Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations"

Transcription

1 Math Finan Econ 8) :3 49 DOI.7/s Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations H. Föllmer W. Schachermayer Received: 3 May 7 / Accepted: April 8 / Published online: May 8 Springer-Verlag 8 Abstract ypical models of mathematical finance admit equivalent martingale measures up to any finite time horizon but not globally, and this means that arbitrage opportunities arise in the long run. In this paper, we derive explicit estimates for asymptotic arbitrage, and we show how they are related to large deviation estimates for the market price of risk. As a case study we consider a geometric Ornstein Uhlenbeck process. In this setting we also compute the optimal trading strategies and the resulting optimal growth rates of expected utility for all HARA utilities. Keywords Asymptotic arbitrage Utility maximization Large deviations Cost averaging JEL Classification G G C6 Introduction In this paper, we investigate the issue of optimizing terminal wealth by investing in a financial market, when the time horizon tends to infinity. We focus on the following issues: i) A better understanding of the features of the financial market S t ) t which insure exponential growth of the terminal wealth X of an investor in this market, for. W. Schachermayer gratefully acknowledges Financial support from the Austrian Science Fund FWF) under the grant P9456, from Vienna Science and echnology Fund WWF) under Grant MA3 and by the Christian Doppler Research Association CDG). H. Föllmer Institut für Mathematik, Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin, Unter den Linden 6, 99 Berlin, Germany W. Schachermayer B) Vienna University of echnology, Wiedner Hauptstrasse 8-/5, 4 Wien, Austria wschach@fam.tuwien.ac.at 3

2 4 H. Föllmer, W. Schachermayer ii) iii) Relating this question to the notion of asymptotic arbitrage, to the theory of large deviations, and to utility maximization with respect to the power utilities Ux) = xα α, for α ], [. Analyzing carefully the case study of a geometric Ornstein Uhlenbeck process and comparing it to the well-known situation of the Black Scholes model by explicitly calculating the optimal strategies for HARA-utility optimizers. We consider an R d -valued semi-martingale S = S t ) t modeling the price process of d risky assets with infinite horizon. he bond is assumed to be normalized by B t, i.e., we consider S in discounted terms. For a fixed finite horizon,let K ={H S) H H}, denote the set of attainable contingent claims, where H denotes the class of predictable, S-integrable, admissible processes for a definition see e.g. [7, Definition 8.., p. 3]). We recall the notion of strong asymptotic arbitrage as introduced by Kabanov and Kramkov [9] which we specialize to the present situation of a varying time horizon. Definition. he process S = S t ) t allows for strong asymptotic arbitrage if, for ε>, there is < and X K satisfying i) X ε, a.s., and ii) P[X ε ] ε. he economic interpretation is straightforward: condition i) means that the maximal loss of the trading strategy, yielding the wealth X at time, is bounded by ε; condition ii) means that with probability ε the terminal wealth X equals at least ε. In [9] a dual characterization of this concept was given in terms of the Hellinger distance of the equivalent martingale measures for the process S t ) t to the original measure P compare also []). In Proposition.we take up this theme again and relate these Hellinger distances to utility maximization for power utility Ux) = xα α,whereα ], [. For the sake of clarity of exposition we shall focus on the setting of diffusions driven by Brownian motion; we note however, that many of the results below could be extended to more general situations. Let, F,F t ) t, P) be a filtered probability space such that F t ) t is the right continuous, saturated) filtration generated by an R N -valued standard Brownian motion W t ) t. Assumption. he process S = S t ) t will be assumed to be an R d -valued diffusion based on, F,F t ) t, P) such that there is a deterministic, time-independent) volatility function as well as a market price of risk function such that σ : R d R d N ) ϕ : R d R N ) ds t = σs t )dw t + ϕs t )dt), 3) where we may and do suppose that ϕs t ) takes its values in kerσ S t )). 3

3 Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations 5 We also assume that Z min t = exp t ϕ u, dw u ) t ϕ u du 4) is a strictly positive martingale, where we put ϕ u = ϕs u ) and where.,.)and. denote the inner product and the corresponding Euclidean norm on R N. We then deduce from Girsanov s formula that, for each, the measure Q min on F defined by dq min dp = Z min is a probability measure equivalent to the restriction of P to F such that S t ) t is a local martingale under Q min. Following [5] we call Qmin the minimal martingale measure for S t ) t. It seems worthwile to comment on the above concepts. Suppose for simplicity that ϕ and σ are constant. If the d N matrix σ is injective, then the law of the process S in 3) uniquely determines the vector ϕ R N ; this corresponds to the case of a complete market. On the other hand, in the incomplete case, i.e. for a non-injective matrix σ, the vector ϕ is only determined by the process S in 3) up to adding elements in the kernel of σ. here is one canonical choice of ϕ, namely the one orthogonal to kerσ ). he fact that this choice of ϕ has minimal norm in R N motivates the name minimal above. A central question of our present investigation will be to understand which features of the above model imply that there is exponential growth of a well chosen attainable portfolio as the time horizon goes to. It is obvious that one has to impose some assumption on the market price of risk. Indeed, if ϕ vanishes then the process S t ) t is a local martingale, and one cannot systematically win by betting on a local martingale in an admissible way. Definition.3 Under the above assumptions we say that the diffusion process S = S t ) t has an average squared market price of risk above the threshold c > if the process ϕ t ) t satisfies the following estimate: P ϕ t dt < c =. 5) If there is c > such that 5) holds true we say that S has a non-trivial market price of risk. We say that the market price of risk satisfies a large deviations estimate if there are constants c, c > such that sup log P ϕ t dt c < c. 6) he economic interpretation of 5) is that the market price of risk should on average be bounded away from zero in the long run. his assumption is satisfied whenever the diffusion is ergodic with invariant measure µ and if the market price of risk function ϕ is not µ-a.s. equal to, since ergodicity implies ϕ t dt = R d ϕx) µdx) P-a.s. 3

4 6 H. Föllmer, W. Schachermayer As explained in Sect. 3, the large deviations estimate 6) for the market price of risk follows by a contraction principle whenever the diffusion process S t ) t is ergodic and satisfies a principle of large deviations. We refer to the large deviations literature for suitable conditions; see, e.g., [8]. For the Black Scholes model the market price of risk is constant, and so the large deviations estimate 6) is trivially satisfied if the market price of risk is assumed to be different from zero. Less trivial is the example of the geometric Ornstein Uhlenbeck process which will be analyzed in Sects. 4 and 5, using large deviations results from [4,8]); see also [3]. In this example the large deviations estimate 6) holds true, and the optimal pairs c, c ) can be calculated explicitly. Assumption 5) is of course weaker than 6), but it is sufficient to deduce the following estimates which will be proved in Sect. 3. heorem.4 Let S = S t ) t be a process satisfying Assumption. and having an average squared market price of risk above the threshold c > ; cf.5). For ε>, γ + γ < c/, and for large enough, there exists X K such that i) X e γ, ii) P [ X e γ ] ε. he message of the theorem is that the assumption of a non-trivial market price of risk 5) implies asymptotic arbitrage; in fact we obtain exponential estimates for the maximal loss in i) as well as for the typical growth in ii). If Assumption 5) is replaced by the stronger large deviation estimate 6), one should even expect an exponential decay in time for the probability of falling short of the exponential lower bound in assertion ii) above. his will be discussed in Sect. 3. In Sect. 4 we illustrate the situation for the geometric Ornstein Uhlenbeck process defined by S t = expy t ), 7) where Y t ) t denotes an Ornstein Uhlenbeck process defined by dy t = ρy t dt + σ dw t, Y = y, 8) for constants σ>, ρ>, and y R. Here the market price of risk ϕ t = ϕs t ) is given by ϕ t = ρ σ Y t + σ see 4)), and we obtain the subsequent explicit results: heorem.5 Let S t ) t be a geometric ] Ornstein Uhlenbeck [ process as in 7). For any γ,γ,γ R such that γ + γ <γ, σ 8 + ρ 4, there exist attainable contingent claims X K such that i) X e γ, ii) log P [ X < e γ ] ) = σ 8 γ + ρ 4. σ 8 γ + ρ In fact we are going to prove a stronger version, with sharper bounds in i) and a corresponding optimality result for the rate of convergence in ii); cf. heorem 4. and Remark 4.3. Remark 4.4 describes the extension to an Ornstein Uhlenbeck process with drift. A corresponding result for the Black Scholes model is given in heorem

5 Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations 7 How are these results, which ensure asymptotic arbitrage in a rather strong sense, related to the theme of utility maximization? For the case of logarithmic utility, heorem.4 easily implies a lower bound for the attainable expected utility per unit time; see Proposition 3.. In fact, there is a deeper connection of the results on asymptotic arbitrage and utility maximization. In Proposition.3 we give rather sharp estimates between asymptotic arbitrage and utility maximization with respect to the power utilities Ux) = xα α,whereα ranges in ], [. his result is interesting in its own right and also allows for a better understanding of the duality theory of asymptotic arbitrage [9,]. In Sect. 5 we continue our case study of the geometric Ornstein Uhlenbeck process and calculate explicitly the optimal trading strategies and the resulting expected utility u x) for all > and all HARA-utilities. As a corollary we obtain the optimal growth rates for u x). In the case of power utility, this may be viewed as a probabilistic complement to the dynamic programming approach in Fleming and Sheu [3], as explained in Remark 5.8. While for logarithmic utility there are no surprises and our findings are similar to the wellknown results of R. Merton in the case of the Black Scholes model [6,7], we find some counter-intuitive results in the case of power utility Ux) = xα α,forα ], [ \{}, and of exponential utility Ux) = exp λx). Asymptotic arbitrage and power utility We start with an easy but surprisingly sharp dual characterization of the notion of asymptotic arbitrage. In this proposition we take the horizon as fixed. Proposition. Let S = S t ) t be an R d -valued locally bounded semi-martingale such that M e S) ={Q P SisalocalQ-martingale} =. For >ε,ε > the statements a) and b) are equivalent: a) here is X K such that i) X ε, ii) P[X ε ] ε. b) here is A F with P[A ] ε such that, for each Q M e S) we have Q[A ] ε. In this case we say that S admits an ε,ε )-arbitrage up to time ). Proof a) b): Let A ={X < ε } so that P[A ] ε,andtakeq M e S). Since X K implies E Q [X ] see, e.g., [5, heorem 5.7]), we may estimate ε )Q[ \A ] ε Q[A ] E Q [X ], hence Q[A ] ε. b) a): If A satisfies the assumptions of b) then X = ε A + ε ) \A has properties i) and ii) and satisfies E Q [X ] for each Q M e S). Applying again the superhedging theorem [5, heorem 5.7] we see that X is dominated by an element X K,and X clearly inherits properties i) and ii). 3

