Liquidation of an indivisible asset with independent investment

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Liquidation of an indivisible asset with independent investment"

Transcription

1 Liquidation of an indivisible asset with independent investment Emilie Fabre Guillaume Royer Nizar Touzi January 3, 25 Abstract We provide an extension of the explicit solution of a mixed optimal stopping optimal stochastic control problem introduced by Henderson and Hobson. The problem examines whether the optimal investment problem on a local martingale financial market is affected by the optimal liquidation of an independent indivisible asset. The indivisible asset process is defined by a homogeneous scalar stochastic differential equation, and the investor s preferences are defined by a general expected utility function. The value function is obtained in explicit form, and we prove the existence of an optimal stopping investment strategy characterized as the limit of an explicit maximizing strategy. Our approach is based on the standard dynamic programming approach. Key words: Optimal stopping, optimal control, viscosity solutions. AMS 2 subject classifications: 93E2, 6H3. Introduction This paper considers a mixed optimal stopping/optimal control problem introduced by Henderson and Hobson [7 corresponding to the question of optimal liquidation of an indivisible asset in incomplete market, so that it is impossible to hedge it, while the agent is allowed to trade continuously in another financial asset. This question is motivated by problems on real option, see Dixit and Pindyck [3, and Henderson [9. The framework of [7 is the following: an investor holds an indivisible asset, with price process defined as a geometric Brownian motion. In addition, a nonrisky asset, normalized CMAP, Ecole Polytechnique Paris, emilie.fabre@polytechnique.edu. CMAP, Ecole Polytechnique Paris, guillaume.royer@polytechnique.edu. CMAP, Ecole Polytechnique Paris, nizar.touzi@polytechnique.edu. Research supported by the Chair Financial Risks of the Risk Foundation sponsored by Société Générale, and the Chair Finance and Sustainable Development sponsored by EDF and Calyon.

2 to unity, and a financial asset are available for frictionless continuous-time trading. The risky asset price process is a local martingale with zero covariation with the indivisible asset process. The investor s preferences are defined by the expected power utility function. The objective of the risk averse investor is to choose optimally a stopping time for selling the indivisible asset, while optimally continuously trading on the financial market. In the absence of the indivisible asset, the problem reduces to a pure portfolio investment problem. Since the risky asset price process is a local martingale, it follows from the Jensen inequality that the optimal investment strategy of the risk averse investor consists in not trading the risky asset. Therefore, the main question raised by [7 is whether this optimal strategy is affected by the optimal liquidation problem of the independent indivisible asset. In the context of the power utility function, [7 shows that the answer to this question depends on the model parameters, and they provide the optimal stopping-investment strategies. We observe that the last problem has been also studied in the case of correlated asset by Evans, Henderson and Hobson [4. We also refer to Henderson and Hobson for applications to American Options [8. In this paper we focus on the case where the financial asset is martingale and uncorrelated to the indivisible asset, corresponding to the setup of [7. Our objective is to extend their results in two directions. First, the indivisible asset price process is defined by an arbitrary scalar homogeneous stochastic differential equation. Second, the investor s preferences are characterized by a general expected utility function. In contrast with [7, we use the standard dynamic programming approach to stochastic control and optimal stopping to show that a lower bound is given by the limit of a sequence of functions defined by successive concavifications with respect to each variable. The resulting function is then the smallest majorant of the utility function which is partially concave in each of the variables. This construction of the lower bound induces a maximizing sequence of stopping times and portfolio strategies. This observation allows to prove that this lower bound indeed coincides with the value function. Finally, we prove that this maximizing sequence is weakly compact, and we deduce the existence of an optimal strategy. The construction of [7 depends strongly on the particular specification of the Black-Scholes dynamics for the price process of the illiquid asset, and the power utility function. Moreover, specific arguments are adopted to solve the problem in various cases. Our approach using dynamic programming equations as a guess allows to get an insight of the value in a general context. Moreover this characterization as an increasing limit of concave envelopes made computation of the value function more easy and tractable. In particular the interest of gambling while trying to liquidate an indivisible asset boils down to verify if the first concave function considered is equal to the value function. We illustrate as well our result by recomputing the results of [7 as this limit of concave envelopes in the Appendix. The paper is organized as follows. The problem is formulated in Section 2. The main results are stated in Section 3. In particular, in Subsection 3.2, we specialize the discussion to the original context of [7, and we show that our general results cover their findings. The 2

3 explicit derivation of the value function is reported in Section 4. Finally, Section 5 contains the proof of existence of an optimal stopping-investment strategy. 2 Problem formulation Let B be a Brownian motion on a filtered probability space (Ω, F, F := {F t } t, P. Throughout this paper, we consider an indivisible asset with price process Y y defined by the stochastic differential equation: dy y t [ = Y y t µ(y y t dt + σ(y y t db t, Y y = y > where the coefficients µ, σ : (, R are bounded, locally Lipschitz-continuous, and σ >. In particular, this ensures the existence and uniqueness of a strong solution to the previous SDE. The first objective of the investor is to decide about an optimal stopping time τ for the liquidation of the indivisible asset. We shall denote by T the collection of all finite F stopping times. The financial market also allows for the continuous frictionless trading of a risky security whose price process is a local martingale orthogonal to W. Then assuming a zero interest rate (or, in other words, considering forward prices, the return from a self-financing portfolio strategy is a process X in the set M (x := {X càdlàg martingale with X = x, and [X, B = }, (2. where [X, B denotes the quadratic covariation process between X and B. In the last admissibility set, the condition [X, B = reflects that the indivisible asset cannot be partially hedged by the financial assets, while the martingale condition implies that, in the absence of the indivisible asset, the optimal investment in risky security of a risk-averse agent is zero. Following Hendersen and Hobson [7, our objective is precisely to analyze the impact of the presence of the indivisible asset on this optimal no-trading strategy. Let U : R + R { } be a nondecreasing concave function, with U > on (,, be the utility function of a risk-averse investor. Our problem of interest is: where D := {R (, ; x + y }, V (x, y := sup E [ U(X τ + Yτ y, (x, y D, (2.2 (X,τ S(x,y S(x, y := { (X, τ M (x T : (X + Y y. τ and {U(X τ θ + Y y τ θ } θ T is UI }, and UI is an abreviation for uniformly integrable. We also introduce the corresponding no-trade problem: m(x, y := sup E [ U(x + Yτ y, (x, y D, (2.3 τ T (x,y 3

4 where T (x, y := {τ T : (x, τ S(x, y} and we abuse notation by identifying x to the constant process equal to x. While (2.3 is a classical infinite horizon optimal stopping problem, we notice that (2.2 is a mixed stochastic control optimal stopping problem. We shall address both of them by means of the standard dynamic programming approach, see Fleming and Soner [5 and Touzi [. We observe that, similar to the last references, stochastic control and optimal stopping problems are studied separately in view of isolating the main arguments for the solution approach. However, it is well-known that mixed stochastic control optimal stopping problems are easily addressed by an obvious superposition of the corresponding arguments. 3 Main results 3. General utility function We first introduce a suitable change of variable, transforming the process Y y into a local martingale. This is classically obtained by means of the scale function S of Y y defined as a solution of: S (yyµ(y + 2 y2 σ 2 (ys (y =. By additionally requiring that S (c = and S(c =, for some c in the domain of the diffusion Y, this ordinary differential equation induces a uniquely defined continuous one-to-one function S : (, dom(s = ( S(, S(. We denote R := S its continuous inverse. Then the process Z := S(Y y is a local martingale satisfying the stochastic differential equation: dz t = σ(z t db t, with σ(z = R(zS (R(zσ(R(z. From now on, we will work with the process Z instead of Y y. We define the corresponding domain and we introduce the functions: D := {(x, z R dom(s : x + R(z }, m(x, z := m(x, R(z, V (x, z := V (x, R(z and Ū(x, z := U(x + R(z, (x, z D. Notice that Ū is in general not concave w.r.t. z but still concave w.r.t. x. We then introduce Ū := (Ūconcz, where conc z denotes the concave envelope w.r.t. z. We first give the characterization of the no trade-problem, namely the value of m: Proposition 3.. Assume that Ū is locally bounded on int( D, then m(x, y = Ū (x, S(y for all (x, y D. 4

5 Proof. We organize the proof in three steps. Step : We first show that m Ū. Let (x, z D, τ T (x, R(z, θ n a localizing sequence for the local martingale Z, and define τ n = τ θ n. By the Jensen inequality, we have: E [ Ū(x, Z τn E [ Ū (x, Z τn Ū (x, E[Z τn = Ū (x, z. Then, it follows from the Fatou Lemma that: lim inf E [ Ū(x, Z τn + [ E lim inf Ū(x, Z τn + n n = E [ Ū(x, Z τ +. By the uniform integrability of the family {U(x + Y τ θ, θ T }, we obtain: lim E [ Ū(x, Z τn = E [ Ū(x, Z τ. n Then, E [ Ū(x, Z τ Ū (x, z, and therefore m Ū, by the arbitrariness of τ T (x, R(z. Step 2: For the second inequality we use the PDE characterization of the problem. Let m (x, z := lim inf m(x, z be the lower semicontinuous envelop of the function x z z, (x,z D m(x, z. From Step, we have Ū m Ū. Then, by the assumption that Ū is locally bounded, it follows that m is finite. By classical tools of stochastic control, we have that m (x, is a viscosity super-solution of: min{u Ū(x,, u zz }, on int( D. Then it follows from Lemmas 6.9 and 6.23 in [ that m (x, z Ū (x, z for all (x, z int( D. Combining with Step, we have thus proved that m Ū m m on int( D. (3. Step 3: The property is also true on D. Indeed for x R, denote z x := inf{z dom(s : x + R(z }. We then have D = {(x, z x, x R : z x dom(s}. We now fix x such that (x, z x is in D. Any element τ T (x, R(z x must verify Z τ zx S( x, with initial condition Z zx = S( x. Now since Z zx is a local martingale and σ >, we deduce that τ = a.s., so that m(x, z x = Ū(x, z x. Finally, since Ū (x, is the concave envelop of a continuous non-decreasing function defined on [z x, S(, it follows that Ū (x, z x = Ū(x, zx at the left extreme point z x of the domain. We next return to our problem of interest V. Notice that Ū is in general not concave in x, see the power utility example in Subsection 3.2. We remark also that the calculations performed in this context show that Ū is not even continuous, in general, as illustrated by the case < γ p of Proposition 3.7 in which we have Ū locally bounded but discontinuous in the x variable (discontinuity at x =. 5

