Politecnico di Torino. Porto Institutional Repository

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Politecnico di Torino. Porto Institutional Repository"

Transcription

1 Politecnico di Torino Porto Institutional Repository [Article] Stability analysis of transportation networks with multiscale drier decisions Original Citation: Como, Giacomo; Sala, Ketan; Acemoglu, Daron; Dahleh, Munther A.; Frazzoli, Emilio (2013). Stability analysis of transportation networks with multiscale drier decisions. In: SIAM JOURNAL ON CONTROL AND OPTIMIZATION, ol. 51 n. 1, pp ISSN Aailability: This ersion is aailable at : since: Noember 2015 Publisher: SIAM Published ersion: DOI: / Terms of use: This article is made aailable under terms and conditions applicable to Open Access Policy Article ("Public - All rights resered"), as described at html Porto, the institutional repository of the Politecnico di Torino, is proided by the Uniersity Library and the IT-Serices. The aim is to enable open access to all the world. Please share with us how this access benefits you. Your story matters. (Article begins on next page)

2 STABILITY ANALYSIS OF TRANSPORTATION NETWORKS WITH MULTISCALE DRIVER DECISIONS GIACOMO COMO, KETAN SAVLA, DARON ACEMOGLU, MUNTHER A. DAHLEH, AND EMILIO FRAZZOLI Abstract. Stability of Wardrop equilibria is analyzed for dynamical transportation networks in which the driers route choices are influenced by information at multiple temporal and spatial scales. The considered model inoles a continuum of nonatomic indistinguishable driers commuting between a common origin/destination pair in an acyclic transportation network. The driers route choices are affected by their, relatiely infrequent, perturbed best responses to global information about the current network congestion leels, as well as their instantaneous local obseration of the immediate surroundings as they transit through the network. A noel model is proposed for the driers route choice behaior, exhibiting local consistency with their preference toward globally less congested paths as well as myopic decisions in faor of locally less congested paths. The simultaneous eolution of the traffic congestion on the network and of the aggregate path preference is modeled by a system of coupled ordinary differential equations. The main result shows that, if the frequency of updates of path preferences is sufficiently small as compared to the frequency of the traffic flow dynamics, then the state of the transportation network ultimately approaches a neighborhood of the Wardrop equilibrium. The presented results may be read as a further eidence in support of Wardrop s postulate of equilibrium, showing robustness of it with respect to non-persistent perturbations. The proposed analysis combines techniques from singular perturbation theory, eolutionary game theory, and cooperatie dynamical systems. Key words. Transportation networks, Wardrop equilibrium, traffic flows, eolutionary game dynamics, route choice behaior, multiscale decisions. 1. Introduction. As transportation demand is fast approaching its infrastructure capacity, a rigorous understanding of the relationship between the macroscopic properties of transportation networks and realistic drier route choice behaior is attracting renewed research interest. Such an analysis is essential, among other things, for appropriate design of incenties influencing driers behaior in order to induce a desired socially optimal usage of the transportation infrastructure. A particularly releant issue is the impact of driers en route responses to unexpected eents on the oerall transportation network dynamics. This issue is particularly significant in modern transportation network settings, where recent technological adancements in intelligent traeller information deices hae enabled driers to be much more flexible in selecting their routes to destination een while being en route. While there has been a significant research effort to inestigate the effect of such technologies on the This work was supported in part by NSF EFRI-ARES grant number and AFOSR grant number FA The first author was partially supported by the Swedish Research Council, through the the junior research grant Information Dynamics in Large-Scale Networks and the Linnaeus excellence center LCCC. Any opinions, findings, and conclusions or recommendations expressed in this publication are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the iews of the supporting organizations. Department of Automatic Control, Lund Uniersity, BOX 118, SE Lund, Sweden (giacomo.como@control.lth.se). Sonny Astani Department of Ciil and Enironmental Engineering, Uniersity of Southern California, Los Angeles (CA), , US (ksala@usc.edu). Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 77 Mass Ae, Cambridge (MA), 02139, US (daron@mit.edu). Laboratory for Information and Decision Systems, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 77 Mass Ae, Cambridge (MA), 02139, US (dahleh@mit.edu). Laboratory for Information and Decision Systems, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 77 Mass Ae, Cambridge (MA), 02139, US (frazzoli@mit.edu). 1

3 route choice behaior of driers, e.g., see [26, 22], the analytical study of the dynamical properties of the whole network under such behaior has attracted ery little attention. This paper is focused on the stability analysis of transportation networks in a setup where the driers hae access to traffic information at multiple temporal and spatial scales and they hae the flexibility to switch their route to destination at eery intermediate traffic intersection. Specifically, we consider a model in which the driers choose their routes while haing access to relatiely infrequent global information about the network congestion state, and real-time local information as they transit through the network. The driers route choice behaior is then influenced by relatiely slowly eoling path preferences as well as myopic responses to the instantaneous obseration of the local congestion leels at the intersections. This setup captures many real-life scenarios where unexpected eents obsered en route might cause driers to take a temporary detour, but not necessarily to change their path preferences. Such path preferences may instead be updated, e.g., on a daily, weekly, or longer time basis, in response to information about the global congestion state of the different origin-destination paths collected from the driers personal experience, their opinion exchanges with their peers, as well as from information media. Howeer, since the traffic dynamics is significantly influenced by the driers response to real-time local information, such responses can influence the driers path preference thereby modifying their global route choice behaior in the long run. We propose and analyze a noel model for the driers route choice behaior that combines relatiely infrequent information about the global congestion status of the network with real-time local obserations as explained below. In our model, the network is represented by a directed acyclic graph with one origin and one destination. A continuous constant flow of nonatomic indistinguishable driers enters from the origin, and flows through the network until reaching the destination node. Traffic parameters, such as aerage speed, traffic density, and flow, are modeled as homogeneous quantities on eery link, related to each other by functional dependencies representatie of the links congestion properties. The dynamics of such traffic parameters is goerned by the law of conseration of mass, as well as the driers route choice behaior. In turn, the driers route choice behaior is assumed to be influenced by two factors: the aggregate path preference, measuring the relatie appeal of the different routes to the driers, and local obserations of the current congestion leels. The path preference dynamics eole at a slow time scale (as compared to the traffic dynamics), following a perturbed best response to global information, embodied by the current congestion leels on the whole network. When traersing an intermediate node in the network, driers behae according to their path preference, if this is consistent with the current, locally obsered, aggregate behaior of the other driers. On the other hand, when there is a discrepancy between the aggregate path preference and the locally obsered aggregate behaior, then driers tend to compensate this by myopically preferring routes which appear to be locally less congested. The model described aboe gies rise to a double feedback dynamics, goerned by a finite-dimensional system of coupled ordinary differential equations. Such a dynamical system has two natural time scales, characterizing the dynamics of the driers aggregate path preference and of the traffic parameters on the different links, respectiely. We study the long-time behaior of this dynamical system: our main result shows that, in the limit of small update rate of the aggregate path preferences, a 2

4 state of approximate Wardrop equilibrium [27] is approached. The latter is a configuration in which the delay associated to any source-destination path chosen by a nonzero fraction of driers does not exceed the delay associated to any other path. Our results contribute to proiding a stronger eidence in support of the significance of Wardrop s postulate of equilibrium for a transportation network. They may also be read as a sort of robustness of such equilibrium notion with respect to non-persistent perturbations of the network. The analytical arguments we propose mainly rely on three ideas: adopting a singular perturbation approach [16], by considering the aggregate path preference as quasi-static when studying the fast scale dynamics of the traffic parameters, and the traffic parameters as almost equilibrated when analyzing the slow scale dynamics of the aggregate path preference; exploiting the inherent cooperatie 1 dependence of the route choice function on the local traffic parameters in order to establish exponential stability of the fast scale dynamics of the traffic parameters; adapting results from eolutionary population games [15, 24] in order to establish stability properties of the slow scale perturbed best response dynamics of the aggregate path preference. Our work is naturally related to two streams of literature on transportation networks. On the one hand, traffic flows on networks hae been widely analyzed with fluid-dynamical and kinetic models: see, e.g., [11], and references therein. As compared to these models (typically described by integro- or partial differential equations), ours significantly simplifies the eolution of the traffic parameters (treating them as homogeneous quantities on the links, representatie of spatial aerages), whereas it highlights the role of the driers route choice behaior with its double feedback dynamics, which is typically neglected in that literature. On the other hand, transportation networks hae been studied from a decisiontheoretic perspectie within the framework of congestion games [3, 23]. In these models, driers make sequential myopic route choice decisions in pursuit of minimizing their personal trael times, in response to complete information about the whole network. Congestion games are known to belong to the class of potential games [19], a consequence of which is that, best responses of the driers are aligned with the gradient of a common potential function and hence the system eentually conerges to a critical point of this potential function, which, under appropriate monotonicity conditions of the congestion properties of the links of the network, corresponds to a Wardrop equilibrium. Such an approach has been used, for example in [18]. Dynamical systems framework for stability analysis of transportation equilibria hae also been deeloped in [25, 5, 20]. The stability of Wardrop equilibrium in the context of communication networks has been studied in [4]. It is important to note that the two salient features of a typical congestion game setup are that information is aailable to the driers at a single temporal and spatial scale, and that the dynamics of traffic parameters are completely neglected by assuming that they are instantaneously equilibrated. In contrast, we study the stability of Wardrop equilibrium in a setting where the dynamics of the traffic parameters are not neglected, and the driers route choice decisions are affected by relatiely infrequent global information, as well as their realtime local information as they transit through the network. As a consequence, classic results of eolutionary game theory and population dynamics [15, 24] are not directly applicable to our framework, and noel analytical tools hae to be deeloped, particularly for the analysis of the fast scale dynamics of the traffic parameters. For such dynamics, the most noel technical feature of our approach consists in proing local 1 Here, the adjectie cooperatie is intended in the sense of Hirsch [12, 13]. 3

