Characterization of Equilibrium Paths in a Two-Sector Economy with CES Production Functions and Sector-Specific Externality

Similar documents
Global Externalities, Endogenous Growth and Sunspot fluctuations

Local indeterminacy in continuous-time models: the role of returns to scale

Local and global indeterminacy in two-sector models of endogenous growth

L institution sportive : rêve et illusion

Passerelle entre les arts : la sculpture sonore

Optimal Cycles and Social Inequality: What Do We Learn from the Gini Index?

Methylation-associated PHOX2B gene silencing is a rare event in human neuroblastoma.

Completeness of the Tree System for Propositional Classical Logic

Territorial Intelligence and Innovation for the Socio-Ecological Transition

Case report on the article Water nanoelectrolysis: A simple model, Journal of Applied Physics (2017) 122,

Weak Concavity Properties of Indirect Utility Functions in Multisector Optimal Growth Models

A new simple recursive algorithm for finding prime numbers using Rosser s theorem

The marginal propensity to consume and multidimensional risk

About partial probabilistic information

Easter bracelets for years

Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities

Smart Bolometer: Toward Monolithic Bolometer with Smart Functions

On Symmetric Norm Inequalities And Hermitian Block-Matrices

The core of voting games: a partition approach

Dispersion relation results for VCS at JLab

Soundness of the System of Semantic Trees for Classical Logic based on Fitting and Smullyan

Evolution of the cooperation and consequences of a decrease in plant diversity on the root symbiont diversity

Thomas Lugand. To cite this version: HAL Id: tel

Can we reduce health inequalities? An analysis of the English strategy ( )

The Core of a coalitional exchange economy

The FLRW cosmological model revisited: relation of the local time with th e local curvature and consequences on the Heisenberg uncertainty principle

Influence of network metrics in urban simulation: introducing accessibility in graph-cellular automata.

Hook lengths and shifted parts of partitions

On Symmetric Norm Inequalities And Hermitian Block-Matrices

Methods for territorial intelligence.

Cutwidth and degeneracy of graphs

b-chromatic number of cacti

Multiple sensor fault detection in heat exchanger system

A remark on a theorem of A. E. Ingham.

A new approach of the concept of prime number

Linear Quadratic Zero-Sum Two-Person Differential Games

Replicator Dynamics and Correlated Equilibrium

From Unstructured 3D Point Clouds to Structured Knowledge - A Semantics Approach

Low frequency resolvent estimates for long range perturbations of the Euclidean Laplacian

GENERALIZED OPTICAL BISTABILITY AND CHAOS IN A LASER WITH A SATURABLE ABSORBER

Comment on: Sadi Carnot on Carnot s theorem.

On the longest path in a recursively partitionable graph

Analysis of Boyer and Moore s MJRTY algorithm

On size, radius and minimum degree

Vibro-acoustic simulation of a car window

Towards an active anechoic room

How to make R, PostGIS and QGis cooperate for statistical modelling duties: a case study on hedonic regressions

BERGE VAISMAN AND NASH EQUILIBRIA: TRANSFORMATION OF GAMES

A non-commutative algorithm for multiplying (7 7) matrices using 250 multiplications

A simple kinetic equation of swarm formation: blow up and global existence

A partial characterization of the core in Bertrand oligopoly TU-games with transferable technologies

Full-order observers for linear systems with unknown inputs

FORMAL TREATMENT OF RADIATION FIELD FLUCTUATIONS IN VACUUM

Stochastic invariances and Lamperti transformations for Stochastic Processes

Wealth inequality, preference heterogeneity and macroeconomic volatility in two-sector economies

On Poincare-Wirtinger inequalities in spaces of functions of bounded variation

Sunspot fluctuations in two-sector economies with heterogeneous agents

A Simple Model for Cavitation with Non-condensable Gases

Basic concepts and models in continuum damage mechanics

The spreading of fundamental methods and research design in territorial information analysis within the social sciences and humanities

On production costs in vertical differentiation models

There are infinitely many twin primes 30n+11 and 30n+13, 30n+17 and 30n+19, 30n+29 and 30n+31

