Solutions to Odd Number Exercises in Chapter 6

Similar documents
Solutions to Exercises in Chapter 12

The Simple Linear Regression Model: Reporting the Results and Choosing the Functional Form

Econ107 Applied Econometrics Topic 7: Multicollinearity (Studenmund, Chapter 8)

R t. C t P t. + u t. C t = αp t + βr t + v t. + β + w t

Chapter 11. Heteroskedasticity The Nature of Heteroskedasticity. In Chapter 3 we introduced the linear model (11.1.1)

ACE 562 Fall Lecture 8: The Simple Linear Regression Model: R 2, Reporting the Results and Prediction. by Professor Scott H.

Econ Autocorrelation. Sanjaya DeSilva

y = β 1 + β 2 x (11.1.1)

Time series Decomposition method

Estimation Uncertainty

ACE 562 Fall Lecture 4: Simple Linear Regression Model: Specification and Estimation. by Professor Scott H. Irwin

Licenciatura de ADE y Licenciatura conjunta Derecho y ADE. Hoja de ejercicios 2 PARTE A

Chapter 16. Regression with Time Series Data

Comparing Means: t-tests for One Sample & Two Related Samples

CHAPTER 9. Exercise Solutions

The Multiple Regression Model: Hypothesis Tests and the Use of Nonsample Information

20. Applications of the Genetic-Drift Model

Errata (1 st Edition)

Dynamic Econometric Models: Y t = + 0 X t + 1 X t X t k X t-k + e t. A. Autoregressive Model:

ACE 564 Spring Lecture 7. Extensions of The Multiple Regression Model: Dummy Independent Variables. by Professor Scott H.

Innova Junior College H2 Mathematics JC2 Preliminary Examinations Paper 2 Solutions 0 (*)

Financial Econometrics Jeffrey R. Russell Midterm Winter 2009 SOLUTIONS

(a) Set up the least squares estimation procedure for this problem, which will consist in minimizing the sum of squared residuals. 2 t.

Solutions: Wednesday, November 14

Unit Root Time Series. Univariate random walk

ECON 482 / WH Hong Time Series Data Analysis 1. The Nature of Time Series Data. Example of time series data (inflation and unemployment rates)

Vectorautoregressive Model and Cointegration Analysis. Time Series Analysis Dr. Sevtap Kestel 1

Vehicle Arrival Models : Headway

Chapter 15. Time Series: Descriptive Analyses, Models, and Forecasting

Distribution of Estimates

Wednesday, November 7 Handout: Heteroskedasticity

Robust estimation based on the first- and third-moment restrictions of the power transformation model

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

1. Diagnostic (Misspeci cation) Tests: Testing the Assumptions

CHAPTER 17: DYNAMIC ECONOMETRIC MODELS: AUTOREGRESSIVE AND DISTRIBUTED-LAG MODELS

Hypothesis Testing in the Classical Normal Linear Regression Model. 1. Components of Hypothesis Tests

The General Linear Test in the Ridge Regression

On Measuring Pro-Poor Growth. 1. On Various Ways of Measuring Pro-Poor Growth: A Short Review of the Literature

A Specification Test for Linear Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Models

3.1 More on model selection

Math 10B: Mock Mid II. April 13, 2016

OBJECTIVES OF TIME SERIES ANALYSIS

ACE 562 Fall Lecture 5: The Simple Linear Regression Model: Sampling Properties of the Least Squares Estimators. by Professor Scott H.

Department of Economics East Carolina University Greenville, NC Phone: Fax:

Summer Term Albert-Ludwigs-Universität Freiburg Empirische Forschung und Okonometrie. Time Series Analysis

Diebold, Chapter 7. Francis X. Diebold, Elements of Forecasting, 4th Edition (Mason, Ohio: Cengage Learning, 2006). Chapter 7. Characterizing Cycles

Testing the Random Walk Model. i.i.d. ( ) r

FORECASTING WITH REGRESSION

Outline. lse-logo. Outline. Outline. 1 Wald Test. 2 The Likelihood Ratio Test. 3 Lagrange Multiplier Tests

STRUCTURAL CHANGE IN TIME SERIES OF THE EXCHANGE RATES BETWEEN YEN-DOLLAR AND YEN-EURO IN

4.1 Other Interpretations of Ridge Regression

Modeling and Forecasting Volatility Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity Models. Economic Forecasting Anthony Tay Slide 1

Chapter 7: Solving Trig Equations

FITTING OF A PARTIALLY REPARAMETERIZED GOMPERTZ MODEL TO BROILER DATA

Matlab and Python programming: how to get started

A note on spurious regressions between stationary series

Types of Exponential Smoothing Methods. Simple Exponential Smoothing. Simple Exponential Smoothing

2.7. Some common engineering functions. Introduction. Prerequisites. Learning Outcomes

Lecture 4. Classical Linear Regression Model: Overview

Nature Neuroscience: doi: /nn Supplementary Figure 1. Spike-count autocorrelations in time.

