Relative Deep Habits

Similar documents
Deep Habits: Technical Notes

Pricing To Habits and the Law of One Price

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Deep Habits, Nominal Rigidities and Interest Rate Rules

1 The Basic RBC Model

Macroeconomics Theory II

The Real Business Cycle Model

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Explaining the Effects of Government Spending Shocks on Consumption and the Real Exchange Rate. M. Ravn S. Schmitt-Grohé M. Uribe.

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Problem 1 (30 points)

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Equilibrium Conditions (symmetric across all differentiated goods)

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Chapter 11 The Stochastic Growth Model and Aggregate Fluctuations

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Advanced Macroeconomics

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Advanced Macroeconomics

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy

Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities

Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations?

The Smets-Wouters Model

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Economic transition following an emission tax in a RBC model with endogenous growth. EC-IILS JOINT DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES No. 17

The Small-Open-Economy Real Business Cycle Model

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

What s News In Business Cycles

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHAT'S NEWS IN BUSINESS CYCLES. Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe Martin Uribe. Working Paper

Learning and Global Dynamics

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle. June 7, 2018

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

slides chapter 3 an open economy with capital

Potential Output, the Output Gap, and the Labor Wedge

News Driven Business Cycles in Heterogenous Agents Economies

optimal simple nonlinear rules for monetary policy in a new-keynesian model

The Natural Rate of Interest and its Usefulness for Monetary Policy

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Empirical and Policy Performance of a Forward-Looking Monetary Model

What s News In Business Cycles: Supplementary Materials

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

Housing and the Business Cycle

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy

Implementable Fiscal Policy Rules

With Realistic Parameters the Basic Real Business Cycle Model Acts Like the Solow Growth Model

Reconciling Jaimovich-Rebello Preferences, Habit in Consumption and Labor Supply

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Real Business Cycle Models. Jordi Galí. Universitat Pompeu Fabra Spring 2018

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Potential Output, the Output Gap, and the Labor Wedge

Graduate Macro Theory II: Business Cycle Accounting and Wedges

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

Optimal Monetary Policy with Informational Frictions

Expanding Variety Models

Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING

Time-varying Consumption Tax, Productive Government Spending, and Aggregate Instability.

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

News Shocks and Business Cycles: Evidence from Forecast Data

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno

Gold Rush Fever in Business Cycles

Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model.

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Graduate Macroeconomics - Econ 551

Population Aging, Government Policy and the Postwar Japanese Economy

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models

Introduction to Macroeconomics

Stochastic simulations with DYNARE. A practical guide.

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth

Closing Small Open Economy Models

Nonlinearity. Exploring this idea and what to do about it requires solving a non linear model.

Monetary Policy and Equilibrium Indeterminacy in a Cash in Advance Economy with Investment. Abstract

Structural change in a multi-sector model of the climate and the economy

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

COMPANION APPENDIX TO Fiscal Consolidation with Tax Evasion and Corruption (not intended for publication)

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

RBC Model with Indivisible Labor. Advanced Macroeconomic Theory

HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 17 in Marnix Amand s mailbox.

Transcription:

Relative Deep Habits Morten Ravn Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martín Uribe May 5, 25 Abstract This note presents a detailed formal derivation of the equilibrium conditions of a variation of the deep habit model developed by Ravn, Schmitt-Grohé, and Uribe (23). In the present note, the single-period utility function depends on the quasi ratio of current consumption to the stock of habit of each variety, whereas in the original deep habit model it depends on the quasi difference of these two variables. We refer to the case discussed in this note as relative deep habits. JEL Classification: D1, D12, D42, E3. Keywords: Habit formation, customer market models, switching cost models, time varying markups and business cycles. London Business School and CEPR. Phone: +44 27 262 55 ext. 3717. E-mail: mravn@london.edu. Duke University, CEPR, and NBER. Phone: 919 66 1889. E-mail: grohe@duke.edu. Duke University and NBER. Phone: 919 66 1888. E-mail: uribe@duke.edu.

