Unified Discrete-Time and Continuous-Time Models. and High-Frequency Financial Data

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Unified Discrete-Time and Continuous-Time Models. and High-Frequency Financial Data"

Transcription

1 Unified Discrete-Time and Continuous-Time Models and Statistical Inferences for Merged Low-Frequency and High-Frequency Financial Data Donggyu Kim and Yazhen Wang University of Wisconsin-Madison December 24, 2014 Abstract This paper introduces a unified model, which can accommodate both a continuoustime Itô process used to model high-frequency stock prices and a GARCH process employed to model low-frequency stock prices, by embedding a discrete-time GARCH volatility in its continuous-time instantaneous volatility. This model is called a unified GARCH-Itô model. We adopt realized volatility estimators based on high-frequency financial data and the quasi-likelihood function for the low-frequency GARCH structure to develop parameter estimation methods for the combined high-frequency and low-frequency data. We establish asymptotic theory for the proposed estimators and conduct a simulation study to check finite sample performances of the estimators. We apply the proposed estimation approach to Bank of America stock price data. Keywords GARCH, high-frequency data, low-frequency data, Itô process, quasi-maximum likelihood estimator, realized volatility, stochastic differential equation. Running title Unified Models and Inferences for Low- and High-Frequency Data 1

2 1 Introduction Since the seminal papers by Engle (1982) and Bollerslev (1986), generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedastic (GARCH) models have been often used in volatility analysis of low-frequency financial data. On the other hand, as high-frequency financial data are now widely available, it becomes popular to model high-frequency financial data by continuoustime Itô processes and develop nonparametric realized volatility estimators from the highfrequency data (Zhang et al. (2005), Zhang (2006), Fan and Wang (2007), Barndorff-Nielsen et al. (2008), Jacod et al. (2009), and Xiu (2010)). Here low-frequency financial data are referred to as observed price data on financial assets at daily or longer time horizons, with high-frequency financial data for intra-day data observed on the prices of financial assets. Financial models and econometric analysis for low-frequency and high-frequency data are developed quite independently. As high-frequency and low-frequency are just different time scales, the models and data at these different time scales must be inter-related. However, typical GARCH models for low-frequency data and stochastic processes for high-frequency data are often separately treated as unrelated. It is scientifically interesting and financially important to develop unified model and statistical inference approaches for combining both high-frequency and low-frequency financial data. There are some attempts to bridge the gap between discrete-time and continuous-time modeling and reconcile volatility analysis at high-frequency and low-frequency levels. On the model side, Nelson (1990) established the continuous-time diffusion limit for the discrete-time GARCH model by showing that GARCH processes weakly converge to some bivariate diffusions, as the length of the discrete time intervals goes to zero, Wang (2002) studied the statistical relationship between the GARCH and diffusion models, and Kallsen and Taqqu (1998) embedded a discrete-time ARCH model in a continuous-time diffusion model and investigated the option pricing relationship between the GARCH and diffusion models. For volatility analysis, combined inferences include the realized GARCH model (Hansen et al. (2012)), the high-frequencybased volatility model (Shephard and Shephard (2010)), the multiplicative error model 2

3 (Engle and Gallo (2006)), and the realized volatility and factor model approach (Tao et al. (2011)). In this paper we introduce a unified model at all time scales for modeling both lowfrequency and high-frequency financial data and drawing inferences for the combined highfrequency and low-frequency data. The unified model is a continuous-time Itô process with a GARCH volatility embedded in its continuous instantaneous volatility at integer time points. As a result, the instantaneous volatility at integer time points is a GARCH volatility, and thus the model at the discrete time points can be viewed as a volatility model for low-frequency log price data, while the model between the integer time points is a continuous-time Itô process often used as a log price model for high-frequency financial data. It provides a unified price model for both low-frequency and high-frequency financial data. The model is called a unified GARCH-Itô model. For the unified model, its lowfrequency volatility obeys a parametric GARCH volatility structure, we may estimate the model parameters by the following combing high-frequency and low-frequency approach. First, as the high-frequency volatility is nonparametric, we may use high-frequency data to construct nonparametric realized volatility estimators of integrated volatility over consecutive integer time points. Second, we treat the realized volatility estimators as proxy for low-frequency volatilities in the GARCH volatility structure of the unified model and develop a quasi-maximum likelihood estimation for the GARCH structure to estimate the model parameters. As a comparison, we also employ only the GARCH volatility structure at integer time points to develop a GARCH quasi-maximum likelihood estimation for estimating model parameters based on low-frequency data alone. We establish asymptotic theory for the proposed estimators. A simulation study is conducted to check finite sample performances of the estimation methods. Both asymptotic theory and simulation study show that while both estimators have good performances, the estimator based on the combined data is much better than the estimator using only low-frequency data. We illustrate the estimation methods through an application to Bank of America stock price data. 3

4 The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces a unified GARCH-Itô model and illustrates volatility properties for the model. Section 3 proposes quasi-maximum likelihood estimation methods based on combined high-frequency and low-frequency data and based on low-frequency data alone and develops asymptotic theory for the proposed estimators. Section 4 presents a simulation study to check the finite sample performances of the proposed estimators and an application of the estimation methods to Bank of America stock price data. All the proofs are collected in Section 5. 2 Unified discrete-time and continuous-time models 2.1 Discrete-time and continuous-time models Discrete-time GARCH processes and continuous-time Itô processes provide common stochastic models in finance. A discrete-time GARCH model may be described as follows, X t X t 1 = µ + ξ t, t = 1,..., n, where we denote by X t the true log price at time t, random errors ξ t satisfy E[ξ t F LF t 1] = 0 a.s., F LF t = σ(x t, X t 1,...), and their conditional variances obey E [ ] [ ξt 2 Ft 1 LF = ω + γe ξ 2 t 1 Ft 2] LF + βξ 2 t 1. Because of simplicity in statistical inferences, GARCH models are often employed in empirical financial studies. Continuous-time models play a pivotal role in theoretical finance particularly in asset pricing. The models are often defined by stochastic differential equations. Although the two kinds of models are developed independently and have very different characteristics, there are deep relationships between GARCH and diffusion models (Nelson (1990), Wang (2002), Duan et al. (2009), and Kallsen and Taqqu (1998)). For example, Kallsen and Taqqu (1998) embedded a special ARCH model in an Itô process to study GARCH option pricing. Discrete GARCH models are often used to model low-frequency financial data, 4

5 and continuous-time Itô processes are commonly employed in the study of high-frequency financial data. It is desirable to combine both low-frequency and high-frequency financial data by developing unified financial models. Some recent attempts in such studies may include Engle and Gallo (2006), Shephard and Shephard (2010), Hansen et al. (2012), and Tao et al. (2011). 2.2 Instantaneous volatility process Set R + = [0, ) and denote by N the set of all non-negative integers. We define a unified modeling approach by embedding a standard GARCH(1, 1) model into an Itô process with an instantaneous volatility as follows. Definition 1 We call a log stock price X t, t R +, to follow a unified GARCH-Itô model if it satisfies dx t = µdt + σ t db t, (2.1) ( t ) 2 σt 2 = σ[t] 2 + (t [t]){ω + (γ 1)σ[t]} 2 + β σ s db s, (2.2) where µ is a drift, [t] denotes the integer part of t, B t is a standard Brownian motion with respect to a filtration F t, σ t is a volatility process adapted to F t, and θ = (ω, β, γ) are model parameters. [t] For a unified GARCH-Itô model, instantaneous volatility σt 2 is a continuous-time process defined at all times t R +, and when restricted to integer times t N it obeys a GARCH structure σt 2 = ω + γσt βzt 2, Z t = t t 1 σ s db s, t N. (2.3) We may interpret the unified GARCH-Itô model as a unified model for both high-frequency and low-frequency financial data as follows. The process X t and volatility σt 2 at integer time points t N are treated as low-frequency the daily log price and daily GARCH volatility, respectively. For time t between integers, we may view X t as the high-frequency log price, σt 2 5

6 as high-frequency instantaneous volatility, and integral of σ 2 t over two consecutive integers as integrated volatility. The continuous-time GARCH model proposed by Kallsen and Taqqu (1998) is a special case of the unified GARCH-Itô model. 2.3 Integrated volatility for the unified model High-frequency volatility analysis often estimates integrated volatility n σ2 t dt, while the low-frequency volatilities σ 2 n obey a GARCH structure used for parameter estimation and volatility prediction. We study integrated volatilities over consecutive integers, which will be employed for statistical inferences later. Proposition 1 For a unified GARCH-Itô model we have the iterative relationships for integrated volatilities. (a) For 0 < β < 1 and k, n N, R(k) n (n t) k σt 2 dt k! = ω + (γ + k + 1)σ2 (k + 2)! + 2β n (n t) k+1 (k + 1)! t σ s db s σ t db t + βr(k + 1). In particular, n σt 2 β ( ) k ω + (γ + k + 1)σ 2 n (β(n t)) k+1 t dt = + 2 σ s db s σ t db t (k + 2)! k=0 (k + 1)! = h n (θ) + D n, (2.4) where h n (θ) = β 2 (e β 1 β)ω + [(γ 1)β 2 (e β 1 β) + β 1 (e β 1)]σ 2 = ω g + γh (θ) + β g Z 2, (2.5) ω g = β 1 (e β 1)ω, β g = β 1 (γ 1)(e β 1 β) + e β 1, τ(θ) = (ω g, β g, γ), (2.6) and is a martingale difference. n t D n = 2 (e (n t)β 1) σ s db s σ t db t 6

7 (b) For 0 < β < 1 and k, n N, [ n ] (n t) k E σt 2 dt k! F In particular, where h n is defined in (2.5). (c) For 0 < β g + γ < 1 and n N, = ω + (γ + k + [ n 1)σ2 +βe (k + 2)! [ n E (n t) k+1 (k + 1)! ] σt 2 dt F. ] σt 2 dt F = h n (θ), (2.7) E [h n (θ)] = ω g 1 β g γ and E [ ] σn 2 ω(1 β g γ) + βω g = (1 β g γ)(1 γ), (2.8) where ω g and β g are defined in (2.6). Proposition 1 (a) shows that the integrated volatilities can be decomposed into h n (θ) and D n. h n (θ) is adapted to the low-frequency filtration, F LF = σ ({X i : i {n 1, n 2,...}}), which is a sigma field generated by daily stock prices and may be viewed as low-frequency information based on daily stock prices. Note that the filtration F at integers n 1 is generated by stock prices at all past times and interpreted as the high-frequency filtration, and of course F F LF. Both σ 2 n and h n (θ) obey linear GARCH(1, 1) volatility structures with model parameter θ = (ω, β, γ) for σ 2 n and model parameter τ(θ) in (2.6) for h n (θ). The decomposition in (2.4) shows that the integrated volatilities consist of a GARCH volatility h n (θ) and a martingale difference D n. The proof of Lemma 2 (b) further shows that D n can be expressed as D n = β n e (n t)β ( t σ s db s ) 2 dt n ( e (n t)β 1 ) σ 2 t dt. 3 Parameter estimation for the unified model 3.1 Low-frequency and high-frequency financial data Discrete-time GARCH models are often used to fit low-frequency financial data, and continuous-time Itô processes are commonly employed to model log stock prices in high- 7

