Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting"

Transcription

1 Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting Eric Avenel Université de Rennes I et CREM (UMR CNRS 6) March, 00 Abstract This article presents a model of private vertical contracting with a capacity constrained monopolistic supplier. I consider full capacity beliefs that are consistent with an upstream capacity constraint and are wary when the constraint is tight or production is costless. I show that, facing a capacity constraint, the supplier may preserve its monopoly power in equilibrium. This result stands in sharp contrast to the standard result that the supplier cannot preserve its monopoly power, which holds under the usual implicit assumption of an in nite production capacity. Introduction It is a well-established result in the literature on vertical contracting that when an upstream monopolist (the supplier ) contracts bilaterally and privately with two (or more) competing downstream rms (the retailers ), it is not able to preserve its market power and induce the monopoly outcome on the downstream market (Hart and Tirole (990), McAfee and Schwartz (994), Segal (999), Rey and Tirole (007)). This results from the monopolist s inability to commit to a given set of contracts, which is a consequence of the assumption that o ers are secret. With public o ers, the monopolist is able to eliminate competition between retailers through manipulations of wholesale prices, typically raising these prices. However, the equilibrium set of public contracts is not an equilibrium of the game with secret contracts because the monopolist has an incentive to deviate and o er to one of the downstream rms a lower wholesale price. While the assumption of public contracts may make sense in some speci c situations, for example because the law prohibits o ering di erent contracts to di erent rms, it is in general di cult to justify. So, we are left with this uncomfortable Address: 7 place Hoche, F Rennes, FRANCE. eric.avenel@univ-rennes.fr

2 result of a total inability for the monopolist to preserve its market power. This result is uncomfortable essentially because its robustness is questionable. The rst reason why the robustness of this result is questionable is that vertical contracting games typically have many equilibria. Due to the secrecy of o ers, these are games of incomplete information and we thus have to consider (weak) perfect Bayesian equilibria (Mas-Colell, Whinston, Green (995)). In a PBE, there is no constraint on out of equilibrium beliefs. There are many possible out of equilibrium beliefs and, as a consequence, there are many PBE, even if not any system of beliefs can be part of an equilibrium. The equilibrium discussed above, in which the monopolist is unable to preserve its market power is in fact the PBE when retailers have passive beliefs. Alternatively, one can assume that retailers have symmetry beliefs and then the monopolist is able to eliminate competition on the nal market, just as in the game with public o ers. The choice of out of equilibrium beliefs is thus critical. It is also a di cult choice because we don t know much about the way retailers think about the discussions between the supplier and their competitors. 3 There is however a fruitful theoretical approach to this issue, rst proposed by McAfee and Schwartz (994), then reformulated by Rey and Vergé (004). Rather than choosing beliefs, these authors propose a criterion that acceptable beliefs should satisfy and that allows them to select beliefs. They call these beliefs wary beliefs. If a system of beliefs can be shown to correspond to the wary beliefs in a given game, it is reasonable to assume that this system of beliefs holds in equilibrium. Let us now consider the second reason why the robustness of this result is questionable. The result depends very much on some of the assumptions underlying the game. In particular, the monopolist is implicitly assumed not to face any capacity constraint. As noted by Rey and Tirole (007), a tight capacity constraint may allow the monopolist to reduce the output on the nal market and come closer to the monopoly outcome. However, neither Rey and Tirole (007) nor any other contribution I am aware of work out the resolution of a vertical contracting game with a capacity constrained supplier. In this article, I consider a vertical contracting game with a capacity constrained supplier. Introducing a capacity constraint in the model makes it necessary to fully reconsider the issue of out of equilibrium beliefs since passive beliefs cannot be assumed any more. 4 I consider full capacity beliefs that are consistent with an upstream capacity constraint. I demonstrate that these beliefs are wary beliefs when the capacity constraint is tight or production is costless. In the rst case, the supplier s ability to preserve its monopoly power in equilibrium depends on its production capacity. The preservation of monopoly power is achieved when the supplier s production capacity is equal to the monopoly They have to be consistent with strategy sets: players should not believe other players to make moves that they cannot make. As pointed at by McAfee and Schwartz (995), this leads to the condition of pairwiseproofness imposed by Cremer and Riordan (987) and O Brien and Sha er (99). 3 This is certainly a point on which experimental economics may be very helpful (Martin et al. (00)). 4 Symmetry beliefs cannot either be assumed when the supplier faces a capacity constraint.

3 output. In the second case, a su cient condition for the supplier to preserve its monopoly power is that its production capacity is larger than or equal to the monopoly output. The assumption of costless production may seem quite strong. However, many industries have recently been profoundly transformed by a process of dematerialization. The assumption is not so far from reality for at least some of these industries. For a rm selling music through the internet, the capacity constraint is a more important technical data than the marginal production cost, which is negligible. In section, I present the game and de ne full capacity beliefs. In section 3, I present the PBE of the game when the supplier faces a tight capacity constraint and retailers have full capacity beliefs. I then show that these equilibria are wary beliefs equilibria of the game. In section 4, I consider the case of costless production and show that the PBE of the game with full capacity beliefs are wary beliefs equilibria. In both cases, I determine the conditions under which the supplier is able to preserve its monopoly power. Section 5 concludes. The game I consider an industry composed of a monopolistic supplier (S) selling its product to nal consumers through independent retailers. There are two retailers (R and R ) competing on the nal market à la Cournot. The demand on the nal market is assumed to be linear, with P (X) = X. S supports a constant marginal cost of production equal to c 0 for Q Q and c = + for Q > Q. The supplier s production capacity, Q, is nite, exogenous and it is public knowledge. Retailing costs are assumed to be null. I denote the supplier s pro t by S and industry pro ts, i.e. the joint-pro ts of S, R and R, by. For X Q, (X) = (P (X) c)x. Following Segal (999), I consider a two stage game (Q; c). The timing of moves is: Stage (o ers): S makes each retailer an o er that is observed only by this retailer. R i is o ered a pair (q i ; t i ) where q i is the quantity supplied by S and t i is the transfer from R i to S. Stage (acceptances and competition): Each retailer decides whether to accept or reject the o er it received from the supplier. If R i accepts the contract (q i ; t i ), it pays t i, receives q i, and puts x i q i on the market. 5 To maximize industry pro ts, the output on the nal market should be equal to Q (c) = c. We will refer to this output level as the monopoly output. It is indeed the output that a fully integrated monopolist would select. It is also the equilibrium of the public contracting game. S can for example o er Q (c) ; (c), with (c) = (Q (c)), to each retailer. Both accept and put 5 The retailing sector is a Cournot duopoly in which rms have a capacity constraint: they cannot sell more than the quantity they purchased from the monopolist. There is however the possibility that they don t put on the market all the quantity purchased from the monopolist. This is why in general, x i q i. 3