6 Since the risky asset price process is a local martingale, the value function is expected to be concave in x, because of the maximization over the trading strategies in the risky asset. We are then naturally lead to introduce a function Ū 2 := ( Ū conc x as a further concavification of Ū with respect to the x variable, which may again loose the concavity with respect to the z variable. This leads naturally to the following sequence ( Ū n : n Ū = Ū, Ū 2n+ = ( Ū 2n conc z, Ū 2n+2 = ( Ū 2n+ conc x, n. The sequence ( Ū n is clearly non decreasing, and then converges pointwise to a limit Ū n taking values in R {+ }. It is then easy to check that Ū is the smallest dominant of Ū which is partially concave in x, and partially concave in z. The first main result of the paper is the following: Theorem 3.2. Assume that the filtered probability space (Ω, F, F, P is sufficiently rich in the following sence: (H Either, there is a Brownian motion W independent of B, (H2 Or, there is a sequence (ξ n n of independent uniformly distributed random variables which may be added to enrich the initial filtration. Then, V (x, y = Ū (x, S(y for all (x, y D. In particular, V = m iff Ū = Ū. Moreover, considering the restriction of Ū on int( D, we obtain that if Ū is locally bounded, then it is continuous. If Ū is not locally bounded, then Ū = + on int( D. The proof that V (x, y Ū (x, S(y is reported in section 4.. The reverse inequality is proved under condition (H in section 4.2, using the characterization by means of the dynamic programming equation, and under condition (H2 in section 5., by building and explicit sequence of approximately optimal strategies. Theorem 3.2 states that the value function is given by Ū. Explicit calculation of Ū is possible in many cases as we will illustrate in Proposition 3.7 and the Appendix. In general, one may resort to numerical approximation techniques by exploiting the definition of Ū as a limit of one-dimensional concave envelopes. The last part of Theorem 3.2 answers the economic relevant question raised by Hendersen and Hobson [9. Namely, at any starting point (x, y, gambling has an interest for the investor if and only if Ū (x, S(y = Ū (x, S(y. Remark 3.3. Conditions (H and (H2 are necessary in order to allow for non-trivial orthogonal martingales. Indeed, if the probability space is not sufficiently rich, it may happen that M (x is reduced to the constant process x, so that no gambling is possible and the problems V and m are identical. The last conclusion is not altered if one allows for randomized strategies along the standard relaxation technique in control theory. This shows that Conditions (H and (H2 are of different nature than the introduction of randomized strategies. 6

7 We next focus on the existence and the characterization of a solution to the problem V. We need to introduce the following assumption: Assumption 3.4. For all (x, z int( D, there exists an open bounded subset O := O x,z of D, with (x, z O and cl(o int( D, such that Ū = Ū on O. Since Ū Ū n Ū for all n, this assumption implies that: Ū n = Ū on O for all n. Remark 3.5. Assumption 3.4 implies that Ū is locally bounded. This is a consequence of Lemma 4. below. The second main contribution of this paper is the following existence result. Theorem 3.6. Let Assumption 3.4 hold true, and assume that the filtered probability space satisfies Condition (H2 of Theorem 3.2. Then for all (x, y D: V (x, y = E[U(Xτ + Y y τ for some (X, τ S(x, y. This result is proved in section 5. The optimal strategy (X, τ will be characterized as the limit of an explicit sequence. Moreover if Ū (x, z = Ū n (x, z for some n, then (X, τ is derived explicitly for the starting point (x, z. We shall argue in Remark 3. below that Assumption 3.4 is necessary in the sense that we may find a situation where it is not satisfied and existence of optimal strategies fails. 3.2 The power utility case In [7, the indivisible asset Y y is defined as a geometric Brownian motion: dy y t = Y y t (µdt + σdb t, Y y = y > and the agent preferences are characterized by a power utility function with parameter p (, : U p (x = x p p, p, and U (x = ln(x. (3.2 Following [7, we introduce the constants γ and ˆγ p defined by: γ = 2µ σ 2 and ˆγ p (, p, (p ˆγ p p (p + ˆγ p (2p ˆγ p p ( ˆγ p =, where the existence and uniqueness of ˆγ p follows from direct calculation. 7

8 Proposition 3.7. Let U = U p as defined in (3.2. Then: (i for γ, we have Ū = Ū <, (ii for < γ ˆγ p, we have Ū = Ū < and Ū Ū, (iii for ˆγ p < γ < p, we have Ū = Ū 2 < and Ū Ū 2, (iv for γ p, (iv-a p, we have Ū = Ū 2 = +, (iv-b p >, and γ p, we have Ū = Ū 2 < +, (iv-c p >, and γ > p, we have Ū = Ū < +. The proofs of these results are reported in the Appendix, and are obtained by explicit computation of the succession of concave envelopes. Corollary 3.8. Let U = U p as defined in (3.2 and assume either (H or (H2. Then (i V = m if and only if γ ˆγ p or γ > p >, (ii for γ < p, Assumption 3.4 holds true, so that under condition (H2 an optimal hedging-stopping strategy exists. Remark 3.9. In the present power utility example, Proposition 3.7 states in particular that Ū equals either U, U, or U 2, whenever Ū <. Then, the optimal strategy is directly obtained from Lemma 5.3, and there is no need to the limiting argument of Section 5. Remark 3.. From our explicit calculations, we observe that Assumption 3.4 fails in cases (iv-b and (iv-c of Proposition 3.7. Our explicit calculations in these cases show that Ū is asymptotic to Ū near infinity. Notice that this rules out the existence of an optimal strategy. Indeed, the optimal strategy in optimal stopping theory is given by the first hitting time of the obstacle by the value function. Therefore, if the value function is asymptotic to the obstacle, then such a hitting time may take the value +, which is excluded by our definition of admissible stopping strategies. The result of Corollary 3.8 is in line with the findings of [7, and in fact complements with some missing cases there in. Loosely speaking, Corollary 3.8 states that when γ ˆγ p or when γ > p >, the agent is indifferent to do fair investments on the market; the optimal strategy consists in keeping a constant wealth and solving an optimal stopping problem, i.e. m. Instead, when ˆγ p < γ p, the agent can take advantage of a dynamic management strategy of its portfolio. Remark 3.. The methodology used in [7 is the following. - They construct a parametric family of stopping rules and admissible martingales by first fixing the portfolio value and waiting until the indivisible asset reaches a certain level, and then fixing the time and optimizing the jump of the portfolio value process. - For each element of this family, they evaluate the corresponding performance, and optimize over the parameter values. 8

9 The rigorous proof follows from a verification argument. Our methodology relies on the standard dynamic programming approach to stochastic control, provides a better understanding of the value function V, and justifies the above construction of optimal strategies. Moreover, it shows that the result holds in a wider generality allowing for a larger class of utility functions and richer dynamics of the illiquid asset price process. 4 Characterizing the value function We first prove in section 4. that V Ū. In section 4.2, we prove the reverse inequality under Condition (H on the probability space. The corresponding result under Condition (H2 will be proved at the end of Subsection 5.. Notice that all of our subsequent proofs consider starting values (x, z int( D. Indeed, recall from Step 3 of the proof of Proposition 3. that D = {(x, z x, x R : z x dom(s}, we obtain easily that Ū = Ū on D = {(x, z x, x R : z x dom(s}, and that for any (x, z D, the corresponding set of admissible strategies S(x, R(z is reduced to the constant martingale and stopping time equal to. 4. Upper bound Lemma 4.. Ū is continuous on int( D iff it is locally bounded. If Ū is not locally bounded on int( D, then Ū = + on int( D. Proof. We first assume that Ū locally bounded on int( D. Since Ū is locally bounded, concave w.r.t. x and concave w.r.t. z, we have that Ū (x, and Ū (, z are continuous on the interior of their domain, for all x and z. Now assume on the contrary that there exists ɛ >, (x, z int( D and a sequence (x n, z n int( D, (x n, z n (x, z such that: n + Without loss of generality, we assume that: n, Ū (x n, z n Ū (x, z > ɛ. Ū (x n, z n > Ū (x, z + ɛ. By continuity of Ū (, z, we have for n large enough: Ū (x n, z n Ū (x n, z > ɛ 2. Without loss of generality, we assume z n z for all n. We then define z n = z z n z, and observe from the concavity of Ū (, z that: Ū (x n, z Ū (x n, z n Ū (x n, z n Ū (x n, z z z n z n z 9 > ɛ 2 z n z.

10 Then: Ū (x n, z Ū (x n, z n > ɛ 2 zn z. Since (x n, z n n + (x, z, this is a contradiction with the local boundedness of Ū. We next assume that Ū is not locally bounded on int( D, i.e. there exists (x, z int( D and (x n, z n (x, z such that Ū(x n, z n +. Let c > be such that (x + c, z + c int( D. Then it follows from the non-decrease of Ū in both variables x and z that Ū (x + c, z + c Ū (x n, z + c Ū (x n, z n, as n. Since Ū is partially concave w.r.t. to both variables, this implies that Ū = on D. We now focus on the first inequality in Theorem 3.2. Lemma 4.2. V Ū on D. In order to prove Lemma 4.2, we use a regularization argument in the case Ū locally bounded. By Lemma 4., Ū is continuous on the interior of D. But in general, it is not twice differentiable in each variable. Therefore, we introduce for any ɛ (, : Ūɛ n (x, z = Ū n (ξ, ζρ ɛ (x ξ, z ζdξdζ, (x, z D, for all n [,, (4. where for all u in R 2 : D ρ ɛ (u = ɛ 2 ρ(u/ɛ with ρ(u = Ce /( u 2 u <, and C is chosen such that R 2 ρ(udu = B(, ρ(udu =. Clearly, ρ ɛ is C, compactly supported, and ρ ɛ converges pointwise to the Dirac mass at zero. We set by convention Ū n := Ū n for ɛ =. We also intoduce for any δ : Ū n ɛ,δ(x, z := Ū n ɛ (x + 2δ, z, (x + 2δ, z D, for all n [,. Lemma 4.3. Ūɛ Ū pointwise on D, Ūɛ C ( D, Ūɛ Ūɛ on D, and Ū ɛ,δ is ɛ partially concave in each variable, for all < ɛ < δ. Proof. The first three claims follow from classical properties of the convolution with respect to a non-negative kernel ρ ɛ, together with the construction of Ū. Let us prove the concavity of Ūɛ,δ w.r.t. x. The same proof holds for z. For arbitrary < ɛ < δ, we fix x, x and z such that (x, z D and (x, z D. For λ [,, denote ˆx := λx + ( λx. Then using the concavity of Ū in x: Ūɛ,δ(ˆx, z = Ū (λ(x + 2δ + ξ + ( λ(x + 2δ + ξ, z + ζρ ɛ (ξ, ζdξdζ R 2 ( λ Ū (x + 2δ + ξ, z + ζ + ( λū (x + 2δ + ξ, z + ζ ρ ɛ (ξ, ζdξdζ R 2 = λū ɛ,δ(x, z + ( λū ɛ,δ(x, z.