8 frequency financial data. It is desirable to unify both high-frequency and low-frequency financial models and fit the unified models to the combined high-frequency and low-frequency financial data. For low-frequency data, GARCH models are parametric models, and model parameters are estimated by (quasi) maximum likelihood estimation. For high-frequency data, Itô processes are non-parametric models, and realized volatility methods are adopted to estimate integrated volatility for the Itô processes. Our proposal for the unified GARCH- Itô model is the quasi-maximum likelihood estimation (QMLE) approach, where we substitute volatilities in a quasi-likelihood function by the realized volatility estimators obtained from high-frequency data and estimate GARCH parameters by maximizing the quasi-likelihood function. We assume that the underlying log price process follows a unified GARCH-Itô model. The low-frequency data are observed log prices at integer times, namely, X t, t = 0, 1, 2,, n. The high-frequency data are observed log prices at time points between integers, that is, let t i,j be the high-frequency observed time points during the i-th period that satisfy i 1 = t i,0 < t i,1 <... < t i,mi < t i,mi +1 = t i+1,0 = i, and observed log prices Y tij obey Y ti,j = X ti,j + ɛ ti,j, (3.1) where ɛ ti,j are micro-structure noises independent of price and volatility processes, and for each i, ɛ ti,j, j = 1,, m i, are i.i.d. with Eɛ ti,j = 0. The low-frequency drift µ over consecutive integers can be easily estimated by the sample mean of low-frequency returns, while the drift µ has asymptotically negligible effects on high-frequency realized volatility estimators. Thus, to focus on volatility analysis we may take µ = 0 in (2.1) for simplicity. 3.2 Quasi-maximum likelihood estimation based on both highfrequency and low-frequency data We can nonparametrically estimate integrated volatility by using high-frequency financial data in the i-th period. In the low-frequency view, we may treat the estimated integrated 8

9 volatilities as observations and define a quasi-likelihood function L m,n(θ) for the lowfrequency GARCH structure as follows, ˆL n,m(θ) = 1 2n log(h i (θ)) + RV i h i (θ), where RV i is the multi-scale realized volatility estimator (kernel realized volatility estimator or pre-averaging volatility estimator) based on m i high-frequency data during the i-th period. As an estimator of the integrated volatility over the i-th period, RV i may have convergence rate m 1/4 i. From Proposition 1, the integrated volatility over the i-th period is equal to h i (θ 0 ) plus a martingale difference D i, where θ 0 = (ω 0, β 0, γ 0 ) denotes the true parameter value. In the quasi-likelihood function we drop the martingale differences from the integrated volatilities, because the effects of martingale differences are asymptotically negligible. To evaluate the quasi-likelihood function we need initial volatility σ 2 0 to obtain h i (θ). Taking Z 2 1 = (X 1 X 0 ) 2 as an initial value of σ 2 0, we compute the quasi-likelihood function ˆL n,m(θ) and maximize it over parameter space Θ. Denote the maximizer by ˆθ, that is, ˆθ = argmax θ Θ ˆL n,m(θ). We estimate θ 0 by ˆθ and model parameter τ(θ 0 ) in (2.6) by τ(ˆθ ) Asymptotic theory This section establishes consistency and asymptotic distribution for the proposed estimator ˆθ. First we fix notations. For a matrix A = (A i,j ) i,j=1,...,k, and a vector a = (a 1,..., a k ), define A max = max i,j A i,j and a max = max i a i. Given a random variable X and p 1, let X Lp = {E [ X p ]} 1/p. Let C s be positive generic constants whose values are free of θ, n and m i, and may change from appearance to appearance. We need the following assumptions. Assumption 1 9

10 (a) Let Θ = {θ = (ω, β, γ) : ω l < ω < ω u, β l < β < β u, γ l < γ < γ u, γ + β g < 1}, where ω l, ω u, γ l, γ u, β l, β u are known positive constants, and β g is defined in (2.6). (b) { D i : i N} is uniformly integrable. (c) One of the following conditions is satisfied. (c1) E[Z4 i F i 1] h 2 i (θ 0) C a.s. for any i N. (c2) There exists a positive constant δ such that E (d) (D i, Z 2 i ) is a stationary ergodic process. [ ( ) ] Z 2 2+δ i h i (θ 0 C for any i N. ) (e) Let m = n m i/n. We have C 1 m m i C 2 m, and sup 1 j mi t i,j t i,j 1 = O(m 1 ) and n 2 m 1 0 as m, n. (f) sup i N RVi i i 1 σ2 t dt C m 1/4 for some δ > 0. L1+δ [ i (g) For any i N, E [RV i F i 1 ] C E i 1 σ2 t dt ] F i 1 + C a.s. Assumption 1 (a)-(d) are for the low-frequency part of the model, with Assumption 1 (e)-(g) for the high-frequency part. A sufficient condition of Assumption 1 (b) is sup i N E( D i 1+δ ) < for some δ > 0. Assumption 1 (c) is required moment conditions where (c1) is similar to the moment condition in Lee and Hansen (1992) and (c2) is relatively easy to check. Since m is the average number of high-frequency data, with n for low-frequency sample size, Assumption 1 (e) is typical conditions in high-frequency volatility analysis. We may take RV i as one of multi-scale realized volatility (Zhang (2006) and Fan and Wang (2007)), kernel realized volatility (Barndorff-Nielsen et al. (2008)), and pre-averaging realized volatility (Jacod et al. (2009)), and Tao et al. (2013, theorem 1) and Kim and Wang (2014, theorems 1 and 3) indicate that Assumption 1 (f)-(g) are reasonable. The following theorems establish consistency and convergence rate for ˆθ. 10

11 Theorem 1 Under Assumption 1 (a)-(b), (e)-(f), there is a unique maximizer of L n (θ) and as m, n, ˆθ θ 0 in probability. Theorem 2 Under Assumption 1 (a)-(c), (e)-(g), we have ˆθ θ 0 max = O p (m 1/4 + n 1/2 ). Theorem 2 shows that the convergence rate of ˆθ has two components m 1/4 and n 1/2. The rate m 1/4 is due to the high-frequency volatility estimation, which is the optimal convergence rate for estimating integrated volatilities based on high-frequency data with market microstructure noise, and n 1/2 is from the usual parametric convergence rate based on low-frequency data. The stationary ergodic condition Assumption 1 (d) is used to obtain asymptotic normality. Theorem 3 Under Assumption 1, we have as m, n, n(ˆθ θ 0 ) d N(0, B 1 A B 1 ), where and [ A h1 (θ) = E h 1 (θ) h θ=θ0 4 T 1 (θ 0 ) B = 1 2 E [ h1 (θ) 1 0 ] (e β0(1 t) 1) 2 (X t X 0 ) 2 σt 2 dt h 1 (θ) ] h θ=θ0 2 T 1 (θ 0 ). Theorem 3 provides an asymptotic normal distribution for ˆθ. Though the asymptotic variance is quite complicated, we will demonstrate in the next section via asymptotic analysis that the estimation based on combined high-frequency and low-frequency approach is better than that based on low-frequency alone. 11

12 3.3 Quasi-maximum likelihood estimation based on only lowfrequency data This section considers the estimation of θ 0 using only low-frequency data X 0, X 1,, X n and compare it with combined low-frequency and high-frequency approach. As we have seen in Section 3.2, θ 0 and τ(θ 0 ) are model parameters for σi 2 and h i (θ 0 ), respectively. Due to the continuous nature of the unified GARCH-Itô model, low-frequency return Z i = X i X i 1 corresponds to integrated volatility of σt 2 over (i 1, i] but not σi 2. Thus we can not directly apply standard GARCH likelihood or quasi-likelihood estimation methods to return data Z i and estimate θ 0, although (2.3) may lead to think such direct applications. We estimate θ 0 using the GARCH structure between low-frequency return squares Z 2 i and GARCH volatilities h i (θ 0 ). Specifically, by Itô s lemma and Proposition 1 (a), we have i Zi 2 = (X i X i 1 ) 2 = 2 = h i (θ 0 ) + 2 i i 1 i 1 (X t X i 1 )dx t + i i 1 σ 2 t dt e (n t)β 0 (X t X i 1 )dx t = h i (θ 0 ) + D L i, where D L i = 2 i i 1 e(n t)β 0 (X t X i 1 )dx t. We define the quasi-likelihood function ˆL GL n (θ) = 1 2n log(h i (θ)) + Z2 i h i (θ), and maximizes GL ˆL n (θ) over the parameter space Θ. Denote the maximizer by ˆθ GL, that is, ˆθ GL = argmax θ Θ ˆL GL n (θ), where we use Z 2 1 as an initial value of σ 2 0 in the expressions of h i (θ) and Section 3.2. We estimate θ 0 by ˆθ GL and τ(θ 0 ) in (2.6) by τ(ˆθ GL ). GL ˆL n (θ), as in The following theorems establish consistency and convergence rate for ˆθ GL. Theorem 4 Under Assumption 1 (a)-(b), there exists a unique maximizer of L GL n (θ) and as n, ˆθ GL θ 0 in probability. 12

13 Theorem 5 Under Assumption 1 (a)-(c), we have ˆθ GL θ 0 max = O p (n 1/2 ). Theorem 6 Under Assumption 1 (a)-(d), we have as n, n(ˆθgl θ 0 ) d N(0, B 1 A GL B 1 ), where [ A GL h1 (θ) = E and B is defined in Theorem 3. h 1 (θ) h θ=θ0 4 T 1 (θ 0 ) 1 0 ] e 2β0(1 t) (X t X 0 ) 2 σt 2 dt, Theorems 3 and 6 establish asymptotic normality for ˆθ and ˆθ GL, respectively. Their asymptotic variances have the same structure, but A GL is larger than A. It may be intuitively explained by the fact that ˆθ is constructed by combining both high-frequency and low-frequency data, while ˆθ is obtained by using only low-frequency data. Technically it is due to the difference between D i and D L i, where E[(D L 1 ) 2 ] = E[ 1 0 e2β 0(1 t) (X t X 0 ) 2 σ 2 t dt] and E[D 2 1] = E[ 1 0 (eβ 0(1 t) 1) 2 (X t X 0 ) 2 σ 2 t dt], and the integrated volatilities i i 1 σ2 t dt are closer to the GARCH volatilities h i (θ 0 ) than the low-frequency return squares Z 2 i. Thus, ˆθ GL has a bigger asymptotic variance than ˆθ, and ˆθ is asymptotically more efficient. 4 Numerical Analysis 4.1 A simulation study We conducted simulations to check the finite sample performances of the proposed estimators ˆθ and ˆθ GL and compare their performances. We generated the log prices X ti,j, t i,j = i 1 + j/m, i = 1,, n, j = 1,, m, from the unified GARCH-Itô model in (2.1) and (2.2) with the following form, dx t = σ t db t, dσ 2 t = ( ω 0 + (γ 0 1)σ 2 [t] + β 0 σ 2 t ) dt + 2β0 (X t X [t] )σ t db t, 13