4 x = Q (c) on the nal market. Industry pro ts are maximized and captured by the supplier which in this case is able to preserve its monopoly power despite the fact that its product is retailed by a duopoly. In the private contracting game with in nite production capacity and passive beliefs, o ering Q (c) ; (c) to each retailer is not an equilibrium. S can pro tably deviate from this strategy by o ering one of the retailers a slightly larger quantity for a slightly larger transfer. The retailer will accept the offer. The other retailer will still accept Q (c) ; (c), which will lead to a loss for this retailer, and the monopolist will enjoy larger pro ts. In equilibrium, Q S o ers each retailer C (c) ; ( QC (c))q C (c), where Q C (c) = 3 ( c) is the equilibrium aggregate output of a Cournot duopoly with marginal cost equal to c. Both retailers accept the contract and put q C (c) = QC (c) on the market. Industry pro ts are reduced as compared to the previous case due to the supplier s inability to preserve its monopoly power. Let us now consider the private contracting game with a nite production capacity. (Q; c) is an extensive form game of imperfect information. The resolution strategy is to look for the (weak) perfect Bayesian equilibria (PBE) of this game (Mas-Colell, Whinston, Green (995)). A PBE is an assessment (; ), where is a strategy pro le and is a system of beliefs, which has two properties: the strategy pro le is sequentially rational given belief system, and the system of beliefs is consistent with the strategies. Before we use these properties to determine the PBE of the game, it is necessary to characterize the sets of admissible strategy pro les and belief systems for. I assumen that S cannot o er more than Q. The o supplier s strategy set is thus S := ((q ; t ); (q ; t )) (R + ) 4 : q + q Q. A strategy for retailer R i is a function x i from [0; Q] into f?g [ R +, where x i =? means that R i rejects the o er and 0 x i q i means that it accepts the o er and puts the quantity x i on the market. R i holds beliefs i. Given (q i ; t i ), i speci es a distribution of probability on the set of admissible values of (q j ; t j ). I restrict my attention to beliefs that put probability one on a particular contract, denoted by ~q j (q i ; t i ); ~t j (q i ; t i ). Beliefs must be compatible with the supplier s strategy set, that is, q i ; t i ; ~q j (q i ; t i ); ~t j (q i ; t i ) S. This condition disquali es passive beliefs as well as symmetry beliefs. Passive beliefs are in fact constant beliefs. Regardless of (q i ; t i ), R i believes that, with probability one, R j is o ered the same contract qj ; t j. Now suppose that Ri is o ered a contract specifying q i = Q. R i has no choice but to believe that R j is o ered q j = 0. Passive beliefs are acceptable only if each retailer believes that the other retailer receives q = 0. This will certainly not be part of a PBE. Under symmetry beliefs, each retailer believes that the other retailer receives exactly the same o er as he does. The same reasoning leads to the disquali cation of symmetry beliefs. I propose to consider full capacity beliefs. De nition Under full capacity beliefs, when R i receives (q i ; t i ), it believes 4

5 that R j is o ered ~q j = Q q i. As regards the transfer t j, R i believes that S sets ~t j so as to leave no rent to R j given that R j has full capacity beliefs. Obviously, full capacity beliefs are compatible with the supplier s strategy set. The following sections characterize the PBE of (Q; c) under full capacity beliefs and compare it with the PBE under wary beliefs in two particular cases. 3 Tight production capacity constraint When the supplier s capacity constraint is tight, we can expect that retailers don t retain product in equilibrium, but rather put on the market all the product they receive from the supplier. This intuition is correct if we de ne a tight capacity constraint by the two following conditions. First, Q c. This ensures that industry pro ts are non-negative when S supplies retailers with Q and retailers put Q on the market. Second, Q Q (0). If R i receives Q > Q (0), it keeps Q Q (0) out of the market because Q (0) is the output of a monopolistic retailer. In this section, I demonstrate that there exists perfect Bayesian equilibria with full capacity beliefs for the private contracting game (Q; c) when the capacity constraint is tight. Furthermore, I characterize the set of perfect Bayesian equilibria with full capacity beliefs and show that full capacity beliefs are wary beliefs. I also show that, for Q = Q (c), industry pro ts are maximized and entirely captured by the supplier. This means that private contracting is not in itself the origin of the loss of market power for a supplier that sells its product through independent retailers. The origin of this result is the combination of privacy, passive beliefs and in nite production capacity. 6 The existence of a capacity constraint disquali es passive beliefs and, under full capacity beliefs, which are also wary beliefs, the supplier may preserve its monopoly power. It will certainly do so if it is able to choose Q. I rst de ne a family of assessments in which retailers hold full capacity beliefs. De nition For any [0; ], E (Q) = x ; x ; q ; t ; q ; t ; ; ~q ; ~t ; ~q ; ~t, where:. (q ; t ; q ; t ) = Q; ( Q)Q; ( )Q; ( )( Q)Q. For i f; g ; x i = q i for t i ( Q)q i, x i =? otherwise and ( ~q j (q i ; t i ); ~t j (q i ; t i ) = Q q i ; ( Q)(Q q i ) : In E (Q), retailers either reject the contract or put on the market all the product they receive from the supplier. The supplier produces at full capacity and shares the product between the retailers. Regardless of, the output on the 6 Recall that with in nite production capacity and symmetry beliefs, the supplier is able to preserve its monopoly power. However, symmetry beliefs are impossible when the supplier s production capacity is nite. 5

6 nal market is Q. The following proposition shows that these assessments are perfect Bayesian equilibria when the supplier faces a tight capacity constraint. Proposition For any Q min(q (0); c) and any [0; ], E (Q) is a perfect Bayesian equilibrium with full capacity beliefs of the extensive form game (Q; c). Proof. I prove the proposition by checking the sequential rationality of strategies and the consistency of beliefs. Consistency of beliefs ( ~q j (q i ; t i ); ~t j (q i ; t i ) is deduced from strategies through Bayes rule when (q ; t ; q ; t ) = Q; ( Q)Q; ( )Q; ( )( Q)Q. Sequential rationality for R i Strategy x i should be optimal for R i given other players strategies and the system of beliefs. Being o ered (q i ; t i ), R i believes that R j is o ered ( ~q j (q i ; t i ); ~t j (q i ; t i ) = Q q i ; ( Q)(Q q i ). If R j is indeed o ered this contract, x j = Q q i because ~t j ( Q)~q j. Because of that, R i s pro t will be Q + q i x i xi t i if it accepts the contract and puts x i on the market. As a consequence, R i puts q i on the market if and only if q i ArgMax Q + q i x i xi () qi Q, which holds for q i Q Q (0). If retailer R i accepts the contract, it puts the quantity q i on the market and makes a pro t equal to Q q i t i. R i accepts the contract if and only if t i ( Q)q i. The strategy x i is sequentially rational in E (Q). Sequential rationality for S Assume that S deviates from (q ; t ; q ; t ) and o ers (q; 0 t 0 ; q; 0 t 0 ) S. Setting transfers at the highest values that retailers can accept, S gets Q c (q 0 + q). 0 For Q c, pro ts are maximized over S for q 0 + q 0 = Q, as in E (Q). There is no pro table deviation from E (Q) for the supplier. Because the capacity constraint is tight, retailers are always capacity constrained in the sense that for any q i, the best reply of R i to ~q j is larger than q i. As a consequence, there is no product retention by retailers. As regards the supplier, changing the transfers without changing the quantities cannot be pro table because, in E a (Q), no rent is left to retailers. Changing quantities and adapting transfers optimally to the new quantities leads to E a 0(Q) for some 0. This has no impact on pro ts. While proposition demonstrates the existence of equilibria and describes a family of equilibria, there could be other full capacity beliefs equilibria. This is in fact not the case. Proposition For any Q min(q (0); c) and any perfect Bayesian equilibrium with full capacity beliefs E of (Q; c), there exists [0; ] such that E = E (Q). Proof. In any full capacity beliefs equilibrium, the supplier produces at full capacity and shares its production between the retailers. As a consequence, (q ; q ) = Q; ( )Q for some [0; ]. Sequential rationality constraints imply that E a is the unique full capacity beliefs equilibrium such that (q ; q ) = Q; ( )Q. In particular, (t ; t ) 6= ( Q)Q; ( )( Q)Q would 6