11 Proof of Lemma 4.2 In the case Ū not locally bounded, then by Lemma 4., we have Ū = + and the result is obvious. Now assume that Ū is locally bounded. We proceed in two steps. Step. Let (θ n n be a localizing sequence for the local martingale Z. We fix δ > and we consider 2ɛ < δ. Let (X, τ S(x, R(z and τ n = τ θ n. Clearely we have that (X, τ n is in S(x, R(z. Then by Itô s formula for jump processes: Since Ū ɛ,δ Ū ɛ,δ(x t τ, Z t τn Ū ɛ,δ(x, z = t τn t τn 2 xxū ɛ,δ(x u, Z u d[x, X c u + + z Ūɛ,δ(X u, Z u σ(z u db u + + t τn t τn 2 zzū ɛ,δ(x u, Z u σ 2 (Z u du x Ū ɛ,δ(x u, Z u dx u <u t τ n (Ū ɛ,δ (X u, Z u Ū ɛ,δ(x u, Z u x Ū ɛ,δ(x u, Z u X u. is concave in x and in z, then: Ū ɛ,δ(x t τn, Z t τn Ū ɛ,δ(x, z We have for all ( x, z: Ū ɛ,δ ( x, z = t τn z Ū ɛ,δ(x u, Z u σ(z u db u + t τn Ū( x + 2δ u, z vρ ɛ (u, vdudv B(( x, z,ɛ U (δ ρ ɛ (u, vdudv = U (δ, B(( x, z,ɛ x Ū ɛ,δ(x u, Z u dx u. (4.2 where the last inequality follows from the fact that U is non decreasing and x + 2δ u + R( z v δ on B(( x, z, ɛ. By Lemma 4.3, this implies: Since, U (δ <, the local martingale: t τn z Ū ɛ,δ(x u, Z u σ(z u db u + Ū ɛ,δ(x t τn, Z t τn U (δ. t τn x Ū ɛ,δ(x u, Z u dx u, t, is bounded from below so it is a supermartingale. Then it follows from (4.2 that: E[Ū ɛ,δ(x t τn, Z t τn Ū ɛ,δ(x, z. Step 2 Notice that Ū ɛ,δ (X t τ n, Z t τn is bounded from below by U( δ Then, it follows from 2 the pointwise convergence Ū ɛ,δ (x, z Ū (x + 2δ, z, together with Fatou s Lemma, that: ɛ E [ Ū (X τ + 2δ, Z τ [ = E lim Ūɛ,δ(X t τn, Z t τn lim infe [ Ūɛ,δ(X t τn, Z t τn t,n ɛ t,n ɛ Ū (x + 2δ, z,

12 By the arbitrariness of (X, τ S(x, R(z, this implies that V (x, z Ū (x + 2δ, z, and therefore V (x, z Ū (x, z, by the continuity of Ū in the x-variable. 4.2 Lower bound for the value function under (H Under Assumption (H on the filtration, it follows that M is non-trivial, and contains the set: M W (x := {X C -mart : X t = x + t φ s dw s for some φ H 2 loc}. In this subsection, we use the PDE characterization of the problem to obtain the lower bound for the value function. In order to use the classical tools of stochastic control and viscosity solutions we introduce the following simplified problem V : V (x, y := sup E[U(X τ + Yτ y, (X,τ S W (x,y where S W (x, y := { (X, τ S(x, y : X M W (x }. Since M W (x M (x, we have V (x, y V (x, y. The reason for introducing the problem V is that it has the standard form of a (singular stochastic control problem which may be addressed by the classical dynamic programming approach. We recall the definition of the lower semi-continuous envelope: V (x, y := lim inf (x,y (x,y V (x, y, (x, y D. By Lemma 4.2, we have U(x + y V (x, y V (x, y Ū (x, R(y. Then, if Ū is locally bounded, so is V, and it follows that V is finite. We now derive the dynamic programming equation, which will provide us with the lower bound. For notation simplicity, we shall use subscripts to indicate partial derivatives with respect to the corresponding variables. Proposition 4.4. Assume that Ū is locally bounded, then V is a viscosity supersolution of: min{ v zz, v xx, v Ū} = on int( D. In particular V is partially concave w.r.t x and z. Proof. We first show that V is a viscosity supersolution of: min{ 2 y2 σ(y 2 v yy (x, y yµ(yv y (x, y; v xx (x, y; v U(x + y} = (4.3 on D. First, since immediate selling of the illiquid asset is legitimate, we see that V (x, y U(x + y, and therefore V (x, y U(x + y, by the continuity of U. 2

13 We next continue by using the first part of the weak dynamic programming principle of Theorem 4. in [2: V (x, y sup E [ V (X θ, Y y θ θ τ + U(X θ + Y y θ θ>τ for all θ stopping time. (X,τ S W (x,y In order to justify the viscosity supersolution property, we consider an interior point (x, y and a test function φ C 2,2 (R such that: min(v φ = (V φ(x, y =. Let (x n, y n n be a sequence such that (x n, y n, V (x n, y n (x, y, V (x, y as n. For fixed α R, define (X n, Y n := (x n + αw θn, Y yn θ n, where c > is a constant, and: θ n := h n inf { t : X n t x n + Y n t y n c }, with h n := β n βn + n β n= where β n := V (x n, y n φ(x n, y n. Since (x, y is in the interior of the domain, notice that we may choose the constant c > sufficiently small so as to ensure that (X n, θ n S W (x n, y n. By the dynamic programming principle together with Itô s formula, it follows that: This leads to: V (x n, y n = β n + φ(x n, y n E[φ(Xθ n n, Yθ n n [ θ n ( = φ(x n, y n + E yµφ y + 2 y2 σ 2 φ yy + (X 2 α2 n φ xx u, Yu n du. [ θ n β n E (yµφ y + 2 y2 σ 2 φ yy + 2 α2 φ xx (Xu n, Yu n du Since µ and σ are locally Lipschitz continuous and have linear growth, one can show the following standard estimate for all h > : [ E sup Ys yn y n 2 Ch 2 ( + y n 2. t s t+h This leads to (X n, Y n (x +αw, Y y P-a.s. Moreover by definition of θ n, the following n quantity θn ( yµφ y + 2 y2 σ 2 φ yy + 2 αφ xx (Xu n, Yu n du h n is bounded, uniformly in n. Therefore, by the mean value and the dominated convergence theorem, 2 y2 σ 2 (y φ yy (x, y + y µ(y φ y (x, y + 2 α2 φ xx (x, y. 3

14 By the arbitrariness of α R, this implies that φ xx (x, y. Hence, V supersolution on D of: min{ 2 y2 σ 2 (yv yy yµ(yv y ; v xx ; v(x, y U(x + y} =. is a viscosity Finally, the supersolution stated in the proposition is a direct consequence of the first step and the change of variable in the theory of viscosity solutions, see e.g. [5. The partial concavity property follows from Lemmas 6.9 and 6.23 in [. Corollary 4.5. Assume Ū is locally bounded. Then for all (x, y D, we have: V (x, y Ū (x, S(y. Proof. We already know that V (x, y V (x, y V (x, S(y. On the other hand, since V is partially concave w.r.t. x and w.r.t. z, and is a majorant of Ū, it follows that V is a majorant of Ū. This completes the proof. 5 Optimal strategy We now derive an optimal strategy under Assumption 3.4 together with Condition (H2 of Theorem 3.2. This will allow also to recover the case Ū = + since the construction is robust, whenever the concave envelopes are not finite. 5. Construction of a maximizing sequence under (H2 We fix (X, Z = (x, z int( D and we consider O := O x,z the open set defined in Assumption 3.4. We define the following sequence of stopping times (τ n n : Since Ū is the concavification of Ū with respect to the z-variable, we introduce the stopping time with frozen x-variable: τ = inf{t : Ū (X, Z t = Ū (X, Z t }, At time τ, Z τ takes values in {z, z 2 } where z = sup{z Z : Ū (X, z = Ū(X, z} and z 2 = inf{z Z : Ū (X, z = Ū(X, z}. Notice that z and z 2 anre finite, since (X, z and (X, z 2 are both in cl(o. We then define: [ where E η(x, Z τ F τ = X and: X t := X {t<τ } + η(x, Z τ {t τ }, P [ η(x, Z τ = a(x, Z τ (X, Z τ = p(x, Z τ, P [ η(x, Z τ = b(x, Z τ (X, Z τ = p(x, Z τ, 4

15 with: d(v := {x R : (x, v D}, a(u, v := inf{α d(v, α u : Ū 2 (α, v = Ū (α, v}, b(u, v := sup{α d(v, α u : Ū 2 (α, v = Ū (α, v}, and p(u, v is defined by: u = p(u, va(u, v + ( p(u, vb(u, v. Similarly, we define a sequence of stopping times (τ n i i n+ by τ n =, and: τ n i := inf { t τ n i : Ū (2(n i++ (X n τ n i, Z t = Ū 2(n i+ (X n τ n i, Z t }, i n +, where the martingale X n is constructed as follows. Let: a n i (u, v := inf { α d(v, α u : Ū 2(n i+ (α, v = Ū 2(n i+ (α, v }, b n i (u, v := sup { α d(v, α u : Ū 2(n i+ (α, v = Ū 2(n i+ (α, v }. By Assumption 3.4, (a n (u, v, v and (b n (u, v, v are in cl(o and Ū 2n i+ (, v is linear on [a n i (u, v, b n i (u, v. We then define p n i (u, v [, by: so that: u = p n i (u, va n i (u, v + ( p n i (u, vb n i (u, v, Ū 2(n i+ (u, v = p n i (u, vū 2(n i+ (a n i (u, v, v + ( p n i (u, vū 2(n i+ (b n i (u, v, v. With these notations, we define the process X n : n Xt n = X n [,τ n (t + ηi n (Xτ n, Z i n τi n [τi n,τ i+ n (t + ηn(x n τ n, Z n n τn [τn, (t, i= where each r.v. ηi n (Xτ n, Z i n τi n is independant of F τi n and has distribution: P [η ni (X nτ, Z ni τ ni = ani (X nτ, Z ni τ ni F τ ni = p n i (Xτ n, Z i n τi n, P [η ni (X nτ, Z ni τ ni = bni (X nτ, Z ni τ ni F τ ni = p n i (Xτ n, Z i n τi n. The existence of such r.v. {η n i, i n} n is guaranteed by Assumption (H2. Remark 5.. There is no issue of measurability of p n i, a n i and b n i as they are only involved in a finite number of values at each step. Lemma 5.2. Under assumption 3.4, (X n, τ n n+ S(x, y for all n. 5

