Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam Faculty of Sciences MASTER THESIS. Michal Rychnovský Portfolio Credit Risk Models. Department of Mathematics

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam Faculty of Sciences MASTER THESIS. Michal Rychnovský Portfolio Credit Risk Models. Department of Mathematics"

Transcription

1 Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam Faculty of Sciences MASTER THESIS Michal Rychnovský Portfolio Credit Risk Models Department of Mathematics Supervisor: Dr. P.J.C. Spreij Program of Study: Stochastics and Financial Mathematics 2010

2 Acknowledgments I would like to thank Dr. Peter Spreij for all his help, discussions and comments in writing this thesis. Michal Rychnovský ii

3 Abstract Title: Portfolio Credit Risk Models Author: Michal Rychnovský Author s address: michal@rychnovsky.cz Supervisor: Dr. P.J.C. Spreij Supervisor s university: Universiteit van Amsterdam Supervisor s department: Korteweg-de Vries Institute for Mathematics Supervisor s address: p.j.c.spreij@uva.nl Abstract: The aim of the present work is to describe possible models for portfolio credit risk. Our main interest is put on such models where the correlation structure is described by a copula. We start by introducing the terms of probability of default and expected loss, together with some single obligor models. Then we give an example of a duo basket model, followed by a discussion about copulas and dependence measures. Finally, we focus on threshold models and their limit behavior for number of loans going to infinity; here we derive the tail expression of the limit distribution of average losses. Keywords: Portfolio credit risk, copula, dependence measure, threshold model, limit behavior. iii

4 Contents Introduction 1 1 Single Obligor Credit Risk Models Expected Loss Scoring Models Dynamic Models Structural Models Duo Basket Example Threshold Model Default Correlation First-to-Default and Second-to-Default Probability Copula Functions Definition of Copula Sklar s Theorem Frechét-Hoeffding s bounds Comonotonicity and Countermonotonicity Some Examples of Copulae Dependence Measures Linear Correlation Rank Correlation Tail Dependence Multivariate Tail Dependence Portfolio Credit Risk Models Threshold Model Industry Models iv

5 5.3 Properties of Models Limit Behavior of Large Portfolios Expected Average Loss Polynomially Declining Tails Exponentially Declining Tails Conclusions 56 Bibliography 57 A Probability 60 A.1 Quantile Function A.2 Gamma and Inverse Gamma Distribution A.3 Multivariate t-distribution B Extreme Value Theory 63 B.1 Regularly Varying Functions B.2 Class M a θ v

6 Introduction The banking sector is one of the most profitable but also one of the riskiest industries, where most risk is connected to the event called default. Default is usually defined as a violation of debt contract conditions, such as a lack of will or a disability to pay a loan back. In the case of default, the creditor e.g. a bank or other financial institution suffers a loss. The risk is usually called credit risk. In order to quantify credit risk, banks try to develop analytical models to estimate default probabilities and expected losses, and calculate an adequate capital reserve to cover all unexpected losses. This is in practice done under supervision of regulatory institutions such as the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. In this work we describe the principles of several credit risk models. In the first chapter we summarize the most common approaches to single obligor credit risk modeling. Then we start with an introductory example of a simple duo basket model. Our main interest is put on credit risk of a portfolio of loans, where its correlation structure is described by a copula. Therefore in Chapters 3 and 4 we describe the mathematical foundations of copula functions and dependence measures. In Chapter 5 we define two of the most common industry models based on copula functions. Finally, in the last chapter we focus on the average loss, when the number of losses goes to infinity, and describe the tail expression for the limit distribution. 1

7 Chapter 1 Single Obligor Credit Risk Models In the first chapter we introduce several common approaches used for credit risk modeling. Throughout this chapter we assume that we have one client with certain characteristics asking for a loan. The first section is mainly based on Rychnovský 2008 and the second section on Pazdera et al In the following chapters we then focus on the multiple loans portfolios. 1.1 Expected Loss Consider a probability space Ω, F, P with an F-measurable random variable L = 1 D, where D is the event that default occurs in a one-year horizon. Then we can define the one-year Probability of Default P D as P D = PL = What is important in the field of credit risk, is the distribution of potential losses, and in particular, the expected loss. In order to quantify the expected loss caused by the client s default, Basel II 2001 defines the following characteristics: Exposure at Default EAD is the amount of money owed at the moment of default, and Loss Given Default LGD is the percentage of EAD which has not been recovered after default. 1 LGD is usually assumed to be discounted and corrected for recovery costs. 1 At the moment of default the bank begins to recover its money back. This process is often partially successful; sometimes even the whole sum is recovered. 2

8 Then the expected loss can be calculated as EL = P D LGD EAD. 1.2 The unexpected loss is according to Basel II 2001 defined as the Value at Risk, i.e. the 1 α quantile of the loss distribution see Figure 1.1, where X is a potential loss and α is a predefined level. PX > VaR = α, 1.3 Figure 1.1: Value at Risk according to Basel For specification of Value at Risk or other quantiles Basel II 2001 uses Vašíček formula as the mapping function. For more details see the original articles Vašíček 1987, The three characteristics in 1.2 are usually modeled separately. In further sections we focus on different approaches for Probability of Default modeling. For more information about Loss Given Default and Exposure at Default modeling we refer to Engelmann and Rauhmeier 2006, Kim and Kim 2006 or Witzany et al Scoring Models There are several approaches for Probability of Default modeling, based on different information about the obligor. Usually we suppose we have a database of previous clients and their defaults to calibrate the model. For the scoring model we want to evaluate score the obligor according to his characteristics in order to quantify his ability to pay the money back and in consequence his P D. 3

9 Before presenting some of these scoring functions used in practice, we introduce some useful notation. Suppose that our database contains s explanatory categorical variables regressors for each client, where the i-th variable consists of s i categories. Then put Z = { i, j : i {1,..., s}, j {1,... s i, } } 1.4 the set of all ordered pairs i, j of variables i and their categories j. Then for each client k we have the vector x k = x i j k : i, j Z 1.5 of dummy variables i.e. x i j k = 1 if the client k lies in the category j of the variable i, and x i j k = 0 otherwise. Then we denote by G the index set of all non-defaulted clients and B the index set of all defaulted clients, and in the same spirit we define G i j = { k : k {1,..., n}, k G, x i j k = 1 } as the index set of all non-defaulted clients k lying in the category j of the variable i; and B i j = { k : k {1,..., n}, k B, x i j k = 1 } as the index set of all defaulted clients k lying in the category j of the variable i. Now, based on the database of the observed clients, we define the total odds as the ratio of the number of non-defaulted vs. defaulted clients in the sample, odds = G B, 1.6 and also for individual categories j of variable i the odds i j for certain category, odds i j = Gi j 1.7 Bj i. Finally we define the odds ratio OR i j as the ratio of categorical odds i j and total odds, OR i j = oddsi j odds. 1.8 Now, we are ready to introduce three scoring functions used in the financial practice. In all cases the scoring function represents an estimate of the client s 1 P Dx oddsx =, conditional to his regressors. The derivation and practical implementation of these models can be found in Rychnovský P Dx

10 1.2.1 Independence Model The Independence model is based on the assumption that all the values of the regressors are independent. Due to its simplicity, this model is very often used, although this assumption is in practice seldom fulfilled. In the independence model there are no parameters to be estimated and the conditional odds can be represented in the terms of a scoring function in the following way, S IM x = odds ORj i xi j, 1.9 i,j Z where x = x i j : i, j Z is the set of dummy variables representing the client. Sometimes also a logarithm of this function is used as a scoring function, 2 ln S IM x = lnodds + i,j Z x i j lnor i j The main disadvantage of this model is the assumption of independence and the fact that all categories have the same weights. Therefore, there are two more models generalizing this approach by adding a nonnegative weight to each variable or even to each category WOE Model The first generalization of the function 1.9 is the WOE model for Weight of Evidence, where to all variables a weight is assigned according to their statistical importance. 3 This way we get a scoring function in the form S W OE x, w = odds ORj i wi x i j, 1.11 i,j Z or a logarithm of the scoring function in the form ln S W OE x, w = lnodds + i,j Z w i x i j lnor i j According to Aspey et al. 2003, the WOE model is suitable for databases with at least 150 defaults. 2 In this case the score value corresponds to logit of the function 1 P D. 3 The weights are then estimated using logistic regression. For more information about logistic regression we refer to Agresti 1990 or Hosmer and Lemeshow

11 1.2.3 Full Logistic Model Finally, in the full logistic model we put a certain weight to each category of the categorical variables i.e. to each dummy variable. 4 The scoring function is then in the form S F LM x, w = odds ORj i wi j xi j, 1.13 or in its logarithmic form, i,j Z ln S F LM x, w = lnodds + i,j Z w i jx i j lnor i j This model is the most flexible but also the most complicated from the three introduced models. From the form 1.14 we can see that due to the used logit function this approach is equivalent to the common logistic regression used for PD estimation. According to Aspey et al. 2003, the full logistic model is suitable for databases with at least 1200 defaults. 1.3 Dynamic Models Whereas the scoring models estimate only the one-year Probability of Default based on defaults occurring in a one year horizon, dynamic models understand the time until default as a random variable. One of the most common dynamic approaches is based on survival analysis. This section is based mainly on Kalbfleisch et al and Collett Survival Analysis Survival analysis deals with modeling of the time elapsed until some particular event occurs it is called exit or end-point, conditional on the specific characteristics of the subject. In the case of P D modeling we model the time until default of the client with given characteristics. First we introduce several terms of survival analysis. Assume that X is an absolutely continuous nonnegative random variable representing the time to default of a client. Denote F the distribution function and f the density of X. Then we define a hazard function or intensity of the client as 1 λt = lim Pt X < t + h X t h 0+ h 4 The weights are then again estimated using logistic regression. 6

12 By a survivor function St we denote the probability that the client will not default until time t will survive, i.e. St = 1 F t. Using this relation we can rewrite the hazard function 1.15 into the form λt = lim h 0+ F t + h F t h From 1.16 we get also a converse relation [ St = exp 1 St = ft St = d log St dt t Finally, we define a cumulative hazard function as Λt = t 0 0 ] λudu λudu = log St Cox Model D. R. Cox in Cox 1972 assumed the hazard function of subject k at time t in the form λt; x k = λ 0 t expx kβ, 1.19 where x k is the vector of characteristics of subject k and β is a vector of parameters. The function λ 0 t is then called a baseline hazard function, independent of the client s characteristics. Due to the fact that the relation λt; x k λt; x l = expx k β expx l β depends only on clients characteristics, the Cox model is often called the proportional hazards model. In Cox 1975 Cox introduced a generalization of 1.19 by implementing time dependent explanatory characteristics x k t. This model then assumes the hazard function in the form λt, x k t = λ 0 t expx k t β The corresponding survivor function is then [ St, x k t = P T > t x k t = exp t 0 ] λ 0 u expx k u βdu. Then for the case of discrete time and no multiple defaults at any time, we can derive the Breslow-Crowley maximum likelihood estimator of the baseline hazard function. If n is the number of clients in our database, Y k t is an indicator that 7

