The δ-core and Stable Partitions in Asymmetric Oligopolies

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The δ-core and Stable Partitions in Asymmetric Oligopolies"

Transcription

1 The δ-core and Stable Partitions in Asymmetric Oligopolies By Jingang Zhao * February 2009 Department of Economics University of Saskatchewan 9 Campus Drive Saskatoon, Saskatchewan CANADA S7N 5A5 Tel: (306) Fax: (306) j.zhao@usask.ca Abstract: This paper solves merger formation problem in Cournot oligopolies by a cooperative and computational approach. In three-firm linear oligopolies, monopoly will be formed (or be stable) if its merging cost is sufficiently low and cost differentials are sufficiently large. When monopoly is unprofitable due to high merging costs, a profitable two-member merger will be formed if its efficient member receives a sufficiently large share of the merger s gain and cost differentials are sufficiently small. In n-firm linear oligopolies, monopoly will be formed if number of firms and merging costs both are sufficiently small and cost differentials are sufficiently large. JEL Classification Number: C62, C71, C72, D43, L10 Keywords: Core, δ-core, Cournot equilibrium, hybrid equilibrium, merger analysis, stable partition * This paper replaces an earlier working paper titled A Stable Market Structure as the Solution for Cournot Oligopolies (2002). I would like to thank Andreas Blume, Donald Smythe, and seminar participants at American U., Australian National U., Iowa State U., U. Kansas, U. Melbourne, U. Missouri, U. Saskatchewan, and 2001 NASMES at U. Maryland for comments on the earlier draft. All errors, of course, are my own.

2 1. Introduction Consider the four possible mergers in an asymmetric oligopoly with three firms: 123; 12, 13 and 23. Which one, if any, will be formed and be free of subsequent breakups or new mergers? Although the question seems fairly simple, it is one of the most fundamental questions in both game theory and industrial organization that has not been thoroughly studied prior to this study. This paper provides a complete answer for linear Cournot oligopolies by studying stable partition or stable market structure, which is defined as a set of simultaneous mergers that are free of profitable subsequent mergers or breakups. Briefly answering the question (in order), monopoly will be formed if monopoly merging cost is low and the two inefficient firms are sufficiently small; and each of the twomember mergers will be formed if i) it is profitable; ii) monopoly is unprofitable (due to high merging cost); iii) efficient member s share of the merger s gain is sufficiently large; and iv) the inefficient member is not too small. The paper provides complete characterizations for each of the five partitions to be stable over the space of three firm linear oligopolies. Next, it provides complete characterizations for stable monopoly in two classes of n- firm linear oligopolies. Finally, the paper provides computational characterizations for stable partitions in general n-firm oligopolies. Our cooperative and computational approach has two advantages over the previous literature. First, it allows us to investigate how asymmetry such as cost differentials affect a stable partition, while most previous works, in both cooperative (e.g., Yong [2004], Funaki and Yamato [1999] and Rajan [1989]) and non-cooperative (see Yong [2004] and Ray and Vohra [1999] for short surveys) approaches, have assumed that players have symmetric or identical payoff functions. Second, it allows us to study the effect 2

3 of merging cost (the cost of coalition formation) 1 on stable partitions, which has not been studied in the previous literature. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the model and merger contacts; section 3 defines the δ-core and stable partitions; and section 4 characterizes stability in three firm linear oligopolies. Section 5 extends the results to n-firm markets, section 6 concludes, and the appendix provides proofs. 2. Description of the model and merger contracts A linear Cournot oligopoly for a homogeneous good is given by a linear inverse demand p(σ x j )=a Σ x j and n linear cost functions: C i (x i )=c i x i, 0 q i z i, i=1,,n, which can be defined by a (2n+1)-vector (a,c,z) R 2n+1 ++, with a>0 as the intercept of inverse demand, c=(c 1,.., c n )>> 0 as vector of marginal costs, and z=(z 1,.., z n )>> 0 as vector of capacities. Without loss of generality, assume c 1... c n, so firm 1 is most efficient and firm n is least efficient. Alternatively, the above model is equivalent to the following normal form game: Γ = {N, Z i, π i }, (1) where N={1, 2,..., n} is the set of firms; for each firm i N, Z i =[0, z i ] is its production set bounded by its capacity z i >0, and π i (x)=p(σ x j )x i C i (x i )=(a Σ x j c i )x i is its profit function. We assume that each merger generates a weak synergy denoted as the following A0: A0 (Assumption 0): (i) For each merger S N, its capacity and cost function are: z S =Σ j S z j, C S (q)= c S q, q z S, where c S = Min{c j j S}; and (2) (ii) at any equilibrium, the optimal supply by each S N is an interior solution. 1 A major part of merging costs is the fee paid to accounting firms to access the value of targeted firms, which runs from 3% to 9% of the targeted firm s value. 3

4 Under A0, a merger removes inefficient members and raises the efficient member s capacity to z S. For each non-monopoly merger S N, its guaranteed (or worst) profit is: 2 v(s) = MaxMin x S which defines a coalitional game y -S Σ i S π i (x S, y -S ) = Min y -S Max x S Σ i S π i (x S, y -S ), Γ C ={N, v}, (3) where the Min in v(s) is taken over Z -S = j S Z j, the Max over {x S R S + Σ j Sx j z S }, (x S,y -S )=w is a vector with w i =x i if i S, =y i if i S, and v(n)=π is the monopoly profits. The core of monopoly merger or the core of (1) is the core of (3), which is denoted as Core(Γ ) ={λ R n + Σλ i=π, and Σ i Sλ i v(s), all S N }. (4) In words, a profit vector is in the monopoly s core if it splits the monopoly profits in such a way that it is unblocked by each non-monopoly merger. Let x denote monopoly supply. Define a monopoly merger contract as a pair (x ;λ) of the monopoly s supply and a split of its profits. Then, a precondition for each monopoly merger contract (x ;λ) is that λ Core(Γ ). Zhao (2001) showed the equivalence between Core(Γ ) and v(n) MNBP, where MNBP is the minimum no-blocking payoff given by 3 2 In more general situations, one would have v α (S) = MaxMinΣ i S π i (x S, y -S ) < v β (S) = MinMaxΣ i S π i (x S, y -S ), x S y -S y -S x S which implies β-core α-core (Aumann [1959], Scarf [1971]). Since α-core = β-core holds in an oligopoly (Zhao, 1999), there is no need to make the α- and β-distinction here and one can simply use the term core. 3 The non-empty core and profitability preconditions are independent of each other. As an example, let n=3, (a;c;z)=(6; 0.5,0.5,0.5; 2,2,2),and merging costs be MC N =2, MC S =0, S N. Then, π i =1.89, π m =7.56, MNBP=4.59<v(N)=(π m -MC N )=5.56<Σπ i =5.67, so monopoly has a non-empty core and is unprofitable. 4

5 MNBP(Γ) = Min Σx i subject to x R n + ;Σ i Sx i v(s) for all S N. (5) As readers will see, one major task in this study is to obtain the precise expressions of MNBP in terms of the parameter vector (a,c,z). Bain (1959) defined market structure as the number and size distribution of firms. In contrast, we define market structure as the number and size distribution of mergers or a set of simultaneous mergers, which is a partition of the firms Δ={S 1,...,S J } (i.e., S j =N, S i S j = for all i j). A market structure Δ assumes that binding contracts are, at the time of consideration, available for each merger S Δ and unavailable for all other mergers T Δ. Given a partition Δ, let ~ x (Δ) = {x ~ S(Δ) S Δ} and π ~ (Δ) = {π ~ S(Δ) S Δ} be the unique post-merger supply and profit vectors. 4 Then, a merger contract for Δ is a list of pairs {x ~ S(Δ); λ S (Δ)} of post-merger supply and split of post-merger profits (i.e., λ S 0, Σ j S λ j =π ~ S(Δ)) for each merger S Δ. The non-empty core precondition requires that each λ S be in the core of S, or equivalently, in the core of the following normal form game: Γ S (x ~ -S) = {S, Z i, π i (x S, x ~ -S)}, (6) where π i (x S, x ~ -S) = (a Σ j S x j Σ j S x ~ j c i )x i, i S, are parameterized by the fixed x ~ -S. Note that the core for each S Δ is only defined for the fixed outsiders supply x ~ -S (Δ). Otherwise, the problem of dividing its post-merger profits would not exist. At the postmerger equilibrium, each merger S Δ splits its profits within its core, so the merger contract (x ~ (Δ), λ(δ)) = {(x ~ S,λ S ) S Δ} specifies a hybrid equilibrium (Zhao, 1992). 4 x ~ (Δ) satisfies: for each S Δ, 0 Σ j S x ~ j z S, π ~ S (Δ) = Σ j Sπ j (x ~ S, x ~ -S) π S (y S ; x ~ -S) for all 0 Σ j S y j z S. 5

6 As shown in Figure 1, the spectrum of hybrid equilibria includes the core of monopoly merger (for Δ m = {N}) and Cournot equilibrium (for Δ 0 = {(1),..., (n)}) as its two end points, which will be endogenized as a stable partition in the next three sections. k =1 Monopoly k =2 Duopoly 2 < k < (n-1) O ther O ligo po lies k = (n-1) Single merger with S = 2 k = n Cournot Structure Δ m = {N} Δ = {S, N/S} Δ = {S1,..., Sk } Δ = {S, i1,..., in-2} Δ 0 = {1,..., n} k Number of Coalitions Binding c o ntra ct fo r N Binding contracts for each T Δ N o binding contract the Co re (non-degenerate) H yb rid Eq uilib ria for each Δ Cournot/Nash Equil Figure 1. The spectrum of hybrid equilib ria, where k (1 k n ) is th e n u mb e r o f c o a litio n s in Δ. 3. δ-core as a special case of stable partitions Let Π be the set of partitions of N. For each Δ Π, its unique post-merger profits π ~ (Δ) ={π ~ T(Δ) T Δ} convert (1) into a partition function game (Thrall and Lucas, 1963): Γ PF = {N, φ}, (7) which specifies a joint profit φ(t,δ) = π ~ T(Δ) for each merger T Δ and each partition Δ Π. Given Δ and its merger contract (x ~ (Δ),λ(Δ))={(x ~ T,λ T ) T Δ}, consider the deviation by (or possible formation of) a different merger S Δ (this implicitly assumes that binding contracts now are available to S and all of its proper sub-coalitions). Let Π(S) = {B Π B = {S, T 1,..., T m }}, (8) denote the set of partitions of which S is a member. S has incentives to move to B Π(S) if φ(s,b)=π ~ S(B)>Σ j S λ j (Δ). Hence, "whether S Δ will deviate from Δ" or whether a new 6

7 merger S Δ will be formed depends on two factors: i) its members current profits on the contract λ(δ), and ii) its joint profits at the new partition B Π(S). In reality, merger contracts, although binding, usually have clauses allowing members to break up the deal under penalty and specifying how the remaining members will react to a breakup. Two common reactions to a breakup (Hart and Kurz, 1983) are: i) remaining members breakup into singletons, and ii) remaining members remain loyal to each other and stay together as a smaller coalition, which are formally given as below: B δ (S,Δ) = {S, T δ 1,..., Tδ } Π(S) (for loyal belief), and m(δ) (9) B γ(s,δ) = {S, T γ 1,..., Tγ } Π(S) (for breakup belief), m(γ) (10) where for j = 1,, m(δ), T δ j = T /S = {i i T, i S} for some T Δ; and for i = 1,, m(γ), T γ i = T for some T Δ with S T=, = (i j ) T for some T Δ with S T. As an example, for Δ={1,(2,3,4,5)} and S=(1,2), one has: Bγ(S,Δ)={(1,2), 3, 4, 5}, B δ (S,Δ)={(1,2), (3, 4, 5)}. In addition to the above two beliefs, another well known belief is the worst partition (among Π(S)) based on cautious belief as given below: 5 B α (S,Δ) B α (S) = {S, T α 1,..., Tα m(α) } Π(S) (for cautious belief), (11) which is the solution of Min{φ(S,B) B Π(S)}. Note that the above worst partition for S is independent of the current partition Δ. Definition 1 below defines stable partitions. Definition 1: A partition Δ is α- (γ-;δ-) stable or stable under the cautious (breakup; loyal) belief if it has a merger contract (x ~ (Δ),λ(Δ)) such that for all S Δ, Σ j S λ j (Δ) 5 Yong (2004) introduces the efficient-belief, under which outsiders choose the efficient one among all partitions of N\S. Let v γ (S), v δ (S), v e (S) denote the value of S under δ-, γ- and e- beliefs; and X γ, X δ, and X e the associated payoffs. Then, v e (S) v γ (S), v δ (S) v γ (S)>v(S) and v e (S) v δ (S) lead to {X e X δ } X γ Core. 7

