MARTINGALE OPTIMAL TRANSPORT AND ROBUST HEDGING IN CONTINUOUS TIME

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "MARTINGALE OPTIMAL TRANSPORT AND ROBUST HEDGING IN CONTINUOUS TIME"

Transcription

1 MARTIGALE OPTIMAL TRASPORT AD ROBUST HEDGIG I COTIUOUS TIME YA DOLISKY AD H.METE SOER HEBREW UIVERSITY OF JERUSALEM AD ETH ZURICH Abstract. The duality between the robust or equivalently, model independent hedging of path dependent European options and a martingale optimal transport problem is proved. The financial maret is modeled through a risy asset whose price is only assumed to be a continuous function of time. The hedging problem is to construct a minimal super-hedging portfolio that consists of dynamically trading the underlying risy asset and a static position of vanilla options which can be exercised at the given, fixed maturity. The dual is a Monge-Kantorovich type martingale transport problem of maximizing the expected value of the option over all martingale measures that has the given marginal at maturity. In addition to duality, a family of simple, piecewise constant super-replication portfolios that asymptotically achieve the minimal super-replication cost is constructed. 1. Introduction The original transport problem proposed by Monge [18] is to optimally move a pile of soil to an excavation. Mathematically, given two measures ν and µ of equal mass, we loo for an optimal bijection of R d which moves ν to µ, i.e., loo for a map S so that ϕsxdνx = R d ϕxdµx, R d for all continuous functions ϕ. Then, with a given cost function c, the objective is to minimize cx, Sx dνx R d over all bijections S. In his classical papers [15, 16], Kantorovich relaxed this problem by considering a probability measure on R d R d, whose marginals agree with ν and µ, instead of a bijection. This generalization linearizes the problem. Hence, allows for an easy existence result and enables one to identify its convex dual. Indeed, the dual elements are real-valued continuous maps g, h of R d satisfying the constraint 1.1 gx + hy cx, y. Date: January 22, Mathematics Subject Classification. 91G1, 6G44. Key words and phrases. European Options, Robust Hedging, Min Max Theorems, Prohorov Metric, Optimal transport. Research partly supported by the European Research Council under the grant FiRM, by the ETH Foundation and by the Swiss Finance Institute. 1

2 2 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner The dual objective function is to maximize gx dνx + hy dµy R d R d overall g, h satisfying the constraint 1.1. In the last decades an impressive theory has been developed and we refer the reader to [1, 23, 24] and to the references therein. In robust hedging problems, we are also given two measures. amely, the initial and the final distributions of a stoc process. We then construct an optimal connection. In general, however, the cost functional depends on the whole path of this connection and not simply on the final value. Hence, one needs to consider processes instead of simply the maps S. The probability distribution of this process has prescribed marginals at final and initial times. Thus, it is in direct analogy with the Kantorovich measure. But, financial considerations restrict the process to be a martingale see Definition 2.4. Interestingly, the dual also has a financial interpretation as a robust hedging super-replication problem. Indeed, the replication constraint is similar to 1.1. The formal connection between the original Monge-Kantorovich problem and the financial problem is further discussed in Remar 2.7 and also in the papers [4] and [12]. We continue by describing the robust hedging problem. Consider a financial maret consisting of one risy asset with a continuous price process. As in the classical paper of Hobson [13], all call options are liquid assets and can be traded for a reasonable price that is nown initially. Hence, the portfolio of an investor consists of static positions in the call options in addition to the usual dynamically updated risy asset. This leads us to a similar structure as in [13] and in other papers that consider robust hedging of model-independent price bounds. Apart from the continuity of the price process no other model assumptions are placed on the dynamics of the price process. In this maret, we prove the Kantorovich duality, Theorem 2.6, and an approximation result, Theorem 2.8, for a general class of path-dependent options. The classical duality theorem, for a maret with a given semi-martingale, states that the minimal super-replication cost of a contingent claim is equal to the supremum of its expected value over all martingale measures that are equivalent to a given measure. We refer the reader to Delbaen & Schachermayer [1] Theorem 5.7 for the general semi-martingale processes and to El-Karoui & Quenez [11] for its dynamic version in the diffusion case. Theorem 2.6 below, also provides a dual representation of the minimal super-replication cost but for the general model independent marets. The dual is given as the supremum of the expectations of the contingent claim over all martingale measures with a given marginal at the maturity but with no dominating measure. Since no probabilistic model is pre-assumed for the price process, the class of all martingale measures is quite large. Indeed, typically martingale measures are orthogonal to each other and this fact renders the problem difficult. However, the additional feature of the maret that the call prices are nown, introduces the new marginal constraint. This in turn, provides the connection to the problem of optimal transport. In the literature, there are two earlier results in this direction. In a purely discrete setup, a similar result was recently proved by Beiglboc, Henry-Labordère and Penner [4]. In their model, the investor is allowed to buy all call options at finitely many given maturities and the stoc is traded only at these possible

3 Martingale Optimal Transport 3 maturities. In this paper, however, the stoc is traded in continuous time together with a static position in the calls with one maturity. In [4] the dual is recognized as a Monge-Kantorovich type optimal transport for martingale measures and is essentially used. In continuous time, Galichon, Henry-Labordère and Touzi [12] prove a different duality and then use the dual to convert the problem to an optimal control problem. There are two main differences between our result and the one proved in [12]. The duality result, Proposition 2.1 in [12], states that the minimal super-replication cost is given as the infimum over Lagrange multipliers and supremum over martingale measures without the final time constraint and the Lagrange multipliers are related to the constraint. Also the problem formulation is different. The model in [12] assumes a large class of possible martingale measures for the price process. The duality is then proved by extending an earlier unconstrained result proved in [21]. As in the unconstrained model of [21, 22], the super-replication is defined not pathwise but rather probabilistically through quasi-sure inequalities. amely, the superreplication cost is the minimal initial wealth from which one can super-replicate the option with probability one with respect to all measures in a given class. In general, these measures are not dominated with one measure. As already mentioned this is the main difficulty and differs the current problem from the classical duality discussed earlier. However, our duality result together with the results of [12] implies that these two approaches namely, robust hedging through the path-wise definition of this paper and the quasi-sure definition of [12, 21] yield the same value. This is proved in Section 3 below. Our second result provides a class of portfolios which are managed on a finite number of random times and asymptotically achieve the minimal super-replication cost. This result may have practical implications allowing us to numerically investigate the corresponding discrete hedges, but we relegate this to a future study. The robust hedging has been an active research area over the past decade. The initial paper of Hobson [13] studies the case of the loobac option. The connection to the Sorohod embedding is also made in this paper and an explicit solution for the minimal super-replication cost is obtained. This approach was further developed by Brown, Hobson and Rogers [5] and Cox and Obloj [7] and in several other papers. We refer the reader to the excellent survey of Hobson [14] and the references therein. Also a similar modeling approach was applied to volatility options by Carr and Lee [6]. We refer to the recent paper by Cox and Wang [8] for more information and a discussion of various constructions of the Root s solution of the Sorohod embedding. Also in a recent paper, Davis and Obloj [9] considered the variance swaps in a maret with finitely many put options. In particular, in [9] the class of admissible portfolios is enlarged and numerical evidence is obtained by analyzing the S&P5 index options data. As already mentioned above, the dual approach is used by Galichon, Henry- Labordère and Touzi [12] and Henry-Labordère and Touzi [17] as well. In these papers, the duality provides a connection to stochastic optimal control which can be then used to compute the solution in a more systematic manner. Our approach is to represent the original robust hedging problem as a limit of robust hedging problems which live on a sequence of countable spaces. For these type of problems, robust hedging is the same as the classical hedging, under the right choice of the probability measure. Thus we can apply the classical duality

4 4 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner results for super hedging of European options on a given probability space. The last step is to analyze the limit of the obtained prices. We combine methods from arbitrage free pricing and limit theorems for stochastic processes. The paper is organized as follows. Main results are formulated in the next section. In Section 3, the connection between the quasi sure approach and ours is proved. The last two sections are devoted to the proof of one inequality which implies the main results. Acnowledgements. The authors would lie to than Mathias Beiglboc, David Belius, Alex Cox, Jan Obloj, Walter Schachermayer and izar Touzi for insightful discussions and comments. In particular, Section 3 resulted from discussions with Obloj and Touzi and Shachermayer pointed out a mistae in an earlier version. 2. Preliminaries and main results The financial maret consists of a savings account which is normalized to unity B t 1 by discounting and of a risy asset S t, t [, T ], where T < is the maturity date. Let s := S > be the initial stoc price and without loss of generality, we set s = 1. Denote by C + [, T ] the set of all strictly positive functions f : [, T ] R + which satisfy f = 1. We assume that S t is a continuous process. Then, any element of C + [, T ] can be a possible path for the stoc price process S. Let us emphasis that this the only assumption that we mae on our financial maret. Denote by D[, T ] the space of all measurable functions υ : [, T ] R with the norm υ = sup t T υ t. Let G : D[, T ] R be a given deterministic map. We then consider a path dependent European option with the payoff 2.1 X = GS, where S is viewed as an element in D[, T ] An assumption on the claim. Since our approach is through approximation, we need the regularity of the pay-off functional G. A discussion of this assumption is given in Remar 2.2. In particular, it is related to the classical Sorohod topology, and Asian and loobac type options satisfy the below condition. We need the following definition. Let D [, T ] be the subset of D[, T ] that are piecewise constant with possible jumps t = < t 1 < t 2 <... < t T, i.e., v D [, T ] if and only if v t = v i χ [ti 1,t it + v +1 χ [t,t ]t, where v i := v ti 1. i=1 We mae the following standing assumption on G. Assumption 2.1. There exists a constant L > so that Gω G ω L ω ω, ω, ω D[, T ]. Moreover, let υ, υ D [, T ] be such that υ i = υ i for all i = 1,...,. Then, Gυ G υ L υ t t, =1 where as usual t := t t 1 and t := t t 1.