13 client k has not defaulted until time t, and dn k t is an indicator that client k defaulted in the time interval t 1, t], we can estimate the baseline hazard function as n k=1 λ 0 t = dn kt n k=1 exp x k tβ Y k t For β we then substitute an estimate β. If m is the number of defaulted clients and t 1 < < t m are the observed default times, we can define auxiliary functions M and N as expx k t k β Mβ, t k = n i=1 Y kt k expx k t k β and N β, t k = m Y k t k x k t k Mβ, t k. i=1 Using this notation, the estimate of β can be computed from the expression for the partial likelihood function by solving the equation m [x k t k N β, t k ] = k=1 The t-year Probability of Default can be in terms of 1.17 and 1.20 then estimated as [ t ] P Dx, t = 1 exp λ 0 t expx βdu, where x is the vector of clients characteristics. For further details as well as formulas for multiple defaults we refer to Collett As a parametric alternative to the Cox model also the Accelerated Failure Time AFT model can be used see e.g. Kalbfleisch et al Structural Models The models presented in the previous sections all belong to the class of so called reduced form models. These models are easily calibrated to estimate the Probability of Default but give no information about the circumstances of the default. This is on the other hand the main aim of so called structural or firm-value models. These approaches are designed to model the underlying structure of the firm s value in time. In the following text we describe the Merton model as the original concept for many of the present structural models. 8

14 1.4.1 Merton Model The original model was introduced in Merton Consider a firm with a stochastic value process V t. Assume that the value V t of the firm s assets at time t consists of its equity value S t and its debt value B t the value in time t of a single debt obligation with maturity T and face value B. Thus, V t = S t + B t for t [0, T ] At time T two situations may occur. 1. V T > B. In this case the value of the firm s assets exceeds the value of the debt. Here the debt is fully recovered and the shareholders get the residual value. Then B T = B and S T = V T B. 2. V T B. In this case the value of the firm s assets is less than its liabilities, and the firm falls into default. Here all the value of the firm s assets is paid to the bondholders. Then B T = V T and S T = 0. Summarizing these two situations, we get similar expressions as we know from derivatives pricing models, S T = V T B B T = B B V T Therefore, to develop the Black-Scholes-type pricing model, Merton 1974 makes the following assumptions: 1. There are no transactions costs, taxes, or problems with indivisibilities of assets. 2. There is a sufficient number of investors with comparable wealth levels so that each investor believes that he can buy and sell as much of an asset as he wants at the market price. 3. There exists an exchange market for borrowing and lending at the same rate of interest. 4. Short-sales of all assets, with full use of the proceeds, is allowed. 5. Trading in assets takes place continuously in time. 6. The Modigliani-Miller theorem that the value of the firm is invariant to its capital structure obtains. 9

15 7. The Term-Structure is flat and known with certainty. I.e., the price of a riskless discount bond which promises a payment of one dollar at time T in the future is P T = exp[ rt ] where r is the instantaneous riskless rate of interest, the same for all time. 8. The dynamics for the value of the firm, V t, through time can be described by a diffusion-type stochastic process with stochastic differential equation dv t = αv t Cdt + σv t dw t, 1.27 where α is the instantaneous expected rate of return on the firm per unit time, C is the total dollar payouts by the firm per unit time to either its shareholders or liabilities-holders e.g., dividends or interest payments if positive, and it is the net dollars received by the firm from new financing if negative; σ 2 is the instantaneous variance of the return on the firm per unit time; dw t is a standard Wiener process. According to 1.25, the equity value at the terminal time T corresponds to a European call option on V t with strike price B and maturity T. Then the value of the equity today can be expressed in the Black-Scholes-type formula, S 0 = V 0 Φd 1 Be rt Φd 2, 1.28 where Φ is the cumulative distribution function of the standard normal distribution, and d 1 = log V 0 + r + 1 B 2 σ2 T σ, 1.29 T d 2 = d 1 σ T Moreover, under the risk neutral measure Q we have log V T N log V 0 + r 1 2 σ2 T, σ 2 T. And thus at time t = 0 we get the Probability of Default as log V 0 B P D = QV T B = 1 Φ + r σ2 T σ σ T, 1.31 T i.e. in the form P D = 1 Φd 2. For more information about structural models together with some applications we refer to McNeil et al or Schönbucher

16 Chapter 2 Duo Basket Example In this chapter we start with credit risk valuation for a portfolio consisting of more loans than one. For better understanding the basics of portfolio dependence structure, we start with an introductory example of a particular duo basket, i.e. a portfolio of two loans. This example is taken from Bluhm and Overbeck Threshold Model Suppose we have two loans in our basket. Loan A has its probability of default p A and loan B has its probability of default p B. For both loans we expect EAD being 100% of the face value and LGD = 1, i.e. in the case of default all the investment will be lost. In the case of threshold models we suppose that for each obligor there exists a random variable X representing a creditworthiness index, and that default occurs if and only if this index falls bellow a certain bound. In our example we follow an approach of CreditMetrics, see Gupton et al For a one-year horizon we introduce Bernoulli variables L A and L B, L A = 1 {XA <d A }, 2.1 L B = 1 {XB <d B }, 2.2 where X A and X B are standard normal random variables with correlation coefficient ρ, and d A and d B are real bounds. Then we get for the probabilities of default the relations p A = PL A = 1 = PX A < d A = Φd A, p B = PL B = 1 = PX B < d B = Φd B, 11

17 where Φ is the cumulative distribution function of the standard normal distribution. We also get the converse relations d A = Φ 1 p A, d B = Φ 1 p B. According to CreditMetrics, a specific structure is assumed. Suppose that X A and X B are defined as follows: X A = ρ Y + 1 ρ ε A, 2.3 X B = ρ Y + 1 ρ ε B, 2.4 where Y, ε A and ε B are independent, standard normal random variables. In this structure, Y is called a common factor representing the state of the economy, and ε A and ε B are specific factors for individual loans. It is not difficult to check that according to this definition, X A and X B are again standard normally distributed with correlation coefficient ρ. Moreover, we can compute the joint distribution of X A and X B. Proposition 2.1. Let Y, ε A and ε B be independent, standard normal random variables. Then X A and X B defined in 2.3 and 2.4 have a bivariate normal joint distribution, XA 0 1 ρ N 2, ρ 1 X B Proof. If we rewrite equations 2.3 and 2.4 into a matrix form, we get Y XA ρ 1 ρ 0 =, 2.6 ρ 0 1 ρ X B where due to the independence of its components, the random vector Y, ε A, ε B has a joint normal distribution, Y Z = N 3 0, We denote B = ε A ε B ρ 1 ρ 0 ρ 0 1 ρ normal distribution with the expectation XA E = B E Z = X B and get that 0 0 ε A ε B XA and the covariance matrix XA Var = VarBZ = BVar ZB = BB = X B X B = BZ has also a 1 ρ. ρ 1 12

18 2.2 Default Correlation In the previous section we defined ρ as the correlation coefficient of the random variables X A and X B. However, the real subject of our concern is the default correlation, i.e. the correlation between the default indicators L A and L B. Proposition 2.2. Let A and B be two loans with default probabilities p A and p B and correlation ρ = CorrX A, X B. Then under the CreditMetrics model the default correlation of the loans A and B is of the form CorrL A, L B = Φ 2,ρ Φ 1 p A, Φ 1 p B p A p B, 2.7 pa 1 p A p B 1 p B where Φ 2,ρ denotes the standard bivariate normal distribution function with correlation ρ, i.e. a b 1 Φ 2,ρ a, b = 2π 1 ρ exp x2 + y 2 ρxy dxdy ρ 2 Proof. First recall that L A and L B are Bernoulli variables with parameters p A and p B. Thus, we have E L A = p A, E L B = p B and Var L A = p A 1 p A, Var L B = p B 1 p B. Furthermore, we can compute E L A L B = PL A = 1, L B = 1 = PX A < d A, X B < d B = P X A < Φ 1 p A, X B < Φ 1 p B = Φ 2,ρ Φ 1 p A, Φ 1 p B, where the last step is a result of Proposition 2.1. Then we can compute the default correlation as CorrL A, L B = CovL A, L B Var LA Var LB = E L AL B E L A E L B Var LA Var LB = Φ 2,ρ Φ 1 p A, Φ 1 p B p A p B. pa 1 p A p B 1 p B 2.3 First-to-Default and Second-to-Default Probability In our explanatory example we try to simulate the concept of Collateralized Debt Obligations CDOs. In this concept, a portfolio of loans is sold to a special 13

19 purpose vehicle SPV and the cash flows from the loans are allocated to tranches with different risks and adequate returns. In our case we consider a first-to-default tranche and a second-to-default tranche, and compute their default probabilities. Definition 2.3. We define a first-to-default probability as the probability that at least one obligor defaults, i.e. p 1st = P {X A < d A } {X B < d B }, 2.9 and a second-to-default probability as the probability that both obligors default, i.e. p 2nd = P {X A < d A } {X B < d B } Lemma 2.4. Suppose the CreditMetrics model given by 2.3 and 2.4. Then the random variables L A and L B defined in 2.1 and 2.2 are conditionally independent for a given state of economy Y = y, and the conditional probabilities of default g pa,ρy = PL A = 1 Y = y and g pb,ρy = PL B = 1 Y = y are given by Φ 1 p A ρy g pa,ρy = Φ, ρ Φ 1 p B ρy g pb,ρy = Φ ρ Proof. The conditional independence of L A and L B follows from the conditional independence of X A and X B defined in 2.3 and 2.4, where ε A and ε B are independent. The conditional probability of default for loan A can be computed as g pa,ρy = P L A = 1 Y = y = P X A < d A Y = y ρ = P Y + 1 ρ εa < d A Y = y = P ε A < d A ρ Y Y = y 1 ρ da ρy = Φ 1 ρ Φ 1 p A ρy = Φ. 1 ρ Then g pb,ρ is computed analogously. Proposition 2.5. The one-year first-to-default probability equals p 1st = g pa,ρy + g pb,ρy 1 g pa,ρy dφy where g pa,ρ and g pb,ρ are the one-year conditional probabilities of default, defined in 2.11 and

