Walrasian Equilibrium Computation, Network Formation, and the Wen Theorem

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Walrasian Equilibrium Computation, Network Formation, and the Wen Theorem"

Transcription

1 Review of Development Economics, 6(3), 45 47, 00 Walrasian Equilibrium Computation, Network Formation, and the Wen Theorem Shuntian Yao* Abstract The paper studies the Walrasian equilibrium theory of division of labor for large economies with weakly convex production techniques and with the presence of transaction costs. Earlier results published by Wen are revised and generalized so that the new versions can be applied to a much larger category of economic models. A simple example demonstrates how the theoretical results can be used for Walrasian equilibrium computation and equilibrium network structure identification.. Introduction Economic growth and development are two of the most challenging issues facing all developed and developing countries. All countries require a good international economic environment, and each country itself needs to improve its domestic economic infrastructure. Both these issues can be related to so-called economic networking theory, which studies how economic agents should choose their activities, how they should choose their trading partners, and how they could improve transaction efficiency; and in general, how they can maximize their utility with their given resources. As is well known, given some economic resource, different economic infrastructures or different economic networking decisions can lead to totally different economic outcomes. China can serve as a convincing example. Following the introduction of economic reforms, China has developed a more efficient economic network for its domestic market and for its international affairs. The per capita GNP of the Chinese economy has more than tripled over the past 0 years or so. Most recently, because of the rapid development of the computer industry and Internet communication, all economic agents are potentially linked to a worldwide e-commerce network. This, on the one hand, gives more freedom to any economic agent (including any developing country) to make decisions. However, the decision process becomes more complicated because the agent has to deal with more variables than before. In this sense, the study of economic networking theory has become more important for development economists. The topics addressed by this paper are some of the basic analytical issues in the general-equilibrium theory of economic networks. As will be seen later, the results presented here provide a systematic approach for computation of general equilibria and for identification of equilibrium network structures. As pioneers in applying inframarginal analysis to increasing-returns-to-scale economic models, Xiaokai Yang and Yew Kwang Ng, together with many of their colleagues, have made a series of helpful contributions to the general-equilibrium theory of division of labor and economic networking theory (e.g., Yang and Ng, 998; Wen, 998a,b; Ng, 00). They have investigated many typical examples, with interesting results. For example, they have shown that, as the transaction costs in an economy * Yao: Division of Applied Economics, Nanyang Business School, Nanyang Technological University, Singapore. Tel: ; astyao@ntu.edu.sg. I wish to thank Mei Wen for helpful discussion., 08 Cowley Road, Oxford OX4 JF, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 048, USA

2 46 Shuntian Yao became sufficiently low, a higher level of division of labor should lead to a higherefficiency general equilibrium. To concentrate on the relationship between economic efficiency and specialization, in most of their examples Yang and his colleagues consider simple models with a population of identical individuals and with a limited number of goods. The most interesting feature of the general equilibria of these examples is that, when the transaction costs are low, the ex-ante identical individuals, aiming at utility maximization, divide themselves into several groups, each group choosing a different configuration and trading with the other groups of individuals. Such a configuration is characterized by the subset of goods to be produced, the subset of goods to be sold, and the subset of goods to be bought. In the Yang Ng framework, determining the different basic configurations is the most important step in both the equilibrium existence proof and the equilibrium computation (Sun et al., 000). In this respect, the following result referred to as the Wen theorem by Yang and his colleagues (Yang, 00), plays a very important role: In any Walrasian market with any price vector given, any rational agent with convex production technique will never sell more than one of her produces, and will never simultaneously produce and buy the same good. With the help of this, they can divide the population of ex-ante identical agents into several groups, each consisting of those selling one single good. They can then compute an equilibrium at which all agents in the same group choose the same optimal decision, and a trading network is formed. However, as I will show in the next section, what Mei Wen proved (998a, p ; and 998b) does not have the general implications mentioned above. Moreover, some of her claims appear to be false.. Wen s Result and a Counter Example What is referred to as the Wen theorem is her following result in Wen (998a): Consider an economy E with a population of individuals and a finite number of goods and with the presence of transaction costs. Assume that the following assumptions hold. () Every individual in E has a strictly quasi-concave and twice continuously differentiable utility function. () The production function f i of every individual i satisfies either (i) f i ( ) > 0, f i ( ) > 0, and f i is continuous for l i > 0; or (ii) f i (l i ) = a i l i - b i, where a i,b i > 0. (3) Every transaction function has positive first derivative and nonnegative second derivative in the whole domain. Then given any price vector p for the goods, the optimal decision of any individual does not involve buying and selling the same good, does not involve selling more than one good, and does not involve self-providing and buying the same good. In Wen s proof, her arguments under assumption (i) are correct, but the requirements in (i) are too strong. Actually, in order to derive the consequences we need only assume the strict convexity of the production functions (see later). It is well known that production functions with positive second derivative in the whole domain just form an extremely tiny subset of the set of strictly convex production functions. In most of the examples studied by Yang, Ng, and their colleagues, the conditions in (i) were not satisfied, and Wen s result was inappropriately applied. With regard to Wen s assumption (ii), what Wen should have used is the following functional form:

3 f ( l )= max { 0, al -b}; i i i i i otherwise the meaning of negative quantities of the produce needs to be explained. The main reason for Wen to choose the functional form in (ii) seems to be that the inverse of the production function is required in her arguments for not involving buying and selling the same good (Wen, 998a, p. 74). But under her assumption that the transaction efficiency k is below, claim in her analysis could be easily established without using the existence of the inverse production function. Wen s claim (selling one good at most) is not correct under assumption (ii). In her arguments for claim, she did pay attention to (ii). However, in discussing the sign of p j a j - p k a k she ignored the case of p j a j - p k a k = 0, and it is then that claim is false! Let us turn to Wen s claim 3 (not self-providing and buying the same good). On the one hand her argument relies on the conclusion of claim, which is false under assumption (ii). On the other hand, to establish the consequence, she requires the strict inequality: Ê pi0 ˆ X ( l)= f ()+ l Á ( - ) + ( - )> Ë p f l l k pi0 j j i j p kf j i l l j WALRASIAN EQUILIBRIUM COMPUTATION 47 The inequality could be false for a weakly convex transaction function k j under assumption (ii) (where all the f i =0), because k j =0 will lead to X j (l) = 0. Thus Wen s arguments in claim 3 are only good for the case under assumption (i). j A Counter Example To see that Wen s claim is false under her assumption (ii), let us consider an economy E with four goods {,, 3, 4} and a set of agents I. Assume that one of the agents has an initial endowment of unit of labor, and has the same utility function given by u(w, x, y, z) = wxyz, where w, x, y, and z are, respectively, the quantities of good, good, good 3, and good 4 she consumes. Assume that this agent has a set of production functions q j = max{0, L j - 0.}, j =, and q j = max{0, L k - 0.6}, k = 3, 4. Here L j is the amount of labor allocated for good j s production, and L k is the amount of labor for good k s production. Finally assume that, because of the presence of the transaction costs, when this agent buys y j units of any good j, the amount she actually receives is 0.6y j. Let us imagine that a price vector p = (,,, ) is announced by the referee. We look at the optimal decision of this agent. If she chooses autarky, because of the fixed learning costs, she can never produce these four goods simultaneously all in positive amounts. As a result her maximal utility in an autarky is 0. On the other hand, if she wants to trade, in view of her production technology and the market prices she should never produce good 3 or good 4; instead she should produce good or good or both, selling part of her produces in exchange for the other two goods. We first consider the case in which she produces good only. We may assume that she allocates all her labor towards good production, producing 0.9 units of good, then selling x units of good for buying good, selling y units of good again for buying good 3, and selling y units of good again for buying good 4. Because of the transaction costs, she will consume x - y units of good, 0.6x units of good, and 0.6(y) units of each of the other two goods. As a result she gets a utility of u = (0.9 - x - y)(0.6x)(.y). By elementary calculus it is easy to verify that her utility is maximized at x = 9/40 and y = 9/40. The maximal utility in this case is 4(0.6) 3 (9/40) 4 = 0.00.

