The Inconsistent Neoclassical Theory of the Firm and Its Remedy

Similar documents
New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

Problem Set 2 Solutions

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

ECON 186 Class Notes: Optimization Part 2

Modelling Production

Scarf Instability and Production: A Simulation

Neoclassical Growth Model: I

The Heckscher-Ohlin model: Mathematical treatment*

Lecture 04 Production Theory

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model

Maximum Value Functions and the Envelope Theorem

INTRODUCTORY MATHEMATICS FOR ECONOMICS MSCS. LECTURE 3: MULTIVARIABLE FUNCTIONS AND CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION. HUW DAVID DIXON CARDIFF BUSINESS SCHOOL.

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

A Summary of Economic Methodology

Lecture 5 Markups and Hedonics. Bronwyn H. Hall Economics 220C, UC Berkeley Spring 2005

ECON 255 Introduction to Mathematical Economics

Econ 11: Intermediate Microeconomics. Preliminaries

Mathematics Review Revised: January 9, 2008

Information and Communication Technologies and the Income Distribution: A General Equilibrium Simulation

Volume 30, Issue 3. Ramsey Fiscal Policy and Endogenous Growth: A Comment. Jenn-hong Tang Department of Economics, National Tsing-Hua University

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

Chapter 9. Natural Resources and Economic Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Econ 58 Gary Smith Spring Final Exam Answers

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture 2 : Balance Growth Paths

Population growth and technological progress in the optimal growth model

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 6: Partial and General Equilibrium

Intermediate Macroeconomics, EC2201. L1: Economic growth I

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

4.4 The functional distribution of income

Growth Theory: Review

With Realistic Parameters the Basic Real Business Cycle Model Acts Like the Solow Growth Model

Chapter 9. Natural Resources and Economic Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

( )! ±" and g( x)! ±" ], or ( )! 0 ] as x! c, x! c, x! c, or x! ±". If f!(x) g!(x) "!,

Aggregate Production Function. Production. Mark Huggett. Georgetown University. January 11, 2018

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Economics 210B Due: September 16, Problem Set 10. s.t. k t+1 = R(k t c t ) for all t 0, and k 0 given, lim. and

Lecture #3. General equilibrium

Economics 101 Lecture 5 - Firms and Production

Economics th April 2011

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Econ 5110 Solutions to the Practice Questions for the Midterm Exam

Theoretical premises of the Keynesian approach

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Introductory Microeconomics

Answers to Spring 2014 Microeconomics Prelim

Endogenous Growth Theory

Tvestlanka Karagyozova University of Connecticut

The Harris-Todaro model

Lecture Notes on Monotone Comparative Statics and Producer Theory

Foundation of (virtually) all DSGE models (e.g., RBC model) is Solow growth model

Lecture Notes October 18, Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I.

One-Sector Models of Endogenous Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

On the Dynamic Implications of the Cobb- Douglas Production Function

Problem Set Suggested Answers

Trade, Neoclassical Growth and Heterogeneous Firms

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition

Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-financing Undo Capital Misallocation?

WHY ARE THERE RICH AND POOR COUNTRIES? SYMMETRY BREAKING IN THE WORLD ECONOMY: A Note

Advanced Microeconomics

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Math Review ECON 300: Spring 2014 Benjamin A. Jones MATH/CALCULUS REVIEW

Econ 7110 slides Growth models: Solow, Diamond, Malthus. January 8, 2017

Handout: Competitive Equilibrium

Midterm Exam - Solutions

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

Economic Growth: Lecture 12, Directed Technological Change

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

From Difference to Differential Equations I

Professor: Alan G. Isaac These notes are very rough. Suggestions welcome. Samuelson (1938, p.71) introduced revealed preference theory hoping

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Directed Technological Change

Rice University. Fall Semester Final Examination ECON501 Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Writing Period: Three Hours

Optimization, constrained optimization and applications of integrals.

ECON Answers Homework #4. = 0 6q q 2 = 0 q 3 9q = 0 q = 12. = 9q 2 108q AC(12) = 3(12) = 500

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

Growth Theory: Review

Modern Urban and Regional Economics

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Comparative Statics. Autumn 2018

Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model.

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Functional Form. Econometrics. ADEi.

EconS Cost Structures

Constrained optimization.

T R(y(L)) w L = 0. L so we can write this as p ] (b) Recall that with the perfectly competitive firm, demand for labor was such that

Aggregate Supply. Econ 208. April 3, Lecture 16. Econ 208 (Lecture 16) Aggregate Supply April 3, / 12

τ σ 1 (n 3 + m) + (n 1 + n 2 )τ σ 1 n 1, n 2, n 3, m 0 In this equilibrium, (A.1)-(A.4) are all equalities. Solving (A.1)-(A.