Tropical Graph Signal Processing

On a series of Ramanujan

On optimal growth models when the discount factor is near 1 or equal to 1

Finite Volume for Fusion Simulations

Reduced Models (and control) of in-situ decontamination of large water resources

DYNAMICAL PROPERTIES OF MONOTONE DENDRITE MAPS

A proximal approach to the inversion of ill-conditioned matrices

On path partitions of the divisor graph

On Politics and Argumentation

Spatial representativeness of an air quality monitoring station. Application to NO2 in urban areas

A Simple Proof of P versus NP

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

The beam-gas method for luminosity measurement at LHCb

Stickelberger s congruences for absolute norms of relative discriminants

Exogenous input estimation in Electronic Power Steering (EPS) systems

STATISTICAL ENERGY ANALYSIS: CORRELATION BETWEEN DIFFUSE FIELD AND ENERGY EQUIPARTITION

Sunspot Fluctuations in Two-Sector Models: New Results with Additively-Separable Preferences

Entropies and fractal dimensions

A non-linear simulator written in C for orbital spacecraft rendezvous applications.

Numerical Modeling of Eddy Current Nondestructive Evaluation of Ferromagnetic Tubes via an Integral. Equation Approach

Solving the neutron slowing down equation

Nonlocal computational methods applied to composites structures

A Context free language associated with interval maps

Prompt Photon Production in p-a Collisions at LHC and the Extraction of Gluon Shadowing

Impedance Transmission Conditions for the Electric Potential across a Highly Conductive Casing

Voltage Stability of Multiple Distributed Generators in Distribution Networks

Thermodynamic form of the equation of motion for perfect fluids of grade n

A Study of the Regular Pentagon with a Classic Geometric Approach

The Mahler measure of trinomials of height 1

Global maritime connectivity: a long-term perspective

On the Griesmer bound for nonlinear codes

Quasi-periodic solutions of the 2D Euler equation

Sound intensity as a function of sound insulation partition

On constraint qualifications with generalized convexity and optimality conditions

Polychotomous regression : application to landcover prediction

Impairment of Shooting Performance by Background Complexity and Motion

New estimates for the div-curl-grad operators and elliptic problems with L1-data in the half-space

Exact Comparison of Quadratic Irrationals

Transcription:

Characterization of Equilibrium Paths in a Two-Sector Economy with CES Production Functions and Sector-Specific Externality Miki Matsuo, Kazuo Nishimura, Tomoya Sakagami, Alain Venditti To cite this version: Miki Matsuo, Kazuo Nishimura, Tomoya Sakagami, Alain Venditti. Characterization of Equilibrium Paths in a Two-Sector Economy with CES Production Functions and Sector-Specific Externality. 2008. <halshs-0028642> HAL Id: halshs-0028642 https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-0028642 Submitted on 23 May 2008 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access archive for the deposit and dissemination of scientific research documents, whether they are published or not. The documents may come from teaching and research institutions in France or abroad, or from public or private research centers. L archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, émanant des établissements d enseignement et de recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires publics ou privés.

GREQAM Groupement de Recherche en Economie Quantitative d'aix-marseille - UMR-CNRS 6579 Ecole des Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociales Universités d'aix-marseille II et III CHARACTERIZATION OF EQUILIBRIUM PATHS IN A TWO-SECTOR ECONOMY WITH CES PRODUCTION FUNCTIONS AND SECTOR-SPECIFIC EXTERNALITY Document de Travail n 2008-23 Miki MATSUO Kazuo NISHIMURA Tomoya SAKAGAMI Alain VENDITTI May 2008

Characterization of Equilibrium Paths in a Two-Sector Economy with CES Production Functions and Sector-Specific Externality Miki Matsuo Institute of Economic Research Kyoto University Kazuo Nishimura Institute of Economic Research Kyoto University Tomoya Sakagami Kumamoto Gakuen University Alain Venditti CNRS-GREQAM and Institute of Economic Research Kyoto University Abstract In this paper, we study a two-sector CES economy with sector-specific externality as described by Nishimura and Venditti [5]. We characterize the equilibrium paths in the case that allows negative externality as that equlibrium paths were not explicitly discussed by Nishimura and Venditti. We show how the degree of externality affects the local behavior of the equilibrium path around the steady state. Introduction This paper characterizes the local behavior of the equilibrium paths around the steady state in a two-sector model with CES production functions and sector- This paper is dedicated to Koji Shimomura. We miss Koji who was a very good friend and a distinguished economist. We would like to thank an anonymous referee for useful comments. Corresponding author. E-mail: nishimura@kier.kyoto-u.ac.jp This paper has been revised while Alain Venditti was visiting the Institute of Economic Research of Kyoto University. He thanks Professor Kazuo Nishimura and all the staff of the Institute for their kind invitation.