8 φ(s,bα(s)) ( φ(s,bγ(s,δ)); φ(s,bδ(s,δ))), where φ, B α, B γ, and Bδ are given in (7)-(11). To put it differently, mergers in Δ will be formed in the α- (γ-, δ-) fashion if no other merger S could make more profits by moving to B α (S) (B γ (S,Δ), B δ (S,Δ)). Because all profitable breakups and mergers are ruled out, a stable partition or a stable market structure is a candidate for the solution of oligopoly markets. For each market structure Δ, let X α (Δ), X γ (Δ), and X δ (Δ) (12) denote respectively the sets of its α-, γ- and δ- stable profit vectors (or precisely sets of profit vectors in its α-, γ- and δ- stable merger contacts). Two remarks about (12) are in order. First, we refer the above X γ (Δ m ) and X δ (Δ m ) as the monopoly s γ- and δ-core (or the γ- and δ-core of (1)), where Δ m = {N} is the grand coalition or the coarsest partition. If Δ is not the grand coalition, it will be improper to apply the term core to the payoffs in (12) because core is reserved for the grand coalition. Hence, for Δ Δ m, the payoffs in (12) will be referred as the α-, γ- and δ-stable payoffs of Δ, respectively. Second, it will also be improper to refer X α (Δ m ) as the α-core because the term α-core has been used already (i.e., the core in (4) is the α-core). Therefore, we refer X α (Δ m ) as the monopoly s α-stable payoff. The difference between X α (Δ m ) and the α-core is that there exist strategic interactions between each S and its outsiders N\S in X α (Δ m ), while there are no such interactions in the a-core. Proposition 1 below summarizes the relationship among the above stability concepts. Proposition 1: Given a market structure Δ of (1), let Core(Γ), X α (Δ), X γ (Δ), and X δ (Δ) be given in (4) and (12), respectively. Then, the following two claims hold: (i) X δ (Δ) X γ (Δ) X α (Δ) Core(Γ); and (ii) X δ (Δ m ) X γ (Δ m ) = X α (Δ m ) Core(Γ). 8

9 By the proposition, δ-stability is stronger than γ-stability, which is stronger than the α-stability, and they are all refinements of the core, whose existence has been reported in Norde et al (2002) and Zhao (2009). 6 Part (ii) shows that the monopoly s α-and γ-stabilities are identical, because each S has the lowest profits when the outsiders are singletons. Although one might favor one version of stability over another, only future empirical evidences could determine which version is the most appropriate one. 4. Stable market structures with three asymmetric firms This section characterizes the stability for each of the five partitions of (1) with n = 3, which is given by (a; c; z) = (a; c 1, c 2, c 3 ; z 1, z 2, z 3 ) R 7 ++ (c 1 c 2 c 3 ). It is useful to begin with three observations. First, there is no need to make the α and γ- distinction for a stable monopoly because its α- and γ-stable sets are identical. Second, although the three-firm model seems to be restrictive at first glance, evaluating its stability in seven dimensional space is extremely complicated and challenging. Fortunately, we are able to simplify the problem from seven dimensions to two dimensions by assuming A0 and by introducing two intermediate variables: ε 2 = (c 2 -c 1 )/(a-c 1 ) and ε 3 = (c 3 -c 1 )/(a-c 1 ), (13) which represent firm 1 s relative cost advantages over firms 2 and 3. The usual assumptions imply ε 2 ε 3 0.5, so all possible cases are covered by the area above the 45 0 line (see figures 2-4). A large ε 2 represents large cost differentials (or the two inefficient firms are small), and a small ε 3 represents small cost differentials (or the most inefficient firm is not too small). 6 See Bejan and Gómez (2009), Yong (2004), Funaki and Yamato (1999), and Rajan (1989) for related core refinements. 9

10 Even with such simplification, it would have been impossible to carry out this study without mathematical software (see (21) or Figure 5 or the long proof of Lemma 1 for a taste of its complexity). In deed, the involved polynomial equations are solved by Scientific WorkPlace, and all analytical predictions are confirmed separately by numerical examples using Excel. 7 Third, our model is also sufficiently general to analyze the effects of cost differentials, internal allocation and merging costs on stable partitions, which is a major advantage over symmetric models whose predictions will generally collapse in the presence of asymmetry (see Stamatopoulos and Tauman [2009] for an example of such collapse). The monopoly s stability and optimality are characterized by comparing ε 3 against the following two functions of ε 2, respectively: ω 1 (ε 2 ) = {2 1+8ε 2-20ε 2 2 }/4, and (14) ω 2 = ω 2 (ε 2 ) = (7+31ε 2 )/69. (15) Here, the optimal partition Δ* is optimal in the sense of second best, as it has the maximal welfare W* (= total profits + consumer surplus) among the five partitions. Proposition 2: Under A0, the following two claims hold: (i) Δ m = {123} is always α- stable; (ii) Δ m is δ-stable ε 3 ω 1 (ε 2 ), and ε 3 ω 1 (ε 2 ) always holds if ε 2 [1/6, 1/2]. By Proposition 2, monopoly will be formed in δ fashion if firms 2 and 3 have very small market shares (e.g., ε 3 ε 2 1/6), and it will be formed in α fashion but not δ fashion if firms 2 and 3 have similar and sizable market shares (i.e., ε 3 <ω 1 (ε 2 )), which are illustrated by Regions I and II in Figure 2a. In particular, Δ m will not be formed in δ fashion in 7 The Excel program is available from the author to readers for their classroom use or future research. 10

11 symmetric markets (i.e., ε 2 =ε 3 =0). 8 ε Part (a) always δ-stable ε Part (b) ΙΙΙ: Δ* = Δ m ΙΙ: Δ* = Δ 1 or Δ ΙΙ: δ-stable ω 1 (ε 2 ) 0.18 ω 2(ε 2) Ι: δ-unstable 0.10 Ι : Δ* = Δ /6.17 1/2 =.5 ε ε 2 7/ / /2 =.5 Figure 2. (a) The δ-stability of Δ m = {123}; (b) the optimal partitions for n = 3. In both parts, the feasible region is in the area above the 45 0 line. Proposition 3: Under A0, Δ* and W* are given by: Δ*= Δ m = {123} if 5/22 ε 2 1/2 Δ 1 ={1;23} or Δ 2 ={13;2} if 7/38<ε 2 <5/22 or if ε 2 7/38 & ε 3 ω 2 Δ 0 = {1; 2; 3} if ε 2 7/38; ε 3 < ω 2 ; (16) 3(a-c 1) 2 /8 if 5/22 ε 2 1/2 W* = (a-c 1 ) 2 (8-8ε 2 +11ε 22 )/18 if 7/38<ε 2 <5/22 or if ε 2 7/38 & ε 3 ω 2 (a-c 1 ) 2 [15-10(ε 2 +ε 3 )-18ε 2 ε 3 +23(ε 22 +ε 32 )]/32 if ε 2 7/38; ε 3 < ω 2. (17) Propositions 2 and 3 lead directly to the following corollary: Corollary 1: If ε 2 5/22, Δ m = {123} is both δ-stable and socially optimal. Hence, monopoly is both δ stable and optimal if cost savings are sufficiently large (i.e., ε 2 5/22>1/6). In such cases, no anti-trust regulation is needed as monopoly is the best market structure. These are illustrated in Figure 2b and in Example 1 below. 8 Rajan (1989) reported such symmetric case with n=3 and n=4. 11

12 Example 1: For (a; c; z) = (6; 0.5, 1, 1.2; 2, 2, 2), one has: ε 2 = 0.09, ε 3 = 0.127, ω 1 = 0.19, ω 2 = By ε 3 < ω 1 and Proposition 2, Δ m is δ-unstable. By ε 2 < 7/38 and ε 3 < ω 2, and by (16), Δ 0 is optimal. Let costs be increased to c=(0.5, 1.9, 2) and (a, z) be unchanged, then ε 2 = 0.26 > 5/22. By Corollary 1, monopoly now is both δ-stable and optimal. Proposition 2 is proved by computing the MNBP defined in (5), which allows us to analyze the effects of merging costs (or costs of coalition formation) on the stability of each partition. For each S N, let MC S denote its merging costs (synergy if negative). Since an analysis of MC S > 0 for S N requires a separate study, we only study the effects of monopoly merging costs under the following assumption: A1 (Assumption 1): MC N 0, and MC S = 0 for all S N. Corollary 2: Under A0 and A1, Δ m = {123} is α-(δ-) stable MC N [v(n)-mnbp α ] ([v(n)-mnbp δ ]), where v(n), MNBP α and MNBP δ are given in (A10-A16) in appendix. Hence, large monopoly merging costs will weaken monopoly s stability, and the difference between monopoly s profits and its MNBP defines an upper bound for its merging costs above which they will destroy the formation of monopoly merger, see Zhao (2009) on the estimation of such merging costs. Another advantage of the MNBP method is that it allows us to analyze whether a monopoly will remain stable in face of outside perturbations (i.e., its external stability). Corollary 3: Under A0-A1, an α-(δ-) stable monopoly remains as a stable monopoly for small perturbations in market parameters MC N < [v(n)-mnbp α ] ([v(n)-mnbp δ ]). 9 In other words, a monopoly merger will unravel in the face of small perturbations if it 9 Precisely, a stable Δ m in (a, c, z) = t R 7 ++ remains stable against small perturbations if there exists ε >0 such that Δ m is stable for all t B ε (t), where for t R 7, B ε (t) = {y R 7 t y < ε} and t 2 = Σt 2 i. 12

13 is unstable or if it is stable with MC N =[v(n)-mnbp α ] (=[v(n)-mnbp δ ]). It is straightforward to extend Corollaries 2 and 3 on merging costs and sensitivity to non-monopoly partitions, we therefore will skip such extensions in the rest of this paper. We now study the stability of Δ 1 ={1;23}, Δ 2 ={13;2}, and Δ 3 ={12;3}. Because the α-, γ- and δ-stabilities for each Δ i (i = 1, 2, 3) are identical (though they are different for Δ m and for n>3), there is no need to make such distinction here. The outsiders or the single firms post-merger profits at each Δ i are equal to π ~ 1(Δ 1 ) = (a-c 1 ) 2 (1+ε 2 ) 2 /9, π ~ 2(Δ 2 ) = (a-c 1 ) 2 (1-2ε 2 ) 2 /9, and π ~ 3(Δ 3 ) = (a-c 1 ) 2 (1-2ε 3 ) 2 /9. (18) Denote the merger s gain for each S = {12}, {13} and {23} by d 12 = π ~ 12(Δ 3 ) ( π 1 +π 2 ), d 13 = π ~ 13(Δ 2 ) ( π 1 +π 3 ), d 23 = π ~ 23(Δ 1 ) (π 2 +π 3 ); (19) and denote the efficient member s share of the above gains by t [0, 1]. Then, the three dimensional post-merger profit vector λ(t) for each Δ i can be given as for Δ 1, λ 1 = π ~ 1(Δ 1 ), λ 2 = π 2 + t d 23, and λ 3 = π 3 + (1-t) d 23 ; for Δ 2, λ 1 = π 1 + t d 13, λ 2 = π ~ 2(Δ 2 ), and λ 3 = π 3 + (1-t) d 13 ; and for Δ 3, λ 1 = π 1 + t d 12, λ 2 = π 2 + (1-t)d 12, and λ 3 = π ~ 3(Δ 3 ). (20) The stability of each Δ i requires two preconditions: its merger S is profitable (i.e., d S >0) and monopoly is unprofitable due to high merging costs (i.e., (v(n)-mc N )<Σλ j ). Under these two preconditions, the stability of each Δ i is determined by the magnitude of cost differential ε i and by the size of the share t, which are captured by a critical level μ i (ε i,t) given in appendix: μ 1 (ε 2,t) in (C14), μ 2 (ε 2,t) in (C16), and μ 3 (ε 3,t) = μ 2 (ε 3,t). Proposition 4: Given (a,c,z) R 7 ++, suppose Σλ j>(v(n)-mc N ) and d S >0 for each S = 13