7 violate the supplier s sequential rationality condition, either because it leads to rejection by one of the retailers or because it leaves a rent to one of the retailers. Propositions and show that the set of perfect Bayesian equilibria with full capacity beliefs for (Q; c) is exactly the set of the assessments E a for [0; ]. This allows us to establish two results that are valid for any full capacity beliefs PBE of (Q; c). Corollary For any Q min(q (0); c), the supplier s pro t is S = (P (Q) c)q in any perfect Bayesian equilibrium with full capacity beliefs of (Q; c). Proof. 8 [0; ], in E, x + x = q + q = Q and t + t = ( S = t + t c(q + q ) = (P (Q) c)q. Q)Q. Corollary When Q = Q (c), S = (c) in any full capacity beliefs perfect Bayesian equilibrium of (Q; c). Proof. Q (c) min(q (0); c) and (c) = (P (Q (c)) c)q (c). In equilibrium, retailers put all the product they get from the supplier on the market. So, the output on the nal market is X = Q. Through the transfers, the supplier captures downstream pro ts and S = (P (Q) c)q. S is rst increasing in Q, and then decreasing, with a maximum reached at Q = Q (c). Eventually, S may be lower than the pro t the supplier would make in the absence of a capacity constraint under passive beliefs, that is, P (Q C (c)) c Q C (c). This happens for Q C (c) Q min( c; Q (0)), which requires c =4. For Q = Q (c), S is equal to : The supplier preserves its monopoly power when its production capacity is equal to the monopoly output. This is a direct consequence of the existence of a full capacity beliefs PBE in which retailers put all the product on the market. This existence is proved by proposition. Proposition further proves that there are no other full capacity beliefs PBE. However, there may be other PBE relying on other beliefs. This raises the question of whether the assumption of full capacity beliefs is convincing. I now show that full capacity beliefs are wary beliefs, as de ned in Rey and Vergé (004). Proposition 3 For any Q min(q (0); c), any full capacity beliefs perfect Bayesian equilibrium of (Q; c) is a wary beliefs perfect Bayesian equilibrium of (Q; c). Proof. For E to be a wary beliefs perfect Bayesian equilibrium of (Q; c), ( ~q j (q i ; t i ); ~t j (q i ; t i ) = Q q i ; ( Q)(Q q i ) must be pro t maximizing for S for any admissible (q i ; t i ). By de nition of full capacity beliefs, S leaves no rent to R j. If S is not maximizing pro ts, this can only be because the quantity o ered is not optimal. Since S cannot o er more than ~q j = Q q i, the question is whether it may be pro table for S to o er a lower quantity to R j and adjust the transfer to extract all the rent from R j. If S o ers a 7

8 quantity q j < Q q i to R j, R j believes that R i receives Q q j. Given R i s strategy, it means that R i will put on the market the quantity Q q j. R j, if it accepts the contract, will choose x j so as to maximize ( Q + q j x j )x j. As shown before, it is optimal for R j to choose x j = q j for Q Q (0). R j s gross pro t is ( Q)q j and S extracts this pro t by setting t j = ( Q)q j. Thus, S = ( Q c)(q i + q j ). Given q i, the supplier s pro t maximizing o er to R j is clearly (q j ; t j ) = Q q i ; ( Q)(Q q i ) = ( ~q j (q i ; t i ); ~t j (q i ; t i ) for c Q. When the supplier o ers q i to R i, it has no incentive to o er q j < Q q i to R j. Indeed, this would induce R j to believe that R i was o ered more than q i. R j accepts to pay a larger transfer when it receives Q q i and believes that R i receives q i than when it receives q j < Q q i and believes R i receives more than q i. This is why full capacity beliefs are wary beliefs when the capacity constraint is tight. This result provides a strong support to the assumption that retailers hold full capacity beliefs. While I don t solve the model for a loose capacity constraint and a strictly positive upstream marginal cost, it is possible to give some insights on what happens in this case. To clarify, let us assume that Q is large and c > 0. Then, if the supplier produces at full capacity and sells all of its output to retailers, at least one of the retailers will nd it optimal to put on the market only a fraction of the quantity received from the supplier. Part of the supplier s output stays out of the market and thus generates no revenue, while producing it is still costly for the supplier. So, when Q is above a certain threshold, an increase in Q will reduce the supplier s pro t. At the extreme, the supplier would make a loss at a PBE with full capacity beliefs, which means that there is no such equilibrium. An equilibrium with full capacity beliefs may not exist when the capacity constraint is loose. Furthermore, full capacity beliefs may not coincide with wary beliefs. I leave for future work the question of the exact range of values of Q over which our propositions in the general case are valid, but in the next section, I deal with this issue in the special case in which production is costless (c = 0). 4 Costless production The discussion above indicates that the non-existence of a PBE with full capacity beliefs when the capacity constraint is loose is related to upstream production costs. This suggests that the range of value of Q for which such an equilibrium exists may increase when upstream marginal costs decrease. In this section, I make the extreme assumption that production is costless. Assuming Q > Q (0), since the results from section 3 apply to Q Q (0), I show that a PBE with full capacity beliefs exists. I characterize the set of perfect Bayesian equilibria with full capacity beliefs and show that, in any of these PBE, the supplier maximizes and captures industry pro ts. I also show that full capacity beliefs are wary beliefs. In this section, I drop the argument of functions when it is equal to 8

9 zero. For example, Q denotes Q (0). 7 The supplier is able to produce more than the output of a monopolistic retailer. This implies that there is some production retention by retailers. We will consider two ranges of values of Q, depending on whether Q is smaller or larger than the output of a Cournot duopoly, Q C. For Q (Q ; Q C ], it is useful to introduce two particular values of q. When R i is o ered (q i ; t i ), it believes that R j receives Q q i. As a consequence, R i would like to put on the market a quantity corresponding to its best reply to Q q i in the Cournot game. Given that R i s best reply function is BR(q j ) = ( q j), R i would like to play ( Q+q i), which he can do only if ( Q+q i) q i () q i Q. I de ne q 0 by q 0 = Q. When a retailer receives a quantity above q 0, it is able to play its best reply to what it believes its competitor receives. Part of the product received from the supplier stays out of the market. When a retailer receives a quantity below q 0, it is constrained and puts on the market all the product it receives from the supplier. Consider the situation from the point of view of R j. R j receives Q q i. R j believes that R i receives q i and that it is thus optimal to play BR(q i ) = ( q i). R j will indeed do so if ( q i) Q q i () q i q 00, where q 00 = Q. Otherwise, R j will be constrained and put Q q i on the market. Note that for Q (Q ; Q C ], 0 q 00 q 0 < Q. These values appear in the following de nition. De nition 3 For any f0; g, E 0 (Q) = x ; x ; q ; t ; q ; t ; ; ~q ; ~t ; ~q ; ~t, where:. (q ; t ; q ; t ) = Q; ; ( )Q; ( ). For i f; g, (a) Q (Q ; Q C ]: For 0 q i q 00, x i = q i for t i ( q i BR(q i ))q i, x i =? otherwise and ( ~q j (q i ; t i ); ~t j (q i ; t i ) = Q q i ; ( q i BR(q i ))BR(q i ). For q 00 q i q 0, x i = q i for t i ( Q)q i, x i =? otherwise and ( ~q j (q i ; t i ); ~t j (q i ; t i ) = Q q i ; ( Q)(Q q i ) : For q 0 q i Q, x i = BR(Q q i ) < q i for t i ( BR(Q q i ) Q + q i )BR(Q q i ), x i =? otherwise and ( ~q j (q i ; t i ); ~t j (q i ; t i ) = Q q i ; ( Q + q i BR(Q q i ))(Q q i ) : (b) Q > Q C : For 0 q i q C, x i = q i for t i ( q i BR(q i ))q i, x i =? otherwise and ( ~q j (q i ; t i ); ~t j (q i ; t i ) = Q q i ; ( q i BR(q i ))BR(q i ) : For q C q i Q q C, x i = q C for t i ( q C )q C, x i =? otherwise and ( ~q j (q i ; t i ); ~t j (q i ; t i ) = Q q i ; ( q C )q C : For Q q C q i Q, x i = BR(Q q i ) < q i for t i ( BR(Q q i ) Q + q i )BR(Q q i ), x i =? otherwise and ( ~q j (q i ; t i ); ~t j (q i ; t i ) = Q q i ; ( Q + q i BR(Q q i ))(Q q i ) : 7 Q = ; QC = 3 ; = 4 and C = 9. 9