Properties of Autocorrelated Processes Economics 30331

Chickens vs. Eggs: Replicating Thurman and Fisher (1988) by Arianto A. Patunru Department of Economics, University of Indonesia 2004

Explaining Total Factor Productivity. Ulrich Kohli University of Geneva December 2015

Methodology. -ratios are biased and that the appropriate critical values have to be increased by an amount. that depends on the sample size.

Cointegration and Implications for Forecasting

DEPARTMENT OF STATISTICS

GDP Advance Estimate, 2016Q4

Regression with Time Series Data

Final Exam. Tuesday, December hours

Bias in Conditional and Unconditional Fixed Effects Logit Estimation: a Correction * Tom Coupé

Kriging Models Predicting Atrazine Concentrations in Surface Water Draining Agricultural Watersheds

14 Autoregressive Moving Average Models

(10) (a) Derive and plot the spectrum of y. Discuss how the seasonality in the process is evident in spectrum.

Economics 8105 Macroeconomic Theory Recitation 6

Chapter 2. Models, Censoring, and Likelihood for Failure-Time Data

GMM - Generalized Method of Moments

Biol. 356 Lab 8. Mortality, Recruitment, and Migration Rates

Linear Combinations of Volatility Forecasts for the WIG20 and Polish Exchange Rates

INTRODUCTION TO MACHINE LEARNING 3RD EDITION

Macroeconomic Theory Ph.D. Qualifying Examination Fall 2005 ANSWER EACH PART IN A SEPARATE BLUE BOOK. PART ONE: ANSWER IN BOOK 1 WEIGHT 1/3

3.1.3 INTRODUCTION TO DYNAMIC OPTIMIZATION: DISCRETE TIME PROBLEMS. A. The Hamiltonian and First-Order Conditions in a Finite Time Horizon

KINEMATICS IN ONE DIMENSION

Macroeconometrics. Christophe BOUCHER. Session 2 A brief overview of the classical linear regression model 1

Math 333 Problem Set #2 Solution 14 February 2003

Non-uniform circular motion *

NCSS Statistical Software. , contains a periodic (cyclic) component. A natural model of the periodic component would be

Derived Short-Run and Long-Run Softwood Lumber Demand and Supply

State-Space Models. Initialization, Estimation and Smoothing of the Kalman Filter

ESTIMATION OF DYNAMIC PANEL DATA MODELS WHEN REGRESSION COEFFICIENTS AND INDIVIDUAL EFFECTS ARE TIME-VARYING

23.5. Half-Range Series. Introduction. Prerequisites. Learning Outcomes

The general Solow model

Math 2142 Exam 1 Review Problems. x 2 + f (0) 3! for the 3rd Taylor polynomial at x = 0. To calculate the various quantities:

WEEK-3 Recitation PHYS 131. of the projectile s velocity remains constant throughout the motion, since the acceleration a x

CHAPTER 2 Signals And Spectra

AP CALCULUS AB 2003 SCORING GUIDELINES (Form B)

Introduction D P. r = constant discount rate, g = Gordon Model (1962): constant dividend growth rate.

Excel-Based Solution Method For The Optimal Policy Of The Hadley And Whittin s Exact Model With Arma Demand

EXERCISES FOR SECTION 1.5

Sterilization D Values

Reliability of Technical Systems

Transcription:

1 Soluions o Odd Number Exercises in 6.1 R y eˆ 1.7151 y 6.3 From eˆ ( T K) ˆ R 1 1 SST SST SST (1 R ) 55.36(1.7911) we have, ˆ 6.414 T K ( ) 6.5 y ye ye y e 1 1 Consider he erms e and xe b b x e y e b e b x e y e e y b b x y Tb b x 1 1 1 1 xe x y b bx xy b x b x The las expressions in each of hese equaions become zero from he normal equaions ha are used o solve for he leas squares esimaors. Subsiuing e = and xe = back ino he original equaion, we obain y ye. 6.7 (a) Knowledge of he relaionship beween he rae of change of wages and he unemploymen rae is very imporan for governmen policy makers and unions. Typically, governmens like o keep he lid on inflaion, bu he cos of doing so may be increasing unemploymen. Unions are always aemping o negoiae pay rises for heir employees. However, hey mus be wary of doing so if wage rises mean ha fewer of heir workers can ge jobs. An economic model for relaing he rae of change in wages o unemploymen was derived in Secion 6.3.. I is called he Phillips' curve and is given by 1 %w 1 u A corresponding saisical model is %w 1 1 e u

where some saisical assumpions are needed for he random error e. We assume he e are independen normally disribued random variables wih zero mean and consan variance. To esimae his model, we use a se of 18 observaions on w and u for he period 1949 o 1966. The esimaion mehod used is he linear leas squares mehod regressing %w on 1/u. This mehod gives he esimaed equaion as % w 1 = 1484. 8. 739 R =.393 (. 355) (. 838) u where sandard errors are in parenheses. We would expec 1 < and >. Thus, from he esimaed equaion, b 1 and b give he expeced signs. The sandard error of b 1 is.355 which is relaively large and leads o b 1 being saisically insignifican. The esimae for b is saisically significan, bu, as we discovered in Exercise 6.(h), is large sandard error leads o a wide confidence inerval ha conveys lile economic informaion. Some of he economic implicaions were discussed in he answers o Exercise 6.. (b) From he Economic Repor o he Presiden we can consruc he following able where u is he unemploymen rae for all workers, w is average gross hourly earnings in curren dollars for he oal privae non-agriculural secor, and % w 1( w w 1) / w 1. Year w u %w 1974 4.4 5.5-1975 4.53 8.3 6.8396 1976 4.86 7.6 7.848 1977 5.5 6.9 8.47 1978 5.69 6. 8.381 1979 6.16 5.8 8.61 198 6.66 7. 8.1169 1981 7.5 7.5 8.8589 198 7.67 9.5 5.7931 1983 8.1 9.5 4.439 (c) The esimaed equaion for he Phillips' curve using he daa for he years 1975 o 1983 is % w 1 = 8311. 47851. R =.635 (. 18884) ( 13. 71) u where sandard errors are in parenheses. The esimae b 1 =.8311 suggess ha he annual wage increase will never drop below.83%, even as he unemploymen rae becomes very large. This oucome may be unrealisic; we may expec workers o accep a drop in real wages for very high unemploymen raes. If so, b 1 should be negaive. The very high sandard error of b 1, and is consequen insignificance, do no rule ou he possibiliy of 1 being negaive. The esimae b = 47.851 wih se(b ) = 13.71 is economically feasible and significan. However, he resuling confidence inerval is sill wide. I conveys lile informaion, alhough he large value of b suggess wage changes are very responsive o he unemploymen rae.

3 6.9 In he learning curve model ln( u) 1 ln( q), 1 is he logarihm of he uni cos of producion for he firs uni produced and is he elasiciy of uni cos wih respec o cumulaive producion. A 1% change in he cumulaive producion leads o a % change in he uni cos equal o.

4 6.11 The resuls are summarised in he following able. Sandard errors are in parenheses. Changing he unis of y only changes boh b 1 and b, making hem one hundred imes smaller. Changing he unis of x only influences only b, making i 1 imes bigger. When boh x and y are scaled b 1 changes bu no b. Regression b 1 b (i) y on x 4.768.183 (.14) (35) (ii) y on x* 4.768 1.83 (.14) (3.5) (iii) y* on x.4768 183 (.14) (35) (iv) y* on x*.4768.183 (.14) (35) 6.13 To es H : normally disribued errors for he preferable equaion, equaion 3, we need values of skewness and kurosis. They are S = -8465 and k = 3.567. The es saisic is T ( k 3) JB S.188 6 4 The hypohesis H is rejeced if JB () for a given significance level. Since () 5.991 a he 5 level of significance, we do no rejec H. Therefore, here is insufficien evidence o conclude ha he normal disribuion assumpion is unreasonable. Differen sofware packages can use differen esimaors for skewness and kurosis; and some repor excess kurosis ( k 3) as he kurosis. For example, SAS yields S.8741 and k 3.411, leading o a es value of JB.416. 6.15 (a) For households wih 1 child wfood 1.99.1495ln( oexp) (41) (9) se For households wih children: (5.19) (-16.7) R.33 wfood.9535.194ln( oexp) (365) (8) se (6.1) (-16.16) R 6

