X 1 and X 3, y = µ 1 X 1 + µ 3 X 3, then it holds that µ 1 = γ 1 + γ 2 λ 1 and µ 3 = γ 2 λ 3. Let γ = (γ 1, γ 2 ), λ = (λ 1, λ 3 ), µ = (µ 1, µ 3 ), Z 1 = (X 1 X 2 ) and Z 2 = (X 1 X 3 ). Then it holds that µ = (Z 2Z 2 ) 1 Z 2y = (Z 2Z 2 ) 1 Z 2(γ 1 X 1 + γ 2 X 2 ) = γ 2 λ + γ 1 (Z 2Z 2 ) 1 Z 2X 1 = γ 2 λ + (γ 1 0) = (γ 2 λ 1 + γ 1, γ 2 λ 3 ) 13

14 already, even in the absence of stochastic match quality. As a result we have to take into account that the difference in wages depends on the change in business cycle conditions. We therefore add the first difference in q to the regression. Note that if match quality is stochastic, the level of q has to be (positively) significant. If the coefficients on q t are zero, this implies that E t (ẽ 1 ) = E t (ẽ 2 ), that is selection is absent, what is possible only if e is identical to zero. As a result, γ 2 = 0 (and also γ 3 ). Thus the finding that the coefficients on the terms of T are zero, (ρ 1) = 0, and thus ρ = 1. In particular, the returns to tenure are unbiased since the potential bias, (ρ 1+γ 3 ) = Contracts In many models wages do not only reflect contemporaneous condition but instead contracts decouple current wages from current productivity, see for example Postel-Vinay and Robin (2002) and Cahuc, Postel-Vinay, and Robin (2006). A feature of wage formation in these models is that wages can be renegotiated upwards if a counteroffer is on the table. The probability that a worker and a firm engage in bargaining and increase the wage is increasing in the probability to receive a counteroffer. As a result the difference in wages, log(w it ) log(w it 1 ), is increasing in market tightness in these models. We thus implement the following regression: log(w ijt ) log(w ijt 1 ) = αt T + αijt E + χ 1 log(q t 1 ) + χ 2 log(q t 1 ) 2 + ν ijt, (4) where αt T is the tenure dummy for the increase from tenure level T 1 to T, αe t is the experience dummy for the increase from t 1 to t and ν ijt is the residual of this regression. Again we have to take into account that the difference in wages depends on the change in business cycle conditions. We therefore add the first difference in q to the regression. Note that if such types of contracts are present, the level of q has to be (positively) significant. In Section 5.6 we will document that the coefficients χ 1 and χ 2 are jointly insignificant. This implies that wages are not renegotiated. Contracts may still be present however by stipulating a constant wage. This is not relevant for our purposes though. We are interested in the volatility of wages due to search frictions. 14

15 The wage with contracts equals log w C it = β C 1 X + β C 2 T + log(µ i ) + log(φ ij ) + log(e C it), (5) where β2 C T is the remuneration to tenure and β1 C X is the remuneration to experience (could be different from the spot wage model). There is an individual fixed effect log(u i ) (also potentially be different) and log(e C it) is the remuneration to the idiosyncratic effect. Finally log(φ ij ) is the remuneration to match quality, which due to the presence of contracts is constant on the job spell. We again have to estimate the returns to tenure and experience first. Again we proceed in two steps. We first regress wages at the beginning of the employment cycle on experience at the beginning of the employment cycle (including individual fixed effects). This gives us the true experience dummy for experience at the beginning of the job. The reason is again that experience at the beginning of the employment cycle and match quality are uncorrelated since workers just leave unemployment. In a second step we first subtract the estimated contribution of experience from wages, ŵ = w β 1 X, and regress this residual on tenure and completed tenure (and an individual fixed effect). As before in the model without contracts (but a Mincer wage regression), the returns to tenure are unbiased if we add completed tenure to the regression. The remaining procedure also remains the same. We compare the volatility of wages for switchers and stayers. Since match quality does not change during the job, the analysis for stayers is identical as only changes in e C contribute to the volatility of wages during the job once the returns to tenure and experience have been accounted for. The volatility of wages for stayers is again different from the volatility of switchers because now match quality changes, even in the presence of contracts. The procedure is the same in the presence and in the absence of contracts but theoretically the results can be different. Contracts translate an existing amount of dispersion in match quality into a different amount of wage dispersion than a model without contracts would do. From our measurement perspective however, this distinction does not matter. 15

16 Whether an existing amount of volatility of wages is generated by a model without or with contracts does not affect our conclusion. We are just interested in the wage dispersion that is due to search frictions. If contracts eliminated any wage dispersion although productivity differences due to search frictions are large, we would conclude that there is no wage dispersion due to search frictions; although the amount of inefficiency due to search frictions is large. 4.3 Occupation-Specific Human Capital Let φ P be the match quality, T P be the tenure and T P be completed tenure specific to an occupation. Overall match quality then equals φ + φ P. We use completed tenure in the occupation to approximate occupation-specific match quality: φ P = α P 0 + α P 1 T P ij + α P 2 (T P ij) 2 + δ P ijt Estimating the returns to occupation-specific human capital log(w ijt ) = β 1 X ijt + β 2 T ijt + β P 2 T P ijt + log(µ i ) + log(φ ijt ). (6) The first step where we estimate the returns to initial experience is the same. The second step has to be adapted. As before we first subtract the estimated contribution of experience from wages, ŵ = w β 1 X. We have now to take into account that one occupational spell can contain more than one job spell. Let these job spells start at 1, 1+T 1,... 1+T m and thus end at times T 1, T 2,... T m. The job spells thus last from 1..T 1, from 1 + T 1..T 2 and from 1 + T m 1..T m. We then define the following adjusted completed duration variables for job spell k: T k = T k 1 + T k T k

17 It then holds that summarizing T P T k over job spell k yields: = T k T P =1+T k 1 (T P T k ) T k T k 1 T P =1 (T P (T k T k 1 + 1) ) 2 = (T k T k 1 )(T k T k 1 + 1) 2 = 0. (T k T k 1 )(T k T k 1 + 1) 2 As a result using T P T k as an instrument yields unbiased estimates since this variable is uncorrelated with both φ and φ P since both these variables are constant on each job spell Measure the volatility of φ P The procedure is very similar to the benchmark case discussed above. All the differences arise for the switchers. - Define the wage residual: log w P it = log w it β 1 X it β 2 T it β P 2 T P it log(µ i ) = log(φ ijt ) + log(φ P ijt) + log(ɛ it ) = α 0 + α 1 T ij + α 2 T 2 ij + α P 0 + α P 1 T P ij + α P 2 (T P ij) 2 + δ P ijt + log(ɛ it ) Note that we approximate the sum log(φ ijt ) + log(φ P ijt) with T ij and T P ij (at the same time). - Wage growth for occupational switchers (from job k to job k and from occupation m to m ): 10 κ (k,k ),(m,m ) = log(ɛ i k) + log(φ k,k ) + log(φ P m,m ) 10 If m = m there is no occupational switch, if m = m + 1, then the worker switched the occupation. 17