10 Contrary to what happens in E, in E0 0 and E, 0 retailers may keep part of the product they receive from the supplier out of the market. For example, for Q > Q C, when R receives q C and R receives q C + " < Q q C, both retailers put q C on the market and R keeps " out of the market. When R receives Q, it believes that R receives zero and, thus, plays its best reply to zero, which is just the monopoly output, Q. Again, this is less than Q. The proposition establishes that this last situation is precisely what happens in equilibrium. Proposition 4 For Q > Q, (Q; 0) has two perfect Bayesian equilibria with full capacity beliefs, E0 0 and E. 0 The output on the nal market is Q. Proof. ) Q (Q ; Q C ] Sequential rationality of R i For 0 q i q 00, ~q j q 0 : Given R j s strategy and ~t j (q i ; t i ), R j accepts the contract and plays x j = BR(Q ~q j ) = BR(q i ) = ( q i). x i = min(br(br(q i )); q i ) = q i () t i ( q i BR(q i ))q i. For q 00 q i q 0, ~q j [q 00 ; q 0 ]. x j = ~q j and x i = min(br(q q i ); q i ) = q i () t i ( Q)q i. For q 0 q i Q, 0 ~q j q 00. x j = ~q j and x i = min(br(q q i ); q i ) = BR(Q q i ) () t i ( BR(Q q i ) Q + q i )BR(Q q i ). Consistency of R i s beliefs Full capacity beliefs are consistent with the supplier s equilibrium strategy. Sequential rationality for S Without loss of generality, I establish the proof for E 0 under the assumption that S makes acceptable o ers to retailers. In E, 0 the supplier o ers Q to R and ~q = 0. Consequently, x = BR(0) = Q. S = t + t =. Let us now consider all the possible deviations and show that they cannot be pro table. If S o ers q [0; q 00 ], it can o er any q 0; Q q, with Q q > q 0. For q [0; q 00 ], S can charge R i a transfer equal to ( q i BR(q i ))q i = ( q i)q i. S maximizes pro ts by o ering q = q = q 00 and gets ( q 00 )q 00 <. For q [q 00 ; q 0 ], S charges t = ( q )q and t = ( Q)q. Maximizing t +t, S gets ( q00 )q 00 +( Q)q 0 = ( Q)(Q ) + ( Q) = ( Q)Q <. For q q 0 ; Q q, S gets t = ( BR (Q. q ) Q + q )BR (Q q ) = 4 Q + q This is maximal for q = Q q. So, S chooses q in order to maximize ( q )q + 4 ( q ) = 4 q. S o ers (q ; q ) = (0; Q) =) S =. If S o ers q [q 00 ; q 0 ], it can o er any q 0; Q q, where q 00 Q q q 0. There is no pro table deviation with q [0; q 00 ] (see above by symmetry). For q q 00 ; Q q, S charges t = ( Q)q and t = ( Q)q and gets ( Q)(q + q ) <. If S o ers q q 0 ; Q, it can o er any q 0; Q q, where Q q q 00. S maximizes t + t = 4 Q + q + ( q )q. This requires that q = Q q, leading to t +t = 4 Q + q + ( Q+q ) Q q = 4 Q q. This is maximal for q = Q, as in E. 0 ) Q > Q C Sequential rationality of R i For 0 q i q C, ~q j Q q C. x j = BR(q i ) and x i = min(br(br(q i )); q i ) = q i () t i ( q i BR(q i ))q i. For q C 0

11 q i Q q C, q C ~q j Q q C. x j = q C and x i = q C. For Q q C q i Q, 0 ~q j q C. x j = Q q i and x i = min(br(q q i ); q i ) = BR(Q q i ) q i. Sequential rationality of S I consider all the possible deviations for S and check that none of those is pro table. If S o ers q 0; q C, it can o er any q up to Q q > Q q C. For q 0; q C, S gets transfers equal to t + t = ( q )q + ( q )q. This is obviously maximal for q = q = q C, but ( q C )q C <. For q q C ; Q q C, t +t = ( q )q +( q C )q C. Arg max(t + t ) = q C, but t (q C ) + t (q C ) <. For q Q q C ; Q q,. t + t = ( q )q + 4 Q + q S would set q = Q q and t + t = ( q )q + 4 ( q ) = 4 q =) (q ; q ) = (0; Q) and S =. If S o ers q q C ; Q q C, it can o er any q up to Q q q C ; Q q C. The case q 0; q C was examined above (by symmetry). For q q C ; Q q. t + t = ( q C )q C <. If S o ers q Q q C ; Q, it can o er any q up to Q q q C. t + t = 4 Q + q + ( q )q. S would choose q = Q q and t + t = 4 Q q. This is maximal for q = Q, as in E. 0 Consistency of retailers beliefs Obvious. Corollary 3 For Q > Q, S = in any perfect Bayesian equilibrium with full capacity beliefs of (Q; 0). Proof. S = t + t = ( Q )Q =. In equilibrium, the supplier s pro t is equal to. No deviation allows S to increase pro ts above this value. To get an intuition of why this is the case, suppose that Q (Q ; Q C ] and the supplier deviates from (q ; q ) = (Q; 0) by o ering to R a small amount < q 00 and reducing its o er to R to Q. R will put on the market and R will put BR(). The highest pro t that the supplier can make given retailers beliefs is ( BR() c)(+br()). This is smaller than because ( X)X is maximal for X = Q and +BR() > Q. O ering a positive quantity to R (with an acceptable transfer) leads to an increase in the total output on the nal market and to a reduction in the supplier s pro t. Any deviation strictly reduces the supplier s pro t, except a switch from (q ; q ) = (Q; 0) to (q ; q ) = (0; Q), that is, from E 0 to E0, 0 that leaves the supplier s pro t unchanged. The intuition for the absence of a strictly pro table deviation for Q > Q C is the same. With a nite production capacity, the supplier can credibly commit not to supply one of the retailers and thus to place the other retailer in a monopoly position on the nal market. The supplier can do so by producing at full capacity and transferring all of its production to one retailer. This retailer will put the monopoly output Q on the nal market and keep all the di erence between the monopoly output and the supplier s production out of the market. This is not necessarily an equilibrium strategy for the supplier and if marginal costs at the upstream level are high, it is certainly not, but when marginal costs are low enough, it may be an equilibrium. With zero marginal costs, it is indeed