5 Martingale Optimal Transport 5 Remar 2.2. In our setup, the process S represents the discounted stoc price and GS represents the discounted award. Let r > be the constant interest rate. Then, the payoff GS := e rt H e rt S T, min t T ert S t, max t T ert S t, T e rt S t dt with a Lipschitz continuous function H : R 4 R satisfies the above assumption. The above condition on G is, in fact, a Lipschitz assumption with respect to a metric very similar to the Sorohod one. However, it is weaer than to assume Lipschitz continuity with respect to the Sorohod metric. Recall that this classical metric is given by df, g := inf λ sup t T max ft gλt, λt t, where the infimum is taen over all time changes. A time change is a strictly increasing continuous function which satisfy λ = and λt = T. We refer the reader to Chapter 3 in [3] for more information. In particular, while T S tdt is continuous with respect to the Sorohod metric in C[, T ], it is not Lipschitz continuous in C[, T ] and it is not even continuous in D[, T ]. Although we assume S to be continuous, since in our analysis we need to consider approximations in D[, T ], the above assumption is needed in order to include Asian options. Moreover, from our proof of the main results it can be shown that Theorems 2.6 and 2.8 can be extended to payoffs of the form e rt H e rt1 S t1,..., e rt S t, min t T ert S t, max t T ert S t, T e rt S t dt where H is Lipschitz and < t 1 <... < t T. Finally, one can extend the results to barrier options, by considering a discretization that is adapted to the barriers. In this paper, we choose not to include this extension to avoid more technicalities., 2.2. European Calls. Let µ be a given probability measure on R +. At time zero, the investor is allowed to buy any call option with with strie K, for a price CK := x K + dµx. The probability measure µ is assumed to be derived from observed call prices that are liquidly traded in the maret. One may also thin that µ describes the probabilistic belief of the firm for the stoc price at time T. Then, an arbitrage and an approximation arguments imply that the price of an option with the payoff gs T with a bounded, measurable g must be given by gdµ. We then assume that this formula also holds for all g L 1 R +, µ. Also, since C is the price of a forward, it must be equal to the initial stoc price S which is normalized to one. Therefore, although the probability measure µ is quite general, in order to avoid arbitrage, it should satisfy that 2.2 C = xdµx = S = 1.

6 6 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner Technically, we also assume that there exists p > 1 such that 2.3 x p dµx < Admissible portfolios. We continue by describing the continuous time trading in the underlying asset S. Since we do not assume any semi-martingale structure of the risy asset, this question is nontrivial. We adopt the path-wise approach of Hobson and require that the trading strategy in the risy asset is of finite variation. Then, for any function h : [, T ] R of finite variation and continuous function S C[, T ], we use integration by parts to define t h u ds u := h t S t h S t S u dh u, where the last term in the above right hand side is the standard Stieltjes integral. We are now ready to give the definition of semi-static portfolios and superhedging. Recall the exponent p in 2.3. Definition We say that a map φ : A D[, T ] D[, T ] is progressively measurable, if for any v, ṽ A, 2.4 v u = ṽ u, u [, t] φv t = φṽ t. 2. A semi-static portfolio is a pair π := g, γ, where g L 1 R +, µ and γ : C + [, T ] D[, T ] is a progressively measurable map of bounded variation. 3. The corresponding discounted portfolio value is given by, Z π t S = gs T χ {t=t } + t γ u SdS u, t [, T ], where χ A is the indicator of the set A. A semi-static portfolio is admissible, if there exists M > such that 2.5 Zt π S M 1 + sup Su p, t [, T ], S C + [, T ]. u t 4. An admissible semi-static portfolio is called super-replicating, if Z π T S GS, S C + [, T ]. 5. The minimal super-hedging cost of G is defined by, { V G := inf gdµ : γ such that π := g, γ is super-replicating otice that the set of admissible portfolios depend on the exponent p which appears in the assumption 2.3. We suppress this possible dependence to simplify the exposition. }.

7 Martingale Optimal Transport Martingale optimal transport. Since the dual formula refers to a probabilistic structure, we need to introduce that structure as well. Set Ω := C + [, T ] and let S = S t t T be the canonical process given by S t ω := ω t, for all ω Ω. Let F t := σs s, s t be the canonical filtration. The following class of probability measures are central to our results. Recall that we have normalized the stoc prices to have initial value one. Therefore, below the probability measures need to satisfy this condition as well. Definition 2.4. A probability measure P on the space Ω, F is a martingale measure, if the canonical process S t T t= is a local martingale with respect to P and S = 1 P-a.s. For a probability measure µ on R +, M µ is the set of all martingale measures P such that the probability distribution of S T under P is equal to µ. ote that if µ satisfies 2.2, then the canonical process S t T t= is a martingale not only a local martingale under any measure P M µ. Remar 2.5. Observe that 2.2 yields that the set M µ is not empty. Indeed, consider a complete probability space Ω W, F W, P W together with a standard one dimensional Brownian motion W t t=, and the natural filtration Ft W which is the completion of σ{w s s t}. Then, there exists a function f : R R + such that the probability distribution of fw T is equal to µ. Define the martingale M t := E W fw T Ft W, t [, T ]. In view of 2.2, M = 1. Since M is a Brownian martingale, it is continuous. Moreover, since µ has support on the positive real line, f and consequently, M. Then, the distribution of M on the space Ω is an element in M µ. The following is the main result of the paper. An outline of its proof is given in the subsection 2.6, below. Theorem 2.6. Assume that the European claim G satisfies the Assumption 2.1 and the probability measure µ satisfies 2.2 and 2.3. Then, the minimal super-hedging cost is given by V G = sup E P [GS], where E P denotes the expectation with respect to P. Remar 2.7. One may consider the maximizer, if exists, of the expression sup E P [GS], as the optimal transport of the initial probability measure ν = δ {1} to the final distribution µ. However, an additional constraint that the connection is a martingale imposed. This in turn places a restriction on the measures, namely 2.2. The penalty function c is replaced by a more general functional G. In this context, one may also consider general initial distributions ν rather than Dirac measures. Then, the martingale measures with given marginals corresponds to the Kantorovich generalization of the mass transport problem. The super-replication problem is also analogous to the Kantorovich dual. However, the dual elements reflect the fact that the cost functional depends on the whole path of the connection. The reader may also consult [4] for a very clear discussion of the connection between the robust hedging and the optimal transport.

8 8 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner 2.5. A discrete time approximation. ext we construct a special class of simple strategies which achieve asymptotically the super hedging cost V. For a positive integer and any S C + [, T ], set τ S =. Then, recursively define, 2.6 τ S = inf { t > τ 1 S : S t S τ S = 1 } T, 1 where we set τ S = T, when the above set is empty. Also, define 2.7 H S = min{ : τ S = T }. Observe that for any S C + [, T ], H S <. Denote by A the set of all portfolios for which the trading in the stoc occurs only at the moments = τ S < τ 1 S <... < τ S = T. Formally, H S π := g, γ A, if it is progressively measurable in the sense of 2.4 and it is of the form γ t S = H S 1 = γ Sχ τ S,τ S]t, +1 for some γ S s. ote that, γ S can depend on S only through its values up to time τ S, so that γ t is progressively measurable. Set { V G := inf } gdµ : γ such that π := g, γ A is super-replicating. It is clear that for any integer 1, V G V G V G. The following result proves the convergence to V G. This approximation result is the second main result of this paper. Also, it is the ey analytical step in the proof of duality. Theorem 2.8. Under the assumptions of Theorem 2.6, lim V G = V G Proofs of Theorems 2.6 and 2.8. In order to establish Theorem 2.6 and Theorem 2.8 it is sufficient to prove that 2.8 lim sup V G sup E P [GS] and V G sup E P [GS]. The first inequality is the difficult one and it will be proved in the last two sections. The second inequality is simpler and we provide its proof here. Let P M µ and let π = g, γ be super-replicating. Since γ is progressively measurable in the sense of 2.4, the stochastic integral t γ u SdS u

9 Martingale Optimal Transport 9 is defined with respect to P. Also P is a martingale measure and G satisfies the lower bound 2.5. Hence, the above stochastic integral is a P local martingale. Moreover, t γ u SdS u GS M1 + sup S t p. t T Also in view of 2.3 and the Doob-Kolmogorov inequality, sup S t p C p E P S T p = C p x p dµ <. E P t T T Therefore, E P γ usds u. Since π is super-replicating, this together with 2.5 implies that T E P [GS] E P γ u SdS u + gs T E P [gs T ] = gdµ, where in the last equality we again used that the distribution of S T under P equals to µ. This completes the proof of the lower bound. Together with 2.8, which will be proved in the last sections, it also completes the proofs of the theorems. 3. Quasi sure approach and full duality An alternate approach to define robust hedging is to use the notion of quasi sure super-hedging as it was done in [12, 21]. Let us briefly recall this notion. Let Q be the set of all martingale measures P on the canonical space C + [, T ] under which the canonical process S satisfies S = 1, P-a.s., has quadratic variation and satisfies E P sup t T S t <. In this maret, an admissible hedging strategy or a portfolio is defined as a pair π = g, γ, where g L 1 R +, µ and γ is a progressively measurable process such that the stochastic integral t γ u ds u, t [, T ] exists for any probability measure in the set P Q and satisfies 2.5 P-a.s. We refer the reader to [21] for a complete characterization of this class. In particular, one does not restrict the trading strategies to be of bounded variation. A portfolio π = g, γ is called an admissible quasi-sure super-hedge, provided that gs T + T γ u ds u GS, P a.s., for all P Q. Then, the minimal super-hedging cost is given by { } V qs G := inf gdµ : γ such that π := g, γ is a quasi-sure super-hedge. Clearly, V G V qs G. From simple arbitrage arguments it follows that V qs G inf E P GS λs T + sup λ L 1 R +,µ P Q λdµ

10 1 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner where we set E P ξ, if E P ξ =. Since inf sup sup inf, the above two inequalities yield, V G V qs G inf sup λ L 1 R +,µ sup inf P Q E P P Q λ L 1 R +,µ E P GS λs T + GS λs T + λdµ λdµ. ow if P M µ, then the two terms with λ are equal. So we first restrict the measures to the set M µ and then use Theorem 2.6, to arrive at V G V qs G inf E P GS λs T + λdµ sup inf sup λ L 1 R +,µ P Q E P P Q λ L 1 R +,µ sup E P [GS] = V G. GS λs T + λdµ Hence, all terms in the above are equal. We summarize this in the following which can be seen as the full duality. Proposition 3.1. Assume that the European claim G satisfies Assumption 2.1 and the probability measure µ satisfies 2.2,2.3. Then, V G = V qs G = sup E P [GS] = inf sup λ L 1 R +,µ P Q = sup inf E P P Q λ L 1 R +,µ E P GS λs T + GS λs T + λdµ λdµ. 4. Proof of the main results The rest of the paper is devoted to the proof of Reduction to bounded claims. We start with a reduction to claims that are bounded from above. Towards this result, we first prove a technical result. Consider a claim with pay-off α K S := S χ { S K} + S K. Recall that V α K is defined in subsection 2.5. Lemma 4.1. lim sup K lim sup V α K =. Proof. In this proof, we always assume that > K > 1. Let τ = τ S and n = H S be as in 2.6, 2.7, respectively, and set θ := θ K S = min { : S τ K 1} n.

