LM Test of Neglected Correlated Random E ects and Its Application

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "LM Test of Neglected Correlated Random E ects and Its Application"

Transcription

1 LM Test of Neglected Correlated Random E ects and Its Application Jinyong Hahn UCLA Hyungsik Roger Moon USC May, 4 Connan Snider UCLA Introduction Econometric model speci cation is usually tested by exploiting one of the three principles, including (i) the Wald test, which is based on the asymptotic distribution of parameter estimates; (ii) the Likelihood Ratio (LR) test; and (iii) the Lagrange Multiplier (LM) procedure, which is based on the derivative of the log likelihood (score) imposing the hypothesis. The LM procedure seems to dominate the other two in terms of convenience when the objective of the test is to detect neglected heterogeneity in a given econometric model. The LM test statistic is solely based on the parameter estimates under the null hypothesis that there is no neglected heterogeneity and, as such, it eliminates the burden of specifying and estimating the model under the alternative hypothesis that there is some neglected heterogeneity. The possibility of using the LM test as a way of detecting individual heterogeneity was discussed in Breusch and Pagan (98), Chesher (984), Lee and Chesher (986), and Hahn, Newey, and Smith (4), among others. These tests can be viewed as a version of White s (98) Information Matrix test, as discussed in Chesher (984). Alternatively, they can be understood to be a test of overdispersion as in Cox (983), which is our interpretation in this paper. Implicit in these tests is the assumption that the neglected heterogeneity (under the alternative hypothesis) is more or less independent of the randomness that generates the main model, although the assumption is made more explicit in Hahn, Newey, and Smith (4, Lemmas 3. and 3.). In the panel data context, this assumption amounts to the random e ects speci cation, as developed in Balestra and Nerlove (966) or Maddala (97). In other The relationship among the three tests are reviewed in Engle (984), e.g.

2 words, in panel data applications we may roughly say that these tests are designed to detect random e ects, but not xed e ects (or equivalently, correlated random e ects). It is therefore of interest to revisit the LM test and analyze the test of neglected heterogeneity under more general conditions. This paper aims at achieving two distinct goals. The rst is to extend the existing LM test to the situation where the alternative hypothesis is characterized by the xed e ects model, where we adopt convention of equating the xed e ects with the correlated random e ects model. We begin by analyzing a model where the (local) alternative hypothesis is characterized by an arbitrary correlated random e ects, where the mean independence assumption is violated. We obtain a result that the test to detect such an arbitrary correlated random e ects would take the form of the test of conditional moment restriction. We then go on to analyze a more restricted version of correlated random e ects, where the e ects are assumed to be mean independent of the covariates of interest. For the latter case, we obtain an interesting result that the test against the random e ects model, where the conditional variance of the e ects does not depend on the covariates, has certain max-min type optimality property. We will call such test the LM test of overdispersion. In addition, while we show the LM test of overdispersion may have no power in linear models where the mean independence assumption is violated, we show the test may have some robustness properties against such violations in nonlinear models. As an example, we show the test has power against the arbitrary correlated random e ects alternative in the case of the logit model commonly used in applications. These results suggest the most natural applications for the LM test of overdispersion is to nonlinear models where the mean independence assumption is expected to hold. We nd such an application in the context of two-step semiparametric estimation of Bayesian game models commonly applied to the analysis of environments with social or strategic interactions among agents. This leads to the second goal of the paper, which is to draw a connection between panel data analysis and the analysis of multiplicity of equilibrium in games. We argue that multiplicity can be viewed as a particular form of neglected heterogeneity satisfying the mean independence assumption and propose an intuitive speci cation test for a class of two step game estimators. Moreover, the canonical speci cation of these games is a system of logit discrete choice models, to which we show the test is robust against more general forms of neglected heterogeneity that may arise from elsewhere in the model. Two step estimators of Bayesian game models exploit the two requirements of Bayes Nash See Chamberlain (984), e.g.

3 equilibrium. 3 First, equilibrium requires that players strategies are optimal given their beliefs about the distribution of opponent play and, second, that these beliefs are consistent with the true equilibrium distribution, conditional on any common knowledge determinants of player payo s. Under some assumptions about the nature of unobserved heterogeneity, the latter assumption allows the econometrician to, in the rst step, nonparametrically estimate player beliefs directly from the data by estimating conditional equilibrium choice probabilities. Treating these estimates as data, the problem of estimating the model of interdependent actions reduces to one of estimating a single agent choice model in the second step. This two step procedure allows the model to be estimated without ever having to solve the model, an often computationally expensive task. 4 The rst stage estimates conditional choice probabilities generally require pooling across a large number of observed game outcomes, which necessitates restrictive assumptions about two types of unobserved heterogeneity. First, we require there be no persistent unobserved state variables. That is, we rule out, for example, random and xed e ects in player payo functions. Second, while the underlying game is permitted to have multiple equilibria, we have to assume a single equilibrium is played in the data. If the rst stage estimates pool across games where multiple equilibria are played, the resulting choice probabilities with be weighted average of these equilibria, where the weights are given by the equilibrium selection probabilities. Nonlinearity in the second step estimator then leads to inconsistent parameter estimates. Some progress has been made on relaxing these assumptions 5, however, these xes often only apply to relatively restrictive classes of games and outside these classes custom solutions must be developed. Moreover, implementing these solutions often require increasing the computational complexity and burden of estimation. These considerations suggest that speci cation tests of these assumptions may be an attractive toolkit to practitioners. We argue that the LM test of overdispersion naturally applies here, because the meanindependence assumption is natural given the way that the conditional choice probability is computed in the rst step. Even if one were to consider an alternative that does not satisfy the mean-independence assumption, the LM test of overdispersion would have power due to the nonlinearity of the second step. Our proposed LM test can be viewed as a simple triage 3 See, e.g., Aguirregabiria and Mira (), Bajari, Hong, Krainer, and Nekipelov (). 4 This insight has been particularly important in the literature on estimating dynamic games (Aguirregabiria and Mira 7, Bajari, Benkard, and Levin 7, Berry, Pakes, and Ostrovsky 7, Pesendorfer and Schmidt- Dengler 7), where calculating equilibrium is so computationally expensive that full solution approaches to estimation are generally infeasible. 5 See Aguirregabiria and Nevo (3) for a survey. 3

4 tool that allows the researcher to estimate the relatively inexpensive, restrictive model and then use the LM test to decide whether the more complicated model is needed. Again, the main advantage of the LM test over the Wald test and the LR test is that we can construct the test statistics only under the null hypothesis of no heterogeneity (in this case, a single equilibrium is played), and we do not have to identify the model under the alternative that multiple equilibria played. We demonstrate the performance of our test in detecting failure of the single equilibrium assumption in a Monte Carlo exercise based on the application of Sweeting (9), who analyzes the timing of radio commercials among rival stations. Test of Neglected Correlated Random E ects - LM Test Revisited Assume that we observe a random sample (Y i ; X i ), i = ; : : : ; n. The Y and X can be vectors. For example, in the panel data analysis where each individual is observed over T time periods, we will have Y i = (Y i ; : : : ; X it ) and X i = (X i ; : : : ; X it ). We will assume that the conditional density of Y given X is given by the density f (yj x; ; ), where (; ) is the parameter that characterizes the density. Under the null hypothesis, is xed at, but under the alternative hypothesis, the may be a random variable potentially correlated with X. Our purpose is to develop an LM test to detect such neglected heterogeneity in. For simplicity, we will assume that the is a scalar. Following the convention in the literature, e.g., Chesher (984), we will also treat both and as known/ xed, which is the basis of our analysis throughout the rest of this section. Note that we can write f (yj x; ; ) = f (yj x; )without loss of generality. We will assume that under the alternative hypothesis, the is drawn from a distribution whose density is s (j x; ) = g x () where Z wg (wj x) dw b (x) : () Note that the conditional density of given X is allowed to depends on the realization of X. In the existing literature, including Breusch and Pagan (98), Chesher (984), Lee and Chesher (986), and Hahn, Newey, and Smith (4), it is (implicitly or explicitly) assumed that (i) and X are independent of each other; and (ii) the mean of is zero, so that b (x) =. Our speci cation and analysis di er from the existing literature that both of these restrictions are relaxed. In what follows we consider two cases, (i) when b (x) is unknown and not 4

5 necessarily zero and (ii) when b (x) = :. Case : Arbitrary b (x) When the conditional density function of is g observation Y is Z h (yjx; ; ) = x as in (), the density function of the f (yj x; ) g x d: (3) By the change-of-variable = + w, we have Z h (yj x; ; ) = f (yj x; + w) g (wj x) dw: The null hypothesis of interest is that there is no heterogeneity in the parameter. In the model above, this is equivalent to the test of the null H : = against H : 6=. Our LM test is based on s (y; x; ; (yj x; ; h (yj x; ; ) evaluated at =. We can easily see that at =, we have s (y; x; ; ) = f Z (yj x; ) wg (wj x) dw = s (yj x; ) b (x) ; (4) f (yj x; ) where s (yj x; ) f (yj x; ) f (yj x; ) : The analysis leading to (4) implies that the LM test reduces to a test of the moment restriction E [s (yj x; ) b (x)] = : (5) If we are to have power against all possible distribution of, we should have the above conditional moment restriction to hold for all (square integrable) b (x). Obviously it is equivalent to the test of conditional moment restriction E [s (yj x; )j x] = : (6) Tests of conditional moment restrictions in general have been studied by numerous papers in the econometrics literature. 6 Our contribution is the recognition that a particular test of conditional moment restrictions (6) can be viewed as an LM test against arbitrary correlated random e ects. 6 A partial list includes Newey (985), Bierens (99, 9), and Donald, Imbens, and Newey (3). 5