20 Proof. Denote A = {X A < d A } and B = {X B < d B }. Due to the conditional independence from Lemma 2.4 we can write the one-year first-to-default probability from Definition 2.3 as p 1st = P A B A B \ A = P = = = P A B \ A Y = y dφy B P A Y = y + P A C Y = y dφy g pa,ρy + g pb,ρy 1 g pa,ρy dφy. Proposition 2.6. The one-year second-to-default probability equals p 2nd = g pa,ρyg pb,ρy dφy where g pa,ρ and g pb,ρ are the one-year conditional probabilities of default, defined in 2.11 and Proof. Again denote A = {X A < d A } and B = {X B < d B }. Then due to the conditional independence from Lemma 2.4 we can write the one-year second-todefault probability from Definition 2.3 as p 2nd = P A B = = = P A B Y = y dφy P A Y = y P B Y = y dφy g pa,ρyg pb,ρy dφy. Proposition 2.7. From Definition 2.3 we can write the one-year second-to-default probability in the equivalent form p 2nd = Φ 2,ρ Φ 1 p A, Φ 1 p B, 2.15 where Φ 2,ρ again denotes the standard bivariate normal distribution function with correlation ρ, as defined in

21 Proof. Using the definition of the second-to-default probability and the joint distribution of X A, X B from Proposition 2.1, we can write p 2nd = P {X A < d A } {X B < d B } = P X A < Φ 1 p A, X B < Φ 1 p B = Φ 2,ρ Φ 1 p A, Φ 1 p B. The probability of the form 2.15 is often referred as the joint default probability. As we will see in the next chapter, this form can be understood as a Gaussian copula. 16

22 Chapter 3 Copula Functions As it is seen in the previous example, the concept of copula functions arises naturally when we speak about joint default probabilities. Although there are several sophisticated methods to specify the distribution of potential losses of a single obligor see Chapter 1, this is usually not sufficient to determine the joint distribution. Therefore, a copula approach brings a way to combine given marginal distributions to get possible joint distributions. In this chapter, based mainly on McNeil et al. 2005, Embrechts et al. 2002, Embrechts 2009 and Bluhm and Overbeck 2006, we present a mathematical background. 3.1 Definition of Copula In this section we present two equivalent definitions of copula together with some basic properties. Definition 3.1. A copula is the distribution function of a random vector in [0, 1] d with standard uniform marginal distributions. Remark 3.2. Alternatively, a copula is any function C : [0, 1] d [0, 1] which has the following three properties. 1. Cx 1,..., x d is increasing in each component x i. 2. C1,..., 1, x i, 1,..., 1 = x i for all i {1,..., d}, x i [0, 1]. 3. For all a 1,..., a d, b 1,..., b d [0, 1] d with a i b i we have: 2 i 1 =1 2 1 i 1+ +i d Cx 1i1,..., x did 0, 3.1 i d =1 where x j1 = a j and x j2 = b j for all j {1,..., d}. 17

23 Definition 3.3. A copula C is called exchangeable if it is the distribution function of an exchangeable random vector of standard uniform variates, i.e. Cu 1,..., u d = Cu Π1,..., u Πd for any permutation Π1,..., Πd of 1,..., d. Definition 3.4. A copula C is called radially symmetric if it is the distribution function of a radially symmetric random vector U, i.e. if U d = 1 U for 1 = 1,..., 1. Definition 3.5. Suppose that a copula C is the distribution function of a random vector U. Then the distribution function of 1 U is called survival copula of U, and is denoted by Ĉ. Proposition 3.6. If a copula C is radially symmetric, then for the corresponding survival copula Ĉ we have C = Ĉ. Proof. The radial symmetry of C gives the relation U d = 1 U. It follows that the distribution functions of U and 1 U equal. Proposition 3.7. Suppose that a bivariate copula C is the distribution function of a random vector U 1, U 2. Then for the corresponding survival copula Ĉ we have the relation Ĉu 1, u 2 = C1 u 1, 1 u 2 + u 1 + u 2 1. Proof. We start from the definition of survival copula and compute, Ĉu 1, u 2 = P1 U 1 u 1, 1 U 2 u 2 = PU 1 1 u 1, U 2 1 u 2 = 1 PU 1 < 1 u 1 PU 2 < 1 u 2 + PU 1 < 1 u 1, U 2 < 1 u 2 = 1 1 u 1 1 u 2 + C1 u 1, 1 u 2 = C1 u 1, 1 u 2 + u 1 + u Sklar s Theorem Whereas the definition of copula is rather formal, Sklar s theorem offers the key properties used in practice. First we present a proposition and then the theorem. Proposition 3.8. Let F be a distribution function and F 1 denote the left-continuous quantile function, i.e. F 1 u = inf{x : F x u} from Definition A.3. Then the following two properties hold. 1. Quantile transformation If U has the standard uniform distribution, then F 1 U has distribution function F. 18

24 2. Probability transformation If Y has a continuous distribution function F, then F Y has the standard uniform distribution. Proof. For all y R and u [0, 1], we have 1. As F is increasing, it follows from Proposition A.2 iv that P F 1 U y = P U F y = F y. 2. Since F is continuous, F 1 is strictly increasing from Proposition A.2 ii. Now using Proposition A.4 and Proposition A.2 viii, we get P F Y u = P Y F 1 u = F F 1 u = u. Theorem 3.9. Sklar Let F be a joint distribution function with univariate marginal distribution functions F 1,..., F d. Then there exists a copula C : [0, 1] d [0, 1] such that, for all x 1,..., x d in R = [, ], F x 1,..., x d = C F 1 x 1,..., F d x d. 3.2 If the margins are continuous, then C is unique. Conversely, if C is a copula and F 1,..., F d are univariate distribution functions, then the function F defined in 3.2 is a joint distribution function with margins F 1,..., F d. Proof. We show the existence and uniqueness of the copula for the case of continuous margins F 1,..., F d. The complete proof can be found for instance in Nelsen For all x 1,..., x d in R = [, ] we have F x 1,..., x d = PX 1 x 1,..., X d x d = P F 1 X 1 F 1 x 1,..., F d X d F d x d = C F 1 x 1,..., F d x d, where C is a copula because F 1 X 1,..., F d X d U0, 1 according to Proposition 3.8 for continuous margins. If we now substitute x i = F 1 i u i for u i [0, 1], i {1,..., d} to 3.2 and use Proposition A.2 viii, we get a unique expression of the copula, Cu 1,..., u d = F F1 1 u 1,..., F 1 d u d. 3.3 Conversely, for a copula C and univariate distribution functions F 1,..., F d, we construct a random vector X 1,..., X d = F1 1 U 1,..., F 1 U d, where U 1,..., U d d 19

25 are standard uniform random variables with the joint distribution function C. Then for the distribution function F of the random vector X 1,..., X d we get F x 1,..., x d = PX 1 x 1,..., X d x d = P F1 1 U 1 x 1,..., F 1 d U d x d = P U 1 F 1 x 1,..., U d F d x d = C F 1 x 1,..., F d x d, where we again used the equivalence of Proposition A.2 iv. As we see, Sklar s theorem gives us a way to construct a joint distribution with given margins using a chosen copula. In the next sections we present some more properties of copula functions. 3.3 Frechét-Hoeffding s bounds Theorem Frechét-Hoeffding s bounds For any copula Cu 1,..., u d we have the bounds { d } max u i + 1 d, 0 Cu 1,..., u d min{u 1,..., u d }. 3.4 i=1 Proof. Let U 1,..., U d U0, 1. The first inequality is given by d d Cu 1,..., u d = P {U i u i } = 1 P {U i > u i } 1 i=1 d P U i > u i = i=1 i=1 i=1 d u i + 1 d. And the second inequality follows from the expression d Cu 1,..., u d = P {U i u i } P U k u k i=1 for all k {1,..., d}. Proposition Let U be a standard uniformly distributed random variable. Then a the bivariate Frechét-Hoeffding lower bound is the copula of random vector U, 1 U, and 20

26 b the bivariate Frechét-Hoeffding upper bound is the copula of U, U. Proof. As both U and 1 U are standard uniform margins, the distribution function of U, 1 U resp. U, U is a copula according to Definition 3.1. a The distribution function of U, 1 U is F x 1, x 2 = PU x 1, 1 U x 2 = P1 x 2 U x 1 { x 1 + x 2 1 for 1 x 2 < x 2, = 0 for 1 x 2 x 2 = max {x 1 + x 2 1, 0}, which is the Frechét-Hoeffding lower bound. b The distribution function of U, U is F x 1, x 2 = PU x 1, U x 2 = PU min{x 1, x 2 } = min{x 1, x 2 }, which is the Frechét-Hoeffding upper bound. 3.4 Comonotonicity and Countermonotonicity In this section we introduce the definitions of comonotonicity and countermonotonicity and their most important properties Comonotonicity Definition Random variables X 1,..., X d are called comonotonic if they admit as copula the Frechét-Hoeffding upper bound comonotonic copula C u u 1,..., u d = min{u 1,..., u d }. 3.5 Proposition Random variables X 1,..., X d are comonotonic if and only if X 1,..., X d d = v 1 Z,..., v d Z 3.6 for some random variable Z and increasing functions v 1,..., v d. 21

27 Proof. Suppose that X 1,..., X d are comonotonic random variables with a joint distribution function F and marginal distribution functions F 1,..., F d. Let U be a standard uniform random variable. From comonotonicity we get F x 1,..., x d = min { F 1 x 1,..., F d x d } = P U min { F 1 x 1,..., F d x d } = P U F 1 x 1,..., U F d x d where F 1 i = P F 1 1 U x 1,..., F 1 d U x d, denote the quantile function, F 1 i u = inf{x : F i x u}, and the last equality follows from the equivalence in Proposition A.2 iv. Then the last expression gives X 1,..., X d = d F1 1 U,..., F 1 d U, where F1 1,..., F 1 d are increasing functions and U is a random variable, i.e. an expression of the form 3.6. Conversely, assume that X 1,..., X d d = v 1 Z,..., v d Z for some random variable Z and increasing functions v 1,..., v d. Then F x 1,..., x d = PX 1 x 1,..., X d x d = P v 1 Z x 1,..., v d Z x d = PZ A 1,..., Z A d, with A i = v 1 i, x i ] for all i {1,..., d}. From monotonicity of all v i we get that A i are intervals of the form, k i or, k i ]. Then there exists such k that d i=1 A i = A k ; and thus, d F x 1,..., x d = PZ A 1,..., Z A d = PZ A i i=1 = min { PZ A 1,..., PZ A d } { = min P } v 1 Z x 1,..., P vd Z x 1 = min { PX 1 x 1,..., PX d x d } = min { F 1 x 1,..., F d x d }, which is the Frechét-Hoeffding upper bound copula Countermonotonicity Definition Random variables X 1 and X 2 are called countermonotonic if they admit as copula the Frechét-Hoeffding lower bound countermonotonic copula C l u 1, u 2 = max {u 1 + u 2 1, 0}