4 48 Shuntian Yao The second case is that she produces good only. By symmetry it is easy to see that her maximal utility in this case is also 4(0.6) 3 (9/40) 4. Now consider the third case in which this agent produces both good and good. In view of her production technique and the transaction costs, when these two goods are produced she will no longer buy one of them by selling the other; i.e., her consumption of these two goods will be all self-provided. On the other hand, she will sell part of her produce for buying good 3 and good 4. By symmetry, she does not care which good she sells as long as she has sufficient of it left for self-consumption. Let us assume that she self-consumes x units of each of good and good. Since she can produce 0.8 units of these two goods as a whole, she will sell x units of them in the market, which is sufficient for buying x of each of the other two goods. (Note that the price of good or good is twice as high as that of good 3 or good 4.) Because of the transaction costs, her utility will be u = x [0.6(0.8 - x)], which is maximized at x = 0..The maximal utility is (0.) (0.4) = Compared with the first two cases, this case gives the highest utility she can achieve. To sum up, with the price vector p = (,,, ) given, this agent has a continuum of different optimal decisions: allocating l units of labor for good s production and - l units of labor for good s production (0.3 l 0.7), keeping 0. units of good and 0. units of good for self-consumption, selling all the remainder of them for buying 0.4 units of each of good 3 and good 4. In particular, when l = 0.5, she sells 0. units of each of good and good. Thus Wen theorem does not hold in this example. 3. Revised Theorems Although most readers may be familiar with the definitions and properties of weakly convex functions and strictly convex functions, for convenience I present a brief review here. For more details refer to Stromberg (98), for example. Definition. A function f:[0, ] Æ R is said to be weakly convex if, for any x, x Œ[0, ],x< x and any l Œ (0, ): f( lx+ ( -l) x ) lf( x)+ ( -l) f( x ). () Moreover, f is said to be strictly convex if in the above inequality the sign is replaced with <. Proposition. Assume that f:[0, ] Æ R is weakly convex. Then for any x Œ [0, ], Dx > 0, and a > 0 such that x + a +Dx, it holds that f( x+ a+ Dx)- f( x+ a) f( x+ a)- f( x). Dx a () Moreover, if f is strictly convex, then the above inequality holds with replaced by >. Proof. Choose l =Dx/(a +Dx) and x =x + a +Dx in (). It is easy to verify that - l = a/(a +Dx) and that lx + ( - l)x =x + a. As a result we have f ( x x + a ) a x f x a D ( )+ + a x f ( x + a + D x ). D + D (3)

5 WALRASIAN EQUILIBRIUM COMPUTATION 49 On multiplying both sides of (3) by (a +Dx) and re-arranging terms, we obtain [ ] [ + ] a f( x+ a+ Dx)- f( x+ a) Dx f( x a)- f( x). On dividing both sides of (4) by adx, () thus follows. (4) We now consider a Walrasian market with m goods. Assume that a price vector p >> 0 for all these goods is given. Assume that an agent is endowed with unit of labor. A decision by her consists of 3m nonnegative variables: L j, Dx j, Dy j, j =,...,m, where L j is the amount of labor she allocates for good j s production, Dx j is the amount of good j she sells, and Dy j is the amount of good j she buys. We will denote by f j her production function for good j, and by g j her transaction function for good j. Assume that this agent has a continuous utility function given by u = u(z,...,z m ), where z j is the amount of good j she consumes. Statement of Theorem Consider a Walrasian market with m goods with or without transaction costs; i.e., g j (y j ) < y j or g j (y j ) = y j, respectively. Assume that the utility function u is continuous and is nondecreasing in each of the variables. Assume that the production functions f j are all defined and weakly convex on [0, ]. Then for any given price vector p >> 0, the maximal utility U(p) for this agent can always be achieved by a decision to sell no more than one good. Moreover, if u is strictly increasing in each of the variables and all the f j are strictly convex on [0, ], then any utility-maximization decision made by her must involve no more than one good being sold. Proof of Theorem First consider the case that u is nondecreasing and the f j are weakly convex. Assume that u is maximized by a decision in which there are two or more goods being sold. It suffices to show that this agent can reduce the number of goods sold and still achieve the same maximal utility. Assume that originally good and good are sold by her. Let L and L, respectively, be the amounts of labor she allocates for the production of these two goods. Let x and x, respectively, be the quantities of these two goods produced. Let Dx and Dx, respectively, be the amounts of them being sold. Let l j be the amount of labor satisfying f j (l j ) = x j -Dx j, j =,. Let Dl j = L j - l j. We then have Dxj = fj( lj + Dlj)- fj( lj), j =,. (5) Let p j be the price of good j. Then the contribution to the budget by selling these two goods is where  pj[ fj( lj + Dlj)- fj( lj) ]= k Dl + k Dl j= k j [ ] pj fj( lj + Dlj)- fj( lj) =. Dl j, (6) (7) Proof of the first part of the theorem It suffices to show that this agent can achieve a looser (or at least not tighter) budget for buying through reallocating labor on the

6 40 Shuntian Yao production of these two goods, selling just one of them but not changing the selfconsumed amounts of each, and not changing the other part of her decision on production and selling of the other goods (if any).we need to consider two different cases. Case (i): k k In this case we will consider her decision to sell good only. Imagine that she now allocates just l units of labor for good s production, producing x -Dx units of good all for self-consumption; and she allocates l +Dl +Dl units of labor on good s production, consuming the same amount x -Dx = f (l ) as before. By selling the other part of good, she receives an amount of money [ ] p f( l + Dl + Dl)- f( l) = p[ f( l + Dl + Dl)- f( l + Dl) ]+ p[ f( l + Dl)- f( l) ] p[ f( l + Dl + Dl)- f( l + Dl) ] = Dl + Dl p f ( l + D l )- f ( l ) Dl Dl p[ f( l + Dl)- f( l) ] ( Dl + Dl) = ( Dl + Dl ) k Dl k Dl + k Dl. Thus we can see by selling good only, she can really guarantee a budget at least as good as before, and, as a result, she can achieve a utility either greater than or at least equal to the original one. Note that, in deriving the above inequality, Proposition was applied to obtain [ ] [ + ] = p f( l + Dl + Dl)- f( l + Dl) Dl p f( l Dl)- f( l) k. Dl [ ] (8) Case (ii): k > k In this case we consider her decision to sell good only. Assume that she allocates l +Dl +Dl units of labor for good s production, and l units of labor for good s production. Using a very similar argument to that for case (i), we can conclude that by selling good only, she can guarantee a looser budget and can achieve a higher utility. On combining cases (i) and (ii), the first part of the theorem is proved. Proof of the second part of the theorem Simply note that when strict convexity is assumed, the expression (8) becomes a strict inequality. As a result, this agent can always achieve a higher budget by reducing the number of goods sold. She can thus buy more and consumes more. In view of the strictly increasing property of her utility function, she can thus achieve a higher utility. Statement of Theorem Consider a Walrasian market with m goods as described in Theorem. Assume that all the transaction functions g j are weakly convex (including the linear case). If all the f j of the agent are weakly convex and her utility function u is nondecreasing in each of the variables, then for any given price vector p >> 0 her maximal utility U(p) can be always achieved by a decision to not buy and produce the same good simultaneously. Moreover, if the f j are strictly convex and u is strictly increasing in each variable, then any utility-maximization decision by her must not allow any good being simultaneously produced and purchased.