1 Relative Deep Habits in an Economy Without Capital 1.1 Households The economy is populated by a continuum of identical households of measure one indexed by j, 1]. Each household j has preferences defined over consumption of a continuum of differentiated consumption goods, c j it indexed by i, 1] and labor effort, hj t. Following Abel (199), preferences feature catching up with the Joneses. However, unlike in the work of Abel, we assume that consumption externalities operate at the level of each individual good rather than at the level of some composite final good. We refer to this variant as catching up with the Joneses good by good. Specifically, we assume that household j derives utility from an object x j t defined by x j t = 1 ( c j it s θ it 1 ) 1 1/η di 1/(1 1/η), (1) where s it 1 denotes the stock of external habit in consuming good i in period t 1, which is assumed to evolve over time according to the following law of motion s it = ρs it 1 +(1 ρ)c it, (2) where c it 1 cj itdj denotes the cross-section average level of consumption of variety i, which the household takes as exogenously given. The parameter θ measures the degree of time nonseparability in consumption of each variety. When θ =, we have the benchmark case of time separable preferences. At the same time, the parameter η > denotes the intratemporal elasticity of substitution of habit-adjusted consumption of different varieties. It will become clear shortly that the introduction of catching up with the Joneses at the level of individual goods introduces a supply-side channel of transmission inducing more persistence in aggregate variables. The utility function of the household is assumed to be of the form E t= β t U(x j t v t,h j t), (3) where E t denotes the mathematical expectations operator conditional on information available at time t, β (, 1) represents a subjective discount factor, and U is a period utility index assumed to be strictly increasing in its first argument, strictly decreasing in its second argument, twice continuously differentiable, and strictly concave. The variable v t denotes an 1

exogenous and stochastic preference shock that follows a univariate autoregressive process of the form v t = ρ v v t 1 + ɛ v t, where ρ v, 1) and ɛ v t i.i.d. with mean zero and standard deviation σ v. This shock is meant to capture innovations in private nonbusiness absorption. Households have two sources of wealth: wages and pure profits from the ownership of firms. At the same time, households allocate their income to purchases of consumption goods, c j it. Households face the following sequential budget constraint: 1 p it c j it di = w th j t +Φ j t, (4) where p it denotes the relative price of good i, w t denotes the real wage rate and Φ j t denotes lump-sum profits originated in household j s ownership of shares in firms. In addition, households are assumed to be subject to a borrowing constraint that prevents them from engaging in Ponzi games. Clearly, for any given levels of x j t, purchases of each variety i, 1] in period t must solve the dual problems of minimizing total expenditure, 1 p itc j itdi, subject to the aggregation constraints (1). The optimal level of c j it for i, 1] is given by ( ) η c j it = pit s θ(1 η) it 1 x j p t, (5) t ] 1 1 where P t P 1 η 1 η it di, is a price index, p it P it P t, is the relative price of variety i in terms of the composite good, and 1 p t ] 1 ( ) pit s θ 1 η 1 η it 1 di is the relative price of x t in terms of the composite good. Note that consumption of each variety depends negatively on its externality-adjusted relative price p it / p t. At the optimum, we have that p t x j t = 1 p itc j itdi. Then, the representative household s problem can be stated as consisting in choosing processes x j t and h j t so as to maximize the lifetime utility function (3) subject to p t x j t = w t h j t + φ j t, (6) given processes p t, w t, and Φ j t. The first-order condition associated with the household s 2

problem is U h(x j t,h j t) U x (x j t,h j t) = w t p t (7) 1.2 Firms Goods are produced by monopolistic firms. Each good i, 1] is produced using labor as the sole input via the following homogenous-of-degree-one production technology: y it = A t h it φ, (8) where y it denotes output of good i, h it denotes services of labor, φ denotes a fixed cost of production, and A t denotes an aggregate technology shock. We assume that the logarithm of A t follows a univariate autoregressive process of the form ln A t = ρ a ln A t 1 + ɛ a t, (9) where ɛ a t is a white noise with standard deviation σ a. On aggregate, households demand c it 1 cj itdj units of good i for consumption purposes. Equation (3) implies that c it = ( pit p t ) η s θ(1 η) it 1 x t (1) where x t 1 xj tdj. Firms are price setters. In exchange, they must stand ready to satisfy demand at the announced prices. Formally, firm i must satisfy A t h it φ c it. (11) Firm i s problem consists in choosing processes p it, c it, s it, and h it so as to maximize the present discounted value of profits, E t= r,t p it c it w t h it ], (12) subject to (2), (39), and (41), given processes r,t, p t, w t, A t, and x t, and initial condition s 1. The variable r,t is a pricing kernel determining the period-zero utility value of one unit of the composite good delivered in a particular state of period t. It follows from the household s problem that r,t β t U x (x t,h t )/ p t. The Lagrangian associated with firm i s 3