18 - Covariance of wages for job-to-job switchers (from job k to job k and from occupation m to m ). γ (k,k ),(m,m ) = Cov(log( w (k,m )), log( w k,m )) = Cov(log(ɛ (k,m )), log(ɛ (k,m) )) + Cov(log(φ k ) + log(φ P m ), log(φ k) + log(φ P m)) It then holds that V ar(κ (k,k ),(m,m ) ) = V ar(log(ɛ k,m ) + log(φ i k) + log(φ i m)) + V ar(log(ɛ k,m ) + log(φi k ) + log(φi m )) 2γ (k,k ),(m,m ). Thus since ɛ and φ are uncorrelated: V ar(log(ɛ i k,m )) + V ar(log(φi k) + log(φ i m)) + V ar(log(ɛ i k,m)) + V ar(log(φ i k ) + log(φi m )) = V ar(κ (k,k ),(m,m ) ) + 2γ (k,k ),(m,m ). The RHS can be obtained from the data, so that the LHS is known. The volatility of ɛ is treated the same way as above as it refers to within job movements only. We thus have that V ar(log(φ k ) + log(φ P m)) + V ar(log(φ k ) + log(φ P m )) = V ar(κ (k,k ),(m,m ) ) + 2γ (k,k ),(m,m ) V ar(log(ɛ i k,m )) V ar(log(ɛi k,m)). = V ar(κ (k,k ),(m,m ) ) V ar(g i t) + 2(γ (k,k ),(m,m ) c). Since T and T P on the one hand and δ P on the other hand are uncorrelated, V ar(log(φ k ) + log(φ P m)) + V ar(log(φ k ) + log(φ P m )) = V ar(α 1 T k + α 2 T 2 k + α1 P T P m + α2 P (T P m) 2 ) + V ar(α 1 T k + α 2 T 2 k + αp 1 T P m + αp 2 (T P m )2 ) + V ar(log(δ k,m )) + V ar(log(δ k,m )). 18

19 That is we know about the variance of δ that V ar(log(δ k,m )) + V ar(log(δ k,m ) = V ar(κ (k,k ),(m,m ) ) V ar(gt) i + 2(γ (k,k ),(m,m ) c) V ar(α 1 T k + α 2 T 2 k + α1 P T P m + α2 P (T P m) 2 ) V ar(α 1 T k + α 2 T 2 k + αp 1 T P m + αp 2 (T P m )2 ) 19

20 5 Empirical Results Our empirical analysis is based on the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth described in detail below. NLSY is convenient because it contains detailed work-history data on its respondents in which we can track employment cycles. 5.1 National Longitudinal Survey of Youth Data The NLSY79 is a nationally representative sample of young men and women who were 14 to 22 years of age when first surveyed in We use the data up to NLSY is convenient because it allows to measure all the variables we are interested in. In particular, it contains detailed work-history data on its respondents in which we can track employment cycles. Each year through 1994 and every second year afterward, respondents were asked questions about all the jobs they held since their previous interview, including starting and stopping dates, the wage paid, and the reason for leaving each job. The NLSY consists of three subsamples: A cross-sectional sample of 6,111 youths designed to be representative of noninstitutionalized civilian youths living in the United States in 1979 and born between January 1, 1957, and December 31, 1964; a supplemental sample designed to oversample civilian Hispanic, black, and economically disadvantaged nonblack/non-hispanic youths; and a military sample designed to represent the youths enlisted in the active military forces as of September 30, Since many members of supplemental and military samples were dropped from the NLSY over time due to funding constraints, we restrict our sample to members of the representative cross-sectional sample throughout. We construct a complete work history for each individual by utilizing information on starting and stopping dates of all jobs the individual reports working at and linking jobs across interviews. In each week the individual is in the sample we identify the main job as the job with the highest hours and concentrate our analysis on it. Hours information is missing in some interviews in which case we impute it if hours are reported for the same job at other interviews. We ignore jobs that in which individual works for less than 15 hours per week or that last for less than 4 weeks We have also experimented with the following more complicated algorithm with no impact on our 20

21 We partition all jobs into employment cycles following the procedure in Barlevy (2008). We identify the end of an employment cycle with an involuntary termination of a job. In particular, we consider whether the worker reported being laid off from his job (as opposed to quitting). We use the workers stated reason for leaving his job as long as he starts his next job within 8 weeks of when his previous job ended, but treat him as an involuntary job changer regardless of his stated reason if he does not start his next job until more than 8 weeks later. 12 If the worker offers no reason for leaving his job, we classify his job change as voluntary if he starts his next job within 8 weeks and involuntary if he starts it after 8 weeks. We ignore employment cycles that began before the NLSY respondents were first interviewed in At each interview the information is recorded for each job held since the last interview on average hours, wages, industry, occupation, etc. Thus, we do not have information on, e.g., wage changes in a given job during the time between the two interviews. This leads us to define the unit of analysis, or an observation, as an intersection of jobs and interviews. A new observation starts when a worker either starts a new job or is interviewed by the NLSY and ends when the job ends or at the next interview, whichever event happens first. Thus, if an entire job falls in between of two consecutive interviews, it constitutes an observation. If an interview falls during a job, we will have two observations for that job: the one between the previous interview and the current one, and the one between the current interview and the next one (during which the information on the second observation would be collected). conclusions. (1) Hours between all the jobs held in a given week are compared and the job with the highest hours is assigned as the main job for that week. (2) If a worker has the main job A, takes up a concurrent job B for a short period of time, then leaves job B and continues with the original main job A, we ignore job B and consider job A to be the main one throughout (regardless of how many hours the person works in job B). (3) If a worker has the main job A, takes up a concurrent job B, then leaves job A and continues with job B, we assign job B to be the primary one during the period the two jobs overlap (regardless of how many hours the person works in job B). 12 As Barlevy (2008) notes, most workers who report a layoff do spend at least one week without a job, and most workers who move directly into their next job report quitting their job rather than being laid off. However, nearly half of all workers who report quitting do not start their next job for weeks or even months. Some of these delays may be planned. Yet in many of these instances the worker probably resumed searching from scratch after quitting, e.g. because he quit to avoid being laid off or he was not willing to admit he was laid off. 21