6 Example Consider the model y it = + x it + " it where " it is i.i.d. N (;! ) with! = known. We have so and the test of interest is log f (yj x; ) = (y it x it ) t= s (yj x; ) = (y it x it ) t= " # E (y it x it ) x i; : : : ; x it = : t= Remark In Example, a simple practical version of the test is a J-test for the moment 7 )!3 x i 7 E 6B 4@. C A (y it x it 5 = :. Case : b (x) = x it t= We now consider the special case, where we impose the restriction that b (x) =. The restriction leads to the problem that the LM test statistic in (4) becomes identically equal to. In order to tackle this problem, we follow Chesher (984) and Lee and Chesher (986), e.g., and work instead with p, i.e., Z h (yjx; ; ) = f (yj x; ) p g p x d: (7) We show in Appendix A that the LM test should be based on the p n-standardized sample average of where f (yj x; ) f (yj x; ) (x) ; (8) Z (x) w g (wj x) dw: 7 Here we treat and to be known, although in practice, we would plug in a consistent estimators of and. Therefore, the critical value in practice would have to re ect the sampling variation of the plugged-in estimators as well as the test statistic itself. 6

7 h Because the variance of (8) is E (X i ) ( (X i )) i, where we de ne " # f (Y i j X i ; ) (X i ) E f (Y i j X i ; ) X i ; (9) our test statistic would take the form T n = nx (X i ) (X i ) n i=.. Max-Min Consideration! p n nx i=! f (Y i j X i ; ) f (Y i j X i ; ) (X i ) : () The test statistic in () is inconvenient because it requires that (x) be speci ed. In this section, we provide a justi cation of using (x) = from a (local) max-min perspective. For expositional simplicity, we will suppose that and () is known. Our max-min justi cation is based on the following result: Lemma Under the sequence of distributions characterized by the density Z f (yjx; + p w) g (wj x) dw with = p n and g (wjx) such that R wg (wjx) dw = b (x) = and R w g (wj x) dw = (x) >, the test statistic T n ( ) in () converges to a noncentral distribution with the noncentrality parameter equal to Proof. In Appendix A. () ; () (E [ (X i ) (X i ) (X i )]) E (X i ) ( (X i )) : We will interpret the distribution with g as the true alternative chosen by the nature. The result above describes the asymptotic distribution of the test statistic () under the nature s alternative hypothesis. For a given critical value c, the power of the test is then given by P n [T n ( ) c], where P n denotes the probability measure under the local alternative sequence chosen by the nature. and therefore, the local power is P n [T n ( ) c] is determined by ( () ; ()). Our max-min justi cation is given in the following result: Proposition Consider the problem max min () ; () where (x) and (x) are normalized such that E [ (X i ) (X i )] = E [ (X i ) (X i )] =. The solution is such that () is a constant function. 7

8 Proof. In Appendix A. The decision problem we consider is that for given () ; the nature chooses the alternative () to minimize the lower power, i.e., ( () ; ()), and then, econometrician chooses () by maximizing the local power, i.e., ( () ; ()). The result above establishes that the econometrician s choice is such that () is constant. In other words, a constant choice for (x) is optimal from a max-min decision perspective. Remark Our discussion above suggests that it would be reasonable to take (X i ) = and can be justi ed by the max-min principle. Assuming that (X i ) > almost everywhere, we can see that the (; ()) > for any (X i ) as long as (X i ) > with positive probability. Given that the probability (X i ) > is positive for any reasonable (X i ), we can conclude that the test statistic T n ( ) with (X i ) = has a local power against any reasonable alternatives... Additional Consideration We ask whether the test of overdispersion has any power against the local alternative where the mean independence assumption may be violated. Test of the conditional moment restriction (6) is not expected to have any power if the alternative satis es the mean independence assumption b (x) =. Although the LM test of overdispersion is developed under the assumption that b (x) =, if it has a power even when b (x) 6=, we may argue that it is a more robust than the test of conditional restriction. We provide two examples, and discuss the power of the LM test of overdispersion. Given the max-min consideration, we will take () = without loss of generality, and consider the power of the test statistic () under the local alternative where the mean independence may be violated: Proposition Under the sequence of distributions characterized by the density (3) with = p n, the test statistic () is asymptotically noncentral with the noncentrality parameter equal to (E [ (X i ) b (X i )]) E [ (X i )], where (X i ) E f (Y i j X i ; ) f (Y i j X i ; ) f (Y i j X i ; ) X i : f (Y i j X i ; ) f ( Y i jx i ;) f( Y i jx i is ;) P Proof. Using the same argument as in Appendix A, we can show that p n n i= asymptotically normal with mean equal to E [ (X i ) b (X i )] and variance equal to E [ (X i )], from which the conclusion follows. Below we present two examples, one of which is such that the local power is zero because (X i ) =, and the other one is such that it is not necessarily the case. 8

9 Example (Example - continued) The textbook linear model in Example is such that we have log f (Y i j X i ; ) = C f (Y i j X i ; ) f (Y i j X i ; ) = (y it x it ) t= (y it x it )! T = t= f (Y i j X i ; ) f (Y i j X i ; ) = (y it x it ) = t= t= " it! " it T t= and using the symmetry of the normal distribution, we obtain (X i ) =. It follows that the test of overdispersion does not have any (local) power against the alternative as in (). Example 3 (Panel Logit) Consider the panel logit model where f (Y i j X i ; ) = TY t= exp (x it + ) yit + exp (x it + ) + exp (x it + ) yit We can see that log f (Y i j X i ; ) = y it (x it + ) t= log ( + exp (x it + )) t= f (Y i j X i ; ) f (Y i j X i ; ) = exp (x y it + ) it + exp (x it + ) f (Y i j X i ; ) f (Y i j X i ; ) = t= t=! exp (x y it + ) it + exp (x it + ) t= exp (x it + ) ( + exp (x it + )) and (X i ) = exp (x it + ) ( exp (x it + )) ( + exp (x it + : ))3 t= 3 Application In the previous section, we showed, rst, the test of overdispersion along the lines of Breusch and Pagan (98), Chesher (984), Lee and Chesher (986), and Hahn, Newey, and Smith (4), i.e., the variants of the statistic (8) with () =, have some local max-min optimality properties. Second, we showed that the tests have power against general correlated random 9

10 e ects (b(x) 6= ) in logit models, which is the property that is expected to carry over to other nonlinear models. Therefore, one may argue that the LM test of overdispersion is particularly well-suited for nonlinear models. A potentially important application of our test arises in the context of estimating static binary choice models with social and strategic interactions. These models have been employed to analyze a wide variety of applications including rm entry (Seim 6), the timing of radio commercials (Sweeting 9), labor force participation (Bjorn and Vuong 984), teen sex (Card and Giuliano ), and many more. In these models the payo associated with any particular discrete action, d i f; g, for an agent i depend on the actions of all other agents in the model. The optimal action for agent i then depends on his beliefs about the likely actions of other agents in the model. Under some assumptions about the nature of unobserved heterogeneity in the model, these models can be estimated using a simple two step, semiparametric estimator where, in the rst step, the econometrician estimates the equilibrium beliefs of the agents and in then, in the second step, estimates the parameters of the model that rationalize those estimated beliefs as an equilibrium. We consider a scenario in which the econometrician has access to data fd ig ; X ig g g=;:::;n i=;:::;k g on actions and covariates for K g agents interacting in each of n groups/games. The objective of estimation is to estimate payo s u(d ig ; d ig ; x ig ; ) that rationalize observed choice behavior, where D ig is the vector of choices of all agents except i. Following Bajari, Hong, Krainer, and Nekipelov () we assume the data is generated by a Bayes-Nash equilibrium of a game of incomplete information where players choose actions, d ig f; g to maximize 3 E D i [u(d ig ; D ig ; x ig ; ) + " ig (d ig )jx g ] = 4 X d i Pr(D ig = d i jx g = x g )u(d ig ; d i ; X ig ; ) 5 +" ig (d ig ); where " i (d ig ) is an i.i.d., across agents and games, private information payo shock drawn from a commonly known distribution and we use the convention X g probability that player i chooses d ig = is then = (X g; :::; X Kgg). The f(d ig = jx g ; ) = Pr(" ig () " i () E D i [u(; D ig ; x ig ; ) u(; D ig ; x ig ; )jx g = x g ]) () In a Bayes-Nash equilibrium, player i s beliefs about the distribution of opponent play are required to be consistent with the true distribution of play. This assumption and the observation that the econometrician is able to condition on all the data player i uses in forming his or her beliefs leads to a natural two step estimator for. In the rst step, the econometrician estimates,

11 ideally nonparametrically, conditional choice probabilities (CCP) 8 Pr [D ig = j X g ] = (X g ) () In the second step, the econometrician then formulates an estimator, using a (pseudo) likelihood or moment equation approach, based on the optimality condition (). The basic two step structure of this model was pioneered by Hotz and Miller (993) in the context of dynamic discrete choice models and has subsequently been extended to static discrete games (Agguiregabiria and Mira 3, Bajari, Hong, Krainer, and Nekipelov ) and dynamic games (Agguiregabiria and Mira 7, Bajari, Benkard, and Levin 7, Berry, Pakes, and Ostrovsky 7, Pesendorfer and Schmidt-Dengler 7). The rst stage CCP estimates, by nature of the exercise, require pooling of observations across games and agents, which leads to two sources of potential neglected heterogeneity that may invalidate the approach. First, unobserved individual or game/group level payo heterogeneity and second, multiple equilibria being played across games. Both of these make the CCP inconsistent estimates of equilibrium choice probabilities and, in turn, lead to inconsistency of the second stage estimates. When there are multiple equilibria, E [D i j X g ] can be viewed as a random variable (X g ); the moment equation () de nes a pseudo-parameter (x), which is an average of the (x) weighted by the probability of equilibrium selection. Non-linearity then leads the second stage estimator to be inconsistent for. Consistency thus requires the economist to assume a single equilibrium is played in the data. A similar issue arises in the presence of unobserved heterogeneity in player payo s, often referred to as unobserved state variables in dynamic models. Some progress has been made on identi cation and two step estimation of models with multiple equilibria and unobserved payo heterogeneity, in particular, by Kasahara and Shimotsu (9). However, in contrast to our LM test, the approaches pursued in the literature and both the Wald and LR tests require the econometrician to be able to specify the number of equilibria/types. In addition, even if these numbers are known, the LR test is often complicated due to the technical problem that certain parameters are often not identi ed under the null (Lin and Shao 3, Cho and White 7). Moreover, much of the appeal of the two step estimators is their computational convenience-they can often be programmed with a couple of 8 In the common usage the CCP for this example would be the individual conditional choice probability E[D j jx g ]. Here we implicitly assume players are anonymous and, conditional on X, symmetric so behavior can be described by the number of players that chose d j =. In our usage the CCP is a function of the individual CCPs Y Y Pr[D i = d i jx g ] = E[D j jx g ] ( E[D j jx g ]) j:d i(j)= j:d i(j)=