specific externality. It is well known that externalities may cause indeterminate equilibrium paths in an infinite horizon model. Benhabib and Farmer [] have shown that indeterminacy could occur in a one-sector growth model with both externality and increasing returns. In their model, the production function has constant returns to scale from the private perspective, while it has increasing returns to scale from the social perspective. Since then, there have been many papers about the existence of indeterminate equilibria in dynamic general equilibrium models. However, until Benhabib and Nishimura [2, 3], most of the literature dealt with models in which the production function has increasing returns to scale from the social perspective. They proved indeed that indeterminacy may arise in a continuous time economy in which the production functions from the social perspective have constant returns to scale. Benhabib, Nishimura and Venditti [4] then studied a discrete-time two-sector model with sector-specific external effects. They assumed that each sector has a Cobb- Douglas production function with positive sector-specific externalities, that are a special case of CES functions, and there is an infinitely-lived representative agent with a linear utility function. Under these assumptions, they provided conditions in which indeterminacy may occur even if the production functions have decreasing returns to scale from the social perspective. Nishimura and Venditti [5] consider a CES economy with sector-specific external effects and partial depreciation of capital. They study the interplay between the elasticity of capital-labor substitution and the rate of depreciation of capital, and its influence on the local behavior of the equilibrium paths in the neighborhood of the steady state. In this paper, we study the Nishimura and Venditti [5] model, focussing on the external effect of the capital-labor ratio in the pure capital good sector and characterize the equilibrium paths in the case that allows negative externality. That particular scenario was not explicitly discussed by Nishimura and Venditti. We assume indeed that the externality is given by the capital stock per capita. Such a formulation then implies that for a given level of capital, the externality from labor is negative. We demonstrate that the degree of externality affects the local behavior of the equilibrium path around the steady state. In Section 2 we describe the model. We discuss the existence of a steady state and give the local characterization of the equilibrium paths around the steady state in Section 3. Section 4 contains some concluding comments. 2 The Model We consider a two-sector model with an infinitely-lived representative agent. We assume that its single period linear utility function is given by u (c t ) = c t. We assume that the consumption good, c, and the capital good, y, are produced with a CES technology. 2

c t = [ α K ρc ct y t = ] + α 2 L ρc ρc ct, () [ ] β K ρy yt + β 2 L ρy ρy yt + e t, (2) where ρ c, ρ y > and e t represents the time-dependent externality in the investment good sector. Let the elasticity of capital-labor substitution in each sector be σ c = +ρ c 0 and σ y = +ρ y 0. We assume that the externalities are as follows: e t = b b L ρy yt, (3) K ρy yt where b > 0, and K y and L y represents the economy-wide average values. The representative agent takes these economy-wide average values as given. Definition We call y = [ β K ρy y + β 2 L ρy y from the private perspective, and y = production function from the social perspective. ] ρy + e [ (β + b) K ρy y the production function + (β 2 b) L ρy y ] ρy In the rest of the paper we will assume that α + α 2 = β + β 2 =. Thus, if ˆβ = β + b and ˆβ 2 = β 2 b, then ˆβ + ˆβ 2 =. Remark Notice that the externality (3) may be expressed as follows [ ( ) ρy ] Ky e = b L y ρy. (4) L y Now consider the production function from the social perspective as given in Definition. Dividing both sides by L y, we get denoting k y = K y /L y and ỹ = y/l y ỹ = [ (β + b) ky ρy + (β 2 b) ] ρy. (5) From equations (4) and (5) we derive that the externality is given in terms of the capital-labor ratio in the investment good sector. This implies that for a given level of capital Ky, the externality from labor L y is negative. The aggregate capital is divided between sectors, k t = K ct + K yt, and the labor endowment is normalized to one and divided between sectors, The capital accumulation equation is L ct + L yt =. k t+ = y t, the 3