22 Consecutive observations on the same job broken up by the interviews will identify the wage changes for job-stayers. Following Barlevy (2008), we removed observations with an reported hourly wage less than or equal to $0.10 or greater than or equal to $1,000. Many of these outliers appear to be coding errors, since they are out of line with what the same workers report at other dates, including on the same job. We also eliminated employment cycles where wages change by more than a factor of two between consecutive observations. To each observation we assign a unique value of worker s job tenure, labor market experience, race, marital status, education, smsa status, and region of residence, and whether the job is unionized. Since the underlying data is weekly, the unique value for each of these variables in each observation is the mode of the underlying variable (the mean for tenure and experience) across all weeks corresponding to that observation. The educational attainment variable is forced to be non-decreasing over time. We merge the individual data from the NLSY with the aggregate data on unemployment and vacancies. Aggregate unemployment rate, u, is constructed by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) from the Current Population Survey (CPS). The help-wanted advertising index, v, is constructed by the Conference Board. Both u and v are quarterly averages of monthly series. The ratio of v to u is the measure of the labor market tightness. We use the underlying weekly data for each observation (job-interview intersection) to construct aggregate statistics corresponding to that observation. The current unemployment rate for a given observation is the average unemployment rate over all the weeks corresponding to that observation. Similarly, the current labor market tightness for a given observation is the average labor market tightness over all the weeks corresponding to that observation. All empirical experiments that we conduct are based on the individual data weighted using custom weights provided by the NLSY which adjust both for the complex survey design and for using data from multiple surveys over our sample period. In practice, we found that using weighted or unweighted data has no impact on our substantive findings. 5.2 Results The varaince of log wages in our sample is

23 Table 1: Estimating Returns to Experience. NLSY Data. Coefficient Estimates Experience Experience 2 Experience 3 Experience e e e-13 ( ) (1.20e-06) (1.66e-09) (7.15e-13) Returns to Experience 2 Years 5 Years 10 Years 15 Years Note - Standard errors are in parentheses. 5.3 Wage Regression We obtain residual wages following the two-step procedure described above. We first estimate returns to experience by regressing wages at the beginning of the employment cycle on a quartic in experience at the beginning of the employment cycle. The regression includes individual fixed effects. We also control for education, industry, region, union, and marital status dummies. The estimated coefficients on experience terms and the implied returns to experiences are reported in Table 1. In a second step we first subtract the estimated contribution of experience from wages, and regress this residual on quartics in tenure and completed tenure. The regression includes individual fixed effects and dummies for education, industry, region, union, and marital status. The estimated coefficients on tenure and completed tenure and the implied returns to tenure are reported in Table 2. The residual wage variance not accounted for by the observables in this regression is

24 Table 2: Estimating Returns to Tenure. NLSY Data. Coefficient Estimates Tenure Tenure 2 Tenure 3 Tenure e e e-13 ( ) (4.69e-07) (7.83e-10) (4.08e-13) Compl. Tenure Compl. Tenure 2 Compl. Tenure 3 Compl. Tenure e e e-12 ( ) (8.31e-07) (1.33e-09) (6.52e-13) Returns to Tenure 2 Years 5 Years 10 Years 15 Years Note - Standard errors are in parentheses. 5.4 Volatility of φ To compute the volatility of match qualities we first sustract estimated returns to experience and tenure, and the estimated individaul fixed effects from raw wages: log w it = log w it β 1 X it β 2 T it log(µ i ). Using that V ar(log(φ)) = V ar(log( w)) V ar(log(log ɛ)) we obtain that V ar(log(φ)) = Comparing this to the total variance of log wages in our sample, we obtain that that the fraction of wage dispersion accounted for by search frictions is 5.5 Stochastic Match Quality = As implied by the theoretical analysis above one can discriminate between models with stochastic and constant match quality by estimating a regression of the difference in wages 24

25 Table 3: Stochastic Match Quality? NLSY Data. Coefficient Estimates T T 2 T 3 T e e e e-13 ( ) (9.61e-07) (1.32e-09) (5.83e-13) q t qt 2 qt 3 qt ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) Note - Standard errors are in parentheses. on tenure and experience dummies α T ijt and α E ijt, a quartic in complited tenure T and in the probability to receive an offer q t which we measure through the observable labor market tigtness. The estimated coefficients on T and q t are reported in Table 3 and are all individually and jointly insignificant. The fact that the coefficients on q t are statistically equal to zero, implies that E t ( ɛ 1 ) = E t ( ɛ 2 ), that is selection is absent, what is possible only if the variance of innovations in the match quality is equal to zero. As a result, γ 2 = 0 and γ 3 = 0. Thus the finding that the coefficients on the terms of T are zero implies that the persistence of the match quality is equal to one. Thus, the model with a constant match quality is more consistent with the data. Note as well, that since we found ρ = 1 and γ 3 = 0 the estimated returns to tenure are unbiased. 5.6 Contracts To asses whether the data is better described by a model in which employers committ to matching outside offers, as in, e.g., Postel-Vinay and Robin (2002) and Cahuc, Postel-Vinay, and Robin (2006), we check whether whether wage growth is increasing in the labor market tightness (the probability to receive an offer and a counteroffer). To do so we regress wage 25

26 Table 4: Offer Matching. NLSY Data. Coefficient Estimates q t qt 2 qt 3 qt ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) Note - Standard errors are in parentheses. growth on on tenure and experience dummies αijt T and αijt, E and a quartic in the probability to receive an offer q t which we measure through the observable labor market tigtness. The estimated coefficients on q t are reported in Table 4 and are all individually and jointly insignificant. 6 Model Simulations To be written 7 Conclusion - We proposed a method to measure the dispersion of match qualities in the data. - A model with constant match quality on the job appears to be a good description of the data. - A large class of models seems inconsistent with properties of the wage growth of job stayers. - Search frictions account for about 6% of wage dispersion. 26

27 References Abraham, K. G., and H. Farber (1987): Job Duration, Seniority and Earnings, American Economic Review, 77(3), Altonji, J., and R. Shakotko (1987): Do Wages Rise with Job Seniority, Review of Economic Studies, 54, Altonji, J. G., and N. Williams (2005): Do Wages Rise with Job Seniority? A Reassessment, Industrial & Labor Relations Review, 58(3), Barlevy, G. (2008): Identification of Search Models using Record Statistics, Review of Economic Studies, 75(1), Burdett, K., and K. L. Judd (1983): Equilibrium Price Dispersion, Econometrica, 51(4), Burdett, K., and D. Mortensen (1998): Wage Differentials, Employer Size, and Unemployment, International Economic Review, 39(2), Butters, G. R. (1977): Equilibrium Distributions of Sales and Advertising Prices, Review of Economic Studies, 44(3), Cahuc, P., F. Postel-Vinay, and J.-M. Robin (2006): Wage Bargaining with Onthe-Job Search: Theory and Evidence, Econometrica, 74(2), Dimond, P. A. (1982): Wage Determination and Efficiency in Search Equilibrium, Review of Economic Studies, 49(2), Dustmann, C., and C. Meghir (2005): Wages, Experience and Seniority, Review of Economic Studies, 72(1), Fallick, B., and C. A. Fleischman (2004): Employer-to Employer Flows in the U.S. Labor Market: The Complete Picture of Gross Worker Flows, Working Paper, Federal Reserve Bank Board of Governors. 27