5 contraction properties which follow from the cooperatie nature and other structural properties of the system. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we formulate the model and state the main result. Section 3 is a technical section that contains the proofs for the main result including intermediate results. In Section 4, we report results from illustratie numerical experiments. Finally, we conclude in Section 5 and also mention potential future research directions. Before proceeding, we establish here some notations to be used throughout the paper. Let R be the set of reals, R := {x R : x 0} be the set of nonnegatie reals. Let A and B be finite sets. Then, A will denote the cardinality of A, R A (respectiely, R A ) the space of real-alued (nonnegatie-real-alued) ectors whose components are labeled by elements of A, and R A B the space of matrices whose real entries are labeled by pairs of elements in A B. The transpose of a matrix M R A B, will be denoted by M R B A, while I will be an identity matrix, and 1 the all-one ector, whose size will be clear from the context. We shall use the notation Φ := I A 1 11 R A A to denote the projection matrix on the space orthogonal to 1. The simplex of probability ectors oer a finite set A will be denoted by S(A) := {x R A : 1 x = 1}. If B A, 1 B : A {0, 1} will stand for the indicator function of B, with 1 B (a) = 1 if a B, 1 B (a) = 0 if a A \ B. For p [1, ], p is the p-norm. By default, let := 2 denote the Euclidean norm. Let int(x ) be the interior of a set X R d, and X denote its boundary. Let sgn : R { 1, 0, 1} be the sign function, defined by sgn(x) is 1 if x > 0, sgn(x) = 1 if x < 0, and sgn(x) = 0 if x = 0. By conention, we shall assume the identity d x /dx = sgn(x) to be alid for eery x R, including x = 0. Finally, we shall adopt the conention that the gradient f of a function f : D R, where D R A, be a column ector in R A, while f := Φ f will stand for the projected gradient on S(A). 2. Model formulation and main result. In this section, we formulate the problem and state the main result. In our formulation, we represent the dynamics of the traffic and the route choice behaior on a transportation network as a system of coupled ordinary differential equations with two time scales representatie of route choice behaior influenced by the two leels of information. The dynamics of the physical ariables, i.e., density and flow on each link, eole at the fast time scale and are drien by local information on the current physical state of the network, whereas the aggregate path preferences eole at the slow time scale in response to global information on the current physical state of the network. The key components of our model are: network topology, congestion properties of the links, path preference dynamics, and node-wise route choice decision. We next describe each of these components in detail Network characteristics. Let the topology of the transportation network be described by a directed graph (in short, di-graph) G = (V, E), where V is a finite set of nodes and E V V is the set of (directed) links. For eery node V, we shall denote by E, and E, the sets of its incoming, and, respectiely, outgoing links. A length-l (directed) path from u V to V is an l-tuple of consecutie links {( j 1, j ) E : 1 j l} with 0 = u, and l =. A cycle is path of length l 1 from a node to itself. Throughout this paper, we shall assume that: Assumption 1. The di-graph G contains no cycles, has a unique origin (i.e., some V such that E = ), and a unique destination (i.e., some V such that E = ). Moreoer, there exists a path to the destination node from eery other node in V, as well as from the origin node to any other node in V. 4

6 Assumption 1 implies that one can find a (not necessarily unique) topological ordering of the node set V (see, e.g., [8]). We shall assume to hae fixed one such ordering, identifying V with the integer set {0, 1,..., n}, where n := V 1, in such a way that E 0 u< E u, = 0,..., n. We shall model the traffic parameters as time-arying quantities which are homogeneous oer each link of the network. Specifically, for eery link e E, and time instant t 0, we shall denote the current traffic density, and flow, by ρ e (t), and f e (t), respectiely, while ρ(t) := {ρ e (t) : e E}, f(t) := {f e (t) : e E} will stand for the ectors of all traffic densities, and flows, respectiely. Current traffic flow and density on each link are related by a functional dependence f e = µ e (ρ e ), e E. (2.1) Such functional dependence models the driers speed and lane adjustment behaior in response to traffic density on a particular segment of a road. It will be assumed to satisfy the following: Assumption 2. For eery link e E, the flow-density function µ e : R R is continuously differentiable, strictly increasing, strictly concae and is such that d µ e (0) = 0, lim µ e (ρ e ) <. ρe 0 dρ e Remark 1. Flow-density functions commonly used in transportation theory typically are not globally increasing, but rather hae a -shaped graph [11]: µ e (ρ e ) increases from µ e (0) = 0 until achieing a maximum C e = µ e ( ρ e ), and then decreases for ρ e ρ e. Assumption 2 remains a good approximation of this setting, proided that ρ e stays in the interal [0, ρ e ). It should be noted that the fact that the support of the flow function is unbounded, i.e., that the density can grow as large as possible, preents the (fast time scale) dynamics (2.11) of the physical ariables to take into account backward propagation of perturbations. For eery link e E, let C e := sup{µ e (ρ e ) : ρ e 0} = lim µ e(ρ e ) ρ e be its maximum flow capacity. Moreoer, let F := [0, C e ), F := e E[0, C e ) e E be the sets of local, and, respectiely, global feasible flow ectors. Obsere that our formulation allows for both the cases of bounded and unbounded maximum flow capacities. As the flow f e is the product of speed and density, it is natural to introduce the delay function if f e C e T : R E [0, ] E, T e (f e ) := µ 1 e (f e )/f e if f e (0, C e ), (2.2) 1/ dµe dρ e (0) if f e = 0, 5

7 whose components measure the flow-dependent time taken to traerse the different links. 2 Example 1. A flow-density function that satisfies Assumption 2 is gien by µ e (ρ e ) = C e ( 1 e θ eρ e ) e E, (2.3) where C e > 0, and θ e > 0. The corresponding delay function is T e (f e ) = 1 C e log. θ e f e C e f e We shall denote by P the set of distinct paths in G from the origin node 0 to the destination node n. Let { A R E P 1 if e p, A ep = 0 if e / p, be the link-path incidence matrix of G. The relatie appeal of the different paths to the driers will be modeled by a time-arying probability ector oer P, which will be referred to as the current aggregate path preference, and denoted by π(t). If one assumes, as we shall do throughout this paper, a constant unit in-flow in the origin node, it is natural to consider the ector f π := Aπ of the flows associated to the current aggregate path preference. Indeed, the e-th entry, fe π = p A epπ p, represents the total traffic flow that a link e E would sustain in a static condition in which the fraction of driers choosing any path p P is gien by π p. Now, let Π := {π S(P) : f π e < C e, e E} be the set of feasible path preferences. Here, the term feasible refers to the fact that the flow ector f π associated to any π Π satisfies the capacity constraint fe π < C e for eery e E. Obsere that, wheneer C e > 1 for eery e E (or, when link capacities are infinite), the set of feasible path preferences Π coincides with the whole simplex S(P). In contrast, when C e 1 for some e E, Π S(P) is a strict inclusion. On the other hand, the following result shows that whether Π is empty or not depends solely on the alue of the min-cut capacity of the network [1, Ch. 4]. Let C := min C U, C U := C e, U V: 0 U,n/ U where E U := {e = (u, ) E : u U, V \ U}. Proposition 2.1. The set Π is nonempty if and only if C > 1. Proof. Fix a cut-set U V such that 0 U, and n / U. Then, eery path p P contains exactly one link (u, ) p such that u U, and V \ U. Hence, for eery π Π, one has that C U = π p = 1. length. e E U C e > p e E U e E U A ep π p = p 2 Here, it has implicitly been assumed, without any loss of generality, that all the links are of unit 6

8 Minimizing oer all cut-sets U shows that C > 1 is necessary for Π to be nonempty. For the inerse implication, consider a network with the same topology G and link capacities c e = max{c e E 1 (C 1), 0}. The min-cut capacity of this network satisfies c C (C 1) = 1. Note also that, from our construction, C e > c e 0. Therefore, the max-flow min-cut theorem (see, e.g., [1, Thm. 4.1]) implies that there exists some π Π, thus proing that Π is nonempty. In the case when C 1 it is not hard to show that the system will grow unstable, i.e., ρ e (t) is unbounded as t grows large, for some link e E. Therefore, throughout this paper, we shall confine ourseles to transportation networks satisfying: Assumption 3. The min-cut capacity satisfies C > Route choice behaior and traffic dynamics. We now describe the driers route choice behaior and traffic dynamics on the network. We enision a continuum of indistinguishable driers traeling through the network. Driers enter the network from the origin node 0 at a constant unit rate, trael through it, and leae the network from the destination node n. While inside the network, driers occupy some link e E. The time required by the driers to traerse link e, and the current flow on such link are goerned by its congestion properties, as gien by (2.2), and (2.1), respectiely. When entering the network from the origin node = 0, as well as when reaching the head node {1, 2,..., n 1} of some link e / En, the driers instantaneously join some link e E. In this paper, we shall model the choice of such new link to depend on infrequently updated perturbed best responses of the driers to global information about the congestion status of the whole network as well as on their instantaneous obseration of the local congestion leels. We next describe these two aspects of the model in detail. Aggregate path preference dynamics. The driers aggregate path preference π(t), already introduced in Sect. 2.1, models the relatie appeal of the different paths to the driers population. It is updated as driers access global information about the current congestion status of the whole network. This occurs at some rate η > 0, which could be thought of as being small with respect to the time-scale of the network flow dynamics. Information about the current status of the network is embodied by the current traffic flow ector f(t). From f(t), driers can ealuate the ector A T (f(t)), whose p-th entry, e A ept e (f e (t)), coincides with the total delay a drier expects to incur on path p assuming that the congestion leels on that path won t change during her journey. 3 Driers are modeled as reacting to such global information by updating their path preferences independently at rate η according to some feasible path preference F h (f(t)) Π, so that the aggregate path preference π(t) eoles as d dt π(t) = η ( F h (f(t)) π(t) ). (2.4) Here F h : F Π is a perturbed (or smoothed) best response function, as per Assumption 4 formulated below. First, let us introduce the notion of admissible perturbation. 3 The delay that a drier would actually incur taking path p at time t would in fact possibly differ from e AepTe(fe(t)), since by the time t t the drier reaches a certain link e p, the delay on that link, T e(f e(t )), might well hae changed from its alue T e(f e(t)) at time t, as a result of the fast-scale dynamics of the physical ariables ρ e(t) and f e(t). 7