11 Martingale Optimal Transport 11 We next define a portfolio g,k, γ,k A as follows. For t τ, τ +1 ] and =, 1,..., n 1, set γ,k t S = γ τ,k p 2 S = max Kp 1 i Sp 1 τ i p2 p 1 χ { θ} max θ i Sp 1 τ i and with c p := p/p 1 define g,k by g,k x = 1 K 1 + c px p c p + + c p x p c p K 1 p We use Proposition 2.1 in [2] and the inequality x < 1 + x p, x R +, to conclude that for any t [, T ] where g,k S t + t γ u ds u S t K + S t χ { St K}, S t := max u t S u. Therefore, π,k := g,k, γ,k satisfies 2.5 and super-replicates α K. Hence, V α K g,k dµ. Also, in view of 2.3, lim sup K lim sup g,k dµ =. These two inequalities complete the proof of the lemma. A corollary of the above estimate is the following reduction to claims that are bounded from above. Lemma 4.2. If suffices to prove 2.8 for claims G that are non-negative, bounded from above and satisfying the Assumption 2.1. Proof. We proceed in two steps. First suppose that 2.8 holds for nonnegative claims that are bounded from above. Then, the conclusions of Theorem 2.6 and Theorem 2.8 also hold for such claims. ow let G be a non-negative claim satisfying Assumption 2.1. For K >, set G K := G K. Then, G K is bounded and 2.8 holds for G K. Therefore, In view of Assumption 2.1, lim sup V G K sup E P [G K S] sup E P [GS]. GS G + L S. Hence, the set {GS K} is included in the set {L S + G K} and G G K + L S + G K χ {L S +G K}. By the linearity of the maret, this inequality implies that V G V G K + V L S + G K χ{l S +G K}.

12 12 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner Moreover, in view of the previous lemma, lim sup K Using these, we conclude that lim sup V L S + G K χ{l S +G K} =. lim sup V G sup E P [GS]. Hence, 2.8 holds for all functions that are non-negative and satisfy Assumption 2.1. By adding an appropriate constant this results extends to all claims that are bounded from below and satisfying Assumption 2.1. ow suppose that G is a general function that satisfies Assumption 2.1. For c >, set Ǧ c := G c. Then, Ǧ is bounded from below and 2.8 holds, i.e., lim sup V G lim sup V Ǧc = sup E P [Ǧc S ]. By Assumption 2.1, Ǧ c S G S + ě c S where the error function is ě c S := L S G c χ {L S G c } S. Since ě c and it satisfies the Assumption 2.1, In view of Lemma 4.1, lim sup c sup sup E P [ě c S] = V ě c = lim V ê c. E P [ě c S] = lim sup c We combine the above inequalities to conclude that c lim sup V G lim sup sup E P [Ǧc S ] This exactly 2.8. sup E P [G S] + lim sup c = sup E P [G S]. lim sup V ě c =. sup E P [ě c S] 4.2. A countable class of piecewise constant functions. In this section, we provide a piece-wise constant approximation of any continuous function S. Fix a positive integer. For any S C + [, T ], let τ S and H S be the times defined in 2.6 and 2.7, respectively. To simplify the notation, we suppress their dependence on S and and also set 4.1 n = H S. We first define the obvious piecewise constant approximation Ŝ = Ŝ S using these times. Indeed, set n 1 [ Ŝ t := S τ χ [τ,τ +1 t + S τn ] signs T S τn 1 χ {T } t, = where as usual signx = 1 if x, and signx = 1 for x <.

13 Martingale Optimal Transport 13 The function, that taes S to Ŝ is a map of C+ [, T ] into the set of all functions with values in the target set A = {i/ : i =, 1, 2,..., }. Indeed, Ŝ is behind the definition of the approximating costs V. However, this set of functions is not countable as the jump times are not restricted to a countable set. So, we provide yet another approximation by restricting the jump times as well. Let D[, T ] be the space of all right continuous functions f : [, T ] R + with left hand limits càdlàg functions. For integers,, let U := { i/2 : i = 1, 2,..., } { 1/i2 : i = 1, 2,..., }, be the sets of possible differences between two consecutive jump times. ext, we define a subset D of D[, T ]. Definition 4.3. A function f D[, T ] belongs to D, if it satisfies the followings, 1. f = 1, 2. f is piecewise constant with jumps at times t 1,..., t n, where t = < t 1 < t 2 <... < t n < T, 3. for any = 1,..., n, ft ft 1 = 1/, 4. for any = 1,..., n, t t 1 U. We emphasize, in the fourth condition, the dependence of the set U on. So as gets larger, jump times tae values in a finer grid. We now define an approximation F : C + [, T ] D, as follow. Recall τ = τ S, n = H S from above and also from 2.6, 2.7. Set ˆτ :=, and for = 1,..., n, define ˆτ := ˆτ i, i=1 ˆτ i = max{ t U i : t < τ i = τ i τ i 1 }. It is clear that = ˆτ < ˆτ 1 <... < ˆτ n < T and ˆτ < τ for all =,..., n. We now define F S by, 4.2 n 2 F t S = [1 S τ1 ] + = S τ+1 χ [ˆτ,ˆτ +1 t [ + S τn ] signs T S τn 1 χ [ˆτn 1,T ]t, where we set ˆτ 1 =. Observe that the value of the -th jump of the process F S equals to the value of the + 1-th jump of the discretization Ŝ of the original process S. Indeed, 4.3 F ˆτ m F ˆτ m 1 = S τm+1 S τm, m = 1,..., n 2, and F ˆτ n 1 F ˆτ n 2 = 1 sign S T S τn 1. This shift is essential in order to deal with some delicate questions of adeptness and predictability. We also recall that the jump times of Ŝ are the random times

14 14 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner τ s while the jump times of F S are ˆτ s and that all these times depend both on and S. Moreover, by construction, F S D. But, it may not be progressively measurable as defined in 2.4. However, we use F only to lift progressively measurable maps defined on D to the initial space Ω = C + [, T ] and this yields progressively measurable maps on Ω. This procedure is defined and the measurability is proved in Lemma 4.7, below. The following lemma shows that F is close to S in the sense of Assumption 2.1. We also point out that the following result is a consequence of the particular structure of D and in particular U s. Lemma 4.4. Let F be the map defined in 4.2. For any G satisfying the Assumption 2.1 with the constant L, GS GF S 5L S, S C+ [, T ]. Proof. Define the map n 1 [ ˆF t S := S τ χ [ˆτ,ˆτ +1 t + S τn ] signs T S τn 1 χ [ˆτn,T ]t. = First recall Assumption 2.1 and observe that Ŝ and ˆF = ˆF are lie the functions υ and υ in that definition. Hence, GŜ G ˆF n L S τ ˆτ. For < n, The definition of U Therefore, 4.4 =1 { } ˆτ = max t U : t < τ. implies that τ ˆτ 1 2, = 1,..., n 1. n 1 τ ˆτ 2 = 1. =1 =1 Combining the above inequalities, we arrive at GŜ G ˆF L S. Set F = F S and directly estimate that G GS GF GS GŜ + Ŝ G ˆF + G ˆF GF L S G L S Ŝ + + ˆF GF = 3L S G + ˆF GF. Finally, we observe that by construction, ˆF F 2 GF, 2L G ˆF.

15 Martingale Optimal Transport 15 The above inequalities completes the proof of the lemma. Remar 4.5. The proof of the above Lemma provides one of the reasons behind the particular structure of U. Indeed, 4.4 is a ey estimate which provides a uniform upper bound for the sum of the differences over. Since there is no upper bound on, the approximating set U for the -th difference must depend on. Moreover, it should have a summable structure over. That explains the terms 2. On the other hand, the reason for the part {1/i2 : i = 1, 2,... } in U is to mae sure that ˆτ >. For probabilistic reasons i.e. adaptability, we want ˆτ τ. This forces us to approximate τ by ˆτ from below. This and ˆτ > would be possible only if U has a subsequence converging to zero. Hence, different sets of U s are also possible provided that they have these two properties A countable probabilistic structure. An essential step in the proof of 2.8 is a duality result for probabilistic problems. We first introduce this structure and then relate it to the problem V. Let ˆΩ := D[, T ] be the space of all right continuous functions f : [, T ] R + with left hand limits càdlàg functions. Denote by Ŝ = Ŝt t T the canonical process on the space ˆΩ. The set D defined in Definition 4.3 is a countable subset of ˆΩ. We choose any probability measure ˆP on ˆΩ which satisfies ˆP D = 1 and ˆP {f} > ˆF t for all f D. Let, t [, T ] by the filtration which is generated by the process Ŝ and satisfying the usual assumptions right continuous and contains ˆP null sets. Under the measure ˆP, the canonical map Ŝ has finitely many jumps. Let = ˆτ Ŝ < ˆτ 1Ŝ <... < ˆτ ĤŜŜ < T, be the jump times of Ŝ. ote that in Definition 4.3, the final jump time is always strictly less than T. Then, a trading strategy on the filtered probability space ˆΩ, ˆF, ˆF t T t=, ˆP is a càdlàg progressively measurable stochastic process ˆγ t T t=. Thus, there exists a map φ : D[, T ] D[, T ], so that it is progressively measurable in the sense of 2.4 and ˆγ = φŝ, ˆP-a.s. Since we may always wor with φ instead of ˆγ, there is no loss of generality in assuming that ˆγ is itself is progressively measurable in the sense of 2.4. We now give the probabilistic counterpart of the Definition 2.3. Definition A probabilistic semi-static portfolio is a pair h, ˆγ such that ˆγ : D[, T ] D[, T ] is càdlàg, progressively measurable and h : A R. 2. A semi-static portfolio is ˆP -admissible, if h is bounded and there exists M > such that 4.5 t ˆγ u- dŝu M, ˆP a.s., t [, T ], where ˆγ u- is the left limit of the càdlàg function ˆγ at time u.

16 16 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner 3. An admissible semi-static portfolio is ˆP -super-replicating, if 4.6 hŝt + T ˆγ u- dŝu GŜ, ˆP a.s Approximating µ. Recall the set A of portfolios used in the definition of V in subsection 2.5. ext we provide a connection between the probabilistic super-replication and the discrete robust problem. However, h in Definition 4.6 above is defined only on A while the static part of the hedges in A are functions defined on R +. So for a given h : A R, we define the following operator by g := L h : R + R g x := 1 + x xh x / + x x h1 + x /, where for a real number r, r is the largest integer that is not larger than r. ext, define a measure µ on the set A by and for any positive integer, µ {/} := / µ {} := 1/ 1/ x + 1 dµx + 1 x dµx +1/ / 1 + x dµx. This construction has the following important property. For any bounded function h : A R, let g = L h be as above. Then, 4.7 hdµ = g dµ. In particular, by taing h 1, we conclude that µ is a probability measure. Also, since g converges pointwise to g, one may directly show by Lebesgue s dominated convergence theorem that µ converges wealy to µ Probabilistic super-replication. We now introduce the super-replication problem by requiring that the inequalities in 4.6 hold ˆP -almost surely. Let G be a European claim as before and be a positive integer. Then, the probabilistic super-replication problem is given by, { } ˆV G = inf hdµ : ˆγ s.t. h, ˆγ is a ˆP admissible super hedge of G. Recall that in the probabilistic structure, admissibility and related notions are defined in Definition 4.6. We continue by establishing a connection between the probabilistic super hedging ˆV and the discrete robust problem V. Suppose that we are given a probabilistic semi-static portfolio ˆπ = g, ˆγ in sense of Definition 4.6. We lift this portfolio to a semi-static portfolio π = g, γ A as defined in the subsection 2.5.

