Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network"

Transcription

1 Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network Effects Adriana Gama Mario Samano September 7, 218 Abstract We establish an important difference between Cournot oligopolies with and without positive network effects. When there is a single-network with perfectly compatible products, and there are business-stealing effects (individual production decreases with entry), there may be under or excessive entry with respect to the social planner s (second-best) solution. This contrasts with the standard Cournot oligopoly model (without network effects) result, where excessive entry is the norm (under-entry might happen but only by one firm). Our results have important implications for competition policy: allowing for free entry when there are network effects may make consumers worse-off than with regulated entry. JEL codes: D43, L13, L14. Keywords: Cournot competition, positive network effects, complete compatibility, underentry, excessive entry. Corresponding author. Centro de Estudios Económicos, El Colegio de México, Carretera Picacho-Ajusco 2, Col. Ampliación Fuentes del Pedregal, Tlalpan 1411, Mexico City, Mexico. agama@colmex.mx HEC Montreal, Department of Applied Economics. mario.samano@hec.ca 1

2 1 Introduction It is well known that in a standard Cournot oligopoly with business-stealing effects (that is, individual output decreases with more firms), entry in the absence of regulation is excessive compared to the second-best number of firms (Mankiw and Whinston [1986], henceforth MW). 1 If entry of competitors increases the production by firm (business-enhancing effect), then, free entry is insufficient to achieve the second-best (Amir et al. [214], henceforth ACK). However, business-enhancing competition is rare in a standard Cournot oligopoly, and can be globally achieved only in the absence of variable costs (Amir [1996]). Our paper shows that the introduction of positive network effects to a Cournot oligopoly results in under-entry for a broader set of industries, even in the presence of variable costs or more surprisingly, under business-stealing competition. By industries with positive network effects we mean industries where the consumers willingness to pay increases with the number of people the network that will, or are expected to purchase a compatible good. That is, consumers benefit from the size of the network, an effect also known as demand-side economies of scale. We consider oligopolies with positive network effects and complete compatibility. As defined by Katz and Shapiro [1985] (henceforth KS), this corresponds to goods that are compatible no matter which firm produced them, and therefore, there is a single-network. Some examples are the telephone (landline and cell phones), instant messaging, DVDs, fashion, 1 Such result holds when one ignores the integer constraint; accounting for it implies that free entry might be lower than the second-best solution, but by no more than one firm. For simplicity, we refer to the latter result as excessive entry. Second-best refers to the regulation of entry, not production. 2

3 and goods created under the umbrella of an SSO (standard-setting organization) 2. Amir and Lazzati [211] (henceforth AZ) provide a thorough study of industries with network effects and complete compatibility. They analyze the important issue of viability (when an equilibrium with strictly positive production exists) and the effects of entry on the industry, while providing a comparison with the standard Cournot oligopoly (without network effects) for an exogenous number of firms. In this paper, we endogenize the number of firms in the industry with network externalities in the same fashion as Mankiw and Whinston [1986]. That is, we compare the second-best number of firms with the free entry outcome for a symmetric oligopoly with a single-network. Besides other relatively standard assumptions detailed in the next section, we assume that the cost of production is linear, for simplicity and because it is enough to provide insightful results about the oligopoly with positive network externalities. AZ show that in network industries, per-firm profits may increase or decrease with entry of new competitors. In the absence of network effects, such profits always decrease. 3 Then, we divide our main results into two parts: i) when equilibrium individual profits decrease with entry, and ii) when they increase. When profits decrease with the number of firms, we prove that under-entry is plausible under the business-stealing competition, while in standard Cournot, it only happens when competition is business-enhancing. Intuitively, if the network effect is strong enough, it might offset the business-stealing effect, mimicking the benefit that firms have on each other when individual production increases with entry. 2 See Shapiro [2]. 3 See Amir and Lambson [2] (henceforth AL) for a thorough study on existence and comparative statics of the oligopoly without network effects, also referred to as standard Cournot oligopoly in this work. 3

4 On the other hand, with business-enhancing competition, the standard result of underentry prevails whenever individual profits decrease with entry. If instead of decreasing, individual profits increase with competition (together with the business-enhancing effect), both the number of firms under free and second-best entry coincide. An important consequence of our results for competition policy is that by allowing for free entry when there are network effects, it is possible (depending on parameter values and the nature of the demand function) that consumer surplus is lower than under regulation. The next section provides the setting of the industry and its assumptions, Section 3 presents the results divided by the effects of entry on individual profits, and Section 4 concludes. All the comparisons ( increasing, decreasing, under-entry, etc.) refer to weak notions, unless it is specified that they are strict. 2 Preliminaries We consider a Cournot oligopoly with n firms producing homogenous goods that are perfectly compatible in an industry with positive network effects. In other words, a consumer values a good more when more people use this or a compatible product, which is any product of the industry. We assume that every consumer buys exactly one unit of the good, therefore, the expected size of the network is equivalent to the expected number of buyers. Given the positive externalities in demand, consumers form a belief on the size of the network that cannot be directly influenced by the firms, hence the use of the term expected size of the network. As we detail in the next section, these beliefs are confirmed in equilibrium. The firms in the industry are symmetric, that is, all of them face the same inverse de- 4

5 mand function P (z, s) and the same technology C(x), where z denotes total output, s is the expected size of the network, and x is the production of the firm under consideration. Then, π(x, y, s) = xp (x + y, s) cx is the profit of a given firm, before it pays the cost of entry K >. Hence, for a fixed number of firms n N in the industry, each firm solves max{π(x, y, s) K}, (1) x where y denotes the production by the other n 1 firms, that is, z = x + y. Let x n denote the solution to problem (1) when there are n firms, z n the equilibrium total output (z n = nx n ), π n the optimal profits (before paying the entry cost), and W n the social welfare without the entry costs, nk. Then, if individual profits decrease with n, the number of firms under free entry is n e N such that π n e K and π n e +1 < K. The second-best number of firms is the solution n N to the regulator s problem: max {W n nk}. n Throughout the paper we make the following assumptions. We use subindices for the function P to denote partial derivatives with respect to the first and second arguments. (A1) P : R + R + R + is twice continuously differentiable, P 1 (z, s) < and P 2 (z, s) >. (A2) C(x) = cx, c. (A3) Each firm s individual output is bounded by X >. (A4) P (z, s)p 12 (z, s) P 1 (z, s)p 2 (z, s) >, for all (z, s). (A5) π 1 > K, K >. 5

6 Assumptions (A1)-(A4) imply that a symmetric equilibrium exists in both oligopolies (with and without network effects) and that no asymmetric equilibria exist in either of the two (AL and AZ). Since there may be multiple equilibria, all of our results refer to the extremal equilibria with respect to total output. The reason is that the comparative static results used in this work, due to AL and AZ, apply to extremal equilibria only. In particular, P 1 < reflects the law of demand, and P 2 > the demand-side economies of scale (willingness-to-pay increases with the expected size of the network). We restrict our study to a technology with constant returns to scale (A2) because this is enough to show crucial differences between the standard Cournot oligopoly model and the one with network effects that are due only to the network and not to the production technology. The firms capacity constraint given by (A3) is a technical requirement that deals with the existence of equilibria and prevents technical problems with unbounded production, but X can be as large as needed. Assumption (A4) is used to guarantee the existence of the equilibrium in the oligopoly with compatible networks. It has the precise interpretation that the elasticity of demand increases with the expected size of the network, which is a characteristic of the industries with network effects (see AZ for further discussion). In addition, it allows the inclusion of industries with pure network goods, that is, where P (z, ) =. Finally, (A5) states that at least one firm can survive in the market and guarantees that the industry is viable, that is, an equilibrium with strictly positive production exists. 6