28 Hagedorn, M., and I. Manovskii (2010): Job Selection and Wages over the Business Cycle, mimeo, University of Pennsylvania. Hornstein, A., P. Krusell, and G. L. Violante (2009): Frictional Wage Dispersion in Search Models: A Quantitative Assessment, Working Paper, New York University. Kambourov, G., and I. Manovskii (2009): Occupational Specificity of Human Capital, International Economic Review, 50(1), Mortensen, D. T. (1982): The Matching Process as a Non-Cooperative/Bargaining Game, in The Economics of Information and Uncertainty, ed. by J. McCall, pp NBER. (1991): Equilibrium Wage Distributions: A Synthesis, in Panel Data and Labor Market Studies, ed. by J. Hartog, G. Ridder, and T. Jules. Amsterdam: North Holland. Press. (2005): Wage Dispersion: Why are Similar Workers Paid Differently? The MIT Mortensen, D. T., and C. Pissarides (1994): Job Creation and Job Destruction in the Theory of Unemployment, Review of Economic Studies, 61(3), Moscarini, G., and K. Thomsson (2007): Occupational and Job Mobility in the US, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 109(4), Pissarides, C. (1985): Short-Run Equilibrium Dynamics of Unemployment, Vacancies, and Real Wages, American Economic Review, 75(4), ed. (2000): Equilibrium Unemployment Theory. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, second Postel-Vinay, F., and J.-M. Robin (2002): Wage Dispersion with Worker and Employer Heterogeneity, Econometrica, 70(6), Raab, G. M. (1981): Estimation of a Variance Function, with Application to Immunoassay, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series C (Applied Statistics), 30(1),

Frictional Wage Dispersion in Search Models: A Quantitative Assessment

Frictional Wage Dispersion in Search Models: A Quantitative Assessment Frictional Wage Dispersion in Search Models: A Quantitative Assessment Andreas Hornstein Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Per Krusell Princeton University, IIES-Stockholm and CEPR Gianluca Violante New

More information

Spot Wages over the Business Cycle?

Spot Wages over the Business Cycle? Spot Wages over the Business Cycle? Marcus Hagedorn University of Zurich Iourii Manovsii University of Pennsylvania August 27, 2009 Abstract We consider a model with on-the-job search where current wages

More information

McCall Model. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. November 22, Econ720

McCall Model. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. November 22, Econ720 McCall Model Prof. Lutz Hendricks Econ720 November 22, 2017 1 / 30 Motivation We would like to study basic labor market data: unemployment and its duration wage heterogeneity among seemingly identical

More information

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions Daniel Němec Faculty of Economics and Administrations Masaryk University Brno, Czech Republic nemecd@econ.muni.cz ESF MU (Brno)

More information

Job Selection and Wages over the Business Cycle

Job Selection and Wages over the Business Cycle Job Selection and Wages over the Business Cycle Marcus Hagedorn University of Zurich Iourii Manovsii University of Pennsylvania August 29, 2010 Abstract We consider a model with on-the-job search where

More information

Econometrics (60 points) as the multivariate regression of Y on X 1 and X 2? [6 points]

Econometrics (60 points) as the multivariate regression of Y on X 1 and X 2? [6 points] Econometrics (60 points) Question 7: Short Answers (30 points) Answer parts 1-6 with a brief explanation. 1. Suppose the model of interest is Y i = 0 + 1 X 1i + 2 X 2i + u i, where E(u X)=0 and E(u 2 X)=

More information

Job Search Models. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde. University of Pennsylvania. February 12, 2016

Job Search Models. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde. University of Pennsylvania. February 12, 2016 Job Search Models Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania February 12, 2016 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Job Search February 12, 2016 1 / 57 Motivation Introduction Trade in the labor

More information

More on Roy Model of Self-Selection

More on Roy Model of Self-Selection V. J. Hotz Rev. May 26, 2007 More on Roy Model of Self-Selection Results drawn on Heckman and Sedlacek JPE, 1985 and Heckman and Honoré, Econometrica, 1986. Two-sector model in which: Agents are income

More information

NASH BARGAINING, ON-THE-JOB SEARCH AND LABOR MARKET EQUILIBRIUM

NASH BARGAINING, ON-THE-JOB SEARCH AND LABOR MARKET EQUILIBRIUM NASH BARGAINING, ON-THE-JOB SEARCH AND LABOR MARKET EQUILIBRIUM Roberto Bonilla Department of Economics University of Newcastle Business School University of Newcastle upon Tyne Newcastle upon Tyne U.K.

More information

Lecture 1: Facts To Be Explained

Lecture 1: Facts To Be Explained ECONG205 MRes Applied Job Search Models Lecture 1: Facts To Be Explained Fabien Postel-Vinay Department of Economics, University College London. 1 / 31 WAGE DISPERSION 2 / 31 The Sources of Wage Dispersion

More information

Other Models of Labor Dynamics

Other Models of Labor Dynamics Other Models of Labor Dynamics Christopher Taber Department of Economics University of Wisconsin-Madison March 2, 2014 Outline 1 Kambourov and Manovskii 2 Neal 3 Pavan Occupational Specificity of Human

More information

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk Optimal Insurance of Search Risk Mikhail Golosov Yale University and NBER Pricila Maziero University of Pennsylvania Guido Menzio University of Pennsylvania and NBER November 2011 Introduction Search and

More information

The Dark Corners of the Labor Market

The Dark Corners of the Labor Market The Dark Corners of the Labor Market Vincent Sterk Conference on Persistent Output Gaps: Causes and Policy Remedies EABCN / University of Cambridge / INET University College London September 2015 Sterk

More information

Mortenson Pissarides Model

Mortenson Pissarides Model Mortenson Pissarides Model Prof. Lutz Hendricks Econ720 November 22, 2017 1 / 47 Mortenson / Pissarides Model Search models are popular in many contexts: labor markets, monetary theory, etc. They are distinguished

More information

Competitive Search: A Test of Direction and Efficiency

Competitive Search: A Test of Direction and Efficiency Bryan Engelhardt 1 Peter Rupert 2 1 College of the Holy Cross 2 University of California, Santa Barbara November 20, 2009 1 / 26 Introduction Search & Matching: Important framework for labor market analysis

More information

Stock Sampling with Interval-Censored Elapsed Duration: A Monte Carlo Analysis

Stock Sampling with Interval-Censored Elapsed Duration: A Monte Carlo Analysis Stock Sampling with Interval-Censored Elapsed Duration: A Monte Carlo Analysis Michael P. Babington and Javier Cano-Urbina August 31, 2018 Abstract Duration data obtained from a given stock of individuals