14 12, 13, 23. Under A0 and A1, the following three claims hold: (i) Δ 1 = {1; 23} with λ(t) is stable ε 3 μ 1 (ε 2,t); ε 3 μ 1 (ε 2,t) holds if 0 ε 2 1/11; and ε 3 > μ 1 (ε 2,t) holds if 113/316< ε 2 ½. (ii) Δ 2 = {13; 2} with λ(t) is stable ε 3 μ 2 (ε 2,t). Let e 2 (t) = (2t-9)/[14(2t-3)]. Then, ε 3 μ 2 (ε 2,t) holds if 0 ε 2 < 1/11; ε 3 > μ 2 (ε 2,t) holds if e 2 (t)< ε 2 ½. (iii) Δ 3 = {12; 3} with λ(t) is stable ε 2 μ 3 (ε 3,t); and it holds if 0 ε 3 3/14. To see the intuition of these results, let us focus our attention on Δ 1 ={1;23} with λ(t) = {π ~ 1(Δ 1 ), π 2 +td 23, π 3 +(1-t)d 23 }. Because Δ 0 and Δ m are ruled out by preconditions and Δ 2 ={13,2} has the same profits of Δ 1, the only possible deviation is Δ 3 ={12,3}, when firm 2 breaks up T={23} and merges with firm 1. In this light, part (i) is transparent: since a larger share of d 23 by firm 2 or a smaller ε 3 makes the deviation from Δ 1 to Δ 3 less profitable for S={12}, Δ 1 with λ(t) will be stable with a smaller ε 3 or a larger t, or precisely ε 3 μ 1 (ε 2,t) holds (note μ 1 (ε 2,t) is increasing in t 10 ). Indeed, inverting t in μ 1 (ε 2,t)=ε 3 yields t 1 (ε 2, ε 3 ) = 1 2 7ε 32-97ε ε 2 ε 3 +14ε 3 +22ε ε ε ε 2 ε 3-18ε 3 +14ε 2 +1, (21) which leads to an alternative characterization for the stability of Δ 1 given below: Corollary 4: Let ε 2 [1/11, 113/316]. Then, Δ 1 with λ(t) is stable t t 1 (ε 2,ε 3 ). Hence, internal cooperation within a merger (or the share t) is a key determinant for merger stability. The set of markets with a stable Δ 1 is given by Region I in Figure 3a, where the feasible region is bounded by θ 0 and θ 6 (see (A6) in appendix) due to preconditions. Similarly, Region I in Figures 3b and 4 represent markets in which Δ 2 and Δ 3 are stable, 10 μ 1 (ε 2,t) could be increasing or decreasing in ε 2 (see Figure 3a), so the effects of ε 2 are ambiguous. 14

15 respectively. 11 The stability of Δ 1 is also illustrated numerically by Example 2 below: Example 2: Let (a;c;z)=(6;0.5,1.05,2.46;3,3,3), then ε 2 =0.1, ε 3 =0.356, (π 1,π 2,π 3 ) =(4.01,2.11,0.002),(π ~ 1,π ~ 23)=(4.067,2.152),t 1 (ε 2,ε 3 )=0.12. Hence, t=0.1 or λ(0.1)=(4.067, 2.114,0.038) is unstable, and t=0.2 or λ(0.2)=(4.067,2.118,0.034) is stable. If c 3 rises so ε 3 = 0.358, then t 1 (ε 2,ε 3 ) becomes t 1 (0.1,0.358)=0.45, so t=0.2 or λ(0.2) is now unstable. 0.5 ε 3 Part (a) 0.5 ε 3 Part (b) μ 1 ( ε 2,0) θ 0 (ε 2 ) μ 2 ( ε 2,0) θ 0 (ε 2 ) II: unstable 0.36 II: uns table I: stable θ 6 (ε 2 ) I: stable θ 4 (ε 2 ) 1/ / / ε 2 1/15 0 1/ = e 2 (0) 0.5 ε 2 Figure 3. (a) Stability of Δ 1, feas ib le reg io n is Max{ε 2, θ 6 } ε 3 θ 0 ; (b) s ta b ility of Δ 2, feas ib le reg io n is Max{ε 2, θ 4 } ε 3 θ 0. In both cases, t is set at ε 3 θ 2 (ε 2 ) θ 0 (ε 2 ) μ 5 ( ε 2,0) II:.293 unstable 3/ I: stable μ 50 ( ε 2,0) ε2 0 1/ Figure 4. The Stability of Δ 3, fe a s ib le re g io n is ε 2 ε 3 M in{θ 0,θ 2 }, t is set at 0, and μ 3 ( ε 3,0) is represented by μ 5 (ε 2,0) an d μ 50 (ε 2,0 ). Finally, we now know that the original Cournot structure Δ 0 = {1; 2; 3} is stable if 11 Figure 4 shows the two solutions of ε 3 in ε 2 =μ 3 (ε 3, t): ε 3 =μ 5 (ε 2, t) ε 3 =μ 50 (ε 2, t), and the minimum of μ 3 (ε 3, t) is ε * 2(t)=Min{μ 3 (ε 3, t) ε 3 }=μ 3 (ε * 3(t), t), where ε * 2(0)=0.179 and ε * 3(0)= Then, part (iii) becomes: λ(t) is stable if (a) ε 2 ε * 2(t), or (b) ε 2 >ε * 2(t),ε 3 ε * 3(t),ε 3 μ 50 (ε 2, t); or (c) ε 2 >ε * 2(t), ε 3 >ε * 3(t), ε 3 μ 5 (ε 2,t). 15

16 and only if none of the four mergers are profitable, which is given by the corollary below: Corollary 5: Δ 0 = {1; 2; 3} is stable if and only if the following (22) holds: θ 2 < ε 3 θ 4, and (v(n)- MC N ) < (π 1 + π 2 + π 3 ). (22) p(x) = (a-σxj), C i (x i ) = c i x i ; ε 2 = (c 2 -c 1 )/(a-c 1 ), ε3 = (c 3 -c 1 )/(a-c 1 ); θ 0 = (1+ε 2 )/ 3, θ 2 = 15ε 2-1, θ 4 = (1+ε 2 )/ 15, θ 6 = (1+13ε 2 )/ 15; ρ 1 = (5-11ε 2 )/11, ρ 5 = ( /2 )/ θ 4 θ 6 θ 0 θ 4 θ 6 θ 0 θ 4 θ 6 θ 0 θ 4 θ 6 θ 0 ε 2 θ 2 ρ 1 ε 2 ρ 1 θ 2 ρ 5.22 ε 2 θ 2 ρ 1 θ 4 θ 6 θ 0 θ 4 θ 6 θ 0 ρ 1 ε 2 θ 2 0 ε θ 2 ε 2 ρ 2 ρ 1 θ 2 1 1/ / / / /22.23 d 12 < 0 d 12 > 0 ε 3 < θ 2 d 12 > 0 1/2 =.5 ε2 d 13 > 0 ε 3 > θ 4 d 13 > 0 d 23 > 0 ε 3 > θ 6 Figure 5. The profitability for n = 3 and the relations among its parameters. As shown in Figure 5, Δ 0 will always be unstable if ε 2 1/14, because θ 4 <θ 2 (or d 13 >0) holds for all ε 2 [1/14, 1/2]. To summarize our conclusions for three-firm Cournot oligopolies, monopoly will be the solution if it is profitable and the two inefficient firms are sufficiently small (i.e., ε 2 is large). 12 When monopoly is ruled out by high merging costs, a profitable duopoly will be the solution if cost differentials are small (i.e., ε 3 is small). Finally, Cournot equilibrium will be the solution if none of the four mergers is profitable. 5. Extensions to markets with n firms Recall that monopoly s α- and γ-stabilities are identical, so we only need to check the 12 Otherwise, there will be no solution, as market structure could move cyclically among the five partitions (i.e., Δ m will be formed, broken up, and then formed again). This generates a new form of business 16

17 α- and δ-stabilities of Δ m. Let the MNBP against α- and δ-deviations from Δ m be given by MNBP α = {Min Σx i x R n + ; Σ i S x i φ(s, B α (S)), all S N}, and (23) MNBP δ = {Min Σx i x R n + ; Σ i S x i φ(s, B δ (S,Δ m )), all S N}, (24) where φ(s,δ), B α (S)={S,(i 1 ),...,(i n-k )} and B δ (S,Δ m )={S,N/S} are given in (7)-(11). For a nonmonopoly partition Δ Δ m, let Y α (Δ) = {x R n + Σ i Sx i φ(s,b α (Δ,S)) for all S N, S Δ }, Y γ (Δ) = {x R n + Σ i Sx i φ(s,b γ (Δ,S)) for all S N, S Δ }, (25) Y δ (Δ) = {x R n + Σ i Sx i φ(s,b δ (Δ,S)) for all S N, S Δ }. denote the sets of profit vectors immune to the α-, γ-, and δ-deviations, respectively, and let MNBP α (Δ) = {Min Σx i x Y α (Δ)}, MNBP γ (Δ) = {Min Σx i x Y γ (Δ)}, and, (26) MNBP δ (Δ) = {Min Σx i x Y δ (Δ)} denote the corresponding values of MNBP. Proposition 5 below provides a computational characterization for each stable partition in a general linear oligopoly. Proposition 5: i) Under A0 and A1, the monopoly merger is α- (δ -) stable if and only if (v(n)-mc N ) MNBP α ( MNBP δ ). ii) Given Δ Δ m, assume A0, A1, and Σ S Δ π ~ S(Δ)>(v(N)-MC N ). Then, Δ is α-(γ-; δ-) stable if and only if Σ S Δ π ~ S(Δ) MNBP α (Δ) (MNBP γ (Δ); MNBP δ (Δ)). By part i), monopoly will be formed in the α- (δ-) fashion if its profits after paying the merging costs exceed MNBP α (MNBP δ ). By part ii), mergers in Δ Δ m will be formed in cycle if partition changes take a fixed length of time. 17

18 the α- (γ-; δ-) fashion if the current total profits are no less than MNBP α (MNBP γ ; MNBP δ ). Such computational results also hold in n-firm non-linear oligopolies, as one could compute the values of MNBP in (23)-(24) and (26) and then compare them with v(n) or Σ S Δ π ~ S(Δ). We now characterize a stable monopoly in a class of asymmetric linear oligopolies, which is similar to the dominant cartel model with a finite number of Cournot fringe firms. We leave the stability for Δ Δ m in these oligopolies to future studies, whose computations (those given in part ii) of Proposition 5) are beyond the interests of this paper. Precisely, the model is given by (a, c, z) R 2n+1 ++ with c j c 2 c 1 for all j 3. Let ε = ε 2 = (c 2 -c 1 )/(a-c 1 ) (27) be firm 1 s relative cost savings over the fringe firms (j 2, all j), and define ω 0 by ω 0 = ω 0 (n) = (4n-9)/(8n-6). (28) Proposition 6: Given (a,c,z) R 2n+1 ++ with c j c 2 c 1, all j 3. Under A0, the following three claims hold: (i) monopoly is α-stable for all n; (ii) monopoly is δ-stable for n = 2; and (iii) monopoly is δ-stable for n 3 if and only if ε ω 0 holds. By part (iii) and by the fact that ω 0 (n) is increasing in n, larger cost savings will strengthen the monopoly s δ stability, and more firms will harm its δ stability. Since monopoly is optimal if cost savings are sufficiently large, the stability and optimality of the monopoly merger go hand in hand in markets with large cost savings. In the symmetric case (i.e., ε=0), monopoly will be formed in the α-fashion and not be formed in the δ-fashion (except with n=2), which can be given as a corollary below. Corollary 6: Given (a, c, z) R 2n+1 ++ with c j c 1, all j. Under A0, the following two 18