14 where θ 0 = (ω 0, β 0, γ 0 ) = (0.2, 0.3, 0.4), and B t is a standard Brownian motion. We took n = 250, m = 2160, and initial values X 0 = 10 and σ0 2 = E(σ1) 2 = in (2.8). The values for m and n were chosen so that low-frequency data are daily observations and high-frequency data correspond to stock prices observed every ten seconds. The Euler scheme was used to discretize the continuous-time Itô process driving by B t. The low-frequency data were taken to be X i, i = 0,, n. The high-frequency data Y ti,j were simulated from model (3.1) where X ti,j were taken from the generated log prices from the unified GARCH-Itô model, and market microstructure noises ɛ ti,j were simulated from i.i.d. normal distribution with mean zero and standard deviation σ ɛ = In the simulation, we estimated integrated volatilities by the multi-scale realized volatility estimator (Zhang (2006) and Fan and Wang (2007)). Specifically, the i-th period integrated volatility estimator is where RV K i = 1 K m i r=k mi RV i = k=1 a k RV K k i + ζ ( RV K 1 i ) RV K m i i, (4.1) [Y (t i,r ) Y (t i,r K )] 2, a k = 12(k + m i )(k m i /2 1/2), mi (m i 1) K k = m i + k, and ζ = 2 m i ( m i + 1) (m i + 1)( m i 1). We estimated the model parameters by the two estimators ˆθ and ˆθ GL proposed in Section 3. The whole simulation procedure was repeated 1000 times. Table 1: The squared biases, variances, and MSEs of ˆθ and ˆθ GL for estimating θ 0 = (ω 0, β 0, γ 0 ) based on data simulated from the unified GARCH-Itô model with m = 2160, n = 250 and σ ɛ = The squared biases, variances, and MSEs reported are based on 1000 repetitions and multiplied by 100. ω β γ Bias 2 Variance MSE Bias 2 Variance MSE Bias 2 Variance MSE ˆθ ˆθ GL The simulation results are reported in Table 1 and displayed in Figure 1. Table 1 provides the squared biases, variances, and mean squared errors (MSEs) of the proposed 14

15 estimators ˆθ based on combined high-frequency and low-frequency data and ˆθ GL based on low-frequency data alone, and Figure 1 shows their box plots. The simulation results demonstrate that the proposed estimators have good finite sample performances, and as we expected, ˆθ GL has much larger bias and variance than ˆθ. The simulations confirm the theoretical findings in Sections 2 and 3 that the bias and variance components for constructing ˆθ based on the combined data are smaller than those for ˆθ GL based on only low-frequency data. ω β γ Estimated value ω 0 Method GL Estimated value β 0 Method GL Estimated value γ 0 Method GL Figure 1: Boxplots of ˆθ and ˆθ GL for estimating θ 0 = (ω 0, β 0, γ 0 ) based on data simulated from the unified GARCH-Itô model with m = 2160, n = 250 and σ ɛ = 0.05, where and GL represent ˆθ and ˆθ GL, respectively. 4.2 An empirical study We applied the unified GARCH-Itô model to high-frequency trading data of Bank of America Corporation (BAC) over a period of 146 days in 2012 with n = 146 and m = 175, 745. The high-frequency data were available between open and close, and lowfrequency data were obtained by computing open-to-close returns. The multi-scale realized volatility estimators RV i in (4.1) were employed to estimate daily integrated volatilities based on the high-frequency data, and according to the description in Section 3, we calculated ˆθ based on combined high-frequency and low-frequency data (all data) 15

16 Volatility for BAC with open to close returns Volatility time o RV GL Figure 2: Plots of daily volatility estimates RV i, h i (ˆθ ) and h i (ˆθ ), where RV, and GL stand for realized volatility estimates RV i, GARCH volatility estimates h i (ˆθ ) based on all data, and GARCH volatility estimates h i (ˆθ GL ) based on low-frequency data alone. and ˆθ GL based on only the low-frequency data to estimate θ. The estimated values were ˆθ = ( , , ) and ˆθ GL = ( , , ). In Figure 2 we displayed the estimated daily volatilities by realized volatility estimators RV i, daily volatility estimators h i (ˆθ ) based on combined high-frequency and low-frequency data and daily volatility estimators h i (ˆθ GL ) using low-frequency data alone. From the plot we can see that while the low-frequency estimators h i (ˆθ GL ) were quite flat, RV i are very rough and volatile, and the combined estimators h i (ˆθ ) were somewhat between the two types of the estimators and followed the realized volatility estimators more than the low-frequency ones. The phenomenon may be due to the facts that RV i are nonparametric estimators and free of any parametric assumption, h i (ˆθ ) and h i (ˆθ GL ) were obtained under the unified GARCH-Itô model, and h i (ˆθ GL ) more or less rely on low-frequency data and the parametric GARCH structure embedded in the unified GARCH-Itô model, while h i (ˆθ ) pool the strength of the parametric GARCH structure embedded in the unified GARCH-Itô model for the lowfrequency data and the nonparametric realized volatility approach for the high-frequency data. 16

17 5 Proofs Let C > 0 and 0 < ρ < 1 be generic constants whose values are free of θ, n and m and may change from appearance to appearance. 5.1 Proof of Proposition 1 Proof of Proposition 1. (a). By Itô s lemma we have R(k) = σ 2 + β n n n s = ω + (γ + k + 1)σ2 (k + 2)! (n t) k dt + ( ) n ω + (γ 1)σ 2 (n t) k t r dt k! k! (n t) k n n ( σ 2 (n t) k s k! sdtds + 2β dt s k! n (n t) k+1 t + 2β (k + 1)! Using the iterative relationship we can easily prove (2.4). To show (2.5), since σ 2 n has a standard GARCH(1,1) form, we have ) σ h db h σ s db s σ s db s σ t db t + βr(k + 1). h n (θ) = β 2 (e β 1 β)ω ( ) +[(γ 1)β 2 (e β 1 β) + β 1 (e β ω 1)] 1 γ + β γ i Z i 2 i=0 ω g = 1 γ + βg γ i Z i 2 = ω g + γh (θ) + β g Z. 2 i=0 As the integrand of D n is predictable, D n is a martingale difference. (b). It is an immediate consequence of E [D n F ] = 0. (c). By Itô s lemma we conclude [ n E[Zn] 2 = 2E = E[h n (θ)], t ] [ n ] σ s db s σ t db t + E σt 2 dt where the last equality is due to the fact that n t σ sdb s σ t db t is a martingale difference. Then, we have E[h n (θ)] = ω g + (γ + β g )E[h (θ)] = 17 ω g 1 γ β g.

18 Similarly, we can show ω g E[σn] 2 = ω + γe[σ] 2 + β 1 γ β = ω(1 βg γ) + βω g g (1 β g γ)(1 γ). 5.2 Initial value We use Z 2 1 as the initial value of σ 2 0 to evaluate h i (θ) and the quasi-likelihood. The following lemma shows that the impact of the initial value is asymptotically negligible. Lemma 1 As h i (θ) depends on the initial value σ 2 0, write h i (θ) as h i (θ, σ 2 0) to explicitly express its dependence on the initial value σ 2 0. Under Assumption 1 (a), we have for any ξ = O p (1) and i N, hi (θ, ξ) h i (θ, σ 2 0) = Op (γ i 1 ). Proof : Simple algebra shows h i (θ, ξ) h i (θ, σ 2 0) = γ i 1 β 1 β g (ξ σ 2 0) = O p (γ i 1 ). Lemma 1 shows that the dependence of h i (θ) on the initial value is exponentially decaying. Thus, as n, the difference between the quasi-likelihood functions with the true initial value σ0 2 and initial value Z1 2 decays faster than O p (n 1 ). Thus we may use the true initial value σ0 2 in the rest of proofs. 5.3 Proof of Theorem 1 Note the notation τ(θ 0 ) = (ω g 0, β g 0, γ 0 ). Let ˆL n,m(θ) = 1 2n log(h i (θ)) + RV i h i (θ) = 1 2n ˆl i (θ) and ˆψ n,m(θ) = ˆL n,m (θ) ; 18

19 ˆL n (θ) = 1 2n L n (θ) = 1 2n log(h i (θ)) + i i 1 σ2 t dt h i (θ) log(h i (θ)) + h i(θ 0 ) h i (θ) and and ψ n ˆψ n (θ) = ˆL n (θ) = L n (θ). (θ) ; Let (β g l, βg u) and (ω g l, ωg u) be the lower bound and the upper bound of β g and ω g, respectively. To ease notations, we denote derivatives of any function f at x 0 by f(x 0 ) x Lemma 2 Under Assumption 1 (a), we have (a) E (Z 2 i ) = E = f(x) x. x=x0 ( ) i i 1 σ2 t dt = E (h i (θ 0 )), sup i N E (Zi 2 ) ωg 0 1 γ 0 + E (h β g 1 (θ 0 )) <, and 0 sup i N E (sup θ Θ h i (θ)) < ; (b) D i = β 0 i i 1 e(n t)β 0 (X t X i 1 ) 2 dt i i 1 ( e (n t)β 0 1 ) σ 2 t dt a.s. for any i N; (c) if γ γ 0, sup i N h i (θ 0 ) h i (θ) < a.s.; (d) there exists a neighborhood B(θ 0 ) of θ 0 such that for any p 1, sup i N supθ B(θ0 ) and B(θ 0 ) Θ; (e) for any p 1, sup i N supθ Θ h i (θ) j Lp C, sup i N supθ Θ 2 h i (θ) j k Lp sup i N supθ Θ (ω, β, γ). h i (θ 0 ) h i (θ) C and 3 h i (θ) j k l Lp C for any j, k, l {1, 2, 3}, where θ = (θ 1, θ 2, θ 3 ) = < Lp Proof : (a). By Itô s lemma and Proposition 1 (b) we have E ( ( ) i ) Zi 2 = E σt 2 dt = E (h i (θ 0 )). Simple algebra shows i 1 E (h i (θ 0 )) = ω g 0 + γ 0 E (h i 1 (θ 0 )) + β0e ( ) g Zi 1 2 = ω g 0 + (β g 0 + γ 0 )E (h i 1 (θ 0 )). Using this iterative equation and the fact that β g 0 + γ 0 < 1 we can easily prove E (h i (θ 0 )) = ωg 0(1 (β g 0 + γ 0 ) i 1 ) 1 β g 0 γ 0 +(β g 0 +γ 0 ) i 1 E (h 1 (θ 0 )) 19 ω g 0 1 γ 0 β g +E (h 1 (θ 0 )) <. 0