5 (b) In erms of we would expec a negaive value because as he oal expendiure increases he food share should decrease. Boh esimaions give he expeced sign. The sandard errors for b 1 and b from boh esimaions are relaively small resuling in high values of raios and significan esimaes. For households wih 1 child, he average oal expendiure is 94.848 and b1b ln( oexp) 1 1.99.1495ln(94.848) 1 ˆ.5461 b b ln( oexp) 1.99.1495ln(94.848) 1 For households wih children, he average oal expendiure is 11.17 and b1bln( oexp) 1.9535.194ln(11.17) 1 ˆ.6366 b b ln( oexp).9535.194ln(11.17) 1 Boh of he elasiciies are less han one; herefore, food is a necessiy.

6.8.4.6. WFOOD1.4. -. 3 4 5 6 -.4 3 4 5 6 X1 X1 Figure 6.4a Figure 6.4b (c) Figures 6.4a and 6.4b are he fied curve and he residual plos for households wih 1 child. The funcion linear in wfood and ln(oexp) seems o be an appropriae one. However, he observaions vary considerably around he fied line, consisen wih he low R value. Also, he absolue magniude of he residuals appears o decline as ln(oexp) increases. In Chaper 11 we discover ha such behavior suggess he exisence of heeroskedasiciy. Figures 6.5a and 6.5b are plos of he fied equaion and he residuals for households wih children. They are similar o he ones wih 1 child, indicaing ha he funcional form is a reasonable one. The values of JB for esing H : errors are normally disribued are 1.7941 and 6.3794 for households wih 1 child and children, respecively. Since boh values are greaer han he criical () 5.991, we rejec H. The p-values obained are 5 and 41, respecively, confirming ha H is rejeced. We conclude ha for boh cases he errors are no normally disribued. (Using SAS esimaes for skewness and excess kurosis, he JB values are 11.6 and 6.65, respecively.).8.4.6. WFOOD.4. -. 3.5 4. 4.5 5. 5.5 6. -.4 3.5 4. 4.5 5. 5.5 6. X Figure 6.5a Figure 6.5b X

7 6.17 (a) For households wih 1 child wfuel.395 486ln( oexp) (17) (48) For households wih children: (14.3) (-15) R.1458 se (b) wfuel.39 464ln( oexp) (198) (43) se (15.) (-1.71) R.115 We expec fuel o be a necessary good and as oal expendiure increases he fuel share should decrease. Tha is, we expec he sign of o be negaive. Boh esimaions give he expeced sign. The sandard errors for b 1 and b from boh esimaions are relaively small resuling in high values of raios. For households wih 1 child, he average oal expendiure is 94.848 and b1bln( oexp) 1.395 486ln(94.848) 1 ˆ.4494 b b ln( oexp).395 486ln(94.848) 1 For households wih children, he average oal expendiure is 11.17 and b1bln( oexp) 1.39 464ln(11.17) 1 ˆ.4647 b b ln( oexp).39 464ln(11.17) 1 Boh of he elasiciies are less han one; herefore, fuel is a necessiy..4.3.3. WFUEL1..1.1 3 4 5 6 -.1 3 4 5 6 X1 Figure 6.6a Figure 6.6b (c) Figures 6.6a and 6.6b are he fied curve and he residual plos for households wih 1 child. The plo of he acual observaions and he fied equaon is in Figure 6.6a. The funcional form is reasonable in he sense ha i is difficul o sugges an alernaive funcion which will be a beer fi o he scaer of poins. On he oher hand, he funcion provides a poor explanaion of variaion in he budge share of fuel. Consisen wih he low R, he observaions vary widely around he fied line. Also he variaion of he observaions around he fied line decreases as he oal X1