16 Proof. [X n, Z = follows from the fact that X is a pure jump process and Z is continuous. We also see that (X n, Z takes values in the compact cl(o given by assumption 3.4, so τn+ n T and the process X n + R(Z is non negative. We now prove the martingale property. For all i {,..., n}: t (τ n i, τ n i+ E[X n t F t = X n t, If t = τ n i, then: E[X n t F t = E[η n i (X n τ n i, Z τ n i F t = a n i (X n τ n i, Z τ n i E[ η n i =an i F t + b n i (X n τ n i, Z τ n i E[ η n i =an i F t = X n τ n i = Xn t. The crucial property of the sequence (X n, τ n n+ n is the following. Lemma 5.3. For all n, we have: E[Ū(Xn τ n n+, Z τ n n+ = Ū 2n+ (x, z. (5. Proof. We organize the proof in three steps. Step: We first show that for all i {,..., n + }, we have: ( 2(n i+ E [Ū Xτ n, Z i n τi n = E [Ū 2(n i+ ( X n τ n i, Z τ n i. (5.2 Indeed: ( ( [ 2(n i+ E [Ū Xτ n, Z i n τi n = E[Ū 2(n i+ a n i (Xτ n, Z i n τi n, Z τi n E η n i =a n Xn i τ, Z i n τi n [ + (b Ū 2(n i+ n i (Xτ n, Z i n τi n, Z τi n E η n i =b n Xn i τ, Z i n τi n = E[Ū (a 2(n i+ n i (Xτ n, Z i n τi n, Z τi n p n i (Xτ n, Z i n τi n + (b Ū 2(n i+ n i (Xτ n, Z i n τi n, Z τi n ( p n i (Xτ n, Z i n τi n. Then by definition of the random variables a n i (Xτ n, Z i n τi n and bn i (Xτ n, Z i n τi n, and the linearity of Ū 2(n i+ (, Z τ n i on [b ni (X nτ, Z ni τ ni, ani (X nτ, Z ni τ ni, we have: ( E [Ū 2(n i+ (Xτ n, Z i n τi n 2(n i+ = E [Ū a n i (Xτ n, Z i n τi n, Z τi n p n i (Xτ n, Z i n τi n +Ū (b 2(n i+ n i (Xτ n, Z i n τi n, Z τi n ( p ni (X nτ, Z ni τ ni = E [Ū 2(n i+ (Xτ n, Z i n τi n. 6

17 Step 2: We next show that: E [Ū 2(n i+ (Xτ n, Z i n τi n = E [Ū 2(n i++ (Xτ n, Z i n τi n. (5.3 We emphasize here that the process X n takes its values in a finite set. Then the fact that ( σ > and continuous ensures that σ > c > on proj z cl(o and then if follows that for all i, τi n < and that E[Xτ n i n Xn τ = X i n τi ( n. Then we know that Ū 2(n i++ Xτ n, z is linear on H n i n i where: H n i := { z > : Ū 2(n i++ (X n τ n i, z > Ū 2(n i+ (X n τ n i, z}. We can now conclude, by definition of τi n that: E [Ū 2(n i+ (Xτ n, Z i n τi n = E [Ū 2(n i++ (Xτ n, Z i n τi n = E [Ū 2(n i++ (Xτ n, Z i n τi n. Step 3: we now prove (5.: Using (5.2 and (5.3 we have: Ū 2n+ (x, z = n i= + E [Ū 2(n i+ (Xτ n, Z i n τi n Ū 2(n i+ (Xτ n, Z i n τi n n i= E [Ū 2(n i+ (Xτ n, Z i n τi n Ū 2(n i+ 2 (Xτ n, Z i n τi+ n + E [Ū (Xτ n, Z n τn+ n =E [Ū (Xτ n, Z n τn+ n. By construction, we have τn+ n τn n so we have Xτ n = n+ n Xn τ and then: n Ū 2n+ (x, z = E [Ū (Xτ n, Z n+ n τn+ n. Proof of Theorem 3.2 under (H2 By Lemma 4.2, V Ū. Then, since the sequence (Ū n n converges towards Ū, it follows immediately from Lemma 5.3 that (X n, τ n n+ n is a maximizing sequence of strategies. Remark 5.4. Notice that Assumption 3.4 and the local boundedness condition of Ū are not necessary to obtain a maximizing sequence. Indeed we have that the concave envelope f conc of a function f defined on an interval I R is given by: { sup λ(y, y 2 f(y + ( λ(y, y 2 f(y 2 }, with λ(y, y 2 = y 2 y, y y y 2 y 2 y y,y 2 I 7

18 with the convention λ(y, = and λ(, y =. So we could have considered ɛ-optimal sequences of coefficients a n i and b n i rather than optimal ones, which may not exist in the general case, and the proof holds. However the present construction is crucial for the existence result of the subsequent section. 5.2 Existence of an optimal strategy Proof of Theorem 3.6 Let (Xτ n, Z n+ n τn+ n n be the sequence defined in Lemma 5.3. These pairs of random variables take values in the compact subset cl(o. We then define µ n the law of (Xτ n, Z n+ n τn+ n. This is a sequence of probability distributions with support in the compact subset cl(o. Then (µ n is tight, and by the Prokhorov theorem we may find a subsequence, still renamed (µ n, which converges to some probability distribution µ with support in cl(o. Step : We first prove that Ū(ξ, ζdµ(ξ, ζ = Ū (x, z. cl(o Indeed, we have that Ū is continuous on D and cl(o is a compact of D, So by Lemma 5.3 together with the weak convergence property, we obtain: Ū (x, z = lim Ū n (x, z = lim Ū(ξ, ζdµ n n cl(o n (ξ, ζ = Ū(ξ, ζdµ(ξ, ζ. cl(o Step 2: We next introduce a pair (X, τ such that (Xτ, Z τ µ. First, we consider τ a (σ(b s t t -stopping time such that Z τ µ z, where µ z (A := µ(dx, dz is the z-marginal law of µ. Such a stopping time exists because µ R A z is compactly supported and σ c > on cl(o for some c >, thanks to the assumption that σ >. Moreover we consider this stopping time such that τ is smaller than the exit time of the support of µ z. This result is proved in [9, section 4.3, or in Monroe [. We now consider f : [, 2 K a Borel function such that the pushforward measure of the lesbegue measure on [, 2 by f is µ and f(x, y = (f (x, y, f 2 (y. The existence of this function corresponds to the existence of the conditional probability distribution. We denote F µz the cumulative distribution function of µ z. ζ denotes a uniform random variable independent of B and we implicitly assume that the filtration F is rich enough to support that ζ is F τ -measurable and independant of F τ. In particular, ζ is independent of σ(b s τ. The candidate process X is then: Then we clearely have that (Xτ, Z τ µ. X t := f (ζ, F µz (Z τ t τ, t. Step 3: It remains to prove that the pair (X, τ is in S(x, R(z. We first show that X is a martingale in M. First, since Xτ takes values in a compact subset, the weak convergence implies that: E[Xτ = xµ(dx, dz = lim xµ n (dx, dz = X n 8

19 We next prove that X is independent of σ(b s τ. By construction of X, we have that E[Xτ σ(b s τ = E[X τ Z τ, and so we have to prove that E[X τ Z τ = X, i.e. for all bounded continuous function φ: E[(Xτ X φ(z τ = (x X φ(zµ(dx, dz =. By continuity of φ, and the fact that µ is compactly supported, we have that: (x X φ(zµ(dx, dz = lim (x X φ(zµ n (dx, dz cl(o We next compute that: cl(o n + E [ (Xτ n X φ ( [( n+ Z n+ n τ n n+ = E = = cl(o = lim n + E[(Xn τ n n+ X φ(z τ n n+. i= n+ i= X n τ n i X n τ n i φ ( Z τ nn+ n+ E [ {( ( } E τ n i X n τ n i Xτi n φ n Zτ n n+ E [( Xτ n i n i= { ( Xτi n n Eτ n i φ Zτ n n+}. [ ( ( By continuity of Z, we have that E τ n i φ Zτ n n+ = Eτ n i [ φ Zτ n n+, and therefore: E [( { ( [( { ( } Xτ n X n i n τi n Eτ n i φ Zτ n n+} = E X n τ n X n i τi n Eτ n i φ Zτ n n+ = E [ E τ n i { φ ( Zτ n n+ } Eτ n i { X n τ n i X n τ n i } =, where we used the fact that E τ n i [ X n τ n i = X n τ n. This concludes the proof. i Step 4: We finally prove that we have (X +R(Z z τ and {U(Xτ θ +R(Zz τ θ } θ T is uniformly integrable. We shall in fact prove that X τ + R(Zz τ > C dt dp-a.e. for some C >, which ensures that the two previous properties are trivially verified. For that purpose, first notice that since cl(o is a compact subset of int( D, we have the existence of C > such that P(Xτ + R(Z τ > C =, that is equivalent to: [ (X E τ + R(Z τ A > CP[A, for all A F τ measurable. (5.4 9

20 We now show that P[x + R(Z τ > C =. Indeed we have x + R(Z τ = (X + Z τ. Then assume that we have ɛ > such that P [A >, where A := {x + R(Z τ < C ɛ}. Using the fact that X is a martingale, we obtain: [ (X E τ + R(Z [ (x τ A = E + R(Zτ A < (C ɛp[a, which contradicts 5.4. Finally we recall from the choice of τ in Step 2 that τ is smaller than the exit time of the support of µ z, which means in particular that we have Z τ S(C x dt dp-a.s. 6 Appendix: power utility function Our goal is to compute explicitly the function Ū in the context of the power utility function of Section 3.2. Proposition 3.7 then follows immediately from our explicit calculations. The scale function S γ of Y is given up to an affine transformation by S γ (y = sgn( γy γ if γ and S (y = ln(y. Then, the corresponding inverse function is: and R γ (z := (sgn( γz γ whenever sgn( γz R +, for γ, The process Z is the martingale defined by: and R (z := e z for all z R. Z t := Z e γ σbt 2 ( γ2 σ 2t, with Z = sgn( γy γ, for γ, Z t := Z + σb t, with Z = ln(y, for γ =. For notational convenience, we will drop the dependance of R on γ. Proof of Proposition 3.7 We consider separately several cases. (i γ < : Then, the domain of R is (, +. (i- p : We first recall the value of the derivatives with respect to z: z Ū(x, z = γ z γ γ (x + z p γ 2

21 zz Ū(x, z = ( γ z 2γ 2 γ (x + z p [ γ γ (x + z γ pz γ (i-a γ > p: For any x, zz Ū(x, z > for z large enough. Since the domain of this function is (,, and Ū(x, z + when z +, we have Ū (x, = +. So Ū = Ū = +. (i-b γ = p: For x >, zz Ū(x, z > and the same argument as above leads to Ū (x, z = +. For x, zz Ū(x, z and then Ū (x, z = Ū(x, z. We then have Ū (x, z = Ū(x, z x + x>. For z (,, we now focus on the function Ū (, z on ( z γ,. Since Ū = + for x large enough, we have Ū 2 (x, z = + for every (x, z in the domain. So Ū = Ū 2 = + (i-c γ < p: γ leads to zz Ū(x, z so that Ū is concave w.r.t. x and z and then Ū = Ū. γ >. For x, we have zz Ū(x, z so that Ū (x, = Ū(x,. For x >, there exists z(x such that zz Ū(x, z > for z < z(x and zz Ū(x, z for z z(x. Since z Ū(x, z when z +, there exists z(x such that Ū (x, z = U(x + z z Ū(x, z(x for z z(x and Ū (x, z = Ū(x, z for z > z(x. We see that z(x is the unique solution of: Ū(x, z(x U(x = z(x z Ū(x, z(x. i.e. if we denote ξ(x := x z(x γ, then ξ(x is the unique solution of Θ(ξ = where: Θ(ξ := ( + ξ p p ξ γ ( + ξ p. We easily observe that ξ := ξ(x is independant of x and then: ( x Ū p (x, z = Ū(x, z xξ z γ + + zx γ p ξ γ p γ ( + ξ p Notice that xx Ū (x, z on ( z γ, z γ ξ that:. On the interval ( z x Ū (x, z = x p + γ p γ xγ p zξ γ ( + ξ p xx Ū (x, z = px p [ γ ξ xξ >z γ. (γ p(γ p zx γ ξ γ ( + ξ p. p( γ In order to investigate the sign of xx Ū, we introduce the function (ξ := (p + γ(p γ ξ γ ξ γ ( + ξ p, ξ [, ξ, p( γ, +, we compute and search for a solution ξ to the equation (ξ =. The function is non-increasing with ( =. In order to investigate the sign of (ξ, we introduce the function: (x := (p + γ(p γ x( + x p > for all x >. p( γ 2