12 an equilibrium. For the supplier to be able to preserve its market power, it is thus not necessary that its production capacity is equal to the monopoly output when production is costless. The necessary condition is rather that the supplier is able to produce at least the monopoly output. I now show that full capacity beliefs are wary. Proposition 5 For Q > Q, any perfect Bayesian equilibrium with full capacity beliefs of (Q; 0) is a perfect Bayesian equilibrium with wary beliefs of (Q; 0). Proof. This proof requires to show that, for any admissible (q i ; t i ), R i maximizes pro ts when o ering to R j the contract ( ~q j (q i ; t i ); ~t j (q i ; t i ). ) Q (Q ; Q C ] For q i 0; Q q 0 ; q j 0; Q q i, with Q qi q 0. For q j [0; q 00 ], t j = ( q j) q j. S chooses q j = q 00 and gets t j = ( q00 ) q 00. For q j [q 00 ; q 0 ], t j = ( Q)q j. S chooses q j = q 0 and gets t j = ( Q)q 0 = ( Q). For q j. q 0 ; Q q i, tj = 4 Q + q j S chooses qj = Q q i and gets t j = 4 ( q i). Since ( q00 ) q 00 ( Q) 4 ( q i), S maximizes pro ts by o ering q j = Q q i and charging the highest acceptable transfer ~t j (q i ; t i ). For q i Q q 0 ; Q q 00 ; q j 0; Q q i, with q 00 Q q i q 0. For q j [0; q 00 ], t j = ( q j) q j. S chooses q j = q 00 and gets t j = ( q00 ) q 00. For q j q 00 ; Q q i, tj = ( Q)q j. S chooses q j = Q q i and gets t j = Q Q q i. Since ( q00 ) q 00 Q Q q i, S maximizes pro ts by o ering q j = Q q i and charging the highest acceptable transfer ~t j (q i ; t i ). For q i Q q 00 ; Q, q j 0; Q q [0; q 00 ]. t j = ( q j) q j, which is maximal for q j = Q q i. ) Q > Q C For q i 0; q C ; q j 0; Q q i, with Q q C Q q i Q. For q j 0; q C, t j = ( q j) q j. S chooses q j = q C and gets t j = qc q C. For q j q C ; Q q C, t j = ( q C )q C. For q j Q q C ; Q q i, tj = 4 Q + q. j S chooses q j = Q q i and gets t j = 4 ( q i). Since qc q C = ( q C )q C 4 ( q i), q j = Q q i. For q i q C ; Q q C ; q j 0; Q q i, with q C Q q i Q q C. For q j 0; q C, t j = ( q j) q j. S chooses q j = q C and gets t j = qc q C. For q j q C ; Q q i, tj = ( q C )q C. Since qc q C = ( q C )q C, S is indi erent as regards the value of q j. In particular, q j = Q q i maximizes S s pro t. For q i Q q C ; Q, q j 0; Q q i 0; q C and t j = ( q j) q j, which is maximal for q j = Q q i. The intuition for this result is the same as for a tight capacity constraint. The only di erence is that, because the supplier s production capacity is large, the supplier may be indi erent between o ering R j a quantity equal to the production capacity available after its o er to R i and producing below capacity. Indeed, as long as both retailers are o ered more than the Cournot duopoly output, they are indi erent regarding a variation in the quantity o ered to them or to their competitor.

13 5 Conclusion This article contributes to the literature in two ways. It exposes the source of a standard result, namely that a monopolist supplying retailers through secret contracts under passive beliefs as well as under wary beliefs is unable to preserve its monopoly power. This result is a consequence of the implicit assumption that the monopolist enjoys an in nite capacity of production. The article develops a theoretical framework to analyze vertical contracting in the presence of a nite production capacity at the upstream level. While the article doesn t present a resolution of the game for every value of production capacity and upstream marginal cost, it presents a full resolution in two signi cant cases. In both cases, I characterize the (non-empty) set of perfect Bayesian equilibria of the game in which retailers hold full capacity beliefs, a type of beliefs that is discussed here for the rst time. I further show that these full capacity beliefs correspond, in these cases, to the wary beliefs introduced by McAfee and Schwartz and reformulated by Rey and Vergé. With costless production, as soon as the monopolist s production capacity is su ciently large, but nite, the monopolist can extend its monopoly power into the nal market, maximize industry pro ts and entirely capture these pro ts. With costly production, the supplier maximizes and captures industry pro ts when the upstream capacity is equal to the monopoly output. A direct consequence of this result is that if the monopolist is able to choose its production capacity, it will be able to monopolize the nal market. I leave for future work the characterization of wary beliefs and full capacity beliefs perfect Bayesian equilibria when upstream marginal costs are strictly positive and the capacity constraint is loose. This characterization is not necessary to establish, as I do in this article, that the standard model of private vertical contracting includes an implicit assumption (in nite upstream production capacity) that is the source of a supplier s inability to preserve its market power when selling its product through competing retailers. Incorporating a capacity constraint into the model leads to very di erent results and certainly improves the predictive power of the model for many industries. 6 References Cremer, J. and M. H. Riordan, 987, On governing multilateral transactions with bilateral contracts, RAND Journal of Economics, 8, Hart, O. and J. Tirole, 990, Vertical integration and market foreclosure, Brookings papers on Economic Activity (Microeconomics), 990, Martin, S., H.-T. Normann and C. Snyder, 00, Vertical foreclosure in experimental markets, RAND Journal of Economics, 3, Mas-Colell, A., M. Whinston and J. Green, 995, Microeconomic theory, Oxford University Press. McAfee, R.P. and M. Schwartz, 994, Opportunism in multilateral vertical contracting: Nondiscrimination, exclusivity, and uniformity, American Eco- 3

14 nomic Review, 84(), McAfee, R.P. and M. Schwartz, 995, The non-existence of pairwise-proof equilibrium, Economics Letters, 49, O Brien, D. and G. Sha er, 99, Vertical control with bilateral contracts, RAND Journal of Economics, 3, Rey, P. and T. Vergé, 004, Bilateral control with vertical contracts, RAND Journal of Economics, 35(4), Segal, I., 999, Contracting with externalities, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 4(),

Limit pricing models and PBE 1

Limit pricing models and PBE 1 EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Limit pricing models and PBE 1 1 Model Consider an entry game with an incumbent monopolist (Firm 1) and an entrant (Firm ) who analyzes whether or not to join the

More information

Equilibrium Selection in Imperfect Information Games with Externalities

Equilibrium Selection in Imperfect Information Games with Externalities Equilibrium Selection in Imperfect Information Games with Externalities Jon X. Eguia (NYU) Rebecca Morton (NYU) z Aniol Llorente-Saguer (Max Planck) y April 9, 2013 Antonio Nicolò (U. Padova) x Abstract

More information

Bilateral Control with Vertical Contracts

Bilateral Control with Vertical Contracts Bilateral Control with Vertical Contracts Patrick Rey * Thibaud Vergé ** July 15, 2003 (*) University of Toulouse (IDEI and GREMAQ), Manufacture des Tabacs, 21 allée de Brienne, 31000 Toulouse, France

More information

Advanced Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomics Advanced Microeconomics Leonardo Felli EC441: Room D.106, Z.332, D.109 Lecture 8 bis: 24 November 2004 Monopoly Consider now the pricing behavior of a profit maximizing monopolist: a firm that is the only

More information

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours. University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring 2012 EC941: Game Theory Prof. Francesco Squintani Final Exam Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours. 1. Consider

More information

Extensive Form Games with Perfect Information

Extensive Form Games with Perfect Information Extensive Form Games with Perfect Information Pei-yu Lo 1 Introduction Recap: BoS. Look for all Nash equilibria. show how to nd pure strategy Nash equilibria. Show how to nd mixed strategy Nash equilibria.