20 Similarly, we can show ( ) sup E sup h i (θ) i N θ Θ <. (b). Let f(t, X t ) = ( e (i t)β 0 1 ) (X t X i 1 ) 2. By Itô s lemma we have df(t, X t ) = [ β 0 e (i t)β 0 (X t X i 1 ) 2 + ( e (i t)β 0 1 ) σ 2 t ] dt +2 ( e (i t)β 0 1 ) (X t X i 1 ) dx t. Then 0 = i i 1 [ β0 e (i t)β 0 (X t X i 1 ) 2 + ( e (i t)β 0 1 ) ] σt 2 dt + Di. (c). The statement follows from Lemma 4 (4) in Lee and Hansen (1994). (d). For any δ > 0, there exists a neighborhood B(θ 0 ) Θ such that γ 0 (1 + δ)γ for any θ B(θ 0 ). By the fact that x/(1 + x) x s for all x 0 and any s [0, 1] we have h i (θ 0 ) sup θ B(θ 0 ) h i (θ) C + βg 0 β g l i 2 k=0 i 2 C + C k=0 i 2 C + C k=0 sup θ B(θ 0 ) sup θ B(θ 0 ) ( γ0 ( γ0 γ γ ) k γ k β g Z 2 i 1 k ω g + γ k β g Z 2 i 1 k ) k γ sk Z 2s i 1 k (1 + δ) k γ sk u Z 2s i 1 k. Take 0 < δ < 1 γs u. Then (1 + δ) γ s γu s u < 1. Choose s [0, 1] such that sup i N E ( Zi 1 k) 2ps <, and by Minkowski s inequality we have sup h i (θ 0 ) i 2 C + C ρ k Z 2s h i (θ) Lp θ B(θ 0 ) k=0 i 1 k Lp <. Since ρ < 1, sup i N sup θ B(θ 0 ) h i (θ 0 ) h i (θ) <. Lp (e). First, we investigate the first derivatives. Since σ 2 i is the linear function of β and ω, we can show h i (θ) 1 h i(θ) j C a.s. for j = 1, 2. (5.1) 20

21 Using the fact that x/(1 + x) x s for any s [0, 1] and all x 0 we can show 0 h i (θ) 1 h i(θ) γ { i 2 [ = h i (θ) 1 kγ k 1 (ω g + β g Zi 1 k) 2 + γ k β 1 (e β 1 β)zi 1 k] 2 k=1 +(i 1)γ i 2 h 1(θ) γ } i 2 γ k (ω g + β g Zi 1 k 2 C k ) ω g + γ k (ω g + β g Zi 1 k 2 ) + C k=1 i 2 C kρ ks (ωu g + βuz g i 1 k) 2 s + C. k=1 Choose s [0, 1] such that E ( ω g u + β g uz 2 i 1 k) sp <, and by the fact that ρ < 1 we have sup i N sup θ Θ h i (θ) γ C. Lp Similarly, we can show the bound for the second and third derivatives. Lemma 3 Under Assumption 1 (a), (b), (e), and (f), we have sup θ Θ ˆL n,m(θ) L n (θ) = O p (m 1/4 ) + o p (1). (5.2) Proof : By the triangular inequality we have ˆL n,m(θ) L n (θ) ˆL n,m(θ) ˆL n (θ) + ˆL n (θ) L n (θ). (5.3) For the first term on the right hand side of (5.3), since h i (θ) stays away from zero, we have [ E sup θ Θ ˆL n,m(θ) ˆL n ] (θ) C 1 n [ E RV i where the last inequality is due to Assumption 1 (f). Thus, i i 1 ] σt 2 dt Cm 1/4, sup θ Θ ˆL n,m(θ) ˆL n (θ) = O p (m 1/4 ). For the second term on the right hand side of (5.3), simple algebra shows ˆL n (θ) L n (θ) = 1 2n D i h i (θ). 21

22 D Since h i (θ) is adapted to F i 1, i is also a martingale difference. The fact that D i h i (θ) h i (θ) 1 D ω g i implies the uniform integrability of D i h i (θ). By Theorem 2.22 in Hall and Heyde (1980), we have ˆL n (θ) L n (θ) 0 in probability. Now we need to establish the uniform convergence. Let G n (θ) = ˆL n (θ) L n (θ). If G n (θ) is stochastic equicontinuous, the uniform convergence can be obtained. By Taylor expansion and the mean value theorem there exists θ between θ and θ such that G n (θ) G n (θ 1 h i (θ ) D i ) = 2n h 2 i (θ ) (θ θ ) C 1 2n sup h i (θ ) D i θ Θ h 2 i (θ ) (θ θ ) max. max In case of β and ω, by (5.1) we have for j = 1, 2, sup h i (θ ) θ Θ j D i h 2 i (θ ) C D i L1 C <. L1 In case of γ, by Lemma 2 (b) and (e) we have sup h i (θ ) D i θ Θ γ h 2 i (θ ) C L1 sup h i (θ i ) (X i 1 t X i 1 ) 2 dt + i i 1 σ2 t dt θ Θ γ h 2 i (θ ) L1 C sup h i (θ ) h i (θ 0 ) θ Θ γ h 2 i (θ ), (5.4) L1 where the second inequality is due to Itô s Lemma and the tower property. If γ γ 0, Lemma 2 (c) and (e) imply that (5.4) is bounded. Thus we just need to work for the case of γ γ 0. For any 0 k i 1, we have k 1 h i (θ 0 ) h i (θ) C + C l=0 γ l 0 Z 2 i 1 l + γ k γ l Zi 1 l 2 0 h i k (θ 0 ) h i (θ) C + C [ k ( ) ] k γ0 + γ k h i k (θ 0 ) 0 γ h i (θ). Thus, by Lemma 2 (a) we obtain that the right hand side of (5.4) is bounded by { [ i 2 C sup ( ) ] } γ k k h i 1 k (θ) γ0 C + C k + γ k h i k (θ 0 ) 0 θ Θ h i (θ) γ h i (θ) k=0 L 1 i 2 C sup { γ k u h i 1 k (θ) + kγ0 k h i 1 k (θ) + γ0 k h i k (θ 0 ) } θ Θ k=0 22 L 1

23 { i 2 C k=0 C <, γ k u } sup h i 1 k (θ) + kγ0 k sup h i 1 k (θ) + γ0 k h i k (θ 0 ) L1 θ Θ L1 θ Θ L1 where the first inequality is due to γk h i 1 k (θ) h i (θ) 1. Therefore, G n (θ) satisfies a weak Lipschitz condition, and Theorem 3 in Andrews (1992) implies that it uniformly converges to zero. Proof of Theorem 1. First, we show that there is a unique maximizer of L n (θ). From the definition of L n (θ), simple algebra shows max θ Θ L n (θ) 1 2n min log(h i(θ i )) + h i(θ 0 ) θ i Θ h i (θ i ). θ 0i is the minimizer of the i-th summand on the right hand side of above inequality, if θ 0i satisfies h i (θ 0i ) = h i (θ 0 ). Thus, if there exists θ Θ such that h i (θ ) = h i (θ 0 ) for all i = 1, 2,..., n, then θ is the maximizer. Note that θ 0 is one of the candidates θ. Below we will show that in fact such θ must be equal to θ 0 a.s. Since h i (θ) = ω g + γh i 1 (θ) + β g Z 2 i 1, θ and θ 0 satisfies the following equation, 1 h 1 (θ 0 ) Z h 2 (θ 0 ) Z2 2 ω g ω g 0 ω g ω g 0 γ γ 0... M γ γ 0 = 0 a.s., β g β g 1 h (θ 0 ) Z 2 0 β g β g 0 where ω g = β 1 (e β 1)ω and β g = β 1 (γ 1)(e β 1 β ) + e β 1. Since Z i s are nondegenerate, M is of full rank. Then, M T M is invertible, and ω g ω g 0 γ γ 0 = 0 a.s. β g β g 0 Since given γ, β g is a strictly increasing function with respect to β, θ = θ 0, and there is a unique maximizer. Then, since L n (θ) is a continuous function, for any ε > 0, there is a 23

24 constant ϑ > 0 such that L n (θ 0 ) max θ Θ: θ θ 0 max ε L n (θ) > ϑ a.s. (5.5) Now the theorem is a consequence of Theorem 1 in Xiu (2010), Lemma 3 and (5.5). 5.4 Proof of Theorem 2 Lemma 4 Under Assumption 1 (a) and (g), we have 3ˆl (θ) supθ B(θ0 i (a) there exists a neighborhood B(θ 0 ) of θ 0 such that sup i N ) j k l L1 for any j, k, l {1, 2, 3}, where θ = (θ 1, θ 2, θ 3 ) = (ω, β, γ); < (b) ψ n (θ 0 ) is a positive definite matrix for n 3. Proof : (a). Simple algebraic manipulations show 3ˆl i (θ) = j k l By Assumption 1 (g) we get { 1 RV } { } i 1 3 h i (θ) { h i (θ) h i (θ) j k l + 2 RV } { } { } i 1 h i (θ) 1 h i (θ) 1 2 h i (θ) { h i (θ) j h i (θ) k l + 2 RV } { } { } i 1 h i (θ) 1 h i (θ) 1 2 h i (θ) { h i (θ) k h i (θ) j l + 2 RV } { } { } i 1 h i (θ) 1 h i (θ) 1 2 h i (θ) { h i (θ) l h i (θ) j k RV } { } { i 1 h i (θ) 1 h i (θ) h i (θ) h i (θ) j h i (θ) k [ i E [RV i F i 1 ] CE i 1 } { 1 h i (θ) ] σt 2 dt F i 1 + C = C h i (θ 0 ) + C a.s. } h i (θ). l Then, by Lemma 2 (d) and (e) we have [ { } ] [ ] E sup RV i 1 h i (θ) h i (θ 0 ) CE sup 1 h i (θ) θ B(θ 0 ) h i (θ) h i (θ) j k l θ B(θ 0 ) h i (θ) h i (θ) j k l + C C sup h i (θ 0 ) h i (θ) sup 1 h i (θ) h i (θ) j k l + C C <, Lq θ B(θ 0 ) Lp θ B(θ 0 ) 24

25 where 1/p + 1/q = 1, p > 1 and q > 1, and the first and second inequalities are due to the tower property and Hölder s inequality, respectively. Similarly, we can bound the rest of terms. (b). Simple algebra shows where h θ,i = h i(θ 0 ) ψ n (θ 0 ) = 1 2n h i (θ 0 ) T h i (θ 0 ) h i (θ 0 ) 2 = 1 2n h θ,i h T θ,i, h i (θ 0 ) 1. Suppose that ψn (θ 0 ) is not a positive definite matrix. Then, there exists λ 0 such that 1 n 2n λt h θ,i h T θ,iλ = 0. This implies h T θ,iλ = 0 a.s. for all i = 1,..., n. Since h i (θ 0 ) stays away from zero, we can rewrite this as h 1 (θ 0 ) ω ω g 0 + γ h 1(θ 0 ) ω ω. ω g 0 + γ h (θ 0 ) ω ω where ωg 0 ω β g 0 β h 1 (θ 0 ) β h 1 (θ 0 ) γ ω g 0 + βg 0 β β Z2 1 + γ h 1(θ 0 ) h β 1 (θ) + βg 0 γ Z2 1 + γ h 1(θ 0 ) γ.. ω g 0 + βg 0 β β Z2 + γ h (θ 0 ) h β (θ) + βg 0 γ Z2 + γ h (θ 0 ) γ = β 1 0 (e β 0 1), ω g 0 β = [β 2 0 (1 e β 0 ) + e β 0 ]ω g 0, β g 0 γ λ = 0 a.s., = β 1 0 (e β 0 1 β 0 ), and = (γ 0 1)(e β 0 β 2 0 e β 0 + β 2 0 ) + β 0 e β 0. Since Z i s are nondegenerate, the matrix on the left hand side is of full rank a.s. Thus, λ = 0 a.s., which is a contradiction. Proof of Theorem 2. By Taylor expansion and the mean value theorem we have for some θ between θ 0 and ˆθ, ˆψ n,m(ˆθ ) ˆψ n,m(θ 0 ) = ˆψ n,m(θ 0 ) = ˆψ n,m(θ )(ˆθ θ 0 ). If ˆψ n,m(θ ) p ψn (θ 0 ) which is a positive definite matrix by Lemma 4 (b), then the convergence rate of ˆθ θ 0 is the same as that of ˆψ n,m(θ ) ψn (θ 0 ) = o p (1) and max To prove the second result, we first show ˆψ n,m(θ 0 ) ˆψ n,m(θ 0 ). So it is enough to show ˆψ n,m(θ 0 ) = O p (m 1/4 ) + O p (n 1/2 ). ˆψ n (θ 0 ) max = O p (m 1/4 ). 25