9 Definition 2.2. An admissible perturbation is a function h : Π h R where Π h Π is a closed conex set, h( ) is strictly conex, twice differentiable in int(π h ), and is such that lim π Πh h(π) =. Example 2. Let D := {e E : C e 1} be the, possibly empty, set of links with capacity not exceeding 1. For a ε (0, min e C e ), and β > 0, let and define h : Π h R by Π h := {π Π : f π d C d ε, d D}, h(π) := β 1 p π p log π p β 1 d (C d ε f π d ) log(c d ε f π d ), where the summation indices p and d run oer the sets P and D, respectiely, and the standard conention 0 log 0 := 0 is adopted. It can be readily erified that Π h Π is a nonempty conex polytope, and lim π Πh h(π) =. Hence, h is an admissible perturbation. Obsere that, if C e > 1 for all e E, then D is empty, Π h = Π, and h(π) = β 1 p π p log π p reduces to the standard negatie entropy function. Obsere that compactness and conexity of Π h, together with strict conexity of h(ω) imply existence and uniqueness of a minimizer of ω A T (f) h(ω) in Π h. This supports the following. Assumption 4. The function F h : F Π is a perturbed best response, i.e., F h (f) := argmin { ω A T (f) h(ω) }, f F, (2.5) ω Π h where h : Π h R is an admissible perturbation (as per Definition 2.2). In fact, Assumption 4 and Definition 2.2 imply that F h (f) int(π h ) and that F h (f) is continuously differentiable on F. The perturbed best response function F h (f) proides an idealized description of the behaior of driers whose decisions are based on inexact information about the state of the network. In particular, it can be shown that the form of F h (f) gien in (2.5) is equialent to the minimization, oer paths p P, of the expected delay e A ept e (f e ) corrupted by some (admissible) stochastic perturbation (see e.g. [14]). Moreoer, it is well known [24] that, as h 0, and Π h Π, the perturbed best response F h (f) conerges to the set argmin{ω A T (f) : ω Π} of best responses. 4 Example 3. Assume that C e > 1 for all e E, and fix a noise parameter β > 0. Define a perturbed best response by putting Π h = Π, and h(π) = β 1 p π p log π p for all π Π, as in the special case of Example 2. Then, the corresponding perturbed best response is the logit function F h p (f) = exp( β(a T (f)) p ) q P exp( β(a T (f)) q ), p P. (2.6) For any fixed f F, one has that lim β F h (f), with F h (f) as defined in (2.6), is a uniform distribution oer the set argmin{(a T (f)) p : p P}. We refer the reader to [10, 15] for more on the connection between F h characterized by Assumption 4 and smoothed best response functions. Remark 2. The micro-foundations of the aggregate path dynamics in (2.4) can be heuristically justified by looking at it as the mean-field limit of a stochastic finite 4 Here, the conergences Π h Π, and {F h (f)} argmin{ω A T (f) : ω Π} are intended to hold in the Hausdorff metric. (see, e.g., [2, Def ]) 8

10 population model along the following lines. Consider a model with a large but finite drier population, with each drier updating her path preference at the clicking of an independent Poisson clock of rate η by choosing a new preferred path p with probability Fp h (f(t)). Then one could show that the conditional aerage ariation of the aggregate path preference from time t to time t ε, for small ε > 0, is gien by η ( F h (f(t)) π(t) ) εo(ε). As the stochastic elements of the driers updating mechanisms are idiosynchratic, one may expect such stochastic influences to be aeraged away as the population size grows large, by appealing to some law of large numbers in the spirit of Kurtz s theorem [17], [9, Chapter 11]. We will not attempt to formally justify the micro-foundations of the model discussed in this paper, but rather leae it as a topic for future work. Remark 3. In the eolutionary game theory literature, e.g., see [15, 24], the domain of an admissible perturbation function h, as well as the one of the minimization in the right-hand side of (2.5), is typically assumed to be the whole simplex S(P), instead of a closed polytope Π h Π S(P). Notice that, as already obsered in Sect. 2.1, when C e > 1 for eery e E, Π = S(P) is a closed polytope, so that one can choose Π h = Π. Therefore, in this case, Definition 2.2 does not introduce any additional restriction with respect to such theory. On the other hand, when C e 1 for some e E, then the inclusions of Π h Π S(P) are both strict, so that Definition 2.2 does introduce additional restrictions on the admissible perturbations. Howeer, it is worth obsering that, in a classic eolutionary game theoretic framework, the dynamics of the aggregate path preference would be autonomous rather than coupled to the one of the actual flow. In particular, perturbed best response dynamics in that framework would read as d dt π(t) = F h (f π (t)) π(t), (2.7) rather than as in (2.4). For such dynamics, the fact that T e (fe π ) = wheneer fe π C e, can be shown to imply that π(t) reaches a compact Π h Π in some finite time and neer leae it. In contrast, in the two time-scale model of coupled dynamics considered in this paper (see (2.13)), such more restrictie assumption is needed in order to ensure the same property for the trajectories of π(t) (see Lemma 3.4). Local route decisions. We now describe the local route decisions, characterizing the fraction of driers choosing each link e E when traersing a non-destination node. Such a fraction will be assumed to be a continuously differentiable function G e(f E, π) of the local traffic flow f E := {f e : e E }, as well as of the current aggregate path preference π. We shall refer to G : F Π S(E ) (2.8) as the local decision function at node {0, 1,..., n 1}, and assume that it satisfies the following: Assumption 5. For all 0 < n, and π Π, ( j E f π j ) G e ( f π, π E ) = fe π, e E. Assumption 6. For all 0 < n, π Π, and f E F, f e G j (f E, π) 0, j e E. 9

11 Assumption 5 is a consistency assumption. It postulates that, when the locally obsered flow coincides with the one associated to the aggregate path preference π, driers choose to join link e E with frequency equal to the ratio between the flow fe π and the total outgoing flow j E f j π. Assumption 6 instead models the driers myopic behaior in response to ariations of the local congestion leels. It postulates that, if the congestion on one link increases while the congestion on the other links outgoing from the same node is kept constant, the frequency with which each of the other outgoing links is chosen does not decrease. It is worth obsering that Assumption 6 is reminiscent of Hirsch s notion of cooperatie dynamical system [12, 13]. Example 4. An example of local decision function G satisfying Assumptions 5 and 6 is the i-logit function. The i-logit route choice function with sensitiity γ 0 is gien by G e(f E, π) = fe π exp( γ(f e fe π )) j E f j π exp( γ(f j fj π, (2.9) )) for eery e E, 0 < n. Obsere that in the extreme case γ = 0, (2.9) reduces to G e(f E, π) = fe π j E f j π, (2.10) which models a situation where the driers do not take into account the local obseration on the current flow, and always act in a way that is consistent with their aggregate path preference. For eery non-destination node {0, 1,..., n 1}, and outgoing link e E, conseration of mass implies that where d dt ρ e(t) = H e (f(t), π(t)), (2.11) H e (f, π) := { G e (f E, π) f e if = 0 ( j E f j)g e(f E, π) f e if 1 < n, (2.12) for all π Π and f F Objectie of the paper and main result. The objectie of this paper is to study the eolution of the coupled dynamics d dt π(t) = η ( F h (f(t)) π(t) ) d ρ(t) = H(f(t), π(t)), dt (2.13) where: F h is the perturbed best response function defined in (2.5); η > 0 is the rate at which global information becomes aailable; H(f, π) = {H e (f, π) : e E}, with H e defined in (2.11); f and ρ are related by the functional dependence (2.1). In particular, our analysis will focus on the double limiting case of small η and small h. We shall proe that, in such limiting regime, the long-time behaior of the system is 10

12 approximately at Wardrop equilibrium [27, 21]. The latter is a configuration in which the delay is the same on all the paths chosen by a nonzero fraction of driers. More formally, one has the following: Definition 2.3 (Wardrop Equilibrium). A feasible flow ector f W F is a Wardrop equilibrium if f W = Aπ for some π Π such that, for all p P, π p > 0 = (A T (Aπ)) p (A T (Aπ)) q, q P. (2.14) Existence and uniqueness of a Wardrop equilibrium are guaranteed by the following standard result: Proposition 2.4 (Existence and uniqueness of Wardrop equilibrium). Let Assumptions 1-3 be satisfied. Then, there exists a unique Wardrop equilibrium f W F. Proof. It follows from Assumption 2 that, for eery e E, the delay function T e (f e ) is continuous, strictly increasing, and such that T e (0) > 0. The proposition then follows by applying Theorems 2.4 and 2.5 from [21]. The following is the main result of this paper. It will be proed in Sect. 3 using a singular perturbation approach. Theorem 2.5. Let Assumptions 1 6 be satisfied. Then, for eery initial condition π(0) int(s(p)), ρ(0) (0, ) E, there exists a unique solution of (2.13). Moreoer, there exists a perturbed equilibrium flow f (h) F such that, for all η > 0, lim sup f(t) f (h) δ(η), (2.15) t where δ(η) is a nonnegatie-real-alued, nondecreasing function of η > 0, such that lim η 0 δ(η) = 0. Moreoer, for eery sequence of admissible perturbations {h k } such that lim k h k = 0, and lim k Π hk = Π, one has lim k f (h k) = f W. (2.16) Theorem 2.5 states that, in the large time limit, the flow ector f(t) approaches a neighborhood of the Wardrop equilibrium, whose size anishes as both the time-scale ratio η and the perturbation norm h anish. While a qualitatiely similar result is known to hold [24] in a classic eolutionary game theoretic framework (i.e., neglecting the traffic dynamics, and assuming it is instantaneously equilibrated, as in the ODE system (2.7)), the significance of the aboe is to show that an approximate Wardrop equilibrium configuration is expected to emerge also in our more realistic model of twotime scale dynamics. Therefore, our results proide a stronger eidence in support of the significance of Wardrop s postulate of equilibrium for a transportation network. In fact, they may be read as a sort of robustness of such equilibrium notion with respect to non-persistent perturbations. 3. Proofs. In this section, Theorem 2.5 is proed. First, obsere that, thanks to the continuous differentiability of F h, G, and µ, standard analytical arguments imply the existence and uniqueness of a solution of the initial alue problem associated to the system (2.13), with initial condition ρ(0) (0, ) E, π(0) int(s(p)). In order to proe the rest of the statement, we shall adopt a singular perturbation approach (e.g., see [16]), iewing the traffic density ρ (or, equialently, the traffic flow f) as a fast transient, and the aggregate path preference π as a slow component. Hence, we shall first think of π as quasi-static (i.e., almost a constant ) while analyzing 11