More information

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS 8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS We have studied competitive markets where there are a large number of rms and each rm takes market prices as given. When a market contain only a few relevant rms, rms may

More information

9 A Class of Dynamic Games of Incomplete Information:

9 A Class of Dynamic Games of Incomplete Information: A Class of Dynamic Games of Incomplete Information: Signalling Games In general, a dynamic game of incomplete information is any extensive form game in which at least one player is uninformed about some

More information

Solving Extensive Form Games

Solving Extensive Form Games Chapter 8 Solving Extensive Form Games 8.1 The Extensive Form of a Game The extensive form of a game contains the following information: (1) the set of players (2) the order of moves (that is, who moves

More information

EconS Vertical Integration

EconS Vertical Integration EconS 425 - Vertical Integration Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 26 Introduction Let s continue

More information

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition 4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition Partial equilibrium studies the existence of equilibrium in the market of a given commodity and analyzes its properties. Prices in other markets as well

More information

Some Notes on Adverse Selection

Some Notes on Adverse Selection Some Notes on Adverse Selection John Morgan Haas School of Business and Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Overview This set of lecture notes covers a general model of adverse selection

More information

Bilateral Control with Vertical Contracts

Bilateral Control with Vertical Contracts CMPO Working Paper Series No. 02/48 Bilateral Control with Vertical Contracts Patrick Rey 1 and Thibaud Vergé 2 1 GREMAQ IDEI, Université des Sciences Sociales (Toulouse) 2 CMPO, and Department of Economics,

More information

EconS Oligopoly - Part 2

EconS Oligopoly - Part 2 EconS 305 - Oligopoly - Part 2 Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu November 29, 2015 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 32 November 29, 2015 1 / 28 Introduction Last time,

More information

EconS Sequential Competition

EconS Sequential Competition EconS 425 - Sequential Competition Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 47 A Warmup 1 x i x j (x

More information

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam #2 - Answer Key

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam #2 - Answer Key EconS 50 - Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam # - Answer Key 1. Revenue comparison in two auction formats. Consider a sealed-bid auction with bidders. Every bidder i privately observes his valuation

More information

The Intuitive and Divinity Criterion:

The Intuitive and Divinity Criterion: The Intuitive and Divinity Criterion: Interpretation and Step-by-Step Examples Ana Espínola-Arredondo School of Economic Sciences Washington State University Pullman, WA 99164 Félix Muñoz-García y School

More information

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 Bertrand Model of Price Competition Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 ҧ Bertrand Model of Price Competition Consider: An industry with two firms, 1 and 2, selling a homogeneous product Firms face market

More information

Cross-Licensing and Competition

Cross-Licensing and Competition Cross-Licensing and Competition Doh-Shin Jeon and Yassine Lefouili y June 7, 2013 Very preliminary and incomplete - Please do not circulate Abstract We study bilateral cross-licensing agreements among

More information

1 Games in Normal Form (Strategic Form)

1 Games in Normal Form (Strategic Form) Games in Normal Form (Strategic Form) A Game in Normal (strategic) Form consists of three components. A set of players. For each player, a set of strategies (called actions in textbook). The interpretation

More information

Barnali Gupta Miami University, Ohio, U.S.A. Abstract

Barnali Gupta Miami University, Ohio, U.S.A. Abstract Spatial Cournot competition in a circular city with transport cost differentials Barnali Gupta Miami University, Ohio, U.S.A. Abstract For an even number of firms with identical transport cost, spatial

More information

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Repeated Games

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Repeated Games EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Repeated Games. MWG 9.B.9 Consider the game in which the following simultaneous-move game as depicted in gure is played twice: Player Player 2 b b 2 b

More information

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016 Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016 1 Modelling incomplete information So far, we have studied games in which information was complete,

More information

Vertical Di erentiation With Congestion E ect

Vertical Di erentiation With Congestion E ect Vertical Di erentiation With Congestion E ect Khaïreddine Jebsi Rim Lahmandi-Ayed y March 13, 007 Abstract Adding a congestion e ect to a vertical di erentiation model, the qualitythen-price equilibrium

More information

Nonlinear Programming (NLP)

Nonlinear Programming (NLP) Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 6: Nonlinear Programming - Unconstrained Optimization Note 6 is based on de la Fuente (2000, Ch. 7), Madden (1986, Ch. 3 and 5) and Simon and Blume

More information

Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!?

Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!? Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!? Mathias Erlei Clausthal University of Technology Julius-Albert-Str. 2, 38678 Clausthal-Zellerfeld, Germany email: m.erlei@tu-clausthal.de Abstract This

More information

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective Alex Possajennikov University of Nottingham January 2012 Abstract Suppose that in aggregative games, in which a player s payoff

More information

Equilibrium Vertical Foreclosure in the Repeated Game

Equilibrium Vertical Foreclosure in the Repeated Game Equilibrium Vertical Foreclosure in the Repeated Game Hans-Theo Normann y Royal HollowayCollege, University of London January 14, 005 Abstract This paper analyzes whether vertical foreclosure can emerge

More information

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Subgame Perfect Equilibrium (SPNE)

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Subgame Perfect Equilibrium (SPNE) EconS 3 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Subgame Perfect Equilibrium (SPNE). Based on MWG 9.B.3 Consider the three-player nite game of perfect information depicted in gure. L R Player 3 l r a b

More information

Online Appendix for Sourcing from Suppliers with Financial Constraints and Performance Risk

Online Appendix for Sourcing from Suppliers with Financial Constraints and Performance Risk Online Appendix for Sourcing from Suppliers with Financial Constraints and Performance Ris Christopher S. Tang S. Alex Yang Jing Wu Appendix A: Proofs Proof of Lemma 1. In a centralized chain, the system

More information

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design 1. Public Good Provision Imagine that you and your colleagues want to buy a co ee machine for your o ce. Suppose that some of you may

More information

Static Models of Oligopoly

Static Models of Oligopoly Static Models of Oligopoly Cournot and Bertrand Models Mateusz Szetela 1 1 Collegium of Economic Analysis Warsaw School of Economics 3 March 2016 Outline 1 Introduction Game Theory and Oligopolies 2 The

More information

Lecture Notes on Game Theory

Lecture Notes on Game Theory Lecture Notes on Game Theory Levent Koçkesen 1 Bayesian Games So far we have assumed that all players had perfect information regarding the elements of a game. These are called games with complete information.

More information

Volume 30, Issue 3. Monotone comparative statics with separable objective functions. Christian Ewerhart University of Zurich

Volume 30, Issue 3. Monotone comparative statics with separable objective functions. Christian Ewerhart University of Zurich Volume 30, Issue 3 Monotone comparative statics with separable objective functions Christian Ewerhart University of Zurich Abstract The Milgrom-Shannon single crossing property is essential for monotone

More information

Carrot and stick games

Carrot and stick games Bond University epublications@bond Bond Business School Publications Bond Business School 6-14-2001 Carrot and stick games Jeffrey J. Kline Bond University, jeffrey_kline@bond.edu.au Follow this and additional

More information

Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly

Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly Rabah Amir Department of Economics, University of Arizona Giuseppe De Feo y CORE, Université Catholique de Louvain February 2007 Abstract This paper addresses the issue

More information

Exclusive Dealing and Vertical Integration in Interlocking Relationships

Exclusive Dealing and Vertical Integration in Interlocking Relationships Exclusive Dealing and Vertical Integration in Interlocking Relationships Volker Nocke Patrick Rey September 20, 2014 Abstract We develop a model of interlocking bilateral relationships between upstream

More information

Vertical integration in the e commerce sector"

Vertical integration in the e commerce sector 8 99 May 208 Vertical integration in the e commerce sector" Claire Borsenberger, Helmuth Cremer, Denis Joram and Jean Marie Lozachmeur Vertical integration in the e-commerce sector Claire Borsenberger

More information

Exclusive contracts and market dominance

Exclusive contracts and market dominance Exclusive contracts and market dominance Giacomo Calzolari and Vincenzo Denicolò Online Appendix. Proofs for the baseline model This Section provides the proofs of Propositions and 2. Proof of Proposition.