28 Proposition Random variables X 1 and X 2 are countermonotonic if and only if X 1, X 2 = d v 1 Z, v 2 Z 3.8 for some random variable Z and functions v 1 and v 2, where v 1 is increasing and v 2 decreasing, or vice versa. Proof. Suppose that X 1 and X 2 are countermonotonic. According to Proposition 3.11 a, the random vector X 1, X 2 admits as copula the Frechét-Hoeffding lower bound the distribution function of U, 1 U, where U has the standard uniform distribution. Then for a corresponding joint distribution function F and marginal distribution functions F 1 and F 2 we get F x 1, x 2 = C l F 1 x 1, F 2 x 2 = P U F 1 x 1, 1 U F 2 x 2 From the last expression we can conclude that = P F 1 1 U x 1, F U x 2. X 1, X 2 d = F 1 1 U, F U, where the function F 1 1 x is increasing and F x is decreasing. Conversely, assume that X 1, X 2 d = v 1 Z, v 2 Z for v 1 increasing and v 2 decreasing. If we now again define the events A 1 = { v 1 Z x 1 } = { Z v 1 1, x 1 ] }, A 2 = { v 2 Z x 2 } = { Z v 1 2, x 2 ] }, we get for the distribution function of v 1 Z, v 2 Z the expression P v 1 Z x 1, v 2 Z x 2 = PA1 A 2. Then there are two cases. a A 1 A 2 =. In this case PA 1 A 2 = 0 and F 1 x 1 + F 2 x 2 = PA 1 + PA 2 < 1. b A 1 A 2. In this case we get PA 1 A 2 = 1 due to the monotonicity of v 1 and v 2. From the formula PA 1 A 2 = PA 1 + PA 2 PA 1 A 2 we get the expression PA 1 A 2 = PA 1 + PA 2 1 = F 1 x 1 + F 2 x 2 1. Therefore, combining both options, we conclude that P v 1 Z x 1, v 2 Z x 2 = PA1 A 2 = max { F 1 x 1 + F 2 x 2 1, 0 }. In the next section we present several copula functions used in credit risk management. 23

29 3.5 Some Examples of Copulae Independence Copula Let U 1,..., U d be independent, standard uniform random variables. Then their joint distribution function is the independence copula of the form C u 1,..., u d = d u i for all u 1,..., u d [0, 1]. 3.9 i= Comonotonic Copula As an opposite to the independence copula we present the comonotonic copula, C u u 1,..., u d = min{u 1,..., u d } for all u 1,..., u d [0, 1] According to Theorem 3.10, this copula represents the upper Frechét-Hoeffding bound, and for any copula C we get Cu 1,..., u d C u u 1,..., u d for all u 1,..., u d [0, 1] Gaussian Copula Probably the most used copula in risk management is the Gaussian copula or normal copula, given by C d,γ u 1,..., u d = Φ d,γ Φ 1 u 1,..., Φ 1 u d 3.11 for all u 1,..., u d [0, 1], where Φ d,γ denotes the cumulative distribution function of the multivariate standard normal distribution with correlation 1 matrix Γ. As we have seen in Proposition 2.7, this copula arises naturally from the CreditMetrics approach Student-t Copula If we use the student-t distribution with m degrees od freedom instead of the normal distribution, we get the definition of the student-t copula, C d,γ,m u 1,..., u d = Θ d,γ,m Θ 1 m u 1,..., Θ 1 m u d Due to the assumed unit variances, Γ is also a covariance matrix. 24

30 for all u 1,..., u d [0, 1], where Θ d,γ,m denotes the cumulative distribution function of the multivariate standard t-distribution with m degrees of freedom and correlation 2 matrix Γ see Definition A.8 for µ = 0 and Γ = Σ, and Θ 1 m denotes the quantile function of the univariate t-distribution with m degrees of freedom. The student-t copula carries a similar relation to the Gaussian copula as the t-distribution to the normal distribution we can observe fatter tails as compared to the Gaussian copula and convergence to the Gaussian copula for m Archimedean Copulae Let ϕ : [0, 1] [0, ] be a continuous, strictly decreasing, convex function satisfying ϕ1 = 0 and ϕ0 =. Then we say that C ϕ is an Archimedean copula, generated by ϕ, if C ϕ u 1,..., u d = ϕ 1 ϕu ϕu d 3.13 for all u 1,..., u d [0, 1]. Such a ϕ is then called a strict generator of the Archimedean copula. Using different ϕ we can generate the whole class of Archimedean copulae. In the following paragraphs we introduce two examples Gumbel Copula If we take the Archimedean generator ϕ Guθ x = log x θ for any θ [1,, we get the Gumbel copula of the form C ϕguθ u 1,..., u d = exp log u 1 θ + + log u d θ 1 θ 3.14 for all u 1,..., u d [0, 1]. For θ = 1 we obtain the independence copula as a special case, and for the limit θ we obtain the comonotonic copula Clayton Copula Finally, for the Archimedean generator ϕ Clη x = x η 1 for any η 0,, we get the Clayton copula, C ϕclη u 1,..., u d = u η u η d + 1 d 1 η 3.15 for all u 1,..., u d [0, 1]. For the limit θ 0 we obtain the independence copula and for θ we obtain the comonotonic copula. 2 Due to the assumed unit variances, Γ is also a covariance matrix. 25

31 Chapter 4 Dependence Measures In this chapter, based mainly on Embrechts et al and McNeil et al. 2005, we introduce several approaches to dependence measures. We start with the usual Pearson linear correlation, followed by rank correlation and coefficient of tail dependence. In the last section we propose several approaches for multivariate tail dependence coefficients. 4.1 Linear Correlation Definition 4.1. The Pearson correlation coefficient ρ linear correlation between random variables X 1 and X 2 with 0 < VarX 1 < and 0 < VarX 2 < is defined as ρx 1, X 2 = CorrX 1, X 2 = CovX 1, X 2 Var X2 Var X Lemma 4.2. Let X 1, X 2 be a random vector with a joint distribution function F and marginal distribution functions F 1 and F 2. Then, if the covariance of X 1 and X 2 is finite, it is given by CovX 1, X 2 = F x 1, x 2 F 1 x 1 F 2 x 2 dx 1 dx Proof. Introduce a random vector X 1, X 2 with a joint distribution function F and marginal distribution functions F 1 and F 2, independent of X 1, X 2. Then we can compute E X 1 X 1X 2 X 2 = EX 1 X 2 EX 1 X 2 EX 1X 2 + EX 1X 2 = 2 EX 1 X 2 2E X 1 E X 2 = 2 CovX 1, X 2. 26

32 Now, if we apply the identity a b = 1{b x} 1 {a x} dx for a = X 1 X1 and b = X 2 X2 and use the notation A 1 = {X 1 x 1 }, A 1 = {X1 x 1 }, A 2 = {X 2 x 2 } and A 2 = {X2 x 2 }, we get 2 CovX 1, X 2 = E X 1 X1X 2 X2 = E 1 A 1 1 A1 1 A 2 1 A2 dx 1 dx 2 = E 1 A 1 A 1 2 A 1 A 2 1 A1 A A 1 A 2 dx 1 dx 2 = = 2 2 PA1 A 2 2 PA 1 PA 2 dx 1 dx 2 F x 1, x 2 F 1 x 1 F 2 x 2 dx 1 dx 2. Theorem 4.3. Let X 1, X 2 be a random vector with marginal distribution functions F 1 and F 2 and an unspecified joint distribution function. If 0 < VarX 1 < and 0 < VarX 2 <, then the following statements hold. 1 The attainable correlations of X 1 and X 2 form a closed interval [ρ min, ρ max ] with ρ min < 0 < ρ max. 2 The correlation is maximal, ρ = ρ max, if and only if X 1 and X 2 are comonotonic, and minimal, ρ = ρ min, if and only if X 1 and X 2 are countermonotonic. 3 The maximal attainable correlation is ρ max = 1 if and only if X 1 and X 2 are of the same type, i.e. if there exist constants α > 0 and β R such that X d 2 = αx 1 + β. The minimal attainable correlation is ρ min = 1 if and only if X 1 and X 2 are of the same type, i.e. if there exist constants α > 0 and β R such that X d 2 = αx 1 + β. Proof. By combining 4.1 and 4.2, we see that linear correlation is dependent only on the unspecified joint distribution function F considering F 1, F 2, VarX 1 and VarX 2 fixed. Now it follows from Theorem 3.10 that correlation is maximal for the Frechét-Hoeffding upper bound C u i.e. X 1 and X 2 comonotonic and minimal for the lower bound C l i.e. X 1 and X 2 countermonotonic. Moreover, if we take as copula the function λc l + 1 λc u, for any λ [0, 1], we get the correlation of λρ min + 1 λρ max. Thus, any ρ [ρ min, ρ max ] is attainable by setting λ = ρmax ρ ρ max ρ min. As the variances are assumed to be positive, the variables X 1 and X 2 are not degenerate, and for its distribution functions we get max { F 1 x 1 + F 2 x 2 1, 0 } < F 1 x 1 F 2 x 2 < min { F 1 x 1, F 2 x 2 }. 27

