Economics 101. Lecture 4 - Equilibrium and Efficiency

Similar documents
Welfare Properties of General Equilibrium. What can be said about optimality properties of resource allocation implied by general equilibrium?

PROBLEM SET 7 GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM

Perfect Competition and the Nash Bargaining Solution

CS294 Topics in Algorithmic Game Theory October 11, Lecture 7

A NOTE ON CES FUNCTIONS Drago Bergholt, BI Norwegian Business School 2011

Equilibrium with Complete Markets. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Copyright (C) 2008 David K. Levine This document is an open textbook; you can redistribute it and/or modify it under the terms of the Creative

Mixed Taxation and Production Efficiency

Economics 8105 Macroeconomic Theory Recitation 1

1 The Sidrauski model

Let p z be the price of z and p 1 and p 2 be the prices of the goods making up y. In general there is no problem in grouping goods.

princeton univ. F 17 cos 521: Advanced Algorithm Design Lecture 7: LP Duality Lecturer: Matt Weinberg

Assortment Optimization under MNL

ECE559VV Project Report

Lecture Notes, January 11, 2010

Online Appendix. t=1 (p t w)q t. Then the first order condition shows that

Market structure and Innovation

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 10: Education Policies and Simpler Theory of Capital Taxation

Kernel Methods and SVMs Extension

University of California, Davis Date: June 22, 2009 Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D.

Online Appendix: Reciprocity with Many Goods

k t+1 + c t A t k t, t=0

The Existence and Optimality of Equilibrium

In the figure below, the point d indicates the location of the consumer that is under competition. Transportation costs are given by td.

Game Theory Course: Jackson, Leyton-Brown & Shoham. Vickrey-Clarke-Groves Mechanisms: Definitions

Lecture 10 Support Vector Machines II

Lectures - Week 4 Matrix norms, Conditioning, Vector Spaces, Linear Independence, Spanning sets and Basis, Null space and Range of a Matrix

The Multiple Classical Linear Regression Model (CLRM): Specification and Assumptions. 1. Introduction

find (x): given element x, return the canonical element of the set containing x;

Supporting Materials for: Two Monetary Models with Alternating Markets

Module 9. Lecture 6. Duality in Assignment Problems

More metrics on cartesian products

Supporting Information for: Two Monetary Models with Alternating Markets

Solutions to exam in SF1811 Optimization, Jan 14, 2015

THE CHINESE REMAINDER THEOREM. We should thank the Chinese for their wonderful remainder theorem. Glenn Stevens

Notes on Kehoe Perri, Econometrica 2002

Société de Calcul Mathématique SA

(1 ) (1 ) 0 (1 ) (1 ) 0

How Strong Are Weak Patents? Joseph Farrell and Carl Shapiro. Supplementary Material Licensing Probabilistic Patents to Cournot Oligopolists *

Section 8.3 Polar Form of Complex Numbers

Unit 5: Government policy in competitive markets I E ciency

f(x,y) = (4(x 2 4)x,2y) = 0 H(x,y) =

Which Separator? Spring 1

Lecture 10: Euler s Equations for Multivariable

Additional Codes using Finite Difference Method. 1 HJB Equation for Consumption-Saving Problem Without Uncertainty

Introduction to Vapor/Liquid Equilibrium, part 2. Raoult s Law:

Edge Isoperimetric Inequalities

Grover s Algorithm + Quantum Zeno Effect + Vaidman

Winter 2008 CS567 Stochastic Linear/Integer Programming Guest Lecturer: Xu, Huan

NUMERICAL DIFFERENTIATION

Section 3.6 Complex Zeros

Module 17: Mechanism Design & Optimal Auctions

Econ107 Applied Econometrics Topic 3: Classical Model (Studenmund, Chapter 4)

Lecture 3: Probability Distributions

3.1 Expectation of Functions of Several Random Variables. )' be a k-dimensional discrete or continuous random vector, with joint PMF p (, E X E X1 E X