More information

Returns to Tenure. Christopher Taber. March 31, Department of Economics University of Wisconsin-Madison

Returns to Tenure. Christopher Taber. March 31, Department of Economics University of Wisconsin-Madison Returns to Tenure Christopher Taber Department of Economics University of Wisconsin-Madison March 31, 2008 Outline 1 Basic Framework 2 Abraham and Farber 3 Altonji and Shakotko 4 Topel Basic Framework

More information

Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies:

Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies: Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies: Explorations with a Dynamic General Equilibrium Model of Labor Earnings based on Heckman, Lochner and Taber, Review of Economic

More information

SUPPLEMENT TO RETURNS TO TENURE OR SENIORITY? : ADDITIONAL TABLES AND ESTIMATIONS (Econometrica, Vol. 82, No. 2, March 2014, )

SUPPLEMENT TO RETURNS TO TENURE OR SENIORITY? : ADDITIONAL TABLES AND ESTIMATIONS (Econometrica, Vol. 82, No. 2, March 2014, ) Econometrica Supplementary Material SUPPLEMENT TO RETURNS TO TENURE OR SENIORITY? : ADDITIONAL TABLES AND ESTIMATIONS (Econometrica, Vol. 82, No. 2, March 2014, 705 730) BY I. SEBASTIAN BUHAI, MIGUEL A.

More information

On the extent of job-to-job transitions

On the extent of job-to-job transitions On the extent of job-to-job transitions Éva Nagypál 1 September, 2005 PRELIMINARY VERSION Abstract The rate of job-to-job transitions is twice as large today as the rate at which workers move from employment

More information

A Distributional Framework for Matched Employer Employee Data

A Distributional Framework for Matched Employer Employee Data A Distributional Framework for Matched Employer Employee Data (Preliminary) Interactions - BFI Bonhomme, Lamadon, Manresa University of Chicago MIT Sloan September 26th - 2015 Wage Dispersion Wages are

More information

Returns to on-the-job search and the dispersion of wages

Returns to on-the-job search and the dispersion of wages Returns to on-the-job search and the dispersion of wages Axel Gottfries 1 and Coen Teulings 1,2 1 University of Cambridge 2 University of Amsterdam March 15, 2017 Abstract A wide class of models with On-the-Job

More information

RBC Model with Indivisible Labor. Advanced Macroeconomic Theory

RBC Model with Indivisible Labor. Advanced Macroeconomic Theory RBC Model with Indivisible Labor Advanced Macroeconomic Theory 1 Last Class What are business cycles? Using HP- lter to decompose data into trend and cyclical components Business cycle facts Standard RBC

More information

On-the-job search and sorting

On-the-job search and sorting On-the-job search and sorting Pieter A. Gautier Coen N. Teulings Aico van Vuuren July, 27 Abstract We characterize the equilibrium for a general class of search models with two sided heterogeneity and

More information

Directed Search on the Job, Heterogeneity, and Aggregate Fluctuations

Directed Search on the Job, Heterogeneity, and Aggregate Fluctuations Directed Search on the Job, Heterogeneity, and Aggregate Fluctuations By GUIDO MENZIO AND SHOUYONG SHI In models of search on the job (e.g. Kenneth Burdett and Dale Mortensen 1998, Burdett and Melvyn Coles

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES UNEMPLOYMENT FLUCTUATIONS, MATCH QUALITY, AND THE WAGE CYCLICALITY OF NEW HIRES

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES UNEMPLOYMENT FLUCTUATIONS, MATCH QUALITY, AND THE WAGE CYCLICALITY OF NEW HIRES NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES UNEMPLOYMENT FLUCTUATIONS, MATCH QUALITY, AND THE WAGE CYCLICALITY OF NEW HIRES Mark Gertler Christopher Huckfeldt Antonella Trigari Working Paper 22341 http://www.nber.org/papers/w22341

More information

Asymmetric Information and Search Frictions: A Neutrality Result

Asymmetric Information and Search Frictions: A Neutrality Result Asymmetric Information and Search Frictions: A Neutrality Result Neel Rao University at Buffalo, SUNY August 26, 2016 Abstract This paper integrates asymmetric information between firms into a canonical

More information

Controlling for Time Invariant Heterogeneity

Controlling for Time Invariant Heterogeneity Controlling for Time Invariant Heterogeneity Yona Rubinstein July 2016 Yona Rubinstein (LSE) Controlling for Time Invariant Heterogeneity 07/16 1 / 19 Observables and Unobservables Confounding Factors

More information

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty 1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty Sofarwehaveassumedawayaggregatefluctuations (i.e., business cycles) in our description of the incomplete-markets economies with uninsurable idiosyncratic risk

More information

Comments on News and Noise in the Post-Great Recession Recovery by Renato Faccini and Leonardo Melosi

Comments on News and Noise in the Post-Great Recession Recovery by Renato Faccini and Leonardo Melosi Comments on News and Noise in the Post-Great Recession Recovery by Renato Faccini and Leonardo Melosi Federico Ravenna Danmarks Nationalbank and University of Copenhagen Konstanz, May 2018 The views expressed

More information

Sources of Inequality: Additive Decomposition of the Gini Coefficient.

Sources of Inequality: Additive Decomposition of the Gini Coefficient. Sources of Inequality: Additive Decomposition of the Gini Coefficient. Carlos Hurtado Econometrics Seminar Department of Economics University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign hrtdmrt2@illinois.edu Feb 24th,

More information

Job Search over the Life Cycle

Job Search over the Life Cycle Job Search over the Life Cycle Hui He y Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Lei Ning z Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Liang Wang x University of Hawaii Manoa March 12, 2014 Preliminary

More information

Estimation of a Roy/Search/Compensating Differential Model of the Labor Market

Estimation of a Roy/Search/Compensating Differential Model of the Labor Market DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 9975 Estimation of a Roy/Search/Compensating Differential Model of the Labor Market Christopher Taber Rune Vejlin May 2016 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute

More information

Estimation of a Roy/Search/Compensating Differential Model of the Labor Market 1

Estimation of a Roy/Search/Compensating Differential Model of the Labor Market 1 Estimation of a Roy/Search/Compensating Differential Model of the Labor Market 1 Christopher Taber University of Wisconsin-Madison Rune Vejlin Aarhus University March 29, 2016 1 We would like to thank

More information

GROWING APART: THE CHANGING FIRM-SIZE WAGE PREMIUM AND ITS INEQUALITY CONSEQUENCES ONLINE APPENDIX

GROWING APART: THE CHANGING FIRM-SIZE WAGE PREMIUM AND ITS INEQUALITY CONSEQUENCES ONLINE APPENDIX GROWING APART: THE CHANGING FIRM-SIZE WAGE PREMIUM AND ITS INEQUALITY CONSEQUENCES ONLINE APPENDIX The following document is the online appendix for the paper, Growing Apart: The Changing Firm-Size Wage