19 claims hold: (i) X α (Δ m ) Ø for all n; and ii) X δ (Δ m ) Ø for n = 2, and =Ø for all n 3. It is interesting to note that the above symmetric results have been reported in the study of a common pool resource problem by Funaki and Yamato (1999). With a production function f(q) = (a-q)q, their Theorem 4 becomes X α (Δ m ) Ø, and their Theorem 6 becomes X δ (Δ m ) =Ø for all n 4. It remains to be seen if X δ (Δ m )=Ø also holds for n = 3 in their model. It will be useful and workable to extend the above results to more general oligopolies in future studies. One extension is a linear oligopoly with two types of firms (i.e., m firms with c 1, and n firms with c 2 ), and another is an oligopoly with non-linear demand and linear costs. These extensions will generate enough results worthy of two or more articles. 6. Conclusion and discussion We have defined and provided a computational characterization for a stable market structure, which is a set of simultaneous mergers that are free of subsequent breakups or new mergers. Our computational results also hold in general oligopolies and normal formal games with transferable utilities, which can be obtained by computing the MNBP for each given partition and then comparing the value against its current total payoffs. John Nash suggested in his 1998 Cowles talk that there isn't any theory yet that seems acceptable as providing a solution concept in cooperative games with at least three players. The author believes that a stable partition or a set of stable merger contracts provides an answer to Nash s challenging comment, because it rules out all possible deviations. Applying the technique to three-firm linear Cournot oligopolies, we have obtained a complete answer to the problem, namely, monopoly will be the solution if its merging cost is 19

20 sufficiently low and cost differentials are sufficiently large. When monopoly is ruled out by high merging costs, a profitable two-member merger will be the solution if its efficient member s share of the merger s gain are sufficiently large and cost differentials are sufficiently small, and Cournot equilibrium will be the solution if none of the four mergers are profitable. Readers are encouraged to apply our technique to more general oligopolies or normal form games to obtain new understandings about stable partitions, and to empirically estimate the size of merging costs which is a crucial determinant for the stability of market structures. APPENDIX We first compute the involved MNBP. Lemma 1 provides the MNBP used in Proposition 6, and Lemmas 2-3 provides the MNBP and profitability in Propositions 2-4. Given (a,c,z) R 2n+1 ++ with c j c 2 c 1 for j 3, let ε be given by (27), and define n 0 by n 0 = 9/(1+4ε) 4; n 0 [ 1, 5]. (A1) Lemma 1: Assume c j c 2 c 1 for j 3. Then, (23) and (24) are given by: MNBP α = (a-c 1) 2 {[1+(n-1)ε] 2 +(n-1)(1-2ε) 2 }/(n+1) 2 if ε 1/8 and n n 0 (a-c 1 ) 2 {(1+ε) 2 /9 +(1-2ε) 2 /(n+1) 2 } if ε 1/8 & n 0 <n 5 or 1/8<ε & n 5 (a-c 1 ) 2 {(1+ε) 2 /9 +(1-2ε) 2 /[9(n-1)]} if 6 n; MNBP δ = (a-c 1 ) 2 [(1+ε) 2 +(n-1)(1-2ε) 2 ] / 9. (A2) (A3) In symmetric case with c j c 1, all j (or ε =0), the above (A2)-(A3) become: MNBP α = MNBP α (a, c, z) = n(a-c 1) 2 / (n+1) 2 if 2 n 5 n(a-c 1 ) 2 / [9(n-1)] if 6 n; MNBP δ = n(a-c 1 ) 2 / 9. (A4) (A5) Let Δ 0 = {1; 2; 3}, Δ 1 = {1; 23}, Δ 2 = {13; 2}, Δ 3 = {12; 3}, Δ m = {(1, 2, 3)}, and π i = 20

21 π i (x^)=v i and π ~ (Δ)={π ~ S(Δ) S Δ} be pre- and post-merger profits. For (a; c 1,c 2,c 3 ;z 1,z 2,z 3 ) R 7 ++, let ε 2 and ε 3 be given by (13), θ i be defined as θ 0 = 1+ε 2 3, θ 2 = 15ε 2 1, θ 4 = 1+ε 2 15, θ 6 = 1+13ε 2 15, and (A6) d 12 = π ~ 12(Δ 3 ) ( π 1 +π 2 ), d 13 = π ~ 13(Δ 2 ) ( π 1 +π 3 ), d 23 = π ~ 23(Δ 1 ) (π 2 +π 3 ) (A7) be the S increase of joint profits for S = 12, 13, and 23. Lemma 2: (I) d 12 >0 ε 3 <θ 2 ; (II) d 13 > 0 ε 3 > θ 4 ; and (III) d 23 > 0 ε 3 > θ 6. As shown in Figure 5, a merger is profitable its cost savings are sufficiently large (note a larger ε 2 or ε 3 represents larger cost saving). Let ρ i, v i and y i be given by ρ 0 = ε 2 +5ε 2 2, ρ 1 = (5-11ε 2 )/11, ρ 2 = -1+27ε ε 2 +42ε 2 2, ρ 3 = 19+27ε ε ε , ρ 4 = 19+27ε ε ε 2 89, (A8) ρ 5 = ; v 1 = π 1 = (a-c 1 ) 2 (1+ε 2 +ε 3 ) 2 /16, v 2 = π 2 = (a-c 1 ) 2 (1-3ε 2 +ε 3 ) 2 /16, v 3 = π 3 = (a-c 1 ) 2 (1-3ε 3 +ε 2 ) 2 /16; (A9) v 12 = (a-c 1 ) 2 (1+ε 3 ) 2 /9, v 13 = v δ 1 = π~ 1(Δ 1 ) = (a-c 1 ) 2 (1+ε 2 ) 2 /9, v 23 = v δ 2 = π~ 2(Δ 2 ) = (a-c 1 ) 2 (1-2ε 2 ) 2 /9, v δ 3 = π~ 3(Δ 3 ) = (a-c 1 ) 2 (1-2ε 3 ) 2 /9, and (A10) v 123 = v(n) = (a-c 1 ) 2 /4; y 1 = (v 12 +v 13 -v 23 )/2, y 2 = (v 12 +v 23 v 13 )/2, y 3 = (v 13 +v 23 v 12 )/2. (A11) Lemma 3: Under parts (ii) and (iii) of A0, (23) and (24) are given by: MNBP δ = v 13 + v 23 + v δ if ε 3 3 ρ 0 v 12 + v δ if ε 3 3> ρ 0 ; For ε , MNBP α = v 1 +v 2 +v 3 if ε 3 < θ 4 v 2 +v 13 if ε 3 θ 4 ; (A12) (A13) 21

22 For 1 14 ε , MNBP α = v 2 +v 13 ; For ε , ε 3 θ 6, MNBP α = For ε , ε 3>θ 6, MNBP α = v 2+v 13 if 1 11 ε v 2 +v 13 if ε 3 ρ 1 ; ε v 3 +v 12 if ε 3 > ρ 1 ; ε v 3 +v 12 if ε ; v 2 +v 13 if ε 3 ρ 2 16 y 1 +y 2 +y 3 if ρ 2 <ε 3 <ρ 3 for ε 2 77 v 3 +v 12 if ε 3 ρ 3 y 1 +y 2 +y 3 if ρ 4 ε 3 ρ 3 for 16 v 3 +v 12 if ε 3 <ρ 4 or ε 3 >ρ 3 77 ε 2 ρ 5 v 3 +v 12 for ε 2 > ρ (A14) (A15) (A16) Our results are proved in the following order with increasing complexity: (a) Proposition 5; (b) Lemma 1 and Proposition 6; (c) Lemmas 2-3; and (d) Propositions 2-4. Proof of Proposition 5: Part i). Suppose (v(n)-mc N ) MNBP α. Let x solve (23), and λ be given by λ i = x i + (v(n)-mc N MNBP α )/n, all i. By (23), Σ j S λ j Σ j S x j φ(b γ (Δ m,s), S) for all S N. Hence, Δ m with λ is α-stale when (v(n)-mc N ) MNBP α. If (v(n)-mc N )< MNBP α, no allocation of (v(n)-mc N ) could satisfy all coalitions, therefore the monopoly merger with any λ will not be α-stale. The proof for part ii) is similar. Q.E.D Before we prove Lemma 1, we first compute the simple case of (A4)-(A5). Derivation of (A4)-(A5): The proof completes in six steps. Step 1. Determine φ(b α (S), S) and φ(b δ (Δ m,s), S). For each 1 k (n-1), let S(k) = {T N T = k }. By A0 and by symmetry, its α- and δ-profits are: φ(b α (S), S) = φ(b γ (Δ m,s), S) = v α (k) = (a-c 1 ) 2 /(n-k+2) 2, φ(b δ (Δ m,s), S) = v δ (k) (a-c 1 ) 2 /9. (B1) (B2) Step 2. Determine MV α (k) and MV δ (k). For each k = 1,..., n-1, define 22

23 MV α (k)={min Σ i N x i x R n + ; Σ i S x i v α(k), for all S S(k)}, and MV δ (k) = {Min Σ i N x i x R n + ; Σ i S x i v δ(k), for all S S(k)}. (B3) There are ( n k ) constraints, and each x i appears ( n 1 k 1 ) times. Summing up, we have ( n 1 k 1 ) Σx i ( n k ) v α(k), and ( n 1 k 1 ) Σx i ( n k ) v δ(k), or Σxi nv α (k)/k, and Σxi n v δ (k)/k. Hence, define MV α (k) = n(a-c 1 ) 2 /[k(n-k+2) 2 ], and MV δ (k) = n(a-c 1 ) 2 /[9k], (B4) and the minimum solutions are x i = (a-c 1 ) 2 /[k(n-k+2) 2 ], all i; and y i = (a-c 1 ) 2 /(9k), all i. Step 3. Determine the maximum of MV α (k) and MV δ (k). By MV δ (k) < 0, Max { MV δ (k) 1 k (n-1) } = MV δ (1) = n(a-c 1 ) 2 /9. (B5) By MV α (k) 0 if k (n+2)/3, and > 0 if k > (n+2)/3, we have Max { MV α (k) 1 k (n-1) }= Max {MV α (1), MV α (n-1)}. Define f(n) = MV α (1)-MV α (n-1), which has the same sign as g(n) = 9(n-1) - (n+1) 2. Since g(n) is -shaped and has two roots: n = 2 < 5, one has: Max {MV α (k) 1 k (n-1)} = n(a-c 1) 2 /(n+1) 2 if 2 n 5 n(a-c 1 ) 2 /[9(n-1)] if 6 n. (B6) Step 4. Enlarge the feasible sets for MV α (k) and MV δ (k). For k = 1,, n-1, let FR α (k) = {x R n + Σ i S x i v α(k), for all S S(k)}, and FR δ (k) = {x R n + Σ i S x i v δ(k), for all S S(k)} (B7) denote the feasible sets in (B3), and define FR α (k)*={x R n + Σ xi MV α (k)}, and FR δ (k)*={x R n + Σ xi MV δ (k)}. (B8) By the arguments in Step 2, the following relations hold for k = 1,, n-1. FR α (k) FR α (k)* and FR δ (k) FR δ (k)*. (B9) Step 5. Enlarge the feasible regions for MNBP α and MNBP δ. The feasible regions for MNBP α and MNBP δ as given in (23) and (24) are: 23