12 lines of code in commonly used statistical packages like STATA. Both full solution approaches, where the economist actually solves for equilibrium for every parameter guess in the estimation search algorithm, and two step approaches admitting multiple equilibria/payo heterogeneity entail a substantial increase in the computational burden of estimation. In this sense, our LM test can be looked at as a triage tool that allows the researcher to judge whether incurring such costs is necessary. These attractive features of the LM test notwithstanding, our test is limited by the fact that it designed to detect only a local alternative, i.e. cases where the departure from the assumption of a single equilibrium is not too severe. When there are multiple equilibria the very fact that (x) is de ned to a pseudo-parameter makes the test of overdispersion particularly useful. The analysis in the literature including Cox (984), Chesher (984) goes through as long as the heterogeneity is mean-independent of the randomness in Y given X. Given the way that the pseudo-parameter (X g ) is de ned, the mean-independence assumption is satis ed by default. It follows that the test statistic of interest in this application is simply nx f D i j X i ; ^; (X) p n f D i j X i ; ^; : (X) i= Obviously one needs to adjust for the error of estimating as well as (X i ). The (X i ) is often estimated nonparametrically, and as such, analysis along the lines of Newey (994) is necessary in order to characterize the asymptotic variance. From a practical perspective, it can be accommodated either by the bootstrap result as in Chen, Linton, and van Keilegom (3), or by the numerical equivalence result as in Ackerberg, Chen, and Hahn (). 9 4 Monte Carlo Our Monte Carlo exercise is inspired by the application of Sweeting (9), who estimates a strategic model of the timing of radio commercials by radio stations. There may be incentives for radio stations to coordinate the timing of their commercials so listeners do not have incentive to switch stations when commercials come on because, if they do, they will just tune to another commercial. The model is estimated using both a two step approach like those described above and a nested xed point approach that requires repeatedly solving for equilibrium. Multiplicity is endemic to such coordination games, yet identi cation of the two step estimator requires 9 In Appendix B, we present a (straightforward) characterization of how the procedure in Ackerberg, Chen, and Hahn () can be used in our context.

13 assuming, within a geographic market, stations play a single equilibrium strategy. De Paula and Tang (3) analyze this model when the single equilibrium assumption is relaxed and show the model is partially identi ed. In particular, they show the sign of the strategic interaction term can be estimated. Often, however, an analyst is interested in more precise, quantitative answers to counterfactual policy questions and these will generally require point estimates. We assume there are K stations competing in each of n games. For ease of exposition we assume the players are local in the sense that each player only competes in game. Stations compete by choosing a binary action d i f; g, which can be interpreted as a choice to play commercials at :5 or :55 minutes past the hour. The payo associated with each choice are given by: E[u(d i = ; D ig ; x g ; )jx g = x g ] = BX ig + JE[P ig jx g = x g ] + " ig E[u(d i = ; D ig ; x g ; )jx g = x g ] = CX ig + JE[P ig jx g = x g ] + " ig where P j6=i P dig = fd jg = dg K is the proportion of rivals choosing action d and expectations are taken with respect to player i s subjective beliefs about rival play. X ig is a vector of rm speci c covariates. Our setup requires variation in these X s as well as the assumption that X ig are excluded from i s payo. Bajari, Hong Krainer, and Nekipelov () discuss su cient conditions for identi cation of the general model. Sweeting (9) relies on panel arguments in lieu of the this exclusion restriction. We assume X ig f ; ; g and are drawn i.i.d uniform across players and games. Finally we assume the " s are drawn i.i.d from a type extreme value distribution. The probability of observing d i = is given by Pr(d ig = jx g ; ) = Pr(~u(d i = ; X; ) ~u(d i = ; X; ) > )) = exp(x ig + J(E[P ig jx g ] )) + exp(x ig + J(E[P ig jx g ] )) Where we let ~u(d i = d; X; ) = E[u(d i = d; D ig ; x g ; )jx g = x g ]. In the second stage, we formulate a (pseudo) maximum likelihood estimator based on the logit conditional choice probabilities. f(djx; ; ^P (X)) = exp(x ig + J( ^P (X i g) )) + exp(x ig + J( ^P (X i g) ))! dig + exp(x ig + J( ^P (X i g) ))! dig where we have used exchangeability of the X s to rearrange X g as X i g = (X ig ; X ig ) and drop the i index on the CCP. The rst stage estimate ^P is the rst stage CCP estimate: 3

14 p nk P n P K ^P (x i nk g= i= g) = P j6=i fd gj=gfx i g =xi g g K P n P K nk g= i= fxi g = x i gg Letting ^ = ( ^; ^J) denote the maximum likelihood estimates, our test statistic is: nx g= KX i= ^ = p nk nx g= KX i= f (a ig jx g ; ^; ^P ig ) f(a ig jx g ; ^; ^P ig ) = fa i =g 4J ( + exp(x ig + ^J( ^P (X i g) ))( exp( b X ig + ^J( ^P (X i g) )) ( + exp(x ig + J( ^P (X i g) )) 3 +fa i = g 4J ( + exp(b X ig + ^J( ^P (X i g) ))( exp( b X ig + ^J( ^P (X i g) )) ( + exp( b X ig + ^J( ^P (X i g) )) 3 exp( b X ig + ^J( ^P (X i g) )) For our Monte Carlo experiments, we rst solve for all the stable equilibria of our game conditional on X g, we then generate data assuming the X g s are drawn from a discrete uniform distribution in the population. To generate choice data under the single equilibrium assumption we randomly selected an equilibrium from the calculated set of equilibria for each X supp(x) and then generated the pro le of choices by drawing from the distribution induced by this equilibrium for every game in which the realization of X g was X. That is, conditional on X, a single equilibrium is played, though multiple equilibria may be played across the di erent X s. As discussed in Sweeting (9) and Brock and Durlauf () this type of realization of multiplicity actually aids in identi cation of the model, particularly in this type of model where, without realization of multiple equilibria, there is very limited, local variation in conditional choice probabilities. To generate the data under the alternative where the single equilibrium assumption fails, we randomly select an equilibrium from the calculated set of equilibria for each realization of X g in the data and then generate choices by drawing from the distribution induced by this equilibrium. In both the case where the single equilibrium assumption holds and where it does not, we use the same equilibrium selection mechanism. To de ne the mechanism, we start by using iterative updating of strategies to nd an equilibrium associated with an initial starting strategy pro le that has all players choosing an action with probability one. There are 3 (= 5 ) such pro les and all converge to one of the, at most, two stable equilibria of the game. For each X g, in the case of the single equilibrium assumption holding, and for each g, in the case of the single equilibrium assumption failing, the selection mechanism chooses uniformly from the 4!!

15 3 equilibrium realizations of one of the, at most, two equilibria found using our iterative updating algorithm. Intuitively, this causes the mechanism to, for example, tend to select the high equilibrium more often when covariate values tend to be higher. De ning the selection mechanism in this way is a natural way to generate dependence of the equilibrium selection on the covariates. Tables and show the results of our Monte Carlo experiments. Table displays the mean and standard deviation of parameter estimates from simulations assuming di erent sample sizes and true underlying interaction e ects. Table explores the power and size attributes of the test, displaying rejection probabilities from simulations across the di erent sample sizes and true interaction e ects. For each simulation we calculate ~ = ^ p var(^) where we use 5 bootstrap to estimate var(^), and compare it to the standard normal critical values. For both tables the statistics are based on simulations. The last three columns of Table illustrate the impact of the failure of the single equilibrium assumption. Both the impact of fundamentals ( ) and strategic e ects (J) are attenuated. The reason for this is simple. Due to multiplicity, actual choice probabilities are either all high or all low depending on which equilibrium is selected. The CCP estimate lies in between as a selection-probability weighted average of these equilibria. In other words, are CCP estimates suggest that equilibrium choices are more independent than they really are and thus more consistent with a game with relatively low strategic interaction e ects. Table shows our multiplicity test performs quite well in this example. When strategic e ects are weaker, variation in outcomes becomes decreasingly dominated by multiplicity and our test has less power in detecting a violation of the single equilibrium assumption. In our example, this happens both because the direct e ect of X i on a player s payo s is larger relative to the strategic e ects and also indirectly because the equilibrium selection mechanism is relatively more dependent on X g. 5

16 Table : Parameter Estimates Single Eq. True (H) Single Eq. False (H) J n ^ (const.; = ) ^( = ) ^J ^ ^ ^J.(.9).36(.3).88(.3) -.(.7).786(.9).758(.4).75.(.6).(.6).784(.9) -.8(.5).774(.).74(.) 5.(.4).9(.).76(.6) -.33(.3).768(.8).73(.6).3(.9).48(.6) 3.88(.8) -.6(.8).583(.5).7(.6) 3.3(.6).6(.8) 3.49(.) -.65(.5).556(.).676(.) 5 -.3(.4).6(.) 3.4(.7) -.68(.3).549(.7).648(.7).7(.).74(.9) 3.357(.) -.35(.6).365(.).59(.6) 3.5.(.7).4(.) 3.3(.5) -.38(.4).355(.7).53(.) 5.(.4977).8(.) 3.68(.8) -.38(.).349(.5).438(.7) Table : Rejection Frequency Single Eq. True (H) Single Eq. False (H) J n reject (p = :) reject (p = :5) reject (p = :) reject (p = :) reject (p = :5) reject (p = :) Notes:Tab le :Average coe cient estimates over simulated data sets, standard deviation of the simulated estimates in parentheses Tab le Fraction of simulations where the null is rejected at the indicated signi cance level. Test statistic distribution estimated using bootstrap repetitions. 6