6 8 H. Föllmer, W. Schachermayer We remark that the assumption of local boundedness is not really relevant in the present context. It could be dropped by replacing the concept of local martingales by the concept of sigma-martingales see [6]). In the next result we relate strong asymptotic arbitrage with dynamic portfolio optimisation for a certain class of utility functions which includes the power utilities Ux) = xα α for <α<astypical examples. Proposition. Let S = S t ) t be an R d -valued locally bounded semi-martingale such that, for each >, thesetm e S) is not empty. Let U : R + R be a strictly increasing concave function such that Ux) =, x Ux) =. x he following assertions are equivalent: a) b) S t ) t allows for strong asymptotic arbitrage. Defining the value function we have u x) = sup E[Ux + X )], X K u x) =, for some x > or, equivalently, for all x > ). Proof a) b): Given x >, let < ε < x.ifx Definition. we get K satisfies i) and ii) of u x) E[Ux + X )] x ) U P[X <ε ]+Uε )P[X ε ] x ) εu + Uε ). Since the latter expression tends to zero as ε, we obtain u x) =. b) a): Suppose that there is x > such that u x) =. hus we may find X K such that X x and E[Ux + X )] =. ake ε>. Applying schebyscheff s inequality in the form we obtain ε > such that P[X < xε ]=P[ Ux + X ) > Ux + xε ) ] Ux + xε )] E[Ux + X )], P[X xε ] ε for ε.sincex x we conclude that εx /x satisfies the requirements of Definition.. 3

7 Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations 9 he preceding result is of a purely qualitative nature. Since we also want to obtain quantitative results on the speed of convergence, we now specialize to the case of power utility U α) x) = xα α, In this case the conjugate function <α<. is given by V y) = sup[u α) x) xy], y >, x> α V y) = V β) y) = yβ β where β = α ], [. As usual in utility optimization we write for the primal and dual value functions [4] u α) x) = sup E[U α) x + X )], x >, X K [ )] v β) y) = inf E V β) y dq Q M e S) dp, y >. We obtain from the scaling property of the power function that we have u α) x) = c U α) x), for some c, as well as v β) y) = c V β) y), wherec = c α + compare [4]). he following proposition is similar to the results in [9] in terms of the concept of Hellinger distance, but there it is not connected with the idea of utility maximization. Again the horizon will be fixed. Proposition.3 Let <α<, β = α α, and an Rd -valued semi-martingale S = S t ) t as in Proposition. be given. For ε, ε,ε > consider the following statements. i) S admits an ε,ε )-arbitrage. i ) here is A F, P[A] ε, such that, for each Q M e S) we have Q[A] ε. ii) For each Q M e S) there is A F, such that P[A] ε and Q[A] ε. iii) u α) x) εu α) x), for some or, equivalently, for all) x >. iii ) v β) y) ε α + V β) y), for some or, equivalently, for all) y >. hen the following assertions hold true: a) b) c) d) i) i ) and iii) iii ). i ) ii). he reverse implication ii) i ) holds true if M e S) ={Q} is a singleton complete financial market). ii) iii) if ε + α maxε,ε α ). iii) i) if ε ε ε α. Proof a) follows from Proposition. and the discussion preceding Proposition.3, while b) is obvious. c): Fix Q M e S) and the corresponding set A F satisfying P[A] ε and Q[A] ε as in ii). By possibly passing to smaller values of ε,ε, we may suppose 3

8 H. Föllmer, W. Schachermayer that P[A] =ε and Q[A] = ε. In view of a) it is enough to verify iii ). By Jensen we obtain [ )] E V β) dq dp = [ ) ] β β E dq dp [ ) Q[A] β ) ] Q[ \ A] β β E A + \A P[A] [ ε β ε ) β + ε ) β ε β = β ) β max ε β,ε β. As this inequality holds true for all Q M e S) we obtain ) v β) ) max ε β,ε β V β) ). Using that α + = α = β we conclude from the assumption ) ε α + max α + α α + ε,ε ) = max ε β,ε β P[ \ A] ] v β) ) ε α + V β) ), which yields iii ). d): Let ε, ε,ε satisfy ε<ε ε α. By assumption iii) there is X K such that E[U α) ε + X )] εu α) ε ) = ε εα α. Clearly X ε a.s. In order to verify i) it remains to show that P[X ε ] ε. Indeed, using schebyscheff we obtain E[U α) ε + X )] P[X < ε ] U α) ), hence and therefore ε εα α P[X < ε ] ), α ε > P[X < ε ]. Remark.4 Statements i ) and ii) above only differ in the order of the quantifiers, so that we have the trivial implication i ) ii), as well as ii) i ) in the case when M e S) is a singleton. he more interesting part of Proposition.3 is that we may also conclude that ii) i ) in the incomplete case, provided we replace the constants ε,ε in i ) by bigger constants 3

9 Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations ε, ε. For example we may choose ε = + α ε, ε = ε,whereα ], [ satisfies ε = ε α. Indeed, for given ε,ε > andα ], [ such that ε = ε α,wehave ii) iii ), if we let ε = + α ε.wethenhaveε ε ε α = + α ε ε so that we obtain iii) i) i ), if we use in i) and i ) the constants ε, ε instead of ε,ε. Summing up, we can reverse the quantifiers in statement ii) provided we content ourselves with somewhat worse constants. his phenomenon is related to a quantitative version of the Halmos Savage theorem, as was stressed in []. 3 Estimates for asymptotic arbitrage In this section we show under suitable regularity conditions that price processes with a nontrivial market price of risk 5) allow for asymptotic arbitrage; more precisely, we prove the estimates of heorem.4. We also show how these estimates can be refined if the market price of risk satisfies a large deviations estimate. Let us fix a diffusion process S satisfying Assumption., and recall the minimal martingale measure Q min for S t ) t defined via 4). It follows from [5] that, for an arbitrary Q M e S) there is a predictable process ψ t ) t such that the density Z = dq dp is given by Z = exp ψ dt) t dw t ψ t, 9) where ψ t ϕ t is in the kernel of σs t ) a.s. for almost all t ). Hence ϕ t is orthogonal to ψ t ϕ t,sothat ψ t ϕ t. herefore the estimates 5)and6) carry over from ϕ t to ψ t. Proposition 3. Suppose that S t ) t satisfies Assumption. and has an average squared market price of risk above the threshold c > ;cf.5). For ε>and <γ < c there is > such that, for, condition ii) of Proposition.3 is satisfied with ε = ε and ε = e γ, i.e., for each Q M e S) there is A F such that P[A ] ε and Q[A ] e γ. Proof Fix <γ <γ< c and find > 4γ γ γ) ε such that, for, P ϕ t dt γ < ε. ) For Q M e S) let ψ t) t be the R N -valued process as in 9) sothat dq dp = Z = exp ψ dt) t dw t ψ t. Define the stopping time τ by τ = inf t [, ] t ψ s ds γ. 3

10 H. Föllmer, W. Schachermayer For the random variable B τ = τ ψ t dw t we infer from τ ψ t dt γ that B τ L γ, P) and so schebyscheff s inequality implies For P [ B τ γ γ) ] Z τ = exp τ γ γ γ) < ε. ) ψ dt) t dw t ψ t we obtain from )and)that P [ Z τ > exp γ ) ] τ ψ t = P B τ dt > γ P [ B τ γ γ) ] τ + P ψ t dt < γ ε + ε. Letting A = {Z τ > exp γ )} we obtain P[A ] ε and Q [A c ]=E[Z τ A c ] e γ. We are now in a position to construct attainable contingent claims which satisfy the arbitrage estimates of heorem.4. Proof of heorem.4 Let the constant c > begivenby5). he preceding Proposition 3. implies that, for any given ε > andε = e d,where < d < c, condition ii) of Proposition.3 is satisfied for sufficiently large. Fix ε>andγ,γ,γ verifying <γ = γ + γ < c, as in the statement of heorem.4.fixd > with γ<d < c,and let µ = d γ d ], [. We now proceed similarly as in Remark.4. Choose such that for > condition ii) of Proposition.3 is satisfied with ε ) µ ε = and ε = e d. 3 Defining α ], [ by the equation ε = ε α. we have that α as. We may assume that has been chosen large enough such that + α 3, for. 3

11 Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations 3 Letting ε = 3ε µ = ε and ε = ε µ) we have ε ε α = 3ε µ ε µ) α = 3ε + α max ε,ε α he last inequality implies that condition iii) of Proposition.3 is satisfied with ε replaced by 3ε. Hence, we may conclude that condition i) of Proposition.3 is satisfied, i.e., there is an ε, ε )-arbitrage, for the pair ε, ε ) = ε, e d µ) ). Note that d µ) > γ. Hence, there is X K such that i) X e d µ) a.s. ii) P [ X e d µ) ] ε. Since d µ) γ >γ, we see that the contingent claim X = e d µ) γ ) X K satisfies, for sufficiently large, ). i) X e γ a.s., ii) P[X e γ ] ε. he message of heorem.4 is that we may achieve exponential growth of a portfolio X with probability close to as, while also controlling the maximal loss by an exponential bound. his implies, for instance, the following lower bound for the growth of logarithmic utility. Corollary 3. Let S = S t ) t be a process satisfying Assumption. and having an average squared market price of risk above the threshold c > as in 5). For any initial capital x >, there exist contingent claims X K such that inf E [ logx + X ) ] c. Proof By heorem.4 we know that for γ = andγ < c/ we may find, for ε>and sufficiently large, X K with i) X, ii) P [ X e γ ] ε. For <α<x we obtain the estimate E[logx + αx )] ε logx α) + ε) logx + αeγ ), hence E[logx + αx )] ε)γ, for sufficiently large, which readily yields the result. heorem.4 is valid under the Assumption 5) of a non-trivial market price of risk. If we replace this assumption by the stronger large deviation estimate 6) we expect a stronger result: the term P[X < e γ ] in statement ii) of heorem.4 should even decay exponentially as. Let us sketch a systematic approach how to obtain such a sharper result; we also take the opportunity to motivate the large deviation estimate 6). 3

12 4 H. Föllmer, W. Schachermayer Let S t ) t be a d-dimensional diffusion satisfying Assumption., and assume that S is in fact ergodic. hus, the empirical distributions ρ ω) := δ St ω)dt converge weakly, P-a.s., to the unique invariant distribution µ of S. ypically, the empirical distributions will satisfy a large deviations principle of the form log P[ρ A] inf I ν) ) ν A with some rate function I defined on the convex set M R d ) of probability measures on R d, where ) should be read as an upper bound for the sup of the left-hand side if A is a closed subset of M R d ) and as a lower bound for the inf if A is open. Under some regularity conditions the market price of risk will then satisfy the large deviations estimate 6) log P ϕ t dt c c for any c < ϕx) µdx), with c := inf I ν) ϕx) dνx) c >, due to the contraction principle see, e.g., [8]). In such a situation one should expect an exponential decay of the probabilities P [Z ] e γ and a corresponding exponential version of the estimates in heorem.4, assuming now uniqueness of the locally equivalent martingale measure Q. However, this will involve a slight refinement of the large deviations principle in its classical form ). Let us sketch the argument for the one-dimensional case. Indeed, By Itô s formula, 3 [ ] P Z e γ = P ϕ t dw t := = ) dst ϕ t σs t ) ϕ tdt f S t )ds t = FS ) FS ) ϕ t dw t + ϕ t dt ϕt dt γ. f S t )σ S t )dt ϕ S t )dt,