Thus capital depreciates completely in one period. To simplify the formulation, we assume that both technologies are characterized by the same properties of substitution, i.e. ρ c = ρ y = ρ. The consumer optimization problem is given by max s.t. t=0 δ t [ α K ρ ct y t = [ β K ρ yt = L ct + L yt k t = K ct + K yt + α 2 L ρ ] ρ ct + β 2 L ρ ] ρ yt + e t (6) y t = k t+ k 0, {e t } t=0 given where δ (0, ) is the discount factor. p t, r t, and w t respectively denote the price of capital goods, the rental rate of the capital goods and the wage rate of labor at time t 0. For any sequences {e t } t=0 of external effects that the representative agent considers as given, the Lagrangian at time t 0 is defined as follows: L t = [ α K ρ ct [ ] + α 2 L ρ ] [β ρ ct + p t K ρ yt + β 2 L ρ ] yt + e ρ t k t+ + r t (k t K ct K yt ) + w t ( L ct L yt ). Then the first order conditions derived from the Lagrangian are as follows: ( ) ct r t = 0, (8) L t = α K ct ( L t ct = α 2 L ct L t K yt = pβ L t L yt = pβ 2 K ct L ct ( yt K yt ( yt L yt (7) ) w t = 0, (9) ) r t = 0, (0) ) w t = 0. () From the above first order conditions, we derive the following equation, ( ) ( ) +ρ α α 2 Kct L ct =. (2) β β 2 K yt L yt We normalize the price of consumption goods to one. 4

If α /α 2 > (<) β /β 2, then the consumption (capital) good sector is capital intensive from the private perspective. For any value of (k t, y t ), solving the first order conditions with respect to K ct, K yt, L ct, L yt gives inputs as functions of capital stock at time t and t +, and external effect, namely: K ct = K c (k t, y t, e t ), L ct = L c (k t, y t, e t ), K yt = K y (k t, y t, e t ), L yt = L y (k t, y t, e t ). For any given sequence {e t } t=0, we define the efficient production frontier as follows: T (k t, k t+, e t ) = [ α K c (k t, y t, e t ) ρ + α 2 L c (k t, y t, e t ) ρ] ρ. Using the envelope theorem we derive the equilibrium prices 2. T 2 (k t, k t+, e t ) = p t, (3) T (k t, k t+, e t ) = r t. (4) Next we solve the intertemporal problem (6). In this model, the lifetime utility function becomes U = δ t T (k t, k t+, e t ). t=0 From the first order conditions with respect to k t+, we obtain the Euler equation T 2 (k t, k t+, e t ) + δt (k t+, k t+2, e t+ ) = 0. (5) The solution of equation (5) also has to satisfy the following transversality condition lim t + δt k t T (k t, k t+, e t ) = 0. (6) We denote the solution of this problem {k t } t=0. This path depends on the choice of the sequence {e t } t=0. If the sequence {e t} t=0 satisfies e t = bk y (k t, y t, e t ) ρ bl y (k t, y t, e t ) ρ, (7) then {ˆk t } t=0 is called an equilibrium path. Definition 2 {k t } t=0 is an equilibrium path if {k t } t=0 satisfies (5), (6) and (7). 2 See Takayama [6] for the envelope theorem, pp60-65. Using the envelope theorem, we get L t = T and L t = T. This is equivalent to (3) and (4). k t k t k t+ k t+ 5

Solving equation (7) for e t, we derive e t as a function of (k t, k t+ ), namely e t = ê (k t, k t+ ). Let us substitute ê (k t, k t+ ) into equations (3) and (4) and define the equilibrium prices as p t = p t (k t, k t+ ), r t = r t (k t, k t+ ). Then the Euler equation (5) evaluated at {k t } t=0 is p (k t, k t+ ) + δr (k t+, k t+2 ) = 0. (8) 3 Steady State and Local Stability Properties Definition 3 A steady state is defined by k t = k t+ = y t = k and is given by the solution of T 2 (k, k, e ) + δt (k, k, e ) = 0 with e = ê (k, k ). In the rest of the paper we assume the following restriction on parameters values that guarantees all the steady state values are positive. Assumption The parameters δ, β, b and ρ satisfy (δβ ) ρ +ρ < β + b. From the proof given in Nishimura and Venditti [5], we can obtain the steady state value. Proposition In this model, there exists a unique stationary capital stock k such that: k = { ( ) ] + αβ +ρ 2 α 2β (δβ ) +ρ [ } [ ] (δβ ) +ρ ˆβ ρ ρ (δβ ) +ρ. (9) ˆβ 2 To study the local behavior of the equilibrium path around the steady state k, we linearize the Euler equation (5) at the steady state k and obtain the following characteristic equation or δt 2 λ 2 + [δt + T 22 ] λ + T 2 = 0, [ δλ 2 + δ T + T ] 22 λ + T 2 = 0. (20) T 2 T 2 T 2 As shown in Nishimura and Venditti [5], the expressions of the characteristic roots are as follows: 6