33 Then it follows from 4.2 that ρ min < 0 < ρ max. The last statement is then a standard result, as ρ = ±1 if and only if there is a linear relationship between X 1 and X Rank Correlation Rank correlations are based on orderings of the sample rather than on the values themselves. Therefore, it does not depend on the marginal distributions but only on the mixing copula see Theorem 4.5 and Theorem Spearman s Rho One of the commonly used rank correlations is Spearman s rho, which is the correlation coefficient of the values of the distribution functions of the data. 1 We introduce its definition and some basic properties. Definition 4.4. Let X 1 and X 2 be random variables with distribution functions F 1 and F 2. Then Spearman s rank correlation coefficient ρ S Spearman s rho for random variables X 1 and X 2 is defined as ρ S X 1, X 2 = Corr F 1 X 1, F 2 X Theorem 4.5. Let X 1 and X 2 be random variables with continuous distribution functions F 1 and F 2 and a unique copula C. Then Spearman s correlation coefficient is given by 1 1 ρ S X 1, X 2 = 12 Cu1, u 2 u 1 u 2 du1 du Proof. By Definition 4.4 we can write 0 0 ρ S X 1, X 2 = Corr F 1 X 1, F 2 X 2 = 12 Cov F 1 X 1, F 2 X 2, as F 1 X 1, F 2 X 2 U0, 1 according to Proposition 3.8, and their variances are 1 thus equal. Then we apply Lemma 4.2 for random variables U 12 1 = F 1 X 1 and U 2 = F 2 X 2 to get ρ S X 1, X 2 = Cu1, u 2 u 1 u 2 du1 du 2. 1 In practice, this is represented by ranks of the sample data. 28

34 Proposition 4.6. Spearman s rho is a symmetric measure taking values in [ 1, 1]. Furthermore, if X 1 and X 2 are random variables with continuous distribution functions F 1 and F 2 and a unique copula C, then the following statements hold. 1 If X 1 and X 2 are independent, then ρ S X 1, X 2 = 0. 2 X 1 and X 2 are comonotonic if and only if ρ S X 1, X 2 = 1. 3 X 1 and X 2 are countermonotonic if and only if ρ S X 1, X 2 = 1. Proof. Symmetry and range follow straight from the definition. If X 1 and X 2 are independent, then their copula is the independence copula C u 1, u 2 = u 1 u 2 and the statement follows from Theorem 4.5. Similarly, the value of formula 4.4 is maximal for the Frechét-Hoeffding upper bound C u i.e. X 1 and X 2 comonotonic and minimal for the lower bound C l i.e. X 1 and X 2 countermonotonic Kendall s Tau Kendall s tau is a measure of concordance. 2 It is defined as the probability that two independent random vectors from the same distribution are concordant minus the probability that they are discordant. In a short form, this can be defined as follows. Definition 4.7. Let X 1, X 2 and X1, X2 be two independent, identically distributed random vectors. Then Kendall s correlation coefficient ρ τ Kendall s tau for random variables X 1 and X 2 is defined as ρ τ X 1, X 2 = E sign X 1 X1X 2 X Theorem 4.8. Let X 1 and X 2 be random variables with continuous distribution functions F 1 and F 2 and a unique copula C. Then Kendall s correlation coefficient is given by ρ τ X 1, X 2 = Cu 1, u 2 dcu 1, u Two pairs x 1, x 2, x 1, x 2 R 2 are said to be concordant if x 1 x 1x 2 x 2 > 0, and discordant if x 1 x 1x 2 x 2 < 0. 29

35 Proof. We can rewrite the definition as ρ τ X 1, X 2 = P X 1 X 1X 2 X 2 > 0 P X 1 X 1X 2 X 2 < 0 = 2 P X 1 X 1X 2 X 2 > 0 1 = 4 PX 1 < X 1, X 2 < X 2 1 = 4 E PX 1 < X 1, X 2 < X 2 X 1, X 2 1 = 4 = 4 = 4 = PX 1 < x 1, X 2 < x 2 df x 1, x 2 1 F x 1, x 2 df x 1, x 2 1 C F 1 x 1, F 2 x 2 dc F 1 x 1, F 2 x 2 1 Cu 1, u 2 dcu 1, u 2 1, where in the last step we used the substitution u 1 = F 1 x 1 and u 2 = F 2 x 2. Proposition 4.9. Kendall s tau is a symmetric measure taking values in [ 1, 1]. Furthermore, if X 1 and X 2 are random variables with continuous distribution functions F 1 and F 2 and a unique copula C, then the following statements hold. 1 If X 1 and X 2 are independent, then ρ τ X 1, X 2 = 0. 2 X 1 and X 2 are comonotonic if and only if ρ τ X 1, X 2 = 1. 3 X 1 and X 2 are countermonotonic if and only if ρ τ X 1, X 2 = 1. Proof. Symmetry and range follow straight from the definition. If X 1 and X 2 are independent, then the probabilities of concordance and discordance equal and Kendall s tau is zero. Now suppose that X 1 and X 2 are comonotonic. According to Proposition 3.6, we can write X 1 = v 1 Z and X 2 = v 2 Z, where v 1 and v 2 are increasing functions. Then for some random variables Z and Z we get [ v1 ρ τ X 1, X 2 = E sign Z v 1 Z v 2 Z v 2 Z ] = 1, since v 1 and v 2 are deterministic increasing functions and F 1 and F 2 are assumed to be continuous thus PX 1 = X 1 = PX 2 = X 2 = 0. Conversely, suppose that ρ τ X 1, X 2 = 1, i.e. P X 1 X 1X 2 X 2 > 0 = 1. For individual random events this means that P P { ω, ω Ω Ω : X 1 ω X 1 ω X 2 ω X 2 ω > 0 } = 1. If we now denote A 1 = {X 1 x 1 } = { ω Ω : X 1 ω x 1 }, A 2 = {X 2 x 2 } = { ω Ω : X 2 ω x 2 }, 30

36 we need to show that X 1 and X 2 admit the comonotonic copula, i.e. PA 1 A 2 = min { PA 1, PA 2 } for all x 1 and x 2. Without loss of generality, assume that PA 1 < PA 2. Now, if PA 1 \A 2 > 0 then also PA 2 \A 1 > 0 and P X 1 X 1X 2 X 2 < 0 > 0, which is a contradiction. Therefore, PA 1 A 2 = PA 1 = min { PA 1, PA 2 }. Similarly, we prove the last statement. First suppose that X 1 and X 2 are countermonotonic. According to Proposition 3.8, we can write X 1 = v 1 Z and X 2 = v 2 Z, where v 1 is increasing and v 2 is decreasing. Then for some random variables Z and Z we get [ v1 ρ τ X 1, X 2 = E sign Z v 1 Z v 2 Z v 2 Z ] = 1, due to monotonicity of v 1 and v 2, and continuity of F 1 and F 2. Conversely, suppose that ρ τ X 1, X 2 = 1, i.e. P X 1 X 1X 2 X 2 < 0 = 1. In this case, we need to show that PA 1 A 2 = max { PA 1 + PA 2 1, 0 } for all x 1 and x 2. Now we distinguish the following two cases. Either PA 1 A 2 = 0 and PA 1 + PA 2 < 1, or PA 1 A 2 > 0. In the latter case we get PX 1 x 1, X 2 x 2 > 0. However, this is only possible when PX 1 > x 1, X 2 > x 2 = 0, which is equivalent to PA 1 A 2 = 1, since 0 = PX 1 > x 1, X 2 > x 2 = PA C 1 A C 2 = 1 PA 1 A 2. Using the formula PA 1 A 2 = PA 1 +PA 2 PA 1 A 2, we then get PA 1 A 2 = PA 1 + PA 2 1. Therefore, combining both options, we conclude that PA 1 A 2 = max { PA 1 + PA 2 1, 0 }. 4.3 Tail Dependence The coefficient of tail dependence is a measure providing information about dependence in a tail of a bivariate distribution. As well as rank correlations, in the case of continuous marginal distribution functions, tail dependence only depends on the mixing copula see Theorem The coefficient of tail dependence is defined as the conditional probability that one variable has an extremal value provided that the other has an extremal value. We present the following formal definition. Definition Let X 1 and X 2 be random variables with distribution functions F 1 and F 2. The coefficient of lower tail dependence of X 1 and X 2 is given by λ l X 1, X 2 = lim P X 2 F2 1 q X 1 F1 1 q,

37 provided the limit exists. If λ l 0, 1], we say that X 1 and X 2 show lower tail dependence; if λ l = 0, we say that X 1 and X 2 are asymptotically independent in the lower tail. Analogously, the coefficient of upper tail dependence of X 1 and X 2 is given by λ u X 1, X 2 = lim P X 2 > F2 1 q X 1 > F1 1 q, 4.8 q 1 provided the limit exists. If λ u 0, 1], we say that X 1 and X 2 show upper tail dependence; if λ u = 0, we say that X 1 and X 2 are asymptotically independent in the upper tail. Theorem Let X 1 and X 2 be random variables with continuous distribution functions F 1 and F 2. Then there exists a unique copula C such that both λ l X 1, X 2 = lim Cq, q q 4.9 and Ĉq, q λ u X 1, X 2 = lim, 4.10 q where Ĉ is the survival copula of C from Definition 3.5. If C is radially symmetric, then λ l = λ u. Proof. We start from the definition of the coefficient of tail dependence and apply Proposition 3.8 and Sklar s theorem. λ l X 1, X 2 = lim P X 2 F2 1 q X 1 F1 1 q P X 1 F1 1 q, X 2 F2 1 q = lim P X 1 F1 1 q P F 1 X 1 q, F 2 X 2 q = lim P F 1 X 1 q Cq, q = lim, q 32

Financial Econometrics and Volatility Models Copulas

Financial Econometrics and Volatility Models Copulas Financial Econometrics and Volatility Models Copulas Eric Zivot Updated: May 10, 2010 Reading MFTS, chapter 19 FMUND, chapters 6 and 7 Introduction Capturing co-movement between financial asset returns

More information

Modelling Dependent Credit Risks

Modelling Dependent Credit Risks Modelling Dependent Credit Risks Filip Lindskog, RiskLab, ETH Zürich 30 November 2000 Home page:http://www.math.ethz.ch/ lindskog E-mail:lindskog@math.ethz.ch RiskLab:http://www.risklab.ch Modelling Dependent

More information

Modelling Dependence with Copulas and Applications to Risk Management. Filip Lindskog, RiskLab, ETH Zürich

Modelling Dependence with Copulas and Applications to Risk Management. Filip Lindskog, RiskLab, ETH Zürich Modelling Dependence with Copulas and Applications to Risk Management Filip Lindskog, RiskLab, ETH Zürich 02-07-2000 Home page: http://www.math.ethz.ch/ lindskog E-mail: lindskog@math.ethz.ch RiskLab:

More information

Asymptotic behaviour of multivariate default probabilities and default correlations under stress