13 Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations 5 whereweput f x) := ϕx) σx), assume f C,andtakeF C such that F = f. hus, [ ] P Z e γ = P FS ) FS )) hs t )dt γ = P FS ) FS )) hx)dρ x) γ wherewedefinehx) = f x)σ x) + ϕ x). An exponential estimate of the form [ ] sup log P Z e γ < will now follow for γ< hdµ, if we have a joint large deviation principle for the random variables FS ) FS ) ) ),ρ with values in R M R d ) or, more specifically, for the random variables FS ) FS )) hx)dρ x). In this paper, we do not try to give a rigorous version of the argument under general conditions. Instead we will illustrate this approach by proving explicit exponential estimates for the geometric Ornstein Uhlenbeck process. 4 A case study: the geometric Ornstein Uhlenbeck process In this section we consider the geometric Ornstein Uhlenbeck process and derive exponential versions of the extimates in heorem.4. In order to keep the notation as transparent as possible, we take the simplest case S t = expy t ), 3) where Y t ) t is the stationary Ornstein Uhlenbeck process defined by dy t = ρy t dt + σ dw t, Y = y, with parameters ρ>andσ>and with initial value y R; see, however, Remark 4.4 below for the extension to an Ornstein Uhlenbeck process with drift. he process S = S t ) t defined by 3) satisfies the SDE σ ds t = S t [ ρy t dt + σ dw t ]+S t dt [ = S t σ dw t ρy t σ ) ] dt. 4) σ For fixed >, the unique equivalent martingale measure Q on F for the process S is defined by dq dp F = Z 3

14 6 H. Föllmer, W. Schachermayer where Z := exp σ ρy t σ ) dw t ρy σ t σ ) dt. 5) In other words, the dynamics of S under Q takes the form where ds t = σ S t dw Q t, W Q t t := W t = σ σ ρy s σ Y t y + σ ) t ) ds 6) is a Wiener process under Q. In this specific model we can describe the large deviations more explicitly. Proposition 4. For any γ and ] [, σ 8 + ρ 4,thesetsA := { Z e γ } satisfy Q[A ] e γ 7) σ log P[A 8 γ + ρ 4 ]= σ 8 γ + ρ ). 8) Proof Clearly, [ ] Q Z e γ = Z dp e γ, {Z e γ } and this implies 7). he proof of 8) consists in combining a result of Florens Landais and Pham [4] for certain large deviations of the Ornstein Uhlenbeck process with a simple perturbation argument. o this end, we write log Z = σ 3 = ρ σ ρy t σ = ρ σ ξ σ ) σ dy t + ρ ) σ Y tdt ρ σ Y t dy t Y Y ) + ρ σ Yt dt σ 8 8, Yt dt σ 8 + ρ Y t dt 9)

15 Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations 7 where ξ := η + ζ, η := Y t dy t + ρ Y t dt = Y Y σ ) + ρ ζ := σ ρ Y Y ). Y t dt, Recall that the Ornstein Uhlenbeck process Y is ergodic with invariant distribution N, σ ρ ), and note that this implies ξ = η = σ + ρ σ ρ = σ 4 P-a.s. ) Let us now look at the corresponding large deviations. Applying heorem. of Florens Landais and Pham [4] with θ = ρ, θ = ρ, and the straightforward extension to the case σ = ), we see that the random variables η satisfy a large deviations principle with rate function ) ρ y σ I y) = + 4 y σ + for y > σ for y σ i.e., sup log P [ η F ] inf y F I y) for any closed set F R and inf log P [ η G ] inf y G I y) for any open set G R. A simple perturbation argument shows that the same large deviations principle with rate function I applies to the random variables ξ. Indeed, the additional terms ζ are normally distributed with means m converging to m R and variances σ converging to σ ], [, and this implies [ ] log P ζ >ε = = ε σ. log π ε σ e y dy 3

16 8 H. Föllmer, W. Schachermayer In particular, [ ] [ ] ξ P F ξ [ P >ε η ] + P F ε [ η ] P F ε for any ε>, F ε := {y dy, F) ε}, andfor large enough. hus, [ ] log P ξ F inf I y) y F ε for closed F and for arbitrary ε>, hence [ ] log P ξ F inf y F I y). he lower bound for open sets follows in the same manner. For y > σ 4 and F := [y, [, these two bounds imply [ ] log P ξ y = I y ). We can now conclude that the asymptotic behavior of [ ] [ ] ρ P Z e γ = P for γ σ ξ 8 σ γ σ )] 8 γ [ ξ = P σ ρ ] [, σ 8 + ρ 4 is described by Eq. 8). We now are prepared to prove heorem.5. In fact we will prove the following stronger version: heorem ] 4. Let [ S t ) t be the geometric Ornstein Uhlenbeck process defined in 7).ake γ, σ 8 + ρ 4 and any γ <γ. hen there exist contingent claims X K such that, for any γ <γ γ, i) X e γ for large, ii) log P [ X < e γ ] = ) σ 8 γ + ρ 4 σ 8 γ + ρ More precisely, we can achieve the tighter bounds iii) X α := e γ Q[Ac ] Q[A ] where A := {Z e γ }, and the decay rate in ii) for the shortfall probabilities P[X < e γ ] is in fact optimal under the constraint iii). Proof Since Q[A c ] e γ by 7), the constants α defined by iii) satisfy α e γ γ ) Q[A ], 3.

17 Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations 9 hence α e γ for large if γ <γ γ. Now consider the contingent claims Clearly, X α,and hence X K. Moreover, since X := e γ A c α A. E Q [X ]=e γ Q[A c ] α Q[A ]=, { X < e γ } = A for large enough, part ii) of heorem 4. follows from 8). In order to check the optimality of the convergence rate in ii) under the constraint iii), take a sequence of contingent claims X K such that X α. he corresponding sets à := { X < e γ } satify Q [ à c ] ) e γ + α α = e γ Q [ à c ] + α )Q [ ] à ] E Q [ X, hence Q [ à c ] α α + e γ = Q[Ac ]. he Neyman Pearson lemma allows us to conclude that P [ à c ] P[A c ]. In particular, the shortfall probabilities P [ X < e γ ] = P[à ] cannot decay at a faster rate than described by ii). Remark 4.3 Note that the constants α defined in part iii) of heorem 4. satisfy t log α = γ + log Q[Ac ] γ γ ), ) where we have used the crude estimate Q[A c ] e γ. Refined large deviation estimates for the probabilities Q[A c ] yield better rates for the convergence of α to. Indeed, Q[A c ]=Q[Z < e γ ] e ηγ E Q [Z η ] = e ηγ E P [Z η ] for any η>. he term E P [Z η ] can be computed explicitly; cf. Proposition 5.6. his yields with log Q[Ac ] γ + f η)) f η) := ρ σ ) η η) + η) 8 γ. 3

18 3 H. Föllmer, W. Schachermayer Sincewehaveassumedγ< σ 8 + ρ 4, the function f attains its maximum value σ f ηγ )) = 8 + ρ ) σ 4 γ 8 + ρ ) γ > ) in ηγ ) = ρ σ, ρ γ and so we can replace the rate γ γ in ) by the better rate γ γ + f ηγ )). Remark 4.4 he preceding discussion also applies to more general versions of the geometric Ornstein Uhlenbeck process. Suppose, for example, that the discounted price process is of the form S t = e Y t +µt with some constant drift parameter µ. In this case, the density Z of the unique equivalent martingale measure is again of the form 5), but with modified parameters σ = σ + µ σ, ρ = ρ + µ ) σ. As a result, Eq. 8) in Proposition 4. is still valid, but with σ instead of σ. Indeed, note that log Z takes the form 9) with ξ = η + ζ,where ζ = σ σ ρ Y Y ). he law of large numbers ) remains valid for ξ, and the large deviations principle for η can be transferred also to ξ. hus [ ] log P Z e γ = σ = I ρ log P [ η σ ρ )) 8 σ γ )] 8 σ γ for γ ], σ 8 + ρ [ 4, and this amounts to Eq. 8) with σ instead of σ. Finally we want to compare the arbitrage estimates for the geometric Ornstein Uhlenbeck case as described in heorem.5 and in Remark 4.4 with the much simpler case of the Black Scholes model. heorem 4.5 Let µ =, σ>and define the Black Scholes model by [ S t = S exp σ W t + µ σ ) ] t. ake γ ], ϕ [,whereϕ t ϕ µ σ. For any γ <γ, there exists X K such that, for any γ <γ γ, i) X e γ for large, ii) log P [ X < e γ ] ) = ϕ. γ ϕ More precisely, we can achieve the tighter bounds iii) X α := e γ Q[Ac ] Q[A ], 3

19 Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations 3 where A ={Z e γ }.hen log α = γ γ ϕ + ϕ ), and the decay rate for the shortfall probabilities in ii) is optimal under the constraint iii). Proof For > the density Z of the unique equivalent martingale measure is given by ] Z = exp [ ϕw ϕ. We have P [ ] A c ] = P [ ϕw ϕ < γ ) ϕ = P W γ < ϕ ϕ = γ ) ) ϕ for ϕ>, and similarly for ϕ<, where denotes the distribution function of a standard normal variable. On the other hand, since Wt Q := W t + ϕt defines a Wiener process under Q, Q [ A c ] = Q [ ϕw Q < γ ϕ ] γ = ϕ + ϕ ) ). Now consider the contingent claim X := e γ A c α A. Clearly, X α and E Q [X ]=hence X K. Finally we have [ ] P X < e γ ϕ = P [A ] = γ ) ). ϕ Since ) log η = η for any η R, we easily obtain [ ] log P X < e γ ϕ = γ ) /. ϕ Inthesamewayweseethat log α = γ + log Q[Ac ] γ = γ ϕ + ϕ ). 3