Proposition 2 The characteristic roots of equation (20) are λ = λ 2 (b) = [ ( ) (δβ 2 ) ( ) ], (2) +ρ β +ρ +ρ β 2 α α 2 [ ( ) (δβ 2 ) ( ) ] +ρ β +b β +ρ β β 2 β2 b +ρ α β 2 α 2. δ The roots of the characteristic equation determine the local behavior of the equilibrium paths. The sign of λ is determined by factor intensity differences from the private perspective. 3 Remark 2 The capital/labor ratio externality, i.e. the negative labor externality, implies that the characteristic root λ 2 (b) in Proposition 2 is larger than the corresponding characteristic root from Nishimura and Venditti [5]. We now characterize the equilibrium paths in this model. In particular we can show that the local behavior of the equilibrium path around the steady state changes according to the degree of external effect in the capital good sector. Definition 4 A steady state k is called locally indeterminate if there exists ε > 0 such that for any k 0 (k ε, k + ε), there are infinitely many equilibrium paths converging to the steady state. As there is one pre-determined variable, the capital stock, local indeterminacy occurs if the stable manifold has two dimensions, i.e. if the two characteristic roots are within the unit circle. We will also present conditions for local determinacy (saddle-point stability) in which there exists a unique equilibrium path. Such a configuration occurs if the stable manifold has one dimension, i.e. if one root is outside the unit circle while the other is inside. When the investment good is capital intensive, local indeterminacy cannot occur. However, depending on the size of the externality, saddle-point stability or total instability may occur. Proposition 3 Suppose that the capital good sector is capital intensive from the private perspective, i.e. α 2 β > α β 2. The following cases hold: (i) If ρ (, 0), there is b (δ) > β 2 such that the steady state is a saddle point for b [0, b (δ)) and is totally unstable for b > b (δ). (ii) If ρ = 0, the steady state is a saddle point for b [0, β 2 ) and is totally unstable for b > β 2. (iii) If ρ > 0, there exists 0 < δ 2 < and 0 < b (δ) < β 2 such that when δ (δ 2, ), the steady state is a saddle point for b < b (δ) and is totally unstable for b > b (δ). When δ (0, δ 2 ), the steady state is totally unstable. 3 If α 2 β α β 2 > 0, the capital good sector is capital intensive from the private perspective. 7