17 Appendix A Technical Details for Section A. Some Details Behind (8) By the change-of-variable, we have Z h (yjx; ; ) = f (yjx; + p w) g (wj x) dw: Obviously the score is equal to s (y; ; ) = h (yjx; ; ) yjx; + p g (wj x) dw; and Z p yjx; + w g (wj x) dw = R f f (yjx; + p w w) p g (wj x) dw yjx; + p w wg (wj x) dw p : Using l Hôpital s rule, we obtain lim! R f yjx; + p w wg (w) dw p = lim! R f yjx; + p w w p wg (wj = f (yjx; ) (x) A. Some Details Behind (3) We prove that the test statistic based on (8), i.e., p n nx i= is asymptotically normal with mean equal to f (Y i j X i ; ) f (Y i j X i ; ) (X i ) E (X i ) (X i ) (X i ) (3) Here we use the Lebesgue s dominated convergence theorem under the condition XX of Assumption XX in the appendix. 7

18 and variance equal to. Here E denotes the expectation operator de ned by the null density f (yj x; ) p (x) ; where p (x) is the marginal density of X i. We rst derive the mean and the variance of the statistic p n nx i= f (Y i j X i ; ) f (Y i j X i ; ) (X i ) under the alternative indexed by ; Z k (yj x; ; ) = f (yjx; + w) g (wj x) dw; where g (wjx) is the conditional density of w on x chosen by the nature. In this section, we assume the following regularity conditions: The mixture distribution g satis es. R wg (wjx) dw =. R w g (wjx) dw = (x) and (x) 6= 3. R jwj 3 g (wjx) dw G (x) : Let p (x) be the density function of X i.the conditional density f (yjx; ) is three times continuously di erentiable with respect to the argument and the derivatives satisfy. sup jf (yjx; )j ; sup jf (yjx; )j ; sup jf (yjx; )j F (y; x; ) for some function F (; ; ). R R f ( yjx;) f( yjx;) (x) F (y; x; ) max f; G (x) p (x)g dydx < We denote P ; E ; and V as the probability measure, the expectation operator, and the variance operator, respectively, de ned by the density k (yj x; ; ) p (x) : De ne P = P ; E = E ; and V = V : We rst derive the limits (i) lim! E f (Y i j X i ; ) f (Y i j X i ; ) (X i ) and (ii) lim! V f (Y i j X i ; ) f (Y i j X i ; ) (X i ) 8

19 Part (i): We apply the third order Taylor approximation to k (yj x; ; ) of around = : Then, f (yj x; ) as a function k (yj x; ; ) f (yj x; ) (yj x; ; ) = k (yj x; ; ) k (yj x; ; ~) where ~ lies between and : Here we have (yj x; ; (yjx; + wg (wj x) dw = Z k (yj x; ; f (yjx; + w g (wj x) dw = = f (yjx; ) Z k (yj x; ; = f (yjx; + 3 w 3 g (wj x) dw =~ F (y; x; ) G (x) : Choose = n =4 : Then, since R f (yj x; ) dy =, we have " # nx f E p (Y i j X i ; ) n f (Y i= i j X i ; ) (X i ) = p Z Z f (yj x; ) n f (yj x; ) (x) k (yj x; ; ) p (x) dydx = p Z Z f (yj x; ) n f (yj x; ) (x) [k (yj x; ; ) f (yj x; )] p (x) dydx Z Z f (yj x; ) f (yj x; ) = f (yj x; ) (x) f (yj x; ) (x) f (yj x; ) p (x) dydx + Z Z f (yj x; k (yj x; ; ~) n =4 f (yj x; ) (x) p (x) dydx (5) Because Z Z f (yj x; k (yj x; ; ~) f (yj x; ) (x) p (x) dydx Z Z f (yj x; ) f (yj x; ) (x) F (y; x; ) G (x) p (x) dydx < ; 9

20 we have " # nx f E p (Y i j X i ; ) n f (Y i= i j X i ; ) (X i ) Z Z f (yj x; ) f (yj x; )! f (yj x; ) (x) f (yj x; ) (x) f (yj x; ) p (x) dydx f (Y i j X i ; ) f (Y i j X i ; ) = E f (Y i j X i ; ) (X i ) f (Y i j X i ; ) (X i ) : Part (ii): As for the variance in (ii), we can use the dominated convergence theorem. Note that " # lim V nx f p (Y i j X i ; )! n f (Y i= i j X i ; ) (X i ) f (Y i j X i ; ) = lim V! f (Y i j X i ; ) (X i ) Z Z f (yj x; ) = f (yj x; ) (x) lim k (yj x; ; ) p (x) dydx! Z Z f (yj x; ) f (yj x; ) (x) lim k (yj x; ; ) p (x) dydx :! It follows that lim! V " p n nx i= # f (Y i j X i ; ) f (Y i j X i ; ) (X i ) Z Z f (yj x; ) = f (yj x; ) (x) f (yj x; ) p (x) dydx Z Z f (yj x; ) f (yj x; ) (x) f (yj x; ) p (x) dydx f (Y i j X i ; ) = E f (Y i j X i ; ) (X i ) = : Proof of (3): Next, we derive the limiting distribution under the sequence of local alternative. For this, we let U i = f ( Y i jx i ;) h f( Y i jx i ;) (X i ) E hv f ( Y i jx i ;) i = f ( Y i jx i ;) f( Y i jx i ;) (X i ) i f( Y i jx i ;) (X i ) and consider a triangular sequence fu i : i ng and its underlying probability measure sequence P n =4: Since fu i g i=;:::;n i:i:d: (; ) under P n =4: Then, by the Lindberg-Feller CLT for the triangular array, we have nx p U i ) N (; ) under P n n =4: (6) i=

21 Then, by Parts (i) and (ii) and (6), under P n =4 we have p n = nx i= V n =4 f (Y i j X i ; ) f (Y i j X i ; ) (X i ) f (Y i j X i ; ) f (Y i j X i ; ) (X i ) = pn! nx U i " # nx f + E n =4 p (Y i j X i ; ) n f (Y i= i j X i ; ) (X i ) ) = f (Y i j X i ; ) f (Y i j X i ; ) N (; ) + E f (Y i j X i ; ) (X i ) f (Y i j X i ; ) (X i ) f (Y i j X i ; ) f (Y i j X i ; ) = N E f (Y i j X i ; ) (X i ) f (Y i j X i ; ) (X i ) ; ; i= under P n =4 as required for (3). A.3 Proof of Max-Min The nature moves rst. In order to minimize the power, it tries to minimize the noncentrality parameter ( () ; ()) by choosing (x) given positivity of () and the normalization restriction and (x). This is equivalent to minimizing E [ (X i ) (X i ) (X i )] with respect to () given positivity of () and the normalization restriction. Let X denotes the support of X i. Notice that for any (X i ) with E [ (X i ) (X i )] = ; it follows that E (X i ) (X i ) (X i ) E min xx (x) (X i ) (X i ) = min xx (x). Therefore, min E (X i ) (X i ) (); E[ (X) (X)]= (X i ) min xx (x) : (7) Suppose that x X achieves the minimum of (x) over x X ; i.e. (x ) (x) for all x X : Suppose that the support of X i ; X ; is discrete. We set ( (x) = (x )p(x for x = x ) : for x 6= x Then, we can see that E [ (X) (X)] = and also E (X i ) (X i ) (X i ) = (x ) : (8)

22 This implies that the lower bound of min (); E[ (X) (X)]= E [ (X i ) (X i ) (X i )] is achieved with and that min E (X i ) (X i ) (); E[ (X) (X)]= (X i ) = (x ) = min xx (x) ; (E [ (X i ) (X i ) (X i )]) min (); E[ (X) (X)]= E (X i ) ( (X i )) = ( (x )) E (X i ) ( (X i )) : When X i is a continuous random variable, we consider a sequence of functions ;m (x) such 8 < R x + ;m m (x) p (x) dx if x (x) = x < x < x m + m m : otherwise Then, for all m; we have E (X) ;m (X) = Z x + m x m (x) p (x) dx Also, as m! ; we have as in (8).! Z E (X i ) (X i ) ;m (X) (x) p (x) x m < x < x + dx = : m = m R (x) (x) p (x) x < x < x m + m m R x + m (x) p (x) dx x m! (x ) Now the econometrician moves. He wants to maximize the power by maximizing this ratio ( (x )) E (X i ) ( (X i )) manipulating (). For this purpose, we can see that h E (X i ) (X i ) i " # E (X i ) inf xx (x) and hence, Note that the upper bound of = 4 (x ) E (X i ) ( (x )) E (X i ) ( (X i )) ( 4 (x )) E [ (X i )] ( 4 (x )) = E [ (X i )] ( (x )) E[ (X i )( (X i )) ] ; E[ (X i ; is achievable by choosing )] (x) = (x ) : This justi es a constant choice for (x) from a minimax decision perspective.