optimization problem can be written as L = E r,t {p it c it w t h it + κ t A t h it φ c it ] t= (pit ) ] } η +ν t x t s θ(1 η) it 1 c it + λ t ρs it 1 +(1 ρ)c it s it ], p t The first-order conditions associated with the firm s problem are equations (2), (3), (41), and (taking derivatives of the Lagrangian with respect to c it, s it, h it, and p it in this order) p it ν t κ t + λ t (1 ρ) =, θ(1 η)e t r t,t+1 ν t+1 c it+1 s it + ρe t r t,t+1 λ t+1 = λ t w t κ t = A t h it c it ην t c it p it = 1.3 Equilibrium In any symmetric equilibrium p it = 1. It then follows from the last equation of the previous subsection that the shadow value of a marginal sale in period t, ν t, is constant and equal to 1/η. We keep the notation regarding habit formation as flexible as possible. Specifically, we allow for two different parameters, θ and θ d. This distinction allows us to capture the following special cases: (1) Superficial habits, θ d =. (2) Deep habits θ = θ d >. In most cases, we consider the special case of deep habits, θ d. The equilibrium conditions are then given by x t = c t (13) 1 1 η wt A t s θ t 1 U x (x t+1 v t+1,h t+1 ) s θ t 1 = βe t U x (x t v t,h t ) s θ t U h(x t v t,h t ) U x (x t v t,h t ) = w t s θ t 1 (14) A t h t φ = c t (15) d (1 η) θ η c t+1 s t + ρ 1 1 η w t+1 A t+1 ] (16) s t = ρs t 1 +(1 ρ)c t (17) ln A t = ρ a ln A t 1 + ɛ a t (18) 4

v t = ρ v v t 1 + ɛ v t (19) This is a system of 7 nonlinear, stochastic, difference equations in 7 unknowns. We look for a stationary solution to this system. 1.4 Calibration and Functional Forms As in Ravn, Schmitt-Grohé, and Uribe (23), we assume that the period utility index is separable in consumption and leisure. Specifically, preferences are of the form U(x, h) = x1 σ 1 1 σ + γ (1 h)1 χ 1, 1 χ where <σ 1,<χ 1, and γ>. In the special case in which σ and χ approach unity, this utility function converges to the log-linear specification adopted in countless businesscycle studies (e.g., King, Plosser, and Rebelo, 1988). We calibrate the model to the U.S. economy following Ravn, Schmitt-Grohé, and Uribe (23). The time unit is meant to be one quarter. Table 2 summarizes the calibration. We Table 1: Calibration Symbol Value Description β.992 Subjective discount factor σ 2 Inverse of intertemporal elasticity of substitution θ, θ d -.1 Degree of habit formation ρ.85 Persistence of habit stock δ.253 Quarterly depreciation rate η 5.3 Elasticity of substitution across varieties ɛ hw 1.3 Frisch elasticity of labor supply h.2 Steady-State fraction of time devoted to work ḡ.318 Steady-state level of government purchases φ.853 Fixed cost ρ v,ρ a.9 Persistence of exogenous shocks set θ =.1, ρ =.85, η =5.3, and σ = 2. We fix the preference parameter γ to ensure that in the deterministic steady state households devote 2 percent of their time to market activities following Prescott (1986). The calibration restrictions that identify the remaining structural parameters of the model are taken from Rotemberg and Woodford (1992). We follow their calibration strategy to facilitate comparison of our model of endogenous markups due to deep habits to their ad-hoc version of the customer-market model. In particular, we set the annual real interest rate to 4 percent and the Frisch labor supply elasticity equal to 5

1.3. These restrictions imply that the subjective discount factor, β, is.99, and that the preference parameter χ is 3.8. As shown later in this note, in our model the steady-state markup of prices over marginal costs, µ, is given by µ = ηm ηm 1, where ( ) 1 βρ m βθ(1 η)+ 1 βρ ] 1 Our calibration implies an average value-added markup of 1.13. Note that in the case of perfect competition, that is, when η, the markup converges to unity. In the case of no relative deep habit, i.e., when θ = θ d =, we have that m equals one, and the markup equals η/(η 1) = 1.23, which relates the markup to the intratemporal elasticity of substitution across varieties in the usual way. This expression for the steady-state markup is the one that emerges from models with imperfect competition and superficial habit (e.g., Giannoni and Woodford, 23; and Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans, 23). Because under deep relative habit, the parameter m is greater than unity, firms have less market power under deep relatie habits than under superficial habits. This finding is akin to the result of Phelps and Winter (197), who show that in a customer-market model, the average markup is below the markup that arises under a standard imperfect competition environment. We set the serial correlation of all two shocks to.9 (i.e., ρ v = ρ a =.9.). These values are in the ball park of available estimates. The next section describes in detail how the calibration restrictions are used to identified the structural parameters of the model and how to solve for the steady-state values of the endogenous variables. Deterministic Steady State Consider shutting off all sources of uncertainty and letting the system settle on a stationary point where any variable x t satisfies x t = x t+1 for all t. In this state, the equilibrium conditions (43)-(19) collapse to: x = c 1 θ (2) γc σ(1 θ)+θ (1 h) = w χ (21) h = c + φ (22) 6