Asymptotic behaviour of multivariate default probabilities and default correlations under stress Asymptotic behaviour of multivariate default probabilities and default correlations under stress 7th General AMaMeF and Swissquote Conference EPFL, Lausanne Natalie Packham joint with Michael Kalkbrener

More information

Contents 1. Coping with Copulas. Thorsten Schmidt 1. Department of Mathematics, University of Leipzig Dec 2006

Contents 1. Coping with Copulas. Thorsten Schmidt 1. Department of Mathematics, University of Leipzig Dec 2006 Contents 1 Coping with Copulas Thorsten Schmidt 1 Department of Mathematics, University of Leipzig Dec 2006 Forthcoming in Risk Books Copulas - From Theory to Applications in Finance Contents 1 Introdcution

More information

GENERAL MULTIVARIATE DEPENDENCE USING ASSOCIATED COPULAS

GENERAL MULTIVARIATE DEPENDENCE USING ASSOCIATED COPULAS REVSTAT Statistical Journal Volume 14, Number 1, February 2016, 1 28 GENERAL MULTIVARIATE DEPENDENCE USING ASSOCIATED COPULAS Author: Yuri Salazar Flores Centre for Financial Risk, Macquarie University,

More information

Solution of the Financial Risk Management Examination

Solution of the Financial Risk Management Examination Solution of the Financial Risk Management Examination Thierry Roncalli January 8 th 014 Remark 1 The first five questions are corrected in TR-GDR 1 and in the document of exercise solutions, which is available

More information

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015 on bivariate Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015 Prof. Dr. Erich Walter Farkas Lecture 07: April 2, 2015 1 / 54 Outline on bivariate 1 2 bivariate 3 Distribution 4 5 6 7 8 Comments and conclusions

More information

Introduction to Dependence Modelling

Introduction to Dependence Modelling Introduction to Dependence Modelling Carole Bernard Berlin, May 2015. 1 Outline Modeling Dependence Part 1: Introduction 1 General concepts on dependence. 2 in 2 or N 3 dimensions. 3 Minimizing the expectation

More information

Dependence. Practitioner Course: Portfolio Optimization. John Dodson. September 10, Dependence. John Dodson. Outline.

Dependence. Practitioner Course: Portfolio Optimization. John Dodson. September 10, Dependence. John Dodson. Outline. Practitioner Course: Portfolio Optimization September 10, 2008 Before we define dependence, it is useful to define Random variables X and Y are independent iff For all x, y. In particular, F (X,Y ) (x,

More information

Modelling and Estimation of Stochastic Dependence

Modelling and Estimation of Stochastic Dependence Modelling and Estimation of Stochastic Dependence Uwe Schmock Based on joint work with Dr. Barbara Dengler Financial and Actuarial Mathematics and Christian Doppler Laboratory for Portfolio Risk Management

More information

Copulas. Mathematisches Seminar (Prof. Dr. D. Filipovic) Di Uhr in E

Copulas. Mathematisches Seminar (Prof. Dr. D. Filipovic) Di Uhr in E Copulas Mathematisches Seminar (Prof. Dr. D. Filipovic) Di. 14-16 Uhr in E41 A Short Introduction 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 The above picture shows a scatterplot (500 points) from a pair

More information

Copulas and dependence measurement

Copulas and dependence measurement Copulas and dependence measurement Thorsten Schmidt. Chemnitz University of Technology, Mathematical Institute, Reichenhainer Str. 41, Chemnitz. thorsten.schmidt@mathematik.tu-chemnitz.de Keywords: copulas,

More information

Losses Given Default in the Presence of Extreme Risks

Losses Given Default in the Presence of Extreme Risks Losses Given Default in the Presence of Extreme Risks Qihe Tang [a] and Zhongyi Yuan [b] [a] Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Iowa [b] Smeal College of Business Pennsylvania

More information

Dependence. MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation. John Dodson. September 11, Dependence. John Dodson. Outline.

Dependence. MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation. John Dodson. September 11, Dependence. John Dodson. Outline. MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation September 11, 2013 Before we define dependence, it is useful to define Random variables X and Y are independent iff For all x, y. In particular, F (X,Y

More information

Multivariate Distribution Models

Multivariate Distribution Models Multivariate Distribution Models Model Description While the probability distribution for an individual random variable is called marginal, the probability distribution for multiple random variables is

More information

A Measure of Monotonicity of Two Random Variables

A Measure of Monotonicity of Two Random Variables Journal of Mathematics and Statistics 8 (): -8, 0 ISSN 549-3644 0 Science Publications A Measure of Monotonicity of Two Random Variables Farida Kachapova and Ilias Kachapov School of Computing and Mathematical

More information

A simple graphical method to explore tail-dependence in stock-return pairs

A simple graphical method to explore tail-dependence in stock-return pairs A simple graphical method to explore tail-dependence in stock-return pairs Klaus Abberger, University of Konstanz, Germany Abstract: For a bivariate data set the dependence structure can not only be measured

More information

Lifetime Dependence Modelling using a Generalized Multivariate Pareto Distribution

Lifetime Dependence Modelling using a Generalized Multivariate Pareto Distribution Lifetime Dependence Modelling using a Generalized Multivariate Pareto Distribution Daniel Alai Zinoviy Landsman Centre of Excellence in Population Ageing Research (CEPAR) School of Mathematics, Statistics

More information

Copulas and Measures of Dependence

Copulas and Measures of Dependence 1 Copulas and Measures of Dependence Uttara Naik-Nimbalkar December 28, 2014 Measures for determining the relationship between two variables: the Pearson s correlation coefficient, Kendalls tau and Spearmans

More information

Multivariate survival modelling: a unified approach with copulas

Multivariate survival modelling: a unified approach with copulas Multivariate survival modelling: a unified approach with copulas P. Georges, A-G. Lamy, E. Nicolas, G. Quibel & T. Roncalli Groupe de Recherche Opérationnelle Crédit Lyonnais France May 28, 2001 Abstract

More information

Copula-based top-down approaches in financial risk aggregation

Copula-based top-down approaches in financial risk aggregation Number 3 Working Paper Series by the University of Applied Sciences of bfi Vienna Copula-based top-down approaches in financial risk aggregation December 6 Christian Cech University of Applied Sciences

More information

Probabilistic Engineering Mechanics. An innovating analysis of the Nataf transformation from the copula viewpoint

Probabilistic Engineering Mechanics. An innovating analysis of the Nataf transformation from the copula viewpoint Probabilistic Engineering Mechanics 4 9 3 3 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Probabilistic Engineering Mechanics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/probengmech An innovating analysis of

More information

Solutions of the Financial Risk Management Examination

Solutions of the Financial Risk Management Examination Solutions of the Financial Risk Management Examination Thierry Roncalli January 9 th 03 Remark The first five questions are corrected in TR-GDR and in the document of exercise solutions, which is available

More information

(6, 4) Is there arbitrage in this market? If so, find all arbitrages. If not, find all pricing kernels.

(6, 4) Is there arbitrage in this market? If so, find all arbitrages. If not, find all pricing kernels. Advanced Financial Models Example sheet - Michaelmas 208 Michael Tehranchi Problem. Consider a two-asset model with prices given by (P, P 2 ) (3, 9) /4 (4, 6) (6, 8) /4 /2 (6, 4) Is there arbitrage in

More information

EMS SCHOOL Risk Theory and Related Topics

EMS SCHOOL Risk Theory and Related Topics EMS SCHOOL Risk Theory and Related Topics Bedlewo, Poland. september 29th- october 8th, 2008 1 Credit Risk: Reduced Form Approach Tomasz R. Bielecki, IIT, Chicago Monique Jeanblanc, University of Evry

More information

VaR vs. Expected Shortfall

VaR vs. Expected Shortfall VaR vs. Expected Shortfall Risk Measures under Solvency II Dietmar Pfeifer (2004) Risk measures and premium principles a comparison VaR vs. Expected Shortfall Dependence and its implications for risk measures

More information

EXTREMAL DEPENDENCE OF MULTIVARIATE DISTRIBUTIONS AND ITS APPLICATIONS YANNAN SUN

EXTREMAL DEPENDENCE OF MULTIVARIATE DISTRIBUTIONS AND ITS APPLICATIONS YANNAN SUN EXTREMAL DEPENDENCE OF MULTIVARIATE DISTRIBUTIONS AND ITS APPLICATIONS By YANNAN SUN A dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY WASHINGTON

More information

Non-parametric Estimation of Elliptical Copulae With Application to Credit Risk

Non-parametric Estimation of Elliptical Copulae With Application to Credit Risk Non-parametric Estimation of Elliptical Copulae With Application to Credit Risk Krassimir Kostadinov Abstract This paper develops a method for statistical estimation of the dependence structure of financial

More information

On the Conditional Value at Risk (CoVaR) from the copula perspective

On the Conditional Value at Risk (CoVaR) from the copula perspective On the Conditional Value at Risk (CoVaR) from the copula perspective Piotr Jaworski Institute of Mathematics, Warsaw University, Poland email: P.Jaworski@mimuw.edu.pl 1 Overview 1. Basics about VaR, CoVaR

More information

Statistical analysis of empirical pairwise copulas for the S&P 500 stocks

Statistical analysis of empirical pairwise copulas for the S&P 500 stocks Statistical analysis of empirical pairwise copulas for the S&P 500 stocks Richard Koivusalo Supervisor KTH : Tatjana Pavlenko July 2012 Abstract It is of great importance to find an analytical copula that

More information

Tail Dependence of Multivariate Pareto Distributions

Tail Dependence of Multivariate Pareto Distributions !#"%$ & ' ") * +!-,#. /10 243537698:6 ;=@?A BCDBFEHGIBJEHKLB MONQP RS?UTV=XW>YZ=eda gihjlknmcoqprj stmfovuxw yy z {} ~ ƒ }ˆŠ ~Œ~Ž f ˆ ` š œžÿ~ ~Ÿ œ } ƒ œ ˆŠ~ œ

More information

A measure of radial asymmetry for bivariate copulas based on Sobolev norm

A measure of radial asymmetry for bivariate copulas based on Sobolev norm A measure of radial asymmetry for bivariate copulas based on Sobolev norm Ahmad Alikhani-Vafa Ali Dolati Abstract The modified Sobolev norm is used to construct an index for measuring the degree of radial

More information

A multivariate dependence measure for aggregating risks

A multivariate dependence measure for aggregating risks A multivariate dependence measure for aggregating risks Jan Dhaene 1 Daniël Linders 2 Wim Schoutens 3 David Vyncke 4 December 1, 2013 1 KU Leuven, Leuven, Belgium. Email: jan.dhaene@econ.kuleuven.be 2

More information

CONTAGION VERSUS FLIGHT TO QUALITY IN FINANCIAL MARKETS

CONTAGION VERSUS FLIGHT TO QUALITY IN FINANCIAL MARKETS EVA IV, CONTAGION VERSUS FLIGHT TO QUALITY IN FINANCIAL MARKETS Jose Olmo Department of Economics City University, London (joint work with Jesús Gonzalo, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid) 4th Conference

More information

X

X Correlation: Pitfalls and Alternatives Paul Embrechts, Alexander McNeil & Daniel Straumann Departement Mathematik, ETH Zentrum, CH-8092 Zürich Tel: +41 1 632 61 62, Fax: +41 1 632 15 23 embrechts/mcneil/strauman@math.ethz.ch

More information

On Backtesting Risk Measurement Models

On Backtesting Risk Measurement Models On Backtesting Risk Measurement Models Hideatsu Tsukahara Department of Economics, Seijo University e-mail address: tsukahar@seijo.ac.jp 1 Introduction In general, the purpose of backtesting is twofold:

More information

Expected Shortfall is not elicitable so what?