23 B An Estimator of the Asymptotic Variance of p n (^ ) If we are to use the results in Ackerberg, Chen, and Hahn (), it su ces to write f (Y i j X i ; (Z i )) E : f (Y i j X i ; (Z i )) We can then view (; ) to be the method of moments estimator log nx f( Y i jx i ; ; b (Z b A n f ( Y i jx i ; ; b (Z b i )) = i= f( Y i jx i ;;(Z i b )) corresponding to the moment equation log f( Yi # jx i ;;(Z i E f ( Y i jx i ;;(Z i = )) f( Y i jx i ;;(Z i )) Note that =. Also note that the asymptotic variance of p nx f Y i j X i ; ; b b (Z i ) n (b ) = pn f Y i j X i ; ; b b (Z i ) i= can be taken care of by the numerical equivalence result as in Ackerberg, Chen, and Hahn (), i.e., we will use the fact that b (Z i ) = Z i ; b in practice for some nite-dimensional b, and apply the usual Murphy-Topel type formula. Let the W i = (Y i ; D i ; X i ; Z i ) : Suppose that one speci es E (D i jz i ) = (Z i ) with a parametric model (Z i ; ) and estimate by solving the exactly identi ed moment condition: n nx S i= D i ; Z i ; ^ = When D i is binary, if we use the logit model with (Z i ; ) = exp(z) i +exp(zi ), the score function is S (D i ; Z i ; ) = (D i (Z i ; )) Z i : If we use the probit model with (Z i ; ) = (Zi) ; then score function is S (D i ; Z i ; ) = (D i )((D i )Zi ) ((D i )Zi ) : Let = (; ) Denote m (W i ; ) = " S (D i ; Z i ; log f( Y i jx i ;;(Z i # = " S (Di ; Z i ; ) f ( Y i jx i ;;(Z i ;)) f( Y i jx i ;;(Z i ;)) # : 3

24 Then, ^ solves Let n nx i= m W i ; ^ = : m (W i ; ; ) = f (Y i j X i ; ; (Z i ; )) f (Y i j X i ; ; (Z i ; )) Then, ^ is estimated by solving the moment condition n P n i= m plugged in for : Denote " ^ ^ # n nx i= m W i ; ^; ^ = : : W i ; ; ^ = after ^ is ^ = 4 Also, denote We have ^ P n n i= m W i ; ^ ^ P m W i ; n n i= m W i ; ^ m W i ; ^; ^ P n n i= m W i ; ^; ^ ^ P m W i ; n n i= m W i ; ^; ^ m W i ; ^; ^ ; = n ; = n ; = n W i ; ^ = n i= W i ; ^; ^ = W i ; ^; ^ = n i= i= i= i ;^) W i ; ^ W i ; ^ W i ; ^; ^ = W i ; ^; ^ f f f h f f i ;^;^) f i f f f f # f @m (W i ; (W i i : 3 5 : 4

25 where f = f Y i j X i ; ^; Z i Y i j X i ; Z i ; ^ : Then, the variance of p N (^ ) is the upper left corner of " ; # " # " ^ ^ ; # : ; ; ^ ^ ; ; Since " ; ; ; " ; ; ; # = " # = 4 ; ; ; ; ; ; ; ; # ; ; 3 5 ; the estimator of the variance of p N (^ h ; ; ; ; i " ; ^ ^ ^ ^ ) is # 4 3 ; ; ; 5 ; = ; ; ; ^ ; ; ; ; ^ ; ; ; ; ; ; ^ ; + ; ^ ; = ; ; ^ ; ; ^ ; ; ; ; ^ + ^ : 5

26 References [] Ackerberg, D., X. Chen, and J. Hahn (): A Practical Asymptotic Variance Estimator for Two-Step Semiparametric Estimators, Review of Economics and Statistics 94, pp [] Aguirregabiria, V. and P. Mira (): Swapping the Nested Fixed Point Algorithm: A Class of Estimators for Discrete Markov Decision Models, Econometrica 7, pp [3] Aguirregabiria, V. and P. Mira (7): Sequential Estimation of Dynamic Discrete Games, Econometrica 75, pp. 53. [4] Aguirregabiria, V. and A. Nevo (3): Recent Developments in Empirical IO: Dynamic Demand and Dynamic Games, in Acemoglu, D., M. Arellano, and E. Deckel, eds. Advances in Economics and Econometrics. Tenth World Congress. Volume 3, Econometrics. [5] Bajari, P., C.L. Benkard, and J. Levin (7): Estimating Dynamic Models of Imperfect Competition, Econometrica 75, pp [6] Bajari, P., H. Hong, J. Krainer and D. Nekipelov (): Estimating Static Models of Strategic Interactions, Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 8, [7] Balestra, P., and M. Nerlove (966): Pooling Cross Section and Time Series Data in the Estimation of a Dynamic Model: The Demand for Natural Gas, Econometrica 34, pp [8] Bierens, H.J. (99): A Consistent Conditional Moment Test of Functional Form, Econometrica, 58, pp [9] Bierens, H.J. (9): Consistent Model Speci cation Tests, Working Paper. [] Breusch, T.S., and A.R. Pagan (98): The Lagrange Multiplier Test and Its Application to Model Speci cation in Econometrics, Review of Economic Studies 47, pp [] Card, D. and L. Giuliano (): Peer E ects and Multiple Equilbria in the Risky Behavior of Friend, UC Berkeley Working Paper. [] Chamberlain, G. (984): Panel Data, in Griliches, Z., and M.D. Intriligator, eds. Handbook of Econometrics, Vol II, pp , North Holland: Amsterdam. 6

27 [3] Chen, X., O. Linton and I. van Keilegom (3): Estimation of Semiparametric Models when the Criterion Function is not Smooth, Econometrica 7, pp [4] Chesher, A. (984): Testing for Neglected Heterogeneity, Econometrica 5, pp [5] Cho, J.S., and H. White (7): Testing for Regime Switching, Econometrica 75, pp [6] Cox, D.R. (983): Some Remarks on Overdispersion, Biometrika 7, pp [7] Engle, R.F. (984): Wald, Likelihood Ratio, and Lagrange Multiplier Tests in Econometrics, in Griliches, Z., and M.D. Intriligator, eds. Handbook of Econometrics, Vol II, pp , North Holland: Amsterdam. [8] Donald, S., G. Imbens, and W.K. Newey (3) "Empirical likelihood estimation and consistent tests with conditional moment restrictions." Journal of Econometrics 7, pp [9] Hahn, J., W.K. Newey, and R.J. Smith (4): Neglected Heterogeneity in Moment Condition Models, Journal of Econometrics 78, pp. 86. [] Hotz, V.J., and R.A. Miller (993): Conditional Choice Probabilities and the Estimation of Dynamic Models, Review of Economic Studies 6, pp [] Kasahara, H., and K. Shimotsu (9): Nonparametric Identi cation of Finite Mixture Models of Dynamic Discrete Choices, Econometrica 77, pp [] Lee, L., and A. Chesher (986): Speci cation Testing when Score Test Statistics Are Identically Zero, Journal of Econometrics 3, pp. 49. [3] Liu, X., and Y. Shao (3): Asymptotics for Likelihood Ratio Tests under Loss of Identi ability, Annals of Statistics 3, pp [4] Maddala, G. S. (97): The Use of Variance Components Models in Pooling Cross Section and Time Series Data, Econometrica 39, pp [5] Newey, W.K. (985): Maximum Likelihood Speci cation Testing and Conditional Moment Tests, Econometrica, 53, pp [6] Newey, W.K. (994): The Asymptotic Variance of Semiparametric Estimators, Econometrica 6,

28 [7] Pakes, A., Ostrovsky, M, and S. Berry (7): Simple Estimators for the Parameters of Discrete Dynamic Games, with Entry/Exit Examples, RAND Journal of Economics 38, [8] Pesendorfer, M. and P. Schmidt-Dengler (8): Asymptotic Least Squares Estimators for Dynamic Games, Review of Economic Studies 75, pp [9] Seim, K. (6): An Empirical Model of Firm Entry with Endogenous Product-Type Choices, RAND Journal of Economics 37, [3] Sweeting, A. (9): The Strategic Timing of Radio Commercials: An Empirical Analysis Using Multiple Equilibria, RAND Journal of Economics 4, pp [3] White, H. (98): Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Misspeci ed Models, Econometrica 5, pp. 5. 8

29 C On-line Appendix: Not for Publication C. Derivation of the Panel Logit Example Note that f (Y i j X i ; ) (X i ) = E f (Y i j X i ; ) = E 4 = t= t= f (Y i j X i ; ) X i f (Y i j X i ; ) y it exp (x it + ) + exp (x it + )!3 exp (x it + ) ( + exp (x it + )) " E y it t=! E " t= exp (x 3 it + ) + exp (x it + ) X i 3 X 5 i exp (x y it + ) it + exp (x it + ) # : # X i The last equality above uses the mathematical induction starting from the following observation: Suppose that A ; A are zero mean independent variables. We then have because E (A + A ) 3 = E A 3 + E A 3 ; (A + A ) 3 = A 3 + 3A A + 3A A + A 3 and recall zero mean assumption and independence, which eliminates all the terms except the two cubic terms. We now claim that (X i ) = t= + = exp (x it + ) ( t= exp(x +) 3 it exp(x +exp(x +) it it +exp(x +) it exp(x it +) +exp(x it +) 3 +exp(x it +) exp (x it + )) ( + exp (x it + ))3 exp(x This is based on the observation that +) it +exp(x +) is the mean of y it, and that if for a Bernouille it variable Z with probability p, we have E (Z p) 3 = ( p) 3 p + ( p) 3 ( p) = p (p ) (p ) which leads the desired result in the panel logit example. C A 9

Mini Course on Structural Estimation of Static and Dynamic Games

Mini Course on Structural Estimation of Static and Dynamic Games Mini Course on Structural Estimation of Static and Dynamic Games Junichi Suzuki University of Toronto June 1st, 2009 1 Part : Estimation of Dynamic Games 2 ntroduction Firms often compete each other overtime

More information

Identification and Estimation of Incomplete Information Games with Multiple Equilibria

Identification and Estimation of Incomplete Information Games with Multiple Equilibria Identification and Estimation of Incomplete Information Games with Multiple Equilibria Ruli Xiao Johns Hopkins University November 20, 2013 Job Market Paper Abstract The presence of multiple equilibria

More information

Estimating Dynamic Discrete-Choice Games of Incomplete Information

Estimating Dynamic Discrete-Choice Games of Incomplete Information Estimating Dynamic Discrete-Choice Games of Incomplete Information Michael Egesdal Zhenyu Lai Che-Lin Su October 5, 2012 Abstract We investigate the estimation of models of dynamic discrete-choice games

More information

Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts

Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts Contents 1 Motivating Examples 1 1.1 Instrumental variable estimator....................... 1 1.2 Estimating parameters in monetary policy rules.............. 2 1.3 Estimating

More information

GMM-based inference in the AR(1) panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails

GMM-based inference in the AR(1) panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails GMM-based inference in the AR() panel data model for parameter values where local identi cation fails Edith Madsen entre for Applied Microeconometrics (AM) Department of Economics, University of openhagen,