7 WALRASIAN EQUILIBRIUM COMPUTATION 4 Proof of Theorem Proof of the first part of the theorem Assume that p is given, and that in her utilitymaximization decision the agent produces and purchases good simultaneously. According to Theorem, we may assume she sells just one good, say good. (Obviously in any case there is no need for her to sell and buy the same good.) Let p j be the market price of good j. Let x = f (l ) be the amount of good she produces for herself. Let y be the amount of good she buys. Let x = f (l +Dl ) be the amount of good she produces, and x -Dx = f(l ) be the amount of good she would just require if she had no need to buy y units of good. Thus Dl is the amount of labor she can save if she does not buy good. We then have y = ( p p) [ f( l + D l)- f( l) ]. (9) Because of the presence of the transaction costs, the actual amount of good she receives from the market is Ê p Dx g D (0) p f l l f l ˆ = [ ( + )- ( ) ] Ë. Let us fix l and define h(x) = g ((p /p )[f (l + x) - f (l )]). Note that h is a weakly convex function; this is because f (l + x) is weakly convex and increasing in x, and (p /p )[f (l + x) - f (l )] is linear in f (l + x) and hence weakly convex and increasing in x. As a composite function of two weakly convex increasing functions, h is also weakly convex. With our new notation we can write Dx = h( Dl), () and consider the following two new decision options of the agent. In option (i), she saves Dl units of labor from the production of good, not selling Dx units of good to exchange for good but adding the saved amount of labor Dl to l for good s production. As a result she will consume f (l +Dl ) units of good and the same amounts of good and all the other goods as before. In option (ii), she does not produce good at all, adding l units of labor saved to l +Dl for good production, selling f (l +Dl + l ) - f (l ) units of good to exchange for good.as a result she will consume h(dl + l ) units of good and the same amounts of good and all the other goods as before. The first part of the theorem will be proved if we can show that at least one of f (l +Dl ) and h(dl + l ) is not less than f (l ) + h(dl ), which is the original amount of good she consumes. Define k and k by f( l) h l h l h 0 k = k = ( D ) ( D )- (), =, () l Dl Dl where we have used the fact that h(0) = 0. We first consider the case k k. With the help of Proposition we have f( L+ Dl)- f( l) f l f( l+ Dl)= Dl + ( ) l Dl l k ( Dl + l ) k l + k Dl = f ( l )+ h( Dl ), which implies that the new option (i) is better than (or at least not worse than) her old decision.

8 4 Shuntian Yao We now consider the case k > k. We have h( Dl + l)- h( Dl) h( Dl + l)= l + h( Dl) l h( Dl)- h() 0 l + h( Dl) Dl = k l + h( Dl )> k l + h( Dl )= f ( l )+ h( Dl ), which implies that option (ii) is better than her old decision. As a result, the first part of Theorem is proved. Proof of the second part of the theorem Simply note that the strict convexity of the production functions implies the strict convexity of h. As a result either option (i) or (ii) will lead to a higher amount of good being consumed than in her original decision. 4. Equilibrium Computation and Network Formation In most published computed examples of general-equilibrium models of a pure exchange economy, the convexity of the consumption sets is assumed and the agents preferences are assumed to be strictly quasiconcave. With such assumptions, given any price vector, each individual has but a unique optimal decision. To compute the optimal decision of every individual in terms of the prices, an equilibrium price vector can be then determined by the market-clearing conditions. In all these examples, net trade occurs only between ex-ante different agents, either because they have different utility functions, or because they have different initial endowments. In Walrasian models where the convexity of the consumption sets or the convexity of the production sets is lacking, although equilibrium existence can still be established for large economies with the convexification idea, no systematic computation method has been proposed. The difficulty is that, given any price vector, an agent usually has quite a few different optimal decisions, all leading to the same maximal utility, but any convex combination of these decisions is no longer feasible to her. On the other hand, if all ex-ante identical agents in the population choose the same optimal decision, the market would not be cleared. As a result, a general equilibrium can be achieved only when the mass of ex-ante identical agents divide into several groups, each group with a suitable measure, and when agents in different groups choose different optimal decisions. An important feature of these economic models is that net trades may occur between ex-ante identical agents. The importance of the Wen theorem is that it provides a systematic approach for the equilibrium computation where convexity is lacking and convexification is required. To explain the application of the two new theorems established in the last section, I next consider a large economy E with m goods and a continuum set I = [0, ] of ex-ante identical consumer producers, each being endowed with unit of labor. I will use the same notations as before, f j for the production functions, g j for the transaction functions, and u for the utility function. Denote by Lj i the labor units that i allocates for good j s production, by xj i the amount of good j that i sells, and by yj i the amount of good j that i buys. We will assume weak convexity of the production functions, linearity of the transaction functions, and a continuous and nondecreasing utility function. In addition we also assume the following property of u: for any given j and any given z > 0,...,z j- > 0, z j+ > 0,...,z m > 0, it holds that