Business Cycles: The Classical Approach

Input-biased technical progress and the aggregate elasticity of substitution: Evidence from 14 EU Member States

News Driven Business Cycles in Heterogenous Agents Economies

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

Monetary Economics. Lecture 15: unemployment in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I

Lecture 5: The neoclassical growth model

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

TECHNICAL APPENDIX. 7. Agents Decisions in the Cobb-Douglas Case

Transcription:

The Inconsistent Neoclassical Theory of the Firm and Its Remedy Consider the following neoclassical theory of the firm, as developed by Walras (1874/1954, Ch.21), Marshall (1907/1948, Ch.13), Samuelson (1965, Ch.4), Varian (1984, Ch.1), and many others. A firm, which operates with a Cobb-Douglas production function: β 1 β Y = AK L, (1) where Y is output, K capital and L labor, and faces the corresponding profit weighing: π = PY rk wl, (2) where P is output price, r rental price of capital and w wage rate, will employ the following profit-maximizing inputs: PβY K =, r (3) Y L =. w (4)

They are also known as the derived demands. In this particular Cobb-Douglas case, their own-price and income elasticities are all equal to one, and there is no cross-price elasticity. Given an exogenous output order, the prescribed demands can be worked out. Example 1 Given A=P=1, β=0.6, w=r=0.2 and Y 0 =20, according to (3) and (4) respectively K=60 and L=40, as also illustrated in Figure 1. However, with the resultant K and L the output according to (1) becomes Y 1 =51! This firm produces more output than what is ordered. Under different circumstances, it may produce less. <Insert Figure 1 Here> When the demands of (3) and (4) are substituted into (1), output becomes: β Y1 = AP r β 1- β w 1 β Y0. (5) Some conclude from this equation that output is indeterminate (Samuelson, 1965,

p.78-79), but such conclusion is misled by the assignment of identical notation to the two outputs, i.e. Y β = AP r β 1 β 1- β w Y. What (5) really indicates is that the inconsistency problem will persist, unless the bracketed term by rare chance happens to be equal to one. Even then output is not indeterminate; it does not exist at all, as shall be illustrated in the next section. Furthermore, when (3) and (4) are substituted into (2), profit becomes: PβY0 Y0 π 1 = PY1 r w. (6) r w Some also draw from this equation the zero profit conclusion (Varian, 1984, p.27; 1993, p.332), but it is again a wrong one. Zero profit would happen only by rare chance when Y 1 =Y 0, otherwise profit can be positive or negative. Consequently, the neoclassical notions of zero and maximum profit are meaningless. Hence, the neoclassical calculation is inconsistent and its conclusions invalid. Appendix I shows that the use of the CES function also produces the inconsistent calculation. For the same set of parameters as in Example 1, given a cost of C=20, the output-maximizing inputs are K PβC = =60 and r C L = =40, which will w produce an output of Y=51. Similarly, given an output of Y=20, the cost-minimizing

inputs are K (1 β ) βw (1 β ) r = Y =23.52 and L = Y =15.68, which means (1 β ) r βw β a cost of C=7.84. If P=1, both output maximization and cost minimization imply profit. However, for a different set of parameters, both of them may imply loss. Thus, these constrained optimization methods are also inconsistent. As the inconsistency is derived from (3) and (4), these demand functions are not trustworthy any more. Similarly, the other neoclassical conclusions about cost and market structure must also be invalid, as will be revealed step by step below. i The consequence of the inconsistent calculation could be catastrophic for real business firms, had they taken the neoclassical advices seriously. Such inconsistent mistake is too severe to be covered by the excuse that the analysis is for the short run. On the contrary, this is precisely the reason for the inconsistency. The neoclassical theory derives an input demand by holding output and the other input constant. It over-emphasizes, perhaps even abuses, the concept of short run. In practice, inputs and output are interdependent. Hence, only a simultaneous method can provide consistent results. i Earlier criticisms to the neoclassical theory include Hall and Hitch (1939), Lester (1946), and Gordon (1948), but after the defense by Machlup (1946, 1967) and

Friedman (1953) the heat of the dispute seems to have faded away. The theme of the dispute at that time, whether marginalism is valid or not, looks superficial now. That is why the dispute has ended in a draw (Machlup, 1956, p.3).