13 the fast-scale dynamics (2.11), and then assume that f is almost equilibrated, i.e., close to f π, and study the slow-scale dynamics (2.4) as a perturbation of (2.7). We shall proceed by proing a series of intermediate technical results, gathered in the following subsections. Before proceeding, we introduce some notation to be used throughout the section. Let ρ π e := µ 1 e (f π e ), σ e := sgn (ρ e ρ π e ) = sgn (f e f π e ) denote, respectiely, the density corresponding to the flow associated to the path preference π, and the sign of the difference between it and the actual density ρ e. Finally, fix some α (0, 1), and define n 1 V (f, π) := α =0 e E n 1 f e fe π, W (ρ, π) := α =0 e E ρ e ρ π e. (3.1) 3.1. Stability of the fast-scale dynamics. We gather here a few properties of the fast-scale dynamics. Our results will essentially amount to showing that V (f, π) and W (ρ, π) are Lyapuno functions for the fast-scale dynamics (2.11) with stationary path preference π. The following result is a consequence of Assumptions 5 and 6 on the driers local decision function. Lemma 3.1. For all π Π, {0,..., n 1}, and f E F, ) σ e (λ π G e(f E, π) fe π 0, e E where λ π := e E f π e. Proof. Throughout this proof, the explicit dependence of G e on π will be dropped. Define J := {e E : f e > f π e }, K := {e E : f e < f π e }, and let G J := j J G j, G K := k K G k, and G J c := e E \J G e. First, obsere that, since e E G e = 1, one has that G J = G J c. Now, we are going to show that G J (f π ) G E J (f E ) 0, (3.2) by writing the difference aboe as a path integral of G J ( ) first along the segment S J from f E to the point f R E with fj := fj π, for j J and f e := f e for e E \ J, and then along the segment S K from f to f π. In this way, one gets: G J (f π ) G E J (f E ) = G J ( f E ) d f E G J ( f E ) d f E S J S K = G J c( f E ) d f E S J G J ( f E ) d f E. S K (3.3) Assumption 6 implies that G J c/ ρ j 0 for all j J, and G J / ρ k 0 for all k K. In turn, this implies that G J c d f E 0 along S J, and G J d f E 0 along S K. This and (3.3) proe (3.2). In a ery similar fashion, one proes that G K (f E ) G K (f π ) 0. (3.4) E 12

14 Now, obsere that Assumption 5 implies that λ π G e(f π, π) = f π E e. From this, (3.2), and (3.4), it follows that 0 λ π = e E ( ) ( G J (f E ) G J (f π ) λ π E ( σ e λ π G e(f E ) λ π G e(f π ) E ) = σ e (λ π G e(f E ) fe π e E which proes the claim., G K (f E ) G K (f π E ) We now proceed to analyzing, for a fixed global decision π Π, the fast scale dynamics (2.11). Let V (f, π) := e E f π e f e, = 0, 1,..., n 1, be the l 1 -distance between the current flows on the outgoing links of, and the flow associated to the aggregate path preference π, and V (f, π) := λ π λ, = 1, 2,..., n, with λ π := e E f e π and λ := e E f e, be the absolute difference between the current flow incoming in node, and the one associated to the aggregate path preference π. Also, let V0 (f, π) := 0. Lemma 3.2. For all = 0, 1,..., n 1, π Π, and f F, e E σ e H e (f, π) V (f, π) V (f, π). ) ) Proof. Writing G e for G e(f E, π), and using Lemma 3.1, one gets that σ e H e (f, π) = e E which proes the claim. e E σ e (λ G e f e ) = σ e (λ λ π )G e σ e (λ π G e fe π ) σ e (fe π f e ) e E e E λ λ π e E f π e f e = V (f, π) V (f, π), By combining Lemma 3.2, and Assumption 1, one gets the result below. Recall the definition of W (ρ, π) from (3.1), and that we are using the conention d x /dx = sgn(x) for all x R. Lemma 3.3. For eery f = µ(ρ) F, and π Π, ρ W (ρ, π) H(f, π) (1 α)v (f, π). e E 13

15 Proof. Obsere that, thanks to the acyclicity of the graph as per Assumption 1, if e E E w for some nodes and w, then necessarily w 1. Since α < 1, it follows that α 1 E (e)1 E w (e) α w1 1 E (e)1 E w (e), for eery 1 n, and 0 w n 1. Hence, α V (f, π) α f e fe π 0 <n = 0 <n e E 1 <n 0 w<n e E α w1 0 w<n e E α α w f e fe π 0 w<n = αv (f, π), α 1 E (e)1 E w (e) f e fe π e E w 1 E w (e) f e f π e 1 <n 1 E (e) where the last inequality follows from the fact that n 1 =1 1 E (e) n =1 1 E (e) = 1, and we recall (3.1) for the definition of V (f, π). Thus, Lemma 3.2 implies that ρ W (ρ, π) H(f, π) = α σ e H e (f, π) which proes the claim. 0 <n 0 <n e E α V (f, π) αv (f, π) V (f, π), 0 <n α V (f, π) 3.2. Boundedness of the traffic densities. We shall now proe a couple of results guaranteeing that the traffic density on eery link remains bounded in time. We start with the following result, guaranteeing that, on eery link e E, the flow associated to the current path preference, f π e (t), stays eentually bounded away from the maximum flow capacity C e. Its proof relies on Assumption 4. Recall that our formulation allows for both the cases of finite and infinite maximum flow capacity on a link. Lemma 3.4. For eery admissible perturbation h, there exists t 0 R, and, for eery link e E, a positie finite constant C e, dependent on h but not on η, such that, for eery initial condition π(0) int (S(P)), ρ(0) (0, ) E, f π e (t) C e < C e, t t 0, e E. Proof. The fact that f π e (t) 1 for all e E follows from the fact that the arrial rate at the origin is unitary. Therefore, for all e E with C e > 1 (and, hence also for C e = ), the claim follows triially with C e = 1 and t 0 = 0. We now proe the lemma for all e E with C e < 1. Recall that, by Definition 2.2, the domain of the admissible perturbation h is a closed set Π h int(π). This, in particular implies that κ e := C e sup{(aω) e : ω Π h } > 0. 14

16 It follows from (2.5) that C e κ e = sup{(aω) e : ω Π h } sup {(A argmin{ω A T (f) h(ω) : ω Π h }) e : f F} = sup {( AF h (f) ) e : f F}. (3.5) Hence, one has This implies that d dt f π e (t) = η ( A(F h (f(t)) π(t)) ) e η (C e κ e f π e ). f π e (t) C e κ e (f π e (0) C e κ e )e ηt e ηt, t 0, (3.6) where the last inequality follows from the fact that f π e (0) = p A epπ p (0) 1, and C e κ e. The lemma for e E with C e < 1 now follows from (3.6), by choosing, e.g., C e := C e κ/2 with κ := min{κ e : e E s.t. C e < 1}, and t 0 := η 1 log(κ/2). The following result shows that the actual flow f e (t) also stays bounded away from the maximum flow capacity C e. Lemma 3.5. For eery admissible perturbation h, there exists η > 0, and a positie finite constant C e, for eery e E, dependent on h but not on η, such that, for eery η < η, and eery initial condition π(0) int (S(P)), ρ(0) (0, ) E, for all t 0 and e E. Proof. For t 0, let us define f e (t) C e < C e, ζ(t) := W (ρ(t), π(t)), χ(t) := V (f(t), π(t)). Obsere that, thanks to Lemma 3.4, there exists t 0 0, and a positie constant C e for eery e E, such that, for eery t t 0, ρ π e (t) ρ e, ρ e := µ 1 e (C e ), e E. (3.7) Since ρ π e (t) 0, the aboe implies that, if ρ e (t) ρ π e (t) 2ρ e for some t t 0, then necessarily ρ e (t) 2ρ e for t t 0. Hence, f e (t) f π e (t) χ e for all t t 0, where χ e := µ e (2ρ e) C e. Obsere that, since µ e is strictly increasing by Assumption 2, one has χ e = µ e (2ρ e) C e > µ e (ρ e) C e = 0. Now, let Notice that ζ := 2 E max{ρ e : e E}, χ := α n 1 min{χ e : e E}. W (ρ, π) E max{ ρ e ρ π e ) : e E}, V (f, π) α n 1 f e f π e, e E. Therefore, it follows that, for any t t 0, if ζ(t) ζ, then for some e E, we hae that ρ e (t) ρ π e 2ρ e for t t 0. This in turn implies that χ(t) χ e χ. Therefore, in summary, ζ(t) ζ = χ(t) χ > 0, t t 0. (3.8) 15

17 On the other hand, obsere that (3.7) implies that there exists some l > 0 such that 0 <n α e E 1 µ e(ρ π e (t)) l, t t 0. By combining the aboe with Lemma 3.3, one finds that, for any u, t t 0, ζ(t) ζ(u) = t u 0 <n t u t t u α ( d σ e ds ρ e d ) ds ρπ e ds e E ρ W (ρ, π) H(f, π)ds u 0 <n α e E ( (1 α)χ(s) 2ηl) ds. η (AF h µ e(ρ π (f π )) e (Aπ) e ds e ) (3.9) Now, let us define η := (1 α)χ /(2l). By contradiction, let us assume that lim sup t f e (t) C e for some e E. Since f e (t) = µ e (ρ e (t)) < C e for eery t 0, this implies that lim sup t ρ e (t) =. This, together with (3.7) implies that lim sup t ζ(t) =. Then, in particular, the set T := {t > 0 : ζ(t) > ζ(s), s < t} is an unbounded union of open interals, with lim t T,t ζ(t) =. This, and (3.8) imply that there exists a non negatie constant t t 0 such that χ(t) χ, t T [t, ). For eery η < η, Equation (3.9) and the aboe gie ζ(t) ζ(u) t u ( (1 α)χ(s) 2ηl) ds t u ( (1 α)χ 2ηl) ds < 0 for eery t > u t such that t and u belong to the same connected component of T. But this contradicts the definition of the set T. Hence, if η < η, then lim sup t f e (t) < C e for eery e E. Since on eery compact time interal I R, one has sup t I f e (t) = f e (ˆt) < C e for some ˆt I, the foregoing implies the claim. The result below is a consequence of Lemma 3.5, and will proe useful in the sequel. Proposition 3.6. There exists K > 0, and t 1 0 such that, for eery initial condition π(0) int (S(P)), ρ(0) (0, ) E, π h(π(t)) K for all t t 1. Proof. First, obsere that, thanks to Lemma 3.5, there exists T > 0 such that T (f(t)) T for all t 0. Thanks to this, and Assumption 4, one has that F h (f(t)) int(π h ), and π h(f h (f(t))) = ΦA T (f(t)), where recall that Φ = I P 1 11 is the projection matrix corresponding to the projected gradient with respect to π on S(P). Hence, π h(f h (f(t))) Φ A T, which implies that there exists a conex compact K int(π h ) such that F h (f(t)) K for all t 0. Define (t) := η 1 e ηt t 0 16 e η(t s) F h (f(s))ds.