7 3 Results With complete compatibility, there is only one single-network composed by all the consumers of the compatible products. Although they compete in quantity, the firms cannot influence the consumers expectation of the network size, so that they are network-size taking. The firms work together to build a common network, yet, they compete to each other to serve it. This concept of equilibrium was introduced by KS and it is known as fulfilled or rational expectations Cournot equilibrium (henceforth RECE or simply equilibrium ); in equilibrium, the firms choose the production that maximize their profits, and the industry s production coincides with the expected size of the network (s = z n ). In other words, both the consumers and the firms correctly predict the market outcome, and the expectations of the consumers are fulfilled. Definition 1 A symmetric RECE of the one-network industry consists of a vector of individual outputs (x 1, x 2,..., x n ) and an expected network size s such that: (1) x i arg max{xp (x + j i x j, s) cx K : x } for each firm i, and (2) n i=1 x i = s. In the equilibrium of the industry without network externalities (and taking s as a parameter), π n (s) always decreases with the number of firms (AL), which is not the case in the industry with a single-network; as noted by AZ, per-firm profit might increase or decrease with the entry of firms. But as in the standard Cournot model, total output always increases with the number of firms n. It is important to keep in mind those results to compare the industries with and without network effects. We summarize them in Table 1 together with our main findings: the comparison of the number of firms from the free-entry (n e ) and second-best (n ) equilibria. 7

8 w/o net. effects w. net. effects π n π n x n x n not n e n n e n possible x n x n x n x n n e n n e n n e = n n e n Table 1: Summary of results For a better exposition of our results, we separate this study in two cases: (i) when per-firm profits in the industry with network effects decrease with entry, and (ii) when they increase. 3.1 Equilibrium per-firm profits decrease with entry We start with the situation where equilibrium individual profits decrease with entry, π n π n+1 for all n, because it provides a similar scenario to the one in the standard Cournot model in which individual profits always decrease with n. In this context we establish an important difference between the industries with and without network effects: with business-stealing competition, under-entry may occur by more than one firm in the presence of demand-side economies of scale Business-stealing competition As brought up by MW and confirmed by ACK, in the absence of network effects, excessive entry (under-entry is possible, but at most by one firm) is a direct consequence of the businessstealing effect. Under business-stealing competition, the regulator allows an additional firm in the market whenever its profits compensate for the social loss generated by the decline in the production of the rest of the firms. With a compatible network, even if entry reduces 8

9 individual output, it also creates a social gain given by the expansion of the network, allowing for the possibility of under-entry by more than one firm. For a better understanding of this phenomenon, consider equation (2) derived by MW that expresses the derivative of social welfare W n in the absence of network effects. Ignoring the integer constraint and taking n as continuous they get W n = π n + n[p (z n ) c]x n. (2) The second term of the right hand side of equation (2) is negative due to the business-stealing effect, and because in equilibrium, price exceeds the marginal cost of production, P (z n ) c. With a compatible network, the derivative of social welfare with respect to n incorporates a third term that is always positive and accounts for the effect of the expansion of the network (recall that P 2 > and that in equilibrium, total output increases in n), that is, W n = π n + n[p (z n, z n ) c]x n + z n zn P 2 (t, z n )dt. (3) Therefore, the sign of the sum of the last two terms is ambiguous when x n decreases in n. In particular ignoring the integer constraint and assuming that the solution is interior, if such sum is positive with n firms, there is under-entry; if it is negative, there is excessive entry (such as in the industry with no network effects). Consequently, the comparison between free and second-best entry cannot be predicted in general, and it depends on the primitives of the industry. Later on, in Remark 1, we summarize the previous finding. First, we show with a simple setting that under-entry with business-stealing competition is easily achieved in the presence of network effects. A particular industry with linear inverse demand function (in z and 9

10 s) and costless production provides insightful results about this particular characteristic of the oligopolies with network effects. Then, under-entry might be more common that it is considered to be. To facilitate the presentation of our first proposition, we invoke Result 1 that is due to AZ; to this end, we define the following functions: 1 (z) P 1 (z, z) + P 2 (z, z), and 2 (z) [P (z, z) c][p 11 (z, z) + P 12 (z, z)] P 1 (z, z)[p 1 (z, z) + P 2 (z, z)]. Notice that 1 (z) accounts for the total change in price when aggregate output changes along the fulfilled expectation path. 2 (z) refers to the fact that, as we discuss in the following section, business-enhancing competition is broader in the oligopoly with network effects (for a detailed discussion, see AZ). Throughout this paper, all the results refer to a Cournot oligopoly with positive network effects and complete compatibility. Result 1 (AZ) If 1 (z) and 2 (z) on [z n, z n+1 ] for all n, then, π n π n+1 and x n x n+1 for all n. Result 1 provides sufficient conditions to attain the situation under study in this section: decreasing equilibrium individual output and profits with respect to n. Now consider a particular industry with a compatible network, inverse demand function given by P (z, s) = a + bs z, with a > and < b < 1, and costless production, c =. 4 Observe that 1 (z) = 2 (z) = 1 + b <, then, by Result 1, x n and π n globally decrease in n. The reader can easily verify that the equilibrium output is given by 5 z n = na 1 + n(1 b), (4) 4 This setting is equivalent to have costly production, c >, and P (z, s) = (a c) + bs z, with a > c. 5 See AZ-Example 2 for details of the calculation. 1

11 and then, we have the following result (this and the rest of the proofs are provided in the Appendix). The constraint on K guarantees that at least one firm can always remain in the market, (assumption (A5)). Proposition 1 Let P (z, s) = a+bs z and c = ; a >, < b < 1, and < K < a 2 /(2 b) 2. a Then x n = and π a 1+n(1 b) n = 2 decrease in n; moreover [1+n(1 b)] 2 i) If b <.5, then, n e n ; ii) If b.5, then, n e n. ACK state that in the absence of network effects, and whenever per-firm output and profits decrease in n (such as in our Proposition 1), we have n e n 1. Hence, we establish a clear difference between the two oligopolies: provided that per-firm profits globally decrease with entry, under-entry by more than one firm is not possible without network effects (b = ) if individual output decreases, yet, under-entry by more than one firm is possible with the existence of a compatible network. This departure from the Cournot model without network effects is due only to the network effects, not to the primitives of the model. Proposition 1 clearly reflects the relevance of the network effect in establishing the relationship between n e and n. In fact, b measures the sensitivity of the consumers willingness to pay to the expected size of the market, an b is the only determinant to whether there is under or excessive entry. When the sensitivity is low (part i), the business-stealing effect is stronger than the network effect (see equation (3)), and more firms than the socially optimal level decide to enter. On the other hand, if b is high (part ii), the positive network effect prevails and there is under-entry. Example 1 illustrates Proposition 1. Example 1. Let P (z, s) = a + bs z and c = ; a >, < b < 1, and < K < a 2 /(2 b) 2. According to Proposition 1, x n and π n globally decrease in n. Table 2 shows 11