] Proof. Notice that λ > 0 and define δ β2 [(β /β 2 ) +ρ (α /α 2 ) ρ +ρ >. 4 From this we obtain λ = (δ /δ) +ρ > for any δ (0, ). Since (β + b)/β > and (β 2 b)/β 2 <, λ 2 (b) is always positive. Thus λ 2 (b) is an increasing function of b. For b = 0, we get λ 2 (0) = δ ρ +ρ δ +ρ and for b = β 2, we have λ 2 (β 2 ) = (δβ ) ρ +ρ. (i) If < ρ < 0, 0 < λ 2 (0) < and λ 2 (β 2 ) <. Therefore there is b (δ) > β 2 such that 0 < λ 2 (b) < for b (0, b (δ)), and λ 2 (b) > for b > b (δ). (ii) If ρ = 0, 0 < λ 2 (0) = δ < and λ 2 (β 2 ) =. Therefore λ 2 (b) < for b < β 2 and λ 2 (b) > for b > β 2. (iii) If ρ > 0, 0 < λ 2 (0) < for δ 2 < δ < and λ 2 (0) > for δ (0, δ 2 ) with δ 2 = δ ρ. Moreover λ 2 (β 2 ) >. Therefore if δ lies in (δ 2, ), there is b (δ) (0, β 2 ) such that λ 2 (b) < for b (0, b (δ)) and λ 2 (b) > for b > b (δ). If δ lies in (0, δ 2 ), then λ 2 (0) > 0 and λ 2 (β 2 ) >, and therefore λ 2 (b) > for all b > 0. Remark 3 Consider the production function from the social perspective as given in Definition and recall from equation (5) that we can express it as follows ỹ = [ (β + b) ky ρy + (β 2 b) ] ρy. (22) According to b β 2, the following inequality holds: for any η >, [ ] (β + b) (ηk y ) ρ ρ + (β 2 b) [ ] (β + b) (ηk y ) ρ + η ρ ρ (β 2 b) = η [ (β + b) k ρ y + (β 2 b) ] ρ If b is larger than β 2, the function ỹ exhibits increasing returns. If b is smaller than β 2 the function ỹ exhibits decreasing returns. Note that larger values of b contribute to have total instability. Next we present our results assuming that the capital good is labor intensive from the private perspective, i.e. α 2 β α β 2 < 0. This case results in local indeterminacy. By rewriting equation (2), the characteristic roots are, λ = [ ( ) (δβ 2 ) ( ) ], (23) +ρ +ρ α α 2 β +ρ β 2 λ 2 (b) = [ ( ) (δβ 2 ) ( ) ] +ρ β 2 b +ρ α β 2 α 2 β+b β +ρ β β 2 δ. h i 4 Note that δ = α 2 (α 2 β ) +ρ (α β 2 ) +ρ ρ > α 2 (α 2 β ) = β >. 8

To get λ (, 0), we need however to suppose a slightly stronger condition than simply ensuring the capital good sector to be labor intensive from the private perspective. The capital intensity difference α β 2 α 2 β needs to be large enough and the discount factor has to be close enough to. Proposition 4 Assume that (α β 2 ) +ρ (α2 β ) with δ 3 = β 2 [(β /β 2 ) +ρ (α /α 2 ) +ρ > α +ρ 2 and δ (δ 3, ) +ρ ] ρ <. Then the following cases hold: (i) If ρ (, 0), there exist b (δ) (0, β 2 ) and b (δ) > β 2 such that the steady state is a saddle point for b (0, b (δ)) (b (δ), + ) and is locally indeterminate for b ( b (δ), b (δ) ). (ii) If ρ = 0, the steady state is a saddle point for b (0, β 2 2α 2 ) (β 2, + ) and is locally indeterminate for b (β 2 2α 2, β 2 ). (iii) If ρ > 0, there are b (δ) and b (δ) in (0, β 2 ) such that the steady state is a saddle point for b (0, b (δ)) (b (δ), + ) and is locally indeterminate for b ( b (δ), b (δ) ). Proof. If (α β 2 ) +ρ (α2 β ) +ρ > α +ρ 2 and δ (δ 3, ), then < λ < 0. The size of λ 2 (b) is determined in the following way. Recall that λ 2 (b) is increasing in b. For b = 0, λ 2 (0) = /δλ < by the above hypothesis and for b = β 2, λ 2 (β 2 ) = (δβ ) ρ +ρ. (i) If < ρ < 0, λ 2 (β 2 ) <. Therefore there exist b (δ) (0, β 2 ) and ( b (δ) > β 2 ) such that λ 2 < for b (0, b (δ)), < λ 2 < for any b b (δ), b (δ) and λ2 > for any b > b (δ). (ii) If ρ = 0, λ 2 (β 2 ) =. Therefore λ 2 (b) < for b (0, β 2 2α 2 ), < λ 2 (b) < for b (β 2 2α 2, β 2 ) and λ 2 (b) > for b > β 2. (iii) If ρ > 0, λ 2 (β 2 ) >. Therefore there exist b (δ) and b (δ) in (0, β 2 such that λ 2 (b) < for b (0, b (δ)), < λ 2 (b) < for b ( b (δ), b (δ) ), and λ 2 (b) > for b > b (δ). Notice that intermediary values for b are necessary to get local indeterminacy. Indeed, values of b that are too small or too large imply saddle-point stability. Remark 4 In Proposition 4 we consider restrictions implying that the first characteristic root λ is negative and larger than. These restrictions also imply that the second characteristic root is such that λ 2 (0) <. As the characteristic root λ 2 (b) is an increasing function of b, a large enough (but not too large) amount of externalities ensures the existence of local indeterminacy. Building on Remark 2, we also derive that local indeterminacy is more likely in our framework than in that of Nishimura and Venditti [5] in the sense that their framework requires a larger amount of externalities. Next we still assume that capital goods are labor intensive from the private perspective with α 2 β α β 2 < 0, but we make λ an unstable root, i.e. λ <. 9