9 WALRASIAN EQUILIBRIUM COMPUTATION 43 lim zj Æ uz (,..., zj-, zj, zj+,..., zm)=. (3) It is easy to see that, as a special example, the Cobb Douglas utility functions satisfy all the requirements mentioned here. Definition. Given a large economy E as described above, a price vector p >> 0 together with a decision d i = (L i j, x i j, y i j: j =,...,m) for each and every agent i Œ I is said to be a Walrasian equilibrium of E if (i) the decision of every consumer producer is a utility-maximizing decision under p, and (ii) the market for every good is cleared under p and the abovementioned individuals decisions. While the existence of a Walrasian equilibrium is an easy consequence following the idea of the classical equilibrium theory for large economies with the convexification trick (Zhou et al., 999; Hildenbrand, 974), the computation problem, as mentioned above, has never been systematically addressed before. The existence proof itself does not provide any computational approach. On the other hand, the revised Wen theorems do provide a systematic approach for equilibrium computation. The general algorithm consists of three steps:. Divide the population of agents into m groups with the measure of the mass w j in group j to be determined later. Assume that every agent in group j is allowed to sell good j only if she does want to sell anything. (She is allowed, however, to produce any good and buy any good.) Assume that all the agents in the same group choose the same optimal decision, and compute a constrained optimal decision d j (p) and the constrained maximal utility U j (p) for every member in each group j in terms of the prices (p,...,p m ). Here we use the word constrained because each agent in group j is allowed to sell good j only.. Compute a price vector p* which equates the maximal utilities of the agents across all different groups: U (p*) =...= U m (p*) = U(p*). 3. Determine the measure of the mass w* j 0 of each group by the market-clearing conditions under the price vector p*. (Note that w* j = 0 means that no agents are in group j, and good j is not sold in the market although it may still be produced.) Proposition. Assume that the price vector p* and the weights w* j have been computed in the above algorithm. Then p* together with the d* j d j (p*) (chosen by every agent in group j) is a Walrasian equilibrium. 3 Proof. The maximal utility U( p*) that every agent receives in the above algorithm is under the constraint that she is allowed to sell only one specific good. We need to show that this is actually the maximal utility she can achieve under p* even if such a constraint is removed. In fact, according to Theorem, given p*, it is always possible for her to achieve the (unconstrained) maximal utility U by choosing a decision to sell no more than one good. Let this be good j; then U = U j (p*) = U(p*). The result of Proposition 3 thus follows. The trade network of this Walrasian equilibrium can be constructed in the following procedure: (a) Vertices. Assume that at the abovementioned equilibrium, I is divided into m groups: I = G... G m, but only the first n groups are of positive measure, which means that at the equilibrium only the first n goods are traded. To construct

10 44 Shuntian Yao the network, we first draw n vertices v,...,v n, each denoted by a small circle, with v j representing group j. Inside the small circle of each vertex we put w* j, which is the measure of the mass of agents in group j(j =,...,n). (b) Reflexive arcs. If each of the members in group j produces amount x j h of good h for self-consumption, then an arc jj labeled with h is constructed, starting from and ending at the same vertex v j. (c) Nonreflexive arcs. If each of the members in group j buys an amount y j k of good k, then an arc kh labeled with k is constructed, starting from vertex v k and ending at vertex v j. Thus the equilibrium network structure constructed above is a weighted digraph. I explain all the details of equilibrium computation and network construction with a simple example in the next section. 5. A Simple Example Consider a large economy E with three goods {,, 3} and a continuum of ex-ante identical agents I = [0, ]. Each agent is endowed with unit of labor. The production functions of each agent are given by f j (L j ) = L j, j =,, and f 3 (L 3 ) = max{0, L 3-0.5}. The transaction functions are given by g j (y j ) = ky j, j =,, 3, k Π[0, ]. The utility function for every agent is given by u(z, z, z 3 ) = z z z 3. With the symmetry in good and good, one can expect that the equilibrium price vector has the form of (,, p). According to the revised Wen theorems, we can divide the population into three groups: G, G, and G 3, with agents in each G j selling only good j (if they sell anything at all) and not simultaneously producing and buying the same good. Assume that the measures of masses in group j is w j. By symmetry we may assume w = w = w, and w 3 = - w. The value of w will be determined in the final stage. Under the price vector (,, p), consider the decision of any agent in group G. She may choose autarky, allocating l units of labor for the production of each of good and good, and - l units of labor for the production of good 3, achieving a utility of u = l (0.5 - l). By elementary calculus it is easy to verify that the best she can do in an autarky structure is to choose l = /6, so - l = 4/6, yielding a utility of /6. The second option for the agent is to produce and sell part of good, to self-provide good, and to buy good 3 from the market. Assume that she allocates l units of labor for good s production and - l units of labor for good s production, selling x units of good in order to buy x/p units of good 3. Her utility is then u = (l - x)( - l)(kx/p), which is maximized at l = /3 and x = /3. The maximal utility is k/7p. The third option for the agent is to produce and sell part of good, to self-provide good 3, and to buy good. Assume that she allocates l units of labor for good s production and - l units of labor for good 3 s production, selling x units of good in order to buy x units of good. Her utility is then u = (l - x)(kx)(0.5 - l), which is maximized at l = /3 and x = /6. The maximal utility is k/6, which is not greater than the maximal utility in autarky no matter what value k assumes. The last option is to produce and sell part of good, and to buy both good and good 3. Assuming she sells x units of good, buying y units of good and y 3 units of good 3. The budget constraint is x = y + py 3. If we write y = y, then y 3 = (x - y)/p.her utility is u = ( - x)(ky)[k(x - y)/p], which is maximized at x = /3 and y = /3. The maximal utility is k /7p, which is not greater than the maximal utility in the second option no matter what value k assumes. To sum up, we have:

11 WALRASIAN EQUILIBRIUM COMPUTATION 45 (a) Any agent in group will choose autarky if k/p < /8, and choose the second option if k/p > /8. (By symmetry) (b) Any agent in group will choose autarky if k/p < /8, and choose self-providing good and buying good 3 if k/p > /8. Now consider the decision of any agent in group 3. If she chooses autarky, her maximal utility is /6. If she produces and sells part of good 3, self-provides good, and buys good, she has a utility of u = ( - l)(kpx)(l x), where l is the amount of labor allocated for good 3 s production, - l is the amount of labor allocated for good s production, and x is the amount of good 3 she sells in order to buy px units of good. The maximal utility is kp/6, achieved at l = 5/6 and x = /6. If she produces and sells part of good 3, self-provides good, and buys good, she ends up with the same maximal utility. Finally she may produce good 3 only and buy both good and good. Let x be the amount of good 3 she sells, y the amount of good she buys; then (px - y) is the amount of good she buys. Her utility is then u = ky[k(px - y)](0.5 - x), which is maximized at x = /3 and y = p/6. The maximal utility is (kp) /6. To sum up, we have: (c) Any agent in group 3 will choose the autarky if kp <, and choose the last option (buying both good and good ) if kp >. If trade does occur among the three groups, at any equilibrium, individuals across all groups must have the same maximal utility, otherwise there is an incentive for individuals of some group to switch to another group. Thus, comparing (a) and (b) with (c), any equilibrium price vector for an active trade market must equate k/7p with (kp) /6, from which one can solve p = /k /3, which is the equilibrium price for good 3. Now it is not difficult to verify that, with the equilibrium price vector (,, /k /3 ):. If k < / 8, we have both k/p < /8 and kp <, and the only Walrasian equilibrium network is the autarky structure.. If k > / 8, we have both k/p > /8 and kp >, and one Walrasian equilibrium network is with three vertices v, v, and v 3. In v, every agent produces /3 units of good and /3 units of good, selling /3 units of good in order to buy k /3 /6 units of good 3. In v, each agent produces /3 units of good and /3 units of good, selling /3 units of good in order to buy k /3 /6 units of good 3. In v 3 each agent allocates all her labor for good 3 s production, producing 0.5 units of good 3, selling /3 units of it in order to buy p/6 units of each of good and good. Finally to determine the measure of the mass of each group, we use the market-clearing condition, say for good 3: ( - w)(/3) = w(k /3 /6). We thus obtain w = /( + k /3 ). 3. In particular, when the transaction costs for good 3 is zero (k = ), the equilibrium price vector is (,, ), the measures of the masses in the three groups are all equal to /3, and the equilibrium utility for every agent is /54 four times as large as the maximal utility from autarky! The equilibrium structures are depicted in Figure. It is interesting to note that, in the final two equilibrium structures, the costs of high production technology (or high fixed learning costs) paid by the good 3 producers are compensated by the high equilibrium price they receive for their produce.