26 For any j {1, 2, 3}, by Hölder s inequality and Lemma 2 (e) we have 1 ( h i (θ 0 ) i h i (θ 0 ) 2 RV i σt dt) 2 2n j i 1 L1 C 1 h i (θ 0 ) i n h i (θ 0 ) 1 j RV i σt 2 dt Cm 1/4, (5.6) Lq Lp where 1 < p 1 + δ and 1/p + 1/q = 1, and the last inequality is due to Assumption 1 (f). Then, we have ˆψ n,m(θ 0 ) = ψn (θ 0 ) + 1 2n = 1 2n h i (θ 0 ) h i (θ 0 ) i 1 D i h i (θ 0 ) 1 h i (θ 0 ) + O p(m 1/4 ) D i h i (θ 0 ) 1 h i (θ 0 ) + O p(m 1/4 ). By Itô s lemma and Itô isometry we have for any j {1, 2, 3}, ( ) 2 [ E 1 h i (θ 0 ) h i (θ 0 ) 1 D i = 1 ( hi ) ] 2 (θ 0 ) E h 2n j h i (θ 0 ) 4n 2 i (θ 0 ) 2 Di 2 j h 2 i (θ 0) [ = 1 ( hi ) ] 2 (θ 0 ) E h 4n 2 i (θ 0 ) 2 E [D2 i F i 1 ] j h 2 i (θ 0) [ = 1 ( ) 2 E hi (θ 0 ) E i 4 ( e (i t)β 0 1 ) ] 2 (Xt X h 4n 2 i (θ 0 ) 2 i 1 i 1 ) 2 σ 2 t dt F i 1 j h 2 i (θ 0) [ C 1 ( hi ) ] 2 (θ 0 ) E h n 2 i (θ 0 ) 2 E [Z4 i F i 1 ] j h 2 i (θ. (5.7) 0) If the condition (c1) in Assumption 1 (c) is satisfied, we immediately conclude from Lemma 2 (e) that (5.7) is of order n 1. If the condition (c2) in Assumption 1 (c) is satisfied, by Hölder s inequality and Lemma 2 (e) we have that (5.7) is of order n 1. Thus, have In the case of ˆψ n,m(θ 0 ) = O p (m 1/4 ) + O p (n 1/2 ). ˆψ n,m(θ ) ψn (θ 0 ) ˆψ n,m(θ ) ψn (θ 0 ) max max 26 + = o p (1), by the triangular inequality we ˆψ n,m(θ ) n (θ 0 ). (5.8) max ˆψ n,m(θ 0 ) max ˆψ n,m(θ 0 ) ψ

27 3ˆl i (θ). For the first term on the right hand side of (5.8), let M i = max j,k,l {1,2,3} 3 sup θ B(θ0 ) j k l For large enough n and m, by Taylor expansion and the mean value theorem we have ˆψ n,m(θ ) ˆψ n,m(θ 0 ) C max n M i θ θ 0 max = o p (1), where the last equality is derived by Therorem 1 and the fact that 1 n n M i = O p (1) implied by Lemma 4 (a). For the second term on the right hand side of (5.8), similar to the proof of (5.6), we can apply Hölder s inequality and Lemma 2 (e) to show On the other hand, we have ˆψ n,m(θ 0 ) = ˆψ n,m(θ 0 ) ˆψ n (θ 0 ) = O p (m 1/4 ). max ˆψ n ( ) where η n = 1 n 2 h i (θ 0 ) 2n h T i (θ 0 ) 1 D i h i (θ 0 + h i(θ 0 ) ) (θ 0 ) + O p (m 1/4 ) = ψn (θ 0 ) + η n + O p (m 1/4 ) a.s., ( ) T hi (θ 0 ) hi (θ 0 ) 2 2D i h i (θ 0. Note that ) η n is a martingale. Then we can show η n max = O p (n 1/2 ) similar to the proof of (5.7). Finally we establish ˆψ n,m(θ 0 ) = ψn (θ 0 ) + O p (n 1/2 ) + O p (m 1/4 ). 5.5 Proof of Theorem 3 Proof of Theorem 3. For any λ R 3, let d i = λ T h i(θ 0 ) D i h i (θ 0 ) 1 h i (θ 0 ). Then d i is a martingale difference, and similar to the proof of (5.7) we can show E(d 2 i ) <. (D i, Z 2 i ) s are stationary and ergodic processes, thus d i is stationary and ergodic. Applying the martingale central limit theorem we obtain 1 n d d i N(0, E(d 2 1)). 27

28 Using Cramér-Wold device we can show n ˆψ n (θ 0 ) = n 1 2n h i (θ 0 ) D i h i (θ 0 ) 1 h i (θ 0 ) d N(0, A ). By the ergodic theorem and the result in the proof of Theorem 2 we have ˆψ n,m(θ 0 ) B in probability, and similar to the proof of Lemma 4 (b) we can show that B is a positive definite matrix. Finally we conclude n(ˆθ θ 0 ) = 1 nb ˆψ n (θ 0 ) + O p (n 1/2 m 1/4 ) + o p (1) d N(0, B 1 A B 1 ). 5.6 Proofs of Theorems 4-6 The arguments to prove Theorems 4-6 are similar to the proofs of Theorems 1-3. Acknowledgement. Yazhen Wang s research was supported in part by the NSF Grants DMS and DMS References [1] Andrews, D. W. K. (1992), Generic uniform convergence, Econometric Theory, 8, [2] Barndorff-Nielsen, O. E., Hansen, P. R., Lunde, A. and Shephard, N. (2008), Designing realized kernels to measure the ex-post variation of equity prices in the presence of noise, Econometrica, 76, [3] Bollerslev, T. (1986), Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity, Journal of Econometrics, 31,

29 [4] Duan, J. C., Wang, Y. and Zou, J. (2009), Convergence speed of GARCH option price to diffusion option price, International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance, 12, [5] Engle, R. F. (1982), Autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity with estimates of the variance of inflation in the United Kingdom, Econometrica, 50, [6] Engle R. F. and Gallo G. (2006), A multiple indicators model for volatility using intra-daily data, Journal of Econometrics, 131, [7] Fan, J. and Wang, Y. (2007), Multi-scale jump and volatility analysis for highfrequency financial data, Journal of the American Statistical Association, 102, [8] Hall, P. and Heyde C. C. (1980), Martingale Limit Theory and Its Application, Academic Press, New York. [9] Hansen, P. R., Huang, Z. and Shek, H. (2012), Realized GARCH: a joint model of returns and realized measures of volatility, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 27, [10] Jacod, J., Li, Y., Mykland, P. A., Podolskij, M. and Vetter, M. (2009), Microstructure noise in the continuous case: the pre-averaging approach, Stochastic Processes and their Applications, 119, [11] Kallsen, J. and Taqqu, M. S. (1998), Option pricing in arch-type models, Mathematical Finance, 8, [12] Kim, D. and Wang, Y. (2014), Asymptotic theory for large volatility matrix estimation based on high-frequency financial data, Manuscript. [13] Lee, S.-W. and Hansen, B. E. (1994), Asymptotic theory for the GARCH(1, 1) quasimaximum likelihood estimator, Econometric Theory, 10,

30 [14] Nelson, D. B. (1990), ARCH models as diffusion approximations, Journal of Econometrics, 45, [15] Shephard, N. and Sheppard, K. (2010), Realising the future: forecasting with high frequency based volatility (HEAVY) models, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 25, [16] Tao, M., Wang, Y. and Chen, X. (2013), Fast convergence rates in estimating large volatility matrices using high-frequency financial data, Econometric Theory, 29, [17] Tao, M., Wang, Y., Yao, Q. and Zou, J. (2011). Large volatility matrix inference via combining low-frequency and high-frequency approaches, Journal of the American Statistical Association, 106, [18] Wang, Y. (2002), Asymptotic nonequivalence of ARCH models and diffusions, The Annals of Statistics, 30, [19] Xiu, D. (2010), Quasi-maximum likelihood estimation of volatility with high frequency data, Journal of Econometrics, 159, [20] Zhang, L. (2006), Efficient estimation of stochastic volatility using noisy observations: a multi-scale approach, Bernoulli, 12, [21] Zhang, L., Mykland, P.A. and Aït-Sahalia, Y. (2005), A tale of two time scales: determining integrated volatility with noisy high-frequency data, Journal of the American Statistical Association, 100, Donggyu Kim, Department of Statistics, University of Wisconsin-Madison, 1300 University Avenue, Madison, WI address: kimd@stat.wisc.edu Yazhen Wang, Department of Statistics, University of Wisconsin-Madison, 1300 University Avenue, Madison, WI address: yzwang@stat.wisc.edu 30

Location Multiplicative Error Model. Asymptotic Inference and Empirical Analysis

Location Multiplicative Error Model. Asymptotic Inference and Empirical Analysis : Asymptotic Inference and Empirical Analysis Qian Li Department of Mathematics and Statistics University of Missouri-Kansas City ql35d@mail.umkc.edu October 29, 2015 Outline of Topics Introduction GARCH

More information

Subsampling Cumulative Covariance Estimator

Subsampling Cumulative Covariance Estimator Subsampling Cumulative Covariance Estimator Taro Kanatani Faculty of Economics, Shiga University 1-1-1 Bamba, Hikone, Shiga 5228522, Japan February 2009 Abstract In this paper subsampling Cumulative Covariance

More information

On Realized Volatility, Covariance and Hedging Coefficient of the Nikkei-225 Futures with Micro-Market Noise

On Realized Volatility, Covariance and Hedging Coefficient of the Nikkei-225 Futures with Micro-Market Noise On Realized Volatility, Covariance and Hedging Coefficient of the Nikkei-225 Futures with Micro-Market Noise Naoto Kunitomo and Seisho Sato October 22, 2008 Abstract For the estimation problem of the realized

More information

Portfolio Allocation using High Frequency Data. Jianqing Fan

Portfolio Allocation using High Frequency Data. Jianqing Fan Portfolio Allocation using High Frequency Data Princeton University With Yingying Li and Ke Yu http://www.princeton.edu/ jqfan September 10, 2010 About this talk How to select sparsely optimal portfolio?