( ) 1 w] = βθ d (1 η)+ 1 βρ ] 1 1 βρ η (23) s = c (24) A =1 v = This is a system of 7 equations in the following 16 unknowns: the 7 endogenous variables x, c, s, h, w, v, A; and 9 structural parameters σ,θ,β,η,φ,χ, γ, ρ, θ d. To identify all 16 unknowns we impose 13 calibration restrictions: h φ uk wh = (25) R = 1.4 1/4 θ = θ d =.86 ρ =.85 η = 5.3 h =.2 σ = 2 ɛ hw ln h ln w = 1.3 λ constant Given the assumed preference specification, the Frisch labor supply elasticity is given by ɛ hw = 1 h hχ. This expression can be solved for χ. The parameter β can be backed out from the assumed value for the interest rate β = 1 R. Now using the fact that in the steady state the markup is given by µ =1/w, use equation (67) to write 1=η 1 1 ]( ) 1 βρ βθ(1 η)+ 1 βρ ] 1 µ Rearranging, we obtain the following expression for the steady-state markup µ = ηm ηm 1, 7

where m ( ) 1 βρ βθ(1 η)+ 1 βρ ] 1 We note that if θ(η 1) > (< ), then m<1(> 1). Using the definition of the markup, we can write the zero-profit condition (77) as φ = ( 1 1 ) h µ The production technology can be used to uncover the steady-state value of output: y = h φ. Consumption, in turn, satisfies, c = y The steady-state wage rate satisfies w = 1 µ Equations (71) determines directly the steady-state value of s. Finally, we can solve (62) for γ to obtain w(1 h)χ γ = c σ(1 θ)+θ Figure 1 displays impulse responses to a positive preference shock (first row) and to a positive productivity shock (second row). The deep habit case is shown with a solid line, the superficial habit case is shown with a broken line, and the economy without habits is shown with a dotted line. 2 An Economy With Capital and Deep Habits Affecting All Components of Aggregate Demand In this section we modify the simple model studied thus far in two dimensions. First, we introduce capital accumulation. Second, we assume that not only private consumption but also government spending and private investment are subject to deep habit formation. The model s parameterization is flexible enough to allow for the case in which any combination of aggregate demand components is subject to deep habits. 8

Figure 1: Impulse Responses to Positive Preference and Productivity Shocks Under Deep Habits, Superficial Habits, and No Habit in an Economy Without Capital.2 Markup Output and Consumption.8 Wage.6 Real Interest Rate.15.1.5.6.4.2.5.1.15.4.2 1 2 1 2.2 1 2 1 2 Markup Output and Consumption.8 1.5 Wage Real Interest Rate.2.4.6.6.4.2 1.5.5.1.15.8 1 2 1 2 1 2.2 1 2 Row 1: Preference Shock. Row 2: Technology shock. Impulse responses are measured in percent deviations from steady state. Horizontal axes display the number of quarters after the shock. 9

2.1 Households The economy is populated by a continuum of identical households of measure one indexed by j, 1]. Each household j has preferences defined over consumption of a continuum of differentiated consumption goods, c j it indexed by i, 1] and labor effort, hj t. Following Abel (199), preferences feature catching up with the Joneses. However, unlike in the work of Abel, we assume that consumption externalities operate at the level of each individual good rather than at the level of some composite final good. We refer to this variant as catching up with the Joneses good by good. Specifically, we assume that household j derives utility from an object x j t defined by equation (1). The utility function of the household is assumed to be of the form given in equation (3). Households have three sources of wealth: wages, rents from capital, and pure profits from the ownership of firms. At the same time, households allocate their income to purchases of consumption goods, c j it, purchases of investment goods, ij it, and to payment of taxes, τ t. Households face the following sequential budget constraint: 1 p it (c j it + ij it )di + τ t = w t h j t + u t k t +Φ j t (26) where p it denotes the price of good i, w t denotes the real wage rate, u t denotes the rental rate of capital, and k j t denotes the stock of capital held by household j, Φ j t denotes lump-sum profits originated in household j s ownership of shares in firms, and τ t denotes real lump-sum taxes levied in period t. The capital stock evolves according to the following law of motion k j t+1 =(1 δ)k j t + x I j t, (27) where x I j t denotes investment by household j in period t. Investment is a composite good produced using intermediate goods via the technology x I j t = 1 ( i j it s I θ I it 1 ) 1 1/η di 1/(1 1/η). (28) The variable s I it 1 summarizes how productive a particular input will. The idea is if a firm has a lot of experience in purchasing intermediate input i, then current purchases of that intermediate good i will be more effective. For each intermediate good i the priorbusiness-capital-stock, s I it 1, is assumed to evolve over time according to s I it = ρsi it 1 +(1 ρ)i it (29) 1