12 46 Shuntian Yao k</8 / 3 /8 / <k< 3 3 k= Figure. The Equilibrium Network Structures Remarks. (i) In this example we do not have an equilibrium structure with complete division of labor for any k <, which results from the linearity of the production functions for good and good. In fact it is not rational to sell one of them to buy another, unless the transaction cost is 0. (ii) In most of situations there is no unique equilibrium structure. 6. Conclusion These results can be applied to economic models with weakly convex production functions. They can be applied to the computation of a Walrasian equilibrium of a large economy with a continuum of ex-ante identical consumer producers. In fact the results can also be applied to economic models with finitely many types of ex-ante different agents, although the argument and the computation will be much more complicated. References Hildenbrand, Werner, Core and Equilibria of a Large Economy, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press (974).

13 WALRASIAN EQUILIBRIUM COMPUTATION 47 Ng, Yew-Kwang, Infra-marginal versus Marginal Analysis of Networking Decisions and E- Commerce, a speech at the International Symposium of E-Commerce and Networking Decisions, Monash University (00). Stromberg, Karl R., An Introduction to Classical Real Analysis, Dordrecht: Kluwer (98). Sun, Yang, and Yao, Theoretical Foundation of Economic Development Based on Networking Decisions in the Competitive Market, Harvard Center for International Development working paper 7 (999). Wen, Mei, An Analytical Framework of Consumer Producers, Economies of Specialization and Transaction Costs, in Arrow, Ng, and Yang (eds), Increasing Returns and Economic Analysis, London: Macmillan (998a):70 85., The Dichotomy between Production and Consumption Decisions and Economic Efficiency, University of Melbourne Economics Department working paper (998b). Yang, Xiaokai and Siang Ng, Specialization and Division of Labor: A Survey, in Arrow, Ng, and Yang (eds), Increasing Returns and Economic Analysis, London: Macmillan (998):3 63. Yang, Xiaokai and Yimin Zhao, Endogenous Transaction Costs and Evolution of Division of Labor, Monash University Economics Department working paper (998). Zhou, Sun, and Yang, General Equilibrium in Large Economies with Endogenous Structure of Division of Labor, Monash University Economics Department working paper (998). Notes. Note that linear functions are included in the class of weakly convex functions.. Note that, unlike in case (i), here we have a strict inequality k > k. 3. For the general existence proof of the p* and the w* j, refer to Sun et al. (999).

General Equilibrium and Welfare

General Equilibrium and Welfare and Welfare Lectures 2 and 3, ECON 4240 Spring 2017 University of Oslo 24.01.2017 and 31.01.2017 1/37 Outline General equilibrium: look at many markets at the same time. Here all prices determined in the

More information

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction Microeconomic Theory -- Introduction. Introduction. Profit maximizing firm with monopoly power 6 3. General results on maximizing with two variables 8 4. Model of a private ownership economy 5. Consumer

More information

Competitive Equilibrium

Competitive Equilibrium Competitive Equilibrium Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 16, October 26 Outline 1 Pareto Effi ciency 2 The Core 3 Planner s Problem(s) 4 Competitive (Walrasian) Equilibrium Decentralized vs. Centralized Economic

More information

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions 1. For each of the following propositions, state whether the proposition is true or false. If true, provide a proof (or at least indicate how a proof could

More information

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice Economics 101 Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice 1 Uncle Léon The canonical model of exchange in economics is sometimes referred to as the Walrasian Model, after the early economist Léon

More information

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers The Ohio State University Department of Economics Econ. 805 Winter 00 Prof. James Peck Homework Set Questions and Answers. Consider the following pure exchange economy with two consumers and two goods.

More information

Introduction to General Equilibrium

Introduction to General Equilibrium Introduction to General Equilibrium Juan Manuel Puerta November 6, 2009 Introduction So far we discussed markets in isolation. We studied the quantities and welfare that results under different assumptions

More information

Market Equilibrium and the Core

Market Equilibrium and the Core Market Equilibrium and the Core Ram Singh Lecture 3-4 September 22/25, 2017 Ram Singh (DSE) Market Equilibrium September 22/25, 2017 1 / 19 Market Exchange: Basics Let us introduce price in our pure exchange

More information

Week 6: Consumer Theory Part 1 (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 1)

Week 6: Consumer Theory Part 1 (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 1) Week 6: Consumer Theory Part 1 (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 1) Tsun-Feng Chiang* *School of Economics, Henan University, Kaifeng, China November 2, 2014 1 / 28 Primitive Notions 1.1 Primitive Notions Consumer

More information

Adding Production to the Theory

Adding Production to the Theory Adding Production to the Theory We begin by considering the simplest situation that includes production: two goods, both of which have consumption value, but one of which can be transformed into the other.

More information

Contracts under Asymmetric Information

Contracts under Asymmetric Information Contracts under Asymmetric Information 1 I Aristotle, economy (oiko and nemo) and the idea of exchange values, subsequently adapted by Ricardo and Marx. Classical economists. An economy consists of a set

More information

1 General Equilibrium

1 General Equilibrium 1 General Equilibrium 1.1 Pure Exchange Economy goods, consumers agent : preferences < or utility : R + R initial endowments, R + consumption bundle, =( 1 ) R + Definition 1 An allocation, =( 1 ) is feasible

More information

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions.

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions. Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 3: Optimization - interior optima 1 Session: 11-12 Aug 2015 (Thu/Fri) 10:00am 1:00pm I. Optimization: introduction Decision-makers (e.g. consumers,

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Question 1. (p p) (x(p, w ) x(p, w)) 0. with strict inequality if x(p, w) x(p, w ).

Question 1. (p p) (x(p, w ) x(p, w)) 0. with strict inequality if x(p, w) x(p, w ). University of California, Davis Date: August 24, 2017 Department of Economics Time: 5 hours Microeconomics Reading Time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Please answer any three

More information

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics Wednesday September 6 th : Lecture 5 Gerzensee, September 2017 Roger E. A. Farmer Warwick University and NIESR Topics for Lecture 5 Sunspots (Cass-Shell paper)

More information

GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production

GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 8, September 21 Outline 1 Generalized Axiom of Revealed Preferences 2 Afriat s Theorem 3 Production Sets and Production Functions 4 Profits

More information

On the Shapley-Scarf Economy: The Case of Multiple Types of Indivisible Goods

On the Shapley-Scarf Economy: The Case of Multiple Types of Indivisible Goods On the Shapley-Scarf Economy: The Case of Multiple Types of Indivisible Goods Hideo Konishi Thomas Quint Jun Wako April, 1997 (first version) October 1997 (revised) July 20, 2000 (second revision) file