17 Martingale Optimal Transport 17 Indeed, let g be as in subsection 4.4 and let ˆγ t- be the left limit of the càdlàg function ˆγ at time t. We now define γ : C + [, T ] D[, T ] by n 1 γ t S = =1 ˆγˆτ - F S χ τ,τ +1 ]t, where τ = τ S is as in 2.6, n is as in 4.1 and F S, ˆτ := ˆτ S is as in 4.2. otice that n, the number of jumps of S, is by construction exactly one more than the number of jumps of F. Also notice that γ t S =, t [, τ 1 ]. Lemma 4.7. For any probabilistic semi-static portfolio g, ˆγ, γ defined above is progressively measurable in the sense of 2.4. Proof. Let S, S C + [, T ] be such that S u = S u for all u t for some t [, T ]. We need to show that γ t S = γ t S. Since the above clearly holds for t = and t = T, we may assume that t, T. Set t S := t S := min{i 1, : τ i t } 1, so that t S n and t τ, τ ts ]. ts+1 It is clear that t S = t S. If t S = t S =, then γ t S = γ t S =. We now assume that t S > and use the definition of ˆτ to conclude that Hence, θ := ˆτ ts = ˆτ tss = ˆτ t S S. γ t S = ˆγ θ- F S, γ t S = ˆγ θ- F S. Moreover, the definition of F implies that F u S = F u S, u [, θ. Therefore, by the progressive measurability of ˆγ we have γ t S = γ t S. The following lemma provides a natural and a crucial connection between the probabilistic super-replication and the discrete robust problem. Recall the set A of portfolios used in the definition of V in subsection 2.5. Lemma 4.8. Suppose G is bounded from above and satisfies the Assumption 2.1. Then, lim sup V G lim sup ˆV G. Proof. Set We first show that G S := GS 6L S. V G ˆV G.

18 18 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner To prove the above inequality, suppose that a portfolio h, ˆγ is a ˆP -admissible super hedge of G. Then, it suffices to construct a map γ : C + [, T ] D[, T ] such that the semi-static portfolio π := g, γ is admisible, belongs to A and super-replicates G in the sense of Definition 2.3. Let g be as in subsection 4.4 and γ be the probabilistic portfolio considered in Lemma 4.7. We claim that π is the desired portfolio. In view of Lemma 4.7, we need to show that π is in A and super-replicates the G in the sense of Definition 2.3. To simplify the notation, we set F := F S. Admissibility of γ. By construction trading is only at the random times τ s. Therefore, π A provided that it satisfies the lower bound 2.5 for every t [, T ]. Fix such a time point t [, T ]. In view of 4.5, there exist M so that ˆγ u- F df u M, t [, T ], F D. We claim that [,t] τ γ u SdS u = ˆγ u- F df u M, [,ˆτ 1 ] for every n 1. Indeed, we use 4.3 and the definitions to compute that [,ˆτ 1 ] ˆγ u- F df u = = = 1 m=1 m=1 τ ˆγˆτm-F 1 Fˆτm Fˆτm 1 = m=1 γ τ m+1 F S τm+1 S τm = τ γ u SdS u. τ 1 ˆγˆτm-F S τm+1 S τm γ u SdS u The last identity follows from the fact that γ is zero on the interval [, τ 1 ]. ow, for a given t [, T and S C + [, T ], let n 1 be the largest integer so that τ t. Construct a function F D by, F [,ˆτ = F [,ˆτ, i.e., Fu = F u, u [, ˆτ, and F u = 2Fˆτ 1 Fˆτ, u ˆτ. ote that the constructed function F depends on S and, since both F and the stopping times τ depend on them. But we suppress these dependences. Since and since Fˆτ Fˆτ 1 = [ Fˆτ Fˆτ 1 ] = ±1/, S t S τ 1/, there exists λ [, 1] depending on t such that S t S τ = λfˆτ Fˆτ λ Fˆτ Fˆτ 1.

19 Martingale Optimal Transport 19 Since F and F agree on [, ˆτ, and ˆγ is progressively measurable ˆγ u F = ˆγ u F for all u ˆτ. Therefore, t γ u SdS u = λ ˆγ u- F df u + 1 λ ˆγ u- F d F u. [,ˆτ ] [,ˆτ ] Also both F, F D, and ˆPF, ˆP F >. Using 4.5 we may conclude that ˆγ u- F df u M, and ˆγ u- F d F u M. [,ˆτ ] Hence, π A. [,ˆτ ] Super-replication. We need to show that g S T + T γ u SdS u G S. We proceed almost exactly as in the proof of admissibility. modification F D by F [,ˆτn 2 = F [,ˆτn 2 and F u = Fˆτn 2 Again we define a for u ˆτ n 2. Set ˆλ := S T S τn 1. Then ˆλ [, 1] and by the construction of g, Hence, g S T + = ˆλ T [ g S T = ˆλhF T + 1 ˆλh F T. γ u SdS u hf T + T ˆλGF + 1 ˆλG F. ˆγ u- F df u ] + 1 ˆλ [ h F T + Since F F 1/, Assumption 2.1 and Lemma 4.4 imply that GS G F GS GF + GF G F 6L S. Consequently, ˆλGF + 1 ˆλG F G S and we conclude that π is super-replication G. Completion of the proof. We have shown that V G 6L S / ˆV G. T ˆγ u- F d F u ] Moreover, the linearity of the maret yields that super-replication cost is subadditive. Hence, Therefore, V G V 6L S / + V G 6L S /. V G V 6L S / + ˆV G.

20 2 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner Finally, by Lemma 4.1, lim sup V 6L S / =. We use the above inequalities to complete the proof of the lemma First duality. Recall the countable set D ˆΩ and its probabilistic structure were introduced in subsection 4.3. We consider two classes of measures on this set. Definition We say that a probability measures Q on the space ˆΩ, ˆF is a martingale measure, if the canonical process Ŝt T t= is a local martingale with respect to Q. 2. M is the set of all martingale measures that are supported on D. 3. For a given K >, M K is the set of all measures Q M that satisfy 4.8 Q ŜT = / µ {/} < K. = The following follows from nown duality results. We will combine it with 4.8 and Proposition 5.1, that will be proved in the next section to complete the proof of the inequality 2.8. Lemma 4.1. Suppose that G bounded from above by K and satisfies the Assumption 2.1. Then, for any positive integer, [ ] ˆV G sup E Q GŜ. Q M K Proof. Fix and define the set Set Z = Z := {h : A R : hx, V := inf sup h Z Q M E Q GŜ hŝt + x}. hdµ. Clearly, for any ɛ >, there exists h Z such that sup E Q GŜ hŝt + hdµ < V + ɛ. Q M By construction, the support of the measure ˆP is ˆD. Also all elements of are piece-wise constant. Thus, ˆP almost surely, the canonical process Ŝ is trivially a semi-martingale. Hence, we may use the results of the GŜ seminal paper [1]. In particular, by Theorem 5.7 in [1], for x > sup Q M E Q hs T, there exists an admissible portfolio strategy ˆγ such that x + T ˆγ u dŝu GŜ hŝt, h Z Q M ˆP a.s. ˆD Thus, h + x, ˆγ satisfies , and ˆV G V + ɛ. We now let ɛ to zero to conclude that 4.9 ˆV G inf sup E Q GŜ hŝt + hdµ.

21 Martingale Optimal Transport 21 The next step is to interchange the order of the above infimum and supremum. Consider the vector space R A of all functions f : A R equiped with the topology of point-wise convergence. Clearly, this space is locally convex. Also, since A is countable, Z is a compact subset of R A. The set M can be naturally considered as a convex subspace of the vector space R D. ow, define the function G : Z M R, by GŜ Gh, Q = E Q hŝt + hdµ. otice that G is affine in each of the variables. From the bounded convergence theorem, it follows that G is continuous in the first variable. ext, we apply the min-max theorem, Theorem 2, in [4] to G. The result is, inf h Z This together with 4.9 yields, 4.1 ˆV G sup Q M sup Gh, Q = sup Q M inf h Z Q M inf Gh, Q. h Z E Q GŜ hŝt + hdµ. Finally, for any measure Q M, define h Q Z by h Q / = sign Q ŜT = / µ {/}, =, 1,.... In view of 4.1, ˆV G sup Q M = sup Q M E Q GŜ + { = E Q GˆB h Q ndµ E Q h Q ŜT } Q ŜT = / µ {/} = Suppose that Q M K. Then, Q ŜT = / µ {/} K. Since G is bounded by K, this implies that E Q GˆB Q ŜT = / µ {/}. = However, since G, we may assume that Q M K. Then, { } ˆV G sup E Q GˆB Q ŜT = / µ {/} Q M K = sup E Q GŜ. Q M K

22 22 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner 5. Approximation of Martingale Measures In this final section, we prove the asymptotic connection between the approximating martingale measures M K defined in Definition 4.9 and the continuous martingale measures M µ satisfying the marginal constraint at the final time, defined in Definition 2.4. The following proposition completes the proof of the inequality 2.8 and consequently the proofs of the main theorems when the claim G is bounded from above. The general case then follows from Lemma 4.2. Proposition 5.1. Suppose that G is bounded from above by K and satisfies the Assumption 2.1. Assume that µ satisfies Then, lim sup sup Q M K E Q [ GŜ ] sup E P [GS]. We prove this result not through a compactness argument as one may expect. Instead, we show that any given measure Q M K has a lifted version in M µ that is close to Q in some sense. Indeed, the above proposition is a direct consequence of the below lemma. Recall the Lipschitz constant L in Assumption 2.1. Lemma 5.2. Under the hypothesis of Proposition 5.1, there exists a continuous function f K with f K =, so that for any Q M K and ɛ >, [ ] E Q GŜ L + f Kɛ + sup E P [GS]. Proof. Fix ɛ, 1, a positive integer and Q M K. Recall that G is bounded from above by K. Jump times. Since the probability measure Q is supported on the set D, the the canonical process Ŝ is a purely jump process under Q, with a finite number of jumps. Introduce the jump times by setting σ = and for >, σ = inf{t > σ 1 : Ŝt Ŝt-} T. ext we introduce the largest random time ˆ := min{ : σ = T }. Then, ˆ < almost surely and consequently, there exists deterministic positive integer m depending on ɛ such that 5.1 Q ˆ > m < ɛ. By the definition of the set D, there is a decreasing sequence of strictly positive numbers t, with t 1 = T, such that for i = 1,..., m, σ i σ i 1 {t } =1 {}, Q a.s. Wiener space. Let Ω W, F W, P W be a complete { probability space together with } a standard m+2 dimensional Brownian motion W t = W 1 t, W 2 t,..., W m+2 t, and the natural filtration F W t = σ{w s s t}. The next step is to construct a t=