More information

Estimating Static Discrete Games

Estimating Static Discrete Games Estimating Static Discrete Games Paul B. Ellickson 1 1 Simon School of Business Administration University of Rochester August 2013 Ellickson (Duke Quant Workshop) Estimating Static Discrete Games August

More information

IDENTIFICATION OF INCOMPLETE INFORMATION GAMES WITH MULTIPLE EQUILIBRIA AND UNOBSERVED HETEROGENEITY

IDENTIFICATION OF INCOMPLETE INFORMATION GAMES WITH MULTIPLE EQUILIBRIA AND UNOBSERVED HETEROGENEITY IDENTIFICATION OF INCOMPLETE INFORMATION GAMES WITH MULTIPLE EQUILIBRIA AND UNOBSERVED HETEROGENEITY by Ruli Xiao A dissertation submitted to The Johns Hopkins University in conformity with the requirements

More information

The Asymptotic Variance of Semi-parametric Estimators with Generated Regressors

The Asymptotic Variance of Semi-parametric Estimators with Generated Regressors The Asymptotic Variance of Semi-parametric stimators with Generated Regressors Jinyong Hahn Department of conomics, UCLA Geert Ridder Department of conomics, USC October 7, 00 Abstract We study the asymptotic

More information

Identifying Dynamic Games with Serially-Correlated Unobservables

Identifying Dynamic Games with Serially-Correlated Unobservables Identifying Dynamic Games with Serially-Correlated Unobservables Yingyao Hu Dept. of Economics, Johns Hopkins University Matthew Shum Division of Humanities and Social Sciences, Caltech First draft: August

More information

Testing for Regime Switching: A Comment

Testing for Regime Switching: A Comment Testing for Regime Switching: A Comment Andrew V. Carter Department of Statistics University of California, Santa Barbara Douglas G. Steigerwald Department of Economics University of California Santa Barbara

More information

Simple Estimators for Semiparametric Multinomial Choice Models

Simple Estimators for Semiparametric Multinomial Choice Models Simple Estimators for Semiparametric Multinomial Choice Models James L. Powell and Paul A. Ruud University of California, Berkeley March 2008 Preliminary and Incomplete Comments Welcome Abstract This paper

More information

Syllabus. By Joan Llull. Microeconometrics. IDEA PhD Program. Fall Chapter 1: Introduction and a Brief Review of Relevant Tools

Syllabus. By Joan Llull. Microeconometrics. IDEA PhD Program. Fall Chapter 1: Introduction and a Brief Review of Relevant Tools Syllabus By Joan Llull Microeconometrics. IDEA PhD Program. Fall 2017 Chapter 1: Introduction and a Brief Review of Relevant Tools I. Overview II. Maximum Likelihood A. The Likelihood Principle B. The

More information

An empirical model of firm entry with endogenous product-type choices

An empirical model of firm entry with endogenous product-type choices and An empirical model of firm entry with endogenous product-type choices, RAND Journal of Economics 31 Jan 2013 Introduction and Before : entry model, identical products In this paper : entry with simultaneous

More information

Nonparametric Identi cation and Estimation of Truncated Regression Models with Heteroskedasticity

Nonparametric Identi cation and Estimation of Truncated Regression Models with Heteroskedasticity Nonparametric Identi cation and Estimation of Truncated Regression Models with Heteroskedasticity Songnian Chen a, Xun Lu a, Xianbo Zhou b and Yahong Zhou c a Department of Economics, Hong Kong University

More information

ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401S) University of Toronto. Department of Economics. Spring 2013 Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria

ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401S) University of Toronto. Department of Economics. Spring 2013 Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401S) University of Toronto. Department of Economics. Spring 2013 Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria SOLUTION TO FINAL EXAM Friday, April 12, 2013. From 9:00-12:00 (3 hours) INSTRUCTIONS:

More information

Solving Extensive Form Games

Solving Extensive Form Games Chapter 8 Solving Extensive Form Games 8.1 The Extensive Form of a Game The extensive form of a game contains the following information: (1) the set of players (2) the order of moves (that is, who moves

More information

A New Computational Algorithm for Random Coe cients Model with Aggregate-level Data

A New Computational Algorithm for Random Coe cients Model with Aggregate-level Data A New Computational Algorithm for Random Coe cients Model with Aggregate-level Data Jinyoung Lee y UCLA February 9, 011 Abstract The norm for estimating di erentiated product demand with aggregate-level

More information

A Note on Demand Estimation with Supply Information. in Non-Linear Models

A Note on Demand Estimation with Supply Information. in Non-Linear Models A Note on Demand Estimation with Supply Information in Non-Linear Models Tongil TI Kim Emory University J. Miguel Villas-Boas University of California, Berkeley May, 2018 Keywords: demand estimation, limited

More information

Identifying Dynamic Games with Serially-Correlated Unobservables

Identifying Dynamic Games with Serially-Correlated Unobservables Identifying Dynamic Games with Serially-Correlated Unobservables Yingyao Hu Dept. of Economics, Johns Hopkins University Matthew Shum Division of Humanities and Social Sciences, Caltech First draft: August

More information

Econ 273B Advanced Econometrics Spring

Econ 273B Advanced Econometrics Spring Econ 273B Advanced Econometrics Spring 2005-6 Aprajit Mahajan email: amahajan@stanford.edu Landau 233 OH: Th 3-5 or by appt. This is a graduate level course in econometrics. The rst part of the course

More information

Industrial Organization II (ECO 2901) Winter Victor Aguirregabiria. Problem Set #1 Due of Friday, March 22, 2013

Industrial Organization II (ECO 2901) Winter Victor Aguirregabiria. Problem Set #1 Due of Friday, March 22, 2013 Industrial Organization II (ECO 2901) Winter 2013. Victor Aguirregabiria Problem Set #1 Due of Friday, March 22, 2013 TOTAL NUMBER OF POINTS: 200 PROBLEM 1 [30 points]. Considertheestimationofamodelofdemandofdifferentiated

More information

13 Endogeneity and Nonparametric IV

13 Endogeneity and Nonparametric IV 13 Endogeneity and Nonparametric IV 13.1 Nonparametric Endogeneity A nonparametric IV equation is Y i = g (X i ) + e i (1) E (e i j i ) = 0 In this model, some elements of X i are potentially endogenous,

More information

Dynamic Discrete Choice Structural Models in Empirical IO. Lectures at Universidad Carlos III, Madrid June 26-30, 2017

Dynamic Discrete Choice Structural Models in Empirical IO. Lectures at Universidad Carlos III, Madrid June 26-30, 2017 Dynamic Discrete Choice Structural Models in Empirical IO Lectures at Universidad Carlos III, Madrid June 26-30, 2017 Victor Aguirregabiria (University of Toronto) Web: http://individual.utoronto.ca/vaguirre

More information

Simultaneous Choice Models: The Sandwich Approach to Nonparametric Analysis

Simultaneous Choice Models: The Sandwich Approach to Nonparametric Analysis Simultaneous Choice Models: The Sandwich Approach to Nonparametric Analysis Natalia Lazzati y November 09, 2013 Abstract We study collective choice models from a revealed preference approach given limited

More information

Models, Testing, and Correction of Heteroskedasticity. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley

Models, Testing, and Correction of Heteroskedasticity. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Models, Testing, and Correction of Heteroskedasticity James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Aitken s GLS and Weighted LS The Generalized Classical Regression Model

More information

MC3: Econometric Theory and Methods. Course Notes 4

MC3: Econometric Theory and Methods. Course Notes 4 University College London Department of Economics M.Sc. in Economics MC3: Econometric Theory and Methods Course Notes 4 Notes on maximum likelihood methods Andrew Chesher 25/0/2005 Course Notes 4, Andrew

More information

Econometric Analysis of Games 1

Econometric Analysis of Games 1 Econometric Analysis of Games 1 HT 2017 Recap Aim: provide an introduction to incomplete models and partial identification in the context of discrete games 1. Coherence & Completeness 2. Basic Framework

More information

Estimating Dynamic Programming Models

Estimating Dynamic Programming Models Estimating Dynamic Programming Models Katsumi Shimotsu 1 Ken Yamada 2 1 Department of Economics Hitotsubashi University 2 School of Economics Singapore Management University Katsumi Shimotsu, Ken Yamada

More information

Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters

Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters Thomas MaCurdy a and Xiaohong Chen b and Han Hong c Introduction Many empirical studies of program evaluations are complicated by the presence of both

More information

ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401S) University of Toronto. Department of Economics. Winter 2016 Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria

ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401S) University of Toronto. Department of Economics. Winter 2016 Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria ECOOMETRICS II (ECO 24S) University of Toronto. Department of Economics. Winter 26 Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria FIAL EAM. Thursday, April 4, 26. From 9:am-2:pm (3 hours) ISTRUCTIOS: - This is a closed-book

More information

Estimating Single-Agent Dynamic Models

Estimating Single-Agent Dynamic Models Estimating Single-Agent Dynamic Models Paul T. Scott Empirical IO Fall, 2013 1 / 49 Why are dynamics important? The motivation for using dynamics is usually external validity: we want to simulate counterfactuals

More information

ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401) Victor Aguirregabiria. Spring 2018 TOPIC 4: INTRODUCTION TO THE EVALUATION OF TREATMENT EFFECTS

ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401) Victor Aguirregabiria. Spring 2018 TOPIC 4: INTRODUCTION TO THE EVALUATION OF TREATMENT EFFECTS ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401) Victor Aguirregabiria Spring 2018 TOPIC 4: INTRODUCTION TO THE EVALUATION OF TREATMENT EFFECTS 1. Introduction and Notation 2. Randomized treatment 3. Conditional independence

More information

Specification Test on Mixed Logit Models

Specification Test on Mixed Logit Models Specification est on Mixed Logit Models Jinyong Hahn UCLA Jerry Hausman MI December 1, 217 Josh Lustig CRA Abstract his paper proposes a specification test of the mixed logit models, by generalizing Hausman

More information

11. Bootstrap Methods

11. Bootstrap Methods 11. Bootstrap Methods c A. Colin Cameron & Pravin K. Trivedi 2006 These transparencies were prepared in 20043. They can be used as an adjunct to Chapter 11 of our subsequent book Microeconometrics: Methods