More information

Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A

Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A December, 2016, Ted Bergstrom, UCSB I asked students to try to answer any 7 of the 8 questions. I intended the exam to have some relatively easy parts and

More information

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

September Math Course: First Order Derivative September Math Course: First Order Derivative Arina Nikandrova Functions Function y = f (x), where x is either be a scalar or a vector of several variables (x,..., x n ), can be thought of as a rule which

More information

Notes on General Equilibrium

Notes on General Equilibrium Notes on General Equilibrium Alejandro Saporiti Alejandro Saporiti (Copyright) General Equilibrium 1 / 42 General equilibrium Reference: Jehle and Reny, Advanced Microeconomic Theory, 3rd ed., Pearson

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 6: Partial and General Equilibrium

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 6: Partial and General Equilibrium Advanced Microeconomic Theory Chapter 6: Partial and General Equilibrium Outline Partial Equilibrium Analysis General Equilibrium Analysis Comparative Statics Welfare Analysis Advanced Microeconomic Theory

More information

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics Ram Singh Lecture 6 September 29, 2015 Ram Singh: (DSE) General Equilibrium Analysis September 29, 2015 1 / 14 First Fundamental Theorem The First Fundamental

More information

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework. Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework. Economy: I consumers, i = 1,...I. J firms, j = 1,...J. L goods, l = 1,...L Initial Endowment of good l in the economy: ω l 0, l = 1,...L. Consumer i : preferences

More information

Problem Set Suggested Answers

Problem Set Suggested Answers Problem Set 3 --- Suggested Answers 1. In chapters 15 18 the treatment is generalized to unbounded production technologies, resulting in the observation that when general equilibrium prices are announced,

More information

On the Maximal Domain Theorem

On the Maximal Domain Theorem On the Maximal Domain Theorem Yi-You Yang April 28, 2016 Abstract The maximal domain theorem by Gul and Stacchetti (J. Econ. Theory 87 (1999), 95-124) shows that for markets with indivisible objects and

More information

First Welfare Theorem

First Welfare Theorem First Welfare Theorem Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 17, October 31 Outline 1 First Welfare Theorem 2 Preliminaries to Second Welfare Theorem Past Definitions A feasible allocation (ˆx, ŷ) is Pareto optimal

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 17, 2009. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 7 November 17, 2009. 1 / 54 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy Andrew McLennan October 28, 2014 Economics 7250 Advanced Mathematical Techniques for Economics Second Semester 2014 Lecture 15 The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy I. Introduction A. The material discussed

More information

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key EconS 503 - Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key 1. WEAs with market power. Consider an exchange economy with two consumers, A and B, whose utility functions are u A (x A 1 ; x A 2 ) = x A

More information

Problem Set 1 Welfare Economics

Problem Set 1 Welfare Economics Problem Set 1 Welfare Economics Solutions 1. Consider a pure exchange economy with two goods, h = 1,, and two consumers, i =1,, with utility functions u 1 and u respectively, and total endowment, e = (e

More information

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model New Notes on the Solow Growth Model Roberto Chang September 2009 1 The Model The firstingredientofadynamicmodelisthedescriptionofthetimehorizon. In the original Solow model, time is continuous and the

More information

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 27 October, 207 Pareto Efficient Allocation Recall the following result: Result An allocation x is Pareto-efficient if and only

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6 Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO April 10, 017 Administrative Stuff Homework # is due at the end of class. I will post the solutions on the website later today. The midterm

More information

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Endogenous Growth with Human Capital Consider the following endogenous growth model with both physical capital (k (t)) and human capital (h (t)) in continuous time. The representative household solves

More information

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S. In the Name of God Sharif University of Technology Graduate School of Management and Economics Microeconomics 1 44715 (1396-97 1 st term) - Group 1 Dr. S. Farshad Fatemi Chapter 10: Competitive Markets

More information

Fisher Equilibrium Price with a Class of Concave Utility Functions

Fisher Equilibrium Price with a Class of Concave Utility Functions Fisher Equilibrium Price with a Class of Concave Utility Functions Ning Chen 1, Xiaotie Deng 2, Xiaoming Sun 3, and Andrew Chi-Chih Yao 4 1 Department of Computer Science & Engineering, University of Washington

More information

Notes I Classical Demand Theory: Review of Important Concepts

Notes I Classical Demand Theory: Review of Important Concepts Notes I Classical Demand Theory: Review of Important Concepts The notes for our course are based on: Mas-Colell, A., M.D. Whinston and J.R. Green (1995), Microeconomic Theory, New York and Oxford: Oxford

More information

Proper Welfare Weights for Social Optimization Problems

Proper Welfare Weights for Social Optimization Problems Proper Welfare Weights for Social Optimization Problems Alexis Anagnostopoulos (Stony Brook University) Eva Cárceles-Poveda (Stony Brook University) Yair Tauman (IDC and Stony Brook University) June 24th

More information

Last Revised: :19: (Fri, 12 Jan 2007)(Revision:

Last Revised: :19: (Fri, 12 Jan 2007)(Revision: 0-0 1 Demand Lecture Last Revised: 2007-01-12 16:19:03-0800 (Fri, 12 Jan 2007)(Revision: 67) a demand correspondence is a special kind of choice correspondence where the set of alternatives is X = { x

More information

Second Welfare Theorem

Second Welfare Theorem Second Welfare Theorem Econ 2100 Fall 2015 Lecture 18, November 2 Outline 1 Second Welfare Theorem From Last Class We want to state a prove a theorem that says that any Pareto optimal allocation is (part

More information

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 19, November 7 Outline 1 Welfare Theorems in the differentiable case. 2 Aggregate excess

More information

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KYOTO INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH Discussion Paper No.992 Intertemporal efficiency does not imply a common price forecast: a leading example Shurojit Chatterji, Atsushi

More information

Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions

Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions Chapter 1 Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions 1.1 Arrow-Debreu model of an economy via Walras equilibrium problem. Let us consider first the so-called Arrow-Debreu model. The presentation

More information

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 4, September 7 Outline 1 Structural Properties of Utility Functions 1 Local Non Satiation 2 Convexity 3 Quasi-linearity

More information

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems Craig Burnside Duke University September 2010 Craig Burnside (Duke University) Competitive Equilibrium September 2010 1 / 32 Competitive Equilibrium and

More information

Equilibrium in Factors Market: Properties

Equilibrium in Factors Market: Properties Equilibrium in Factors Market: Properties Ram Singh Microeconomic Theory Lecture 12 Ram Singh: (DSE) Factor Prices Lecture 12 1 / 17 Questions What is the relationship between output prices and the wage

More information

Controlling versus enabling Online appendix

Controlling versus enabling Online appendix Controlling versus enabling Online appendix Andrei Hagiu and Julian Wright September, 017 Section 1 shows the sense in which Proposition 1 and in Section 4 of the main paper hold in a much more general

More information

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems The Fundamental Welfare Theorems The so-called Fundamental Welfare Theorems of Economics tell us about the relation between market equilibrium and Pareto efficiency. The First Welfare Theorem: Every Walrasian