24 FR α = {x R n + Σ i S x i φ(b α (S), S) for all S N } = n-1 i=1 FR α(k); (B10) FR δ = {x R n + Σ i S x i φ(b δ(δ m,s), S) for all S N} = n-1 i=1 FR δ(k). (B11) By the maximality in Step 3 and by (B8), one has FR* α = n-1 i=1 FR α(k)* = {x R n + Σ x i Max {MV α(1), MV α (n-1)}} {x R n + Σ x i MV α(1)} if 2 n 5 = {x R n + Σ x i MV α(n-1)} if 6 n; (B12) FR* δ = n-1 i=1 FR δ(k)* = {x R n + Σx i MV δ(1)}. (B13) It follows from (B9)-(B13), the following relations hold: FR α FR* α = n-1 i=1 FR α(k)*, and FR δ FR* δ = n-1 i=1 FR δ(k)*. (B14) Step 6. Determine MNBP α and MNBP δ. Observe that the minimum value of {MinΣ i N xi x FR* δ } is equal to. {Min Σ i N x i x FR* δ } = MV δ (1) = n(a-c 1 ) 2 /9. (B15) By the maximality in Step 3, the symmetric minimum solution (i.e., x i = (a-c 1 ) 2 /9, all i) is included in all FR δ (k) and therefore also in FR δ. Since a global min must be a local min when it is locally feasible, it follows from (B14) and (B15) that MNBP δ = {Min Σ x i x FR δ } = {Min Σxi x FR* δ } = n(a-c 1 ) 2 /9. Using similar arguments, one obtains: MNBP α = {Min Σ x i x FR α } = {Min Σx i x FR* α } = n(a-c 1) 2 / (n+1) 2 if 2 n 5 n(a-c 1 ) 2 / [9(n-1)] if 6 n; which leads to (A5). Q.E.D Proof of Lemma 1: This proof is more involved, because there are now two types of mergers: type I mergers (1 S) and type II mergers (1 S). Let ε = (c 2 -c 1 )/(a-c 1 ). We first prove (A3), which involves exactly the same above six steps. The relevant formulae are: 24

25 φ(b δ (S), S) = v δ (k) = v I (k) = (a-c 1) 2 (1-2ε) 2 δ 9 for type I mergers, and v δ (k) = v II(k) = (a-c 1) 2 (1+ε) 2 δ 9 for type II mergers, k = 1,, n-1; MV δ (k) = {Min Σ i N x i x R n + ; Σ i S x i v δ(k), for all S S(k)}. (B16) (B17) Summing up the constraints, one has ( n 1 k 1 )Σx i (n-1 k )vi (k) + (n-1 δ k-1 )vii (k), leading to δ MV δ (k) = (a-c 1) 2 9 whose minimum solution is given by x 1 = (a-c 1) 2 9 [(1+ε) 2 + (n-k)(1-2ε)2 k ], (B18) [(1+ε) 2 - (k-1)(1-2ε)2 k ], x i = (a-c 1 ) 2 (1-2ε) 2 /(9k), all i 2. (B19) Max{MV δ (k) 1 k (n-1)}= MV δ (1)= (a-c 1) 2 [(1+ε) 2 +(n-1)(1-2ε) 2 ] 9. (B20) FR δ = n-1 i=1 FR δ(k) FR* δ = n-1 i=1 FR δ(k)* = {x R n + Σ x i MV δ (1)}. (B21) {Min Σ i N xi x FR* δ } = MV δ (1) = (a-c 1) 2 [(1+ε) 2 +(n-1)(1-2ε) 2 ] 9. (B22) The solution given by (B19) for k = 1 is included in FR δ. Therefore, MNBP δ = {Min Σ x i x FR δ } = {Min Σxi x FR* δ } = MV δ (1), which leads to (A3). We now prove (A2), which is completed in six different parts. Part 1. Determine φ(b α (S), S). The α- profits for type I and II mergers S S(k) are: φ(b α (S), S) = v α (k) = vα I (k) = (a-c 1) 2 (1-2ε) 2 2 (n-k+2) for type I merger, and v α (k) = v II α (k) = (a-c 1) 2 [1+(n-k)ε] 2 (B23) (n-k+2) 2 for type II merger, k = 1,, n-1. Part 2. From the above proof for (A3) and the symmetry among inefficient firms, a min solution x satisfies: x 1 = y 1, x i y all i 2. Using this observation, the constraints in Min{Σ i N xi x R n + ; Σ i S x i v α (k), for all S S(k)} can be simplified as: ky v I α (k) = (a-c 1) 2 (1-2ε) 2 /(n-k+2) 2, and y 1 +(k-1)y v II α (k) = (a-c 1) 2 [1+(n-k)ε] 2 /(n-k+2) 2, (B24) (B25) 25

26 and the objective function is Σ i N x i = y 1 +(n-1)y. (B26) In the next two steps, we determine the smallest y 1 and y within FR α = n-1 i=1 FR α(k). Part 3. Determine the smallest y among all type I mergers. By (B24), y v α I (k) k = (a-c 1) 2 (1-2ε) 2 k(n-k+2) 2, k = 1,, n-1. The right side has the same max point of MV α (k). By (B6), Min {y} is given by y* = Max{ v I α (k) k 1 k n-1} = (a-c 1) 2 (1-2ε) 2 /(n+1) 2 if 2 n 5 (a-c 1 ) 2 (1-2ε) 2 /[9(n-1)] if 6 n. (B27) Part 4. Determine the smallest y 1 among all type II mergers. By (B25) and (B27), for k = 1,, n-1, y 1 satisfies: [1+(n-k)ε] 2 y 1 v II α (k)-(k-1)y* = (a-c (n-k+2) 2 - (k-1)(1-2ε)2 (n+1) 2 if 2 n 5 1) 2 [1+(n-k)ε] 2 (n-k+2) 2 - (k-1)(1-2ε)2 9(n-1) if 6 n. In order to determine Max { v II α (k)-(k-1)y* 1 k n-1}, consider two cases below: Case 1. 2 n 5. Consider f(k), k = 1,, n-1, given by f(k) = [1+(n-k)ε]2 (n-k+2) 2 - (k-1)(1-2ε)2 (n+1) 2. By f(k) > 0 (i.e., f(k) is -shaped), Max f(k) = Max {f(1), f(n-1)}. Therefore, (B28) Max { v II α (k)-(k-1)y* 1 k n-1} = (a-c 1) 2 Max {f(1), f(n-1)}. (B29) Define d(n) = f(1)-f(n-1), which is -shaped (d(n) < 0). The two roots of d(n) = 0 are: n 0 = 9/(1+4ε 2 ) - 4, and n 1 = 2. (B30) By n 0 2 ε 1/8 (see part (a) of Figure 6), one has: Max{f(1), f(n-1)}= f(1) if ε 1/8 and n n 0 f(n-1) if ε 1/8 and n 0 <n 5; or 1/8<ε and n 5. (B31) 26

27 0 d(n) ε 1 /8 Part (a) d(n) ε > 1 /8 n 2 n 0 n 0 2 n d 1 (n) Part (b) n n 3 n Figure 6. (a ) The tw o roots of d(n); (b ) the three roots of d 1 (n ). Case 2. 6 n. Now consider the function f 1 (k) given by f 1 (k) = [1+(n-k)ε]2 (n-k+2) 2 - (k-1)(1-2ε)2 9(n-1). By f 1 (k) > 0 (so f 1 (k) is -shaped), Max f 1 (k) = Max {f 1 (1), f 1 (n-1)}. Therefore, Max { v II α (k)-(k-1)y* 1 k n-1} = (a-c 1) 2 Max {f 1 (1), f 1 (n-1)}. (B32) Define d 1 (n) = f 1 (1) - f 1 (n-1). Then, d 1 (n) = 0 has three roots: n 1 = 2ε ε-92ε2 12ε < 0, n 2 = 2, and n 3 = 2ε ε-92ε2. 12ε The sign of d 1 (n) is the same as that of g 1 (n) = d 1 (n)(n-1)(n+1) 2, whose shape is shown in part (b) of Figure 6. One can show 1 n 3 5. Hence, d 1 (n) < 0 for all n 6. This leads to Max {f 1 (1), f 1 (n-1)} = f 1 (n-1). (B33) It follows from (B28)-(B33) that y* 1 = Max { v II α (k)-(k-1)y* 1 k n-1} = (a-c 1 ) 2 f(1) if ε 1/8 and n n 0 f(n-1) if ε 1/8 and n 0 <n 5; or if 1/8<ε & n 5 f 1 (n-1) if 6 n. (B34) Part 5. Enlarge FR α. By above arguments, Min{ Σ xi x FR α } is equivalent to Min { y 1 +(n-1)y ky vα I (k) and y 1+(k-1)y v II α (k) for all k}. (B35) Define the following two feasible sets: 27

28 FR new = { (y 1,y) ky vα I (k) and y 1+(k-1)y v II α (k), k = 1,..., n-1}, FR * new = { (y 1,y) y y* and y 1 y* 1 }, where FR new is the feasible set in (B35). (B27) and (B34) leads to FR new FR new *. Part 6. Determine MNBP α. By (B26)-(B27) and (B34)-(B35), Min { y 1 +(n-1)y (y 1,y) FR * new } = y* 1 +(n-1)y* = {[1+(n-1)ε]2+(n-1)(1-2ε)2}/(n+1)2 if ε 1/8 & n n 0 (a-c 1 ) 2 (1+ε) 2 /9+(1-2ε) 2 2 if ε 1/8 & n 0 <n 5; or 1/8<ε & n 5 (1+ε) 2 /9+(1-2ε) 2 /[9(n-1)] if 6 n. (B36) By the maximality in parts (3) and (4), one can check that the minimum solution for each of the three cases in (B36) is included in FR new. For example, if n 6, the solutions are: y = (a-c 1 ) 2 (1-2ε) 2 /[9(n-1)], and y 1 = (a-c 1 ) 2 {(1+ε) 2 /9- (n-2)(1-2ε) 2 /[9(n-1)]}. Hence, Min{ Σ x i x FR α } = Min { y 1 +(n-1)y (y 1,y) FR new } = Min { y 1 +(n-1)y (y 1,y) FR new * } = y* 1 +(n-1)y*, which leads to (A2). This completes the proof of Lemma 1. Q.E.D Proof of Proposition 6: To prove part (i), we need to show d = v(n) MNBP α > 0. Consider each of the three cases in (A2). Case 1. ε 1/8 and n n 0 ( 5). d is given by d = (a-c 1 ) 2 { [1+(n-1)ε]2 +(n-2)(1-2ε) 2 (n+1) 2 } = d 1(n) / (n+1) 2. where d 1 (n) = 0 has two roots: n 1 < n 2 = 1. By d 1 (n) < 0, d > 0 for all n 2. Case 2. ε 1/8 and n 0 <n 5; or 1/8<ε and n 5. d is given by d = d 2 (n, ε) = (a-c 1 ) 2 { (1+ε)2 9 - (1-2ε)2 (n+1) 2}, By d 2 (2, 0) >0, d 2 (2, 0.5) = 0, and d 2 (2, ε) < 0, d 2 (2, ε) 0 for all ε. By d 2 (n) > 0, d 2 (3, ε), d 2 (4, ε), d 2 (5, ε) >0 for all ε [0, 0.5]. Hence, d > 0 for all 2 n 5. Case 3. 6 n. d is given by d = d 3 (n) = (a-c 1 ) 2 { (1+ε)2 9 - (1-2ε)2 9(n-1) }, 28