Two cases need to be considered: (α β 2 ) +ρ (α2 β ) +ρ > α +ρ 2 and δ (0, δ 3 ), as well as (α β 2 ) +ρ (α2 β ) +ρ < α +ρ 2. Proposition 5 Suppose that the capital good sector is labor intensive from the ] private perspective and let δ 4 = β ρ 2 [(β /β 2 ) +ρ (α /α 2 ) +ρ ρ +ρ. - If (α β 2 ) +ρ (α2 β ) +ρ > α +ρ 2 and δ (0, δ 3 ), the following results hold: (i) Let ρ (, 0). If δ (0, δ 4 ), then there exist b (δ) (0, β 2 ) and b (δ) > β 2 such that the steady state is a saddle point for b ( b (δ), b (δ) ) and is totally unstable for b (0, b (δ)) (b (δ), + ). If δ (δ 4, δ 3 ), then there exists b (δ) > β 2 such that the steady state is a saddle point for b ( 0, b (δ) ) and is totally unstable for b > b (δ). (ii) Let ρ = 0. Then the steady state is a saddle point for b (β 2 2α 2, β 2 ) and is totally unstable for b (0, β 2 2α 2 ) (β 2, + ). (iii) Let ρ > 0. Then there exist b (δ), b (δ) (0, β 2 ) such that the steady state is a saddle point for b ( b (δ), b (δ) ) and is totally unstable for b (0, b (δ)) (b (δ), + ). 2 - If (α β 2 ) +ρ (α2 β ) +ρ < α +ρ 2, the following results hold: (i) Let ρ (, 0). Then there exists b (δ) > β 2 such that the steady state is saddle point for b ( 0, b (δ) ) and totally unstable for b > b (δ). (ii) Let ρ = 0. Then the steady state is saddle point for b (0, β 2 ) and totally unstable for b > β 2. (iii) Let ρ > 0. If δ (0, δ 4 ), then there exist b (δ) (0, β 2 ) and b (δ) > β 2 such that the steady state is saddle point for b ( b (δ), b (δ) ) and totally unstable for b (0, b (δ)) (b (δ), + ). If δ (δ 4, ), then there exists b (δ) > β 2 such that the steady state is saddle point for b ( 0, b (δ) ) and totally unstable for b > b (δ). Proof. We assume here that λ <. Recall that λ 2 (b) increases with b. ρ +ρ δ +ρ Moreover, for b = 0, we get λ 2 (0) = δ 3, with δ 3 as defined in Proposition 4, and for b = β 2, we get λ 2 (β 2 ) = (δβ ) ρ +ρ. We easily get λ 2 (0) (, 0) if and only if δ ρ > δ3. As shown above, two cases have to be considered: - Let (α β 2 ) +ρ (α2 β ) +ρ > α +ρ 2 and δ (0, δ 3 ) with δ 3 <. (i) When < ρ < 0, we get λ 2 (β 2 ) <, and λ 2 (0) < if and only if δ < δ ρ 3 δ 4. It follows then that δ 4 < δ 3 as δ +ρ ρ 3 <. We conclude that λ 2 (0) < if 0 < δ < δ 4, while λ 2 (0) > if δ (δ 4, δ 3 ). Therefore if δ lies in (0, δ 4 ), there exist b (δ) (0, β 2 ) and b (δ) > β 2 such that λ 2 (b) < for b (0, b (δ)), < λ 2 (b) < for b ( b (δ), b (δ) ), and λ 2 (b) > for b > b (δ). If δ lies in (δ 4, δ 3 ), there exists b (δ) > β 2 such that < λ 2 (b) < for b (0, b (δ)) and λ 2 (b) > for b > b (δ). (ii) If ρ = 0, λ 2 (0) < and λ 2 (β 2 ) =. Therefore < λ 2 (b) < for b (β 2 2α 2, β 2 ) and λ 2 (b) > for b (0, β 2 2α 2 ) or b > β 2. 0