More information

Chapter 1 - Preference and choice

Chapter 1 - Preference and choice http://selod.ensae.net/m1 Paris School of Economics (selod@ens.fr) September 27, 2007 Notations Consider an individual (agent) facing a choice set X. Definition (Choice set, "Consumption set") X is a set

More information

Evolutionary Dynamics of the Market Equilibrium with Division of Labor

Evolutionary Dynamics of the Market Equilibrium with Division of Labor Department of Economics Issn 1441-5429 Discussion paper 12/09 Evolutionary Dynamics of the Market Equilibrium with Division of Labor Haiou Zhou bstract: Recently, a growing literature, known as the new

More information

Economics 101 Lecture 5 - Firms and Production

Economics 101 Lecture 5 - Firms and Production Economics 101 Lecture 5 - Firms and Production 1 The Second Welfare Theorem Last week we proved the First Basic Welfare Theorem, which states that under fairly weak assumptions, a Walrasian equilibrium

More information

Unlinked Allocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One Bad

Unlinked Allocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One Bad Unlinked llocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One ad Chiaki Hara Faculty of Economics and Politics, University of Cambridge Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University pril 16,

More information

Some Notes on Adverse Selection

Some Notes on Adverse Selection Some Notes on Adverse Selection John Morgan Haas School of Business and Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Overview This set of lecture notes covers a general model of adverse selection

More information

Mechanism Design: Bayesian Incentive Compatibility

Mechanism Design: Bayesian Incentive Compatibility May 30, 2013 Setup X : finite set of public alternatives X = {x 1,..., x K } Θ i : the set of possible types for player i, F i is the marginal distribution of θ i. We assume types are independently distributed.

More information

Economic Core, Fair Allocations, and Social Choice Theory

Economic Core, Fair Allocations, and Social Choice Theory Chapter 9 Nathan Smooha Economic Core, Fair Allocations, and Social Choice Theory 9.1 Introduction In this chapter, we briefly discuss some topics in the framework of general equilibrium theory, namely

More information

Intro to Economic analysis

Intro to Economic analysis Intro to Economic analysis Alberto Bisin - NYU 1 Rational Choice The central gure of economics theory is the individual decision-maker (DM). The typical example of a DM is the consumer. We shall assume

More information

Econ 101A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sorry!

Econ 101A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sorry! Econ 0A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sry! This Problem set tests the knowledge that you accumulated mainly in lectures 2 to 26. The problem set is focused

More information

Answers to Spring 2014 Microeconomics Prelim

Answers to Spring 2014 Microeconomics Prelim Answers to Spring 204 Microeconomics Prelim. To model the problem of deciding whether or not to attend college, suppose an individual, Ann, consumes in each of two periods. She is endowed with income w

More information

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes David L. Kelly Department of Economics University of Miami Box 248126 Coral Gables, FL 33134 dkelly@miami.edu Current Version: Fall 2013/Spring 2013 I Introduction A

More information

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Yongmin Chen and David Sappington University of Colorado and University of Florida February 2016 1 / 32 1. Introduction Patent policy: patent protection

More information

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley Firms and returns to scale. Increasing returns to scale and monopoly pricing 2. Natural monopoly 1 C. Constant returns to scale 21 D. The CRS economy 26 E. pplication

More information

Money, Barter, and Hyperinflation. Kao, Yi-Cheng Department of Business Administration, Chung Yuan Christian University

Money, Barter, and Hyperinflation. Kao, Yi-Cheng Department of Business Administration, Chung Yuan Christian University Money, Barter, and Hyperinflation Kao, Yi-Cheng Department of Business Administration, Chung Yuan Christian University 1 Outline Motivation The Model Discussion Extension Conclusion 2 Motivation 3 Economist

More information

TECHNICAL APPENDIX. 7. Agents Decisions in the Cobb-Douglas Case

TECHNICAL APPENDIX. 7. Agents Decisions in the Cobb-Douglas Case TECHNICAL APPENDIX 7 Agents Decisions in the Cobb-Douglas Case A closed form solution for production and trade obtains if we assume that utility is a Cobb-Douglas function of the consumption bundle: u

More information

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. Ph.D. Core Exam -- Macroeconomics 5 January 2015 -- 8:00 am to 3:00 pm Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3. A1 (required): Ending Quantitative Easing Now that the U.S.

More information

A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Sequential Economies

A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Sequential Economies A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Sequential Economies Takashi Kamihigashi September 28, 2015 Abstract We show a simple no-bubble theorem that applies to a wide range of deterministic sequential

More information

Game Theory Fall 2003

Game Theory Fall 2003 Game Theory Fall 2003 Problem Set 1 [1] In this problem (see FT Ex. 1.1) you are asked to play with arbitrary 2 2 games just to get used to the idea of equilibrium computation. Specifically, consider the

More information

General equilibrium with externalities and tradable licenses

General equilibrium with externalities and tradable licenses General equilibrium with externalities and tradable licenses Carlos Hervés-Beloso RGEA. Universidad de Vigo. e-mail: cherves@uvigo.es Emma Moreno-García Universidad de Salamanca. e-mail: emmam@usal.es

More information

Short correct answers are sufficient and get full credit. Including irrelevant (though correct) information in an answer will not increase the score.

Short correct answers are sufficient and get full credit. Including irrelevant (though correct) information in an answer will not increase the score. Economics 200B Part 1 UCSD Winter 2014 Prof. R. Starr, Ms. Isla Globus-Harris Final Exam 1 Your Name: SUGGESTED ANSWERS Please answer all questions. Each of the six questions marked with a big number counts

More information

Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 5: Optimization Kuhn-Tucker conditions for problems with inequality constraints 1

Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 5: Optimization Kuhn-Tucker conditions for problems with inequality constraints 1 Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 5: Optimization Kuhn-Tucker conditions for problems with inequality constraints 1 Session: 15 Aug 2015 (Mon), 10:00am 1:00pm I. Optimization with

More information

Rice University. Fall Semester Final Examination ECON501 Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Writing Period: Three Hours

Rice University. Fall Semester Final Examination ECON501 Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Writing Period: Three Hours Rice University Fall Semester Final Examination 007 ECON50 Advanced Microeconomic Theory Writing Period: Three Hours Permitted Materials: English/Foreign Language Dictionaries and non-programmable calculators

More information

Walras and dividends equilibrium with possibly satiated consumers

Walras and dividends equilibrium with possibly satiated consumers Walras and dividends equilibrium with possibly satiated consumers Nizar Allouch Department of Economics Queen Mary, University of London Mile End Rd, E1 4NS London, United Kingdom n.allouch@qmul.ac.uk

More information

Econ 201: Problem Set 3 Answers

Econ 201: Problem Set 3 Answers Econ 20: Problem Set 3 Ansers Instructor: Alexandre Sollaci T.A.: Ryan Hughes Winter 208 Question a) The firm s fixed cost is F C = a and variable costs are T V Cq) = 2 bq2. b) As seen in class, the optimal

More information

Alfred Marshall s cardinal theory of value: the strong law of demand

Alfred Marshall s cardinal theory of value: the strong law of demand Econ Theory Bull (2014) 2:65 76 DOI 10.1007/s40505-014-0029-5 RESEARCH ARTICLE Alfred Marshall s cardinal theory of value: the strong law of demand Donald J. Brown Caterina Calsamiglia Received: 29 November