In addition, households are assumed to be subject to a borrowing constraint that prevents them from engaging in Ponzi games. Clearly, for any given levels of x j t and x I j t, purchases of each variety i, 1] in period t must solve the dual problems of minimizing total expenditure, 1 p it(c j it + ij it )di, subject to the aggregation constraints (1) and (28). The optimal levels of c j it and ij it for i, 1] are given by and where is the price of x t and ( ) η c j it = pit s θ(1 η) it 1 x j t (3) p t ( ) η i j it = pit s I p I it 1 (1 η) x I j ]θi t (31) t 1 p t 1 p I t ] 1 ( ) pit s θ 1 η 1 η it 1 di ( pit s I it 1] θ) 1 η di ] 1 1 η is the price of a unit of investment, x I t. Note that consumption of each variety depends negatively on its externality-adjusted relative price p it / p t. At the optimum, we have that p t x j t = 1 p itc j it di and pi t xij t = 1 p iti j itdi. Then, the representative household s problem can be stated as consisting in choosing processes x j t, x Ij t, h j t, and k j t, so as to maximize the lifetime utility function (3) subject to (27) and p t x j t + p I t x Ij t + τ t = w t h j t + u t k j t + φ j t, (32) given processes p t, p I t, w t, u t, and Φ j t. The first-order conditions associated with the household s problem are U h(x j t,h j t) U x (x j t,h j t) = w t (33) p t p I t U x (x j t,h j t) p t = βe t U x (x j t+1,h j t+1) p t+1 (1 δ) p I t+1 + u t+1] (34) 2.2 The Government We assume that government expenditures,g t, are exogenous, stochastic, and follow a univariate first-order autoregressive process of the form ln(g t /ḡ) =ρ g ln(g t 1 /ḡ)+ɛ g t, 11

where the innovation ɛ g t distributes i.i.d. with mean zero and standard deviation σ g. The government allocates spending over intermediate goods g it so as to maximize the quantity of a composite good produced with intermediate goods according to the relationship 1 x g t = ( git s g it 1 ]θg ) ] 1 1/η 1/(1 1/η) di. The variable s g it denotes the stock of habit in good i, and evolves over time as s g it = ρsg it 1 +(1 ρ)g it. (35) We justify our specification of the aggregator function for government consumption by assuming that private households value government spending in goods in a way that is separable from private consumption and leisure and that households derive habits on consumption of government provided goods. The government s problem consists in choosing g it, i, 1], so as to maximize x g t subject to the budget constraint 1 p itg it g t and taking as given the initial conditions s g i 1. In solving this maximization problem, the government takes as given the effect of current public consumption on the level of next period s composite good i.e., habits in government consumption are external. Conceivably, government habits could be treated as internal to the government even if they are external to their beneficiaries, namely, households. This, alternative, however, is analytically less tractable. The case of no habits in government consumption results from setting θ g = in the above aggregator function for public goods. We believe that this is not the case of greatest interest under our maintained assumption that government spending on goods is valued by habit-forming private agents. The resulting demand for each good i, 1] by the public sector is where g it = ( pit p g t ) η x g t s gθ(1 η) it 1, (36) g t = p g t x g t 1 ( ) ] 1 1 η p g t p it s gθ 1 η it 1 di Public spending is assumed to be fully financed by lump-sum taxation. g t = τ t, for all t. 12

2.3 Firms Goods are produced by monopolistic firms. Each good i, 1] is produced using labor and capital as inputs via the following homogenous-of-degree-one production technology: y it = A t F (k it,h it ) φ, (37) where y it denotes output of good i, k it and h it denote services of capital and labor, φ denotes a fixed cost of production, and A t denotes an aggregate technology shock. We assume that the logarithm of A t follows a univariate autoregressive process of the form ln A t = ρ a ln A t 1 + ɛ a t, (38) where ɛ a t is a white noise with standard deviation σ a. On aggregate, households demand c it 1 cj it dj units of good i for consumption purposes and i it 1 ij itdj units for investment purposes. Equations (3) and (31) imply that c it = ( pit p t ) η s θ(1 η) it 1 x t (39) and i it = ( pit p I t ) η s I it 1 ]θi (1 η) x I t (4) where x t 1 xj tdj and x I t 1 xij t dj. Firms are price setters. In exchange, they must stand ready to satisfy demand at the announced prices. Formally, firm i must satisfy A t F (k it,h it ) φ c it + i it + g it. (41) Firm i s problem consists in choosing processes p it, c it, i it, g it, s it, s g it, h it, and k it so as to maximize the present discounted value of profits, E t= r,t p it (c it + i it + g it ) w t h it u t k it ], (42) subject to (2), (29) (35), (36), (39), (4), and (41), given processes r,t, p t, p g t, i t, x g t, w t, u t, A t, and x t, and initial conditions s 1 and s g 1. The variable r,t is a pricing kernel determining the period-zero utility value of one unit of the composite good delivered in a particular state of period t. It follows from the household s problem that r,t β t U x (x t,h t )/ p t. The Lagrangian 13