MMA and GCMMA two methods for nonlinear optimization

Managing Capacity Through Reward Programs. on-line companion page. Byung-Do Kim Seoul National University College of Business Administration

Portfolios with Trading Constraints and Payout Restrictions

Journal of Mathematical Economics

College of Computer & Information Science Fall 2009 Northeastern University 20 October 2009

18.1 Introduction and Recap

Module 2. Random Processes. Version 2 ECE IIT, Kharagpur

CS286r Assign One. Answer Key

Week3, Chapter 4. Position and Displacement. Motion in Two Dimensions. Instantaneous Velocity. Average Velocity

On the Multicriteria Integer Network Flow Problem

ANSWERS. Problem 1. and the moment generating function (mgf) by. defined for any real t. Use this to show that E( U) var( U)

Chapter Newton s Method

Vickrey Auction VCG Combinatorial Auctions. Mechanism Design. Algorithms and Data Structures. Winter 2016

Physics 5153 Classical Mechanics. D Alembert s Principle and The Lagrangian-1

Hila Etzion. Min-Seok Pang

Difference Equations

Mathematics Intersection of Lines

2.3 Nilpotent endomorphisms

Linear Approximation with Regularization and Moving Least Squares

HMMT February 2016 February 20, 2016

1. relation between exp. function and IUF

Simultaneous Optimization of Berth Allocation, Quay Crane Assignment and Quay Crane Scheduling Problems in Container Terminals

Pricing and Resource Allocation Game Theoretic Models

The Unique Informational Effciency of the Lindahl Allocation Process in Economies with Public Goods

NP-Completeness : Proofs

Endogenous timing in a mixed oligopoly consisting of a single public firm and foreign competitors. Abstract

Problem Do any of the following determine homomorphisms from GL n (C) to GL n (C)?

Marginal Effects in Probit Models: Interpretation and Testing. 1. Interpreting Probit Coefficients

PHYS 705: Classical Mechanics. Calculus of Variations II

Discontinuous Extraction of a Nonrenewable Resource

Infinitely Split Nash Equilibrium Problems in Repeated Games

Problem Set 3. 1 Offshoring as a Rybzcynski Effect. Economics 245 Fall 2011 International Trade

Externalities in wireless communication: A public goods solution approach to power allocation. by Shrutivandana Sharma

Uniqueness of Nash Equilibrium in Private Provision of Public Goods: Extension. Nobuo Akai *

THE SUMMATION NOTATION Ʃ

Notes on Frequency Estimation in Data Streams

,, MRTS is the marginal rate of technical substitution

Homework Assignment 3 Due in class, Thursday October 15

ON THE EQUIVALENCE OF ORDINAL BAYESIAN INCENTIVE COMPATIBILITY AND DOMINANT STRATEGY INCENTIVE COMPATIBILITY FOR RANDOM RULES

ACTM State Calculus Competition Saturday April 30, 2011

MAGNETISM MAGNETIC DIPOLES

Lecture 4: November 17, Part 1 Single Buffer Management

MATH Sensitivity of Eigenvalue Problems

Module 3 LOSSY IMAGE COMPRESSION SYSTEMS. Version 2 ECE IIT, Kharagpur

Stanford University CS359G: Graph Partitioning and Expanders Handout 4 Luca Trevisan January 13, 2011

Transcription:

Economcs 0 Lecture 4 - Equlbrum and Effcency Intro As dscussed n the prevous lecture, we wll now move from an envronment where we looed at consumers mang decsons n solaton to analyzng economes full of people who exchange good through ths Walrasan mechansm. Loong at consumers behavor gven fxed prces s often called partal equlbrum analyss, whle loong at a settng where prces must equlbrate (to match supply wth demand) s called general equlbrum analyss. Snce we wll be loong at multple consumers wth potentally dfferent utlty functons and endowments, we wll ndex them wth the letter, where {,..., M} and M s the number of consumers n the economy. So we have M consumers n the economy and consumer has an endowment e and utlty functon u. An equlbrum n ths settng must satsfy two condtons. Let x be the equlbrum consumpton of consumer and p be the equlbrum prces. Frst, consumers must choose optmally gven prces, that s, for all x argmax x R N + u (x) s.t. p x p e Second, the goods maret must clear for each good, so for all M x = = M = e It turns out that there s a lot of ntuton to be ganed by loong at the case of an economy wth two consumers and two goods. Remember, we are free to normalze the prce of one of the goods to, so let the prce of good