More information

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Government Purchases and Endogenous Growth Consider the following endogenous growth model with government purchases (G) in continuous time. Government purchases enhance production, and the production

More information

The Pervasive Importance of Tightness in Labor-Market Volatility

The Pervasive Importance of Tightness in Labor-Market Volatility The Pervasive Importance of Tightness in Labor-Market Volatility Robert E. Hall Hoover Institution and Department of Economics, Stanford University National Bureau of Economic Research rehall@stanford.edu;

More information

Exam D0M61A Advanced econometrics

Exam D0M61A Advanced econometrics Exam D0M61A Advanced econometrics 19 January 2009, 9 12am Question 1 (5 pts.) Consider the wage function w i = β 0 + β 1 S i + β 2 E i + β 0 3h i + ε i, where w i is the log-wage of individual i, S i is

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations, Match Quality, and the Wage Cyclicality of New Hires

Unemployment Fluctuations, Match Quality, and the Wage Cyclicality of New Hires Unemployment Fluctuations, Match Quality, and the Wage Cyclicality of New Hires Mark Gertler 1, Christopher Huckfeldt 2, Antonella Trigari 3 1 New York University, NBER 2 Cornell University 3 Bocconi University,

More information

Lecture 9. Matthew Osborne

Lecture 9. Matthew Osborne Lecture 9 Matthew Osborne 22 September 2006 Potential Outcome Model Try to replicate experimental data. Social Experiment: controlled experiment. Caveat: usually very expensive. Natural Experiment: observe

More information

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Labor Economics, 14.661. Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Daron Acemoglu MIT December 6, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Sequential Search December 6, 2011. 1 / 43 Introduction Introduction

More information

Equilibrium Labor Force Participation and Wage Dispersion

Equilibrium Labor Force Participation and Wage Dispersion Equilibrium Labor Force Participation and Wage Dispersion by Chun Seng Yip University of Pennsylvania Job Market Paper (Preliminary Version) September 28, 2003 Abstract An important gap in the literature

More information

Models of Wage Dynamics

Models of Wage Dynamics Models of Wage Dynamics Toshihiko Mukoyama Department of Economics Concordia University and CIREQ mukoyama@alcor.concordia.ca December 13, 2005 1 Introduction This paper introduces four different models

More information

Residual Wage Disparity and Coordination Unemployment

Residual Wage Disparity and Coordination Unemployment Residual Wage Disparity and Coordination Unemployment Benoit Julien, John Kennes, and Ian King First Draft: June 2001 This Draft: April 2005 Abstract How much of residual wage dispersion can be explained

More information

Instrumental Variables

Instrumental Variables Instrumental Variables Yona Rubinstein July 2016 Yona Rubinstein (LSE) Instrumental Variables 07/16 1 / 31 The Limitation of Panel Data So far we learned how to account for selection on time invariant

More information

Wage Inequality, Labor Market Participation and Unemployment

Wage Inequality, Labor Market Participation and Unemployment Wage Inequality, Labor Market Participation and Unemployment Testing the Implications of a Search-Theoretical Model with Regional Data Joachim Möller Alisher Aldashev Universität Regensburg www.wiwi.uni-regensburg.de/moeller/

More information

Labor-market Volatility in Matching Models with Endogenous Separations

Labor-market Volatility in Matching Models with Endogenous Separations Scand. J. of Economics 109(4), 645 665, 2007 DOI: 10.1111/j.1467-9442.2007.00515.x Labor-market Volatility in Matching Models with Endogenous Separations Dale Mortensen Northwestern University, Evanston,

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 9 - Labor markets: The search and matching model with endogenous job destruction March.

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 9 - Labor markets: The search and matching model with endogenous job destruction March. Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 9 - Labor markets: The search and matching model with endogenous job destruction Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 March Empirical relevance of a variable job destruction rate

More information

Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection

Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection Eric Bartelsman, John Haltiwanger & Stefano Scarpetta American Economic Review (2013) Presented by Beatriz González January

More information

UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, :00 am - 2:00 pm

UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, :00 am - 2:00 pm UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, 2017 9:00 am - 2:00 pm INSTRUCTIONS Please place a completed label (from the label sheet provided) on the

More information

Do employment contract reforms affect welfare?

Do employment contract reforms affect welfare? Do employment contract reforms affect welfare? Cristina Tealdi IMT Lucca Institute for Advanced Studies April 26, 2013 Cristina Tealdi (NU / IMT Lucca) Employment contract reforms April 26, 2013 1 Motivation:

More information

The Harris-Todaro model

The Harris-Todaro model Yves Zenou Research Institute of Industrial Economics July 3, 2006 The Harris-Todaro model In two seminal papers, Todaro (1969) and Harris and Todaro (1970) have developed a canonical model of rural-urban

More information

1 The Basic RBC Model

1 The Basic RBC Model IHS 2016, Macroeconomics III Michael Reiter Ch. 1: Notes on RBC Model 1 1 The Basic RBC Model 1.1 Description of Model Variables y z k L c I w r output level of technology (exogenous) capital at end of

More information

A Distributional Framework for Matched Employer Employee Data. Nov 2017

A Distributional Framework for Matched Employer Employee Data. Nov 2017 A Distributional Framework for Matched Employer Employee Data Nov 2017 Introduction Many important labor questions rely on rich worker and firm heterogeneity - decomposing wage inequality, understanding

More information

Cambridge-INET Institute

Cambridge-INET Institute Faculty of Economics Cambridge-INET Institute Cambridge-INET Working Paper Series No: 2017/16 Cambridge Working Papers in Economics: 1736 WAGE POSTING, NOMINAL RIGIDITY, AND CYCLICAL INEFFICIENCIES Axel

More information

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models 4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models Basic Economic Models In Economics, we use theoretical models to explain the economic processes in the real world. These models de ne a relation

More information

Network Search: Climbing the Ladder Faster

Network Search: Climbing the Ladder Faster Network Search: Climbing the Ladder Faster Marcelo Arbex Dennis O Dea David Wiczer University of Windsor University of Washington Fed Reserve Bank of St. Louis. October 3, 2016 The views expressed herein

More information

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999) Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999) The question we are asking is: What are the consequences of a monetary policy shock a shock which is purely related to monetary conditions

More information

Quantitative Economics for the Evaluation of the European Policy

Quantitative Economics for the Evaluation of the European Policy Quantitative Economics for the Evaluation of the European Policy Dipartimento di Economia e Management Irene Brunetti Davide Fiaschi Angela Parenti 1 25th of September, 2017 1 ireneb@ec.unipi.it, davide.fiaschi@unipi.it,