29 By d 3 (n) > 0, d 3 (n) is increasing. By d 3 (6) > 0, d > 0 for all 6 n. This proves part (i). Now we prove parts (ii) and (iii). d = v(n) MNBP δ is given by d = d 4 (n) = (a-c 1 ) 2 { (1+ε)2 +(n-1)(1-2ε) 2 9 } = (4n-3)(a-c 1) 2 9 ( 1 2 -ε) (ε -4n-9 8n-6 ). By ε 1/2, d > 0 if and only if ε ω 0 = (4n-9)/(8n-6). Q.E.D The following expressions are used in proofs for Lemmas 2-3 and Propositions 2-4, where π ~ 12(Δ 3 ) = v 12, π ~ 13(Δ 2 ) = v 13, and π ~ 23(Δ 1 ) = v 23 (see (18) or (A10)). v α = π 1 1 = (a-c 1) 2 (1+ε 2 +ε 3 ) 2 /16, v α = π 2 2 = (a-c 1) 2 (1-3ε 2 +ε 3 ) 2 /16, v α = π 3 3 = (a-c 1 ) 2 (1-3ε 3 +ε 2 ) 2 /16; v δ 1 = (a-c 1) 2 (1+ε 2 ) 2 /9, v δ 2 = (a-c 1) 2 (1-2ε 2 ) 2 /9, v δ 3 = (a-c 1) 2 (1-2ε 3 ) 2 /9; (C1) v 12 = v α 12 = v δ 12 = (a-c 1) 2 (1+ε 3 ) 2 /9, v 13 =v α 13 =v δ 13 =vδ 1 = (a-c 1) 2 (1+ε 2 ) 2 /9, v 23 = v α 23 = v δ 23 = vδ 2 = (a-c 1) 2 (1-2ε 2 ) 2 /9. Proof of Lemma 2: Consider first S = 12. Let d 12 = π ~ 12(Δ 3 ) ( π 1 +π 2 ). (C1) leads to d 12 (ε 3 ) = (a-c 1 ) 2 (1+ε 3-3ε 2 )(15ε 2-1-ε 3 ) /72. By A0, (1+ε 3-3ε 2 ) > 0. Hence, d 12 > 0 ε 3 < θ 2, which is given by θ 2 = 15ε 2-1. (C2) Now consider S = 13. Let d 13 = π ~ 13(Δ 2 ) ( π 1 +π 3 ). (C1) leads to d 13 (ε 3 ) = (a-c 1 ) 2 (1+ε 2-3ε 3 )(15ε 3-1-ε 2 )/72. By (1+ε 2-3ε 3 ) > 0, d 13 > 0 ε 3 > θ 4, which is given by θ 4 = (1+ε 2 )/5. (C3) Finally, consider S = 23. Let d 23 = π ~ 23(Δ 1 ) ( π 2 +π 3 ). By (C1), one has d 23 (ε 3 ) = 5(a-c 1) 2 8 ( 1+ε ε 3)(ε ε 2 15 ) = 5(a-c 1) 2 8 (θ 0 -ε 3 )(ε 3 -θ 6 ). By (θ 0 -ε 3 ) > 0, d 23 > 0 ε 3 > θ 6, where θ 0 and θ 6 are given by 29

30 θ 0 = (1+ε 2 )/3; θ 6 = (1+13ε 2 )/15. (C4) This completes the proof for Lemma 2. Q.E.D The following relations (see Figure 5) are useful in proving Lemma 3. ε 3 θ 2 if ε 2 1/14; ε 3 < θ 2 = 15ε 2-1 if ε 2 > 1/11; ε 3 > θ 4 = (1+ε 2 )/5 if ε 2 > 1/14; θ 4 < θ 6 θ 0 ; ε 2 ε 3 θ 0 ; and ε 2 θ 6. (C5) (C6) (C7) Proof of Lemma 3: We first compute MNBP δ. There are six constraints: x 1 v δ, x 1 2 vδ, x 2 3 v δ; x + x v , x 1 +x 3 v 13, x 2 +x 3 v 23. By v δ = v 1 12, v δ = v 2 23, the problem becomes: MNBP δ = Min { x 1 +x 2 +x 3 x 1 v δ 1, x 2 vδ 2, x 3 vδ 3 ; x 1 + x 2 v 12}, (C8) of which the minimum value is equal to v δ 3 + Max {vδ 1 + vδ 2, v 12}. (C9) Let d(ε 3 ) = v δ 1 + vδ 2 - v 12 = (a-c 1 ) 2 [(1+ε 2 ) 2 +(1-2ε 2 ) 2 -(1+ε 3 ) 2 ]/9. By d < 0, d is -shaped. d(ε 3 ) = 0 has two roots: μ 1 < 0 < μ 2, where μ 2 is given by μ 2 = ρ 0 = ε 2 +5ε 2 2. Hence, Max{v δ 1 +vδ 2, v 12} = v δ 1 +vδ 2 if ε 3 ρ 0, v 12 if ε 3 >ρ 0. Then, (C1) and (C8)-(C9) lead to (A12). We only provide an outline for proving (A13)-(A16), because complete proofs like those for (A12) would make the paper too long. Figure 5 illustrates all the sub-cases. Case 1. ε 2 [0, 1 14 ]. By Lemma 2, d 12 0, so only five constraints are left: x 1 v 1 = v α 1, x 2 v 2 = v α 2, x 3 v 3 = v α 3 ; x 1 +x 3 v 13, x 2 +x 3 v 23. Let h 1 = v 13 v 1, h 2 = v 23 v 2, one has d(ε 2,ε 3 ) = max{h 1, h 2 }= h 1, and v 3 d(ε 2,ε 3 ) ε 3 θ 4. By MNBP α = v 1 + v 2 + max {v 3, d(ε 2, ε 3 )}, MNBP α = v 1 + v 2 + v 3, if ε 3 < θ 4, and MNBP α = v 2 + v 13 if ε 3 θ 4. This proves (A13). Case 2. ε 2 [ 1 14, 4 53 ]. One has θ 4 ε 2 θ 2 < θ 6. If ε 3 θ 2, then d By Case 1, 30

31 MNBP α = v 2 + v 13. If ε 3 < θ 2 < θ 6, then d So the constraint x 2 +x 3 v 23 can be removed. Using similar steps as in Case 1, one can show MNBP α = v 2 + v 13. Case 3. ε , and ε 3 θ 6. By d 23 0, x 2 +x 3 v 23 is removed. Similar to Case 2, and by d 13 > 0, one can show MNBP α = v 2 + v 13 if ε 3 ρ 1, and = v 3 +v 12 if ε 3 > ρ 1. One can also show that 4 53 ε implies ε 3 ρ 1, and ε implies ε 3> ρ 1. Case 4. ε , and ε 3 θ 2 > θ 6. This can only occur for ε 2 [ 4 53, 1 11 ]. By Case 1, d 12 0, and ε 3 θ 4, MNBP α = v 2 + v 13. By Cases 2-3, one gets (A14) and (A15). Case 5. ε , and θ 2 ε 3 > θ 6. One has d 12 > 0, d 13 > 0, d 23 > 0. Note at most one of x 1 v 1, x 2 v 2, x 3 v 3 can be binding. First solving each of the three cases: Case 5.1, x 1 = v 1 ; Case 5.2, x 2 = v 2 ; Case 5.3, x 3 = v 3. Now solve Case 5.4, x 1 >v 1, x 2 >v 2, x 3 >v 3. In case 5.4, one must have x 1 +x 2 = v 12, x 1 +x 3 = v 13, and x 2 +x 3 = v 23. Solving these equations, one gets y 1, y 2, y 3. By checking y i > v i, and using Cases , one can get (A16). Q.E.D Proof of Proposition 2: Part (i). For each of the values of MNBP α, one can show v(n) > MNBP δ. Now consider part (ii). If ε 3 ρ 0, d = v(n) MNBP δ is given by d(ε 3 ) = (a-c 1 ) 2 [ (1+ε 2) 2 +(1-2ε 2 ) 2 +(1-2ε 3 ) 2 9 Using d < 0 and solving the two roots μ 1 < μ 2 for d(ε 3 ) = 0, one has: ]. d > 0 ω 1 ε 3 ρ 0, where ω 1 = μ 1 = ε 2-20ε 2 4 ρ 0. (C10) If ε 3 > ρ 0, d is given by d(ε 3 ) = (a-c 1 ) 2 [ (1+ε 3) 2 +(1-2ε 3 ) 2 9 ] = (a-c 1) 2 36 (1+10ε 3 ) (1-2ε 3 ) >0. Using (C10), one gets d > 0 ω 1 ε 3, which completes the proof of part (ii). Q.E.D Proof of Proposition 3: Since Δ 1 = {1; 23} and Δ 2 = {13; 2} have identical welfare, Δ 2 can be ignored. First, evaluate six cases below. (1) Δ 0 Δ 3. Let d 1 (ε 3 ) = W 3 -W 0. Using d 1 (ε 3 ) < 0 and solving d 1 = 0, one can show: d 1 (ε 3 ) 0 ε 3 σ 1 = (-7+69ε 2 )/31, ε 3 <σ 1 if ε 2 >13/44, and ε 3 > σ 1 if ε 2 < 7/38; 31

Handbook of Game Theory and Industrial Organization, Volume I

Handbook of Game Theory and Industrial Organization, Volume I www.e-elgar.com Handbook of Game Theory and Industrial Organization, Volume I Theory Edited by Luis C. Corchón, Department of Economics, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid, Spain and Marco A. Marini, Department

More information

The Core and Coalition Formation in an N-person Network Game *

The Core and Coalition Formation in an N-person Network Game * The Core and Coalition Formation in an N-person Network Game * By Jingang Zhao February 2008 Department of Economics University of Saskatchewan 9 Campus Drive Saskatoon, Saskatchewan CANADA S7N 5A5 Tel:

More information

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 16-1, 231 253 (2015) Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * Hongkun Ma School of Economics, Shandong University,

More information

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games 1/10 Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games May 4, 2014 2/10 Outline 1 Bertrand Market Game 2 Bertrand Paradox 3 Asymmetric Firms 3/10 Bertrand Duopoly Market Game Discontinuous Payoff Functions (1 p

More information

The Core of a Strategic Game *

The Core of a Strategic Game * The Core of a trategic Game * Parkash Chander January, 2014 Abstract This paper introduces and studies the γ-core of a general strategic game. It shows that a prominent class of games admit nonempty γ-cores.

More information

The core of voting games: a partition approach

The core of voting games: a partition approach The core of voting games: a partition approach Aymeric Lardon To cite this version: Aymeric Lardon. The core of voting games: a partition approach. International Game Theory Review, World Scientific Publishing,

More information

An Infinitely Farsighted Stable Set

An Infinitely Farsighted Stable Set An Infinitely Farsighted Stable Set By Parkash Chander * May 2015 Revised: November 2015 Abstract In this paper, we first introduce and characterize a new and general concept of a credible deviation in

More information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers September 6, 016 ONLINE APPENDIX In this Appendix we present in full additional results and extensions which are only mentioned in the paper. In the exposition

More information

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 Bertrand Model of Price Competition Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 ҧ Bertrand Model of Price Competition Consider: An industry with two firms, 1 and 2, selling a homogeneous product Firms face market

More information

A Coalition Formation Value for Games in Partition Function Form. Michel GRABISCH, Université de Paris I, Yukihiko FUNAKI, Waseda University

A Coalition Formation Value for Games in Partition Function Form. Michel GRABISCH, Université de Paris I, Yukihiko FUNAKI, Waseda University A Coalition Formation Value for Games in Partition Function Form Michel GRABISCH, Université de Paris I, Yukihiko FUNAKI, Waseda University 0. Preliminaries 1. Intoroduction 2. Partition and Embedded Coalition

More information

Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly

Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo June 8, 2010 Abstract I investigate an asymmetric duopoly where

More information

The core of voting games with externalities

The core of voting games with externalities Submitted to Games. Pages 1-8. OPEN ACCESS games ISSN 2073-4336 www.mdpi.com/journal/games Article The core of voting games with externalities LARDON Aymeric 1 1 University of Saint-Etienne, CNRS UMR 5824

More information

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games University of Manchester, UK November 25, 2010 Introduction Suppose we make a finite set of observations T = {1,..., m}, m 1, of a perfectly homogeneous-good oligopoly market. There is a finite number

More information

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of... This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of... John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 1 / 1 We will cover the following topics: with Sequential Moves

More information

Katz and Shapiro (1985)

Katz and Shapiro (1985) Katz and Shapiro (1985) 1 The paper studies the compatibility choice of competing firms in industries with network externalities. Also investigated are the social vs. private incentives of compatibility

More information

A Farsighted Stable Set for Partition Function Games

A Farsighted Stable Set for Partition Function Games 0 A Farsighted Stable Set for Partition Function Games Parkash Chander * August, 2015 Preliminary Draft Abstract In this paper, we introduce a concept of a farsighted stable set for a partition function

More information

A Cooperative Approach to Queue Allocation of Indivisible Objects

A Cooperative Approach to Queue Allocation of Indivisible Objects A Cooperative Approach to Queue Allocation of Indivisible Objects Herbert Hamers a Flip Klijn b Marco Slikker c Bas van Velzen d September 2004 Abstract We consider the allocation of a finite number of