18 As (t) is an aerage of elements of the conex set K, necessarily (t) K for all t 0. Then, π(t) = e ηt π(0) (1 e ηt ) (t) approaches K, which implies that, for large enough t, π(t) K 1 int(π h ), where K 1 is a closed subset of int(π h ) that contains K. Hence, after large enough t, say t 1, π h(π(t)) stays bounded Estimating the distance between the current density and the one associated to the current path preference. We analyze here the behaior in time of W (ρ(t), π(t)). First, we hae the following result, characterizing the ariation of W (ρ, π) as a function of π. Recall that π = Φ π denotes the projected gradient with respect to π on S(P). Lemma 3.7. There exists l > 0, and t 0 0, such that, for eery initial condition π(0) int (S(P)), ρ(0) (0, ) E, π W (ρ(t), π(t)) (F h (f(t)) π(t)) 2l 1 α, t t 0. Proof. First, obsere that, thanks to Lemma 3.4, one has that there exists t 0 0 such that l e := sup{1/µ e(ρ π e (t)) : t t 0 } <. Put l := max{l e : e E}. Then, for eery path p P, and eery t t 0, one has W (ρ, π) π p = = α 0 <n e E α 0 <n e E α 0 <n 0 <n l 1 α, σ e σ e ρ π e πp ) µ 1 e πq (q A epπ q A ep 1 µ e(ρ π e ) e E α A ep l e e E (3.10) where the third inequality follows from the fact that, thanks to Assumption 1 on the acyclicity of the network, each path p P passes through at most one link e E. Therefore, 2l 1 α Fp h (f) W (ρ, π) π p p π p W (ρ, π) π p p Fp h (f) W (ρ, π) π p W (ρ, π) π p p π p p = π W (ρ, π) (F h (f) π), where the first inequality follows upon recalling that both F h (f), and π are probability ectors oer the path set P, and by using (3.10). We can now combine Lemmas 3.3 and 3.7, in order to get the following estimate of the behaior in time of W (ρ(t), π(t)). Lemma 3.8. There exist l > 0, L > 0, η > 0 and t 0 0 such that, for eery initial condition π(0) int (S(P)), ρ(0) (0, ) E, W (ρ(t), π(t)) 2ηlL (1 α) 2 ( W (ρ(t 0 ), π(t 0 )) 17 2ηlL ) (1 α) 2 e (1 α)(t t0)/l

19 for eery t t 0 and η < η. Proof. Define ζ(t) := W (ρ(t), π(t)). Notice that, thanks to Lemmas 3.4 and 3.5, there exist L > 0, η > 0 and t 0 0, such that, for any η < η, This in particular implies that ρ e (t) ρ π e (t) L f e (t) f π e (t), e E, t t 0. V (f(t), π(t)) 1 L W (ρ(t), π(t)) = 1 L ζ(t), η < η, t t 0. Obsere that W (ρ, π) is a Lipschitz function of ρ and π, while both ρ(t) and π(t) are Lipschitz on eery compact time interal. Therefore, ζ(t) is Lipschitz on eery compact time interal, and thus absolutely continuous. Hence, dζ(t)/dt exists for almost eery t 0, and, thanks to Lemmas 3.3 and 3.7, it satisfies d dt ζ(t) = d W (ρ(t), π(t)) dt = ρ W (ρ, π) H(f, π) η π W (ρ, π) (F h (f) π) (1 α)v (f, π) 2ηl 1 α (1 α) 2ηl ζ(t) L 1 α. Then, the claim follows by integrating both sides Proof of Theorem 2.5. We now proceed to proing Theorem 2.5. Let us introduce the function Θ : Π R, Θ(π) := e E f π e 0 T e (s) ds (3.11) and obsere that Θ(π) = ΦA T (f π ), π int(π). (3.12) In game-theoretic terminology, equation (3.12) implies that Θ(π) is the potential function [19] for the continuous-population congestion game with action space P and payoff ector function A T (f π ). 5 5 In fact, (3.12) is equialent to A eqt e(fe π ) A ept e(fe π ) = e e π q Θ(π) π p Θ(π) for eery p, q P, i.e., the difference between the total delays associated to the flow f π on paths q and p equals the limit incremental ratio of Θ(π) with respect to an infinitesimal mass transfer in π from path p to path q. Intuitiely, if a nonatomic drier, whose weight is infinitesimal in the continuum population model, switches path from p to q, the potential Θ increases by an infinitesimal amount equal to the product of the increase in the drier s delay cost times the drier s weight. 18

20 Obsere that, since T e (f e ) is increasing, one has that each term f π e T 0 e (f e ) df e is conex in fe π. Hence, the composition with the linear map π fe π = p A epπ p is conex in π, which in turn implies conexity of Θ oer Π. Then, for any admissible perturbation h : Π h R, Definition 2.2 implies strict conexity of Θ(π) h(π). Therefore, since Π h is compact and conex, there exists a unique minimizer π h := argmin {Θ(π) h(π) : π Π h }. (3.13) Let f (h) := f πh. Then, we hae the following: Lemma 3.9. Let {h k } be any sequence of admissible perturbation functions such that lim k h k = 0, lim k Π hk = Π. Then, lim f (hk) = f W. k Proof. Write π k for π h k, F k for F h k, and Π k for Π hk. Since {Aπ k } AΠ, and AΠ is compact, there exists a conerging sub-sequence {Aπ kj : j N}. Let us denote by f := lim j Aπ kj AΠ its limit, and choose some π Π such that f = Aπ. Notice that, since sup{t e (fe π ) : π Π h } < for all e E, Definition 2.2 implies that the minimizer in (3.13) has to be in the interior of Π h. As a consequence, one finds that necessarily π h(π kj ) = ΦA T (Aπ kj ), which in turn implies that F kj (Aπ kj ) = π kj. Then, using (2.5), one finds that (Aπ kj ) T (Aπ kj ) h kj (π kj ) (Aπ kj ) T (Aπ kj ) h kj (ω), (3.14) k for all ω Π kj. Now, fix any π Π. Since Π k Π, one has that there exists a sequence { π j } such that π j Π kj for all j, and lim j π j = π. Hence, taking ω = π j in (3.14), and passing to the limit as j grows large, one finds that (π ) A T (Aπ ) π A T (Aπ ), π Π. In turn, the aboe can be easily shown to be equialent to the condition (2.14) characterizing Wardrop equilibria. From the uniqueness of the Wardrop equilibrium, it follows that necessarily f = f W. Then the claim follows from the arbitrariness of the accumulation point f. We shall now estimate the time deriatie of Θ h (π) along trajectories of our dynamical system. For this, define Γ(t) := Θ(π(t)) h(π(t)), ψ(t) := ΦA T (f π (t)) π h(π(t))). (3.15) Then, using (3.12), one has d ( dt Γ(t) = π Θ h(π(t)) ) d dt π = ηψ(t) ( F h (f(t)) π(t) ) (3.16) = ηψ(t) ( F h (f π (t)) π(t) ) ηψ(t) ( F h (f(t)) F h (f π (t)) ). Lemma 3.8 implies that there exists t 2 0, η > 0 and M 1 > 0 such that, for any η < η, W (ρ(t), π(t)) ηm 1 for all t t 2. From the definition of W, it also follows that W (ρ, π) α n 1 ρ ρ π 1 for all ρ, π. Moreoer, following Assumption 2, with 19

On resilience of distributed routing in networks under cascade dynamics

On resilience of distributed routing in networks under cascade dynamics On resilience of distributed routing in networks under cascade dynamics Ketan Sala Giacomo Como Munther A. Dahleh Emilio Frazzoli Abstract We consider network flow oer graphs between a single origin-destination

More information

Online Companion to Pricing Services Subject to Congestion: Charge Per-Use Fees or Sell Subscriptions?

Online Companion to Pricing Services Subject to Congestion: Charge Per-Use Fees or Sell Subscriptions? Online Companion to Pricing Serices Subject to Congestion: Charge Per-Use Fees or Sell Subscriptions? Gérard P. Cachon Pnina Feldman Operations and Information Management, The Wharton School, Uniersity

More information

Dynamic Vehicle Routing with Heterogeneous Demands

Dynamic Vehicle Routing with Heterogeneous Demands Dynamic Vehicle Routing with Heterogeneous Demands Stephen L. Smith Marco Paone Francesco Bullo Emilio Frazzoli Abstract In this paper we study a ariation of the Dynamic Traeling Repairperson Problem DTRP

More information

Dynamic Vehicle Routing with Moving Demands Part II: High speed demands or low arrival rates

Dynamic Vehicle Routing with Moving Demands Part II: High speed demands or low arrival rates ACC 9, Submitted St. Louis, MO Dynamic Vehicle Routing with Moing Demands Part II: High speed demands or low arrial rates Stephen L. Smith Shaunak D. Bopardikar Francesco Bullo João P. Hespanha Abstract

More information

Final Exam (Solution) Economics 501b Microeconomic Theory

Final Exam (Solution) Economics 501b Microeconomic Theory Dirk Bergemann and Johannes Hoerner Department of Economics Yale Uniersity Final Exam (Solution) Economics 5b Microeconomic Theory May This is a closed-book exam. The exam lasts for 8 minutes. Please write

More information

Computing Laboratory A GAME-BASED ABSTRACTION-REFINEMENT FRAMEWORK FOR MARKOV DECISION PROCESSES

Computing Laboratory A GAME-BASED ABSTRACTION-REFINEMENT FRAMEWORK FOR MARKOV DECISION PROCESSES Computing Laboratory A GAME-BASED ABSTRACTION-REFINEMENT FRAMEWORK FOR MARKOV DECISION PROCESSES Mark Kattenbelt Marta Kwiatkowska Gethin Norman Daid Parker CL-RR-08-06 Oxford Uniersity Computing Laboratory

More information

A possible mechanism to explain wave-particle duality L D HOWE No current affiliation PACS Numbers: r, w, k

A possible mechanism to explain wave-particle duality L D HOWE No current affiliation PACS Numbers: r, w, k A possible mechanism to explain wae-particle duality L D HOWE No current affiliation PACS Numbers: 0.50.-r, 03.65.-w, 05.60.-k Abstract The relationship between light speed energy and the kinetic energy

More information

On the Linear Threshold Model for Diffusion of Innovations in Multiplex Social Networks

On the Linear Threshold Model for Diffusion of Innovations in Multiplex Social Networks On the Linear Threshold Model for Diffusion of Innoations in Multiplex Social Networks Yaofeng Desmond Zhong 1, Vaibha Sriastaa 2 and Naomi Ehrich Leonard 1 Abstract Diffusion of innoations in social networks

More information

OPTIMIZATION OF FLOWS AND ANALYSIS OF EQUILIBRIA IN TELECOMMUNICATION NETWORKS

OPTIMIZATION OF FLOWS AND ANALYSIS OF EQUILIBRIA IN TELECOMMUNICATION NETWORKS OPTIMIZATION OF FLOWS AND ANALYSIS OF EQUILIBRIA IN TELECOMMUNICATION NETWORKS Ciro D Apice (a, Rosanna Manzo (b, Luigi Rarità (c (a, (b, (c Department of Information Engineering and Applied Mathematics,