be and the prce of good 2 be p. Now we have utlty functons u and u 2 and endowments e and e 2. The budget constrants are The maret clearng condtons are x + px 2 = e + pe 2 () x 2 + px 2 2 = e 2 + pe 2 2 (2) x + x 2 = e + e 2 (3) x 2 + x 2 2 = e 2 + e 2 2 (4) In addton to the above equatons, we also want the consumer to choose optmally, whch under mld assumptons means the frst order condtons must hold u (x, x 2) = λ u 2(x, x 2) = pλ u 2 (x 2, x 2 2) = λ 2 u 2 2(x 2, x 2 2) = pλ 2 Notce that each consumer has ther own Lagrange multpler. Dvdng, we get u (x, x 2) u 2(x, x 2) }{{} MRS = u2 (x 2, x 2 2) = p (5,6) u 2 2(x 2, x }{{ 2 2) } MRS 2 So we can see that snce consumers face a prce of p and any optmal choce wll set MRS = p, n fact the consumers must have the same MRS n equlbrum. Consder what we have now: there are 6 equatons (numbered above) that must be satsfed and only 5 unnown varables (x,x 2,x 2,x 2 2, and p). Normally, we want to have the same number of equatons as unnowns. One way to reconcle ths s to recall that we started wth p and p 2 but normalzed to p =. Another way s to observe the followng Proposton (Walras s Law). If equatons (), (2), and (3) hold, then equaton (4) must hold as well. 2

Proof. () x = e + pe 2 px 2 (2) x 2 = e 2 + pe 2 2 px 2 2 Pluggng these nto (3) e + pe 2 px 2 + e 2 + pe 2 2 px 2 2 = e + e 2 pe 2 px 2 + pe 2 2 px 2 2 = 0 x 2 + x 2 2 = e 2 + e 2 2 So the budget constrants and maret clearng n one of the goods mples maret clearng n the other good. In fact, ths result s true for the general settng wth N goods. If the maret for N goods clears, then the maret for the N th good must clear as well. As t happens, there exsts a truly excellent method for vsualzng a 2 good, 2 consumer economy called the Edgeworth Box. Essentally, we tae the standard graph of consumer s budget set and supermpose on that the graph of consumer 2 s budget set rotated by 80. Now any pont n ths box specfes a full allocaton. Consumer s s gven by the dstance from the southwest orgn, whle consumer 2 s s gven by the dstance to the northeast orgn. Furthermore, f the sze of the box s (e, e 2 ), then maret clearng wll be satsfed as well. Now we defne a new concept called excess demand. Ths s smply the dfference between what s beng demanded and the total amount of goods n the economy. Ths wll depend on the prce p. z (p) = x (p) + x 2 (p) e e 2 z 2 (p) = x 2(p) + x 2 2(p) e 2 e 2 2 An equlbrum wll satsfy z (p ) = z 2 (p ) = 0. Proposton 2. For any p, z (p) + pz 2 (p) = 0. Proof. The consumer s budget constrants mply x (p) + px 2(p) e pe 2 = 0 x 2 (p) + px 2 2(p) e 2 pe 2 2 = 0 3