More information

M-estimators for augmented GARCH(1,1) processes

M-estimators for augmented GARCH(1,1) processes M-estimators for augmented GARCH(1,1) processes Freiburg, DAGStat 2013 Fabian Tinkl 19.03.2013 Chair of Statistics and Econometrics FAU Erlangen-Nuremberg Outline Introduction The augmented GARCH(1,1)

More information

Minjing Tao and Yazhen Wang. University of Wisconsin-Madison. Qiwei Yao. London School of Economics. Jian Zou

Minjing Tao and Yazhen Wang. University of Wisconsin-Madison. Qiwei Yao. London School of Economics. Jian Zou Large Volatility Matrix Inference via Combining Low-Frequency and High-Frequency Approaches Minjing Tao and Yazhen Wang University of Wisconsin-Madison Qiwei Yao London School of Economics Jian Zou National

More information

Model Specification Testing in Nonparametric and Semiparametric Time Series Econometrics. Jiti Gao

Model Specification Testing in Nonparametric and Semiparametric Time Series Econometrics. Jiti Gao Model Specification Testing in Nonparametric and Semiparametric Time Series Econometrics Jiti Gao Department of Statistics School of Mathematics and Statistics The University of Western Australia Crawley

More information

ASYMPTOTIC NORMALITY OF THE QMLE ESTIMATOR OF ARCH IN THE NONSTATIONARY CASE

ASYMPTOTIC NORMALITY OF THE QMLE ESTIMATOR OF ARCH IN THE NONSTATIONARY CASE Econometrica, Vol. 7, No. March, 004), 4 4 ASYMPOIC NORMALIY OF HE QMLE ESIMAOR OF ARCH IN HE NONSAIONARY CASE BY SØREN OLVER JENSEN AND ANDERS RAHBEK We establish consistency and asymptotic normality

More information

Diagnostic Test for GARCH Models Based on Absolute Residual Autocorrelations

Diagnostic Test for GARCH Models Based on Absolute Residual Autocorrelations Diagnostic Test for GARCH Models Based on Absolute Residual Autocorrelations Farhat Iqbal Department of Statistics, University of Balochistan Quetta-Pakistan farhatiqb@gmail.com Abstract In this paper

More information

Asymptotic inference for a nonstationary double ar(1) model

Asymptotic inference for a nonstationary double ar(1) model Asymptotic inference for a nonstationary double ar() model By SHIQING LING and DONG LI Department of Mathematics, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Hong Kong maling@ust.hk malidong@ust.hk

More information

Vast Volatility Matrix Estimation for High Frequency Data

Vast Volatility Matrix Estimation for High Frequency Data Vast Volatility Matrix Estimation for High Frequency Data Yazhen Wang National Science Foundation Yale Workshop, May 14-17, 2009 Disclaimer: My opinion, not the views of NSF Y. Wang (at NSF) 1 / 36 Outline

More information

Least Squares Estimators for Stochastic Differential Equations Driven by Small Lévy Noises

Least Squares Estimators for Stochastic Differential Equations Driven by Small Lévy Noises Least Squares Estimators for Stochastic Differential Equations Driven by Small Lévy Noises Hongwei Long* Department of Mathematical Sciences, Florida Atlantic University, Boca Raton Florida 33431-991,

More information

A nonparametric method of multi-step ahead forecasting in diffusion processes

A nonparametric method of multi-step ahead forecasting in diffusion processes A nonparametric method of multi-step ahead forecasting in diffusion processes Mariko Yamamura a, Isao Shoji b a School of Pharmacy, Kitasato University, Minato-ku, Tokyo, 108-8641, Japan. b Graduate School

More information

FUNCTIONAL DATA ANALYSIS FOR VOLATILITY PROCESS

FUNCTIONAL DATA ANALYSIS FOR VOLATILITY PROCESS FUNCTIONAL DATA ANALYSIS FOR VOLATILITY PROCESS Rituparna Sen Monday, July 31 10:45am-12:30pm Classroom 228 St-C5 Financial Models Joint work with Hans-Georg Müller and Ulrich Stadtmüller 1. INTRODUCTION

More information

Closest Moment Estimation under General Conditions

Closest Moment Estimation under General Conditions Closest Moment Estimation under General Conditions Chirok Han and Robert de Jong January 28, 2002 Abstract This paper considers Closest Moment (CM) estimation with a general distance function, and avoids

More information

On the Statistical Equivalence at Suitable Frequencies of GARCH and Stochastic Volatility Models with the Corresponding Diffusion Model

On the Statistical Equivalence at Suitable Frequencies of GARCH and Stochastic Volatility Models with the Corresponding Diffusion Model On the Statistical Equivalence at Suitable Frequencies of GARCH and Stochastic Volatility Models with the Corresponding Diffusion Model Lawrence D. Brown University of Pennsylvania Yazhen Wang University

More information

Large Volatility Matrix Estimation with Factor-Based Diffusion Model for High-Frequency Financial data

Large Volatility Matrix Estimation with Factor-Based Diffusion Model for High-Frequency Financial data Submitted to Bernoulli Large Volatility Matrix Estimation with Factor-Based Diffusion Model for High-Frequency Financial data DONGGYU KIM *, YI LIU **, and YAZHEN WANG College of Business, Korea Advanced

More information

GARCH Models. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. December Rossi GARCH Financial Econometrics / 50

GARCH Models. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. December Rossi GARCH Financial Econometrics / 50 GARCH Models Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia December 013 Rossi GARCH Financial Econometrics - 013 1 / 50 Outline 1 Stylized Facts ARCH model: definition 3 GARCH model 4 EGARCH 5 Asymmetric Models 6

More information

Multivariate GARCH models.

Multivariate GARCH models. Multivariate GARCH models. Financial market volatility moves together over time across assets and markets. Recognizing this commonality through a multivariate modeling framework leads to obvious gains

More information

Realized Volatility, Covariance and Hedging Coefficient of the Nikkei-225 Futures with Micro-Market Noise

Realized Volatility, Covariance and Hedging Coefficient of the Nikkei-225 Futures with Micro-Market Noise CIRJE-F-601 Realized Volatility, Covariance and Hedging Coefficient of the Nikkei-225 Futures with Micro-Market Noise Naoto Kunitomo University of Tokyo Seisho Sato Institute of Statistical Mathematic

More information

GARCH( 1, 1) processes are near epoch dependent

GARCH( 1, 1) processes are near epoch dependent Economics Letters 36 (1991) 181-186 North-Holland 181 GARCH( 1, 1) processes are near epoch dependent Bruce E. Hansen 1Jnrrwsity of Rochester, Rochester, NY 14627, USA Keceived 22 October 1990 Accepted

More information

The Realized RSDC model

The Realized RSDC model The Realized RSDC model Denis Pelletier North Carolina State University and Aymard Kassi North Carolina State University Current version: March 25, 24 Incomplete and early draft. Abstract We introduce

More information

Discussion of Bootstrap prediction intervals for linear, nonlinear, and nonparametric autoregressions, by Li Pan and Dimitris Politis

Discussion of Bootstrap prediction intervals for linear, nonlinear, and nonparametric autoregressions, by Li Pan and Dimitris Politis Discussion of Bootstrap prediction intervals for linear, nonlinear, and nonparametric autoregressions, by Li Pan and Dimitris Politis Sílvia Gonçalves and Benoit Perron Département de sciences économiques,

More information

Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Time Series Models: A Score-Marked Empirical Process Approach

Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Time Series Models: A Score-Marked Empirical Process Approach Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Time Series Models: A Score-Marked Empirical Process Approach By Shiqing Ling Department of Mathematics Hong Kong University of Science and Technology Let {y t : t = 0, ±1, ±2,

More information

Volatility, Information Feedback and Market Microstructure Noise: A Tale of Two Regimes

Volatility, Information Feedback and Market Microstructure Noise: A Tale of Two Regimes Volatility, Information Feedback and Market Microstructure Noise: A Tale of Two Regimes Torben G. Andersen Northwestern University Gökhan Cebiroglu University of Vienna Nikolaus Hautsch University of Vienna

More information

Interval Estimation for AR(1) and GARCH(1,1) Models

Interval Estimation for AR(1) and GARCH(1,1) Models for AR(1) and GARCH(1,1) Models School of Mathematics Georgia Institute of Technology 2010 This talk is based on the following papers: Ngai Hang Chan, Deyuan Li and (2010). Toward a Unified of Autoregressions.

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES ISSN 1471-0498 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES FACTOR HIGH-FREQUENCY BASED VOLATILITY HEAVY MODELS Kevin Sheppard and Wen Xu Number 710 May 2014 Manor Road Building, Manor Road, Oxford

More information

I forgot to mention last time: in the Ito formula for two standard processes, putting

I forgot to mention last time: in the Ito formula for two standard processes, putting I forgot to mention last time: in the Ito formula for two standard processes, putting dx t = a t dt + b t db t dy t = α t dt + β t db t, and taking f(x, y = xy, one has f x = y, f y = x, and f xx = f yy

More information

LAN property for sde s with additive fractional noise and continuous time observation

LAN property for sde s with additive fractional noise and continuous time observation LAN property for sde s with additive fractional noise and continuous time observation Eulalia Nualart (Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona) joint work with Samy Tindel (Purdue University) Vlad s 6th birthday,

More information

Testing Jumps via False Discovery Rate Control

Testing Jumps via False Discovery Rate Control Testing Jumps via False Discovery Rate Control Yu-Min Yen August 12, 2011 Abstract Many recently developed nonparametric jump tests can be viewed as multiple hypothesis testing problems. For such multiple

More information

Generalized Autoregressive Score Models

Generalized Autoregressive Score Models Generalized Autoregressive Score Models by: Drew Creal, Siem Jan Koopman, André Lucas To capture the dynamic behavior of univariate and multivariate time series processes, we can allow parameters to be

More information

Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods

Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods Robert V. Breunig Centre for Economic Policy Research, Research School of Social Sciences and School of

More information

13. Estimation and Extensions in the ARCH model. MA6622, Ernesto Mordecki, CityU, HK, References for this Lecture:

13. Estimation and Extensions in the ARCH model. MA6622, Ernesto Mordecki, CityU, HK, References for this Lecture: 13. Estimation and Extensions in the ARCH model MA6622, Ernesto Mordecki, CityU, HK, 2006. References for this Lecture: Robert F. Engle. GARCH 101: The Use of ARCH/GARCH Models in Applied Econometrics,

More information

GARCH Models Estimation and Inference

GARCH Models Estimation and Inference GARCH Models Estimation and Inference Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia December 013 Rossi GARCH Financial Econometrics - 013 1 / 1 Likelihood function The procedure most often used in estimating θ 0 in

More information

UC San Diego Recent Work

UC San Diego Recent Work UC San Diego Recent Work Title The Variance of Sample Autocorrelations: Does Barlett's Formula Work With ARCH Data? Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/68c247dp Authors Kokoszka, Piotr S. Politis,