associated with firm i s optimization problem can be written as L = E r,t {p it c it + p it i it + p it g it w t h it u t k it t= +κ t A t F (k it,h it ) φ c it i it g it ] (pit +ν t p t +ν I t +ν g t (pit p I t (pit p g t ) η x t s θ(1 η) it 1 c it ] + λ t ρs it 1 +(1 ρ)c it s it ] ) ] η x I t si it 1 (1 η) i ]θi it + λ I t ρs I it 1 +(1 ρ)i it sit] I ) ] η x g t s g (1 η) it 1 g ]θg it + λ g t ρs g it 1 +(1 ρ)g it sit] } g, The first-order conditions associated with the firm s problem are equations (2), (29), (35), (36), (39), (4), (41) and (taking derivatives of the Lagrangian with respect to c it, s it, i it, s I it, g it, s g it, h it, k it, and p it in this order) 2.4 Equilibrium p it ν t κ t + λ t (1 ρ) =, c it+1 θ(1 η)e t r t,t+1 ν t+1 + ρe t r t,t+1 λ t+1 = λ t s it p it νt I κ t + λ I t (1 ρ) =, θ I (1 η)e t r t,t+1 νt+1 I i it+1 + ρe s I t r t,t+1 λ I t+1 = λi t it p it ν g t κ t + λ g t (1 ρ) =, θ(1 η)e t r t,t+1 ν g g it+1 t+1 s g + ρe t r t,t+1 λ g t+1 = λ g t it w t κ t = A t F h (k it,h it ) u t κ t = A t F k (k it,h it ) c it c it + i it + g it ην t ην I i it t ην g g it t = p it p it p it We keep the notation regarding habit formation as flexible as possible. Specifically, we allow for three different habit parameters θ, θ I and θ g. This distinction allows us to capture the following special cases: (1) Deep habit on private consumption but not on government 14

consumption and not on investment θ> and θ g = θ I = ; (2) Deep habit on private and public consumption, θ g = θ d > and θ I > ; and (3) In the main text, we consider the special case of deep habit uniform across all private and public consumption, θ d = θ g = θ I. In any symmetric equilibrium p it = 1. The equilibrium conditions are then given by x t = c t s θ t 1 (43) w 1 ν t t A tf h (k t,h t) 1 ν I t w t A tf h (k t,h t) 1 ν g t w t A tf h (k t,h t) s I t 1 ]θi U x(x t v t,h t ) s θ t 1 x I t = i t s I t 1 ]θi (44) U h(x t v t,h t ) U x (x t v t,h t ) = w t s θ t 1 (45) U x (x t+1 v t+1,h t+1 ) = βe t (1 δ)s I s θ t + u ]θi t+1 ] (46) t A t F (k t,h t ) φ = c t + i t + g t (47) k t+1 =(1 δ)k t + x i t (48) c t + g t + i t η = ν t c t + ν g t g t + νt I i t (49) θ d c t+1 (1 η)ν t+1 + ρ 1 ν t+1 s t (5) + ρ 1 νi t+1 (51) + ρ 1 νg t+1 (52) F h (k t,h t ) F k (k t,h t ) = w t (53) u t s t = ρs t 1 +(1 ρ)c t (54) U x (x t+1 v t+1,h t+1 ) s θ t 1 = βe t U x (x t v t,h t ) s θ t U x (x t+1 v t+1,h t+1 ) s θ t 1 = βe t θ I (1 η)ν I i t+1 U x (x t v t,h t ) s θ t+1 t s I t U x (x t+1 v t+1,h t+1 ) s θ t 1 = βe t θ g (1 η)ν g g t+1 U x (x t v t,h t ) s θ t+1 t s g t s I t = ρsi t 1 +(1 ρ)i t (55) s g t = ρs g t 1 +(1 ρ)g t (56) ln A t = ρ a ln A t 1 + ɛ a t (57) v t = ρ v v t 1 + ɛ v t (58) ln(g t /ḡ) =ρ g ln(g t 1 /ḡ)+ɛ g t (59) 15 w t+1 A t+1 F h (k t+1,h t+1 ) w t+1 A t+1 F h (k t+1,h t+1 ) w t+1 A t+1 F h (k t+1,h t+1 ) ] ] ]