22 This is clearly a non-increasing continuous and one-to-one function on (,, and we see that the sign of (ξ reduces to the sign of (x under the condition Θ(x =. We are then reduced to the system of non-linear equations: which is immediately seen to be equivalent to: (x = and Θ(x =, (6. ( + ξ p = γ + p γ + ( + ξ p [(γ p ξ ( γ = γ We can see after calculus that the solution of (6. is x = p. Moreover, for a fixed p, we p γ have: G(γ = there is a unique solution to (6., where G(γ := (p γ p (p + γ (2p γ p ( γ. Since G is a non-decreasing continuous and one-to-one function, it admits a unique solution ˆγ p. Moreover, we have that G is negative on γ ˆγ p and positive on γ > ˆγ p. This result gives us that: For γ > ˆγ p, G positive implies (x negative. It means that (ξ is negative, so Ū is not concave in its first variable and admits an inflexion point to be determined. For γ ˆγ p, G negative implies (x positive. This means that (ξ is positive, so Ū is concave in its first variable. We now focus on the case γ > ˆγ p. We are looking for a pair (x, x 2 such that x z γ ξ < x 2 and x maximal such that: Ū (x 2, z Ū (x, z x 2 x = x Ū (x 2, z x Ū (x, z. (6.2 This is the characterization of the concave envelope of Ū w.r.t. x. We observe that this pair exists since x Ū (x, z when x + and x Ū (x, z + when x z γ. An other remark is that for any λ >, we have Ū (λx 2,λ γ z Ū (λx,λ γ z λx 2 λx = λ p Ū (x 2,z Ū (x,z x 2 x and x Ū (λx i, λ γ z = λ p x Ū (x i, z for i {, 2}. We then see that there exists ξ and ξ 2 such that for any (x, z int( D, we have (x, x 2 = ( z γ ξ, z γ ξ 2. Finally we can compute the value of Ū 2 : Ū 2 (x, z =Ū(x, z xξ z γ + Ū (x, z xξ2 z + (x z γ ξ 2 x Ū (z γ ξ 2, z γ + (Ū (z γ ξ 2. z γ <x z γ ξ ξ 2, z 22

23 By construction, Ū 2 is concave w.r.t. x. For the concavity w.r.t. z, we already know that zz Ū 2 out of [ (xξ 2 γ, (xξ 2 γ. We also obtain by tedious calculations that zz Ū 2 on ( (xξ 2 γ, (xξ 2 γ, and that z Ū ( 2 x, (xξ 2 γ x+ Ū ( 2 x, (xξ 2 γ, and z Ū ( 2 x, (xξ γ z+ Ū ( 2 x, (xξ γ, where z (resp z+ corresponds to the left derivative (resp the right derivative with respect to z. (i-2 p = : The derivatives w.r.t. z are: zz Ū(x, z = z Ū(x, z = γ z γ γ (x + z γ, ( γ z 2γ 2 γ (x + z 2 [ γ γ (x + z γ z γ. (i-2a γ : In that situation zz Ū and then Ū = Ū. (i-2b γ > : If x, then zz Ū(x, z and Ū (x, z = Ū(x, z. If x >, there is an inflection point, similarly to the case γ < p, p. We find z(x such that zz Ū(x, z > for z < z(x and zz Ū(x, z for z z(x. Since z Ū(x, z when z +, there exists z(x such that Ū (x, z = U(x + z z Ū(x, z(x for z z(x and Ū (x, z = Ū(x, z for z > z(x. We see that z(x is the unique solution of: Ū(x, z(x U(x = z(x z Ū(x, z(x. i.e. if we denote ξ(x := x z(x γ, then ξ(x is the unique solution of: ln ( + ξ = ξ γ ( + ξ. We easily observe that ξ := ξ(x is independant of x and then: ( Ū (x, z = Ū(x, z xξ z γ + ln(x + zx γ ξ γ γ ( + ξ xξ >z γ. The derivation of Ū 2 is similar to the previous case. Indeed, for x z γ ξ, xx Ū (x, z by definition of U. For x z γ ξ, we have: x Ū (x, z = [ x zx γ 2 ξ γ ( + ξ, xx Ū (x, z = x 2 [ + (2 γzx γ ξ γ ( + ξ. The exact same scheme as the one leading to the system of equations (6. leads to the existence of ˆγ (, such that for γ ˆγ, we have xx Ū, and for γ > ˆγ, there exists an inflexion point. It remains to solve the case γ > ˆγ. We are seeking for a pair (x, x 2 such that x z γ ξ < x 2 with x maximal such that (6.2 is true. By the same arguments, there exists ξ 23

24 ( and ξ 2 such that for any z >, we have (x, x 2 = z γ ξ, z γ ξ 2 and: Ū 2 (x, z =Ū(x, z xξ z γ + Ū (x, z xξ2 z γ (z + (Ū γ, z + (x z γ (z x Ū γ, z ξ 2 The concavity in z is easily obtained by direct calculations. (ii γ = : The admissible domain of R is (,. (ii- p : We have: x Ū(x, z = e z (x + e z p, xx Ū(x, z = e z (x + e z p [(x + e z pe z. ξ 2 ξ 2. z γ <x z γ ξ ξ 2 (ii-a p < : If x, then zz Ū(x, z > and then since z is unbounded ( z R, x + e z > if x, and Ū(x, is strictly convex and Ū(x, z + when z +, we have Ū (x, z = +. For x <, we have zz Ū(x, z for z ln ( p x and zz Ū(x, z > for z > ( p x, and the same argument leads to Ū (x, z = +. (ii-b p > : If x, then zz Ū(x, z and Ū (x, z = Ū(x, z. For x >, we have ( zz Ū(x, z > for z < ln x p ( and zz Ū(x, z for x ln x p. Since Ū(x, z U(x > when z, and Ū(x, z when z +, we have that the concave p envelope is always equal to the limit when z +, i.e. Ū (x, z =. So: p Ū (x, z = Ū(x, z x + p x>. In particular we see that Ū is not continuous. The calculation of Ū 2 is easier than in the previous cases. For a fixed z R. We study Ū (, z on ( e z,. Ū (, z is non decreasing, constant on [, and concave on ( e z,, with Ū ( e z, z =. So there exists x ( e z, such that x Ū (x, z = Ū (,z Ū (x,z x, and Ū 2 (, z is linear on ( x, and Ū 2 (x, z = Ū (x, z elsewhere. x is easily given by x = ez and then: p Ū 2 (x, z =Ū(x, z x ez p p x ( ( + Ū ( ez p, z + (x + ez e pz p p p x ( ez,. p The partial concavity w.r.t. z is then trivial and we have Ū = Ū 2. (ii-2 p = : we have: z Ū(x, z = ( + xe z, 24

25 zz Ū(x, z = xe z ( + xe z 2. For x >, we have zz Ū(x, z > and then as above, since Ū(x, z when z, we have Ū (x, z =. For x, we have zz Ū(x, z and then Ū (x, z = ū(x, z. Summing up: Ū (x, z = Ū(x, z x + x>. As a consequence, we see that: Ū 2 = +. (iii γ > : The admissible domain of R is (,. For any p, the partial derivatives w.r.t. z are given by: z Ū(x, z = γ ( z γ γ (x + ( z p γ, 2γ zz Ū(x, z = ( z γ (x + ( z p [ γ γ (x + ( z γ p ( z γ. (γ 2 (iii- p : For any x, zz Ū(x, z > for z large enough and Ū(x, z + when z so that Ū (x, z = +. (iii-2 < p < γ: For x, we have z Ū(x, z when z and Ū(x, z p when z, so Ū (x, z =. p ( γ γ, ( For x <, for z x γ γ, zz Ū(x, z and for z > x zz Ū(x, z >. p γ p γ Since Ū(x, z when z, there exists z p such that z z Ū(x, z = Ū(x, z p. Similarly to the case γ <, z verifies ( z γ = xξ with ξ = γ. γ p We then have: Ū (x, z =Ū(x, z { xξ >( z γ } + p {x } + z ( x γ p (p p (γ p γ p (γ γ {< xξ ( z γ } The concavity of Ū w.r.t. x is then straightforward. (iii-3 p γ: For x, zz Ū(x, z and Ū (x, z = Ū(x, z. For x >, there is an inflexion point. Now since z Ū(x, z when z, we have Ū (x, z =. So: p Ū (x, z = Ū(x, z x + p x>. We now search Ū 2. For any z (,, Ū (, z is concave on ( ( z γ, and constant on [,, and discontinuous at x =. We are looking for x ( ( z γ, such that: Ū (, z Ū(x, z = x x Ū(x, z. 25

26 The solution is given by x = p p ( z γ and we have: Ū 2 (x, z =Ū(x, z x< p p ( z γ + p x> ( ( + ( z p γ + x + p p ( z γ p p ( z p γ p p ( z γ. x< The concavity of Ū 2 w.r.t. z is easily verified. References [ P. Billingsley (999: Convergence of Probability Measures, Wiley Series in Probability and Statistics. [2 B. Bouchard and N. Touzi (2: Weak Dynamic Programming Principle for Viscosity Solutions. SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, 49, 3, [3 A.K. Dixit and R.S. Pindyck (994: Investment under uncertainty. Princeton Univ. Press. [4 J. Evans, V. Henderson and D. Hobson (28: Optimal timing for an indivisible asset sale. Mathematical Finance, 8, [5 W.H. Fleming and H.M. Soner (986: Controlled Markov Processes and Viscosity Solutions, Applications of Mathematics 25. Springer-Verlag, New York. [6 V. Henderson (27: Valuing the option to invest in an incomplete market. Mathematics and Financial Economics,, [7 V. Henderson and D. Hobson (28: An explicit solution for an optimal stopping/optimal control problem which models an asset sale. Annals of Applied Probability 8(5, [8 V. Henderson and D. Hobson (23: Risk aversion, indivisible timing options and gambling, Operations Research, 6,, [9 D. Hobson (2: The skorokhod embedding problem and model-independent bounds for option prices, Paris-Princeton Lectures on Mathematical Finance, Lecture Notes in Mathematics, Springer. [ I. Monroe (972: On embedding right continuous martingale in Brownian motions, Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 43, [ N. Touzi (22: Optimal Stochastic Control, Stochastic Target Problems, and Backward SDE, Fields Institute Monographs, Vol