12 that the comparison between free and second-best entry changes for three different values of b; similarly, we show the social welfare achieved under each setting. The parameters a = 8 and K = 4 are fixed at those levels only for illustrative purposes. Table 2: Free and second-best entry under complete compatibility with P (z, s) = a + bs z, a = 8, K = 4, c =, and three different values of b. b W n e n e K W n n K n e n A B C In line with Proposition 1, cases A and B correspond to the standard Cournot result of over-entry given the business-stealing effect. Case C presents the departure from the standard model, since there is under-entry by more than one firm. An important consequence of Proposition 1 is that the consumers might be better off with a regulator than with free entry, contrary to what one would think. In the absence of network effects, consumer surplus increases with the number of firms, consequently, the consumers prefer the free entry scheme that leads to more firms. In the industry considered in Proposition 1, consumer surplus also increases with the number of firms (AZ, Theorem 11-i), hence, when b.5, the consumers prefer to be in a regulated industry. Our findings in this section are generalized in Remark 1, when we ignore the integer constraint. The hypothesis is written in terms of the equilibrium variables to consider all the 12

13 industries whose firms in equilibrium, have decreasing profits and production with respect to entry. Yet, the condition π n π n+1 and x n for all n can be replaced by the hypothesis of Result 1. 6 Remark 1 Let n be interior; π n π n+1 and x n for all n; ignore the integer constraint. i) If n [P (z n, z n ) c]x n + zn z n P 2 (t, z n )dt, then, n e n ; ii) If n [P (z n, z n ) c]x n + zn z n P 2 (t, z n )dt, then, n e n. If n is a corner solution, the comparison is straightforward. Otherwise, if n is interior, Remark 1 provides sufficient conditions that lead to excessive or under-entry, that follow immediately from equation (3). Observe that the conditions in Remark 1 are local (for the second-best number of firms); they can be replaced by their global version, but that would considerably reduce the number of industries that satisfy them. Next we study the setting where profit decreases with entry, π n π n+1, but per-firm output expands, x n x n Business-enhancing competition When individual profits decrease with competition but individual production increases, the result in the industry with network effects is equivalent to that of the industry without network effects: there is under-entry. With the network effects and business-enhancing competition, both the increase of individual production and the expansion of the network have the same direction and therefore, there is always under-entry. Specifically, the sum of the last two terms of equation (3) is positive whenever x n increases in n. 6 For ease in the presentation, the condition on equilibrium individual output is globally established, x n. As in ACK, it can be replaced by its local version, x n, to include all the industries that yield to non-monotonic individual output but satisfy x n. 13

14 Recall that in the oligopoly without network effects, individual profits always decrease with n, which is not the case in the presence of network effects. Thus, we make explicit in Proposition 2 that profits decrease with entry. 7 Proposition 2 Let π n π n+1 for all n. If x n x n+1, then, n e n. The industries with and without network effects share the characteristic of under-entry with the business-enhancing competition, but this kind of competition is more common in industries with network effects (AZ). For instance, when P (z, s) is log-concave in z or there are variable costs, business-enhancing is impossible in the standard Cournot model (see AL and ACK), but it is feasible with network effects. However, together with decreasing individual profits, business-enhancing competition under network effects (hypothesis of Proposition 2) might be hard to attain. For instance, it is unfeasible in the industry described in Proposition 1. There, 1 = 2 and according to AZ, whenever these variables are both positive (negative), per-firm output and profits increase (decrease) with n (see Results 1 and 2). Then, if 1 = 2, per-firm output and profits cannot have an opposite direction of change with entry, as required by Proposition 2. The following example presents an industry that satisfies the hypothesis of Proposition 2, it is due to AZ with a slight change on the inverse demand function. 8 Example 2. Consider an industry with a single-network, costless production, and inverse ( ) z demand function given by P (z, s) = exp. The symmetric RECE is implicitly exp(1 1/s) given by x n = exp(1 1/z n ); taking the derivative of the previous expression with respect to 7 As in Remark 1, x n x n+1 can be replaced by x n ( x n ) +1 (see Footnote 6). 8 2z See Example 1 of AZ. There, P (z, s) = exp and the industry is not viable for n = 1 (then, exp(1 1/s) π 1 = ). Changing the coefficient 2 by 1 in P (z, s), makes the monopoly viable (such as in our Example 2). 14

15 n and using the fact that z n is increasing, we have that x n also increases in n. Observe that z 1 = x 1 = 1, and then, the industry is viable for all n 1 (see AZ-Theorem 7). Similarly, it can be verified that π n decreases with n. In particular, if K =.5, we have that n e = 3 and n = 7, in line with Proposition 2. Although AZ provide an example for which per-firm profits decrease in n and x n increases in n under network effects (as required by Proposition 2), they do not provide general conditions for this to happen. To finalize this section, the next proposition establishes such conditions. Proposition 3 Let 1 (z) and 2 (z) on [z n, z n+1 ] for all n. If in addition, 1 (z) [P (z, z) c]/z on [z n, z n+1 ], then, π n π n+1 and x n x n+1. In particular, observe that 1 (z n ) implies that in equilibrium, the demand effect is stronger that the network effect (the magnitude of P 1 dominates that of P 2 ). Intuitively, even though individual output increases with entry, the market effect is so strong that individual profits decrease. 3.2 Equilibrium per-firm profits increase with entry Finally, we study the case where the firms increase their profits with entry, π n π n+1. Although this case might seem strange, AZ discuss its plausibility. In a nutshell, the firms cannot mimic the production of more firms to increase their profits because they cannot influence the consumers expectation of the network size. One justification is that they cannot credibly commit to a given level of production. As discussed earlier, this inability of the firms to influence the consumers beliefs is the spirit of the RECE. 15

16 Intuitively, regardless of the number of firms set by the regulator, firms will improve their profits with a new competitor, and as a consequence, there will always be excessive entry. Yet, it turns out that whenever individual profits and output increase with entry, free and second-best entry will always coincide. As we will see later, free and second-best entry might be finite or infinite according to the primitives of the industry. Proposition 4 Let π n π n+1 for all n, then, n e n. If in addition, x n x n+1 for all n, we have n e = n. The particular case studied in Proposition 1 illustrates Proposition 4 with a finite number of firms entering the market. But first, we state the following result due to AZ (Lemma 9-i and Theorem 1-i), that provides conditions such that both the individual production and profits expand with entry. Result 2 (AZ) If 1 (z) and 2 (z) on [z n, z n+1 ] for all n, then, π n π n+1 and x n x n+1 for all n. Recall that in the industry analyzed in Proposition 1, the inverse demand function is linear in both z and s, P (z, s) = a+bs z, a >, and c =. From 1 (z) = 2 (z) = 1+b, it follows that when b > 1, individual output and profits expand with entry (Result 2). But now, the denominator in equation (4) may become negative if n is big enough, hence, total output becomes na z n = if n < 1 ; 1+n(1 b) b 1, otherwise. Notice that whenever b 2, equilibrium total output is zero, then, we focus on the values 1 < b < 2. Let n denote the maximum number of firms for which the industry is viable (that is, for which z n > ); then, n = 1/(b 1) 1 = min{n N : 1/(b 1) n} 1. Since π n 16