Expected Shortfall is not elicitable so what? Expected Shortfall is not elicitable so what? Dirk Tasche Bank of England Prudential Regulation Authority 1 dirk.tasche@gmx.net Modern Risk Management of Insurance Firms Hannover, January 23, 2014 1 The

More information

Outline. Frailty modelling of Multivariate Survival Data. Clustered survival data. Clustered survival data

Outline. Frailty modelling of Multivariate Survival Data. Clustered survival data. Clustered survival data Outline Frailty modelling of Multivariate Survival Data Thomas Scheike ts@biostat.ku.dk Department of Biostatistics University of Copenhagen Marginal versus Frailty models. Two-stage frailty models: copula

More information

Expected Shortfall is not elicitable so what?

Expected Shortfall is not elicitable so what? Expected Shortfall is not elicitable so what? Dirk Tasche Bank of England Prudential Regulation Authority 1 dirk.tasche@gmx.net Finance & Stochastics seminar Imperial College, November 20, 2013 1 The opinions

More information

Politecnico di Torino. Porto Institutional Repository

Politecnico di Torino. Porto Institutional Repository Politecnico di Torino Porto Institutional Repository [Article] On preservation of ageing under minimum for dependent random lifetimes Original Citation: Pellerey F.; Zalzadeh S. (204). On preservation

More information

Week 1 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Distributions A

Week 1 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Distributions A Week 1 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Distributions A Christopher Ting http://www.mysmu.edu/faculty/christophert/ Christopher Ting : christopherting@smu.edu.sg : 6828 0364 : LKCSB 5036 October

More information

1: PROBABILITY REVIEW

1: PROBABILITY REVIEW 1: PROBABILITY REVIEW Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 1: Probability Review 1 / 56 Outline We will review the following

More information

Convexity of chance constraints with dependent random variables: the use of copulae

Convexity of chance constraints with dependent random variables: the use of copulae Convexity of chance constraints with dependent random variables: the use of copulae René Henrion 1 and Cyrille Strugarek 2 1 Weierstrass Institute for Applied Analysis and Stochastics, 10117 Berlin, Germany.

More information

8 Copulas. 8.1 Introduction

8 Copulas. 8.1 Introduction 8 Copulas 8.1 Introduction Copulas are a popular method for modeling multivariate distributions. A copula models the dependence and only the dependence between the variates in a multivariate distribution

More information

VaR bounds in models with partial dependence information on subgroups

VaR bounds in models with partial dependence information on subgroups VaR bounds in models with partial dependence information on subgroups L. Rüschendorf J. Witting February 23, 2017 Abstract We derive improved estimates for the model risk of risk portfolios when additional

More information

Stochastic orders: a brief introduction and Bruno s contributions. Franco Pellerey

Stochastic orders: a brief introduction and Bruno s contributions. Franco Pellerey Stochastic orders: a brief introduction and Bruno s contributions. Franco Pellerey Stochastic orders (comparisons) Among his main interests in research activity A field where his contributions are still

More information

Regularly Varying Asymptotics for Tail Risk

Regularly Varying Asymptotics for Tail Risk Regularly Varying Asymptotics for Tail Risk Haijun Li Department of Mathematics Washington State University Humboldt Univ-Berlin Haijun Li Regularly Varying Asymptotics for Tail Risk Humboldt Univ-Berlin

More information

Simulating Exchangeable Multivariate Archimedean Copulas and its Applications. Authors: Florence Wu Emiliano A. Valdez Michael Sherris

Simulating Exchangeable Multivariate Archimedean Copulas and its Applications. Authors: Florence Wu Emiliano A. Valdez Michael Sherris Simulating Exchangeable Multivariate Archimedean Copulas and its Applications Authors: Florence Wu Emiliano A. Valdez Michael Sherris Literatures Frees and Valdez (1999) Understanding Relationships Using

More information

Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 10

Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 10 Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 10 Risk Management Haksun Li haksun.li@numericalmethod.com www.numericalmethod.com Outline Value at Risk (VaR) Extreme Value Theory (EVT) References

More information

Stein s method and zero bias transformation: Application to CDO pricing

Stein s method and zero bias transformation: Application to CDO pricing Stein s method and zero bias transformation: Application to CDO pricing ESILV and Ecole Polytechnique Joint work with N. El Karoui Introduction CDO a portfolio credit derivative containing 100 underlying

More information

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales Douglas Gale Piero Gottardi NYU April 23, 2013 Douglas Gale, Piero Gottardi (NYU) Capital Structure April 23, 2013 1 / 55 Introduction Corporate

More information

Lecture 2 One too many inequalities

Lecture 2 One too many inequalities University of Illinois Department of Economics Spring 2017 Econ 574 Roger Koenker Lecture 2 One too many inequalities In lecture 1 we introduced some of the basic conceptual building materials of the course.

More information

Tail Approximation of Value-at-Risk under Multivariate Regular Variation

Tail Approximation of Value-at-Risk under Multivariate Regular Variation Tail Approximation of Value-at-Risk under Multivariate Regular Variation Yannan Sun Haijun Li July 00 Abstract This paper presents a general tail approximation method for evaluating the Valueat-Risk of

More information

Clearly, if F is strictly increasing it has a single quasi-inverse, which equals the (ordinary) inverse function F 1 (or, sometimes, F 1 ).

Clearly, if F is strictly increasing it has a single quasi-inverse, which equals the (ordinary) inverse function F 1 (or, sometimes, F 1 ). APPENDIX A SIMLATION OF COPLAS Copulas have primary and direct applications in the simulation of dependent variables. We now present general procedures to simulate bivariate, as well as multivariate, dependent

More information

Errata for Campbell, Financial Decisions and Markets, 01/02/2019.

Errata for Campbell, Financial Decisions and Markets, 01/02/2019. Errata for Campbell, Financial Decisions and Markets, 01/02/2019. Page xi, section title for Section 11.4.3 should be Endogenous Margin Requirements. Page 20, equation 1.49), expectations operator E should

More information

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty Introduction Extreme Scenarios Asymptotic Behavior Challenges Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Waterloo, Canada Seminar at ETH Zurich

More information

Shape of the return probability density function and extreme value statistics

Shape of the return probability density function and extreme value statistics Shape of the return probability density function and extreme value statistics 13/09/03 Int. Workshop on Risk and Regulation, Budapest Overview I aim to elucidate a relation between one field of research

More information

Construction and estimation of high dimensional copulas

Construction and estimation of high dimensional copulas Construction and estimation of high dimensional copulas Gildas Mazo PhD work supervised by S. Girard and F. Forbes Mistis, Inria and laboratoire Jean Kuntzmann, Grenoble, France Séminaire Statistiques,

More information

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009 Department of Agricultural Economics PhD Qualifier Examination May 009 Instructions: The exam consists of six questions. You must answer all questions. If you need an assumption to complete a question,

More information

Correlation: Copulas and Conditioning

Correlation: Copulas and Conditioning Correlation: Copulas and Conditioning This note reviews two methods of simulating correlated variates: copula methods and conditional distributions, and the relationships between them. Particular emphasis

More information

When is a copula constant? A test for changing relationships

When is a copula constant? A test for changing relationships When is a copula constant? A test for changing relationships Fabio Busetti and Andrew Harvey Bank of Italy and University of Cambridge November 2007 usetti and Harvey (Bank of Italy and University of Cambridge)

More information

Calculating credit risk capital charges with the one-factor model

Calculating credit risk capital charges with the one-factor model Calculating credit risk capital charges with the one-factor model Susanne Emmer Dirk Tasche September 15, 2003 Abstract Even in the simple Vasicek one-factor credit portfolio model, the exact contributions

More information

arxiv:physics/ v1 [physics.soc-ph] 18 Aug 2006

arxiv:physics/ v1 [physics.soc-ph] 18 Aug 2006 arxiv:physics/6819v1 [physics.soc-ph] 18 Aug 26 On Value at Risk for foreign exchange rates - the copula approach Piotr Jaworski Institute of Mathematics, Warsaw University ul. Banacha 2, 2-97 Warszawa,

More information

Optimal exit strategies for investment projects. 7th AMaMeF and Swissquote Conference

Optimal exit strategies for investment projects. 7th AMaMeF and Swissquote Conference Optimal exit strategies for investment projects Simone Scotti Université Paris Diderot Laboratoire de Probabilité et Modèles Aléatories Joint work with : Etienne Chevalier, Université d Evry Vathana Ly

More information

Current Topics in Credit Risk

Current Topics in Credit Risk Risk Measures and Risk Management EURANDOM, Eindhoven, 10 May 2005 Current Topics in Credit Risk Mark Davis Department of Mathematics Imperial College London London SW7 2AZ www.ma.ic.ac.uk/ mdavis 1 Agenda

More information

Asymmetric Dependence, Tail Dependence, and the. Time Interval over which the Variables Are Measured

Asymmetric Dependence, Tail Dependence, and the. Time Interval over which the Variables Are Measured Asymmetric Dependence, Tail Dependence, and the Time Interval over which the Variables Are Measured Byoung Uk Kang and Gunky Kim Preliminary version: August 30, 2013 Comments Welcome! Kang, byoung.kang@polyu.edu.hk,