More information

Advanced Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomics Advanced Microeconomics Leonardo Felli EC441: Room D.106, Z.332, D.109 Lecture 8 bis: 24 November 2004 Monopoly Consider now the pricing behavior of a profit maximizing monopolist: a firm that is the only

More information

Online Appendices for Large Matching Markets: Risk, Unraveling, and Conflation

Online Appendices for Large Matching Markets: Risk, Unraveling, and Conflation Online Appendices for Large Matching Markets: Risk, Unraveling, and Conflation Aaron L. Bodoh-Creed - Cornell University A Online Appendix: Strategic Convergence In section 4 we described the matching

More information

Convexity of Bertrand oligopoly TU-games with differentiated products

Convexity of Bertrand oligopoly TU-games with differentiated products Convexity of Bertrand oligopoly TU-games with differentiated products Aymeric Lardon To cite this version: Aymeric Lardon. Convexity of Bertrand oligopoly TU-games with differentiated products. Working

More information

Basics of Game Theory

Basics of Game Theory Basics of Game Theory Giacomo Bacci and Luca Sanguinetti Department of Information Engineering University of Pisa, Pisa, Italy {giacomo.bacci,luca.sanguinetti}@iet.unipi.it April - May, 2010 G. Bacci and

More information

Stackelberg oligopoly TU-games: characterization of the core and 1-concavity of the dual game

Stackelberg oligopoly TU-games: characterization of the core and 1-concavity of the dual game Stackelberg oligopoly TU-games: characterization of the core and 1-concavity of the dual game Theo Driessen, Dongshuang Hou, Aymeric Lardon To cite this version: Theo Driessen, Dongshuang Hou, Aymeric

More information

Oligopoly. Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009

Oligopoly. Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009 Oligopoly Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009 1 Oligopoly A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. An oligopoly is an industry

More information

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October 23 2011 1 Scores The exam was long. I know this. Final grades will definitely be curved. Here is a rough

More information

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective Alex Possajennikov University of Nottingham January 2012 Abstract Suppose that in aggregative games, in which a player s payoff

More information

Industrial Organization

Industrial Organization Industrial Organization Lecture Notes Sérgio O. Parreiras Fall, 2017 Outline Mathematical Toolbox Intermediate Microeconomic Theory Revision Perfect Competition Monopoly Oligopoly Mathematical Toolbox

More information

Game Theory. Monika Köppl-Turyna. Winter 2017/2018. Institute for Analytical Economics Vienna University of Economics and Business

Game Theory. Monika Köppl-Turyna. Winter 2017/2018. Institute for Analytical Economics Vienna University of Economics and Business Monika Köppl-Turyna Institute for Analytical Economics Vienna University of Economics and Business Winter 2017/2018 Static Games of Incomplete Information Introduction So far we assumed that payoff functions

More information

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

Answer Key: Problem Set 3 Answer Key: Problem Set Econ 409 018 Fall Question 1 a This is a standard monopoly problem; using MR = a 4Q, let MR = MC and solve: Q M = a c 4, P M = a + c, πm = (a c) 8 The Lerner index is then L M P

More information

On the relation between Sion s minimax theorem and existence of Nash equilibrium in asymmetric multi-players zero-sum game with only one alien

On the relation between Sion s minimax theorem and existence of Nash equilibrium in asymmetric multi-players zero-sum game with only one alien arxiv:10607253v1 [econem] 17 Jun 201 On the relation between Sion s i theorem and existence of Nash equilibrium in asymmetric multi-players zero-sum game with only one alien Atsuhiro Satoh Faculty of Economics

More information

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship Journal of Game Theory 2017 6(2): 38-42 DOI: 10.5923/j.jgt.20170602.02 Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship Aika Monden Graduate School

More information

On the Coalitional Stability of Monopoly Power in Differentiated

On the Coalitional Stability of Monopoly Power in Differentiated On the Coalitional Stability of Monopoly Power in Differentiated Bertrand and Cournot Oligopolies Documents de travail GREDEG GREDEG Working Papers Series Aymeric Lardon GREDEG WP No. 2017-10 https://ideas.repec.org/s/gre/wpaper.html

More information

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with Increasing Returns to Scale Abhijit Sengupta and Yair Tauman February 6, 24 Abstract We consider a Cournot Oligopoly market of firms possessing increasing

More information

A NOTE ON FUNAKI AND YAMATO S TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS

A NOTE ON FUNAKI AND YAMATO S TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS A NOTE ON FUNAKI AND YAMATO S TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS LÁSZLÓ Á. KÓCZY Abstract. In the model of Funaki and Yamato (1999) the tragedy of the commons can be avoided with pessimistic players, while this does

More information

Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot

Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot Class Note: There are supplemental readings, including Werden (008) Unilateral Competitive Effects of Horizontal Mergers I: Basic Concepts and Models, that

More information

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly Daisuke Hirata Graduate School of Economics, University of Tokyo March 2008 Abstract This paper investigates a simultaneous move capacity constrained price competition

More information

Online Appendix. (S,S) for v v1. (F,F) for v1 S < v

Online Appendix. (S,S) for v v1. (F,F) for v1 S < v Article submitted to Production & Operations Management 1 Online Appendix Appendix F: When the Retailers Can Decide Whether to Adopt QR Here we describe what happens when the retailers can simultaneously

More information

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples February 24, 2011 Summary: We introduce the Nash Equilibrium: an outcome (action profile) which is stable in the sense that no player

More information

Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly. Abstract Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly Yasuo Sanjo Graduate School of Economics, Nagoya University Abstract We investigate a mixed duopoly market by introducing quality choice

More information

The Impact of Advertising on Media Bias. Web Appendix

The Impact of Advertising on Media Bias. Web Appendix 1 The Impact of Advertising on Media Bias Esther Gal-Or, Tansev Geylani, Tuba Pinar Yildirim Web Appendix DERIVATIONS OF EQUATIONS 16-17 AND PROOF OF LEMMA 1 (i) Single-Homing: Second stage prices are

More information

A partial characterization of the core in Bertrand oligopoly TU-games with transferable technologies

A partial characterization of the core in Bertrand oligopoly TU-games with transferable technologies A partial characterization of the core in Bertrand oligopoly TU-games with transferable technologies Aymeric Lardon To cite this version: Aymeric Lardon. A partial characterization of the core in Bertrand

More information

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley Firms and returns to scale. Increasing returns to scale and monopoly pricing 2. Natural monopoly 1 C. Constant returns to scale 21 D. The CRS economy 26 E. pplication

More information

Inducing stability in hedonic games

Inducing stability in hedonic games School of Economics Working Paper 2016-09 SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS Inducing stability in hedonic games by Dinko Dimitrov* Emiliya A. Lazarova** Shao-Chin Sung*** *Chair of Economic Theory, Saarland University

More information

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale. Increasing returns to scale and monopoly pricing 2. Constant returns to scale 19 C. The CRS economy 25 D. pplication to trade 47 E. Decreasing

More information

Mathematical Appendix. Ramsey Pricing

Mathematical Appendix. Ramsey Pricing Mathematical Appendix Ramsey Pricing PROOF OF THEOREM : I maximize social welfare V subject to π > K. The Lagrangian is V + κπ K the associated first-order conditions are that for each I + κ P I C I cn

More information

Dual Bargaining and the Talmud Bankruptcy Problem

Dual Bargaining and the Talmud Bankruptcy Problem Dual Bargaining and the Talmud Bankruptcy Problem By Jingang Zhao * Revised January 2000 Department of Economics Ohio State University 1945 North High Street Columbus, OH 43210 1172 USA Zhao.18@Osu.Edu

More information

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility Toker Doganoglu and Julian Wright July 19, 2005 We would like to thank two anonymous referees and our editor, Simon Anderson, for their very helpful

More information

The Core can be accessed in a Bounded Number of Steps

The Core can be accessed in a Bounded Number of Steps The Core can be accessed in a Bounded Number of Steps by László Á. KÓCZY Econometrics Center for Economic Studies Discussions Paper Series (DPS) 02.18 http://www.econ.kuleuven.be/ces/discussionpapers/default.htm

More information

Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) -

Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) - Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) - What is the old empirical IO? The old empirical IO refers to studies that tried to draw inferences about the relationship

More information

A RECURSIVE CORE FOR PARTITION FUNCTION FORM GAMES

A RECURSIVE CORE FOR PARTITION FUNCTION FORM GAMES Theory and Decision (2007) 63:41 51 Springer 2007 DOI 10.1007/s11238-007-9030-x A RECURSIVE CORE FOR PARTITION FUNCTION FORM GAMES ABSTRACT. We present a well-defined generalisation of the core to coalitional

More information

NOTES ON COOPERATIVE GAME THEORY AND THE CORE. 1. Introduction

NOTES ON COOPERATIVE GAME THEORY AND THE CORE. 1. Introduction NOTES ON COOPERATIVE GAME THEORY AND THE CORE SARA FROEHLICH 1. Introduction Cooperative game theory is fundamentally different from the types of games we have studied so far, which we will now refer to

More information

Lecture 6. Xavier Gabaix. March 11, 2004

Lecture 6. Xavier Gabaix. March 11, 2004 14.127 Lecture 6 Xavier Gabaix March 11, 2004 0.0.1 Shrouded attributes. A continuation Rational guys U i = q p + max (V p, V e) + σε i = q p + V min (p, e) + σε i = U i + σε i Rational demand for good

More information

Conflict Leads to Cooperation in Demand Bargaining

Conflict Leads to Cooperation in Demand Bargaining Conflict Leads to Cooperation in Demand Bargaining Kareen Rozen Yale University Abstract We consider a multilateral Nash demand game in which short-sighted players come to the bargaining table with requests

More information

A New and Robust Subgame Perfect Equilibrium in a model of Triadic Power Relations *

A New and Robust Subgame Perfect Equilibrium in a model of Triadic Power Relations * A New and Robust Subgame Perfect Equilibrium in a model of Triadic Power Relations * by Magnus Hatlebakk ** Department of Economics, University of Bergen Abstract: We present a new subgame perfect equilibrium

More information

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS CEP 14-11 Horizontal Mergers in the Presence of Capacity Constraints Zhiqi Chen Carleton University Gang Li Nanjing University September 2014 CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS Department of Economics 1125 Colonel

More information

Microeconomics for Business Practice Session 3 - Solutions

Microeconomics for Business Practice Session 3 - Solutions Microeconomics for Business Practice Session - Solutions Instructor: Eloisa Campioni TA: Ugo Zannini University of Rome Tor Vergata April 8, 016 Exercise 1 Show that there are no mixed-strategy Nash equilibria

More information

MS&E 246: Lecture 12 Static games of incomplete information. Ramesh Johari

MS&E 246: Lecture 12 Static games of incomplete information. Ramesh Johari MS&E 246: Lecture 12 Static games of incomplete information Ramesh Johari Incomplete information Complete information means the entire structure of the game is common knowledge Incomplete information means

More information

Price and Capacity Competition

Price and Capacity Competition Price and Capacity Competition Daron Acemoglu, Kostas Bimpikis, and Asuman Ozdaglar October 9, 2007 Abstract We study the efficiency of oligopoly equilibria in a model where firms compete over capacities

More information

Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network

Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network Effects Adriana Gama Mario Samano September 7, 218 Abstract We establish an important difference between Cournot oligopolies with and without positive

More information

The Properly Efficient Bargaining Solutions

The Properly Efficient Bargaining Solutions The Properly Efficient Bargaining Solutions By Jingang Zhao * Department of Economics Iowa State University 260 Heady Hall Ames, Iowa 50011-1070 jingang@iastate.edu Fax: (515) 294-0221 Tel: (515) 294-5245

More information

Static Models of Oligopoly

Static Models of Oligopoly Static Models of Oligopoly Cournot and Bertrand Models Mateusz Szetela 1 1 Collegium of Economic Analysis Warsaw School of Economics 3 March 2016 Outline 1 Introduction Game Theory and Oligopolies 2 The

More information

Monotonic ɛ-equilibria in strongly symmetric games

Monotonic ɛ-equilibria in strongly symmetric games Monotonic ɛ-equilibria in strongly symmetric games Shiran Rachmilevitch April 22, 2016 Abstract ɛ-equilibrium allows for worse actions to be played with higher probability than better actions. I introduce

More information

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Yongmin Chen and David Sappington University of Colorado and University of Florida February 2016 1 / 32 1. Introduction Patent policy: patent protection

More information

Market Power. Economics II: Microeconomics. December Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39

Market Power. Economics II: Microeconomics. December Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39 Market Power Economics II: Microeconomics VŠE Praha December 2009 Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39 Microeconomics Consumers: Firms: People. Households. Monopoly. Oligopoly Now Perfect Competition.