More information

Spatial Competition and Collaboration Networks

Spatial Competition and Collaboration Networks Spatial Competition and Collaboration Networks Yasunori Okumura y Kanagawa University May, 009 Abstract In this paper, we discuss the formation of collaboration networks among rms that are located in a

More information

Final Exam (Solution) Economics 501b Microeconomic Theory

Final Exam (Solution) Economics 501b Microeconomic Theory Dirk Bergemann and Johannes Hoerner Department of Economics Yale Uniersity Final Exam (Solution) Economics 5b Microeconomic Theory May This is a closed-book exam. The exam lasts for 8 minutes. Please write

More information

Merchants vs. Two-Sided Platforms: Competing Intermediation Models

Merchants vs. Two-Sided Platforms: Competing Intermediation Models erchants vs. Two-Sided latforms: Competing Intermediation odels Gary Biglaiser and Andrei Hagiu y RELIINARY AND INCOLETE - LEASE DO NOT CITE February 8, 014 Abstract We build and solve a model of competition

More information

Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection

Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection Geethanjali Selvaretnam Abstract This model takes into consideration the fact that depositors

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS PROFITABILITY OF HORIZONTAL MERGERS IN TRIGGER STRATEGY GAME. Berardino Cesiy University of Rome Tor Vergata

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS PROFITABILITY OF HORIZONTAL MERGERS IN TRIGGER STRATEGY GAME. Berardino Cesiy University of Rome Tor Vergata DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS PROFITABILITY OF HORIZONTAL MERGERS IN TRIGGER STRATEGY GAME Berardino Cesiy University of Rome Tor Vergata Working Paper No. 06/4 January 2006 Pro tability of Horizontal Mergers

More information

DYNAMIC LIMIT PRICING: ONLINE APPENDIX Flavio Toxvaerd. March 8, 2018

DYNAMIC LIMIT PRICING: ONLINE APPENDIX Flavio Toxvaerd. March 8, 2018 DYNAMIC LIMIT PRICING: ONLINE APPENDIX Flavio Toxvaerd March 8, 2018 Abstract. This appendix o ers a detailed and self-contained analysis of the benchmark single-round version of the dynamic model presented

More information

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

Answer Key: Problem Set 3 Answer Key: Problem Set Econ 409 018 Fall Question 1 a This is a standard monopoly problem; using MR = a 4Q, let MR = MC and solve: Q M = a c 4, P M = a + c, πm = (a c) 8 The Lerner index is then L M P

More information

Basics of Game Theory

Basics of Game Theory Basics of Game Theory Giacomo Bacci and Luca Sanguinetti Department of Information Engineering University of Pisa, Pisa, Italy {giacomo.bacci,luca.sanguinetti}@iet.unipi.it April - May, 2010 G. Bacci and

More information

Lecture 7. Simple Dynamic Games

Lecture 7. Simple Dynamic Games Lecture 7. Simple Dynamic Games 1. Two-Stage Games of Complete and Perfect Information Two-Stages dynamic game with two players: player 1 chooses action a 1 from the set of his feasible actions A 1 player

More information

Bayesian Games and Mechanism Design Definition of Bayes Equilibrium

Bayesian Games and Mechanism Design Definition of Bayes Equilibrium Bayesian Games and Mechanism Design Definition of Bayes Equilibrium Harsanyi [1967] What happens when players do not know one another s payoffs? Games of incomplete information versus games of imperfect

More information

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key EconS 503 - Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key 1. WEAs with market power. Consider an exchange economy with two consumers, A and B, whose utility functions are u A (x A 1 ; x A 2 ) = x A

More information

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018 EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 018 Show all your work clearly and make sure you justify all your answers. NAME 1. Consider the market for smart pencil in which only one firm (Superapiz) enjoys a

More information

Market Power. Economics II: Microeconomics. December Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39

Market Power. Economics II: Microeconomics. December Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39 Market Power Economics II: Microeconomics VŠE Praha December 2009 Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39 Microeconomics Consumers: Firms: People. Households. Monopoly. Oligopoly Now Perfect Competition.

More information

Cross-Licensing and Competition

Cross-Licensing and Competition Cross-Licensing and Competition Doh-Shin Jeon y and Yassine Lefouili z September 30, 2013 Abstract We study bilateral cross-licensing agreements among N(> 2) rms that engage in competition after the licensing

More information

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill remium Ariel Burstein UCLA and NBER Jonathan Vogel Columbia and NBER April 22 Abstract In this Addendum we set up a perfectly competitive version

More information

Cartel Stability in a Dynamic Oligopoly with Sticky Prices

Cartel Stability in a Dynamic Oligopoly with Sticky Prices Cartel Stability in a Dynamic Oligopoly with Sticky Prices Hassan Benchekroun and Licun Xue y McGill University and CIREQ, Montreal This version: September 2005 Abstract We study the stability of cartels

More information

Simplifying this, we obtain the following set of PE allocations: (x E ; x W ) 2

Simplifying this, we obtain the following set of PE allocations: (x E ; x W ) 2 Answers Answer for Q (a) ( pts:.5 pts. for the de nition and.5 pts. for its characterization) The de nition of PE is standard. There may be many ways to characterize the set of PE allocations. But whichever

More information

Some Notes on Costless Signaling Games

Some Notes on Costless Signaling Games Some Notes on Costless Signaling Games John Morgan University of California at Berkeley Preliminaries Our running example is that of a decision maker (DM) consulting a knowledgeable expert for advice about

More information

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games University of Manchester, UK November 25, 2010 Introduction Suppose we make a finite set of observations T = {1,..., m}, m 1, of a perfectly homogeneous-good oligopoly market. There is a finite number

More information

Notes on Mechanism Designy

Notes on Mechanism Designy Notes on Mechanism Designy ECON 20B - Game Theory Guillermo Ordoñez UCLA February 0, 2006 Mechanism Design. Informal discussion. Mechanisms are particular types of games of incomplete (or asymmetric) information

More information

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology Daron Acemoglu MIT October 3, 2007 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Advanced Growth Lecture 8 October 3,

More information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers September 6, 016 ONLINE APPENDIX In this Appendix we present in full additional results and extensions which are only mentioned in the paper. In the exposition

More information

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Labor Economics, 14.661. Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Daron Acemoglu MIT December 6, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Sequential Search December 6, 2011. 1 / 43 Introduction Introduction

More information

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship Journal of Game Theory 2017 6(2): 38-42 DOI: 10.5923/j.jgt.20170602.02 Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship Aika Monden Graduate School

More information

Notes on the Mussa-Rosen duopoly model

Notes on the Mussa-Rosen duopoly model Notes on the Mussa-Rosen duopoly model Stephen Martin Faculty of Economics & Econometrics University of msterdam Roetersstraat 08 W msterdam The Netherlands March 000 Contents Demand. Firm...............................

More information

3. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition Competitive Equilibrium

3. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition Competitive Equilibrium 3. Imperfect Competition 3. Partial Equilirium under Imperfect Competition Competitive Equilirium Partial equilirium studies the existence of equilirium in the market of a given commodity and analyzes

More information

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of... This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of... John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 1 / 1 We will cover the following topics: with Sequential Moves

More information

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods 5. Externalities and Public Goods 5. Externalities and Public Goods Externalities Welfare properties of Walrasian Equilibria rely on the hidden assumption of private goods: the consumption of the good

More information

Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition

Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition Luca Lambertini Alessandro Tampieri Quaderni - Working Paper DSE N 750 Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Di erentiated

More information

Cross-Licensing and Competition

Cross-Licensing and Competition Cross-Licensing and Competition Doh-Shin Jeon y Yassine Lefouili z December 23, 2017 Abstract We analyze the competitive e ects of bilateral cross-licensing agreements in a setting with many competing

More information

Experimentation and Observational Learning in a Market with Exit

Experimentation and Observational Learning in a Market with Exit ömmföäflsäafaäsflassflassflas ffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffff Discussion Papers Experimentation and Observational Learning in a Market with Exit Pauli Murto Helsinki School of Economics and HECER