More information

The Debreu-Scarf Theorem: The Core Converges to the Walrasian Allocations

The Debreu-Scarf Theorem: The Core Converges to the Walrasian Allocations The Debreu-Scarf Theorem: The Core Converges to the Walrasian Allocations We ve shown that any Walrasian equilibrium allocation (any WEA) is in the core, but it s obvious that the converse is far from

More information

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata General Equilibrium Equilibrium in Consumption GE begins (1/3) 2-Individual/ 2-good Exchange economy (No production, no transaction costs, full information..) Endowment (Nature): e Private property/ NO

More information

Competitive Market Mechanisms as Social Choice Procedures

Competitive Market Mechanisms as Social Choice Procedures Competitive Market Mechanisms as Social Choice Procedures Peter J. Hammond 1 Department of Economics, Stanford University, CA 94305-6072, U.S.A. 1 Introduction and outline 1.1 Markets and social choice

More information

QUANTITY PRECOMMITMENT AND BERTRAND COMPETITION YIELD COURNOT OUTCOMES: A CASE WITH PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION: REPLY

QUANTITY PRECOMMITMENT AND BERTRAND COMPETITION YIELD COURNOT OUTCOMES: A CASE WITH PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION: REPLY QUANTITY PRECOMMITMENT AND BERTRAND COMPETITION YIELD COURNOT OUTCOMES: A CASE WITH PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION: REPLY XIANGKANG YIN La Trobe University YEW-KWANG NG Monash University Since the publication

More information

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2 EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2 Leonardo Felli 32L.G.06 19 January 2015 Moral Hazard: Consider the contractual relationship between two agents (a principal and an agent) The principal

More information

Lecture 1. History of general equilibrium theory

Lecture 1. History of general equilibrium theory Lecture 1 History of general equilibrium theory Adam Smith: The Wealth of Nations, 1776 many heterogeneous individuals with diverging interests many voluntary but uncoordinated actions (trades) results

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Macroeconomics II 2 The real business cycle model. Introduction This model explains the comovements in the fluctuations of aggregate economic variables around their trend.

More information

Nonlinear Programming (NLP)

Nonlinear Programming (NLP) Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 6: Nonlinear Programming - Unconstrained Optimization Note 6 is based on de la Fuente (2000, Ch. 7), Madden (1986, Ch. 3 and 5) and Simon and Blume

More information

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712 Prof. Peck Fall 20 Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 872. (0 points) The following economy has two consumers, two firms, and three goods. Good is leisure/labor.

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012 The time limit for this exam is 4 hours. It has four sections. Each section includes two questions. You are

More information

ANSWERS TO ODD NUMBERED EXERCISES IN CHAPTER 3

ANSWERS TO ODD NUMBERED EXERCISES IN CHAPTER 3 John Riley 5 Setember 0 NSWERS T DD NUMERED EXERCISES IN CHPTER 3 SECTIN 3: Equilibrium and Efficiency Exercise 3-: Prices with Quasi-linear references (a) Since references are convex, an allocation is

More information

Advanced Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomics Advanced Microeconomics Leonardo Felli EC441: Room D.106, Z.332, D.109 Lecture 8 bis: 24 November 2004 Monopoly Consider now the pricing behavior of a profit maximizing monopolist: a firm that is the only

More information

SURPLUS SHARING WITH A TWO-STAGE MECHANISM. By Todd R. Kaplan and David Wettstein 1. Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel. 1.

SURPLUS SHARING WITH A TWO-STAGE MECHANISM. By Todd R. Kaplan and David Wettstein 1. Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel. 1. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW Vol. 41, No. 2, May 2000 SURPLUS SHARING WITH A TWO-STAGE MECHANISM By Todd R. Kaplan and David Wettstein 1 Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel In this article we consider

More information

Economics 201b Spring 2010 Solutions to Problem Set 1 John Zhu

Economics 201b Spring 2010 Solutions to Problem Set 1 John Zhu Economics 201b Spring 2010 Solutions to Problem Set 1 John Zhu 1a The following is a Edgeworth box characterization of the Pareto optimal, and the individually rational Pareto optimal, along with some

More information

IBM Research Report. Equilibrium in Prediction Markets with Buyers and Sellers

IBM Research Report. Equilibrium in Prediction Markets with Buyers and Sellers RJ10453 (A0910-003) October 1, 2009 Mathematics IBM Research Report Equilibrium in Prediction Markets with Buyers and Sellers Shipra Agrawal Department of Computer Science Stanford University Stanford,

More information

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale. Increasing returns to scale and monopoly pricing 2. Constant returns to scale 19 C. The CRS economy 25 D. pplication to trade 47 E. Decreasing

More information

Arbitrage and global cones: Another counterexample*

Arbitrage and global cones: Another counterexample* Soc Choice Welfare (999) 6: 7±46 Arbitrage and global cones: Another counterexample* Paulo K. Monteiro, Frank H. Page, Jr.,**, Myrna H. Wooders,*** CORE, 4 voie du Roman Pays, B-48 Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium

More information

Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability

Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability Chapter 7 Nathan Smooha Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability 7.1 Introduction Brouwer s Fixed Point Theorem. Let X be a non-empty, compact, and convex subset of R m. If

More information

1 The Basic RBC Model

1 The Basic RBC Model IHS 2016, Macroeconomics III Michael Reiter Ch. 1: Notes on RBC Model 1 1 The Basic RBC Model 1.1 Description of Model Variables y z k L c I w r output level of technology (exogenous) capital at end of

More information

No Equilibrium in Infinite Economies: Two Examples*

No Equilibrium in Infinite Economies: Two Examples* JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC THEORY 34, 180-186 (1984) No Equilibrium in Infinite Economies: Two Examples* AHMET ALKAN Bogaripi Universitesi, Istanbul, Turkey Received December 20, 1982; revised October 14. 1983

More information

0 Aims of this course

0 Aims of this course THE UNIVERSITY OF SOUTHAMPTON Paul Klein Office: Murray Building, 35 Email: p.klein@soton.ac.uk URL: http://paulklein.se Economics 31 Topics in Macroeconomics 3 Fall 21 Aims of this course Clear, critical

More information

Lecture Notes October 18, Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I.

Lecture Notes October 18, Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I. Lecture Notes October 18, 2012 Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I. Economic General Equilibrium Partial and General Economic Equilibrium PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM S k (p o ) = D k k (po

More information

Market Economies with an Endogenous Social Division of Labour

Market Economies with an Endogenous Social Division of Labour Market Economies with an Endogenous Social Division of Labour Robert P. Gilles September 2016 Revised: August 2017 and July 2018 Abstract This paper considers a general equilibrium model of a competitive

More information

Revealed Preferences and Utility Functions

Revealed Preferences and Utility Functions Revealed Preferences and Utility Functions Lecture 2, 1 September Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Outline 1 Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference 2 Equivalence between Axioms and Rationalizable Choices. 3 An Application:

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems The Fundamental Welfare Theorems The so-called Fundamental Welfare Theorems of Economics tell us about the relation between market equilibrium and Pareto efficiency. The First Welfare Theorem: Every Walrasian

More information