More information

Analytical derivates of the APARCH model

Analytical derivates of the APARCH model Analytical derivates of the APARCH model Sébastien Laurent Forthcoming in Computational Economics October 24, 2003 Abstract his paper derives analytical expressions for the score of the APARCH model of

More information

Parameter Estimation for ARCH(1) Models Based on Kalman Filter

Parameter Estimation for ARCH(1) Models Based on Kalman Filter Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 8, 2014, no. 56, 2783-2791 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/10.12988/ams.2014.43164 Parameter Estimation for ARCH(1) Models Based on Kalman Filter Jelloul

More information

On detection of unit roots generalizing the classic Dickey-Fuller approach

On detection of unit roots generalizing the classic Dickey-Fuller approach On detection of unit roots generalizing the classic Dickey-Fuller approach A. Steland Ruhr-Universität Bochum Fakultät für Mathematik Building NA 3/71 D-4478 Bochum, Germany February 18, 25 1 Abstract

More information

Volatility. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University

Volatility. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University Volatility Gerald P. Dwyer Clemson University February 2016 Outline 1 Volatility Characteristics of Time Series Heteroskedasticity Simpler Estimation Strategies Exponentially Weighted Moving Average Use

More information

VAST VOLATILITY MATRIX ESTIMATION FOR HIGH-FREQUENCY FINANCIAL DATA

VAST VOLATILITY MATRIX ESTIMATION FOR HIGH-FREQUENCY FINANCIAL DATA The Annals of Statistics 2010, Vol. 38, No. 2, 943 978 DOI: 10.1214/09-AOS730 Institute of Mathematical Statistics, 2010 VAST VOLATILITY MATRIX ESTIMATION FOR HIGH-FREQUENCY FINANCIAL DATA BY YAZHEN WANG

More information

LAN property for ergodic jump-diffusion processes with discrete observations

LAN property for ergodic jump-diffusion processes with discrete observations LAN property for ergodic jump-diffusion processes with discrete observations Eulalia Nualart (Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona) joint work with Arturo Kohatsu-Higa (Ritsumeikan University, Japan) &

More information

A Modified Fractionally Co-integrated VAR for Predicting Returns

A Modified Fractionally Co-integrated VAR for Predicting Returns A Modified Fractionally Co-integrated VAR for Predicting Returns Xingzhi Yao Marwan Izzeldin Department of Economics, Lancaster University 13 December 215 Yao & Izzeldin (Lancaster University) CFE (215)

More information

Continuous Time Approximations to GARCH(1, 1)-Family Models and Their Limiting Properties

Continuous Time Approximations to GARCH(1, 1)-Family Models and Their Limiting Properties Communications for Statistical Applications and Methods 214, Vol. 21, No. 4, 327 334 DOI: http://dx.doi.org/1.5351/csam.214.21.4.327 Print ISSN 2287-7843 / Online ISSN 2383-4757 Continuous Time Approximations

More information

Empirical properties of large covariance matrices in finance

Empirical properties of large covariance matrices in finance Empirical properties of large covariance matrices in finance Ex: RiskMetrics Group, Geneva Since 2010: Swissquote, Gland December 2009 Covariance and large random matrices Many problems in finance require

More information

GARCH processes continuous counterparts (Part 2)

GARCH processes continuous counterparts (Part 2) GARCH processes continuous counterparts (Part 2) Alexander Lindner Centre of Mathematical Sciences Technical University of Munich D 85747 Garching Germany lindner@ma.tum.de http://www-m1.ma.tum.de/m4/pers/lindner/

More information

Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics & Econometrics

Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics & Econometrics Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics & Econometrics Volume 9, Issue 2 2005 Article 4 A Note on the Hiemstra-Jones Test for Granger Non-causality Cees Diks Valentyn Panchenko University of Amsterdam, C.G.H.Diks@uva.nl

More information

Lecture 6: Univariate Volatility Modelling: ARCH and GARCH Models

Lecture 6: Univariate Volatility Modelling: ARCH and GARCH Models Lecture 6: Univariate Volatility Modelling: ARCH and GARCH Models Prof. Massimo Guidolin 019 Financial Econometrics Winter/Spring 018 Overview ARCH models and their limitations Generalized ARCH models

More information

Econ 623 Econometrics II Topic 2: Stationary Time Series

Econ 623 Econometrics II Topic 2: Stationary Time Series 1 Introduction Econ 623 Econometrics II Topic 2: Stationary Time Series In the regression model we can model the error term as an autoregression AR(1) process. That is, we can use the past value of the

More information

Determining and Forecasting High-Frequency Value-at-Risk by Using Lévy Processes

Determining and Forecasting High-Frequency Value-at-Risk by Using Lévy Processes Determining and Forecasting High-Frequency Value-at-Risk by Using Lévy Processes W ei Sun 1, Svetlozar Rachev 1,2, F rank J. F abozzi 3 1 Institute of Statistics and Mathematical Economics, University

More information

Asymptotic Nonequivalence of Nonparametric Experiments When the Smoothness Index is ½

Asymptotic Nonequivalence of Nonparametric Experiments When the Smoothness Index is ½ University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Statistics Papers Wharton Faculty Research 1998 Asymptotic Nonequivalence of Nonparametric Experiments When the Smoothness Index is ½ Lawrence D. Brown University

More information

GARCH Models Estimation and Inference

GARCH Models Estimation and Inference Università di Pavia GARCH Models Estimation and Inference Eduardo Rossi Likelihood function The procedure most often used in estimating θ 0 in ARCH models involves the maximization of a likelihood function

More information

Pathwise volatility in a long-memory pricing model: estimation and asymptotic behavior

Pathwise volatility in a long-memory pricing model: estimation and asymptotic behavior Pathwise volatility in a long-memory pricing model: estimation and asymptotic behavior Ehsan Azmoodeh University of Vaasa Finland 7th General AMaMeF and Swissquote Conference September 7 1, 215 Outline

More information

Closest Moment Estimation under General Conditions

Closest Moment Estimation under General Conditions Closest Moment Estimation under General Conditions Chirok Han Victoria University of Wellington New Zealand Robert de Jong Ohio State University U.S.A October, 2003 Abstract This paper considers Closest

More information

Common Dynamics in Volatility: a Composite vmem Approach

Common Dynamics in Volatility: a Composite vmem Approach Common Dynamics in Volatility: a Composite vmem Approach Fabrizio Cipollini Giampiero M. Gallo Preliminary and incomplete draft Measuring and Modeling Risk with High Frequency Data SITE Stanford U. 20-2/06/20

More information

Estimating GARCH models: when to use what?

Estimating GARCH models: when to use what? Econometrics Journal (2008), volume, pp. 27 38. doi: 0./j.368-423X.2008.00229.x Estimating GARCH models: when to use what? DA HUANG, HANSHENG WANG AND QIWEI YAO, Guanghua School of Management, Peking University,

More information

July 31, 2009 / Ben Kedem Symposium

July 31, 2009 / Ben Kedem Symposium ing The s ing The Department of Statistics North Carolina State University July 31, 2009 / Ben Kedem Symposium Outline ing The s 1 2 s 3 4 5 Ben Kedem ing The s Ben has made many contributions to time

More information

α i ξ t i, where ξ t i.i.d. (0, 1),

α i ξ t i, where ξ t i.i.d. (0, 1), PROBABILITY AND MATHEMATICAL STATISTICS Vol. 31, Fasc. 1 (2011), pp. 300 000 NONLINEARITY OF ARCH AND STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY MODELS AND BARTLETT S FORMULA BY PIOTR S. KO KO S Z K A (LOGAN) AND DIMITRIS

More information

Testing Monotonicity of Pricing Kernels

Testing Monotonicity of Pricing Kernels Yuri Golubev Wolfgang Härdle Roman Timofeev C.A.S.E. Center for Applied Statistics and Economics Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin 12 1 8 6 4 2 2 4 25 2 15 1 5 5 1 15 2 25 Motivation 2-2 Motivation An investor

More information

GARCH processes probabilistic properties (Part 1)

GARCH processes probabilistic properties (Part 1) GARCH processes probabilistic properties (Part 1) Alexander Lindner Centre of Mathematical Sciences Technical University of Munich D 85747 Garching Germany lindner@ma.tum.de http://www-m1.ma.tum.de/m4/pers/lindner/

More information

Consistency of Quasi-Maximum Likelihood Estimators for the Regime-Switching GARCH Models

Consistency of Quasi-Maximum Likelihood Estimators for the Regime-Switching GARCH Models Consistency of Quasi-Maximum Likelihood Estimators for the Regime-Switching GARCH Models Yingfu Xie Research Report Centre of Biostochastics Swedish University of Report 2005:3 Agricultural Sciences ISSN

More information

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1 Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1 John C. Chao April 25, 2017 1 These notes are based in large part on Chapter 16 of Stock and Watson (2011). They are for instructional purposes

More information

Stochastic Calculus. Kevin Sinclair. August 2, 2016

Stochastic Calculus. Kevin Sinclair. August 2, 2016 Stochastic Calculus Kevin Sinclair August, 16 1 Background Suppose we have a Brownian motion W. This is a process, and the value of W at a particular time T (which we write W T ) is a normally distributed

More information

Accounting for Missing Values in Score- Driven Time-Varying Parameter Models

Accounting for Missing Values in Score- Driven Time-Varying Parameter Models TI 2016-067/IV Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper Accounting for Missing Values in Score- Driven Time-Varying Parameter Models André Lucas Anne Opschoor Julia Schaumburg Faculty of Economics and Business

More information

Backward martingale representation and endogenous completeness in finance

Backward martingale representation and endogenous completeness in finance Backward martingale representation and endogenous completeness in finance Dmitry Kramkov (with Silviu Predoiu) Carnegie Mellon University 1 / 19 Bibliography Robert M. Anderson and Roberto C. Raimondo.