17 increase in n n and π 1 > K, free entry leads to n e = n firms. Similarly, it can be shown that the regulator will pick n = n e = n. Proposition 5 Let P (z, s) = a + bs z and c = ; a >, 1 < b < 2, < K < a 2 /(2 b) 2, and n = 1/(b 1) 1. Then, n e = n = n. Proposition 5 provides an example of an industry where n e = n is finite. Example 3 shows that n e = n might be infinite. Example 3. Consider an industry with a compatible network, inverse demand function P (z, s) = a + bs α z, with a, b and α strictly positive, and costless production (c = ). Observe that if 1 (z) = 2 (z) = 1 + αbz α 1 on [z n, z n+1 ], then, x n and π n globally increase with n (Result 2). For instance, such is the case when a = 1.3, b =.99, α = 1.2 and K = 2, then, the number of firms that enter the market is unbounded, which coincides with the regulator s decision. Note that 1 (z) = 2 (z) increases in z provided α > 1. By AZ, z n increases in n and thus, 1 (z) = 2 (z) take their lowest value when n = 1. Hence, z 1 = 1.24 establishes the lower bound of 1 (z) = 2 (z), which is equal to Final Remarks We have shown that a simple modification to the standard Cournot oligopoly model the existence of network effects is enough to change the conventional wisdom that excessive entry (under-entry) is a direct consequence of the business-stealing (business-enhancing) competition. With a single-network, under-entry occurs under business-enhancing competition, but may also happen with the business-stealing competition. Moreover, under-entry as 17

18 a consequence of business-enhancing competition is more common when network effects exist (provided its plausibility discussed in Proposition 3), then, under-entry in oligopolies may be more common than one would think. Recall that without network effects, the firms decrease their profits with competition, and in general, they also decrease their production with entry (business-stealing competition) hence, there is excessive entry. Consequently, the firms obtain less profits than in the socially optimal scenario and the consumers benefit from it by getting lower prices. With the existence of network externalities, such as in telecommunications industries, there might be under-entry even if the firms hurt each other with competition, then, the firms are better off with free entry and the consumers decrease their surplus. Hence, one has to be very careful when allowing free entry of firms if the objective is to maximize consumer surplus; although it is natural to assume that free entry benefits the consumers, it might be the opposite in the presence of network effects. 5 Appendix Proof of Proposition 1. The assumption < K < a 2 /(2 b) 2 implies that at least one firm is active, π 1 > K. < b < 1 implies that 1 (z) = 2 (z) = 1 + b <, so that x n and π n decrease in n (Result 1). In general, the problem of the regulator is zn max [W n nk = P (t, z n )dt ncx n nk], n 18

19 with FOC: π n K + n[p (z n, z n ) c]x n + z n zn P 2 (t, z n )dt =. (5) When P (z, s) = a + bs z and c =, the left-hand side of the FOC (5) becomes and the second order condition (SOC) is a 2 (1 + bn) (1 + n(1 b)) K = π n(1 + bn) K, (6) n(1 b) a 2 (4b 3 2bn(1 b)) (1 + n(1 b)) 4 <, which holds for b.75 or for n sufficiently large, n > (4b 3)/[2b(1 b)]. i) Assume that < b <.5. At n e + 1, equation (6) becomes π n e +1(1 + b(n e + 1)) 1 + (n e + 1)(1 b) K < K(1 + b(ne + 1)) 1 + (n e + 1)(1 b) K = K(ne + 1)(2b 1) 1 + (n e + 1)(1 b) <. The first inequality follows by the free entry condition, π n e +1 < K, and the second one, by < b <.5. Then, provided that W n is strictly concave in n (given b.75), the regulator must decrease the number of firms in order to optimize social welfare, n < n e + 1, which implies n n e. ii) Now suppose that.5 b < 1. Analogous to part i), but using the fact that π n e K, we have π n e(1 + bn e ) 1 + n e (1 b) K K(1 + bne ) 1 + n e (1 b) K = Kne (2b 1) 1 + n e (1 b). If.5 b.75, the result follows immediately by the strict concavity of W n. Otherwise, if.75 < b < 1, the second order condition holds when n > (4b 3)/[2b(1 b)]. Similarly, note that when n = 1, the regulator can (weakly) improve social welfare with an additional firm, 19

20 which can be seen from equation (6): π 1 (1 + b) 2 b K > K(1 + b) 2 b K = K(2b 1) 2 b (the first inequality follows by (A5), π 1 > K, and the second one, by.5 b < 1). Hence, social welfare is first increasing and convex, then changes curvature and finally decreases. Altogether, we have n e n. Proof of Remark 1. Let n be an interior solution of the regulator, then, ignoring the integer constraint, it satisfies the FOC (5). i) If n [P (z n, z n ) c]x n +z n zn P 2 (t, z n )dt, then π n K, and since π n π n+1 for all n, we have n e n. The proof of ii) is analogous to that of i). Proof of Proposition 2. First notice that since P 1 < and x n +1 > (if x n +1 = the result is immediate, n = n e = ), x n +1P (z n +1, z n +1) Also, by optimality of n, (n +1)x n +1 n x n +1 P (t, z n +1)dt < P (t, z n +1)dt. (7) W n n K W n +1 (n + 1)K, 2

21 that is zn P (t, z n )dt n cx n n K zn +1 P (t, z n +1)dt (n + 1)cx n +1 (n + 1)K. Then, we have the following expressions π n +1 K x n +1P (z n +1, z n +1) + zn zn x n +1P (z n +1, z n +1) + n x n +1 < P (t, z n +1)dt + P (t, z n )dt P (t, z n +1)dt zn zn +1 zn +1 P (t, z n +1)dt n c(x n x n +1) n (x n x n +1)P (z n +1, z n +1) n c(x n x n +1) = n [P (z n +1, z n +1) c](x n x n +1). P (t, z n +1)dt n c(x n x n +1) P (t, z n +1)dt n c(x n x n +1) The first inequality follows by π n +1 = x n +1P (z n +1, z n +1) cx n +1; the second one by z n +1 z n (AZ) and P 2 >, and the third one by (7). The fourth inequality is given by P 1 < and z n +1 n x n +1 n x n = z n. The last one follows by P (z n +1, z n +1) c and x n +1 x n. Hence, π n +1 < K, and by π n π n+1, we have the result. Proof of Proposition 3. By AZ Lemma 9i, 2 (z) on [z n, z n+1 ], implies that x n x n+1. Now observe that π n = x n [P (z n, z n ) c], taking derivative with respect to n, we have π n = x n[p (z n, z n ) c] + z n[p 1 (z n, z n ) + P 2 (z n, z n )]x n. 21