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EQUILIBRIUM WAGE AND EMPLOYMENT DYNAMICS IN A MODEL OF WAGE POSTING WITHOUT COMMITMENT. Melvyn G. Coles Dale T.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EQUILIBRIUM WAGE AND EMPLOYMENT DYNAMICS IN A MODEL OF WAGE POSTING WITHOUT COMMITMENT. Melvyn G. Coles Dale T. NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EQUILIBRIUM WAGE AND EMPLOYMENT DYNAMICS IN A MODEL OF WAGE POSTING WITHOUT COMMITMENT Melvyn G. Coles Dale T. Mortensen Working Paper 17284 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17284

More information

Lecture 5: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory

Lecture 5: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory Lecture 5: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory Spring 2017 Lars Calmfors Literature: Chapter 7 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: 435-445 1 Topics Weakly efficient bargaining Strongly efficient bargaining

More information

The Cyclicality of Search Intensity in a Competitive Search Model

The Cyclicality of Search Intensity in a Competitive Search Model The Cyclicality of Search Intensity in a Competitive Search Model Paul Gomme Damba Lkhagvasuren May 28, 2013 Abstract Reasonably calibrated versions of the Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides search and matching

More information

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA On the Solution of the Growth Model with Investment-Specific Technological Change Jesús Fernández-Villaverde and Juan Francisco Rubio-Ramírez Working Paper 2004-39 December

More information

Missing dependent variables in panel data models

Missing dependent variables in panel data models Missing dependent variables in panel data models Jason Abrevaya Abstract This paper considers estimation of a fixed-effects model in which the dependent variable may be missing. For cross-sectional units

More information

Housing and the Labor Market: Time to Move and Aggregate Unemployment

Housing and the Labor Market: Time to Move and Aggregate Unemployment Housing and the Labor Market: Time to Move and Aggregate Unemployment Peter Rupert 1 Etienne Wasmer 2 1 University of California, Santa Barbara 2 Sciences-Po. Paris and OFCE search class April 1, 2011

More information

Macroeconomics Theory II

Macroeconomics Theory II Macroeconomics Theory II Francesco Franco FEUNL February 2011 Francesco Franco Macroeconomics Theory II 1/34 The log-linear plain vanilla RBC and ν(σ n )= ĉ t = Y C ẑt +(1 α) Y C ˆn t + K βc ˆk t 1 + K

More information

1. Unemployment. March 20, Nr. 1

1. Unemployment. March 20, Nr. 1 1. Unemployment March 20, 2007 Nr. 1 Job destruction, and employment protection. I So far, only creation decision. Clearly both creation and destruction margins. So endogenize job destruction. Can then

More information

Economics Bulletin, 2012, Vol. 32 No. 1 pp Introduction

Economics Bulletin, 2012, Vol. 32 No. 1 pp Introduction 1. Introduction The past decades have been harsh for young workers as their unemployment rate was double the rest of the populations in many developed countries. In Europe the youth unemployment rate (15

More information

Part VII. Accounting for the Endogeneity of Schooling. Endogeneity of schooling Mean growth rate of earnings Mean growth rate Selection bias Summary

Part VII. Accounting for the Endogeneity of Schooling. Endogeneity of schooling Mean growth rate of earnings Mean growth rate Selection bias Summary Part VII Accounting for the Endogeneity of Schooling 327 / 785 Much of the CPS-Census literature on the returns to schooling ignores the choice of schooling and its consequences for estimating the rate

More information

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk Optimal Insurance of Search Risk Mikhail Golosov Yale University and NBER Pricila Maziero University of Pennsylvania Guido Menzio University of Pennsylvania and NBER May 27, 2011 Introduction Search and

More information

Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides Model

Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides Model Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides Model Dongpeng Liu Nanjing University March 2016 D. Liu (NJU) DMP 03/16 1 / 35 Introduction Motivation In the previous lecture, McCall s model was introduced McCall s model

More information

This note introduces some key concepts in time series econometrics. First, we

This note introduces some key concepts in time series econometrics. First, we INTRODUCTION TO TIME SERIES Econometrics 2 Heino Bohn Nielsen September, 2005 This note introduces some key concepts in time series econometrics. First, we present by means of examples some characteristic

More information

Remarks on Structural Estimation The Search Framework

Remarks on Structural Estimation The Search Framework Remarks on Structural Estimation The Search Framework Christopher Flinn NYU and Collegio Carlo Alberto November 2009 1 The Estimation of Search Models We develop a simple model of single agent search set

More information

Applied Microeconometrics (L5): Panel Data-Basics

Applied Microeconometrics (L5): Panel Data-Basics Applied Microeconometrics (L5): Panel Data-Basics Nicholas Giannakopoulos University of Patras Department of Economics ngias@upatras.gr November 10, 2015 Nicholas Giannakopoulos (UPatras) MSc Applied Economics

More information

Re-estimating Euler Equations

Re-estimating Euler Equations Re-estimating Euler Equations Olga Gorbachev September 1, 2016 Abstract I estimate an extended version of the incomplete markets consumption model allowing for heterogeneity in discount factors, nonseparable

More information

Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 3d ed. Chapter 16: Simultaneous equations models. An obvious reason for the endogeneity of explanatory

Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 3d ed. Chapter 16: Simultaneous equations models. An obvious reason for the endogeneity of explanatory Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 3d ed. Chapter 16: Simultaneous equations models An obvious reason for the endogeneity of explanatory variables in a regression model is simultaneity: that is, one

More information

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture notes #9 : the Mortensen-Pissarides matching model

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture notes #9 : the Mortensen-Pissarides matching model 2012-2013 Master 2 Macro I Lecture notes #9 : the Mortensen-Pissarides matching model Franck Portier (based on Gilles Saint-Paul lecture notes) franck.portier@tse-fr.eu Toulouse School of Economics Version

More information

Estimating Macroeconomic Models: A Likelihood Approach

Estimating Macroeconomic Models: A Likelihood Approach Estimating Macroeconomic Models: A Likelihood Approach Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania, NBER, and CEPR Juan Rubio-Ramírez Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Estimating Dynamic Macroeconomic

More information

On-The-Job Search and Sorting

On-The-Job Search and Sorting DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 1687 On-The-Job Search and Sorting Pieter A. Gautier Coen N. Teulings Aico van Vuuren July 2005 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor

More information

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC) Real Business Cycle Model (RBC) Seyed Ali Madanizadeh November 2013 RBC Model Lucas 1980: One of the functions of theoretical economics is to provide fully articulated, artificial economic systems that

More information

Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters

Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters Thomas MaCurdy a and Xiaohong Chen b and Han Hong c Introduction Many empirical studies of program evaluations are complicated by the presence of both

More information

Making sense of Econometrics: Basics

Making sense of Econometrics: Basics Making sense of Econometrics: Basics Lecture 4: Qualitative influences and Heteroskedasticity Egypt Scholars Economic Society November 1, 2014 Assignment & feedback enter classroom at http://b.socrative.com/login/student/