More information

Balanced Partitions of Vector Sequences

Balanced Partitions of Vector Sequences Balanced Partitions of Vector Sequences Imre Bárány Benjamin Doerr December 20, 2004 Abstract Let d,r N and be any norm on R d. Let B denote the unit ball with respect to this norm. We show that any sequence

More information

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec pp. ec1 ec31

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec pp. ec1 ec31 MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi 10.1287/mnsc.1060.0650ec pp. ec1 ec31 e-companion ONLY AVAILABLE IN ELECTRONIC FORM informs 2007 INFORMS Electronic Companion Temporary and Permanent Buyout Prices in Online Auctions

More information

Reversal in time order of interactive events: Collision of inclined rods

Reversal in time order of interactive events: Collision of inclined rods Reersal in time order of interactie eents: Collision of inclined rods Published in The European Journal of Physics Eur. J. Phys. 27 819-824 http://www.iop.org/ej/abstract/0143-0807/27/4/013 Chandru Iyer

More information

The Inverse Function Theorem

The Inverse Function Theorem Inerse Function Theorem April, 3 The Inerse Function Theorem Suppose and Y are Banach spaces and f : Y is C (continuousl differentiable) Under what circumstances does a (local) inerse f exist? In the simplest

More information

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics Ozan Candogan, Asuman Ozdaglar and Pablo A. Parrilo January 29, 2012 Abstract Potential games are a special class of games for which many adaptive user dynamics

More information

Integer Parameter Synthesis for Real-time Systems

Integer Parameter Synthesis for Real-time Systems 1 Integer Parameter Synthesis for Real-time Systems Aleksandra Joanoić, Didier Lime and Oliier H. Roux École Centrale de Nantes - IRCCyN UMR CNRS 6597 Nantes, France Abstract We proide a subclass of parametric

More information

A Regularization Framework for Learning from Graph Data

A Regularization Framework for Learning from Graph Data A Regularization Framework for Learning from Graph Data Dengyong Zhou Max Planck Institute for Biological Cybernetics Spemannstr. 38, 7076 Tuebingen, Germany Bernhard Schölkopf Max Planck Institute for

More information

Section 6: PRISMATIC BEAMS. Beam Theory

Section 6: PRISMATIC BEAMS. Beam Theory Beam Theory There are two types of beam theory aailable to craft beam element formulations from. They are Bernoulli-Euler beam theory Timoshenko beam theory One learns the details of Bernoulli-Euler beam

More information

Dynamic Vehicle Routing with Moving Demands Part II: High speed demands or low arrival rates

Dynamic Vehicle Routing with Moving Demands Part II: High speed demands or low arrival rates Dynamic Vehicle Routing with Moing Demands Part II: High speed demands or low arrial rates Stephen L. Smith Shaunak D. Bopardikar Francesco Bullo João P. Hespanha Abstract In the companion paper we introduced

More information

Transmission lines using a distributed equivalent circuit

Transmission lines using a distributed equivalent circuit Cambridge Uniersity Press 978-1-107-02600-1 - Transmission Lines Equialent Circuits, Electromagnetic Theory, and Photons Part 1 Transmission lines using a distributed equialent circuit in this web serice

More information

Towards Universal Cover Decoding

Towards Universal Cover Decoding International Symposium on Information Theory and its Applications, ISITA2008 Auckland, New Zealand, 7-10, December, 2008 Towards Uniersal Coer Decoding Nathan Axig, Deanna Dreher, Katherine Morrison,

More information

An Elastic Contact Problem with Normal Compliance and Memory Term

An Elastic Contact Problem with Normal Compliance and Memory Term Machine Dynamics Research 2012, Vol. 36, No 1, 15 25 Abstract An Elastic Contact Problem with Normal Compliance and Memory Term Mikäel Barboteu, Ahmad Ramadan, Mircea Sofonea Uniersité de Perpignan, France

More information

The Riemann-Roch Theorem: a Proof, an Extension, and an Application MATH 780, Spring 2019

The Riemann-Roch Theorem: a Proof, an Extension, and an Application MATH 780, Spring 2019 The Riemann-Roch Theorem: a Proof, an Extension, and an Application MATH 780, Spring 2019 This handout continues the notational conentions of the preious one on the Riemann-Roch Theorem, with one slight

More information

0 a 3 a 2 a 3 0 a 1 a 2 a 1 0

0 a 3 a 2 a 3 0 a 1 a 2 a 1 0 Chapter Flow kinematics Vector and tensor formulae This introductory section presents a brief account of different definitions of ector and tensor analysis that will be used in the following chapters.

More information

Purpose of the experiment

Purpose of the experiment Impulse and Momentum PES 116 Adanced Physics Lab I Purpose of the experiment Measure a cart s momentum change and compare to the impulse it receies. Compare aerage and peak forces in impulses. To put the

More information

Scalar multiplication and algebraic direction of a vector

Scalar multiplication and algebraic direction of a vector Roberto s Notes on Linear Algebra Chapter 1: Geometric ectors Section 5 Scalar multiplication and algebraic direction of a ector What you need to know already: of a geometric ectors. Length and geometric

More information

Collective circular motion of multi-vehicle systems with sensory limitations

Collective circular motion of multi-vehicle systems with sensory limitations Collectie circular motion of multi-ehicle systems with sensory limitations Nicola Ceccarelli, Mauro Di Marco, Andrea Garulli, Antonello Giannitrapani Dipartimento di Ingegneria dell Informazione Uniersità

More information

THE DESCRIPTIVE COMPLEXITY OF SERIES REARRANGEMENTS

THE DESCRIPTIVE COMPLEXITY OF SERIES REARRANGEMENTS THE DESCRIPTIVE COMPLEXITY OF SERIES REARRANGEMENTS MICHAEL P. COHEN Abstract. We consider the descriptie complexity of some subsets of the infinite permutation group S which arise naturally from the classical

More information

Network Flow Problems Luis Goddyn, Math 408

Network Flow Problems Luis Goddyn, Math 408 Network Flow Problems Luis Goddyn, Math 48 Let D = (V, A) be a directed graph, and let s, t V (D). For S V we write δ + (S) = {u A : u S, S} and δ (S) = {u A : u S, S} for the in-arcs and out-arcs of S

More information

The Kinetic Theory of Gases

The Kinetic Theory of Gases 978-1-107-1788-3 Classical and Quantum Thermal Physics The Kinetic Theory of Gases CHAPTER 1 1.0 Kinetic Theory, Classical and Quantum Thermodynamics Two important components of the unierse are: the matter

More information

Theory of Network Communication

Theory of Network Communication Theory of Network Communication Dr. Christian Scheideler Johns Hopkins Uniersity, Sept. 9 2002 Introduction The goal of this lecture is to gie an introduction to the state of the art in the theory of network

More information

VISUAL PHYSICS ONLINE RECTLINEAR MOTION: UNIFORM ACCELERATION

VISUAL PHYSICS ONLINE RECTLINEAR MOTION: UNIFORM ACCELERATION VISUAL PHYSICS ONLINE RECTLINEAR MOTION: UNIFORM ACCELERATION Predict Obsere Explain Exercise 1 Take an A4 sheet of paper and a heay object (cricket ball, basketball, brick, book, etc). Predict what will

More information

OVERVIEW OF TATE S THESIS

OVERVIEW OF TATE S THESIS OVERVIEW O TATE S THESIS ALEX MINE Abstract. This paper gies an oeriew of the main idea of John Tate s 1950 PhD thesis. I will explain the methods he used without going into too much technical detail.

More information

arxiv: v2 [math.co] 12 Jul 2009

arxiv: v2 [math.co] 12 Jul 2009 A Proof of the Molecular Conjecture Naoki Katoh and Shin-ichi Tanigawa arxi:0902.02362 [math.co] 12 Jul 2009 Department of Architecture and Architectural Engineering, Kyoto Uniersity, Kyoto Daigaku Katsura,

More information

Dynamic Vehicle Routing for Translating Demands: Stability Analysis and Receding-Horizon Policies

Dynamic Vehicle Routing for Translating Demands: Stability Analysis and Receding-Horizon Policies 1 Dynamic Vehicle Routing for Translating Demands: Stability Analysis and Receding-Horizon Policies Shaunak D. Bopardikar Stephen L. Smith Francesco Bullo João P. Hespanha Abstract We introduce a problem

More information

1 Lyapunov theory of stability

1 Lyapunov theory of stability M.Kawski, APM 581 Diff Equns Intro to Lyapunov theory. November 15, 29 1 1 Lyapunov theory of stability Introduction. Lyapunov s second (or direct) method provides tools for studying (asymptotic) stability

More information

Bc. Dominik Lachman. Bruhat-Tits buildings

Bc. Dominik Lachman. Bruhat-Tits buildings MASTER THESIS Bc. Dominik Lachman Bruhat-Tits buildings Department of Algebra Superisor of the master thesis: Study programme: Study branch: Mgr. Vítězsla Kala, Ph.D. Mathematics Mathematical structure

More information

LECTURE 15: COMPLETENESS AND CONVEXITY

LECTURE 15: COMPLETENESS AND CONVEXITY LECTURE 15: COMPLETENESS AND CONVEXITY 1. The Hopf-Rinow Theorem Recall that a Riemannian manifold (M, g) is called geodesically complete if the maximal defining interval of any geodesic is R. On the other

More information

Math Mathematical Notation

Math Mathematical Notation Math 160 - Mathematical Notation Purpose One goal in any course is to properly use the language of that subject. Finite Mathematics is no different and may often seem like a foreign language. These notations

More information

4. A Physical Model for an Electron with Angular Momentum. An Electron in a Bohr Orbit. The Quantum Magnet Resulting from Orbital Motion.