(iii) If ρ > 0, then δ 4 > δ 3 and thus λ 2 (0) < for any δ (0, δ 3 ). Moreover λ 2 (β 2 ) >. Therefore, there exist b (δ) and b (δ) in (0, β 2 ) such that λ 2 (0) < for b (0, b (δ)), < λ 2 (b) < for b ( b (δ), b (δ) ) and λ 2 (0) > for b > b (δ). 2 - Let (α β 2 ) +ρ (α2 β ) +ρ < α +ρ 2. In this case we have δ 3 >. (i) When < ρ < 0, λ 2 (β 2 ) <. Moreover, we get δ ρ > > δ3 so that λ 2 (0) >. Then there exists b (δ) > β 2 such that < λ 2 (b) < for b ( 0, b (δ) ), and λ 2 (b) > for b > b (δ). (ii) If ρ = 0, < λ 2 (0) < 0 and λ 2 (β 2 ) =. Therefore < λ 2 (b) < for b (0, β 2 ) and λ 2 (b) > for b > β 2. (iii) If ρ > 0, then λ 2 (0) > if and only if δ > δ ρ 3 δ 4 with δ 4 < and thus λ 2 (0) < for any δ (0, δ 4 ). Moreover λ 2 (β 2 ) >. Therefore if δ lies in (0, δ 4 ), then there exist b (δ) (0, β 2 ) and b (δ) > β 2 such that λ 2 (b) < for b (0, b (δ)), < λ 2 (b) < for b ( b (δ), b (δ) ), and λ 2 (b) > for b > b (δ). If δ lies in (δ 4, ), there exists b (δ) > β 2 such that < λ 2 (b) < for b (0, b (δ)) and λ 2 (b) > for b > b (δ). Notice that the impact of b on the local stability properties of the steady state depends on the value of the discount factor δ. If δ is not too small, larger values of b contributes to total instability as in Proposition 3 (see cases -i) with δ (δ 4, δ 3 ) and 2-iii) with δ (δ 4, ) in Proposition 5). On the contrary, if δ is close enough to zero, local instability is obtained for low enough and large enough values of b. 4 Concluding Remarks In this paper we have characterized the local dynamics of the equilibrium paths depending on the size of the external effects b. We have shown that when the investment good is capital intensive, large values of b contributes to total instability. When the consumption good is capital intensive, the effect of b on the local dynamics of the equilibrium path is more complex. If the capital intensity difference is large enough, local indeterminacy occurs for intermediary values of b while saddle-point stability is obtained when b is low enough or large enough. If the capital intensity difference is small, local indeterminacy cannot occur and the role of b depends on the size of the discount factor. When the discount factor is not too low, larger values of b again contributes to total instability. However, when the discount factor is close enough to zero, total instability is also obtained for small values of b. In this case indeed, saddle-point stability requires intermediary values of b. In this paper, we have assumed that both sectors have the same elasticity of capital-labor substitution. It would be interesting to study the characterization of the equilibrium paths by introducing heterogeneity.

References [] Benhabib, J., Farmer, R. (994). Indeterminacy and Increasing Returns. Journal of Economic Theory, 20, 9-4. [2] Benhabib, J., Nishimura, K. (998). Indeterminacy and Sunspots with Constant Returns. Journal of Economic Theory, 8, 58-96. [3] Benhabib, J., Nishimura, K. (999). Indeterminacy Arising in Multisector Economies. Japanese Economic Review, 50, 485-506. [4] Benhabib, J., Nishimura, K., Venditti, A. (2002). Indeterminacy and Cycles in Two-Sector Discrete-Time Model. Economic Theory, 20, 27-235. [5] Nishimura, K., Venditti, A. (2004). Capital Depreciation, Factor Substitutability and Indeterminacy. Journal of Difference Equations and Applications, 0, 53-69. [6] Takayama, A. (997). Mathematical Economics. Second edition. Cambridge University Press. 2