Addng these together yelds [ ] [ ] x (p) + x 2 (p) e e 2 + p x 2 (p) + x 2 2(p) e 2 e 2 2 = 0 z (p) + pz 2 (p) = 0 Notce that the above actually mples Walras s Law, whch can be stated smply as [z (p) = 0] [z 2 (p) = 0] Example. Consder the two consumer, two good case. We ll use Cobb- Douglas utlty for both consumers u (x, x 2) = α log(x ) + ( α ) log(x 2) As we ve seen before, the demand s x (p) = α w x 2(p) = ( α )w p where w = e + pe 2 s the wealth of consumer. Because of Walras s Law, we smply need to fnd some p such that z (p) = 0. 0 = z (p) 0 = x (p) + x 2 (p) e e 2 0 = α w + α 2 w 2 e e 2 0 = α (e + pe 2) + α 2 (e 2 + pe 2 2) e e 2 0 = p(α e 2 + α 2 e 2 2) ( α )e ( α 2 )e 2 Now we solve for p to fnd the equlbrum prce p = ( α )e + ( α 2 )e 2 α e 2 + α 2 e 2 2 4

From here we can fnd optmal consumpton x = α (e + p e 2) ( ) e x 2 = ( α ) + p e 2 Consder the specal case where e = e 2 = e 2 = e 2 2 = /2. Ths yelds prces p and consumpton p = ( α ) + ( α 2 ) α + α 2 + p = α + α 2 x = α α + α 2 and x 2 = α ( α ) + ( α 2 ) So each person consumes n proporton to ther preference parameter. 2 Welfare Up untl now, we have been dealng wth ndvdual utlty functons n solaton. Ultmately, we would le to use the utlty specfcatons to mae statements about the desrablty of partcular allocatons of goods. That s, gven the total amount of goods n an economy, how should we best dstrbute them amongst the agent. Not surprsngly, there s no one rght answer to ths queston, even f we now exactly what people s utlty functons are. We can, however, narrow our focus to a set of allocatons that are consdered to be better than the rest. Frst, we must defne some terms Allocaton: a specfcaton of consumpton for each consumer x = (x,..., x M ). such that M x = = M e = e = 5

Notce that the above s the same as the maret clearng condton from a Walrasan equlbrum. In ths case, we call f feasblty. Now we defne the standard noton of effcency n economcs Pareto Effcent: An allocaton x such that there s no other allocaton ˆx wth u (ˆx ) u (x ) u (ˆx ) > u (x ) for all for some A related term that we may use as well s Pareto Domnated: An allocaton ˆx Pareto domnates x f u (ˆx ) u (x ) u (ˆx ) > u (x ) for all for some So you can see that an allocaton s Pareto effcent f t s not Pareto domnated by any other allocaton. In plan Englsh, an allocaton s Pareto optmal f there s no way to transfer goods so that everyone s mae wealy better off and at least one person s made strctly better off. Pareto effcency does not guarantee that an allocaton has other propertes that are consdered desrable, such as farness. It s Pareto effcent for me to have everythng and you to have nothng. The reverse s also Pareto effcent. In general, there s a set of Pareto effcent allocatons Proposton. Gven β,..., β M wth β = and β > 0, f x maxmzes W (x β) = M β u (x ) = then t s Pareto effcent. Proof. Suppose x maxmzed W (x β) and was not Pareto effcent. there s some ˆx such that Then u (ˆx ) u (x ) u (ˆx ) > u (x ) for all for some 6

Ths mples that M β u (ˆx ) > = M β u (x ) = or W (ˆx β) > W (x β). So x does not maxmze W ( β), contradctng our ntal assumpton that t dd, so x must be Pareto effcent. A partal converse to ths statement, whch we wll not prove, s Proposton 2. For an Pareto effcent allocaton x, there s some β such that x maxmzes W ( β). So by loong over all β values, we could concevable map out the set of Pareto effcent allocatons. We can vsualze Pareto effcent allocatons usng the Edgeworth box. Here, the set of Pareto effcent allocatons wll le on a lne extendng form consumer s orgn to consumer 2 s orgn. Ths lne s called the contract curve. Let s wor out the Pareto problem n the 2 consumer, 2 good case. Here our welfare functon s And we wsh to solve W (x β) = βu (x ) + ( β)u ( x 2 ) max x R N + βu (x, x 2) + ( β)u 2 (x 2, x 2 2) s.t. x + x 2 = e + e 2 = e x 2 + x 2 2 = e 2 + e 2 2 = e 2 Thus we wll have two Lagrange multplers, one for each good, and the Lagrangan functon s L = βu (x, x 2) + ( β)u 2 (x 2, x 2 2) + λ (e + e 2 x x 2 ) + λ 2 (e 2 + e 2 2 x 2 x 2 2) Tang the FOC s βu (x, x 2) = λ ( β)u 2 (x 2, x 2 2) = λ βu 2(x, x 2) = λ 2 ( β)u 2 2(x 2, x 2 2) = λ 2 7