This is a system of 17 nonlinear, stochastic, difference equations in 17 unknowns. We look for a stationary solution to this system. 2.5 Calibration and Functional Forms As in Ravn, Schmitt-Grohé, and Uribe (23), we assume that the period utility index is separable in consumption and leisure. Specifically, preferences are of the form U(x, h) = x1 σ 1 1 σ + γ (1 h)1 χ 1, 1 χ where <σ 1,<χ 1, and γ>. In the special case in which σ and χ approach unity, this utility function converges to the log-linear specification adopted in countless businesscycle studies (e.g., King, Plosser, and Rebelo, 1988). The production function is assumed to be of the Cobb-Douglas type F (k, h) =k α h 1 α ; α (, 1). We calibrate the model to the U.S. economy following Ravn, Schmitt-Grohé, and Uribe (23). The time unit is meant to be one quarter. Table 2 summarizes the calibration. Table 2: Calibration Symbol Value Description β.992 Subjective discount factor σ 2 Inverse of intertemporal elasticity of substitution θ, θ d,θ s -.1 Degree of habit formation ρ.85 Persistence of habit stock α.25 capital elasticity of output δ.253 Quarterly depreciation rate η 5.3 Elasticity of substitution across varieties ɛ hw 1.3 Frisch elasticity of labor supply h.2 Steady-State fraction of time devoted to work ḡ.318 Steady-state level of government purchases φ.853 Fixed cost ρ v,ρ g,ρ a.9 Persistence of exogenous shocks We set θ = θ s = θ g =.1, ρ =.85, η = 5.3, and σ = 2. We fix the preference parameter γ to ensure that in the deterministic steady state households devote 2 percent of their time to market activities following Prescott (1986). The calibration restrictions that identify the remaining structural parameters of the model are taken from Rotemberg and 16

Woodford (1992). We follow their calibration strategy to facilitate comparison of our model of endogenous markups due to deep habits to their ad-hoc version of the customer-market model. In particular, we set the labor share in GDP to 75 percent, the consumption share to 7 percent, the government consumption share to 12 percent, the annual real interest rate to 4 percent, and the Frisch labor supply elasticity equal to 1.3. These restrictions imply that the capital elasticity of output in production, α, is.25, the depreciation rate, δ, is.25 per quarter, the subjective discount factor, β, is.99, and that the preference parameter χ is 3.8. As shown later in this note, in our model the steady-state markup of price over marginal cost, µ, is given by µ = ηm ηm 1, where m ( ) 1 βρ βθ(1 η)+ 1 βρ ] 1 s c + ( ) 1 βρ βθ g (1 η)+ 1 βρ ] 1 s g + s i Our calibration implies an average value-added markup of 1.13. Note that in the case of perfect competition, that is, when η, the markup converges to unity. In the case of no relative deep habit, i.e., when θ = θ d = θ g =, we have that m equals one, and the markup equals η/(η 1) = 1.23, which relates the markup to the intratemporal elasticity of substitution across varieties in the usual way. This expression for the steady-state markup is the one that emerges from models with imperfect competition and superficial habit (e.g., Giannoni and Woodford, 23; and Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans, 23). Because under deep relative habit, the parameter m is greater than unity, firms have less market power under deep relatie habits than under superficial habits. This finding is akin to the result of Phelps and Winter (197), who show that in a customer-market model, the average markup is below the markup that arises under a standard imperfect competition environment. We set the serial correlation of all three shocks to.9 (i.e., ρ v = ρ g = ρ a =.9.). These values are in the ball park of available estimates. The next section describes in detail how the calibration restrictions are used to identified the structural parameters of the model and how to solve for the steady-state values of the endogenous variables. 17

Deterministic Steady State Consider shutting off all sources of uncertainty and letting the system settle on a stationary point where any variable x t satisfies x t = x t+1 for all t. In this state, the equilibrium conditions (43)-(59) collapse to: x = c 1 θ (6) x I = i 1 θi (61) γc σ(1 θ)+θ (1 h) χ = w (62) 1=β1 δ + i θi u] (63) k α h 1 α = c + i + g + φ (64) i 1 θi = δk (65) 1 w (1 α)(k/h) α c + g + i = νc + ν g g + ν I i (66) η ] ( ) = βθ d (1 η)+ 1 βρ ] ν (67) 1 βρ ] ( ) w 1 = βθ I (1 η)+ 1 βρ ] ν I (1 α)(k/h) α 1 βρ (68) ] ( ) w t 1 = βθ g (1 η)+ 1 βρ ] ν g (1 α)(k/h) α 1 βρ (69) 1 α α k h = w u (7) s = c (71) s I = i (72) s g = g (73) A = 1 (74) v = (75) 18