4. A Physical Model for an Electron with Angular Momentum. An Electron in a Bohr Orbit. The Quantum Magnet Resulting from Orbital Motion. 4. A Physical Model for an Electron with Angular Momentum. An Electron in a Bohr Orbit. The Quantum Magnet Resulting from Orbital Motion. We now hae deeloped a ector model that allows the ready isualization

More information

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics Ozan Candogan, Asuman Ozdaglar and Pablo A. Parrilo September 6, 2011 Abstract Potential games are a special class of games for which many adaptive user dynamics

More information

Stability of Feedback Solutions for Infinite Horizon Noncooperative Differential Games

Stability of Feedback Solutions for Infinite Horizon Noncooperative Differential Games Stability of Feedback Solutions for Infinite Horizon Noncooperative Differential Games Alberto Bressan ) and Khai T. Nguyen ) *) Department of Mathematics, Penn State University **) Department of Mathematics,

More information

Lecture 1. 1 Overview. 2 Maximum Flow. COMPSCI 532: Design and Analysis of Algorithms August 26, 2015

Lecture 1. 1 Overview. 2 Maximum Flow. COMPSCI 532: Design and Analysis of Algorithms August 26, 2015 COMPSCI 532: Design and Analysis of Algorithms August 26, 205 Lecture Lecturer: Debmalya Panigrahi Scribe: Allen Xiao Oeriew In this lecture, we will define the maximum flow problem and discuss two algorithms

More information

An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control

An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control Vasile Staicu University of Aveiro UNICA, May 2018 Vasile Staicu (University of Aveiro) An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control UNICA, May 2018

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.co] 25 Apr 2016

arxiv: v1 [math.co] 25 Apr 2016 On the zone complexity of a ertex Shira Zerbib arxi:604.07268 [math.co] 25 Apr 206 April 26, 206 Abstract Let L be a set of n lines in the real projectie plane in general position. We show that there exists

More information

SINCE the passage of the Telecommunications Act in 1996,

SINCE the passage of the Telecommunications Act in 1996, JOURNAL ON SELECTED AREAS IN COMMUNICATIONS, VOL. XX, NO. XX, MONTH 20XX 1 Partially Optimal Routing Daron Acemoglu, Ramesh Johari, Member, IEEE, Asuman Ozdaglar, Member, IEEE Abstract Most large-scale

More information

A Geometric Review of Linear Algebra

A Geometric Review of Linear Algebra A Geometric Reiew of Linear Algebra The following is a compact reiew of the primary concepts of linear algebra. The order of presentation is unconentional, with emphasis on geometric intuition rather than

More information

Partially Optimal Routing

Partially Optimal Routing Partially Optimal Routing Daron Acemoglu, Ramesh Johari, and Asuman Ozdaglar May 27, 2006 Abstract Most large-scale communication networks, such as the Internet, consist of interconnected administrative

More information

BAYESIAN PREMIUM AND ASYMPTOTIC APPROXIMATION FOR A CLASS OF LOSS FUNCTIONS

BAYESIAN PREMIUM AND ASYMPTOTIC APPROXIMATION FOR A CLASS OF LOSS FUNCTIONS TH USHNG HOUS ROCDNGS OF TH ROMANAN ACADMY Series A OF TH ROMANAN ACADMY Volume 6 Number 3/005 pp 000-000 AYSAN RMUM AND ASYMTOTC AROMATON FOR A CASS OF OSS FUNCTONS Roxana CUMARA Department of Mathematics

More information

4 Fundamentals of Continuum Thermomechanics

4 Fundamentals of Continuum Thermomechanics 4 Fundamentals of Continuum Thermomechanics In this Chapter, the laws of thermodynamics are reiewed and formulated for a continuum. The classical theory of thermodynamics, which is concerned with simple

More information

Collective circular motion of multi-vehicle systems with sensory limitations

Collective circular motion of multi-vehicle systems with sensory limitations Proceedings of the 44th IEEE Conference on Decision and Control, and the European Control Conference 2005 Seille, Spain, December 12-15, 2005 MoB032 Collectie circular motion of multi-ehicle systems with

More information

FREEWAY WEAVING. Highway Capacity Manual 2000 CHAPTER 24 CONTENTS EXHIBITS

FREEWAY WEAVING. Highway Capacity Manual 2000 CHAPTER 24 CONTENTS EXHIBITS CHAPTER 24 FREEWAY WEAVING CONTENTS I. INTRODUCTION... 24-1 Scope of the Methodology...24-1 Limitations of the Methodology...24-1 II. METHODOLOGY...24-1 LOS...24-2 Weaing Segment Parameters...24-3 Determining

More information

PRODUCTS IN CONDITIONAL EXTREME VALUE MODEL

PRODUCTS IN CONDITIONAL EXTREME VALUE MODEL PRODUCTS IN CONDITIONAL ETREME VALUE MODEL RAJAT SUBHRA HAZRA AND KRISHANU MAULIK Abstract. The classical multiariate extreme alue theory tries to capture the extremal dependence between the components

More information

4-vectors. Chapter Definition of 4-vectors

4-vectors. Chapter Definition of 4-vectors Chapter 12 4-ectors Copyright 2004 by Daid Morin, morin@physics.harard.edu We now come to a ery powerful concept in relatiity, namely that of 4-ectors. Although it is possible to derie eerything in special

More information

An Explicit Lower Bound of 5n o(n) for Boolean Circuits

An Explicit Lower Bound of 5n o(n) for Boolean Circuits An Eplicit Lower Bound of 5n o(n) for Boolean Circuits Kazuo Iwama, Oded Lachish, Hiroki Morizumi, and Ran Raz Graduate School of Informatics, Kyoto Uniersity, Kyoto, JAPAN {iwama, morizumi}@kuis.kyoto-u.ac.jp

More information

Lecture 5: The Bellman Equation

Lecture 5: The Bellman Equation Lecture 5: The Bellman Equation Florian Scheuer 1 Plan Prove properties of the Bellman equation (In particular, existence and uniqueness of solution) Use this to prove properties of the solution Think

More information

The Budgeted Minimum Cost Flow Problem with Unit Upgrading Cost

The Budgeted Minimum Cost Flow Problem with Unit Upgrading Cost The Budgeted Minimum Cost Flow Problem with Unit Upgrading Cost Christina Büsing Sarah Kirchner Arie Koster Annika Thome October 6, 2015 Abstract The budgeted minimum cost flow problem (BMCF(K)) with unit

More information

Astrometric Errors Correlated Strongly Across Multiple SIRTF Images

Astrometric Errors Correlated Strongly Across Multiple SIRTF Images Astrometric Errors Correlated Strongly Across Multiple SIRTF Images John Fowler 28 March 23 The possibility exists that after pointing transfer has been performed for each BCD (i.e. a calibrated image

More information

Asymptotic Normality of an Entropy Estimator with Exponentially Decaying Bias

Asymptotic Normality of an Entropy Estimator with Exponentially Decaying Bias Asymptotic Normality of an Entropy Estimator with Exponentially Decaying Bias Zhiyi Zhang Department of Mathematics and Statistics Uniersity of North Carolina at Charlotte Charlotte, NC 28223 Abstract

More information

A Geometric Review of Linear Algebra

A Geometric Review of Linear Algebra A Geometric Reiew of Linear Algebra The following is a compact reiew of the primary concepts of linear algebra. I assume the reader is familiar with basic (i.e., high school) algebra and trigonometry.

More information

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Chiaki Hara April 5, 2004 Abstract We give a theorem on the existence of an equilibrium price vector for an excess

More information

Optimization Problems in Multiple Subtree Graphs

Optimization Problems in Multiple Subtree Graphs Optimization Problems in Multiple Subtree Graphs Danny Hermelin Dror Rawitz February 28, 2010 Abstract We study arious optimization problems in t-subtree graphs, the intersection graphs of t- subtrees,

More information

DESIGN METHOD BASED ON THE CONCEPT OF EMERGENCE AND ITS APPLICATION

DESIGN METHOD BASED ON THE CONCEPT OF EMERGENCE AND ITS APPLICATION DESIGN METHOD BASED ON THE CONCEPT OF EMERGENCE AND ITS APPLICATION Koichiro Sato¹ and Yoshiyuki Matsuoka 2 ¹ Graduate School of Science and Technology, Keio Uniersity, Yokohama, Japan Koichiro_Sato@a7.keio.jp,

More information

Dynamic Vehicle Routing with Moving Demands Part I: Low speed demands and high arrival rates

Dynamic Vehicle Routing with Moving Demands Part I: Low speed demands and high arrival rates ACC 2009, Submitted St. Louis, MO Dynamic Vehicle Routing with Moing Demands Part I: Low speed demands and high arrial rates Shaunak D. Bopardikar Stephen L. Smith Francesco Bullo João P. Hespanha Abstract

More information

Towards Green Distributed Storage Systems

Towards Green Distributed Storage Systems Towards Green Distributed Storage Systems Abdelrahman M. Ibrahim, Ahmed A. Zewail, and Aylin Yener Wireless Communications and Networking Laboratory (WCAN) Electrical Engineering Department The Pennsylania

More information

A spectral Turán theorem

A spectral Turán theorem A spectral Turán theorem Fan Chung Abstract If all nonzero eigenalues of the (normalized) Laplacian of a graph G are close to, then G is t-turán in the sense that any subgraph of G containing no K t+ contains

More information

ISSN BCAM Do Quality Ladders Rationalise the Observed Engel Curves? Vincenzo Merella University of Cagliari.

ISSN BCAM Do Quality Ladders Rationalise the Observed Engel Curves? Vincenzo Merella University of Cagliari. Birkbeck Centre for Applied Macroeconomics ISSN 1745-8587 BCAM 1401 Do Quality Ladders Rationalise the Obsered Engel Cures? incenzo Merella Uniersity of Cagliari March 2014 Birkbeck, Uniersity of London

More information

Are the two relativistic theories compatible?

Are the two relativistic theories compatible? Are the two relatiistic theories compatible? F. Selleri Dipartimento di Fisica - Uniersità di Bari INFN - Sezione di Bari In a famous relatiistic argument ("clock paradox") a clock U 1 is at rest in an

More information

Selecting Efficient Correlated Equilibria Through Distributed Learning. Jason R. Marden

Selecting Efficient Correlated Equilibria Through Distributed Learning. Jason R. Marden 1 Selecting Efficient Correlated Equilibria Through Distributed Learning Jason R. Marden Abstract A learning rule is completely uncoupled if each player s behavior is conditioned only on his own realized

More information

Course 212: Academic Year Section 1: Metric Spaces

Course 212: Academic Year Section 1: Metric Spaces Course 212: Academic Year 1991-2 Section 1: Metric Spaces D. R. Wilkins Contents 1 Metric Spaces 3 1.1 Distance Functions and Metric Spaces............. 3 1.2 Convergence and Continuity in Metric Spaces.........

More information

Information Propagation Speed in Bidirectional Vehicular Delay Tolerant Networks

Information Propagation Speed in Bidirectional Vehicular Delay Tolerant Networks Information Propagation Speed in Bidirectional Vehicular Delay Tolerant Networks Emmanuel Baccelli, Philippe Jacquet, Bernard Mans, Georgios Rodolakis INRIA, France, {firstname.lastname}@inria.fr Macquarie

More information

DO PHYSICS ONLINE. WEB activity: Use the web to find out more about: Aristotle, Copernicus, Kepler, Galileo and Newton.