20 3 H. Föllmer, W. Schachermayer As in the proof of heorem 4., optimality of the decay rate in ii) under the constraints iii) follows by applying the Neyman Pearson lemma. 5 Optimal strategies for the geometric Ornstein Uhlenbeck process for HARA utilities Let us return to the geometric Ornstein Uhlenbeck model introduced in Sect. 4. For three standard choices of a utility function U, we are going to compute the maximal expected utility u x) := E P [UX )] attainable at time > using some self-financing trading strategy and the initial capital x >. Recall see, e.g, [,]) that the optimal contingent claim X is of the form where the Lagrange multiplier y > isgivenby X = U ) yz ) ) E Q [ U ) yz ) ] = x. 3) Hence X x K. A little warning on the notation seems appropriate: While in the previous sections it was natural to have X K, we now follow the usual notation in utility maximization, where we fix an initial endowment x R and let X denote a random variable such that X x K. We are also going to identify the optimal trading strategy, i.e., the predictable process ξ ) t ) t such that X t ) := E Q [X F t ] t = x + ξ ) s ds s 4) for any t [, ]. It is clearly equivalent to compute the optimal proportion t := ξ t ) S t π ) of the capital X t ) generated up to time t which should be invested in the financial asset. Moreover, we are going to describe the growth of u x) and the iting form of the optimal strategy as increases to, and to give some financial interpretation in terms of certainty equivalents. 5. Logarithmic utility For the logarithmic utility function Ux) = log x it follows from ) and3) that the optimal contingent claim at time is given by X = xz. 6) hus the maximal expected utility takes the form 3 X ) t 5) u x) = log x + H P Q) 7)

21 Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations 33 where [ ] [ ] H P Q) := E P log dp = E P log Z F dq denotes the relative entropy of P with respect to Q on F. Proposition 5. he maximal expected utility at time is given by u x) = log x + 4 ρ ) e ρ + ρ 8 4 σ y ) e ρ ) y e ρ + 8 σ. 8) In particular u x) grows linearly at the rate u x) = 4 ρ + 8 σ. 9) Proof In view of 7) it is enough to compute the relative entropy H P Q) = E P ρy t ) σ σ dw t + E P σ ρy t ) σ dt. Note that the first term vanishes, and recall that the first two moments of the Ornstein Uhlenbeck process Y t ) t are given by and hus E P [Y t ]=y e ρt 3) E P [Y t ]= σ ρ e ρt ) + e ρt y. H P Q) = ρ σ E P [Yt ]dt ρ E P [Y t ]dt + 8 σ = ρ ) 4 σ y e ρ ) y e ρ ) e ρ ρ + 8 σ. In the logarithmic case the optimal strategy does not depend on the horizon : Proposition 5. he optimal proportion defined by 5) is given by π t ) = σ ρy t. 3) Proof In view of 5), 6)and6) the optimal contingent claim is given by X = x exp ρy t ) σ σ dw t + σ ρy t ) σ dt = x exp ρy t ) σ σ dwt Q σ ρy t ) σ dt. 3

22 34 H. Föllmer, W. Schachermayer hus the Q-martingale satisfies X t ) := E Q [X F t ] t = x exp σ ρy s ) σ dws Q t σ dx t ) = X t ) ρy t )) σ σ dwt Q = X ) t σ ρy t + ) St ds t, ρy s ) σ ds and so the proportion π t ) defined by 5) is indeed given by 3). Remark 5.3 It is well-known that for logarithmic utility the optimal contingent claim is given by the numéraire portfolio X = x Z min ) = x + X t ϕ σ ) t ds t, 3) i.e., the optimal strategy is simply proportional to the current wealth X t as well as to the quotient ϕ σ ; see, e.g., [] and[4]. Note that these results also hold true in the general incomplete case. In our special case of the geometric Ornstein Uhlenbeck process, this is of course consistent with the explicit formula 3) for the optimal proportion. Formula 3) implies in particular that any estimate from below) on E [ log Z min)] yields an estimate from below) on E[logX )]. 5. Exponential utility For the exponential utility function Ux) = exp λx) with parameter λ>wehave U ) y) = λ log λ y ), so that the optimal contingent claim in ) takes the form X = x + λ H Q P) log Z ), where H Q P) := E Q [log Z ] denotes the relative entropy of Q with respect to P on F. Proposition 5.4 he maximal expected utility is given by u x) = exp λx H Q P)) 33) where ρ H Q P)= σ y ρ y + ) 8 σ + 4 ρ y )+ ) 8 ρσ + 4 ρ σ 3. 34) In particular, u x) grows to its upper bound at the rate 3 3 log u x)) = 4 ρ σ.

23 Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations 35 Proof Since by ) [ u x) = E P exp λx ) ] = exp λx H Q P)), it remains to compute the relative entropy in our special setting. In view of 5)and6)we have H Q P) = E Q ρy t ) σ σ dw t σ ρy t ) σ dt = E Q ρy t ) σ σ dwt Q + σ ρy t ) σ ds = ρ σ E Q [Yt ]dt ρ E Q [Y t ]dt + 8 σ. Since Y t = σ W Q t and + y σ t by 6), the first two moments are given by E Q [Y t ]=y σ t. E Q [Yt ]=σ t + y y σ t + 4 σ 4 t, and this yields Eq. 34). Let us now identify the optimal strategy for a fixed horizon >. Proposition 5.5 he optimal quantity ξ t ) defined by 4) is given by ξ t ) = [ ρ + ρ λs t σ t) ) Y t ρ t)) + ]. 35) 4 Proof Consider the Q-martingale X t ) := E Q [X F t ] = x + λ H Q P) λσ t ρy s ) σ dws Q t λ λ E Q σ ρy s ) σ ds F t. t he last term can be computed explicitly using the conditional moments and E Q [Y s F t ]=σ W Q t E Q [Y s F t]=σ s t) + σ W Q t + y σ s ) + y σ s σ ρy s ) σ ds ) + σ Wt Q y ) σ s. 3

24 36 H. Föllmer, W. Schachermayer Since the components of bounded variation in our equation for the Q-martingale X t ) must sum up to the constant x, we finally obtain X ) t = x + λ = x + λ t t [ ) σ σ ρy s ρ σ s)y σ s 4 + σ ρ + ρ 4ρ s) ) ] dws Q S s [ ) ρσ ρ s) Y σ s ρ s)) + ] ds s. 4 his shows that the integrand ξ ) t ) defined via 4) is indeed given by 35). 5.3 Power utility Consider the power utility function Ux) = α xα with parameter α ], [\{}. Since U ) y) = y γ with γ := α ], [, the optimal contingent claim for > is given by X = xz γ E [ γ ] [ ] γ Q Z = xz E P Z β, 36) and the maximal expected utility takes the form u x) = E P [UX )] 37) u x) = xα [ ] α E P Z β α 38) where β := α ], [\{}. α he following proposition provides an explicit formula for u x). In particular it allows us to compute its rate of growth as. Note that for α>eq.4) describes the exponential growth of u x) to infinity, while for α<itspecifies the exponential decay of the distance between u x) and its maximal value. Proposition 5.6 We have E P [Z β ]=A ) exp B + A ) ) C, 39) where A ± := ) β ± exp ρ )) β, B := βy ρ ) [ β β) σ y 8 βσ + ρ ) ] β β), and C := y β exp ρ ) β + ρ ) y β β) σ exp ρ ) β + β σ 6 ρ β) exp ρ )) β. 3

25 Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations 37 In particular, the maximal expected utility grows at the rate log u x) ) = 8 ασ + ρ α). 4) Proof In order to compute the expectation of Z β = exp ρβ σ Y s dy s + βρ σ Ys ds βy y ) 8 βσ, we first einate the energy term Y s ds appearing in the exponent by means of a suitable Girsanov transformation. For δ>wedenote by P δ the probability measure on F with density ϕ δ := exp ρ δ Y s dw s ) ρ δ Y s ds σ σ = exp ρ δ σ Y s dy s + ρ δ σ Ys ds 4) with respect to P.Since W δ t t := W t ρ δ Y s ds σ defines a Wiener process under P δ, Y t ) t becomes an Ornstein Uhlenbeck process under P δ with parameter δ, i.e., dy t = δy t dt + σ dwt δ. 4) Setting δ := ρ β and using Itô s formula Y s dy s = Y y ) σ, we obtain [ E P [Z β ]=Eδ Z β ) ] ϕ δ = E δ exp ρ ) β β) σ Y s dy s βy y ) 8 βσ ρ ) = expb ) E [exp δ β β) σ Y )] βy. In view of 4), Y is Gaussian with mean m := e δ y and variance ν := σ δ e δ ). Using the fact that E[expλY +ηy )]= λν ) exp λν ) λm +ηm+ )) η ν 43) 3

26 38 H. Föllmer, W. Schachermayer for any random variable Y with normal distribution Nm,ν ) and for λν <,wefinally obtain Eq. 39). Combining 38) with 39), we see that log u x) =α log x log α + α) B + A ) ) C α) log A. Since A and C converge to a finite it as, log u x) = α) B [ = α ) 8 βσ + ρ ) ] β β) = 8 ασ + ρ ) α. Our next goal is to identify the optimal strategy ξ t ) ) t defined by 4). It will be described in terms of the optimal proportion π t ) of the capital X t ) = E Q [X F t ] which should be invested in the financial asset at time t for any t [, ], see5). Proposition 5.7 he optimal proportion π t ) is an affine function of the logarithmic stock price given by π t ) = a t)y t + b t), 44) where a t) := ρ β A + σ t A t ) and b t) := [ A t ) β exp ρ )] β t). In particular, the asymptotic form of the optimal strategy for is given by π t := π ) ρ t = σ α Y t +. 45) Proof Consider the Q-martingale M t ) t defined by M t := E Q [Z γ F t], and recall the measure P δ introduced in the proof of Proposition 5.6 for δ := ρ β. In terms of its densities ϕt δ := E P [ϕ δ F t] with respect to P where ϕ δ is given by 4), M t takes the form ] M t = Zt E P [Z β F [ t ] = Zt ϕt δ Eδ Z β ϕδ ) F t [ = L t E δ ρ ) exp β β) σ Y ) ] βy F t 3

27 Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations 39 with log L t := δ t σ Y s dy s δ t σ Y s ds + Y t y ) + 8 σ t + B where B was defined in Proposition 5.6. In view of 4) the random variable Y is Gaussian under the conditional distribution P δ [. F t ], with conditional mean m := Y t exp δ t)) and conditional variance ρ := σ δ exp δ t))). Using again formula 43) we finally obtain an expression of the form where M t = expn t )D t, N t := t π t ) σ dws Q is a Q-martingale, π t ) is given by 44)andD t ) t is some adapted process with continuous paths of bounded variation. But M t ) t is a Q-martingale, and this implies M t = M exp N t ) N t, hence and dx ) dm t = M t dn t t = X t ) dn t = X ) = X ) t π t ) t π t ) σ dw Q t S t ds t. hus we have shown that the trading strategy ξ t ) ) in 4) isgivenby ξ ) t = X ) t π t ) S t, and so the quantity π t ) defined by 44) is indeed the optimal proportion of the available capital X t ) which should be invested in the financial asset at time t. Since we obtain and A± = ) β, a t) = ρ ρ β = σ σ α b t) =, and so the asymptotic form of the strategy for is given by 45). 3