A new approach for investment performance measurement. 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009

A new approach for investment performance measurement. 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009 A new approach for investment performance measurement 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009 Thaleia Zariphopoulou University of Oxford, Oxford-Man Institute and The University of Texas at Austin 1 Performance

More information

Optimal exit strategies for investment projects. 7th AMaMeF and Swissquote Conference

Optimal exit strategies for investment projects. 7th AMaMeF and Swissquote Conference Optimal exit strategies for investment projects Simone Scotti Université Paris Diderot Laboratoire de Probabilité et Modèles Aléatories Joint work with : Etienne Chevalier, Université d Evry Vathana Ly

More information

The Azéma-Yor Embedding in Non-Singular Diffusions

The Azéma-Yor Embedding in Non-Singular Diffusions Stochastic Process. Appl. Vol. 96, No. 2, 2001, 305-312 Research Report No. 406, 1999, Dept. Theoret. Statist. Aarhus The Azéma-Yor Embedding in Non-Singular Diffusions J. L. Pedersen and G. Peskir Let

More information

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Tim Leung 1, Qingshuo Song 2, and Jie Yang 3 1 Columbia University, New York, USA; leung@ieor.columbia.edu 2 City

More information

Multi-dimensional Stochastic Singular Control Via Dynkin Game and Dirichlet Form

Multi-dimensional Stochastic Singular Control Via Dynkin Game and Dirichlet Form Multi-dimensional Stochastic Singular Control Via Dynkin Game and Dirichlet Form Yipeng Yang * Under the supervision of Dr. Michael Taksar Department of Mathematics University of Missouri-Columbia Oct

More information

THE ASYMPTOTIC ELASTICITY OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS 1

THE ASYMPTOTIC ELASTICITY OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS 1 The Annals of Applied Probability 1999, Vol. 9, No. 3, 94 95 THE ASYMPTOTIC ELASTICITY OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS 1 By D. Kramkov 2 and W. Schachermayer Steklov Mathematical

More information

Necessary Conditions for the Existence of Utility Maximizing Strategies under Transaction Costs

Necessary Conditions for the Existence of Utility Maximizing Strategies under Transaction Costs Necessary Conditions for the Existence of Utility Maximizing Strategies under Transaction Costs Paolo Guasoni Boston University and University of Pisa Walter Schachermayer Vienna University of Technology

More information

Exercises in stochastic analysis

Exercises in stochastic analysis Exercises in stochastic analysis Franco Flandoli, Mario Maurelli, Dario Trevisan The exercises with a P are those which have been done totally or partially) in the previous lectures; the exercises with

More information

A Model of Optimal Portfolio Selection under. Liquidity Risk and Price Impact

A Model of Optimal Portfolio Selection under. Liquidity Risk and Price Impact A Model of Optimal Portfolio Selection under Liquidity Risk and Price Impact Huyên PHAM Workshop on PDE and Mathematical Finance KTH, Stockholm, August 15, 2005 Laboratoire de Probabilités et Modèles Aléatoires

More information

On the Multi-Dimensional Controller and Stopper Games

On the Multi-Dimensional Controller and Stopper Games On the Multi-Dimensional Controller and Stopper Games Joint work with Yu-Jui Huang University of Michigan, Ann Arbor June 7, 2012 Outline Introduction 1 Introduction 2 3 4 5 Consider a zero-sum controller-and-stopper

More information

Thomas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover

Thomas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover Optimal long term investment under model ambiguity Optimal long term investment under model ambiguity homas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover knispel@stochastik.uni-hannover.de AnStAp0 Vienna, July

More information

of space-time diffusions

of space-time diffusions Optimal investment for all time horizons and Martin boundary of space-time diffusions Sergey Nadtochiy and Michael Tehranchi October 5, 2012 Abstract This paper is concerned with the axiomatic foundation

More information

Minimal Sufficient Conditions for a Primal Optimizer in Nonsmooth Utility Maximization

Minimal Sufficient Conditions for a Primal Optimizer in Nonsmooth Utility Maximization Finance and Stochastics manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) Minimal Sufficient Conditions for a Primal Optimizer in Nonsmooth Utility Maximization Nicholas Westray Harry Zheng. Received: date

More information

Dynamic Risk Measures and Nonlinear Expectations with Markov Chain noise

Dynamic Risk Measures and Nonlinear Expectations with Markov Chain noise Dynamic Risk Measures and Nonlinear Expectations with Markov Chain noise Robert J. Elliott 1 Samuel N. Cohen 2 1 Department of Commerce, University of South Australia 2 Mathematical Insitute, University

More information

1. Stochastic Processes and filtrations

1. Stochastic Processes and filtrations 1. Stochastic Processes and 1. Stoch. pr., A stochastic process (X t ) t T is a collection of random variables on (Ω, F) with values in a measurable space (S, S), i.e., for all t, In our case X t : Ω S

More information

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3 Brownian Motion Contents 1 Definition 2 1.1 Brownian Motion................................. 2 1.2 Wiener measure.................................. 3 2 Construction 4 2.1 Gaussian process.................................

More information

Reflected Brownian Motion

Reflected Brownian Motion Chapter 6 Reflected Brownian Motion Often we encounter Diffusions in regions with boundary. If the process can reach the boundary from the interior in finite time with positive probability we need to decide

More information

HJB equations. Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance January 10, 2011

HJB equations. Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance January 10, 2011 Department of Probability and Mathematical Statistics Faculty of Mathematics and Physics, Charles University in Prague petrasek@karlin.mff.cuni.cz Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance

More information

Quasi-sure Stochastic Analysis through Aggregation

Quasi-sure Stochastic Analysis through Aggregation Quasi-sure Stochastic Analysis through Aggregation H. Mete Soner Nizar Touzi Jianfeng Zhang March 7, 21 Abstract This paper is on developing stochastic analysis simultaneously under a general family of

More information

Short-time expansions for close-to-the-money options under a Lévy jump model with stochastic volatility

Short-time expansions for close-to-the-money options under a Lévy jump model with stochastic volatility Short-time expansions for close-to-the-money options under a Lévy jump model with stochastic volatility José Enrique Figueroa-López 1 1 Department of Statistics Purdue University Statistics, Jump Processes,

More information

Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process

Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process Lecture 17: Brownian motion as a Markov process 1 of 14 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 2015 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process Brownian motion is

More information

Liquidity risk and optimal dividend/investment strategies

Liquidity risk and optimal dividend/investment strategies Liquidity risk and optimal dividend/investment strategies Vathana LY VATH Laboratoire de Mathématiques et Modélisation d Evry ENSIIE and Université d Evry Joint work with E. Chevalier and M. Gaigi ICASQF,

More information

Proving the Regularity of the Minimal Probability of Ruin via a Game of Stopping and Control

Proving the Regularity of the Minimal Probability of Ruin via a Game of Stopping and Control Proving the Regularity of the Minimal Probability of Ruin via a Game of Stopping and Control Erhan Bayraktar University of Michigan joint work with Virginia R. Young, University of Michigan K αρλoβασi,

More information

On the dual problem of utility maximization

On the dual problem of utility maximization On the dual problem of utility maximization Yiqing LIN Joint work with L. GU and J. YANG University of Vienna Sept. 2nd 2015 Workshop Advanced methods in financial mathematics Angers 1 Introduction Basic

More information

SEPARABLE TERM STRUCTURES AND THE MAXIMAL DEGREE PROBLEM. 1. Introduction This paper discusses arbitrage-free separable term structure (STS) models

SEPARABLE TERM STRUCTURES AND THE MAXIMAL DEGREE PROBLEM. 1. Introduction This paper discusses arbitrage-free separable term structure (STS) models SEPARABLE TERM STRUCTURES AND THE MAXIMAL DEGREE PROBLEM DAMIR FILIPOVIĆ Abstract. This paper discusses separable term structure diffusion models in an arbitrage-free environment. Using general consistency

More information

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint that the ON PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION UNDER \DRAWDOWN" CONSTRAINTS JAKSA CVITANIC IOANNIS KARATZAS y March 6, 994 Abstract We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the wealth

More information

On the submartingale / supermartingale property of diffusions in natural scale

On the submartingale / supermartingale property of diffusions in natural scale On the submartingale / supermartingale property of diffusions in natural scale Alexander Gushchin Mikhail Urusov Mihail Zervos November 13, 214 Abstract Kotani 5 has characterised the martingale property

More information

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY Elementary properties of convex functions

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY Elementary properties of convex functions Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Ec 181 KC Border Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY 2018 2019 Topic 6: Convex functions I 6.1 Elementary properties of convex functions We may occasionally

More information

Probability and Measure

Probability and Measure Part II Year 2018 2017 2016 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2018 84 Paper 4, Section II 26J Let (X, A) be a measurable space. Let T : X X be a measurable map, and µ a probability

More information

Worst Case Portfolio Optimization and HJB-Systems

Worst Case Portfolio Optimization and HJB-Systems Worst Case Portfolio Optimization and HJB-Systems Ralf Korn and Mogens Steffensen Abstract We formulate a portfolio optimization problem as a game where the investor chooses a portfolio and his opponent,

More information

Filtrations, Markov Processes and Martingales. Lectures on Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus, Braunschweig, Lecture 3: The Lévy-Itô Decomposition

Filtrations, Markov Processes and Martingales. Lectures on Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus, Braunschweig, Lecture 3: The Lévy-Itô Decomposition Filtrations, Markov Processes and Martingales Lectures on Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus, Braunschweig, Lecture 3: The Lévy-Itô Decomposition David pplebaum Probability and Statistics Department,

More information

On continuous time contract theory

On continuous time contract theory Ecole Polytechnique, France Journée de rentrée du CMAP, 3 octobre, 218 Outline 1 2 Semimartingale measures on the canonical space Random horizon 2nd order backward SDEs (Static) Principal-Agent Problem

More information

Optimal portfolio strategies under partial information with expert opinions

Optimal portfolio strategies under partial information with expert opinions 1 / 35 Optimal portfolio strategies under partial information with expert opinions Ralf Wunderlich Brandenburg University of Technology Cottbus, Germany Joint work with Rüdiger Frey Research Seminar WU

More information

On the monotonicity principle of optimal Skorokhod embedding problem

On the monotonicity principle of optimal Skorokhod embedding problem On the monotonicity principle of optimal Skorokhod embedding problem Gaoyue Guo Xiaolu Tan Nizar Touzi June 10, 2015 Abstract This is a continuation of our accompanying paper [18]. We provide an alternative

More information

LECTURE 2: LOCAL TIME FOR BROWNIAN MOTION

LECTURE 2: LOCAL TIME FOR BROWNIAN MOTION LECTURE 2: LOCAL TIME FOR BROWNIAN MOTION We will define local time for one-dimensional Brownian motion, and deduce some of its properties. We will then use the generalized Ray-Knight theorem proved in

More information

Fundamental Inequalities, Convergence and the Optional Stopping Theorem for Continuous-Time Martingales

Fundamental Inequalities, Convergence and the Optional Stopping Theorem for Continuous-Time Martingales Fundamental Inequalities, Convergence and the Optional Stopping Theorem for Continuous-Time Martingales Prakash Balachandran Department of Mathematics Duke University April 2, 2008 1 Review of Discrete-Time

More information

1: PROBABILITY REVIEW

1: PROBABILITY REVIEW 1: PROBABILITY REVIEW Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 1: Probability Review 1 / 56 Outline We will review the following

More information

The first order quasi-linear PDEs

The first order quasi-linear PDEs Chapter 2 The first order quasi-linear PDEs The first order quasi-linear PDEs have the following general form: F (x, u, Du) = 0, (2.1) where x = (x 1, x 2,, x 3 ) R n, u = u(x), Du is the gradient of u.