More information

Nonparametric regression with martingale increment errors

Nonparametric regression with martingale increment errors S. Gaïffas (LSTA - Paris 6) joint work with S. Delattre (LPMA - Paris 7) work in progress Motivations Some facts: Theoretical study of statistical algorithms requires stationary and ergodicity. Concentration

More information

Shape of the return probability density function and extreme value statistics

Shape of the return probability density function and extreme value statistics Shape of the return probability density function and extreme value statistics 13/09/03 Int. Workshop on Risk and Regulation, Budapest Overview I aim to elucidate a relation between one field of research

More information

ECONOMICS 7200 MODERN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Econometric Theory and Applications

ECONOMICS 7200 MODERN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Econometric Theory and Applications ECONOMICS 7200 MODERN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Econometric Theory and Applications Yongmiao Hong Department of Economics & Department of Statistical Sciences Cornell University Spring 2019 Time and uncertainty

More information

Bayesian Inference for DSGE Models. Lawrence J. Christiano

Bayesian Inference for DSGE Models. Lawrence J. Christiano Bayesian Inference for DSGE Models Lawrence J. Christiano Outline State space-observer form. convenient for model estimation and many other things. Preliminaries. Probabilities. Maximum Likelihood. Bayesian

More information

only through simulation studies rather than through mathematical analysis. In a few instances, we discuss small sample refinements such as small

only through simulation studies rather than through mathematical analysis. In a few instances, we discuss small sample refinements such as small Over the past fifteen years or so, the domain of statistical and econometric methods for high-frequency financial data has been experiencing an exponential growth, due to the development of new mathematical

More information

Duration-Based Volatility Estimation

Duration-Based Volatility Estimation A Dual Approach to RV Torben G. Andersen, Northwestern University Dobrislav Dobrev, Federal Reserve Board of Governors Ernst Schaumburg, Northwestern Univeristy CHICAGO-ARGONNE INSTITUTE ON COMPUTATIONAL

More information

Generalized Method of Moments Estimation

Generalized Method of Moments Estimation Generalized Method of Moments Estimation Lars Peter Hansen March 0, 2007 Introduction Generalized methods of moments (GMM) refers to a class of estimators which are constructed from exploiting the sample

More information

Jump-type Levy Processes

Jump-type Levy Processes Jump-type Levy Processes Ernst Eberlein Handbook of Financial Time Series Outline Table of contents Probabilistic Structure of Levy Processes Levy process Levy-Ito decomposition Jump part Probabilistic

More information

Nonparametric Drift Estimation for Stochastic Differential Equations

Nonparametric Drift Estimation for Stochastic Differential Equations Nonparametric Drift Estimation for Stochastic Differential Equations Gareth Roberts 1 Department of Statistics University of Warwick Brazilian Bayesian meeting, March 2010 Joint work with O. Papaspiliopoulos,

More information

High-dimensional Minimum Variance Portfolio Estimation Based on High-frequency Data

High-dimensional Minimum Variance Portfolio Estimation Based on High-frequency Data High-dimensional Minimum Variance Portfolio Estimation Based on High-frequency Data Tony Cai Department of Statistics University of Pennsylvania Yingying Li Department of ISOM & Department of Finance HKUST

More information

Bayesian Semiparametric GARCH Models

Bayesian Semiparametric GARCH Models Bayesian Semiparametric GARCH Models Xibin (Bill) Zhang and Maxwell L. King Department of Econometrics and Business Statistics Faculty of Business and Economics xibin.zhang@monash.edu Quantitative Methods

More information

Lecture 4: Introduction to stochastic processes and stochastic calculus

Lecture 4: Introduction to stochastic processes and stochastic calculus Lecture 4: Introduction to stochastic processes and stochastic calculus Cédric Archambeau Centre for Computational Statistics and Machine Learning Department of Computer Science University College London

More information

Bayesian Semiparametric GARCH Models

Bayesian Semiparametric GARCH Models Bayesian Semiparametric GARCH Models Xibin (Bill) Zhang and Maxwell L. King Department of Econometrics and Business Statistics Faculty of Business and Economics xibin.zhang@monash.edu Quantitative Methods

More information

Online Appendix. j=1. φ T (ω j ) vec (EI T (ω j ) f θ0 (ω j )). vec (EI T (ω) f θ0 (ω)) = O T β+1/2) = o(1), M 1. M T (s) exp ( isω)

Online Appendix. j=1. φ T (ω j ) vec (EI T (ω j ) f θ0 (ω j )). vec (EI T (ω) f θ0 (ω)) = O T β+1/2) = o(1), M 1. M T (s) exp ( isω) Online Appendix Proof of Lemma A.. he proof uses similar arguments as in Dunsmuir 979), but allowing for weak identification and selecting a subset of frequencies using W ω). It consists of two steps.

More information

Bayesian Inference for DSGE Models. Lawrence J. Christiano

Bayesian Inference for DSGE Models. Lawrence J. Christiano Bayesian Inference for DSGE Models Lawrence J. Christiano Outline State space-observer form. convenient for model estimation and many other things. Bayesian inference Bayes rule. Monte Carlo integation.

More information

Lasso Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Parametric Models with Singular Information Matrices

Lasso Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Parametric Models with Singular Information Matrices Article Lasso Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Parametric Models with Singular Information Matrices Fei Jin 1,2 and Lung-fei Lee 3, * 1 School of Economics, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics,

More information

Optimal Weights in Prediction Error and Weighted Least Squares Methods

Optimal Weights in Prediction Error and Weighted Least Squares Methods Optimal Weights in Prediction Error and Weighted Least Squares Methods Kim Nolsøe, Jan Nygaard Nielsen, and Henrik Madsen May, 000 Abstract In this paper an expression for the bias implied by prediction

More information

State-space Model. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. November Rossi State-space Model Fin. Econometrics / 53

State-space Model. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. November Rossi State-space Model Fin. Econometrics / 53 State-space Model Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia November 2014 Rossi State-space Model Fin. Econometrics - 2014 1 / 53 Outline 1 Motivation 2 Introduction 3 The Kalman filter 4 Forecast errors 5 State

More information

Empirical likelihood and self-weighting approach for hypothesis testing of infinite variance processes and its applications

Empirical likelihood and self-weighting approach for hypothesis testing of infinite variance processes and its applications Empirical likelihood and self-weighting approach for hypothesis testing of infinite variance processes and its applications Fumiya Akashi Research Associate Department of Applied Mathematics Waseda University

More information

The properties of L p -GMM estimators

The properties of L p -GMM estimators The properties of L p -GMM estimators Robert de Jong and Chirok Han Michigan State University February 2000 Abstract This paper considers Generalized Method of Moment-type estimators for which a criterion

More information

Affine Processes. Econometric specifications. Eduardo Rossi. University of Pavia. March 17, 2009

Affine Processes. Econometric specifications. Eduardo Rossi. University of Pavia. March 17, 2009 Affine Processes Econometric specifications Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia March 17, 2009 Eduardo Rossi (University of Pavia) Affine Processes March 17, 2009 1 / 40 Outline 1 Affine Processes 2 Affine

More information

Understanding Regressions with Observations Collected at High Frequency over Long Span

Understanding Regressions with Observations Collected at High Frequency over Long Span Understanding Regressions with Observations Collected at High Frequency over Long Span Yoosoon Chang Department of Economics, Indiana University Joon Y. Park Department of Economics, Indiana University

More information

Some functional (Hölderian) limit theorems and their applications (II)

Some functional (Hölderian) limit theorems and their applications (II) Some functional (Hölderian) limit theorems and their applications (II) Alfredas Račkauskas Vilnius University Outils Statistiques et Probabilistes pour la Finance Université de Rouen June 1 5, Rouen (Rouen

More information

Limit theorems for multipower variation in the presence of jumps

Limit theorems for multipower variation in the presence of jumps Limit theorems for multipower variation in the presence of jumps Ole E. Barndorff-Nielsen Department of Mathematical Sciences, University of Aarhus, Ny Munkegade, DK-8 Aarhus C, Denmark oebn@imf.au.dk

More information

A Specification Test for Time Series Models by a Normality Transformation

A Specification Test for Time Series Models by a Normality Transformation A Specification Test for Time Series Models by a Normality Transformation Jin-Chuan Duan (First Draft: May 2003 (This Draft: Oct 2003 Abstract A correctly specified time series model can be used to transform

More information

Chapter 2. Some basic tools. 2.1 Time series: Theory Stochastic processes

Chapter 2. Some basic tools. 2.1 Time series: Theory Stochastic processes Chapter 2 Some basic tools 2.1 Time series: Theory 2.1.1 Stochastic processes A stochastic process is a sequence of random variables..., x 0, x 1, x 2,.... In this class, the subscript always means time.

More information

Nonlinear Parameter Estimation for State-Space ARCH Models with Missing Observations

Nonlinear Parameter Estimation for State-Space ARCH Models with Missing Observations Nonlinear Parameter Estimation for State-Space ARCH Models with Missing Observations SEBASTIÁN OSSANDÓN Pontificia Universidad Católica de Valparaíso Instituto de Matemáticas Blanco Viel 596, Cerro Barón,

More information

Inference in VARs with Conditional Heteroskedasticity of Unknown Form

Inference in VARs with Conditional Heteroskedasticity of Unknown Form Inference in VARs with Conditional Heteroskedasticity of Unknown Form Ralf Brüggemann a Carsten Jentsch b Carsten Trenkler c University of Konstanz University of Mannheim University of Mannheim IAB Nuremberg

More information

GARCH Models Estimation and Inference. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia

GARCH Models Estimation and Inference. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia GARCH Models Estimation and Inference Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia Likelihood function The procedure most often used in estimating θ 0 in ARCH models involves the maximization of a likelihood function

More information

Properties of Estimates of Daily GARCH Parameters. Based on Intra-day Observations. John W. Galbraith and Victoria Zinde-Walsh

Properties of Estimates of Daily GARCH Parameters. Based on Intra-day Observations. John W. Galbraith and Victoria Zinde-Walsh 3.. Properties of Estimates of Daily GARCH Parameters Based on Intra-day Observations John W. Galbraith and Victoria Zinde-Walsh Department of Economics McGill University 855 Sherbrooke St. West Montreal,

More information

STAT 512 sp 2018 Summary Sheet

STAT 512 sp 2018 Summary Sheet STAT 5 sp 08 Summary Sheet Karl B. Gregory Spring 08. Transformations of a random variable Let X be a rv with support X and let g be a function mapping X to Y with inverse mapping g (A = {x X : g(x A}

More information

Statistical Inference for Ergodic Point Processes and Applications to Limit Order Book

Statistical Inference for Ergodic Point Processes and Applications to Limit Order Book Statistical Inference for Ergodic Point Processes and Applications to Limit Order Book Simon Clinet PhD student under the supervision of Pr. Nakahiro Yoshida Graduate School of Mathematical Sciences, University

More information

Simulation and Parametric Estimation of SDEs

Simulation and Parametric Estimation of SDEs Simulation and Parametric Estimation of SDEs Jhonny Gonzalez School of Mathematics The University of Manchester Magical books project August 23, 2012 Motivation The problem Simulation of SDEs SDEs driven

More information

THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO ESTIMATING THE INTEGRATED PARAMETER OF THE LOCALLY PARAMETRIC MODEL IN HIGH-FREQUENCY DATA A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED TO

THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO ESTIMATING THE INTEGRATED PARAMETER OF THE LOCALLY PARAMETRIC MODEL IN HIGH-FREQUENCY DATA A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED TO THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO ESTIMATING THE INTEGRATED PARAMETER OF THE LOCALLY PARAMETRIC MODEL IN HIGH-FREQUENCY DATA A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED TO THE FACULTY OF THE DIVISION OF THE PHYSICAL SCIENCES IN

More information

The Functional Central Limit Theorem and Testing for Time Varying Parameters

The Functional Central Limit Theorem and Testing for Time Varying Parameters NBER Summer Institute Minicourse What s New in Econometrics: ime Series Lecture : July 4, 008 he Functional Central Limit heorem and esting for ime Varying Parameters Lecture -, July, 008 Outline. FCL.

More information

Consistency of the maximum likelihood estimator for general hidden Markov models

Consistency of the maximum likelihood estimator for general hidden Markov models Consistency of the maximum likelihood estimator for general hidden Markov models Jimmy Olsson Centre for Mathematical Sciences Lund University Nordstat 2012 Umeå, Sweden Collaborators Hidden Markov models

More information