Dvng to cancel the λ s, we fnd Cross multplyng yelds u (x, x 2) u 2 (x 2, x 2 2) = β β = u 2(x, x 2) u 2 2(x 2, x 2 2) u (x, x 2) u 2(x, x 2) = u2 (x 2, x 2 2) u 2 2(x 2, x 2 2) whch s smply MRS = MRS 2. So the margnal rates of substtuton are equal at a Pareto optmal allocaton. Furthermore, f you an allocaton where the MRS s are equal, that must be Pareto optmal. Example 2. Agan we ll use Cobb-Douglas utlty for both agents u (x, x 2) = α log(x ) + ( α ) log(x 2) The MRS n ths case s MRS = u (x,, x 2) u 2(x, x 2) = α /x ( α )/x 2 = α α l x 2 x Equatng these two, we get ( α α ) x 2 x ( ) α 2 x 2 = 2 α 2 x 2 Usng the feasblty condtons, ths becomes ( α α ) x 2 x ( ) α 2 e2 x 2 = α 2 e x Now we want to solve for x 2 n terms of x. Ths wll lead us to the contract curve. α ( α 2 )(e x )x 2 = α 2 ( α )(e 2 x 2)x [ α ( α 2 )e + (α 2 α )x ] x 2 = α 2 ( α )e 2 x x 2(x ) = α 2 ( α )e 2 x α ( α 2 )e + (α 2 α )x Notce that x 2(0) = 0 and x 2(e ) = e 2. 8

3 Effcency of Equlbrum Now we move on to the queston of whether a Walrasan equlbrum s effcent. It turns out that t s. Remember that any allocaton where MRS = MRS 2 s effcent. Also recall that we proved that any equlbrum satsfes MRS = MRS 2 = p, so an equlbrum s effcent. Ths of course requres that utlty s ncreasng and concave. However, we can prove t wth weaer assumptons. Theorem (Frst Basc Welfare Theorem). When utlty s ncreasng, any Walrasan equlbrum s effcent. Proof. Suppose we have an equlbrum prce vector p wth allocaton x demanded, and that ths allocaton s not Pareto effcent. Ths means that there s some allocaton ˆx that Pareto domnates x, that s u (ˆx ) u (x ) u (ˆx ) > u (x ) for all for some Recall that snce utlty s ncreasng, any optmal choce wll le on the budget lne, otherwse the consumer could consume a lttle bt more of each good and be better off, so p x = p e Step : For any agent, t must be that p ˆx p e If ths were not the case, then we would have p ˆx < p e Then there would be some pont x wth p x < p e 9

and x > ˆx for all that s also n the budget set. Snce u s ncreasng, ths wll satsfy u ( x ) > u (ˆx ) u (x ). However, ths cannot be, snce we assumed x was chosen optmally, but here we have an affordable pont that gves hgher utlty. Step 2: For, we must have p ˆx If ths were not the case, then p ˆx > p e p e But here we have the same contradcton to the fact that x was chosen optmally, but we have a pont ˆx that s affordable wth u (ˆx ) > u (x ). So now we now that p ˆx p ˆx > p e p e for all Addng these nequaltes together for all, ncludng p ˆx > p ˆx > p ˆx > p ˆx [ p ˆx x p x p x p x > 0 x ] > 0 0

However, we now that ˆx s a feasble allocaton, meang ˆx = e for all Pluggng ths nto the above, we get p 0 > 0 0 > 0 Obvously, ths cannot be, so have reached a contradcton. It must be that x was Pareto effcent after all!