More information

Recitation Notes 6. Konrad Menzel. October 22, 2006

Recitation Notes 6. Konrad Menzel. October 22, 2006 Recitation Notes 6 Konrad Menzel October, 006 Random Coefficient Models. Motivation In the empirical literature on education and earnings, the main object of interest is the human capital earnings function

More information

Estimation of a Roy/Search/Compensating Differential Model of the Labor Market

Estimation of a Roy/Search/Compensating Differential Model of the Labor Market Estimation of a Roy/Search/Compensating Differential Model of the Labor Market Christopher Taber University of Wisconsin-Madison Rune Vejlin Aarhus University August 16, 2011 1 Introduction The four most

More information

Measuring Mismatch in the U.S. Labor Market

Measuring Mismatch in the U.S. Labor Market Measuring Mismatch in the U.S. Labor Market Ayşegül Şahin Federal Reserve Bank of New York Joseph Song Federal Reserve Bank of New York Giorgio Topa Federal Reserve Bank of New York, and IZA Gianluca Violante

More information

Joint-Search Theory. Bulent Guler 1 Fatih Guvenen 2 Gianluca Violante 3. Indiana University

Joint-Search Theory. Bulent Guler 1 Fatih Guvenen 2 Gianluca Violante 3. Indiana University Joint-Search Theory Bulent Guler 1 Fatih Guvenen 2 Gianluca Violante 3 1 Indiana University 2 University of Minnesota 3 New York University Indiana University GGV (UT-Austin, NYU) Joint-Search Theory IUB

More information

A Multisector Equilibrium Search Model of Labor Reallocation

A Multisector Equilibrium Search Model of Labor Reallocation A Multisector Equilibrium Search Model of Labor Reallocation Laura Pilossoph University of Chicago November 19, 2012 Abstract How much unemployment can be attributed to intersectoral mobility frictions?

More information

A Stock-Flow Theory of Unemployment with Endogenous Match Formation

A Stock-Flow Theory of Unemployment with Endogenous Match Formation A Stock-Flow Theory of Unemployment with Endogenous Match Formation Carlos Carrillo-Tudela and William Hawkins Univ. of Essex and Yeshiva University February 2016 Carrillo-Tudela and Hawkins Stock-Flow

More information

Write your identification number on each paper and cover sheet (the number stated in the upper right hand corner on your exam cover).

Write your identification number on each paper and cover sheet (the number stated in the upper right hand corner on your exam cover). Formatmall skapad: 2011-12-01 Uppdaterad: 2015-03-06 / LP Department of Economics Course name: Empirical Methods in Economics 2 Course code: EC2404 Semester: Spring 2015 Type of exam: MAIN Examiner: Peter

More information

Accounting for Mismatch Unemployment. Why are the latest results different from those in previous versions of the paper?

Accounting for Mismatch Unemployment. Why are the latest results different from those in previous versions of the paper? Accounting for Mismatch Unemployment Benedikt Herz and Thijs van Rens December 2018 Why are the latest results different from those in previous versions of the paper? 1 Introduction In earlier versions

More information

Mismatch. Robert Shimer. (American Economic Review, 2007) Presented by Ismael Gálvez. January 23, 2018

Mismatch. Robert Shimer. (American Economic Review, 2007) Presented by Ismael Gálvez. January 23, 2018 Mismatch Robert Shimer (American Economic Review, 2007) Presented by Ismael Gálvez January 23, 2018 Motivation Broad questions: (1) Why do unemployed and job vacancies coexist? (2) What determines the

More information

INFERENCE APPROACHES FOR INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLE QUANTILE REGRESSION. 1. Introduction

INFERENCE APPROACHES FOR INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLE QUANTILE REGRESSION. 1. Introduction INFERENCE APPROACHES FOR INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLE QUANTILE REGRESSION VICTOR CHERNOZHUKOV CHRISTIAN HANSEN MICHAEL JANSSON Abstract. We consider asymptotic and finite-sample confidence bounds in instrumental

More information

Potential Outcomes Model (POM)

Potential Outcomes Model (POM) Potential Outcomes Model (POM) Relationship Between Counterfactual States Causality Empirical Strategies in Labor Economics, Angrist Krueger (1999): The most challenging empirical questions in economics

More information

h Edition Money in Search Equilibrium

h Edition Money in Search Equilibrium In the Name of God Sharif University of Technology Graduate School of Management and Economics Money in Search Equilibrium Diamond (1984) Navid Raeesi Spring 2014 Page 1 Introduction: Markets with Search

More information

Price Discrimination through Refund Contracts in Airlines

Price Discrimination through Refund Contracts in Airlines Introduction Price Discrimination through Refund Contracts in Airlines Paan Jindapon Department of Economics and Finance The University of Texas - Pan American Department of Economics, Finance and Legal

More information

Introduction to Forecasting

Introduction to Forecasting Introduction to Forecasting Introduction to Forecasting Predicting the future Not an exact science but instead consists of a set of statistical tools and techniques that are supported by human judgment

More information

Structural Econometrics: Equilibrium search models. Jean-Marc Robin

Structural Econometrics: Equilibrium search models. Jean-Marc Robin Structural Econometrics: Equilibrium search models Jean-Marc Robin Plan 1. Facts on wage distributions 2. On-the-job search and wage posting { Burdett-Mortensen 3. Sequential auctions { Postel-Vinay Robin

More information

Appendices to: Revisiting the Welfare Effects of Eliminating Business Cycles

Appendices to: Revisiting the Welfare Effects of Eliminating Business Cycles Appendices to: Revisiting the Welfare Effects of Eliminating Business Cycles Per Krusell Toshihiko Mukoyama Ayşegül Şahin Anthony A. Smith, Jr. December 2008 A The integration principle applied to the

More information

Discussion of Revisiting the Relationship Between Unemployment and Wages by Galindo da Fonseca, Gallipoli and Yedid-Levi

Discussion of Revisiting the Relationship Between Unemployment and Wages by Galindo da Fonseca, Gallipoli and Yedid-Levi Discussion of Revisiting the Relationship Between Unemployment and Wages by Galindo da Fonseca, Gallipoli and Yedid-Levi Axel Gottfries University of Cambridge 12th joint ECB/CEPR Labour Market Workshop

More information

Productivity and Job Flows: Heterogeneity of New Hires and Continuing Jobs in the Business Cycle

Productivity and Job Flows: Heterogeneity of New Hires and Continuing Jobs in the Business Cycle Productivity and Job Flows: Heterogeneity of New Hires and Continuing Jobs in the Business Cycle Juha Kilponen Bank of Finland Juuso Vanhala y Bank of Finland April 3, 29 Abstract This paper focuses on

More information