g =ḡ. (76) This is a system of 17 equations in the following 31 unknowns: the 17 endogenous variables x, x I, c, s, s I, h, w, v, ν I, u, A, i, g, k, ν, ν g, and s g ; and 14 structural parameters σ, θ,δ,β,η,α,φ,χ, γ, ρ, θ d, θ I, θ g,ḡ, To identify all 31 unknowns we impose 14 calibration restrictions: wh s h k α h 1 α φ =.75 c s c k α h 1 α φ =.7 ḡ s g k α h 1 α φ =.12 k α h 1 α φ uk wh = (77) R 1 δ + ui θi = 1.4 1/4 θ = θ d = θ g = θ I =.1 ρ =.85 η = 5.3 h =.2 σ = 2 ɛ hw ln h ln w = 1.3 λ constant Given the assumed preference specification, the Frisch labor supply elasticity is given by ɛ hw = 1 h hχ. This expression can be solved for χ. Equation (63) can be solved for β β = 1 R. Equation (67) and (69) imply that ν g ν = ] βθ d (1 η)+ 1 βρ ρ 1 ] βθ g (1 η)+ 1 βρ ρ 1 19

And equations (67) and (68) imply that ν I ν = ] βθ d (1 η)+ 1 βρ ρ 1 ] βθ I (1 η)+ 1 βρ ρ 1 Using those expression we can solve (66) for ν ν = 1 1 ] η s c + νg s ν g + νi s ν i Note that in the special case that θ I = θ g = θ d, we have ν = ν g = ν I and thus ν =1/η. With ν at hand we obtain: ν g = ν νg ν and ν I = ν νi ν Now use equations (67) to find the steady state markup. First, use 1/mu = w/f h : 1 1 ] ( )] = 1+βθ d (1 η) ν µ 1 βρ Rearranging, we obtain the following expression for the steady-state markup µ = 1 ( 1 1+βθ d (1 η) ρ 1 1 βρ )], ν as Using the definition of the markup and (7) we can write the zero-profit condition (77) φ = ( 1 1 ) k α h 1 α µ It follows that the labor share, s h wh/y, is given by s h =1 α. 2

Finally, to determine δ we use the following relation δ = i1 θi k yi θi = s i k = s i ui θi s k = 1 s c s g s h 1 α α β 1 1+δ] The first equality uses (65), and the last one uses (64), (63), and (7). At this point, we have identified 1 of the 13 structural parameters, namely, σ, θ, δ, β, η, α, χ, ρ, θ d, θ g. It remains to determine values for the parameters γ, ḡ and φ and steady-state values for the endogenous variables of the model. We accomplish this task next. To obtain the deterministic-steady-state level of the capital stock, solve (65) for k. This yields k = i1 θi δ = (s iy) 1 θi δ = (s ik α h 1 α φ]) 1 θi δ = (s ik α h 1 α ]/µ) 1 θi = δ ( (s i h 1 α /µ) 1 θi δ ) 1 1 α(1 θ I ) Knowing k and h, the parameter φ was found above to be equal to (1 1/µ)k α h 1 α. The production technology delivers the steady-state value of output: y = k α h 1 α φ. The steady-state values of the components of aggregate demand follow immediately c = s c y i = s i y 21

g = s g y The steady-state value of the rental rate of capital, u, is given by u = β 1 (1 δ) i θi Equation (7) determines the steady-state wage rate. Equations (67), (69), (71), (73), and (76) determine directly the steady-state value of ν, ν g, s, s g, and ḡ, respectively. Finally, we can solve (62) for γ to obtain w(1 h)χ γ = c σ(1 θ)+θ Figure 2 displays impulse responses to a positive preference shock (first row), to a positive government spending shock (second row), and to a positive productivity shock (third row). 22

Figure 2: Impulse Responses to Positive Preference, Government Spending, and Productivity Shocks Under Deep Relative Habits in All Components of Aggregate Demand 7 x 1 3 Markup.4 Output.8 Wage 1 Consumption 6 5 4.3.2.1.9.1.5 3 1 2 1 2.11 1 2 1 2 12 x 1 4 Markup.6 Output.16 Wage.1 Consumption 1.4.17.2 8.2.18.3 6 1 2.19.4 1 2 1 2 1 2.2 Markup 1.5 Output 1 Wage.45 Consumption.2.4 1.5.8.6.4.35.3.6 1 2 1 2.4 1 2.25 1 2 Row 1: Preference Shock. Row 2: Gov t Spending Shock Row 3: Technology shock. Impulse responses are measured in percent deviations from steady state. Horizontal axes display the number of quarters after the shock. 23

References King, Robert G.; Plosser, Charles I.; and Rebelo, Sergio T., Production, Growth, and Business Cycles I. The Basic Neoclassical Model, Journal of Monetary Economics, 21, March-May 1988, 195-232. Ravn, Morten, Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé, and Martín Uribe, Deep Habits, manuscript, Duke University, December, 23. 24