22 Since z n = nx n, we have z n = nx n + x n, and then π n = x n[p (z n, z n ) c + z n [P 1 (z n, z n ) + P 2 (z n, z n )]] + x 2 n[p 1 (z n, z n ) + P 2 (z n, z n )]. If [P 1 (z, z) + P 2 (z, z)] [P (z, z) c]/z and P 1 (z, z) + P 2 (z, z) on [z n, z n+1 ] for all n, we have, π n π n+1 for all n. Proof of Proposition 4. First, since π n increases in n and π 1 > K, it is clear that the firms always have incentives to enter, and hence, n e n. Now suppose that x n x n+1 for all n. Then, W n K = π n K + n[p (z n, z n ) c]x n + z n > n[p (z n, z n ) c]x n + z n zn P 2 (t, z n )dt. zn P 2 (t, z n )dt The first inequality follows by π 1 > K and π n increasing in n; the second one by x n and z n increasing in n, P (z n, z n ) c, and P 2 >. As a consequence, the regulator s objective function is also increasing in n and therefore, she will allow as many firms as possible, which coincides with the firms behavior without regulation. Proof of Proposition 5. Recall that n denotes the maximum number of active firms in the industry; with more than n firms, they will stop to produce. From 1 (z) = 2 (z) = 1 + b >, it follows that π n increases in n for all n < n (Result 2), and so does π n K. Then, (A5) π 1 > K implies that π n > K; as a consequence n e = n. 22

23 On the regulator s side, from the proof of Proposition 1, we have that W n nk is strictly convex in n whenever b > 1, specifically, the SOC of the regulator is then, it chooses between 1 and n firms. a 2 (4b 3 2bn(1 b)) (1 + n(1 b)) 4 > ; Since π 1 > K and π n increase in n, we have that π n > K for all n n; together with b > 1 and equation (6), we have (W n nk) n = π n(1 + bn) K(1 + bn) nk(2b 1) K > K = 1 + n(1 b) 1 + n(1 b) 1 + n(1 b) > for all n < n, then, social welfare is maximized at n = n. References Amir, R. (1996). Cournot Oligopoly and the Theory of Supermodular Games. Games and Economic Behavior, 15: Amir, R., De Castro, L., and Koutsougeras, L. (214). Free Entry versus Socially Optimal Entry. Journal of Economic Theory, 154: Amir, R. and Lambson, V. E. (2). On the Effects of Entry in Cournot Markets. The Review of Economic Studies, 67(2): Amir, R. and Lazzati, N. (211). Network Effects, Market Structure and Industry Performance. Journal of Economic Theory, 146(6): Katz, M. L. and Shapiro, C. (1985). Network Externalities, Competition, and Compatibility. The American Economic Review, 75(3):

24 Mankiw, N. G. and Whinston, M. D. (1986). Free Entry and Social Inefficiency. The RAND Journal of Economics, pages Shapiro, C. (2). Navigating the Patent Thicket: Cross Licenses, Patent Pools, and Standard Setting. Innovation Policy and the Economy, 1:

On oligopoly with positive network effects and incompatible networks

On oligopoly with positive network effects and incompatible networks On oligopoly with positive network effects and incompatible networks Rabah Amir and Adriana Gama January 31, 217 Abstract We consider symmetric oligopolies with positive network effects where each firm

More information

Advanced Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomics Advanced Microeconomics Leonardo Felli EC441: Room D.106, Z.332, D.109 Lecture 8 bis: 24 November 2004 Monopoly Consider now the pricing behavior of a profit maximizing monopolist: a firm that is the only

More information

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 Bertrand Model of Price Competition Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 ҧ Bertrand Model of Price Competition Consider: An industry with two firms, 1 and 2, selling a homogeneous product Firms face market

More information

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 16-1, 231 253 (2015) Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * Hongkun Ma School of Economics, Shandong University,

More information

Free Entry and Social Inefficiency under Vertical Oligopoly: Revisited

Free Entry and Social Inefficiency under Vertical Oligopoly: Revisited Free Entry and Social Inefficiency under Vertical Oligopoly: Revisited Hiroshi Kurata a, Takao Ohkawa b, Makoto Okamura c a Department of Economics, Tohoku Gakuin University, Japan b Department of Economics,

More information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers September 6, 016 ONLINE APPENDIX In this Appendix we present in full additional results and extensions which are only mentioned in the paper. In the exposition

More information

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction Susumu Sato July 9, 2018 I study a monopoly regulation in the setting where consumers can engage in demand-reducing investments. I first

More information

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility Toker Doganoglu and Julian Wright July 19, 2005 We would like to thank two anonymous referees and our editor, Simon Anderson, for their very helpful

More information

Katz and Shapiro (1985)

Katz and Shapiro (1985) Katz and Shapiro (1985) 1 The paper studies the compatibility choice of competing firms in industries with network externalities. Also investigated are the social vs. private incentives of compatibility

More information

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract Entry under an Information-Gathering onopoly Alex Barrachina* June 2016 Abstract The effects of information-gathering activities on a basic entry model with asymmetric information are analyzed. In the

More information

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of... This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of... John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 1 / 1 We will cover the following topics: with Sequential Moves

More information

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley Firms and returns to scale. Increasing returns to scale and monopoly pricing 2. Natural monopoly 1 C. Constant returns to scale 21 D. The CRS economy 26 E. pplication

More information

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship Journal of Game Theory 2017 6(2): 38-42 DOI: 10.5923/j.jgt.20170602.02 Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship Aika Monden Graduate School

More information

Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous?

Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous? Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous? Paolo G. Garella University of Bologna 14 July 004 Abstract The present note shows that innocuous Minimum Quality Standards, namely standards that

More information

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

Answer Key: Problem Set 3 Answer Key: Problem Set Econ 409 018 Fall Question 1 a This is a standard monopoly problem; using MR = a 4Q, let MR = MC and solve: Q M = a c 4, P M = a + c, πm = (a c) 8 The Lerner index is then L M P

More information

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Yongmin Chen and David Sappington University of Colorado and University of Florida February 2016 1 / 32 1. Introduction Patent policy: patent protection

More information

Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership

Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership Kazuhiko Kato and Leonard F.S. Wang December 29, 2012 Abstract The paper compares an emission tax and an emission quota in a

More information

Price and Capacity Competition

Price and Capacity Competition Price and Capacity Competition Daron Acemoglu, Kostas Bimpikis, and Asuman Ozdaglar October 9, 2007 Abstract We study the efficiency of oligopoly equilibria in a model where firms compete over capacities

More information

Free entry and social efficiency in an open economy. Arghya Ghosh, Jonathan Lim, and Hodaka Morita

Free entry and social efficiency in an open economy. Arghya Ghosh, Jonathan Lim, and Hodaka Morita Free entry and social efficiency in an open economy Arghya Ghosh, Jonathan Lim, and Hodaka Morita Abstract Is free entry desirable for social efficiency? We examine this question in an open economy context

More information

Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I

Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I Prepared with SEVI S LIDES Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I Antonio Cabrales & Massimo Motta May 25, 2005 Summary Some definitions Efficiency reasons for tying Tying as a price

More information

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S. In the Name of God Sharif University of Technology Graduate School of Management and Economics Microeconomics 1 44715 (1396-97 1 st term) - Group 1 Dr. S. Farshad Fatemi Chapter 10: Competitive Markets

More information

Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly

Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo June 8, 2010 Abstract I investigate an asymmetric duopoly where

More information

Appendix of Homophily in Peer Groups The Costly Information Case

Appendix of Homophily in Peer Groups The Costly Information Case Appendix of Homophily in Peer Groups The Costly Information Case Mariagiovanna Baccara Leeat Yariv August 19, 2012 1 Introduction In this Appendix we study the information sharing application analyzed

More information

Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!?

Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!? Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!? Mathias Erlei Clausthal University of Technology Julius-Albert-Str. 2, 38678 Clausthal-Zellerfeld, Germany email: m.erlei@tu-clausthal.de Abstract This

More information

Optimal Objective Function

Optimal Objective Function Optimal Objective Function Junichi Haraguchi Taku Masuda June 5 017 PRELIMINARY. ANY COMMENTS APPRECIATED. 1 Introduction In a framework of industrial organization we basically assume firms objective is

More information

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale. Increasing returns to scale and monopoly pricing 2. Constant returns to scale 19 C. The CRS economy 25 D. pplication to trade 47 E. Decreasing

More information

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods 5. Externalities and Public Goods 5. Externalities and Public Goods Externalities Welfare properties of Walrasian Equilibria rely on the hidden assumption of private goods: the consumption of the good

More information

5. Externalities and Public Goods

5. Externalities and Public Goods 5. Externalities and Public Goods Welfare properties of Walrasian Equilibria rely on the hidden assumption of private goods: the consumption of the good by one person has no effect on other people s utility,

More information

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games University of Manchester, UK November 25, 2010 Introduction Suppose we make a finite set of observations T = {1,..., m}, m 1, of a perfectly homogeneous-good oligopoly market. There is a finite number

More information

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples February 24, 2011 Summary: We introduce the Nash Equilibrium: an outcome (action profile) which is stable in the sense that no player

More information

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Hiroaki Ino Institute of Intellectual Property and Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo [Preliminary

More information

ONLINE APPENDIX. Upping the Ante: The Equilibrium Effects of Unconditional Grants to Private Schools

ONLINE APPENDIX. Upping the Ante: The Equilibrium Effects of Unconditional Grants to Private Schools ONLINE APPENDIX Upping the Ante: The Equilibrium Effects of Unconditional Grants to Private Schools T. Andrabi, J. Das, A.I. Khwaja, S. Ozyurt, and N. Singh Contents A Theory A.1 Homogeneous Demand.................................

More information

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games 1/10 Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games May 4, 2014 2/10 Outline 1 Bertrand Market Game 2 Bertrand Paradox 3 Asymmetric Firms 3/10 Bertrand Duopoly Market Game Discontinuous Payoff Functions (1 p

More information

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018 EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 018 Show all your work clearly and make sure you justify all your answers. NAME 1. Consider the market for smart pencil in which only one firm (Superapiz) enjoys a

More information

Monopoly Price Discrimination With Constant Elasticity Demand

Monopoly Price Discrimination With Constant Elasticity Demand Monopoly Price Discrimination With Constant Elasticity Demand September 014 Iñaki Aguirre 1 Simon G. Cowan University of the Basque Country University of Oxford Abstract This paper presents new results

More information

The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers

The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers joint work with Frederic Murphy Climate Policy and Long Term Decisions-Investment and R&D, Bocconi University, Milan,

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6 Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO April 10, 017 Administrative Stuff Homework # is due at the end of class. I will post the solutions on the website later today. The midterm

More information

Econ 8601: Industrial Organization (Thomas J. Holmes) Lecture 1. Part 1: The Cost of Monopoly in General Equilibrium. μ 1

Econ 8601: Industrial Organization (Thomas J. Holmes) Lecture 1. Part 1: The Cost of Monopoly in General Equilibrium. μ 1 Econ 8601: Industrial Organization (Thomas J. Holmes) Lecture 1 Part 1: The Cost of Monopoly in General Equilibrium Set of goods [0, 1], x [0, 1] aparticulargood. Utility function of representative consumer

More information

Price and Capacity Competition

Price and Capacity Competition Price and Capacity Competition Daron Acemoglu a, Kostas Bimpikis b Asuman Ozdaglar c a Department of Economics, MIT, Cambridge, MA b Operations Research Center, MIT, Cambridge, MA c Department of Electrical

More information

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness On-Line Appendix Jérôme Dugast Thierry Foucault August 30, 07 This note is the on-line appendix for Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. It contains

More information

Managerial delegation in multimarket oligopoly

Managerial delegation in multimarket oligopoly Managerial delegation in multimarket oligopoly Arup Bose Barnali Gupta Statistics and Mathematics Unit Department of Economics Indian Statistical Institute Miami University, Ohio INDIA USA bosearu@gmail.com

More information

Ralph s Strategic Disclosure 1

Ralph s Strategic Disclosure 1 Ralph s Strategic Disclosure Ralph manages a firm that operates in a duopoly Both Ralph s (privatevalue) production cost and (common-value) inverse demand are uncertain Ralph s (constant marginal) production

More information

Limit pricing models and PBE 1

Limit pricing models and PBE 1 EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Limit pricing models and PBE 1 1 Model Consider an entry game with an incumbent monopolist (Firm 1) and an entrant (Firm ) who analyzes whether or not to join the

More information

Bertrand-Edgeworth competition with substantial product dierentiation

Bertrand-Edgeworth competition with substantial product dierentiation Bertrand-Edgeworth competition with substantial product dierentiation Robert Somogyi Preliminary version August 21, 2013 Abstract Since Kreps and Scheinkman's seminal article (1983) a large number of papers

More information

Basics of Game Theory

Basics of Game Theory Basics of Game Theory Giacomo Bacci and Luca Sanguinetti Department of Information Engineering University of Pisa, Pisa, Italy {giacomo.bacci,luca.sanguinetti}@iet.unipi.it April - May, 2010 G. Bacci and

More information

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective Alex Possajennikov University of Nottingham January 2012 Abstract Suppose that in aggregative games, in which a player s payoff

More information

Durable goods monopolist

Durable goods monopolist Durable goods monopolist Coase conjecture: A monopolist selling durable good has no monopoly power. Reason: A P 1 P 2 B MC MC D MR Q 1 Q 2 C Q Although Q 1 is optimal output of the monopolist, it faces

More information

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework. Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework. Economy: I consumers, i = 1,...I. J firms, j = 1,...J. L goods, l = 1,...L Initial Endowment of good l in the economy: ω l 0, l = 1,...L. Consumer i : preferences

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRICE AND CAPACITY COMPETITION. Daron Acemoglu Kostas Bimpikis Asuman Ozdaglar

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRICE AND CAPACITY COMPETITION. Daron Acemoglu Kostas Bimpikis Asuman Ozdaglar NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRICE AND CAPACITY COMPETITION Daron Acemoglu Kostas Bimpikis Asuman Ozdaglar Working Paper 12804 http://www.nber.org/papers/w12804 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

Flow Control, Routing, and Performance with a For-profit Service Provider

Flow Control, Routing, and Performance with a For-profit Service Provider November 2004 Flow Control, Routing, and Performance with a For-profit Service Provider by Daron Acemoglu 1 and Asuman Ozdaglar 2 Abstract We consider a game theoretic framework to analyze traffic in a

More information

Supermodular Games. Ichiro Obara. February 6, 2012 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Supermodular Games February 6, / 21