More information

Optimal Stopping Problems and American Options

Optimal Stopping Problems and American Options Optimal Stopping Problems and American Options Nadia Uys A dissertation submitted to the Faculty of Science, University of the Witwatersrand, in fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Master

More information

Green s Functions and Distributions

Green s Functions and Distributions CHAPTER 9 Green s Functions and Distributions 9.1. Boundary Value Problems We would like to study, and solve if possible, boundary value problems such as the following: (1.1) u = f in U u = g on U, where

More information

Nonlinear representation, backward SDEs, and application to the Principal-Agent problem

Nonlinear representation, backward SDEs, and application to the Principal-Agent problem Nonlinear representation, backward SDEs, and application to the Principal-Agent problem Ecole Polytechnique, France April 4, 218 Outline The Principal-Agent problem Formulation 1 The Principal-Agent problem

More information

Stability of Stochastic Differential Equations

Stability of Stochastic Differential Equations Lyapunov stability theory for ODEs s Stability of Stochastic Differential Equations Part 1: Introduction Department of Mathematics and Statistics University of Strathclyde Glasgow, G1 1XH December 2010

More information

QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE

QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE Research Paper 241 December 2008 Viability of Markets with an Infinite Number of Assets Constantinos Kardaras ISSN 1441-8010 VIABILITY

More information

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs Lecture Notes by Walter Schachermayer Nachdiplom-Vorlesung, ETH Zürich, WS 15/16 1 Models on Finite Probability Spaces In this section we consider a stock price

More information

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING 218. HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROF. YURI BAKHTIN Instructions. You are allowed to work on solutions in groups, but you are required to write up solutions on your own. Please

More information

ON THE POLICY IMPROVEMENT ALGORITHM IN CONTINUOUS TIME

ON THE POLICY IMPROVEMENT ALGORITHM IN CONTINUOUS TIME ON THE POLICY IMPROVEMENT ALGORITHM IN CONTINUOUS TIME SAUL D. JACKA AND ALEKSANDAR MIJATOVIĆ Abstract. We develop a general approach to the Policy Improvement Algorithm (PIA) for stochastic control problems

More information

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING 15. HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROF. YURI BAKHTIN Instructions. You are allowed to work on solutions in groups, but you are required to write up solutions on your own. Please

More information

Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales

Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales Lecture 21: Representations of Martingales 1 of 11 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 215 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales Right-continuous inverses Let

More information

4.6 Example of non-uniqueness.

4.6 Example of non-uniqueness. 66 CHAPTER 4. STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS. 4.6 Example of non-uniqueness. If we try to construct a solution to the martingale problem in dimension coresponding to a(x) = x α with

More information

Some aspects of the mean-field stochastic target problem

Some aspects of the mean-field stochastic target problem Some aspects of the mean-field stochastic target problem Quenched Mass ransport of Particles owards a arget Boualem Djehiche KH Royal Institute of echnology, Stockholm (Joint work with B. Bouchard and

More information

A D VA N C E D P R O B A B I L - I T Y

A D VA N C E D P R O B A B I L - I T Y A N D R E W T U L L O C H A D VA N C E D P R O B A B I L - I T Y T R I N I T Y C O L L E G E T H E U N I V E R S I T Y O F C A M B R I D G E Contents 1 Conditional Expectation 5 1.1 Discrete Case 6 1.2

More information

Laplace s Equation. Chapter Mean Value Formulas

Laplace s Equation. Chapter Mean Value Formulas Chapter 1 Laplace s Equation Let be an open set in R n. A function u C 2 () is called harmonic in if it satisfies Laplace s equation n (1.1) u := D ii u = 0 in. i=1 A function u C 2 () is called subharmonic

More information

Prof. Erhan Bayraktar (University of Michigan)

Prof. Erhan Bayraktar (University of Michigan) September 17, 2012 KAP 414 2:15 PM- 3:15 PM Prof. (University of Michigan) Abstract: We consider a zero-sum stochastic differential controller-and-stopper game in which the state process is a controlled

More information

(6, 4) Is there arbitrage in this market? If so, find all arbitrages. If not, find all pricing kernels.

(6, 4) Is there arbitrage in this market? If so, find all arbitrages. If not, find all pricing kernels. Advanced Financial Models Example sheet - Michaelmas 208 Michael Tehranchi Problem. Consider a two-asset model with prices given by (P, P 2 ) (3, 9) /4 (4, 6) (6, 8) /4 /2 (6, 4) Is there arbitrage in

More information

Order book resilience, price manipulation, and the positive portfolio problem

Order book resilience, price manipulation, and the positive portfolio problem Order book resilience, price manipulation, and the positive portfolio problem Alexander Schied Mannheim University Workshop on New Directions in Financial Mathematics Institute for Pure and Applied Mathematics,

More information

n E(X t T n = lim X s Tn = X s

n E(X t T n = lim X s Tn = X s Stochastic Calculus Example sheet - Lent 15 Michael Tehranchi Problem 1. Let X be a local martingale. Prove that X is a uniformly integrable martingale if and only X is of class D. Solution 1. If If direction:

More information

OPTIMAL SOLUTIONS TO STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL INCLUSIONS

OPTIMAL SOLUTIONS TO STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL INCLUSIONS APPLICATIONES MATHEMATICAE 29,4 (22), pp. 387 398 Mariusz Michta (Zielona Góra) OPTIMAL SOLUTIONS TO STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL INCLUSIONS Abstract. A martingale problem approach is used first to analyze

More information

UTILITY OPTIMIZATION IN A FINITE SCENARIO SETTING

UTILITY OPTIMIZATION IN A FINITE SCENARIO SETTING UTILITY OPTIMIZATION IN A FINITE SCENARIO SETTING J. TEICHMANN Abstract. We introduce the main concepts of duality theory for utility optimization in a setting of finitely many economic scenarios. 1. Utility

More information

Uniformly Uniformly-ergodic Markov chains and BSDEs

Uniformly Uniformly-ergodic Markov chains and BSDEs Uniformly Uniformly-ergodic Markov chains and BSDEs Samuel N. Cohen Mathematical Institute, University of Oxford (Based on joint work with Ying Hu, Robert Elliott, Lukas Szpruch) Centre Henri Lebesgue,

More information

1 Brownian Local Time

1 Brownian Local Time 1 Brownian Local Time We first begin by defining the space and variables for Brownian local time. Let W t be a standard 1-D Wiener process. We know that for the set, {t : W t = } P (µ{t : W t = } = ) =

More information

Lecture 22 Girsanov s Theorem

Lecture 22 Girsanov s Theorem Lecture 22: Girsanov s Theorem of 8 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 25 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 22 Girsanov s Theorem An example Consider a finite Gaussian random walk X n = n

More information

OPTIMAL STOPPING OF A BROWNIAN BRIDGE

OPTIMAL STOPPING OF A BROWNIAN BRIDGE OPTIMAL STOPPING OF A BROWNIAN BRIDGE ERIK EKSTRÖM AND HENRIK WANNTORP Abstract. We study several optimal stopping problems in which the gains process is a Brownian bridge or a functional of a Brownian

More information

Duality and Utility Maximization

Duality and Utility Maximization Duality and Utility Maximization Bachelor Thesis Niklas A. Pfister July 11, 2013 Advisor: Prof. Dr. Halil Mete Soner Department of Mathematics, ETH Zürich Abstract This thesis explores the problem of maximizing

More information

Sensitivity analysis of the expected utility maximization problem with respect to model perturbations

Sensitivity analysis of the expected utility maximization problem with respect to model perturbations Sensitivity analysis of the expected utility maximization problem with respect to model perturbations Mihai Sîrbu, The University of Texas at Austin based on joint work with Oleksii Mostovyi University

More information

Minimization of ruin probabilities by investment under transaction costs

Minimization of ruin probabilities by investment under transaction costs Minimization of ruin probabilities by investment under transaction costs Stefan Thonhauser DSA, HEC, Université de Lausanne 13 th Scientific Day, Bonn, 3.4.214 Outline Introduction Risk models and controls

More information

Risk-Sensitive Control with HARA Utility

Risk-Sensitive Control with HARA Utility IEEE TRANSACTIONS ON AUTOMATIC CONTROL, VOL. 46, NO. 4, APRIL 2001 563 Risk-Sensitive Control with HARA Utility Andrew E. B. Lim Xun Yu Zhou, Senior Member, IEEE Abstract In this paper, a control methodology

More information

A MODEL FOR THE LONG-TERM OPTIMAL CAPACITY LEVEL OF AN INVESTMENT PROJECT

A MODEL FOR THE LONG-TERM OPTIMAL CAPACITY LEVEL OF AN INVESTMENT PROJECT A MODEL FOR HE LONG-ERM OPIMAL CAPACIY LEVEL OF AN INVESMEN PROJEC ARNE LØKKA AND MIHAIL ZERVOS Abstract. We consider an investment project that produces a single commodity. he project s operation yields

More information

Question 1. The correct answers are: (a) (2) (b) (1) (c) (2) (d) (3) (e) (2) (f) (1) (g) (2) (h) (1)

Question 1. The correct answers are: (a) (2) (b) (1) (c) (2) (d) (3) (e) (2) (f) (1) (g) (2) (h) (1) Question 1 The correct answers are: a 2 b 1 c 2 d 3 e 2 f 1 g 2 h 1 Question 2 a Any probability measure Q equivalent to P on F 2 can be described by Q[{x 1, x 2 }] := q x1 q x1,x 2, 1 where q x1, q x1,x

More information

are Banach algebras. f(x)g(x) max Example 7.4. Similarly, A = L and A = l with the pointwise multiplication

are Banach algebras. f(x)g(x) max Example 7.4. Similarly, A = L and A = l with the pointwise multiplication 7. Banach algebras Definition 7.1. A is called a Banach algebra (with unit) if: (1) A is a Banach space; (2) There is a multiplication A A A that has the following properties: (xy)z = x(yz), (x + y)z =