28 4 H. Föllmer, W. Schachermayer Remark 5.8 In Fleming and Sheu [3] dynamic programming methods are used in order to compute directly the optimal growth rate = sup sup log E P[UX π )] for power utilities U, where the supremum is taken over all admissible trading strategies; see also Pham [8]. Our Propositions 5.6 and 5.7 provide, in addition, explicit results for any finite horizon and may be viewed as a probabilistic complement to the analytical method in [3]. Remark 5.9 We have considered prices and contingent claims in discounted form since the bond was assumed to be normalized to B t. For a constant risk-free interest rate r >, the undiscounted contingent claim generated by a self-financing trading strategy is of the form X = X e r, and it seems natural to apply a given utility function U to X rather than to X. Moreover one may want to introduce a subjective rate of discounting δ>. Let us denoty by ũ x) the optimal value obtained by maximizing E [ U X )] e δ. For a power utility Ux) = α xα the optimal contingent claim is clearly the same as before, i.e., X = X e r where X is given by 36). Note, however, that Z now depends on r. he optimal value takes the form ũ x) = u x)e αr δ) where u x) is given by 37), and in analogy to Proposition 5.6 we obtain exponential growth at the rate log ũ x) ) = α r + ) ) σ σ r + ρ α ) δ; see [3] for detailed computations and for extensions to more general Ornstein Uhlenbeck processes in a robust setting. 5.4 Certainty equivalents and their growth rates We now shall interpret in financial terms the previous results on optimal investment with respect to the geometric Ornstein Uhlenbeck process for the utility functions considered above. We shall also analyze to which extent the logarithmic utility Ux) = logx) and the exponential utility Ux) = exp x) correspond to the iting cases α and α for power utilities U α) x) = xα α. o make the above results comparable we transform them from the utility scale to the money scale, using the concept of certainty equivalent, due to De Finetti compare, e.g., [7, Example 3.3.5]). We fix an initial endowment x of an economic agent, which we shall eventually normalize by x =, as well as the value function u x). he certainty equivalent CE x) then is the solution to Ux + CE x)) = u x). 46) he interpretation of this formula is that an agent whose preferences are modeled by expected utility U at time is indifferent between having an initial endowment x + CE x) 3

29 Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations 4 without the possibility of investing in the financial market S so that her wealth remains constant during [, ]), as compared to having an initial endowment x as well as the possibility of investing optimally) in the market S during [, ]. By scaling we have CE x) = xce ) in the case of logarithmic and power utility while CE x) is independent of x in the case of the exponential utility. We therefore shall simply write CE for CE ); if we want to emphasize the role of the utility function U, weshall also denote this quantity by CE U. Propositions 5., 5.4 and 5.6 yield an explicit description of the growth of the certainty equivalents as Logarithmic utility We have CE log) x) = x exp H P Q) ), and formula 9) yields exponential growth at the rate log CElog) x) = ρ 4 + σ 8. 47) 5.4. Exponential utility We have CE exp) x) = λ H Q P), and formula 34) yields cubic growth at the rate Power utility 3 CEexp) x) = ρ σ λ 4. 48) For α ], [\{} and Ux) = xα α, the certainty equivalent is given by ] CE α) x) = x E P [Z β ) β, and formula 4) yields exponential growth at the rate log CEα) x) = σ 8 + ρ α). 49) α Remark 5. For the optimization problem formulated in Remark 5.9, the corresponding certainty equivalent CE x) is given by U x + CE x) ) = ũ x). For a power utility Ux) = α xα we obtain ) ) x + CE α) x) = x + CE α) x) r α e δ, 3

30 4 H. Föllmer, W. Schachermayer and 49) implies exponential growth at the rate t log CE α) x) = σ ) σ r + ρ α) + r δ α α. We now discuss the iting behavior α andα. We start with the first case which is easier. x Noting that α α α α = log x and α α = 4,wehavethat49) tends to 47)asα. In fact, a stronger result holds true: one may verify using 8), 38), 39)that, for fixed,wehave α CEα) = CE log). We thus see that α log CE α) ) = log CE log) ) = α log CE α) his formula indicates that the case of logarithmic utility indeed corresponds to the it α for power utility. We observe that the growth rate log CE α) ) of the certainty equivalent is a monotone function in α ], [ ranging from ) α log CE α) = σ 8 via ) α log CE α) ) = log CE log) = σ 8 + ρ 4 to ) α log CE α) = σ 8 + ρ. his reflects the financial intuition that an agent with smaller risk aversion can take better advantage measured in terms of certainty equivalents) of investment opportunities. he analysis of the behavior for α is more subtle than the case α. Recall that the exponential utility represents the it of U α) x) = xα α,asα, after proper affine normalisation: exp x) = x ) α x α) α = α α+. α α α α Hence, up to the multiplicative factor α α+, which is irrelevant for the certainty equivalent, the exponential utility exp x) is close to the shifted power utility U α) x α), as α. Using 34), 38), 39) one may verify that for fixed horizon,weagainhave α CEα) α ) = CEexp). 5) However, the above relation does not carry over to the iting expressions for by interchanging the iting procedures for α and as in the logarithmic case above: the terms in 48) and49) are of a completely different qualitative structure. In fact, the term 3 in 48) looks at first sight rather puzzling. 3 )

31 Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations 43 In order to develop an understanding of the situation it is instructive to have a closer look at the optimal trading strategies. Let us again start with the logarithmic case which is the easiest, as π log, ) t = ρy σ t,asdefinedin3), does not depend on,sothatwemay define π log) t = σ ρy t independently of the horizon. As regards the optimal trading strategy π t α, ) the horizon ; nevertheless the it π α) and one readily verifies that π log) t = ρ σ Y t + = for power utility 44), it does depend on t for exists for each α ], [\{} 45) α ρ σ α Y t + = π t α), α in order words that the logarithmically optimal investment strategy again is the it of the iting α-optimal strategy π α),asα. Passing to the exponential utility, the picture changes drastically: the optimal quantity ξ exp, ) t,givenby35), depends on the horizon in such a way that it is not possible to pass to the it as the leading term is ρ 4λS t t). In order to find the reason why the exponential utility maximizer shows this rather strange behavior let us rewrite the value functions 7), 33)and38) in a form appropriate to argue with the Hamilton Jacobi-Bellman equation. u log) x, y, t) = log x + 4 ρ t) 8 u exp) x, y, t) = exp u α) xα x, y, t) = α where e ρ t)) + ρ 4 σ y e ρ t)) y e ρ t)) + 8 σ t), 5) [ ρ λx σ y ρ y + ) 8 σ t) 4 ρ y) + ) 8 ρσ t) ] 4 ρ σ t) 3, 5) [ A t) exp B t + A ) ) ] α t C t, 53) ) β ± exp ρ )) β t), ρ ) β β) σ y A ± t := B t := βy [ 8 βσ + ρ ) ] β β) t), and C t := ρ yβ exp ) β t) + ρ ) y β β) σ exp ρ ) β t) + β σ 6 ρ β) exp ρ )) β t). A basic feature of dynamic programming is that, fixing and plugging the optimizer X t ) ) t as well as the process Y t) t into the value function above, one obtains a local) martingale u X t ), Y t, t )). We do not try to prove this rigorously which t 3

32 44 H. Föllmer, W. Schachermayer is possible) as we only want to argue formally to develop an intuition for the phenomena encountered above. We shall also use the formal identities E[dW t ]=anddw t ) = dt. We obtain from the martingale property the equation E [ d u X ) t where Itô s formula allows us to write [ ))] E d u X t ), Y t, t = u dt + u [ t x E d X t ) ))], Y t, t =, 54) ] + u y E [dy t] + u x d X t ) + u y dy t) + u x y d X ) t dy t 55) Analyzing the above equation, it turns out that the mixed derivative u x y x, y, t) plays a crucial role: while this term vanishes in the case of logarithmic utility 5), it cannot be neglected in the exponential 5) and the power case 53). Concentrating on the exponential case we deduce from 5) that the leading term w.r. to t)of u exp) x y is given by ) u exp) x y λρ 4 t) u exp). his term dominates for large t) the derivatives uexp) x and λ u exp) respectively. λu exp) as well as u exp), which equal x his gives us a clue to the understanding of the leading term of the optimal strategy ξ t ) ρ t). 56) 4λS t We may interpret the dynamic programming equation 54) in the following way: the exponential utility maximizer chooses at time t the investment ξ t ) in such a way that, when plugging d X t ) = ξ t ) ds t into 54) and55) theterm u t becomes minimal. Indeed, in this case the function u.,.,) becomes maximal for the given boundary condition u x, y, ) = exp λx) as the descent in the time coordinate is steepest. he choice of the control variable ξ t ) in d X t ) = ξ t ) ds t does not effect the behavior of E[dY t ] or dy t ) ; hence, we see from 55) that one has to solve the following maximization problem for the variable ξ R: and Using 3 u x ξe[ds t]+ u x ξ ds t ) + u x y ξds tdy t max! u x = λu, u x = λ u, u x y λρ 4 t) u σ E[dS t ]=e y ) ρy dt, ds t ) = e y σ dt, ds t dy t = σ e y dt

33 Asymptotic arbitrage and large deviations 45 we arrive, letting S t = e y and keeping only the leading terms in t),at λ u ξ e y σ dt λρ 4 t) u ξσ e y dt max! Differentiating with respect to ξ and equating to zero yields 56). Summing up, we see that in the exponential case the joint wobbling d X t ) mixed derivative u x y are the crucial terms which cause the optimal value ξ ) t S t = ρ 4λ dy t and the t) to be of the order t), independently of the current value of the process Y t which determines the market price of risk. Now we are in a position to understand why the double iting procedure α, cannot be interchanged: For fixed horizon we have that u α) x α) tends to u exp) x), asα for x R, and the same iting behavior holds true for the corresponding trading strategies. On the other hand the optimal exponential strategies ξ t ) 56) do not converge, as, while we have seen that, for fixed α [, [\{} the optimal power strategies π t α, ) do converge to π t α). Not only in the case of exponential utility we find remarkable differences to the Black Scholes situation where the optimal strategies are independent of the time horizon, but even in the case of logarithmic utility, which is the most regular one, we find unexpected phenomena. As regards the optimal investment of the logarithmic utility maximizer there are no surprises yet: the optimal investment proportion π log) t given in 3) is proportional to the market price of risk ρ σ Y t + σ of the process S see 4)). When Y t = σ ρ there are no profitable investment opportunities as in this case the market price of risk vanishes: the optimal strategy of the log-optimizer therefore is not to invest into the risky asset in this situation. Now let us look at the value function 5) for the logarithmic utility u log) x, y, t) = log x + 4 ρ t) ρ e t)) 8 + ρ 4 σ y e ρ t)) y e ρ t)) + 8 σ t). Fixing x and t we observe that the minimal value is attained at y min σ ρ for large. Hence the situation for the log-investor is worse if measured by expected utility at time ) if Y t = σ ρ than in the case Y t = σ ρ, when the market price of risk vanishes. o explain this at first glance counter-intuitive phenomenon we quote from Wilhelm ell: He has no choice but through this sunken way to come to Kussnacht. here is no other road. he drift of the Ornstein Uhlenbeck process Y drives the process back towards Y = ; hence a typical path of Y, for which at time t we have Y t = σ ρ, will tend towards and on this way it has to pass through the region around σ ρ where the log-investor will not find profitable investment opportunities. his situation is worse than starting at Y t = σ ρ, where one already may hope to drift out of the sunken way. Let us finally look at the pathwise growth of the capital X generated by the optimal strategy up to time. Note first that ρ log Z = 4 + σ ) P-a.s., 57) 8 due to 9)and). 3