23 Martingale Optimal Transport 23 martingale Z on the Brownian probability space Ω W, F W, P W together with a sequence of stopping times with respect to the Brownian filtration τ 1 τ 2... τ m such that the distribution under the Wiener measure P W of the random vector τ 1,..., τ m, Z τ1,..., Z τm is equal to the distribution of the random vector σ 1,..., σ m, Ŝσ 1,..., Ŝσ m under the measure Q. amely, 5.2 τ1,..., τ m, Z τ1,..., Z τm, P W = σ 1,..., σ m, Ŝσ 1,..., Ŝσ m, Q. The construction is done by induction, at each step we construct the stopping time τ and Z τ such that the conditional probability is the same as in the case of the canonical process Ŝ under the measure Q. Construction of τ s and Z. For an integer n and given x 1,..., x n, introduce the notation x n := x 1,..., x n. Also set T := {t } =1. For = 1,..., m, define the functions Ψ, Φ : T { 1, 1} 1 [, 1] by 5.3 Ψ α ; β 1 := Q σ σ 1 α A, where and A := 5.4 Φ α ; β 1 = Q where B = { } σ i σ i 1 = α i, Ŝσ i Ŝσ i 1 = β i /, i 1, Ŝσ Ŝσ 1 = 1/ B, { } σ < T, σ j σ j 1 = α j, Ŝσ i Ŝσ i 1 = β i /, j, i 1. As usual we set Q. ext, for m, we define the maps Γ, Θ : T { 1, 1} 1 [, ], as the unique solutions of the following equations, 5.5 P W W α 1 < Γ α ; β 1 = Φ α ; β 1, and 5.6 P W W 1 t l W 1 t l+1 < Θ α ; β 1 =1 = Ψ α 1, t l ; β 1 Ψ α 1, t l+1 ; β 1, where l is given by α = t l T. From the definitions it follows that Ψ α 1, t l ; β 1 Ψ α 1, t l+1 ; β 1. Thus if Ψ α 1, t l+1 ; β 1 = for some l, then also Ψ α 1, t l ; β 1 =. We set /. Set τ and define the random variables τ 1,..., τ m, Y 1,..., Y m by the following recursive relations 5.7 τ 1 = t χ 1 {W t W 1 t >Θ +1 1t χ 1 } {W t W 1 j t <Θ, j+1 1t j} Y 1 = 2χ {W 2 {τ 1 >Γ 1τ 1}} 1, j=+1

24 24 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner and for i > 1 τ i = τ i 1 + i Y i = χ {τi<t } 2χ i+1 {W τ i W τ i+1 i 1 >Γ i τ i, Y 1 i 1}, where i = t on the set A i B i, C i, and zero otherwise. These sets are given by, A i := { Y i 1 > }, B i, := {W 1 t +τ i 1 W 1 t +1 +τ i 1 > Θ i τ i 1, t ; Y i 1 }, C i, := {W 1 t j+τ i 1 W 1 t j+1+τ i 1 < Θ i τ i 1, t j ; Y i 1 }. j=+1 Since t is decreasing with t 1 = T, τ 1 τ 2... τ m and they are stopping times with respect to the Brownian filtration. Let m and α ; β 1 T { 1, 1} 1. There exists m such that α = t m T. From , the strong Marov property and the independency of the Brownian motion increments it follows that 5.8 P W τ τ 1 α τ 1 ; Y 1 = α 1 ; β 1 = P W W 1 t j+τ 1 W 1 t j+1+τ 1 < Θ α 1, t j ; β 1 = j=m j=m P W W 1 t j+τ 1 W 1 t j+1+τ 1 < Θ α 1, t j ; Y 1 = Ψ α, β 1, where the last equality follows from 5.6 and the fact that Similarly, from 5.5 and 5.8, we have 5.9 lim Ψ α 1,..., α 1, t l, β 1,..., β 1 = 1. l P W Y = 1 τ < T, τ = α, Y 1 = β 1 = P W W +1 W +1 1 < Γ α ; β 1 i=1 αi i=1 αi = Φ α ; β 1. Using and , we conclude that τ m ; 1 Y m, P W = σ m ; Ŝm, Q where Ŝ = Ŝσ Ŝσ 1, m. Continuous martingale. Set 5.1 Z t = 1 m EW Y i Ft W, t [, T ]. i=1

25 Martingale Optimal Transport 25 Since all Brownian martingales are continuous, so is Z. Moreover, Brownian motion increments are independent and therefore, 5.11 Z τ = 1 Y i, P W a.s., m. i=1 By the construction of Y and τ s, we conclude that 5.2 holds with the process Z. Measure in M µ. The next step in the proof is to modify the martingale Z in such way that the distribution of the modified martingale is an element of M µ. For any two probability measures ν 1, ν 2 on R the Prohorov s metric is defined by dν 1, ν 2 = inf{δ > : ν 1 A ν 2 A δ + δ and ν 2 A ν 1 A δ + δ, A BR}, where BR is the set of all Borel sets A R and A δ := x A x δ, x + δ is the δ neighborhood of A. It is well nown that convergence in the Prohorov metric is equivalent to wea convergence, for more details on the Prohorov s metric see [19], Chapter 3, Section 7. Let ν 1 and ν 2, be the distributions of Ŝσ m and ŜT respectively, under the measure Q. In view of 5.1, dν 1, ν 2 < ɛ. Moreover, 4.8 implies that dν 2, µ < K and µ converges to µ wealy. Hence, the preceding inequalities, together with this convergence yield that for all sufficiently large, dν 1, µ < 2ɛ. Finally, we observe that in view of 5.2, Z T, P W = ν 1. We now use Theorem 4 on page 358 in [19] and Theorem 1 in [2] to construct a measurable function ψ : R 2 R such that the random variable Λ := ψz T, W m+2 T satisfies 5.12 Λ, P W = µ and P W Λ Z T > 2ɛ < 2ɛ. We define a martingale by, Γ t = E W Λ F W t, t [, T ]. In view of 5.12, the distribution of the martingale Γ is an element in M µ. Hence, 5.13 sup E P [GS] E W GΓ. We continue with the estimate that connects the distribution of Γ to Q M K. Observe that E W Λ = E W Z T = 1. This together with 5.12, positivity of Z and Λ, and the Holder inequality yields 5.14 E W Λ Z T = 2E W Λ Z T + E W Λ Z T = 2E W Λ Z T + where p > 1 is as 2.3 and q = p/p 1. 4ɛ + 2E W Λχ { Λ ZT >2ɛ} 4ɛ + 2 x p dµx 1/p 2ɛ 1/q, We now introduce a stochastic process Ẑt T t=, on the Brownian probability space, by, Ẑ t = Z τ for t [τ, τ +1, < m and for t [τ m, T ], we set Ẑt = Z τm. On the space ˆΩ, ˆF, { ˆF t } T t=, ˆP let S t = Ŝt σ m, t [, T ]. Recall that G is

26 26 Y.Dolinsy and H.M.Soner bounded by K. We now use the Assumption 2.1 together with 5.1 and 5.11 to arrive at 5.15 E Q GŜ E QG S Kɛ E W GZ E W GẐ LEW Z Ẑ L. Recall that by 5.2, Ẑ, P W = S, Q. Thus, E W GẐ = E QG S. This together with 5.15 yields 5.16 E Q GŜ L + Kɛ + EW GZ. From Assumption 2.1, the Doob inequality, and 5.16 we obtain sup E P [GS] E W GΓ E W GZ Lɛ 1/2q KE W χ { Γ Z >ɛ 1/2q } E Q GŜ L f Kɛ, where f K ɛ = Kɛ + Lɛ 1/2q + K 4ɛ + 2 x p dµx 1/p 2ɛ 1/q ɛ 1/2q. References [1] L. Ambrosio and A. Pratelli, Existence and stability results in the L 1 theory of optimal transportation In Optimal transportation and applications Martina Franca, 21, volume 1813 of Lecture otes in Math., pages Springer, Berlin, 23 [2] B. Acciaio, M. Beiglboc, F. Penner, W. Schachermayer and J. Temme, A Trajectorial Interpretation of Doob s Martingale Inequalities, to appear in Ann. Appl. Prob. [3] P. Billingsley, Convergence of Probability Measures, Wiley, ew Yor, [4] M. Beiglboc, P. Henry-Labordère and F. Penner, Model independent bounds for option prices: a mass transport approach, preprint. [5] H. Brown, D. Hobson and L.C.G. Rogers, Robust hedging of barrier options, Math.Finance, 11, , 21. [6] P. Carr and R. Lee, Hedging Variance Options on Continuous Semimartingales, Finance and Stochastics, 14, , 21. [7] A.M.G. Cox and J. Obloj, Robust pricing and hedging of double no-touch options, Finance and Stochastics, 15, , 211. [8] A.M.G. Cox and Wang, Root s Barrier: Construction, Optimality and Applications to Variance Options, Annals of Applied Probability, forthcoming, 212. [9] M.H.A. Davis, J. Obloj and V. Raval Arbitrage bounds for prices of weighted variance swaps, Mathematical Finance, forthcoming, 212. [1] F. Delbaen and W. Schachermayer, A general version of the fundamental theorem of asset pricing, Math. Annalen, 3, , [11]. El Karoui and M-C. Quenez, Dynamic programming and pricing of contingent claims in an incomplete maret, SIAM J. Control and Opt., 33/1, 29 66, [12] A. Galichon, P. Henry-Labordère and. Touzi, A stochastic control approach to no-arbitrage bounds given marginals, with an application to Loobac options, preprint. [13] D. Hobson, Robust hedging of the loobac option, Finance and Stochastics, 2, , [14] D. Hobson, The Sorohod Embedding Problem and Model-Independent Bounds for Option Prices, Paris Princeton Lectures on Mathematical Finance, Springer, 21.