Supermodular Games. Ichiro Obara. February 6, 2012 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Supermodular Games February 6, / 21 Supermodular Games Ichiro Obara UCLA February 6, 2012 Obara (UCLA) Supermodular Games February 6, 2012 1 / 21 We study a class of strategic games called supermodular game, which is useful in many applications

More information

Two-sided investments and matching with multi-dimensional cost types and attributes

Two-sided investments and matching with multi-dimensional cost types and attributes Two-sided investments and matching with multi-dimensional cost types and attributes Deniz Dizdar 1 1 Department of Economics, University of Montréal September 15, 2014 1/33 Investments and matching 2/33

More information

Network E ects, Market Structure and Industry Performance

Network E ects, Market Structure and Industry Performance Network E ects, Market Structure and Industry Performance Rabah Amir y and Natalia Lazzati z February 1, 29 Abstract This paper provides a thorough analysis of oligopolistic markets with positive demand-side

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 28 Jun 2016

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 28 Jun 2016 On the Inefficiency of Forward Markets in Leader-Follower Competition Desmond Cai, Anish Agarwal, Adam Wierman arxiv:66.864v [math.oc] 8 Jun 6 June 9, 6 Abstract Motivated by electricity markets, this

More information

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IN ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT Strategic Incentives for Managers in Contests Matthias Kräkel Discussion Paper No. 01-08 GERMAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION - GEABA

More information

Mathematical Appendix. Ramsey Pricing

Mathematical Appendix. Ramsey Pricing Mathematical Appendix Ramsey Pricing PROOF OF THEOREM : I maximize social welfare V subject to π > K. The Lagrangian is V + κπ K the associated first-order conditions are that for each I + κ P I C I cn

More information

Product Variety, Price Elasticity of Demand and Fixed Cost in Spatial Models

Product Variety, Price Elasticity of Demand and Fixed Cost in Spatial Models Product Variety, Price Elasticity of Demand and Fixed Cost in Spatial Models Yiquan Gu 1,2, Tobias Wenzel 3, 1 Technische Universität Dortmund 2 Ruhr Graduate School in Economics 3 Universität Erlangen-Nürnberg

More information

The Value of Sharing Intermittent Spectrum

The Value of Sharing Intermittent Spectrum The Value of Sharing Intermittent Spectrum R. erry, M. Honig, T. Nguyen, V. Subramanian & R. V. Vohra Abstract We consider a model of Cournot competition with congestion motivated by recent initiatives

More information

OPTIMAL TWO-PART TARIFF LICENSING CONTRACTS WITH DIFFERENTIATED GOODS AND ENDOGENOUS R&D* Ramón Faulí-Oller and Joel Sandonís**

OPTIMAL TWO-PART TARIFF LICENSING CONTRACTS WITH DIFFERENTIATED GOODS AND ENDOGENOUS R&D* Ramón Faulí-Oller and Joel Sandonís** OPTIMAL TWO-PART TARIFF LICENSING CONTRACTS WITH DIFFERENTIATED GOODS AND ENDOGENOUS R&D* Ramón Faulí-Oller and Joel Sandonís** WP-AD 2008-12 Corresponding author: R. Fauli-Oller Universidad de Alicante,

More information

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 19, November 7 Outline 1 Welfare Theorems in the differentiable case. 2 Aggregate excess

More information

Oligopoly. Oligopoly. Xiang Sun. Wuhan University. March 23 April 6, /149

Oligopoly. Oligopoly. Xiang Sun. Wuhan University. March 23 April 6, /149 Oligopoly Xiang Sun Wuhan University March 23 April 6, 2016 1/149 Outline 1 Introduction 2 Game theory 3 Oligopoly models 4 Cournot competition Two symmetric firms Two asymmetric firms Many symmetric firms

More information

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October 23 2011 1 Scores The exam was long. I know this. Final grades will definitely be curved. Here is a rough

More information

Multimarket Oligopolies with Restricted Market Access

Multimarket Oligopolies with Restricted Market Access Multimarket Oligopolies with Restricted Market Access Tobias Harks 1 and Max Klimm 2 1 Department of Quantitative Economics, Maastricht University, the Netherlands. t.harks@maastrichtuniversity.nl 2 Department

More information

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009 Department of Agricultural Economics PhD Qualifier Examination May 009 Instructions: The exam consists of six questions. You must answer all questions. If you need an assumption to complete a question,

More information

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 27 October, 207 Pareto Efficient Allocation Recall the following result: Result An allocation x is Pareto-efficient if and only

More information

Definitions and Proofs

Definitions and Proofs Giving Advice vs. Making Decisions: Transparency, Information, and Delegation Online Appendix A Definitions and Proofs A. The Informational Environment The set of states of nature is denoted by = [, ],

More information

A Model of Endogenous Cross-Holdings in Oligopoly

A Model of Endogenous Cross-Holdings in Oligopoly A Model of Endogenous Cross-Holdings in Oligopoly Cheng-Zhong Qin, Shengping Zhang, and Dandan Zhu February 6, 2012 Abstract A network approach is proposed to analyze endogenous cross-holdings and their

More information

Price setting on a network

Price setting on a network Price setting on a network Very preliminary and incomplete. Toomas Hinnosaar May 2018 Abstract Most products are produced and sold by supply chains, where an interconnected network of producers and intermediaries

More information

Alfred Marshall s cardinal theory of value: the strong law of demand

Alfred Marshall s cardinal theory of value: the strong law of demand Econ Theory Bull (2014) 2:65 76 DOI 10.1007/s40505-014-0029-5 RESEARCH ARTICLE Alfred Marshall s cardinal theory of value: the strong law of demand Donald J. Brown Caterina Calsamiglia Received: 29 November

More information

Lecture 6. Xavier Gabaix. March 11, 2004

Lecture 6. Xavier Gabaix. March 11, 2004 14.127 Lecture 6 Xavier Gabaix March 11, 2004 0.0.1 Shrouded attributes. A continuation Rational guys U i = q p + max (V p, V e) + σε i = q p + V min (p, e) + σε i = U i + σε i Rational demand for good

More information

Second Welfare Theorem

Second Welfare Theorem Second Welfare Theorem Econ 2100 Fall 2015 Lecture 18, November 2 Outline 1 Second Welfare Theorem From Last Class We want to state a prove a theorem that says that any Pareto optimal allocation is (part

More information

R&D Collaboration in Collusive Networks

R&D Collaboration in Collusive Networks R&D Collaboration in Collusive Networks Gizem Korkmaz European University Institute December, 2011 Market Sharing Agreements In recent years, the scope for explicit or implicit market sharing agreements

More information

Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly

Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly Rabah Amir Department of Economics, University of Arizona Giuseppe De Feo y CORE, Université Catholique de Louvain February 2007 Abstract This paper addresses the issue

More information

Strongly rational expectations equilibria with endogenous acquisition of information

Strongly rational expectations equilibria with endogenous acquisition of information Strongly rational expectations equilibria with endogenous acquisition of information Gabriel Desgranges Maik Heinemann 9 February 004 This paper analyzes conditions for existence of a strongly rational

More information

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata General Equilibrium Equilibrium in Consumption GE begins (1/3) 2-Individual/ 2-good Exchange economy (No production, no transaction costs, full information..) Endowment (Nature): e Private property/ NO