More information

Convex Functions and Optimization

Convex Functions and Optimization Chapter 5 Convex Functions and Optimization 5.1 Convex Functions Our next topic is that of convex functions. Again, we will concentrate on the context of a map f : R n R although the situation can be generalized

More information

Portfolio Optimization in discrete time

Portfolio Optimization in discrete time Portfolio Optimization in discrete time Wolfgang J. Runggaldier Dipartimento di Matematica Pura ed Applicata Universitá di Padova, Padova http://www.math.unipd.it/runggaldier/index.html Abstract he paper

More information

Skorokhod Embeddings In Bounded Time

Skorokhod Embeddings In Bounded Time Skorokhod Embeddings In Bounded Time Stefan Ankirchner Institute for Applied Mathematics University of Bonn Endenicher Allee 6 D-535 Bonn ankirchner@hcm.uni-bonn.de Philipp Strack Bonn Graduate School

More information

STOCHASTIC PERRON S METHOD AND VERIFICATION WITHOUT SMOOTHNESS USING VISCOSITY COMPARISON: OBSTACLE PROBLEMS AND DYNKIN GAMES

STOCHASTIC PERRON S METHOD AND VERIFICATION WITHOUT SMOOTHNESS USING VISCOSITY COMPARISON: OBSTACLE PROBLEMS AND DYNKIN GAMES STOCHASTIC PERRON S METHOD AND VERIFICATION WITHOUT SMOOTHNESS USING VISCOSITY COMPARISON: OBSTACLE PROBLEMS AND DYNKIN GAMES ERHAN BAYRAKTAR AND MIHAI SÎRBU Abstract. We adapt the Stochastic Perron s

More information

Optimal Skorokhod embedding under finitely-many marginal constraints

Optimal Skorokhod embedding under finitely-many marginal constraints Optimal Skorokhod embedding under finitely-many marginal constraints Gaoyue Guo Xiaolu Tan Nizar Touzi June 10, 2015 Abstract The Skorokhod embedding problem aims to represent a given probability measure

More information

Constrained Optimal Stopping Problems

Constrained Optimal Stopping Problems University of Bath SAMBa EPSRC CDT Thesis Formulation Report For the Degree of MRes in Statistical Applied Mathematics Author: Benjamin A. Robinson Supervisor: Alexander M. G. Cox September 9, 016 Abstract

More information

Convergence of Feller Processes

Convergence of Feller Processes Chapter 15 Convergence of Feller Processes This chapter looks at the convergence of sequences of Feller processes to a iting process. Section 15.1 lays some ground work concerning weak convergence of processes

More information

Minimal Supersolutions of Backward Stochastic Differential Equations and Robust Hedging

Minimal Supersolutions of Backward Stochastic Differential Equations and Robust Hedging Minimal Supersolutions of Backward Stochastic Differential Equations and Robust Hedging SAMUEL DRAPEAU Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin BSDEs, Numerics and Finance Oxford July 2, 2012 joint work with GREGOR

More information

p 1 ( Y p dp) 1/p ( X p dp) 1 1 p

p 1 ( Y p dp) 1/p ( X p dp) 1 1 p Doob s inequality Let X(t) be a right continuous submartingale with respect to F(t), t 1 P(sup s t X(s) λ) 1 λ {sup s t X(s) λ} X + (t)dp 2 For 1 < p

More information

VISCOSITY SOLUTIONS. We follow Han and Lin, Elliptic Partial Differential Equations, 5.

VISCOSITY SOLUTIONS. We follow Han and Lin, Elliptic Partial Differential Equations, 5. VISCOSITY SOLUTIONS PETER HINTZ We follow Han and Lin, Elliptic Partial Differential Equations, 5. 1. Motivation Throughout, we will assume that Ω R n is a bounded and connected domain and that a ij C(Ω)

More information

Optimal stopping for non-linear expectations Part I

Optimal stopping for non-linear expectations Part I Stochastic Processes and their Applications 121 (2011) 185 211 www.elsevier.com/locate/spa Optimal stopping for non-linear expectations Part I Erhan Bayraktar, Song Yao Department of Mathematics, University

More information

STAT 331. Martingale Central Limit Theorem and Related Results

STAT 331. Martingale Central Limit Theorem and Related Results STAT 331 Martingale Central Limit Theorem and Related Results In this unit we discuss a version of the martingale central limit theorem, which states that under certain conditions, a sum of orthogonal

More information

Deterministic Dynamic Programming

Deterministic Dynamic Programming Deterministic Dynamic Programming 1 Value Function Consider the following optimal control problem in Mayer s form: V (t 0, x 0 ) = inf u U J(t 1, x(t 1 )) (1) subject to ẋ(t) = f(t, x(t), u(t)), x(t 0

More information

Notes on Recursive Utility. Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in

Notes on Recursive Utility. Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in Notes on Recursive Utility Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in Section 1 (or Chapter 29, LeRoy & Werner, 2nd Ed.) Let u st be the continuation utility at s t. That

More information

The priority option: the value of being a leader in complete and incomplete markets.

The priority option: the value of being a leader in complete and incomplete markets. s. a leader in s. Mathematics and Statistics - McMaster University Joint work with Vincent Leclère (École de Ponts) Eidgenössische Technische Hochschule Zürich, December 09, 2010 s. 1 2 3 4 s. Combining

More information

Peacocks nearby: approximating sequences of measures

Peacocks nearby: approximating sequences of measures Peacocks nearby: approximating sequences of measures Stefan Gerhold TU Wien sgerhold@fam.tuwien.ac.at I. Cetin Gülüm TU Wien ismail.cetin.gueluem@gmx.at October 2, 2017 Abstract A peacock is a family of

More information

Lecture 5. If we interpret the index n 0 as time, then a Markov chain simply requires that the future depends only on the present and not on the past.

Lecture 5. If we interpret the index n 0 as time, then a Markov chain simply requires that the future depends only on the present and not on the past. 1 Markov chain: definition Lecture 5 Definition 1.1 Markov chain] A sequence of random variables (X n ) n 0 taking values in a measurable state space (S, S) is called a (discrete time) Markov chain, if

More information

Technical Results on Regular Preferences and Demand

Technical Results on Regular Preferences and Demand Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Technical Results on Regular Preferences and Demand KC Border Revised Fall 2011; Winter 2017 Preferences For the purposes of this note, a preference relation

More information

An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control

An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control Vasile Staicu University of Aveiro UNICA, May 2018 Vasile Staicu (University of Aveiro) An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control UNICA, May 2018

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 24 Sep 2018

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 24 Sep 2018 A short note on Anticipative portfolio optimization B. D Auria a,b,1,, J.-A. Salmerón a,1 a Dpto. Estadística, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid. Avda. de la Universidad 3, 8911, Leganés (Madrid Spain b

More information

2.3. The heat equation. A function u(x, t) solves the heat equation if (with σ>0)

2.3. The heat equation. A function u(x, t) solves the heat equation if (with σ>0) 12 VOLKER BETZ 2.3. The heat equation. A function u(x, t) solves the heat equation if (with σ>) (2.1) t u 1 2 σ2 u =. In the simplest case, (2.1) is supposed to hold for all x R n, and all t>, and there

More information

1 Lyapunov theory of stability

1 Lyapunov theory of stability M.Kawski, APM 581 Diff Equns Intro to Lyapunov theory. November 15, 29 1 1 Lyapunov theory of stability Introduction. Lyapunov s second (or direct) method provides tools for studying (asymptotic) stability

More information

A Barrier Version of the Russian Option

A Barrier Version of the Russian Option A Barrier Version of the Russian Option L. A. Shepp, A. N. Shiryaev, A. Sulem Rutgers University; shepp@stat.rutgers.edu Steklov Mathematical Institute; shiryaev@mi.ras.ru INRIA- Rocquencourt; agnes.sulem@inria.fr

More information

STOCHASTIC ANALYSIS, CONTROLLED DYNAMICAL SYSTEMS AN APPLICATIONS

STOCHASTIC ANALYSIS, CONTROLLED DYNAMICAL SYSTEMS AN APPLICATIONS STOCHASTIC ANALYSIS, CONTROLLED DYNAMICAL SYSTEMS AN APPLICATIONS Jena, March 2015 Monique Jeanblanc, LaMME, Université d Évry-Val-D Essonne Enlargement of filtration in discrete time http://upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/5/5a/dragon.jena.jpg/800px-dragon.jena.jpg

More information

Solution for Problem 7.1. We argue by contradiction. If the limit were not infinite, then since τ M (ω) is nondecreasing we would have

Solution for Problem 7.1. We argue by contradiction. If the limit were not infinite, then since τ M (ω) is nondecreasing we would have 362 Problem Hints and Solutions sup g n (ω, t) g(ω, t) sup g(ω, s) g(ω, t) µ n (ω). t T s,t: s t 1/n By the uniform continuity of t g(ω, t) on [, T], one has for each ω that µ n (ω) as n. Two applications

More information

Optimal Stopping under Adverse Nonlinear Expectation and Related Games

Optimal Stopping under Adverse Nonlinear Expectation and Related Games Optimal Stopping under Adverse Nonlinear Expectation and Related Games Marcel Nutz Jianfeng Zhang First version: December 7, 2012. This version: July 21, 2014 Abstract We study the existence of optimal

More information

Random G -Expectations

Random G -Expectations Random G -Expectations Marcel Nutz ETH Zurich New advances in Backward SDEs for nancial engineering applications Tamerza, Tunisia, 28.10.2010 Marcel Nutz (ETH) Random G-Expectations 1 / 17 Outline 1 Random

More information

Some SDEs with distributional drift Part I : General calculus. Flandoli, Franco; Russo, Francesco; Wolf, Jochen

Some SDEs with distributional drift Part I : General calculus. Flandoli, Franco; Russo, Francesco; Wolf, Jochen Title Author(s) Some SDEs with distributional drift Part I : General calculus Flandoli, Franco; Russo, Francesco; Wolf, Jochen Citation Osaka Journal of Mathematics. 4() P.493-P.54 Issue Date 3-6 Text

More information

On the martingales obtained by an extension due to Saisho, Tanemura and Yor of Pitman s theorem

On the martingales obtained by an extension due to Saisho, Tanemura and Yor of Pitman s theorem On the martingales obtained by an extension due to Saisho, Tanemura and Yor of Pitman s theorem Koichiro TAKAOKA Dept of Applied Physics, Tokyo Institute of Technology Abstract M Yor constructed a family

More information

Optimal investment with high-watermark fee in a multi-dimensional jump diffusion model

Optimal investment with high-watermark fee in a multi-dimensional jump diffusion model Optimal investment with high-watermark fee in a multi-dimensional jump diffusion model Karel Janeček Zheng Li Mihai Sîrbu August 2, 218 Abstract This paper studies the problem of optimal investment and

More information