Thomas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover

Thomas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover Optimal long term investment under model ambiguity Optimal long term investment under model ambiguity homas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover knispel@stochastik.uni-hannover.de AnStAp0 Vienna, July

More information

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Tim Leung 1, Qingshuo Song 2, and Jie Yang 3 1 Columbia University, New York, USA; leung@ieor.columbia.edu 2 City

More information

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs Lecture Notes by Walter Schachermayer Nachdiplom-Vorlesung, ETH Zürich, WS 15/16 1 Models on Finite Probability Spaces In this section we consider a stock price

More information

Minimal Sufficient Conditions for a Primal Optimizer in Nonsmooth Utility Maximization

Minimal Sufficient Conditions for a Primal Optimizer in Nonsmooth Utility Maximization Finance and Stochastics manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) Minimal Sufficient Conditions for a Primal Optimizer in Nonsmooth Utility Maximization Nicholas Westray Harry Zheng. Received: date

More information

Dynamic Risk Measures and Nonlinear Expectations with Markov Chain noise

Dynamic Risk Measures and Nonlinear Expectations with Markov Chain noise Dynamic Risk Measures and Nonlinear Expectations with Markov Chain noise Robert J. Elliott 1 Samuel N. Cohen 2 1 Department of Commerce, University of South Australia 2 Mathematical Insitute, University

More information

A new approach for investment performance measurement. 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009

A new approach for investment performance measurement. 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009 A new approach for investment performance measurement 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009 Thaleia Zariphopoulou University of Oxford, Oxford-Man Institute and The University of Texas at Austin 1 Performance

More information

A Note on Robust Representations of Law-Invariant Quasiconvex Functions

A Note on Robust Representations of Law-Invariant Quasiconvex Functions A Note on Robust Representations of Law-Invariant Quasiconvex Functions Samuel Drapeau Michael Kupper Ranja Reda October 6, 21 We give robust representations of law-invariant monotone quasiconvex functions.

More information

THE ASYMPTOTIC ELASTICITY OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS 1

THE ASYMPTOTIC ELASTICITY OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS 1 The Annals of Applied Probability 1999, Vol. 9, No. 3, 94 95 THE ASYMPTOTIC ELASTICITY OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS 1 By D. Kramkov 2 and W. Schachermayer Steklov Mathematical

More information

Worst Case Portfolio Optimization and HJB-Systems

Worst Case Portfolio Optimization and HJB-Systems Worst Case Portfolio Optimization and HJB-Systems Ralf Korn and Mogens Steffensen Abstract We formulate a portfolio optimization problem as a game where the investor chooses a portfolio and his opponent,

More information

Necessary Conditions for the Existence of Utility Maximizing Strategies under Transaction Costs

Necessary Conditions for the Existence of Utility Maximizing Strategies under Transaction Costs Necessary Conditions for the Existence of Utility Maximizing Strategies under Transaction Costs Paolo Guasoni Boston University and University of Pisa Walter Schachermayer Vienna University of Technology

More information

Stochastic Volatility and Correction to the Heat Equation

Stochastic Volatility and Correction to the Heat Equation Stochastic Volatility and Correction to the Heat Equation Jean-Pierre Fouque, George Papanicolaou and Ronnie Sircar Abstract. From a probabilist s point of view the Twentieth Century has been a century

More information

Risk Measures in non-dominated Models

Risk Measures in non-dominated Models Purpose: Study Risk Measures taking into account the model uncertainty in mathematical finance. Plan 1 Non-dominated Models Model Uncertainty Fundamental topological Properties 2 Risk Measures on L p (c)

More information

A MODEL FOR THE LONG-TERM OPTIMAL CAPACITY LEVEL OF AN INVESTMENT PROJECT

A MODEL FOR THE LONG-TERM OPTIMAL CAPACITY LEVEL OF AN INVESTMENT PROJECT A MODEL FOR HE LONG-ERM OPIMAL CAPACIY LEVEL OF AN INVESMEN PROJEC ARNE LØKKA AND MIHAIL ZERVOS Abstract. We consider an investment project that produces a single commodity. he project s operation yields

More information

Some Aspects of Universal Portfolio

Some Aspects of Universal Portfolio 1 Some Aspects of Universal Portfolio Tomoyuki Ichiba (UC Santa Barbara) joint work with Marcel Brod (ETH Zurich) Conference on Stochastic Asymptotics & Applications Sixth Western Conference on Mathematical

More information

On the dual problem of utility maximization

On the dual problem of utility maximization On the dual problem of utility maximization Yiqing LIN Joint work with L. GU and J. YANG University of Vienna Sept. 2nd 2015 Workshop Advanced methods in financial mathematics Angers 1 Introduction Basic

More information

HJB equations. Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance January 10, 2011

HJB equations. Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance January 10, 2011 Department of Probability and Mathematical Statistics Faculty of Mathematics and Physics, Charles University in Prague petrasek@karlin.mff.cuni.cz Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance

More information

Question 1. The correct answers are: (a) (2) (b) (1) (c) (2) (d) (3) (e) (2) (f) (1) (g) (2) (h) (1)

Question 1. The correct answers are: (a) (2) (b) (1) (c) (2) (d) (3) (e) (2) (f) (1) (g) (2) (h) (1) Question 1 The correct answers are: a 2 b 1 c 2 d 3 e 2 f 1 g 2 h 1 Question 2 a Any probability measure Q equivalent to P on F 2 can be described by Q[{x 1, x 2 }] := q x1 q x1,x 2, 1 where q x1, q x1,x

More information

Duality and Utility Maximization

Duality and Utility Maximization Duality and Utility Maximization Bachelor Thesis Niklas A. Pfister July 11, 2013 Advisor: Prof. Dr. Halil Mete Soner Department of Mathematics, ETH Zürich Abstract This thesis explores the problem of maximizing

More information

Sensitivity analysis of the expected utility maximization problem with respect to model perturbations

Sensitivity analysis of the expected utility maximization problem with respect to model perturbations Sensitivity analysis of the expected utility maximization problem with respect to model perturbations Mihai Sîrbu, The University of Texas at Austin based on joint work with Oleksii Mostovyi University

More information

QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE

QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE Research Paper 241 December 2008 Viability of Markets with an Infinite Number of Assets Constantinos Kardaras ISSN 1441-8010 VIABILITY

More information

Risk-Minimality and Orthogonality of Martingales

Risk-Minimality and Orthogonality of Martingales Risk-Minimality and Orthogonality of Martingales Martin Schweizer Universität Bonn Institut für Angewandte Mathematik Wegelerstraße 6 D 53 Bonn 1 (Stochastics and Stochastics Reports 3 (199, 123 131 2

More information

Perturbative Approaches for Robust Intertemporal Optimal Portfolio Selection

Perturbative Approaches for Robust Intertemporal Optimal Portfolio Selection Perturbative Approaches for Robust Intertemporal Optimal Portfolio Selection F. Trojani and P. Vanini ECAS Course, Lugano, October 7-13, 2001 1 Contents Introduction Merton s Model and Perturbative Solution

More information

Fundamentals in Optimal Investments. Lecture I

Fundamentals in Optimal Investments. Lecture I Fundamentals in Optimal Investments Lecture I + 1 Portfolio choice Portfolio allocations and their ordering Performance indices Fundamentals in optimal portfolio choice Expected utility theory and its

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 24 Sep 2018

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 24 Sep 2018 A short note on Anticipative portfolio optimization B. D Auria a,b,1,, J.-A. Salmerón a,1 a Dpto. Estadística, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid. Avda. de la Universidad 3, 8911, Leganés (Madrid Spain b

More information

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint that the ON PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION UNDER \DRAWDOWN" CONSTRAINTS JAKSA CVITANIC IOANNIS KARATZAS y March 6, 994 Abstract We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the wealth

More information

ALEKSANDAR MIJATOVIĆ AND MIKHAIL URUSOV

ALEKSANDAR MIJATOVIĆ AND MIKHAIL URUSOV DETERMINISTIC CRITERIA FOR THE ABSENCE OF ARBITRAGE IN DIFFUSION MODELS ALEKSANDAR MIJATOVIĆ AND MIKHAIL URUSOV Abstract. We obtain a deterministic characterisation of the no free lunch with vanishing

More information

of space-time diffusions

of space-time diffusions Optimal investment for all time horizons and Martin boundary of space-time diffusions Sergey Nadtochiy and Michael Tehranchi October 5, 2012 Abstract This paper is concerned with the axiomatic foundation

More information

SEPARABLE TERM STRUCTURES AND THE MAXIMAL DEGREE PROBLEM. 1. Introduction This paper discusses arbitrage-free separable term structure (STS) models

SEPARABLE TERM STRUCTURES AND THE MAXIMAL DEGREE PROBLEM. 1. Introduction This paper discusses arbitrage-free separable term structure (STS) models SEPARABLE TERM STRUCTURES AND THE MAXIMAL DEGREE PROBLEM DAMIR FILIPOVIĆ Abstract. This paper discusses separable term structure diffusion models in an arbitrage-free environment. Using general consistency

More information

Optimal portfolio strategies under partial information with expert opinions

Optimal portfolio strategies under partial information with expert opinions 1 / 35 Optimal portfolio strategies under partial information with expert opinions Ralf Wunderlich Brandenburg University of Technology Cottbus, Germany Joint work with Rüdiger Frey Research Seminar WU

More information

Order book resilience, price manipulation, and the positive portfolio problem

Order book resilience, price manipulation, and the positive portfolio problem Order book resilience, price manipulation, and the positive portfolio problem Alexander Schied Mannheim University Workshop on New Directions in Financial Mathematics Institute for Pure and Applied Mathematics,

More information

Optimal Trade Execution with Instantaneous Price Impact and Stochastic Resilience

Optimal Trade Execution with Instantaneous Price Impact and Stochastic Resilience Optimal Trade Execution with Instantaneous Price Impact and Stochastic Resilience Ulrich Horst 1 Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin Department of Mathematics and School of Business and Economics Vienna, Nov.

More information

(6, 4) Is there arbitrage in this market? If so, find all arbitrages. If not, find all pricing kernels.