More information

COOPERATIVE GAME THEORY: CORE AND SHAPLEY VALUE

COOPERATIVE GAME THEORY: CORE AND SHAPLEY VALUE 1 / 54 COOPERATIVE GAME THEORY: CORE AND SHAPLEY VALUE Heinrich H. Nax hnax@ethz.ch & Bary S. R. Pradelski bpradelski@ethz.ch February 26, 2018: Lecture 2 2 / 54 What you did last week... There appear

More information

Online Appendix for Sourcing from Suppliers with Financial Constraints and Performance Risk

Online Appendix for Sourcing from Suppliers with Financial Constraints and Performance Risk Online Appendix for Sourcing from Suppliers with Financial Constraints and Performance Ris Christopher S. Tang S. Alex Yang Jing Wu Appendix A: Proofs Proof of Lemma 1. In a centralized chain, the system

More information

On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E.

On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E. Tilburg University On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E. Publication date: 1997 Link to publication General rights Copyright and

More information

Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership

Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership Kazuhiko Kato and Leonard F.S. Wang December 29, 2012 Abstract The paper compares an emission tax and an emission quota in a

More information

R&D Collaboration in Collusive Networks

R&D Collaboration in Collusive Networks R&D Collaboration in Collusive Networks Gizem Korkmaz European University Institute December, 2011 Market Sharing Agreements In recent years, the scope for explicit or implicit market sharing agreements

More information

Heterogenous Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Behavioral Uncertainty

Heterogenous Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Behavioral Uncertainty Heterogenous Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Behavioral Uncertainty Akio Matsumoto Department of Systems Industrial Engineering Univesity of Arizona, USA Department of Economics Chuo University,

More information

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Supermodular Games

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Supermodular Games 6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Asu Ozdaglar MIT February 25, 2010 1 Introduction Outline Uniqueness of a Pure Nash Equilibrium for Continuous Games Reading: Rosen J.B., Existence

More information

Price setting on a network

Price setting on a network Price setting on a network Very preliminary and incomplete. Toomas Hinnosaar May 2018 Abstract Most products are produced and sold by supply chains, where an interconnected network of producers and intermediaries

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 More on strategic games and extensive games with perfect information Block 2 Jun 12, 2016 Food for thought LUPI Many players

More information

2.1 Definition and graphical representation for games with up to three players

2.1 Definition and graphical representation for games with up to three players Lecture 2 The Core Let us assume that we have a TU game (N, v) and that we want to form the grand coalition. We model cooperation between all the agents in N and we focus on the sharing problem: how to

More information

Revealed Preference Tests of the Cournot Model

Revealed Preference Tests of the Cournot Model Andres Carvajal, Rahul Deb, James Fenske, and John K.-H. Quah Department of Economics University of Toronto Introduction Cournot oligopoly is a canonical noncooperative model of firm competition. In this

More information

Sequential mergers with differing differentiation levels

Sequential mergers with differing differentiation levels Sequential mergers with differing differentiation levels March 31, 2008 Discussion Paper No.08-03 Takeshi Ebina and Daisuke Shimizu Sequential mergers with differing differentiation levels Takeshi Ebina

More information

Pollution Tax and Social Welfare in Oligopoly. Asymmetric Taxation on Identical Polluters

Pollution Tax and Social Welfare in Oligopoly. Asymmetric Taxation on Identical Polluters Pollution Tax and Social Welfare in Oligopoly Asymmetric Taxation on Identical Polluters Satoshi HONMA Abstract We study asymmetric pollution taxation on identical polluting oligopolists engaged in Cournot

More information

Dynamic Bertrand and Cournot Competition

Dynamic Bertrand and Cournot Competition Dynamic Bertrand and Cournot Competition Effects of Product Differentiation Andrew Ledvina Department of Operations Research and Financial Engineering Princeton University Joint with Ronnie Sircar Princeton-Lausanne

More information

Collaborative Network Formation in Spatial Oligopolies

Collaborative Network Formation in Spatial Oligopolies Collaborative Network Formation in Spatial Oligopolies 1 Shaun Lichter, Terry Friesz, and Christopher Griffin arxiv:1108.4114v1 [math.oc] 20 Aug 2011 Abstract Recently, it has been shown that networks

More information

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction Susumu Sato July 9, 2018 I study a monopoly regulation in the setting where consumers can engage in demand-reducing investments. I first

More information

Oligopoly. Firm s Profit Maximization Firm i s profit maximization problem: Static oligopoly model with n firms producing homogenous product.

Oligopoly. Firm s Profit Maximization Firm i s profit maximization problem: Static oligopoly model with n firms producing homogenous product. Oligopoly Static oligopoly model with n firms producing homogenous product. Firm s Profit Maximization Firm i s profit maximization problem: Max qi P(Q)q i C i (q i ) P(Q): inverse demand curve: p = P(Q)

More information

Game Theory Correlated equilibrium 1

Game Theory Correlated equilibrium 1 Game Theory Correlated equilibrium 1 Christoph Schottmüller University of Copenhagen 1 License: CC Attribution ShareAlike 4.0 1 / 17 Correlated equilibrium I Example (correlated equilibrium 1) L R U 5,1

More information

A Note on Cost Reducing Alliances in Vertically Differentiated Oligopoly. Abstract

A Note on Cost Reducing Alliances in Vertically Differentiated Oligopoly. Abstract A Note on Cost Reducing Alliances in Vertically Differentiated Oligopoly Frédéric DEROÏAN FORUM Abstract In a vertically differentiated oligopoly, firms raise cost reducing alliances before competing with

More information

Network Topology, Higher Orders of Stability and Efficiency

Network Topology, Higher Orders of Stability and Efficiency MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Network Topology, Higher Orders of Stability and Efficiency Subhadip Chakrabarti and Supanit Tangsangasaksri Queen s University Management School, Queen s University

More information

Computing Equilibria of Repeated And Dynamic Games

Computing Equilibria of Repeated And Dynamic Games Computing Equilibria of Repeated And Dynamic Games Şevin Yeltekin Carnegie Mellon University ICE 2012 July 2012 1 / 44 Introduction Repeated and dynamic games have been used to model dynamic interactions

More information

G-COE GLOPE II Working Paper Series

G-COE GLOPE II Working Paper Series G-COE GLOPE II Working Paper Series Farsighted coalitional stability of price leadership cartel Yoshio Kamijo Faculty of Political Science and Economics, Waseda University, 1-6-1, Nishi-Waseda, Sinjuku-ku,

More information

Lecture 2F: Hotelling s Model

Lecture 2F: Hotelling s Model Econ 46 Urban Economics Lecture F: Hotelling s Model Instructor: Hiroki Watanabe Spring Hiroki Watanabe / 6 Hotelling s Model Monopoly (N = ) 3 (N = ) 4 Nash Equilibrium 5 Oligopoly (N ) N 4 6 Summary

More information

Introduction to Game Theory

Introduction to Game Theory Introduction to Game Theory Part 3. Dynamic games of incomplete information Chapter 3. Job Market Signaling Ciclo Profissional 2 o Semestre / 2011 Graduação em Ciências Econômicas V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha

More information

On Competitive and Welfare Effects of Cross-Holdings with Product Differentiation

On Competitive and Welfare Effects of Cross-Holdings with Product Differentiation On Competitive and Welfare Effects of Cross-Holdings with Product Differentiation Teng Wang October 2, 2017 Abstract Competitive implications of cross-holdings have been extensively analyzed in the literature.

More information

Duopoly and Project Uncertainty

Duopoly and Project Uncertainty Duopoly and Project Uncertainty An analysis of the Bertrand and Cournot duopolies under uncertainty for the buyer Draft Master Thesis Rik Bos Student 345327 June 2016 Erasmus School of Economics Master

More information

Volume 29, Issue 3. Strategic delegation and market competitiveness

Volume 29, Issue 3. Strategic delegation and market competitiveness Volume 29, Issue Strategic delegation and market competitiveness Caterina Colombo Università di Ferrara Alessandra Chirco Università del Salento Marcella Scrimitore Università del Salento Abstract Within

More information

EconS Sequential Competition

EconS Sequential Competition EconS 425 - Sequential Competition Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 47 A Warmup 1 x i x j (x

More information

Game theory and market power

Game theory and market power Game theory and market power Josh Taylor Section 6.1.3, 6.3 in Convex Optimization of Power Systems. 1 Market weaknesses Recall Optimal power flow: minimize p,θ subject to λ i : χ ij 0 : f i (p i ) i p

More information

Theory Field Examination Game Theory (209A) Jan Question 1 (duopoly games with imperfect information)

Theory Field Examination Game Theory (209A) Jan Question 1 (duopoly games with imperfect information) Theory Field Examination Game Theory (209A) Jan 200 Good luck!!! Question (duopoly games with imperfect information) Consider a duopoly game in which the inverse demand function is linear where it is positive

More information

Representation of TU games by coalition production economies

Representation of TU games by coalition production economies Working Papers Institute of Mathematical Economics 430 April 2010 Representation of TU games by coalition production economies Tomoki Inoue IMW Bielefeld University Postfach 100131 33501 Bielefeld Germany

More information

Internet Appendix for The Labor Market for Directors and Externalities in Corporate Governance

Internet Appendix for The Labor Market for Directors and Externalities in Corporate Governance Internet Appendix for The Labor Market for Directors and Externalities in Corporate Governance DORON LEVIT and NADYA MALENKO The Internet Appendix has three sections. Section I contains supplemental materials

More information

Interdependent Value Auctions with an Insider Bidder 1

Interdependent Value Auctions with an Insider Bidder 1 Interdependent Value Auctions with an Insider Bidder Jinwoo Kim We study the efficiency of standard auctions with interdependent values in which one of two bidders is perfectly informed of his value while

More information

ONLINE APPENDIX. Upping the Ante: The Equilibrium Effects of Unconditional Grants to Private Schools

ONLINE APPENDIX. Upping the Ante: The Equilibrium Effects of Unconditional Grants to Private Schools ONLINE APPENDIX Upping the Ante: The Equilibrium Effects of Unconditional Grants to Private Schools T. Andrabi, J. Das, A.I. Khwaja, S. Ozyurt, and N. Singh Contents A Theory A.1 Homogeneous Demand.................................

More information

SELECTION OF MARKOV EQUILIBRIUM IN A DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY WITH PRODUCTION TO ORDER. Milan Horniaček 1

SELECTION OF MARKOV EQUILIBRIUM IN A DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY WITH PRODUCTION TO ORDER. Milan Horniaček 1 SELECTION OF MARKOV EQUILIBRIUM IN A DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY WITH PRODUCTION TO ORDER Milan Horniaček 1 CERGE-EI, Charles University and Academy of Sciences of Czech Republic, Prague We use the requirement of

More information

Bargaining Efficiency and the Repeated Prisoners Dilemma. Bhaskar Chakravorti* and John Conley**

Bargaining Efficiency and the Repeated Prisoners Dilemma. Bhaskar Chakravorti* and John Conley** Bargaining Efficiency and the Repeated Prisoners Dilemma Bhaskar Chakravorti* and John Conley** Published as: Bhaskar Chakravorti and John P. Conley (2004) Bargaining Efficiency and the repeated Prisoners

More information

SANDWICH GAMES. July 9, 2014

SANDWICH GAMES. July 9, 2014 SANDWICH GAMES EHUD LEHRER AND ROEE TEPER July 9, 204 Abstract. The extension of set functions (or capacities) in a concave fashion, namely a concavification, is an important issue in decision theory and

More information