DO PHYSICS ONLINE. WEB activity: Use the web to find out more about: Aristotle, Copernicus, Kepler, Galileo and Newton. DO PHYSICS ONLINE DISPLACEMENT VELOCITY ACCELERATION The objects that make up space are in motion, we moe, soccer balls moe, the Earth moes, electrons moe, - - -. Motion implies change. The study of the

More information

Real Gas Thermodynamics. and the isentropic behavior of substances. P. Nederstigt

Real Gas Thermodynamics. and the isentropic behavior of substances. P. Nederstigt Real Gas Thermodynamics and the isentropic behaior of substances. Nederstigt ii Real Gas Thermodynamics and the isentropic behaior of substances by. Nederstigt in partial fulfillment of the requirements

More information

Analysis Finite and Infinite Sets The Real Numbers The Cantor Set

Analysis Finite and Infinite Sets The Real Numbers The Cantor Set Analysis Finite and Infinite Sets Definition. An initial segment is {n N n n 0 }. Definition. A finite set can be put into one-to-one correspondence with an initial segment. The empty set is also considered

More information

WARDROP EQUILIBRIA IN AN INFINITE NETWORK

WARDROP EQUILIBRIA IN AN INFINITE NETWORK LE MATEMATICHE Vol. LV (2000) Fasc. I, pp. 1728 WARDROP EQUILIBRIA IN AN INFINITE NETWORK BRUCE CALVERT In a nite network, there is a classical theory of trafc ow, which gives existence of a Wardrop equilibrium

More information

Position in the xy plane y position x position

Position in the xy plane y position x position Robust Control of an Underactuated Surface Vessel with Thruster Dynamics K. Y. Pettersen and O. Egeland Department of Engineering Cybernetics Norwegian Uniersity of Science and Technology N- Trondheim,

More information

Patterns of Non-Simple Continued Fractions

Patterns of Non-Simple Continued Fractions Patterns of Non-Simple Continued Fractions Jesse Schmieg A final report written for the Uniersity of Minnesota Undergraduate Research Opportunities Program Adisor: Professor John Greene March 01 Contents

More information

MECHANICAL FORMULATION OF THE ENTROPY OF A SYSTEM

MECHANICAL FORMULATION OF THE ENTROPY OF A SYSTEM JOHN RIUS CAMPS MECHANICAL FORMULATION OF THE ENTROPY OF A SYSTEM 6 TH FEBRUARY 009 ORDIS EDITIONS ORDIS EDITIONS GRAN VIA DE CARLOS III, 59, º, 4ª BARCELONA 0808 6 TH June 008 3 4 . INTRODUCTION. What

More information

Two-sided bounds for L p -norms of combinations of products of independent random variables

Two-sided bounds for L p -norms of combinations of products of independent random variables Two-sided bounds for L p -norms of combinations of products of independent random ariables Ewa Damek (based on the joint work with Rafał Latała, Piotr Nayar and Tomasz Tkocz) Wrocław Uniersity, Uniersity

More information

Simulations of bulk phases. Periodic boundaries. Cubic boxes

Simulations of bulk phases. Periodic boundaries. Cubic boxes Simulations of bulk phases ChE210D Today's lecture: considerations for setting up and running simulations of bulk, isotropic phases (e.g., liquids and gases) Periodic boundaries Cubic boxes In simulations

More information

LECTURE 2: CROSS PRODUCTS, MULTILINEARITY, AND AREAS OF PARALLELOGRAMS

LECTURE 2: CROSS PRODUCTS, MULTILINEARITY, AND AREAS OF PARALLELOGRAMS LECTURE : CROSS PRODUCTS, MULTILINEARITY, AND AREAS OF PARALLELOGRAMS MA1111: LINEAR ALGEBRA I, MICHAELMAS 016 1. Finishing up dot products Last time we stated the following theorem, for which I owe you

More information

Minimal error certificates for detection of faulty sensors using convex optimization

Minimal error certificates for detection of faulty sensors using convex optimization Forty-Seenth Annual Allerton Conference Allerton House, UIUC, Illinois, USA September 30 - October 2, 2009 Minimal error certificates for detection of faulty sensors using conex optimization Christian

More information

The Pentagram map: a discrete integrable system

The Pentagram map: a discrete integrable system The Pentagram map: a discrete integrable system Valentin Osienko Richard Schwartz Serge Tabachniko Abstract The pentagram map is a projectiely natural transformation defined on (twisted) polygons. A twisted

More information

Plasma electron hole kinematics. I. Momentum conservation

Plasma electron hole kinematics. I. Momentum conservation Plasma electron hole kinematics. I. Momentum conseration The MIT Faculty has made this article openly aailable. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters. Citation As Published Publisher

More information

Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces

Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces Bernhard Schmitzer October 19, 2017 1 Convex non-smooth optimization with proximal operators Remark 1.1 (Motivation). Convex optimization: easier to solve,

More information

Trajectory Estimation for Tactical Ballistic Missiles in Terminal Phase Using On-line Input Estimator

Trajectory Estimation for Tactical Ballistic Missiles in Terminal Phase Using On-line Input Estimator Proc. Natl. Sci. Counc. ROC(A) Vol. 23, No. 5, 1999. pp. 644-653 Trajectory Estimation for Tactical Ballistic Missiles in Terminal Phase Using On-line Input Estimator SOU-CHEN LEE, YU-CHAO HUANG, AND CHENG-YU

More information

Optima and Equilibria for Traffic Flow on Networks with Backward Propagating Queues

Optima and Equilibria for Traffic Flow on Networks with Backward Propagating Queues Optima and Equilibria for Traffic Flow on Networks with Backward Propagating Queues Alberto Bressan and Khai T Nguyen Department of Mathematics, Penn State University University Park, PA 16802, USA e-mails:

More information

An Optimal Split-Plot Design for Performing a Mixture-Process Experiment

An Optimal Split-Plot Design for Performing a Mixture-Process Experiment Science Journal of Applied Mathematics and Statistics 217; 5(1): 15-23 http://www.sciencepublishinggroup.com/j/sjams doi: 1.11648/j.sjams.21751.13 ISSN: 2376-9491 (Print); ISSN: 2376-9513 (Online) An Optimal

More information

Metric Spaces and Topology

Metric Spaces and Topology Chapter 2 Metric Spaces and Topology From an engineering perspective, the most important way to construct a topology on a set is to define the topology in terms of a metric on the set. This approach underlies

More information

Rate of Convergence of Learning in Social Networks

Rate of Convergence of Learning in Social Networks Rate of Convergence of Learning in Social Networks Ilan Lobel, Daron Acemoglu, Munther Dahleh and Asuman Ozdaglar Massachusetts Institute of Technology Cambridge, MA Abstract We study the rate of convergence

More information

State-space Modelling of Hysteresis-based Control Schemes

State-space Modelling of Hysteresis-based Control Schemes European Control Conference (ECC) July 7-9,, Zürich, Switzerland. State-space Modelling of Hysteresis-based Control Schemes Soumya Kundu Ian A. Hiskens Abstract The paper deelops a state-space model for

More information

Algorithms Demands and Bounds. Demands and Bounds. Design and Analysis of Algorithms Andrei Bulatov

Algorithms Demands and Bounds. Demands and Bounds. Design and Analysis of Algorithms Andrei Bulatov Algorithms Demands and Bounds Demands and Bounds Design and Analysis of Algorithms Andrei Bulato Algorithms Demands and Bounds 1- Demands In our flow network model there is only 1 source and sink Can we

More information

On reachability under uncertainty. A.B.Kurzhanski. Moscow State University. P.Varaiya. University of California at Berkeley

On reachability under uncertainty. A.B.Kurzhanski. Moscow State University. P.Varaiya. University of California at Berkeley On reachability under uncertainty A.B.Kurzhanski Moscow State Uniersity P.Varaiya Uniersity of California at Berkeley Abstract. The paper studies the problem of reachability for linear systems in the presence

More information

Dynamic Lot Size Problems with One-way Product Substitution 1

Dynamic Lot Size Problems with One-way Product Substitution 1 This is the Pre-Published Version. 03/2002/100057 ynamic Lot Size Problems with One-way Product Substitution 1 Vernon Ning Hsu School of Management George Mason Uniersity Fairfax, VA 22030, USA email hsu@gmu.edu

More information

DEVIL PHYSICS THE BADDEST CLASS ON CAMPUS AP PHYSICS

DEVIL PHYSICS THE BADDEST CLASS ON CAMPUS AP PHYSICS DEVIL PHYSICS THE BADDEST CLASS ON CAMPUS AP PHYSICS LSN 7-4: CONSERVATION OF ENERGY AND MOMENTUM IN COLLISIONS LSN 7-5: ELASTIC COLLISIONS IN ONE DIMENSION LSN 7-6: INELASTIC COLLISIONS Questions From

More information

s P = f(ξ n )(x i x i 1 ). i=1

s P = f(ξ n )(x i x i 1 ). i=1 Compactness and total boundedness via nets The aim of this chapter is to define the notion of a net (generalized sequence) and to characterize compactness and total boundedness by this important topological

More information

UNDERSTAND MOTION IN ONE AND TWO DIMENSIONS

UNDERSTAND MOTION IN ONE AND TWO DIMENSIONS SUBAREA I. COMPETENCY 1.0 UNDERSTAND MOTION IN ONE AND TWO DIMENSIONS MECHANICS Skill 1.1 Calculating displacement, aerage elocity, instantaneous elocity, and acceleration in a gien frame of reference

More information

Dynamics in network games with local coordination and global congestion effects

Dynamics in network games with local coordination and global congestion effects Dynamics in network games with local coordination and global congestion effects Gianluca Brero, Giacomo Como, and Fabio Fagnani Abstract Several strategic interactions over social networks display both

More information

Preliminary Results on Social Learning with Partial Observations

Preliminary Results on Social Learning with Partial Observations Preliminary Results on Social Learning with Partial Observations Ilan Lobel, Daron Acemoglu, Munther Dahleh and Asuman Ozdaglar ABSTRACT We study a model of social learning with partial observations from

More information

Cases of integrability corresponding to the motion of a pendulum on the two-dimensional plane

Cases of integrability corresponding to the motion of a pendulum on the two-dimensional plane Cases of integrability corresponding to the motion of a pendulum on the two-dimensional plane MAXIM V. SHAMOLIN Lomonoso Moscow State Uniersity Institute of Mechanics Michurinskii Ae.,, 99 Moscow RUSSIAN

More information

Symmetric Functions and Difference Equations with Asymptotically Period-two Solutions

Symmetric Functions and Difference Equations with Asymptotically Period-two Solutions International Journal of Difference Equations ISSN 0973-532, Volume 4, Number, pp. 43 48 (2009) http://campus.mst.edu/ijde Symmetric Functions Difference Equations with Asymptotically Period-two Solutions

More information