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 29 Mar 2012

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 29 Mar 2012 Efficiency Loss in a Cournot Oligopoly with Convex Market Demand arxiv:123.6675v1 [math.oc] 29 Mar 212 John N. Tsitsiklis and Yunjian Xu Laboratory or Information and Decision Systems, MIT, Cambridge,

More information

Pollution Tax and Social Welfare in Oligopoly. Asymmetric Taxation on Identical Polluters

Pollution Tax and Social Welfare in Oligopoly. Asymmetric Taxation on Identical Polluters Pollution Tax and Social Welfare in Oligopoly Asymmetric Taxation on Identical Polluters Satoshi HONMA Abstract We study asymmetric pollution taxation on identical polluting oligopolists engaged in Cournot

More information

Heterogenous Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Behavioral Uncertainty

Heterogenous Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Behavioral Uncertainty Heterogenous Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Behavioral Uncertainty Akio Matsumoto Department of Systems Industrial Engineering Univesity of Arizona, USA Department of Economics Chuo University,

More information

Costly Expertise. Dino Gerardi and Leeat Yariv yz. Current Version: December, 2007

Costly Expertise. Dino Gerardi and Leeat Yariv yz. Current Version: December, 2007 Costly Expertise Dino Gerardi and Leeat Yariv yz Current Version: December, 007 In many environments expertise is costly. Costs can manifest themselves in numerous ways, ranging from the time that is required

More information

Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition

Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition Luca Lambertini Alessandro Tampieri Quaderni - Working Paper DSE N 750 Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Di erentiated

More information

Aftermarket Power and Basic Market Competition

Aftermarket Power and Basic Market Competition Aftermarket Power and Basic Market Competition Luís Cabral IESE Business School and CEPR September 009 Abstract I revisit the issue of aftermarkets by developing an infinite period model with overlapping

More information

Online Appendix for Sourcing from Suppliers with Financial Constraints and Performance Risk

Online Appendix for Sourcing from Suppliers with Financial Constraints and Performance Risk Online Appendix for Sourcing from Suppliers with Financial Constraints and Performance Ris Christopher S. Tang S. Alex Yang Jing Wu Appendix A: Proofs Proof of Lemma 1. In a centralized chain, the system

More information

Prices and Heterogeneous Search Costs

Prices and Heterogeneous Search Costs Supplementary Appendix to Prices and Heterogeneous Search Costs José Luis Moraga-González Zsolt Sándor Matthijs R. Wildenbeest June 216 Introduction In this supplementary appendix we present two extensions

More information

Partial Privatization under Multimarket Price Competition

Partial Privatization under Multimarket Price Competition MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Partial Privatization under Multimarket Price Competition Taku Masuda and Susumu Sato Graduate School of Economics, The University of Tokyo, Graduate School of Economics,

More information

Index. Cambridge University Press An Introduction to Mathematics for Economics Akihito Asano. Index.

Index. Cambridge University Press An Introduction to Mathematics for Economics Akihito Asano. Index. , see Q.E.D. ln, see natural logarithmic function e, see Euler s e i, see imaginary number log 10, see common logarithm ceteris paribus, 4 quod erat demonstrandum, see Q.E.D. reductio ad absurdum, see

More information

Answer Key: Problem Set 1

Answer Key: Problem Set 1 Answer Key: Problem Set 1 Econ 409 018 Fall Question 1 a The profit function (revenue minus total cost) is π(q) = P (q)q cq The first order condition with respect to (henceforth wrt) q is P (q )q + P (q

More information

Interconnection Incentives of a Large Network Facing Multiple Rivals. David A. Malueg Marius Schwartz. Working Paper January 2003

Interconnection Incentives of a Large Network Facing Multiple Rivals. David A. Malueg Marius Schwartz. Working Paper January 2003 Interconnection Incentives of a Large Network Facing Multiple Rivals David A Malueg Marius Schwartz Working Paper 03 0 January 003 Georgetown University Department of Economics 580 Intercultural Center

More information

Quantity-setting games with a dominant

Quantity-setting games with a dominant MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Quantity-setting games with a dominant firm Attila Tasnádi Corvinus University of Budapest 24. February 2009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/13612/ MPRA Paper

More information

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change Chapter 7 Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change 225 Economic Growth: Lecture Notes 7.1 Expanding Product Variety: The Romer Model There are three sectors: one for the final good sector, one

More information

Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting

Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting Eric Avenel Université de Rennes I et CREM (UMR CNRS 6) March, 00 Abstract This article presents a model

More information

Industrial Organization

Industrial Organization Industrial Organization Lecture Notes Sérgio O. Parreiras Fall, 2017 Outline Mathematical Toolbox Intermediate Microeconomic Theory Revision Perfect Competition Monopoly Oligopoly Mathematical Toolbox

More information

Introduction to Game Theory

Introduction to Game Theory Introduction to Game Theory Part 2. Dynamic games of complete information Chapter 2. Two-stage games of complete but imperfect information Ciclo Profissional 2 o Semestre / 2011 Graduação em Ciências Econômicas

More information

CSR as a bribe to a government

CSR as a bribe to a government CSR as a bribe to a government Taku Masuda 1 Kosuke Hirose 2 PRELIMINARY. ANY COMMENTS APPRECIATED. 1 Introduction The rationale behind partial privatization of public enterprises or social responsibility

More information

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Chiaki Hara April 5, 2004 Abstract We give a theorem on the existence of an equilibrium price vector for an excess

More information

Competitive Equilibrium

Competitive Equilibrium Competitive Equilibrium Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 16, October 26 Outline 1 Pareto Effi ciency 2 The Core 3 Planner s Problem(s) 4 Competitive (Walrasian) Equilibrium Decentralized vs. Centralized Economic

More information

ON HOTELLING S COMPETITION WITH GENERAL PURPOSE PRODUCTS 1

ON HOTELLING S COMPETITION WITH GENERAL PURPOSE PRODUCTS 1 ON HOTELLING S COMPETITION WITH GENERAL PURPOSE PRODUCTS 1 CRISTIÁN TRONCOSO VALVERDE AND JACQUES ROBERT 3 Abstract. This paper extends the traditional Hotelling s model of spatial competition by allowing

More information

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly Daisuke Hirata Graduate School of Economics, University of Tokyo March 2008 Abstract This paper investigates a simultaneous move capacity constrained price competition

More information

9 A Class of Dynamic Games of Incomplete Information:

9 A Class of Dynamic Games of Incomplete Information: A Class of Dynamic Games of Incomplete Information: Signalling Games In general, a dynamic game of incomplete information is any extensive form game in which at least one player is uninformed about some

More information

Internet Peering, Capacity and Pricing

Internet Peering, Capacity and Pricing Internet Peering, Capacity and Pricing Haim Mendelson Shiri Shneorson June, 2003 Abstract We analyze peering on the Internet with consumer delay costs, finding that they have a substantial effect on market

More information

Price Competition and Endogenous Valuation in Search Advertising

Price Competition and Endogenous Valuation in Search Advertising Price Competition and Endogenous Valuation in Search Advertising Lizhen Xu Jianqing Chen Andrew Whinston Web Appendix A Heterogeneous Consumer Valuation In the baseline model, we assumed that consumers

More information