More information

On the Estimation and Application of Max-Stable Processes

On the Estimation and Application of Max-Stable Processes On the Estimation and Application of Max-Stable Processes Zhengjun Zhang Department of Statistics University of Wisconsin Madison, WI 53706, USA Co-author: Richard Smith EVA 2009, Fort Collins, CO Z. Zhang

More information

The Instability of Correlations: Measurement and the Implications for Market Risk

The Instability of Correlations: Measurement and the Implications for Market Risk The Instability of Correlations: Measurement and the Implications for Market Risk Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20254 Advanced Quantitative Methods for Asset Pricing and Structuring Winter/Spring 2018 Threshold

More information

INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES. Curriculum 2019 SPECIMEN SOLUTIONS

INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES. Curriculum 2019 SPECIMEN SOLUTIONS INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES Curriculum 09 SPECIMEN SOLUTIONS Subject CSA Risk Modelling and Survival Analysis Institute and Faculty of Actuaries Sample path A continuous time, discrete state process

More information

Using Copulas in Risk Management

Using Copulas in Risk Management Using Copulas in Risk Management Master s Thesis by Geert van der Wulp Department of Econometrics & OR Tilburg University Supervisors and Thesis Committee Members Prof. Dr. Bas Werker Department of Econometrics

More information

Systemic Risk and the Mathematics of Falling Dominoes

Systemic Risk and the Mathematics of Falling Dominoes Systemic Risk and the Mathematics of Falling Dominoes Reimer Kühn Disordered Systems Group Department of Mathematics, King s College London http://www.mth.kcl.ac.uk/ kuehn/riskmodeling.html Teachers Conference,

More information

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno Background Much progress made on constructing and estimating models that fit quarterly data well (Smets-Wouters,

More information

Estimation and Goodness of Fit for Multivariate Survival Models Based on Copulas

Estimation and Goodness of Fit for Multivariate Survival Models Based on Copulas Estimation and Goodness of Fit for Multivariate Survival Models Based on Copulas by Yildiz Elif Yilmaz A thesis presented to the University of Waterloo in fulfillment of the thesis requirement for the

More information

Statistics for Copula-based Measures of Multivariate Association

Statistics for Copula-based Measures of Multivariate Association Statistics for Copula-based Measures of Multivariate Association Theory and Applications to Financial Data Inauguraldissertation zur Erlangung des Doktorgrades der Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaftlichen

More information

MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation. John Dodson. February 4, 2015

MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation. John Dodson. February 4, 2015 & & MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation February 4, 2015 & Meucci s Program for Asset Allocation detect market invariance select the invariants estimate the market specify the distribution

More information

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Tim Leung 1, Qingshuo Song 2, and Jie Yang 3 1 Columbia University, New York, USA; leung@ieor.columbia.edu 2 City

More information

Random Variables. Random variables. A numerically valued map X of an outcome ω from a sample space Ω to the real line R

Random Variables. Random variables. A numerically valued map X of an outcome ω from a sample space Ω to the real line R In probabilistic models, a random variable is a variable whose possible values are numerical outcomes of a random phenomenon. As a function or a map, it maps from an element (or an outcome) of a sample

More information

Probability. Table of contents

Probability. Table of contents Probability Table of contents 1. Important definitions 2. Distributions 3. Discrete distributions 4. Continuous distributions 5. The Normal distribution 6. Multivariate random variables 7. Other continuous

More information

J. Marín-Solano (UB), M. Bosch-Príncep (UB), J. Dhaene (KUL), C. Ribas (UB), O. Roch (UB), S. Vanduffel (KUL)

J. Marín-Solano (UB), M. Bosch-Príncep (UB), J. Dhaene (KUL), C. Ribas (UB), O. Roch (UB), S. Vanduffel (KUL) BUY AND HOLD STRATEGIES IN OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO SELECTION PROBLEMS: COMONOTONIC APPROXIMATIONS J. Marín-Solano (UB), M. Bosch-Príncep (UB), J. Dhaene (KUL), C. Ribas (UB), O. Roch (UB), S. Vanduffel (KUL)

More information

Assessing financial model risk

Assessing financial model risk Assessing financial model risk and an application to electricity prices Giacomo Scandolo University of Florence giacomo.scandolo@unifi.it joint works with Pauline Barrieu (LSE) and Angelica Gianfreda (LBS)

More information

Bivariate Paired Numerical Data

Bivariate Paired Numerical Data Bivariate Paired Numerical Data Pearson s correlation, Spearman s ρ and Kendall s τ, tests of independence University of California, San Diego Instructor: Ery Arias-Castro http://math.ucsd.edu/~eariasca/teaching.html

More information

A Brief Introduction to Copulas

A Brief Introduction to Copulas A Brief Introduction to Copulas Speaker: Hua, Lei February 24, 2009 Department of Statistics University of British Columbia Outline Introduction Definition Properties Archimedean Copulas Constructing Copulas

More information

1 Presessional Probability

1 Presessional Probability 1 Presessional Probability Probability theory is essential for the development of mathematical models in finance, because of the randomness nature of price fluctuations in the markets. This presessional

More information

Variables: An Application from Portfolio Theory

Variables: An Application from Portfolio Theory Convergence of Sums of Dependent Bernoulli Random Variables: An Application from Portfolio Theory Madelyn Houser, Dept. of Mathematical Sciences, University of Delaware, mhouser@udel.edu Pak-Wing Fok,

More information

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty Carole Bernard, Xiao Jiang and Ruodu Wang November 213 Abstract Risk aggregation with dependence uncertainty refers to the sum of individual risks with known

More information

Multivariate Operational Risk: Dependence Modelling with Lévy Copulas

Multivariate Operational Risk: Dependence Modelling with Lévy Copulas Multivariate Operational Risk: Dependence Modelling with Lévy Copulas Klaus Böcker Claudia Klüppelberg Abstract Simultaneous modelling of operational risks occurring in different event type/business line

More information

Calculating credit risk capital charges with the one-factor model

Calculating credit risk capital charges with the one-factor model Calculating credit risk capital charges with the one-factor model arxiv:cond-mat/0302402v5 [cond-mat.other] 4 Jan 2005 Susanne Emmer Dirk Tasche Dr. Nagler & Company GmbH, Maximilianstraße 47, 80538 München,

More information

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations Chapter 4 Applications/Variations 149 4.1 Consumption Smoothing 4.1.1 The Intertemporal Budget Economic Growth: Lecture Notes For any given sequence of interest rates {R t } t=0, pick an arbitrary q 0

More information

Coherent Risk Measures. Acceptance Sets. L = {X G : X(ω) < 0, ω Ω}.

Coherent Risk Measures. Acceptance Sets. L = {X G : X(ω) < 0, ω Ω}. So far in this course we have used several different mathematical expressions to quantify risk, without a deeper discussion of their properties. Coherent Risk Measures Lecture 11, Optimisation in Finance

More information

Portfolio Credit Risk with Extremal Dependence: Asymptotic Analysis and Efficient Simulation

Portfolio Credit Risk with Extremal Dependence: Asymptotic Analysis and Efficient Simulation OPERATIONS RESEARCH Vol. 56, No. 3, May June 2008, pp. 593 606 issn 0030-364X eissn 1526-5463 08 5603 0593 informs doi 10.1287/opre.1080.0513 2008 INFORMS Portfolio Credit Risk with Extremal Dependence:

More information

MULTIDIMENSIONAL POVERTY MEASUREMENT: DEPENDENCE BETWEEN WELL-BEING DIMENSIONS USING COPULA FUNCTION

MULTIDIMENSIONAL POVERTY MEASUREMENT: DEPENDENCE BETWEEN WELL-BEING DIMENSIONS USING COPULA FUNCTION Rivista Italiana di Economia Demografia e Statistica Volume LXXII n. 3 Luglio-Settembre 2018 MULTIDIMENSIONAL POVERTY MEASUREMENT: DEPENDENCE BETWEEN WELL-BEING DIMENSIONS USING COPULA FUNCTION Kateryna

More information

Multivariate Measures of Positive Dependence

Multivariate Measures of Positive Dependence Int. J. Contemp. Math. Sciences, Vol. 4, 2009, no. 4, 191-200 Multivariate Measures of Positive Dependence Marta Cardin Department of Applied Mathematics University of Venice, Italy mcardin@unive.it Abstract

More information

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 23 Jul 2002

arxiv:cond-mat/ v1 23 Jul 2002 Remarks on the monotonicity of default probabilities Dirk Tasche arxiv:cond-mat/0207555v1 23 Jul 2002 July 23, 2002 Abstract The consultative papers for the Basel II Accord require rating systems to provide

More information

ON UNIFORM TAIL EXPANSIONS OF BIVARIATE COPULAS

ON UNIFORM TAIL EXPANSIONS OF BIVARIATE COPULAS APPLICATIONES MATHEMATICAE 31,4 2004), pp. 397 415 Piotr Jaworski Warszawa) ON UNIFORM TAIL EXPANSIONS OF BIVARIATE COPULAS Abstract. The theory of copulas provides a useful tool for modelling dependence

More information

Risk Aggregation. Paul Embrechts. Department of Mathematics, ETH Zurich Senior SFI Professor.

Risk Aggregation. Paul Embrechts. Department of Mathematics, ETH Zurich Senior SFI Professor. Risk Aggregation Paul Embrechts Department of Mathematics, ETH Zurich Senior SFI Professor www.math.ethz.ch/~embrechts/ Joint work with P. Arbenz and G. Puccetti 1 / 33 The background Query by practitioner

More information

Probability Distributions and Estimation of Ali-Mikhail-Haq Copula

Probability Distributions and Estimation of Ali-Mikhail-Haq Copula Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 4, 2010, no. 14, 657-666 Probability Distributions and Estimation of Ali-Mikhail-Haq Copula Pranesh Kumar Mathematics Department University of Northern British Columbia

More information

Semi-parametric predictive inference for bivariate data using copulas

Semi-parametric predictive inference for bivariate data using copulas Semi-parametric predictive inference for bivariate data using copulas Tahani Coolen-Maturi a, Frank P.A. Coolen b,, Noryanti Muhammad b a Durham University Business School, Durham University, Durham, DH1

More information

Generalized Autoregressive Score Models

Generalized Autoregressive Score Models Generalized Autoregressive Score Models by: Drew Creal, Siem Jan Koopman, André Lucas To capture the dynamic behavior of univariate and multivariate time series processes, we can allow parameters to be

More information