Additional information and pricing-hedging duality in robust framework

Additional information and pricing-hedging duality in robust framework Additional information and pricing-hedging duality in robust framework Anna Aksamit based on joint work with Zhaoxu Hou and Jan Ob lój London - Paris Bachelier Workshop on Mathematical Finance Paris, September

More information

Robust pricing hedging duality for American options in discrete time financial markets

Robust pricing hedging duality for American options in discrete time financial markets Robust pricing hedging duality for American options in discrete time financial markets Anna Aksamit The University of Sydney based on joint work with Shuoqing Deng, Jan Ob lój and Xiaolu Tan Robust Techniques

More information

On the monotonicity principle of optimal Skorokhod embedding problem

On the monotonicity principle of optimal Skorokhod embedding problem On the monotonicity principle of optimal Skorokhod embedding problem Gaoyue Guo Xiaolu Tan Nizar Touzi June 10, 2015 Abstract This is a continuation of our accompanying paper [18]. We provide an alternative

More information

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Tim Leung 1, Qingshuo Song 2, and Jie Yang 3 1 Columbia University, New York, USA; leung@ieor.columbia.edu 2 City

More information

Canonical Supermartingale Couplings

Canonical Supermartingale Couplings Canonical Supermartingale Couplings Marcel Nutz Columbia University (with Mathias Beiglböck, Florian Stebegg and Nizar Touzi) June 2016 Marcel Nutz (Columbia) Canonical Supermartingale Couplings 1 / 34

More information

Random G -Expectations

Random G -Expectations Random G -Expectations Marcel Nutz ETH Zurich New advances in Backward SDEs for nancial engineering applications Tamerza, Tunisia, 28.10.2010 Marcel Nutz (ETH) Random G-Expectations 1 / 17 Outline 1 Random

More information

Question 1. The correct answers are: (a) (2) (b) (1) (c) (2) (d) (3) (e) (2) (f) (1) (g) (2) (h) (1)

Question 1. The correct answers are: (a) (2) (b) (1) (c) (2) (d) (3) (e) (2) (f) (1) (g) (2) (h) (1) Question 1 The correct answers are: a 2 b 1 c 2 d 3 e 2 f 1 g 2 h 1 Question 2 a Any probability measure Q equivalent to P on F 2 can be described by Q[{x 1, x 2 }] := q x1 q x1,x 2, 1 where q x1, q x1,x

More information

EQUIVALENCE OF TOPOLOGIES AND BOREL FIELDS FOR COUNTABLY-HILBERT SPACES

EQUIVALENCE OF TOPOLOGIES AND BOREL FIELDS FOR COUNTABLY-HILBERT SPACES EQUIVALENCE OF TOPOLOGIES AND BOREL FIELDS FOR COUNTABLY-HILBERT SPACES JEREMY J. BECNEL Abstract. We examine the main topologies wea, strong, and inductive placed on the dual of a countably-normed space

More information

Robust Mean-Variance Hedging via G-Expectation

Robust Mean-Variance Hedging via G-Expectation Robust Mean-Variance Hedging via G-Expectation Francesca Biagini, Jacopo Mancin Thilo Meyer Brandis January 3, 18 Abstract In this paper we study mean-variance hedging under the G-expectation framework.

More information

On a Class of Multidimensional Optimal Transportation Problems

On a Class of Multidimensional Optimal Transportation Problems Journal of Convex Analysis Volume 10 (2003), No. 2, 517 529 On a Class of Multidimensional Optimal Transportation Problems G. Carlier Université Bordeaux 1, MAB, UMR CNRS 5466, France and Université Bordeaux

More information

The Azéma-Yor Embedding in Non-Singular Diffusions

The Azéma-Yor Embedding in Non-Singular Diffusions Stochastic Process. Appl. Vol. 96, No. 2, 2001, 305-312 Research Report No. 406, 1999, Dept. Theoret. Statist. Aarhus The Azéma-Yor Embedding in Non-Singular Diffusions J. L. Pedersen and G. Peskir Let

More information

Brownian motion. Samy Tindel. Purdue University. Probability Theory 2 - MA 539

Brownian motion. Samy Tindel. Purdue University. Probability Theory 2 - MA 539 Brownian motion Samy Tindel Purdue University Probability Theory 2 - MA 539 Mostly taken from Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus by I. Karatzas and S. Shreve Samy T. Brownian motion Probability Theory

More information

Information and Credit Risk

Information and Credit Risk Information and Credit Risk M. L. Bedini Université de Bretagne Occidentale, Brest - Friedrich Schiller Universität, Jena Jena, March 2011 M. L. Bedini (Université de Bretagne Occidentale, Brest Information

More information

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs Lecture Notes by Walter Schachermayer Nachdiplom-Vorlesung, ETH Zürich, WS 15/16 1 Models on Finite Probability Spaces In this section we consider a stock price

More information

OPTIMAL TRANSPORTATION PLANS AND CONVERGENCE IN DISTRIBUTION

OPTIMAL TRANSPORTATION PLANS AND CONVERGENCE IN DISTRIBUTION OPTIMAL TRANSPORTATION PLANS AND CONVERGENCE IN DISTRIBUTION J.A. Cuesta-Albertos 1, C. Matrán 2 and A. Tuero-Díaz 1 1 Departamento de Matemáticas, Estadística y Computación. Universidad de Cantabria.

More information

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3 Brownian Motion Contents 1 Definition 2 1.1 Brownian Motion................................. 2 1.2 Wiener measure.................................. 3 2 Construction 4 2.1 Gaussian process.................................

More information

The Skorokhod reflection problem for functions with discontinuities (contractive case)

The Skorokhod reflection problem for functions with discontinuities (contractive case) The Skorokhod reflection problem for functions with discontinuities (contractive case) TAKIS KONSTANTOPOULOS Univ. of Texas at Austin Revised March 1999 Abstract Basic properties of the Skorokhod reflection

More information

Mathematical finance (extended from lectures of Fall 2012 by Martin Schweizer transcribed by Peter Gracar and Thomas Hille) Josef Teichmann

Mathematical finance (extended from lectures of Fall 2012 by Martin Schweizer transcribed by Peter Gracar and Thomas Hille) Josef Teichmann Mathematical finance (extended from lectures of Fall 2012 by Martin Schweizer transcribed by Peter Gracar and Thomas Hille) Josef Teichmann Contents Chapter 1. Arbitrage Theory 5 1. Stochastic Integration

More information

Quasi-sure Stochastic Analysis through Aggregation

Quasi-sure Stochastic Analysis through Aggregation Quasi-sure Stochastic Analysis through Aggregation H. Mete Soner Nizar Touzi Jianfeng Zhang March 7, 21 Abstract This paper is on developing stochastic analysis simultaneously under a general family of

More information

{σ x >t}p x. (σ x >t)=e at.

{σ x >t}p x. (σ x >t)=e at. 3.11. EXERCISES 121 3.11 Exercises Exercise 3.1 Consider the Ornstein Uhlenbeck process in example 3.1.7(B). Show that the defined process is a Markov process which converges in distribution to an N(0,σ

More information

Some SDEs with distributional drift Part I : General calculus. Flandoli, Franco; Russo, Francesco; Wolf, Jochen

Some SDEs with distributional drift Part I : General calculus. Flandoli, Franco; Russo, Francesco; Wolf, Jochen Title Author(s) Some SDEs with distributional drift Part I : General calculus Flandoli, Franco; Russo, Francesco; Wolf, Jochen Citation Osaka Journal of Mathematics. 4() P.493-P.54 Issue Date 3-6 Text

More information

Almost sure limit theorems for U-statistics

Almost sure limit theorems for U-statistics Almost sure limit theorems for U-statistics Hajo Holzmann, Susanne Koch and Alesey Min 3 Institut für Mathematische Stochasti Georg-August-Universität Göttingen Maschmühlenweg 8 0 37073 Göttingen Germany

More information

Tightness and duality of martingale transport on the Skorokhod space

Tightness and duality of martingale transport on the Skorokhod space Tightness and duality of martingale transport on the Skorokhod space Gaoyue Guo Xiaolu Tan Nizar Touzi July 4, 2015 Abstract The martingale optimal transport aims to optimally transfer a probability measure

More information

Minimal Sufficient Conditions for a Primal Optimizer in Nonsmooth Utility Maximization

Minimal Sufficient Conditions for a Primal Optimizer in Nonsmooth Utility Maximization Finance and Stochastics manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) Minimal Sufficient Conditions for a Primal Optimizer in Nonsmooth Utility Maximization Nicholas Westray Harry Zheng. Received: date

More information

Super-replication and utility maximization in large financial markets

Super-replication and utility maximization in large financial markets Super-replication and utility maximization in large financial markets M. De Donno P. Guasoni, M. Pratelli, Abstract We study the problems of super-replication and utility maximization from terminal wealth

More information

Randomization in the First Hitting Time Problem

Randomization in the First Hitting Time Problem Randomization in the First Hitting Time Problem Ken Jacson Alexander Kreinin Wanhe Zhang February 1, 29 Abstract In this paper we consider the following inverse problem for the first hitting time distribution:

More information

The Skorokhod problem in a time-dependent interval

The Skorokhod problem in a time-dependent interval The Skorokhod problem in a time-dependent interval Krzysztof Burdzy, Weining Kang and Kavita Ramanan University of Washington and Carnegie Mellon University Abstract: We consider the Skorokhod problem

More information

OPTIMAL TRANSPORT AND SKOROKHOD EMBEDDING

OPTIMAL TRANSPORT AND SKOROKHOD EMBEDDING OPTIMAL TRANSPORT AND SKOROKHOD EMBEDDING MATHIAS BEIGLBÖCK, ALEXANDER M. G. COX, AND MARTIN HUESMANN Abstract. The Skorokhod embedding problem is to represent a given probability as the distribution of

More information

STAT 331. Martingale Central Limit Theorem and Related Results

STAT 331. Martingale Central Limit Theorem and Related Results STAT 331 Martingale Central Limit Theorem and Related Results In this unit we discuss a version of the martingale central limit theorem, which states that under certain conditions, a sum of orthogonal

More information

On pathwise stochastic integration

On pathwise stochastic integration On pathwise stochastic integration Rafa l Marcin Lochowski Afican Institute for Mathematical Sciences, Warsaw School of Economics UWC seminar Rafa l Marcin Lochowski (AIMS, WSE) On pathwise stochastic

More information

Fundamental Inequalities, Convergence and the Optional Stopping Theorem for Continuous-Time Martingales

Fundamental Inequalities, Convergence and the Optional Stopping Theorem for Continuous-Time Martingales Fundamental Inequalities, Convergence and the Optional Stopping Theorem for Continuous-Time Martingales Prakash Balachandran Department of Mathematics Duke University April 2, 2008 1 Review of Discrete-Time

More information

Applications of Ito s Formula

Applications of Ito s Formula CHAPTER 4 Applications of Ito s Formula In this chapter, we discuss several basic theorems in stochastic analysis. Their proofs are good examples of applications of Itô s formula. 1. Lévy s martingale

More information

Pathwise Construction of Stochastic Integrals

Pathwise Construction of Stochastic Integrals Pathwise Construction of Stochastic Integrals Marcel Nutz First version: August 14, 211. This version: June 12, 212. Abstract We propose a method to construct the stochastic integral simultaneously under

More information

PROGRESSIVE ENLARGEMENTS OF FILTRATIONS AND SEMIMARTINGALE DECOMPOSITIONS

PROGRESSIVE ENLARGEMENTS OF FILTRATIONS AND SEMIMARTINGALE DECOMPOSITIONS PROGRESSIVE ENLARGEMENTS OF FILTRATIONS AND SEMIMARTINGALE DECOMPOSITIONS Libo Li and Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney NSW 26, Australia July 1, 211 Abstract We

More information

Doléans measures. Appendix C. C.1 Introduction

Doléans measures. Appendix C. C.1 Introduction Appendix C Doléans measures C.1 Introduction Once again all random processes will live on a fixed probability space (Ω, F, P equipped with a filtration {F t : 0 t 1}. We should probably assume the filtration

More information

n E(X t T n = lim X s Tn = X s

n E(X t T n = lim X s Tn = X s Stochastic Calculus Example sheet - Lent 15 Michael Tehranchi Problem 1. Let X be a local martingale. Prove that X is a uniformly integrable martingale if and only X is of class D. Solution 1. If If direction:

More information

arxiv: v5 [math.oc] 6 Jul 2017

arxiv: v5 [math.oc] 6 Jul 2017 Distribution-Constrained Optimal Stopping Erhan Bayratar Christopher W. Miller arxiv:1604.03042v5 math.oc 6 Jul 2017 Abstract We solve the problem of optimal stopping of a Brownian motion subject to the

More information

PATHWISE SUPER-REPLICATION VIA VOVK S OUTER MEASURE

PATHWISE SUPER-REPLICATION VIA VOVK S OUTER MEASURE PATHWISE SUPER-REPLICATION VIA VOVK S OUTER MEASURE MATHIAS BEIGLBÖCK, ALEXANDER M. G. COX, MARTIN HUESMANN, NICOLAS PERKOWSKI, AND DAVID J. PRÖMEL Abstract. Since Hobson s seminal paper [19] the connection

More information

Empirical Processes: General Weak Convergence Theory

Empirical Processes: General Weak Convergence Theory Empirical Processes: General Weak Convergence Theory Moulinath Banerjee May 18, 2010 1 Extended Weak Convergence The lack of measurability of the empirical process with respect to the sigma-field generated

More information

Variance-Optimal Hedging in Discrete Time

Variance-Optimal Hedging in Discrete Time Projetbereich B Discussion Paper No. B 247 Variance-Optimal Hedging in Discrete ime by Martin Schweizer ) February 1993 ) Financial support by Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft, Sonderforschungsbereich 303

More information

On the Multi-Dimensional Controller and Stopper Games

On the Multi-Dimensional Controller and Stopper Games On the Multi-Dimensional Controller and Stopper Games Joint work with Yu-Jui Huang University of Michigan, Ann Arbor June 7, 2012 Outline Introduction 1 Introduction 2 3 4 5 Consider a zero-sum controller-and-stopper

More information

Optimal Stopping Problems and American Options

Optimal Stopping Problems and American Options Optimal Stopping Problems and American Options Nadia Uys A dissertation submitted to the Faculty of Science, University of the Witwatersrand, in fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Master

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 22 Sep 2016

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 22 Sep 2016 EUIVALENCE BETWEEN MINIMAL TIME AND MINIMAL NORM CONTROL PROBLEMS FOR THE HEAT EUATION SHULIN IN AND GENGSHENG WANG arxiv:1609.06860v1 [math.oc] 22 Sep 2016 Abstract. This paper presents the equivalence

More information

UTILITY OPTIMIZATION IN A FINITE SCENARIO SETTING

UTILITY OPTIMIZATION IN A FINITE SCENARIO SETTING UTILITY OPTIMIZATION IN A FINITE SCENARIO SETTING J. TEICHMANN Abstract. We introduce the main concepts of duality theory for utility optimization in a setting of finitely many economic scenarios. 1. Utility

More information

MATH MEASURE THEORY AND FOURIER ANALYSIS. Contents

MATH MEASURE THEORY AND FOURIER ANALYSIS. Contents MATH 3969 - MEASURE THEORY AND FOURIER ANALYSIS ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Measure Theory 2 1.1. Properties of Measures 3 1.2. Constructing σ-algebras and measures 3 1.3. Properties of the Lebesgue measure

More information

Minimal Supersolutions of Backward Stochastic Differential Equations and Robust Hedging

Minimal Supersolutions of Backward Stochastic Differential Equations and Robust Hedging Minimal Supersolutions of Backward Stochastic Differential Equations and Robust Hedging SAMUEL DRAPEAU Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin BSDEs, Numerics and Finance Oxford July 2, 2012 joint work with GREGOR

More information

Conjugate duality in stochastic optimization

Conjugate duality in stochastic optimization Ari-Pekka Perkkiö, Institute of Mathematics, Aalto University Ph.D. instructor/joint work with Teemu Pennanen, Institute of Mathematics, Aalto University March 15th 2010 1 / 13 We study convex problems.

More information

The Pedestrian s Guide to Local Time

The Pedestrian s Guide to Local Time The Pedestrian s Guide to Local Time Tomas Björk, Department of Finance, Stockholm School of Economics, Box 651, SE-113 83 Stockholm, SWEDEN tomas.bjork@hhs.se November 19, 213 Preliminary version Comments

More information

2. The Concept of Convergence: Ultrafilters and Nets

2. The Concept of Convergence: Ultrafilters and Nets 2. The Concept of Convergence: Ultrafilters and Nets NOTE: AS OF 2008, SOME OF THIS STUFF IS A BIT OUT- DATED AND HAS A FEW TYPOS. I WILL REVISE THIS MATE- RIAL SOMETIME. In this lecture we discuss two

More information

Monotone Martingale Transport Plans and Skorohod Embedding

Monotone Martingale Transport Plans and Skorohod Embedding Monotone Martingale Transport Plans and Skorohod Embedding Mathias Beiglböck Pierre Henry-Labordère Nizar Touzi arxiv:1701.06779v1 [math.pr] 24 Jan 2017 March 28, 2018 Abstract We show that the left-monotone

More information

Recent results in game theoretic mathematical finance

Recent results in game theoretic mathematical finance Recent results in game theoretic mathematical finance Nicolas Perkowski Humboldt Universität zu Berlin May 31st, 2017 Thera Stochastics In Honor of Ioannis Karatzas s 65th Birthday Based on joint work

More information

Stability of optimization problems with stochastic dominance constraints

Stability of optimization problems with stochastic dominance constraints Stability of optimization problems with stochastic dominance constraints D. Dentcheva and W. Römisch Stevens Institute of Technology, Hoboken Humboldt-University Berlin www.math.hu-berlin.de/~romisch SIAM

More information

(1) Consider the space S consisting of all continuous real-valued functions on the closed interval [0, 1]. For f, g S, define

(1) Consider the space S consisting of all continuous real-valued functions on the closed interval [0, 1]. For f, g S, define Homework, Real Analysis I, Fall, 2010. (1) Consider the space S consisting of all continuous real-valued functions on the closed interval [0, 1]. For f, g S, define ρ(f, g) = 1 0 f(x) g(x) dx. Show that

More information

A Note on Robust Representations of Law-Invariant Quasiconvex Functions

A Note on Robust Representations of Law-Invariant Quasiconvex Functions A Note on Robust Representations of Law-Invariant Quasiconvex Functions Samuel Drapeau Michael Kupper Ranja Reda October 6, 21 We give robust representations of law-invariant monotone quasiconvex functions.

More information

Spatial Ergodicity of the Harris Flows

Spatial Ergodicity of the Harris Flows Communications on Stochastic Analysis Volume 11 Number 2 Article 6 6-217 Spatial Ergodicity of the Harris Flows E.V. Glinyanaya Institute of Mathematics NAS of Ukraine, glinkate@gmail.com Follow this and

More information

Dynkin (λ-) and π-systems; monotone classes of sets, and of functions with some examples of application (mainly of a probabilistic flavor)

Dynkin (λ-) and π-systems; monotone classes of sets, and of functions with some examples of application (mainly of a probabilistic flavor) Dynkin (λ-) and π-systems; monotone classes of sets, and of functions with some examples of application (mainly of a probabilistic flavor) Matija Vidmar February 7, 2018 1 Dynkin and π-systems Some basic

More information

Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales

Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales Lecture 21: Representations of Martingales 1 of 11 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 215 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales Right-continuous inverses Let

More information

Optimal Skorokhod embedding under finitely-many marginal constraints

Optimal Skorokhod embedding under finitely-many marginal constraints Optimal Skorokhod embedding under finitely-many marginal constraints Gaoyue Guo Xiaolu Tan Nizar Touzi June 10, 2015 Abstract The Skorokhod embedding problem aims to represent a given probability measure

More information

THE UNIQUE MINIMAL DUAL REPRESENTATION OF A CONVEX FUNCTION

THE UNIQUE MINIMAL DUAL REPRESENTATION OF A CONVEX FUNCTION THE UNIQUE MINIMAL DUAL REPRESENTATION OF A CONVEX FUNCTION HALUK ERGIN AND TODD SARVER Abstract. Suppose (i) X is a separable Banach space, (ii) C is a convex subset of X that is a Baire space (when endowed

More information

Existence and Comparisons for BSDEs in general spaces

Existence and Comparisons for BSDEs in general spaces Existence and Comparisons for BSDEs in general spaces Samuel N. Cohen and Robert J. Elliott University of Adelaide and University of Calgary BFS 2010 S.N. Cohen, R.J. Elliott (Adelaide, Calgary) BSDEs

More information

An essay on the general theory of stochastic processes

An essay on the general theory of stochastic processes Probability Surveys Vol. 3 (26) 345 412 ISSN: 1549-5787 DOI: 1.1214/1549578614 An essay on the general theory of stochastic processes Ashkan Nikeghbali ETHZ Departement Mathematik, Rämistrasse 11, HG G16

More information

A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations

A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations Michael Röckner Reference: C. Prevot, M. Röckner: Springer LN in Math. 1905, Berlin (2007) And see the references therein for the original

More information

Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for bounded

Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for bounded Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for bounded càdlàg processes Patrick Cheridito ORFE Princeton University Princeton, NJ, USA dito@princeton.edu Freddy Delbaen Departement für Mathematik ETH Zürich

More information

On the dual problem of utility maximization

On the dual problem of utility maximization On the dual problem of utility maximization Yiqing LIN Joint work with L. GU and J. YANG University of Vienna Sept. 2nd 2015 Workshop Advanced methods in financial mathematics Angers 1 Introduction Basic

More information

Convergence at first and second order of some approximations of stochastic integrals

Convergence at first and second order of some approximations of stochastic integrals Convergence at first and second order of some approximations of stochastic integrals Bérard Bergery Blandine, Vallois Pierre IECN, Nancy-Université, CNRS, INRIA, Boulevard des Aiguillettes B.P. 239 F-5456

More information

Estimates for probabilities of independent events and infinite series

Estimates for probabilities of independent events and infinite series Estimates for probabilities of independent events and infinite series Jürgen Grahl and Shahar evo September 9, 06 arxiv:609.0894v [math.pr] 8 Sep 06 Abstract This paper deals with finite or infinite sequences

More information

Stochastic Processes. Winter Term Paolo Di Tella Technische Universität Dresden Institut für Stochastik

Stochastic Processes. Winter Term Paolo Di Tella Technische Universität Dresden Institut für Stochastik Stochastic Processes Winter Term 2016-2017 Paolo Di Tella Technische Universität Dresden Institut für Stochastik Contents 1 Preliminaries 5 1.1 Uniform integrability.............................. 5 1.2

More information

GENERALIZED COVARIATION FOR BANACH SPACE VALUED PROCESSES, ITÔ FORMULA AND APPLICATIONS

GENERALIZED COVARIATION FOR BANACH SPACE VALUED PROCESSES, ITÔ FORMULA AND APPLICATIONS Di Girolami, C. and Russo, F. Osaka J. Math. 51 (214), 729 783 GENERALIZED COVARIATION FOR BANACH SPACE VALUED PROCESSES, ITÔ FORMULA AND APPLICATIONS CRISTINA DI GIROLAMI and FRANCESCO RUSSO (Received