8 expendiure increases. The posiive residuals vary in magniude from zero o.3 whereas he range of he negaive residuals is zero o.1, suggesing a highly skewed error disribuion. Figures 6.7a and 6.7b are he fied curve and he residual plos for households wih children. They are similar o he ones wih 1 child. While i is difficul o sugges a funcional form which would fi beer han he linear-log one, he funcion is no a good one for explaining variaion in he fuel budge share. Perhaps a muliple regression model wih addiional explanaory variables would be an improvemen..5.6.4.4 WFUEL.3...1 3.5 4. 4.5 5. 5.5 6. -. 3.5 4. 4.5 5. 5.5 6. X Figure 6.7a Figure 6.7b X The values of JB for esing H : errors are normally disribued are 874.4 and 8738. for households wih 1 child and children, respecively. Since boh values are greaer han he criical () 5.991, we rejec H. The p-values are for boh cases confirming ha H is rejeced. We conclude ha for boh cases he errors are no normally disribued. 6.19 (a) Figures 6.1a, 6.1b, 6.1c and 6.1d are he plos of observaions of y agains x, ln(y) agains ln(x), y agains ln(x) and ln(y) agains x, respecively. The funcional forms o choose from are specified in par (b). They are all linear funcions of y and x or he logarihms of hem. The preferable form is he one where he plo of he observaions is bes represened by a linear line. This is he plo of y and x in Figure 6.1a. In all he oher figures a line wih some curvaure would be a beer fi. Thus, he chosen funcional form is he equaion y 1x e. (b) (i) (ii) yˆ.1367 15.6676x (3) (.691) se (4.5) (.667) R.9753

9 ln( y).848.3666ln( x) (.3356) (55) se (.5114) (6.6418) R.774 (iii) (iv) yˆ 1.5535.187ln( x) (.76) (454) se (5.644) (4.13).5663 ln( y) 1.759 3.366x (.1556) (3.5589) se (-11.33) (6.5488) R.7674 To check wheher he level of arsenic in he waer influences he level of arsenic in he oenails we es each equaion for wheher,, and are zero. We rejec an H if a raio is greaer han he absolue criical value. A level of significance 5, and 13 degrees of freedom, 5.16. The calculaed raios for he hypoheses from each equaion are all higher han he criical value. We herefore rejec H and conclude ha here is evidence o sugges ha he level of arsenic in waer does influence he level of arsenic in he oenails. (c) The plos of he residuals from equaion (i) o (iv) are presened in Figures 6.11-6.14. The residuals in Figures 6.1b and 6.13b display a rough U-shape, while hose in Figure 6.14b exhibi a rough invered U-shape. Thus, in hese cases, he residuals for small and large values of x or ln(x) have signs differen o he residuals ha correspond o middle values of x or ln(x). Such paerns sugges inappropriae funcional forms. Since he residuals for he linear funcion do no display such a paern, he plos suppor our choice of funcion in par (a). R.5.3.. Y 1.5 1..1.5 -.1 5.1.15 -. 5.1.15 X Figure 6.11a Figure 6.11b X

1 1 1..5 LNY -1 - -.5-3 -1-8 -6-4 - -1. -1-8 -6-4 - LNX LNX Figure 6.1a Figure 6.1b.5 1.5. 1. Y 1.5 1..5.5 -.5-1 -8-6 -4 - -1. -1-8 -6-4 - LNX LNX Figure 6.13a Figure 6.13b 1 1..5 LNY -1 - -.5-3 5.1.15-1. 5.1.15 X Figure 6.14a Figure 6.14b X

11 6.1 (a) The esimaed equaions for dishwasher shipmens as a funcion of durable goods expendiure and as a funcion of privae residenial invesmen are below. DISH DISH 154.43.856 DUR (95.5) (.548) R.77 67.19.58RES (534.7) (1.95) R.7465 The equaion ha gives he beer predicor is he equaion ha has he higher R. In his case i is he equaion wih DUR as he explanaory variable. Hence, DUR is he beer predicor. (b) (c) DISH DISH 86 154.43.856 DUR86 154.43.856(8.) 464 86 67.19.58RES86 67.19.58(67.) 4119 Since he acual DISH86 3915, for his fuure observaion RES is a beer predicor han DUR. The residual plos for he wo equaions using DUR and RES as he explanaory variables are in Figures 6.15a and 6.15b, respecively. The residuals appear o be correlaed. There is a endency for posiive residuals o follow posiive residuals and negaive residuals o follow negaive residuals. 15 1 1 5-5 5-5 -1 6 6 64 66 68 7 7 74 76 78 8 8 84 DISH Residuals Figure 6.15a using DUR -1 6 6 64 66 68 7 7 74 76 78 8 8 84 DISH Residuals Figure 6.15b using RES