More information

Information Structure and Statistical Information in Discrete Response Models

Information Structure and Statistical Information in Discrete Response Models Information Structure and Statistical Information in Discrete Response Models Shakeeb Khan a and Denis Nekipelov b This version: January 2012 Abstract Strategic interaction parameters characterize the

More information

CCP Estimation of Dynamic Discrete Choice Models with Unobserved Heterogeneity

CCP Estimation of Dynamic Discrete Choice Models with Unobserved Heterogeneity CCP Estimation of Dynamic Discrete Choice Models with Unobserved Heterogeneity Peter Arcidiacono Duke University Robert A. Miller Carnegie Mellon University August 13, 2010 Abstract We adapt the Expectation-Maximization

More information

Limit pricing models and PBE 1

Limit pricing models and PBE 1 EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Limit pricing models and PBE 1 1 Model Consider an entry game with an incumbent monopolist (Firm 1) and an entrant (Firm ) who analyzes whether or not to join the

More information

ECON 594: Lecture #6

ECON 594: Lecture #6 ECON 594: Lecture #6 Thomas Lemieux Vancouver School of Economics, UBC May 2018 1 Limited dependent variables: introduction Up to now, we have been implicitly assuming that the dependent variable, y, was

More information

SEQUENTIAL ESTIMATION OF DYNAMIC DISCRETE GAMES: A COMMENT. MARTIN PESENDORFER London School of Economics, WC2A 2AE London, U.K.

SEQUENTIAL ESTIMATION OF DYNAMIC DISCRETE GAMES: A COMMENT. MARTIN PESENDORFER London School of Economics, WC2A 2AE London, U.K. http://www.econometricsociety.org/ Econometrica, Vol. 78, No. 2 (arch, 2010), 833 842 SEQUENTIAL ESTIATION OF DYNAIC DISCRETE GAES: A COENT ARTIN PESENDORFER London School of Economics, WC2A 2AE London,

More information

Lecture Notes on Measurement Error

Lecture Notes on Measurement Error Steve Pischke Spring 2000 Lecture Notes on Measurement Error These notes summarize a variety of simple results on measurement error which I nd useful. They also provide some references where more complete

More information

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Labor Economics, 14.661. Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Daron Acemoglu MIT December 6, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Sequential Search December 6, 2011. 1 / 43 Introduction Introduction

More information

Estimating Dynamic Models of Imperfect Competition

Estimating Dynamic Models of Imperfect Competition Estimating Dynamic Models of Imperfect Competition Patrick Bajari Department of Economics University of Minnesota and NBER Jonathan Levin Department of Economics Stanford University and NBER C. Lanier

More information

1 Games in Normal Form (Strategic Form)

1 Games in Normal Form (Strategic Form) Games in Normal Form (Strategic Form) A Game in Normal (strategic) Form consists of three components. A set of players. For each player, a set of strategies (called actions in textbook). The interpretation

More information

Simple Estimators for Monotone Index Models

Simple Estimators for Monotone Index Models Simple Estimators for Monotone Index Models Hyungtaik Ahn Dongguk University, Hidehiko Ichimura University College London, James L. Powell University of California, Berkeley (powell@econ.berkeley.edu)

More information

ECO 2901 EMPIRICAL INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION

ECO 2901 EMPIRICAL INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION ECO 2901 EMPIRICAL INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION Lecture 8: Dynamic Games of Oligopoly Competition Victor Aguirregabiria (University of Toronto) Toronto. Winter 2017 Victor Aguirregabiria () Empirical IO Toronto.

More information

Lecture Notes on Game Theory

Lecture Notes on Game Theory Lecture Notes on Game Theory Levent Koçkesen 1 Bayesian Games So far we have assumed that all players had perfect information regarding the elements of a game. These are called games with complete information.

More information

Alvaro Rodrigues-Neto Research School of Economics, Australian National University. ANU Working Papers in Economics and Econometrics # 587

Alvaro Rodrigues-Neto Research School of Economics, Australian National University. ANU Working Papers in Economics and Econometrics # 587 Cycles of length two in monotonic models José Alvaro Rodrigues-Neto Research School of Economics, Australian National University ANU Working Papers in Economics and Econometrics # 587 October 20122 JEL:

More information

Dynamic Discrete Choice Structural Models in Empirical IO

Dynamic Discrete Choice Structural Models in Empirical IO Dynamic Discrete Choice Structural Models in Empirical IO Lecture 4: Euler Equations and Finite Dependence in Dynamic Discrete Choice Models Victor Aguirregabiria (University of Toronto) Carlos III, Madrid

More information

Identification of Discrete Choice Models for Bundles and Binary Games

Identification of Discrete Choice Models for Bundles and Binary Games Identification of Discrete Choice Models for Bundles and Binary Games Jeremy T. Fox University of Michigan and NBER Natalia Lazzati University of Michigan February 2013 Abstract We study nonparametric

More information

Inference about Clustering and Parametric. Assumptions in Covariance Matrix Estimation

Inference about Clustering and Parametric. Assumptions in Covariance Matrix Estimation Inference about Clustering and Parametric Assumptions in Covariance Matrix Estimation Mikko Packalen y Tony Wirjanto z 26 November 2010 Abstract Selecting an estimator for the variance covariance matrix

More information

Estimation of Finite Sequential Games

Estimation of Finite Sequential Games Estimation of Finite Sequential Games Shiko Maruyama April 15, 2012 Abstract I propose a new estimation method for nite sequential games that is e cient, computationally attractive, and applicable to a

More information

GMM Based Tests for Locally Misspeci ed Models

GMM Based Tests for Locally Misspeci ed Models GMM Based Tests for Locally Misspeci ed Models Anil K. Bera Department of Economics University of Illinois, USA Walter Sosa Escudero University of San Andr es and National University of La Plata, Argentina

More information

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours. University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring 2012 EC941: Game Theory Prof. Francesco Squintani Final Exam Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours. 1. Consider

More information

Control Functions in Nonseparable Simultaneous Equations Models 1

Control Functions in Nonseparable Simultaneous Equations Models 1 Control Functions in Nonseparable Simultaneous Equations Models 1 Richard Blundell 2 UCL & IFS and Rosa L. Matzkin 3 UCLA June 2013 Abstract The control function approach (Heckman and Robb (1985)) in a

More information

1 The Multiple Regression Model: Freeing Up the Classical Assumptions

1 The Multiple Regression Model: Freeing Up the Classical Assumptions 1 The Multiple Regression Model: Freeing Up the Classical Assumptions Some or all of classical assumptions were crucial for many of the derivations of the previous chapters. Derivation of the OLS estimator

More information

A Course in Applied Econometrics Lecture 14: Control Functions and Related Methods. Jeff Wooldridge IRP Lectures, UW Madison, August 2008

A Course in Applied Econometrics Lecture 14: Control Functions and Related Methods. Jeff Wooldridge IRP Lectures, UW Madison, August 2008 A Course in Applied Econometrics Lecture 14: Control Functions and Related Methods Jeff Wooldridge IRP Lectures, UW Madison, August 2008 1. Linear-in-Parameters Models: IV versus Control Functions 2. Correlated

More information

Supplemental Material 1 for On Optimal Inference in the Linear IV Model

Supplemental Material 1 for On Optimal Inference in the Linear IV Model Supplemental Material 1 for On Optimal Inference in the Linear IV Model Donald W. K. Andrews Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics Yale University Vadim Marmer Vancouver School of Economics University

More information

Extensive Form Games with Perfect Information

Extensive Form Games with Perfect Information Extensive Form Games with Perfect Information Pei-yu Lo 1 Introduction Recap: BoS. Look for all Nash equilibria. show how to nd pure strategy Nash equilibria. Show how to nd mixed strategy Nash equilibria.

More information

Social Interactions under Incomplete Information with Heterogeneous Expectations

Social Interactions under Incomplete Information with Heterogeneous Expectations Social Interactions under Incomplete Information with Heterogeneous Expectations Chao Yang and Lung-fei Lee Ohio State University February 15, 2014 A Very Preliminary Version Abstract We build a framework

More information

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Subgame Perfect Equilibrium (SPNE)

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Subgame Perfect Equilibrium (SPNE) EconS 3 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Subgame Perfect Equilibrium (SPNE). Based on MWG 9.B.3 Consider the three-player nite game of perfect information depicted in gure. L R Player 3 l r a b

More information

Lecture 8 Inequality Testing and Moment Inequality Models

Lecture 8 Inequality Testing and Moment Inequality Models Lecture 8 Inequality Testing and Moment Inequality Models Inequality Testing In the previous lecture, we discussed how to test the nonlinear hypothesis H 0 : h(θ 0 ) 0 when the sample information comes

More information

SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER. Donald W. K. Andrews. August 2011

SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER. Donald W. K. Andrews. August 2011 SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER By Donald W. K. Andrews August 2011 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1815 COWLES FOUNDATION FOR RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS

More information

ECO 2901 EMPIRICAL INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION

ECO 2901 EMPIRICAL INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION ECO 2901 EMPIRICAL INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION Lecture 12: Dynamic Games of Oligopoly Competition Victor Aguirregabiria (University of Toronto) Toronto. Winter 2018 Victor Aguirregabiria () Empirical IO Toronto.

More information

Lecture Notes on Game Theory

Lecture Notes on Game Theory Lecture Notes on Game Theory Levent Koçkesen Strategic Form Games In this part we will analyze games in which the players choose their actions simultaneously (or without the knowledge of other players

More information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers September 6, 016 ONLINE APPENDIX In this Appendix we present in full additional results and extensions which are only mentioned in the paper. In the exposition

More information

Implicit Function Theorem: One Equation

Implicit Function Theorem: One Equation Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 3: The Implicit Function Theorem Note 3 is based on postol (975, h 3), de la Fuente (2, h5) and Simon and Blume (994, h 5) This note discusses the

More information

CCP Estimation. Robert A. Miller. March Dynamic Discrete Choice. Miller (Dynamic Discrete Choice) cemmap 6 March / 27

CCP Estimation. Robert A. Miller. March Dynamic Discrete Choice. Miller (Dynamic Discrete Choice) cemmap 6 March / 27 CCP Estimation Robert A. Miller Dynamic Discrete Choice March 2018 Miller Dynamic Discrete Choice) cemmap 6 March 2018 1 / 27 Criteria for Evaluating Estimators General principles to apply when assessing

More information

Puri cation 1. Stephen Morris Princeton University. July Economics.