More information

Robust Superhedging with Jumps and Diffusion arxiv: v2 [q-fin.mf] 17 Jul 2015

Robust Superhedging with Jumps and Diffusion arxiv: v2 [q-fin.mf] 17 Jul 2015 Robust Superhedging with Jumps and Diffusion arxiv:1407.1674v2 [q-fin.mf] 17 Jul 2015 Marcel Nutz July 20, 2015 Abstract We establish a nondominated version of the optional decomposition theorem in a setting

More information

Stochastic Calculus for Finance II - some Solutions to Chapter VII

Stochastic Calculus for Finance II - some Solutions to Chapter VII Stochastic Calculus for Finance II - some Solutions to Chapter VII Matthias hul Last Update: June 9, 25 Exercise 7 Black-Scholes-Merton Equation for the up-and-out Call) i) We have ii) We first compute

More information

Order book resilience, price manipulation, and the positive portfolio problem

Order book resilience, price manipulation, and the positive portfolio problem Order book resilience, price manipulation, and the positive portfolio problem Alexander Schied Mannheim University Workshop on New Directions in Financial Mathematics Institute for Pure and Applied Mathematics,

More information

Squared Bessel Process with Delay

Squared Bessel Process with Delay Southern Illinois University Carbondale OpenSIUC Articles and Preprints Department of Mathematics 216 Squared Bessel Process with Delay Harry Randolph Hughes Southern Illinois University Carbondale, hrhughes@siu.edu

More information

Stochastic optimal control with rough paths

Stochastic optimal control with rough paths Stochastic optimal control with rough paths Paul Gassiat TU Berlin Stochastic processes and their statistics in Finance, Okinawa, October 28, 2013 Joint work with Joscha Diehl and Peter Friz Introduction

More information

Notes 1 : Measure-theoretic foundations I

Notes 1 : Measure-theoretic foundations I Notes 1 : Measure-theoretic foundations I Math 733-734: Theory of Probability Lecturer: Sebastien Roch References: [Wil91, Section 1.0-1.8, 2.1-2.3, 3.1-3.11], [Fel68, Sections 7.2, 8.1, 9.6], [Dur10,

More information

SUMMARY OF RESULTS ON PATH SPACES AND CONVERGENCE IN DISTRIBUTION FOR STOCHASTIC PROCESSES

SUMMARY OF RESULTS ON PATH SPACES AND CONVERGENCE IN DISTRIBUTION FOR STOCHASTIC PROCESSES SUMMARY OF RESULTS ON PATH SPACES AND CONVERGENCE IN DISTRIBUTION FOR STOCHASTIC PROCESSES RUTH J. WILLIAMS October 2, 2017 Department of Mathematics, University of California, San Diego, 9500 Gilman Drive,

More information

Supermartingales as Radon-Nikodym Densities and Related Measure Extensions

Supermartingales as Radon-Nikodym Densities and Related Measure Extensions Supermartingales as Radon-Nikodym Densities and Related Measure Extensions Nicolas Perkowski Institut für Mathematik Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin Johannes Ruf Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance

More information

Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for unbounded

Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for unbounded Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for unbounded càdlàg processes Patrick Cheridito ORFE Princeton University Princeton, NJ, USA dito@princeton.edu Freddy Delbaen Departement für Mathematik ETH

More information

Integral Jensen inequality

Integral Jensen inequality Integral Jensen inequality Let us consider a convex set R d, and a convex function f : (, + ]. For any x,..., x n and λ,..., λ n with n λ i =, we have () f( n λ ix i ) n λ if(x i ). For a R d, let δ a

More information

NOTES ON EXISTENCE AND UNIQUENESS THEOREMS FOR ODES

NOTES ON EXISTENCE AND UNIQUENESS THEOREMS FOR ODES NOTES ON EXISTENCE AND UNIQUENESS THEOREMS FOR ODES JONATHAN LUK These notes discuss theorems on the existence, uniqueness and extension of solutions for ODEs. None of these results are original. The proofs

More information

On the martingales obtained by an extension due to Saisho, Tanemura and Yor of Pitman s theorem

On the martingales obtained by an extension due to Saisho, Tanemura and Yor of Pitman s theorem On the martingales obtained by an extension due to Saisho, Tanemura and Yor of Pitman s theorem Koichiro TAKAOKA Dept of Applied Physics, Tokyo Institute of Technology Abstract M Yor constructed a family

More information

Prof. Erhan Bayraktar (University of Michigan)

Prof. Erhan Bayraktar (University of Michigan) September 17, 2012 KAP 414 2:15 PM- 3:15 PM Prof. (University of Michigan) Abstract: We consider a zero-sum stochastic differential controller-and-stopper game in which the state process is a controlled

More information

Stochastic Processes II/ Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie III. Lecture Notes

Stochastic Processes II/ Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie III. Lecture Notes BMS Basic Course Stochastic Processes II/ Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie III Michael Scheutzow Lecture Notes Technische Universität Berlin Sommersemester 218 preliminary version October 12th 218 Contents

More information

Risk-Minimality and Orthogonality of Martingales

Risk-Minimality and Orthogonality of Martingales Risk-Minimality and Orthogonality of Martingales Martin Schweizer Universität Bonn Institut für Angewandte Mathematik Wegelerstraße 6 D 53 Bonn 1 (Stochastics and Stochastics Reports 3 (199, 123 131 2

More information

Lecture 12. F o s, (1.1) F t := s>t

Lecture 12. F o s, (1.1) F t := s>t Lecture 12 1 Brownian motion: the Markov property Let C := C(0, ), R) be the space of continuous functions mapping from 0, ) to R, in which a Brownian motion (B t ) t 0 almost surely takes its value. Let

More information

Duality of multiparameter Hardy spaces H p on spaces of homogeneous type

Duality of multiparameter Hardy spaces H p on spaces of homogeneous type Duality of multiparameter Hardy spaces H p on spaces of homogeneous type Yongsheng Han, Ji Li, and Guozhen Lu Department of Mathematics Vanderbilt University Nashville, TN Internet Analysis Seminar 2012

More information

ASYMPTOTICALLY NONEXPANSIVE MAPPINGS IN MODULAR FUNCTION SPACES ABSTRACT

ASYMPTOTICALLY NONEXPANSIVE MAPPINGS IN MODULAR FUNCTION SPACES ABSTRACT ASYMPTOTICALLY NONEXPANSIVE MAPPINGS IN MODULAR FUNCTION SPACES T. DOMINGUEZ-BENAVIDES, M.A. KHAMSI AND S. SAMADI ABSTRACT In this paper, we prove that if ρ is a convex, σ-finite modular function satisfying

More information

Solutions to Tutorial 11 (Week 12)

Solutions to Tutorial 11 (Week 12) THE UIVERSITY OF SYDEY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS AD STATISTICS Solutions to Tutorial 11 (Week 12) MATH3969: Measure Theory and Fourier Analysis (Advanced) Semester 2, 2017 Web Page: http://sydney.edu.au/science/maths/u/ug/sm/math3969/

More information

Filtrations, Markov Processes and Martingales. Lectures on Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus, Braunschweig, Lecture 3: The Lévy-Itô Decomposition

Filtrations, Markov Processes and Martingales. Lectures on Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus, Braunschweig, Lecture 3: The Lévy-Itô Decomposition Filtrations, Markov Processes and Martingales Lectures on Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus, Braunschweig, Lecture 3: The Lévy-Itô Decomposition David pplebaum Probability and Statistics Department,

More information

1. Stochastic Processes and filtrations

1. Stochastic Processes and filtrations 1. Stochastic Processes and 1. Stoch. pr., A stochastic process (X t ) t T is a collection of random variables on (Ω, F) with values in a measurable space (S, S), i.e., for all t, In our case X t : Ω S

More information

An Introduction to Malliavin calculus and its applications

An Introduction to Malliavin calculus and its applications An Introduction to Malliavin calculus and its applications Lecture 3: Clark-Ocone formula David Nualart Department of Mathematics Kansas University University of Wyoming Summer School 214 David Nualart

More information

Trajectorial Martingales, Null Sets, Convergence and Integration

Trajectorial Martingales, Null Sets, Convergence and Integration Trajectorial Martingales, Null Sets, Convergence and Integration Sebastian Ferrando, Department of Mathematics, Ryerson University, Toronto, Canada Alfredo Gonzalez and Sebastian Ferrando Trajectorial

More information

OPTIMAL SOLUTIONS TO STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL INCLUSIONS

OPTIMAL SOLUTIONS TO STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL INCLUSIONS APPLICATIONES MATHEMATICAE 29,4 (22), pp. 387 398 Mariusz Michta (Zielona Góra) OPTIMAL SOLUTIONS TO STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL INCLUSIONS Abstract. A martingale problem approach is used first to analyze

More information

Local semiconvexity of Kantorovich potentials on non-compact manifolds

Local semiconvexity of Kantorovich potentials on non-compact manifolds Local semiconvexity of Kantorovich potentials on non-compact manifolds Alessio Figalli, Nicola Gigli Abstract We prove that any Kantorovich potential for the cost function c = d / on a Riemannian manifold

More information

Risk Measures in non-dominated Models

Risk Measures in non-dominated Models Purpose: Study Risk Measures taking into account the model uncertainty in mathematical finance. Plan 1 Non-dominated Models Model Uncertainty Fundamental topological Properties 2 Risk Measures on L p (c)

More information

QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE

QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE Research Paper 241 December 2008 Viability of Markets with an Infinite Number of Assets Constantinos Kardaras ISSN 1441-8010 VIABILITY

More information

Necessary Conditions for the Existence of Utility Maximizing Strategies under Transaction Costs

Necessary Conditions for the Existence of Utility Maximizing Strategies under Transaction Costs Necessary Conditions for the Existence of Utility Maximizing Strategies under Transaction Costs Paolo Guasoni Boston University and University of Pisa Walter Schachermayer Vienna University of Technology

More information

Mean-field dual of cooperative reproduction

Mean-field dual of cooperative reproduction The mean-field dual of systems with cooperative reproduction joint with Tibor Mach (Prague) A. Sturm (Göttingen) Friday, July 6th, 2018 Poisson construction of Markov processes Let (X t ) t 0 be a continuous-time

More information

MATHS 730 FC Lecture Notes March 5, Introduction

MATHS 730 FC Lecture Notes March 5, Introduction 1 INTRODUCTION MATHS 730 FC Lecture Notes March 5, 2014 1 Introduction Definition. If A, B are sets and there exists a bijection A B, they have the same cardinality, which we write as A, #A. If there exists

More information

Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process

Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process Lecture 17: Brownian motion as a Markov process 1 of 14 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 2015 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process Brownian motion is

More information

Optimal Stopping under Adverse Nonlinear Expectation and Related Games

Optimal Stopping under Adverse Nonlinear Expectation and Related Games Optimal Stopping under Adverse Nonlinear Expectation and Related Games Marcel Nutz Jianfeng Zhang First version: December 7, 2012. This version: July 21, 2014 Abstract We study the existence of optimal

More information