(6, 4) Is there arbitrage in this market? If so, find all arbitrages. If not, find all pricing kernels. Advanced Financial Models Example sheet - Michaelmas 208 Michael Tehranchi Problem. Consider a two-asset model with prices given by (P, P 2 ) (3, 9) /4 (4, 6) (6, 8) /4 /2 (6, 4) Is there arbitrage in

More information

Lecture 22 Girsanov s Theorem

Lecture 22 Girsanov s Theorem Lecture 22: Girsanov s Theorem of 8 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 25 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 22 Girsanov s Theorem An example Consider a finite Gaussian random walk X n = n

More information

Portfolio Optimization with unobservable Markov-modulated drift process

Portfolio Optimization with unobservable Markov-modulated drift process Portfolio Optimization with unobservable Markov-modulated drift process Ulrich Rieder Department of Optimization and Operations Research University of Ulm, Germany D-89069 Ulm, Germany e-mail: rieder@mathematik.uni-ulm.de

More information

Mean-Variance Hedging for Continuous Processes: New Proofs and Examples

Mean-Variance Hedging for Continuous Processes: New Proofs and Examples Mean-Variance Hedging for Continuous Processes: New Proofs and Examples Huyên Pham Équipe d Analyse et de Mathématiques Appliquées Université de Marne-la-Vallée 2, rue de la Butte Verte F 9366 Noisy-le-Grand

More information

Utility Maximization in Hidden Regime-Switching Markets with Default Risk

Utility Maximization in Hidden Regime-Switching Markets with Default Risk Utility Maximization in Hidden Regime-Switching Markets with Default Risk José E. Figueroa-López Department of Mathematics and Statistics Washington University in St. Louis figueroa-lopez@wustl.edu pages.wustl.edu/figueroa

More information

I forgot to mention last time: in the Ito formula for two standard processes, putting

I forgot to mention last time: in the Ito formula for two standard processes, putting I forgot to mention last time: in the Ito formula for two standard processes, putting dx t = a t dt + b t db t dy t = α t dt + β t db t, and taking f(x, y = xy, one has f x = y, f y = x, and f xx = f yy

More information

Notes on Recursive Utility. Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in

Notes on Recursive Utility. Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in Notes on Recursive Utility Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in Section 1 (or Chapter 29, LeRoy & Werner, 2nd Ed.) Let u st be the continuation utility at s t. That

More information

A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations

A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations Michael Röckner Reference: C. Prevot, M. Röckner: Springer LN in Math. 1905, Berlin (2007) And see the references therein for the original

More information

Introduction Optimality and Asset Pricing

Introduction Optimality and Asset Pricing Introduction Optimality and Asset Pricing Andrea Buraschi Imperial College Business School October 2010 The Euler Equation Take an economy where price is given with respect to the numéraire, which is our

More information

Asymptotic arbitrage in large financial markets

Asymptotic arbitrage in large financial markets Finance Stochast. 2, 143 172 (1998) c Springer-Verlag 1998 Asymptotic arbitrage in large financial markets Yu.M. Kabanov 1, D.O. Kramkov 2 1 Central Economics and Mathematics Institute of the Russian Academy

More information

Super-replication and utility maximization in large financial markets

Super-replication and utility maximization in large financial markets Super-replication and utility maximization in large financial markets M. De Donno P. Guasoni, M. Pratelli, Abstract We study the problems of super-replication and utility maximization from terminal wealth

More information

Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market

Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market 1/51 Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market Ruodu Wang http://sas.uwaterloo.ca/ wang Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Waterloo

More information

Optimal Control. Macroeconomics II SMU. Ömer Özak (SMU) Economic Growth Macroeconomics II 1 / 112

Optimal Control. Macroeconomics II SMU. Ömer Özak (SMU) Economic Growth Macroeconomics II 1 / 112 Optimal Control Ömer Özak SMU Macroeconomics II Ömer Özak (SMU) Economic Growth Macroeconomics II 1 / 112 Review of the Theory of Optimal Control Section 1 Review of the Theory of Optimal Control Ömer

More information

1: PROBABILITY REVIEW

1: PROBABILITY REVIEW 1: PROBABILITY REVIEW Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 1: Probability Review 1 / 56 Outline We will review the following

More information

Market environments, stability and equlibria

Market environments, stability and equlibria Market environments, stability and equlibria Gordan Žitković Department of Mathematics University of exas at Austin Austin, Aug 03, 2009 - Summer School in Mathematical Finance he Information Flow two

More information

University Of Calgary Department of Mathematics and Statistics

University Of Calgary Department of Mathematics and Statistics University Of Calgary Department of Mathematics and Statistics Hawkes Seminar May 23, 2018 1 / 46 Some Problems in Insurance and Reinsurance Mohamed Badaoui Department of Electrical Engineering National

More information

A monetary value for initial information in portfolio optimization

A monetary value for initial information in portfolio optimization A monetary value for initial information in portfolio optimization this version: March 15, 2002; Jürgen Amendinger 1, Dirk Becherer 2, Martin Schweizer 3 1 HypoVereinsbank AG, International Markets, Equity

More information

A Barrier Version of the Russian Option

A Barrier Version of the Russian Option A Barrier Version of the Russian Option L. A. Shepp, A. N. Shiryaev, A. Sulem Rutgers University; shepp@stat.rutgers.edu Steklov Mathematical Institute; shiryaev@mi.ras.ru INRIA- Rocquencourt; agnes.sulem@inria.fr

More information

Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University

Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University TIME CONSISTENT RISK AVERSE DYNAMIC DECISION MODELS: AN ECONOMIC INTERPRETATION Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University brudloff@princeton.edu Alexandre Street

More information

Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman Equation of an Optimal Consumption Problem

Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman Equation of an Optimal Consumption Problem Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman Equation of an Optimal Consumption Problem Shuenn-Jyi Sheu Institute of Mathematics, Academia Sinica WSAF, CityU HK June 29-July 3, 2009 1. Introduction X c,π t is the wealth with

More information

Malliavin Calculus in Finance

Malliavin Calculus in Finance Malliavin Calculus in Finance Peter K. Friz 1 Greeks and the logarithmic derivative trick Model an underlying assent by a Markov process with values in R m with dynamics described by the SDE dx t = b(x

More information

UTILITY OPTIMIZATION IN A FINITE SCENARIO SETTING

UTILITY OPTIMIZATION IN A FINITE SCENARIO SETTING UTILITY OPTIMIZATION IN A FINITE SCENARIO SETTING J. TEICHMANN Abstract. We introduce the main concepts of duality theory for utility optimization in a setting of finitely many economic scenarios. 1. Utility

More information

OPTIMAL STOPPING OF A BROWNIAN BRIDGE

OPTIMAL STOPPING OF A BROWNIAN BRIDGE OPTIMAL STOPPING OF A BROWNIAN BRIDGE ERIK EKSTRÖM AND HENRIK WANNTORP Abstract. We study several optimal stopping problems in which the gains process is a Brownian bridge or a functional of a Brownian

More information

Harnack Inequalities and Applications for Stochastic Equations

Harnack Inequalities and Applications for Stochastic Equations p. 1/32 Harnack Inequalities and Applications for Stochastic Equations PhD Thesis Defense Shun-Xiang Ouyang Under the Supervision of Prof. Michael Röckner & Prof. Feng-Yu Wang March 6, 29 p. 2/32 Outline

More information

Generalized quantiles as risk measures

Generalized quantiles as risk measures Generalized quantiles as risk measures Bellini, Klar, Muller, Rosazza Gianin December 1, 2014 Vorisek Jan Introduction Quantiles q α of a random variable X can be defined as the minimizers of a piecewise

More information

Optimal Stopping Problems and American Options

Optimal Stopping Problems and American Options Optimal Stopping Problems and American Options Nadia Uys A dissertation submitted to the Faculty of Science, University of the Witwatersrand, in fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Master

More information

The Uses of Differential Geometry in Finance

The Uses of Differential Geometry in Finance The Uses of Differential Geometry in Finance Andrew Lesniewski Bloomberg, November 21 2005 The Uses of Differential Geometry in Finance p. 1 Overview Joint with P. Hagan and D. Woodward Motivation: Varadhan

More information

NOTES ON CALCULUS OF VARIATIONS. September 13, 2012

NOTES ON CALCULUS OF VARIATIONS. September 13, 2012 NOTES ON CALCULUS OF VARIATIONS JON JOHNSEN September 13, 212 1. The basic problem In Calculus of Variations one is given a fixed C 2 -function F (t, x, u), where F is defined for t [, t 1 ] and x, u R,

More information

Continuous Time Finance

Continuous Time Finance Continuous Time Finance Lisbon 2013 Tomas Björk Stockholm School of Economics Tomas Björk, 2013 Contents Stochastic Calculus (Ch 4-5). Black-Scholes (Ch 6-7. Completeness and hedging (Ch 8-9. The martingale

More information

Lectures for the Course on Foundations of Mathematical Finance

Lectures for the Course on Foundations of Mathematical Finance Definitions and properties of Lectures for the Course on Foundations of Mathematical Finance First Part: Convex Marco Frittelli Milano University The Fields Institute, Toronto, April 2010 Definitions and

More information

Proving the Regularity of the Minimal Probability of Ruin via a Game of Stopping and Control

Proving the Regularity of the Minimal Probability of Ruin via a Game of Stopping and Control Proving the Regularity of the Minimal Probability of Ruin via a Game of Stopping and Control Erhan Bayraktar University of Michigan joint work with Virginia R. Young, University of Michigan K αρλoβασi,

More information

Backward martingale representation and endogenous completeness in finance

Backward martingale representation and endogenous completeness in finance Backward martingale representation and endogenous completeness in finance Dmitry Kramkov (with Silviu Predoiu) Carnegie Mellon University 1 / 19 Bibliography Robert M. Anderson and Roberto C. Raimondo.