Puri cation 1. Stephen Morris Princeton University. July Economics. Puri cation 1 Stephen Morris Princeton University July 2006 1 This survey was prepared as an entry for the second edition of the New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. In a mixed strategy equilibrium of

More information

Estimation of Large Network Formation Games

Estimation of Large Network Formation Games Estimation of Large Network Formation Games Geert Ridder Shuyang Sheng February 8, 207 Preliminary Abstract This paper develops estimation methods for network formation using observed data from a single

More information

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam #2 - Answer Key

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam #2 - Answer Key EconS 50 - Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam # - Answer Key 1. Revenue comparison in two auction formats. Consider a sealed-bid auction with bidders. Every bidder i privately observes his valuation

More information

9 A Class of Dynamic Games of Incomplete Information:

9 A Class of Dynamic Games of Incomplete Information: A Class of Dynamic Games of Incomplete Information: Signalling Games In general, a dynamic game of incomplete information is any extensive form game in which at least one player is uninformed about some

More information

Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods

Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods Robert V. Breunig Centre for Economic Policy Research, Research School of Social Sciences and School of

More information

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology Daron Acemoglu MIT October 3, 2007 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Advanced Growth Lecture 8 October 3,

More information

Robust Predictions in Games with Incomplete Information

Robust Predictions in Games with Incomplete Information Robust Predictions in Games with Incomplete Information joint with Stephen Morris (Princeton University) November 2010 Payoff Environment in games with incomplete information, the agents are uncertain

More information

Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data

Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data Jeffrey M. Wooldridge / The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England Contents Preface Acknowledgments xvii xxiii I INTRODUCTION AND BACKGROUND

More information

Estimating Single-Agent Dynamic Models

Estimating Single-Agent Dynamic Models Estimating Single-Agent Dynamic Models Paul T. Scott New York University Empirical IO Course Fall 2016 1 / 34 Introduction Why dynamic estimation? External validity Famous example: Hendel and Nevo s (2006)

More information

7 Semiparametric Methods and Partially Linear Regression

7 Semiparametric Methods and Partially Linear Regression 7 Semiparametric Metods and Partially Linear Regression 7. Overview A model is called semiparametric if it is described by and were is nite-dimensional (e.g. parametric) and is in nite-dimensional (nonparametric).

More information

Barnali Gupta Miami University, Ohio, U.S.A. Abstract

Barnali Gupta Miami University, Ohio, U.S.A. Abstract Spatial Cournot competition in a circular city with transport cost differentials Barnali Gupta Miami University, Ohio, U.S.A. Abstract For an even number of firms with identical transport cost, spatial

More information

Estimating the Number of Common Factors in Serially Dependent Approximate Factor Models

Estimating the Number of Common Factors in Serially Dependent Approximate Factor Models Estimating the Number of Common Factors in Serially Dependent Approximate Factor Models Ryan Greenaway-McGrevy y Bureau of Economic Analysis Chirok Han Korea University February 7, 202 Donggyu Sul University

More information

Estimation of Games with Ordered Actions: An Application to Chain-Store Entry

Estimation of Games with Ordered Actions: An Application to Chain-Store Entry Estimation of Games with Ordered Actions: An Application to Chain-Store Entry Andres Aradillas-Lopez and Amit Gandhi Pennsylvania State University and University of Wisconsin-Madison December 3, 2015 Abstract

More information

Game Theory. Bargaining Theory. ordi Massó. International Doctorate in Economic Analysis (IDEA) Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona (UAB)

Game Theory. Bargaining Theory. ordi Massó. International Doctorate in Economic Analysis (IDEA) Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona (UAB) Game Theory Bargaining Theory J International Doctorate in Economic Analysis (IDEA) Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona (UAB) (International Game Theory: Doctorate Bargainingin Theory Economic Analysis (IDEA)

More information

Estimation of Static Discrete Choice Models Using Market Level Data

Estimation of Static Discrete Choice Models Using Market Level Data Estimation of Static Discrete Choice Models Using Market Level Data NBER Methods Lectures Aviv Nevo Northwestern University and NBER July 2012 Data Structures Market-level data cross section/time series/panel

More information

ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401S) University of Toronto. Department of Economics. Winter 2014 Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria

ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401S) University of Toronto. Department of Economics. Winter 2014 Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria ECONOMETRICS II (ECO 2401S) University of Toronto. Department of Economics. Winter 2014 Instructor: Victor guirregabiria SOLUTION TO FINL EXM Monday, pril 14, 2014. From 9:00am-12:00pm (3 hours) INSTRUCTIONS:

More information

GMM based inference for panel data models

GMM based inference for panel data models GMM based inference for panel data models Maurice J.G. Bun and Frank Kleibergen y this version: 24 February 2010 JEL-code: C13; C23 Keywords: dynamic panel data model, Generalized Method of Moments, weak

More information

Notes on Generalized Method of Moments Estimation

Notes on Generalized Method of Moments Estimation Notes on Generalized Method of Moments Estimation c Bronwyn H. Hall March 1996 (revised February 1999) 1. Introduction These notes are a non-technical introduction to the method of estimation popularized

More information

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics Yulei Luo SEF of HKU January 14, 2009 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) MME January 14, 2009 1 / 44 Comparative Statics and The Concept of Derivative Comparative Statics

More information

Jinyong Hahn. Department of Economics Tel: (310) Bunche Hall Fax: (310) Professional Positions

Jinyong Hahn. Department of Economics Tel: (310) Bunche Hall Fax: (310) Professional Positions Jinyong Hahn Department of Economics Tel: (310) 825-2523 8283 Bunche Hall Fax: (310) 825-9528 Mail Stop: 147703 E-mail: hahn@econ.ucla.edu Los Angeles, CA 90095 Education Harvard University, Ph.D. Economics,

More information

GMM estimation of spatial panels

GMM estimation of spatial panels MRA Munich ersonal ReEc Archive GMM estimation of spatial panels Francesco Moscone and Elisa Tosetti Brunel University 7. April 009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/637/ MRA aper No. 637, posted

More information

ECONOMETRICS FIELD EXAM Michigan State University May 9, 2008

ECONOMETRICS FIELD EXAM Michigan State University May 9, 2008 ECONOMETRICS FIELD EXAM Michigan State University May 9, 2008 Instructions: Answer all four (4) questions. Point totals for each question are given in parenthesis; there are 00 points possible. Within

More information

Bayesian Estimation of Discrete Games of Complete Information

Bayesian Estimation of Discrete Games of Complete Information Bayesian Estimation of Discrete Games of Complete Information Sridhar Narayanan August 2012 (First Version: May 2011) Abstract Estimation of discrete games of complete information, which have been applied

More information

Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting

Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting Eric Avenel Université de Rennes I et CREM (UMR CNRS 6) March, 00 Abstract This article presents a model

More information

ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS OF MODELS WITH SOCIAL INTERACTIONS. 1. Introduction

ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS OF MODELS WITH SOCIAL INTERACTIONS. 1. Introduction ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS OF MODELS WITH SOCIAL INTERACTIONS BRENDAN KLINE AND ELIE TAMER 1. Introduction Models with social interactions accommodate the possibility that an individual s outcome may be related

More information

An Instrumental Variable Approach to Dynamic Models

An Instrumental Variable Approach to Dynamic Models An Instrumental Variable Approach to Dynamic Models work in progress, comments welcome Steven Berry and Giovanni Compiani Yale University September 26, 2017 1 Introduction Empirical models of dynamic decision

More information

Estimation under Ambiguity (Very preliminary)

Estimation under Ambiguity (Very preliminary) Estimation under Ambiguity (Very preliminary) Ra aella Giacomini, Toru Kitagawa, y and Harald Uhlig z Abstract To perform a Bayesian analysis for a set-identi ed model, two distinct approaches exist; the

More information

Internet Appendix for The Labor Market for Directors and Externalities in Corporate Governance

Internet Appendix for The Labor Market for Directors and Externalities in Corporate Governance Internet Appendix for The Labor Market for Directors and Externalities in Corporate Governance DORON LEVIT and NADYA MALENKO The Internet Appendix has three sections. Section I contains supplemental materials

More information

Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection

Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection Geethanjali Selvaretnam Abstract This model takes into consideration the fact that depositors

More information

Auctions. data better than the typical data set in industrial organization. auction game is relatively simple, well-specified rules.

Auctions. data better than the typical data set in industrial organization. auction game is relatively simple, well-specified rules. Auctions Introduction of Hendricks and Porter. subject, they argue To sell interest in the auctions are prevalent data better than the typical data set in industrial organization auction game is relatively

More information

Likelihood Ratio Based Test for the Exogeneity and the Relevance of Instrumental Variables

Likelihood Ratio Based Test for the Exogeneity and the Relevance of Instrumental Variables Likelihood Ratio Based est for the Exogeneity and the Relevance of Instrumental Variables Dukpa Kim y Yoonseok Lee z September [under revision] Abstract his paper develops a test for the exogeneity and

More information

Semiparametric Estimation of Signaling Games with Equilibrium Refinement

Semiparametric Estimation of Signaling Games with Equilibrium Refinement Semiparametric Estimation of Signaling Games with Equilibrium Refinement Kyoo il Kim Michigan State University September 23, 2018 Abstract This paper studies an econometric modeling of a signaling game

More information

Bootstrapping the Grainger Causality Test With Integrated Data

Bootstrapping the Grainger Causality Test With Integrated Data Bootstrapping the Grainger Causality Test With Integrated Data Richard Ti n University of Reading July 26, 2006 Abstract A Monte-carlo experiment is conducted to investigate the small sample performance

More information