More information

On Minimal Entropy Martingale Measures

On Minimal Entropy Martingale Measures On Minimal Entropy Martingale Measures Andrii Andrusiv Friedrich Schiller University of Jena, Germany Marie Curie ITN Outline 1. One Period Model Definitions and Notations Minimal Entropy Martingale Measure

More information

Convex Stochastic Control and Conjugate Duality in a Problem of Unconstrained Utility Maximization Under a Regime Switching Model

Convex Stochastic Control and Conjugate Duality in a Problem of Unconstrained Utility Maximization Under a Regime Switching Model Convex Stochastic Control and Conjugate Duality in a Problem of Unconstrained Utility Maximization Under a Regime Switching Model by Aaron Xin Situ A thesis presented to the University of Waterloo in fulfilment

More information

The Codimension of the Zeros of a Stable Process in Random Scenery

The Codimension of the Zeros of a Stable Process in Random Scenery The Codimension of the Zeros of a Stable Process in Random Scenery Davar Khoshnevisan The University of Utah, Department of Mathematics Salt Lake City, UT 84105 0090, U.S.A. davar@math.utah.edu http://www.math.utah.edu/~davar

More information

Lecture 1: Entropy, convexity, and matrix scaling CSE 599S: Entropy optimality, Winter 2016 Instructor: James R. Lee Last updated: January 24, 2016

Lecture 1: Entropy, convexity, and matrix scaling CSE 599S: Entropy optimality, Winter 2016 Instructor: James R. Lee Last updated: January 24, 2016 Lecture 1: Entropy, convexity, and matrix scaling CSE 599S: Entropy optimality, Winter 2016 Instructor: James R. Lee Last updated: January 24, 2016 1 Entropy Since this course is about entropy maximization,

More information

Statistics 612: L p spaces, metrics on spaces of probabilites, and connections to estimation

Statistics 612: L p spaces, metrics on spaces of probabilites, and connections to estimation Statistics 62: L p spaces, metrics on spaces of probabilites, and connections to estimation Moulinath Banerjee December 6, 2006 L p spaces and Hilbert spaces We first formally define L p spaces. Consider

More information

1. Stochastic Processes and filtrations

1. Stochastic Processes and filtrations 1. Stochastic Processes and 1. Stoch. pr., A stochastic process (X t ) t T is a collection of random variables on (Ω, F) with values in a measurable space (S, S), i.e., for all t, In our case X t : Ω S

More information

Backward Stochastic Differential Equations with Infinite Time Horizon

Backward Stochastic Differential Equations with Infinite Time Horizon Backward Stochastic Differential Equations with Infinite Time Horizon Holger Metzler PhD advisor: Prof. G. Tessitore Università di Milano-Bicocca Spring School Stochastic Control in Finance Roscoff, March

More information

Portfolio Optimization in discrete time

Portfolio Optimization in discrete time Portfolio Optimization in discrete time Wolfgang J. Runggaldier Dipartimento di Matematica Pura ed Applicata Universitá di Padova, Padova http://www.math.unipd.it/runggaldier/index.html Abstract he paper

More information

Nonlinear representation, backward SDEs, and application to the Principal-Agent problem

Nonlinear representation, backward SDEs, and application to the Principal-Agent problem Nonlinear representation, backward SDEs, and application to the Principal-Agent problem Ecole Polytechnique, France April 4, 218 Outline The Principal-Agent problem Formulation 1 The Principal-Agent problem

More information

Financial Asset Price Bubbles under Model Uncertainty

Financial Asset Price Bubbles under Model Uncertainty Financial Asset Price Bubbles under Model Uncertainty Francesca Biagini, Jacopo Mancin October 24, 27 Abstract We study the concept of financial bubbles in a market model endowed with a set P of probability

More information

Robust Mean-Variance Hedging via G-Expectation

Robust Mean-Variance Hedging via G-Expectation Robust Mean-Variance Hedging via G-Expectation Francesca Biagini, Jacopo Mancin Thilo Meyer Brandis January 3, 18 Abstract In this paper we study mean-variance hedging under the G-expectation framework.

More information

4. Conditional risk measures and their robust representation

4. Conditional risk measures and their robust representation 4. Conditional risk measures and their robust representation We consider a discrete-time information structure given by a filtration (F t ) t=0,...,t on our probability space (Ω, F, P ). The time horizon

More information

The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1

The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1 The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1 Damir Filipović Gregor Svindland 3 November 2008 Abstract In this paper we establish a one-to-one correspondence between lawinvariant

More information

UNCERTAINTY FUNCTIONAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS FOR FINANCE

UNCERTAINTY FUNCTIONAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS FOR FINANCE Surveys in Mathematics and its Applications ISSN 1842-6298 (electronic), 1843-7265 (print) Volume 5 (2010), 275 284 UNCERTAINTY FUNCTIONAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS FOR FINANCE Iuliana Carmen Bărbăcioru Abstract.

More information

Economics 2010c: Lectures 9-10 Bellman Equation in Continuous Time

Economics 2010c: Lectures 9-10 Bellman Equation in Continuous Time Economics 2010c: Lectures 9-10 Bellman Equation in Continuous Time David Laibson 9/30/2014 Outline Lectures 9-10: 9.1 Continuous-time Bellman Equation 9.2 Application: Merton s Problem 9.3 Application:

More information

Minimization of ruin probabilities by investment under transaction costs

Minimization of ruin probabilities by investment under transaction costs Minimization of ruin probabilities by investment under transaction costs Stefan Thonhauser DSA, HEC, Université de Lausanne 13 th Scientific Day, Bonn, 3.4.214 Outline Introduction Risk models and controls

More information

Information and Credit Risk

Information and Credit Risk Information and Credit Risk M. L. Bedini Université de Bretagne Occidentale, Brest - Friedrich Schiller Universität, Jena Jena, March 2011 M. L. Bedini (Université de Bretagne Occidentale, Brest Information

More information

On continuous time contract theory

On continuous time contract theory Ecole Polytechnique, France Journée de rentrée du CMAP, 3 octobre, 218 Outline 1 2 Semimartingale measures on the canonical space Random horizon 2nd order backward SDEs (Static) Principal-Agent Problem

More information

An Uncertain Control Model with Application to. Production-Inventory System

An Uncertain Control Model with Application to. Production-Inventory System An Uncertain Control Model with Application to Production-Inventory System Kai Yao 1, Zhongfeng Qin 2 1 Department of Mathematical Sciences, Tsinghua University, Beijing 100084, China 2 School of Economics

More information

Lecture 4 Lebesgue spaces and inequalities

Lecture 4 Lebesgue spaces and inequalities Lecture 4: Lebesgue spaces and inequalities 1 of 10 Course: Theory of Probability I Term: Fall 2013 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 4 Lebesgue spaces and inequalities Lebesgue spaces We have seen how

More information

Tail dependence in bivariate skew-normal and skew-t distributions

Tail dependence in bivariate skew-normal and skew-t distributions Tail dependence in bivariate skew-normal and skew-t distributions Paola Bortot Department of Statistical Sciences - University of Bologna paola.bortot@unibo.it Abstract: Quantifying dependence between

More information

Mathematical Methods for Neurosciences. ENS - Master MVA Paris 6 - Master Maths-Bio ( )

Mathematical Methods for Neurosciences. ENS - Master MVA Paris 6 - Master Maths-Bio ( ) Mathematical Methods for Neurosciences. ENS - Master MVA Paris 6 - Master Maths-Bio (2014-2015) Etienne Tanré - Olivier Faugeras INRIA - Team Tosca November 26th, 2014 E. Tanré (INRIA - Team Tosca) Mathematical

More information

Solution of Stochastic Optimal Control Problems and Financial Applications

Solution of Stochastic Optimal Control Problems and Financial Applications Journal of Mathematical Extension Vol. 11, No. 4, (2017), 27-44 ISSN: 1735-8299 URL: http://www.ijmex.com Solution of Stochastic Optimal Control Problems and Financial Applications 2 Mat B. Kafash 1 Faculty

More information

University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming

University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists 1 of 63 University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming Peter J. Hammond Autumn 2013, revised 2014 University of

More information

Minimal entropy preserves the Lévy property: How and why

Minimal entropy preserves the Lévy property: How and why Minimal entropy preserves the Lévy property: How and why Felix Esche Technische Universität Berlin Institut für Mathematik, MA 7-4 Straße des 7. Juni 36 D 623 Berlin Germany and Martin Schweizer ETH Zürich

More information

Geometry and Optimization of Relative Arbitrage

Geometry and Optimization of Relative Arbitrage Geometry and Optimization of Relative Arbitrage Ting-Kam Leonard Wong joint work with Soumik Pal Department of Mathematics, University of Washington Financial/Actuarial Mathematic Seminar, University of

More information

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3 Brownian Motion Contents 1 Definition 2 1.1 Brownian Motion................................. 2 1.2 Wiener measure.................................. 3 2 Construction 4 2.1 Gaussian process.................................

More information

HOPF S DECOMPOSITION AND RECURRENT SEMIGROUPS. Josef Teichmann

HOPF S DECOMPOSITION AND RECURRENT SEMIGROUPS. Josef Teichmann HOPF S DECOMPOSITION AND RECURRENT SEMIGROUPS Josef Teichmann Abstract. Some results of ergodic theory are generalized in the setting of Banach lattices, namely Hopf s maximal ergodic inequality and the

More information

EQUITY MARKET STABILITY

EQUITY MARKET STABILITY EQUITY MARKET STABILITY Adrian Banner INTECH Investment Technologies LLC, Princeton (Joint work with E. Robert Fernholz, Ioannis Karatzas, Vassilios Papathanakos and Phillip Whitman.) Talk at WCMF6 conference,

More information

Conjugate duality in stochastic optimization

Conjugate duality in stochastic optimization Ari-Pekka Perkkiö, Institute of Mathematics, Aalto University Ph.D. instructor/joint work with Teemu Pennanen, Institute of Mathematics, Aalto University March 15th 2010 1 / 13 We study convex problems.

More information

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING 218. HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROF. YURI BAKHTIN Instructions. You are allowed to work on solutions in groups, but you are required to write up solutions on your own. Please

More information

OPTIONAL DECOMPOSITION FOR CONTINUOUS SEMIMARTINGALES UNDER ARBITRARY FILTRATIONS. Introduction

OPTIONAL DECOMPOSITION FOR CONTINUOUS SEMIMARTINGALES UNDER ARBITRARY FILTRATIONS. Introduction OPTIONAL DECOMPOSITION FOR CONTINUOUS SEMIMARTINGALES UNDER ARBITRARY FILTRATIONS IOANNIS KARATZAS AND CONSTANTINOS KARDARAS Abstract. We present an elementary treatment of the Optional Decomposition Theorem

More information

Least Squares Estimators for Stochastic Differential Equations Driven by Small Lévy Noises

Least Squares Estimators for Stochastic Differential Equations Driven by Small Lévy Noises Least Squares Estimators for Stochastic Differential Equations Driven by Small Lévy Noises Hongwei Long* Department of Mathematical Sciences, Florida Atlantic University, Boca Raton Florida 33431-991,

More information

Gaussian Processes. 1. Basic Notions

Gaussian Processes. 1. Basic Notions Gaussian Processes 1. Basic Notions Let T be a set, and X : {X } T a stochastic process, defined on a suitable probability space (Ω P), that is indexed by T. Definition 1.1. We say that X is a Gaussian

More information

On John type ellipsoids

On John type ellipsoids On John type ellipsoids B. Klartag Tel Aviv University Abstract Given an arbitrary convex symmetric body K R n, we construct a natural and non-trivial continuous map u K which associates ellipsoids to

More information

An Introduction to Malliavin calculus and its applications

An Introduction to Malliavin calculus and its applications An Introduction to Malliavin calculus and its applications Lecture 3: Clark-Ocone formula David Nualart Department of Mathematics Kansas University University of Wyoming Summer School 214 David Nualart

More information

Estimates for probabilities of independent events and infinite series

Estimates for probabilities of independent events and infinite series Estimates for probabilities of independent events and infinite series Jürgen Grahl and Shahar evo September 9, 06 arxiv:609.0894v [math.pr] 8 Sep 06 Abstract This paper deals with finite or infinite sequences

More information