More information

5. Externalities and Public Goods

5. Externalities and Public Goods 5. Externalities and Public Goods Welfare properties of Walrasian Equilibria rely on the hidden assumption of private goods: the consumption of the good by one person has no effect on other people s utility,

More information

Modeling Technological Change

Modeling Technological Change Modeling Technological Change Yin-Chi Wang The Chinese University of Hong Kong November, 202 References: Acemoglu (2009) ch2 Concepts of Innovation Innovation by type. Process innovation: reduce cost,

More information

October 16, 2018 Notes on Cournot. 1. Teaching Cournot Equilibrium

October 16, 2018 Notes on Cournot. 1. Teaching Cournot Equilibrium October 1, 2018 Notes on Cournot 1. Teaching Cournot Equilibrium Typically Cournot equilibrium is taught with identical zero or constant-mc cost functions for the two firms, because that is simpler. I

More information

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics Yulei Luo SEF of HKU January 14, 2009 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) MME January 14, 2009 1 / 44 Comparative Statics and The Concept of Derivative Comparative Statics

More information

Equilibrium Selection in Sequential Games with Imperfect Information

Equilibrium Selection in Sequential Games with Imperfect Information Preprints of the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods Bonn 2014/4 Equilibrium Selection in Sequential Games with Imperfect Information Jon X. Eguia Aniol Llorente-Saguer Rebecca Morton

More information

Research and Development

Research and Development Chapter 9. March 7, 2011 Firms spend substantial amounts on. For instance ( expenditure to output sales): aerospace (23%), o ce machines and computers (18%), electronics (10%) and drugs (9%). is classi

More information

Competitive Effects of Vertical Integration with Downstream Oligopsony and Oligopoly

Competitive Effects of Vertical Integration with Downstream Oligopsony and Oligopoly Competitive Effects of Vertical Integration with Downstream Oligopsony and Oligopoly Simon Loertscher and Markus Reisinger March 26, 2008 Abstract This paper analyzes the competitive effects of backward

More information

Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University

Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1846 EFFICIENT AUCTIONS AND INTERDEPENDENT TYPES Dirk Bergemann, Stephen Morris, and Satoru Takahashi

More information

Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I

Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I Prepared with SEVI S LIDES Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I Antonio Cabrales & Massimo Motta May 25, 2005 Summary Some definitions Efficiency reasons for tying Tying as a price

More information

TESIS de DOCTORADO DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO.

TESIS de DOCTORADO DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO. Instituto I N S T Ide T Economía U T O D E E C O N O M Í A TESIS de DOCTORADO DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO 2006 Perfectly Competitive Education with Reputational Concerns Bernardita Vial. www.economia.puc.cl Perfectly

More information

Microeconomics for Business Practice Session 3 - Solutions

Microeconomics for Business Practice Session 3 - Solutions Microeconomics for Business Practice Session - Solutions Instructor: Eloisa Campioni TA: Ugo Zannini University of Rome Tor Vergata April 8, 016 Exercise 1 Show that there are no mixed-strategy Nash equilibria

More information

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with Increasing Returns to Scale Abhijit Sengupta and Yair Tauman February 6, 24 Abstract We consider a Cournot Oligopoly market of firms possessing increasing

More information

Robust Mechanism Design and Robust Implementation

Robust Mechanism Design and Robust Implementation Robust Mechanism Design and Robust Implementation joint work with Stephen Morris August 2009 Barcelona Introduction mechanism design and implementation literatures are theoretical successes mechanisms

More information

When Should a Firm Expand Its Business? The Signaling Implications of Business Expansion

When Should a Firm Expand Its Business? The Signaling Implications of Business Expansion When Should a Firm Expand Its Business? The Signaling Implications of Business Expansion Ana Espínola-Arredondo y Esther Gal-Or z Félix Muñoz-García x June 2, 2009 Abstract We examine an incumbent s trade-o

More information

OPTIMAL TWO-PART TARIFF LICENSING CONTRACTS WITH DIFFERENTIATED GOODS AND ENDOGENOUS R&D* Ramón Faulí-Oller and Joel Sandonís**

OPTIMAL TWO-PART TARIFF LICENSING CONTRACTS WITH DIFFERENTIATED GOODS AND ENDOGENOUS R&D* Ramón Faulí-Oller and Joel Sandonís** OPTIMAL TWO-PART TARIFF LICENSING CONTRACTS WITH DIFFERENTIATED GOODS AND ENDOGENOUS R&D* Ramón Faulí-Oller and Joel Sandonís** WP-AD 2008-12 Corresponding author: R. Fauli-Oller Universidad de Alicante,

More information

Duopoly and Project Uncertainty

Duopoly and Project Uncertainty Duopoly and Project Uncertainty An analysis of the Bertrand and Cournot duopolies under uncertainty for the buyer Draft Master Thesis Rik Bos Student 345327 June 2016 Erasmus School of Economics Master

More information

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation Nicolas Schutz Nicolas Schutz Product Differentiation 1 / 57 Introduction We now finally drop the assumption that firms offer homogeneous products.

More information

MS&E 246: Lecture 12 Static games of incomplete information. Ramesh Johari

MS&E 246: Lecture 12 Static games of incomplete information. Ramesh Johari MS&E 246: Lecture 12 Static games of incomplete information Ramesh Johari Incomplete information Complete information means the entire structure of the game is common knowledge Incomplete information means

More information

Core Discussion Paper 2006/97 Competition in successive markets: entry and mergers

Core Discussion Paper 2006/97 Competition in successive markets: entry and mergers Core Discussion Paper 2006/97 Competition in successive markets: entry and mergers Jean J. Gabszewicz and Skerdilajda Zanaj Center for operations research and econometrics August 29, 2007 Abstract This

More information

Static Information Design

Static Information Design Static nformation Design Dirk Bergemann and Stephen Morris European Summer Symposium in Economic Theory, Gerzensee, July 2016 Mechanism Design and nformation Design Mechanism Design: Fix an economic environment

More information

Dynamic Merger Review

Dynamic Merger Review Dynamic Merger Review Volker Nocke University of Oxford and CEPR Michael D. Whinston Northwestern University and NBER PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE January 11, 2008 Abstract We analyze the optimal dynamic

More information

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I 14.454 - Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I 04/02/2011 Due: Monday 4/11/2011 1 Question 1 - Kocherlakota (2000) Take an economy with a representative, in nitely-lived consumer. The consumer owns a technology

More information

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract Entry under an Information-Gathering onopoly Alex Barrachina* June 2016 Abstract The effects of information-gathering activities on a basic entry model with asymmetric information are analyzed. In the

More information

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly Daisuke Hirata Graduate School of Economics, University of Tokyo March 2008 Abstract This paper investigates a simultaneous move capacity constrained price competition

More information

Framing Competition. March 30, Abstract

Framing Competition. March 30, Abstract Framing Competition Michele Piccione y and Ran Spiegler z March 30, 009 Abstract We analyze a model of market competition in which two identical rms choose prices as well as how to present, or frame, their

More information

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Hiroaki Ino Institute of Intellectual Property and Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo [Preliminary

More information

Pricing to Preclude Sabotage in Regulated Industries

Pricing to Preclude Sabotage in Regulated Industries Pricing to Preclude Sabotage in Regulated Industries by Arup Bose*, Debashis Pal**, and David E. M. Sappington*** Abstract We characterize the optimal access price and retail price for a vertically-integrated

More information

Simultaneous Choice Models: The Sandwich Approach to Nonparametric Analysis

Simultaneous Choice Models: The Sandwich Approach to Nonparametric Analysis Simultaneous Choice Models: The Sandwich Approach to Nonparametric Analysis Natalia Lazzati y November 09, 2013 Abstract We study collective choice models from a revealed preference approach given limited

More information

Puri cation 1. Stephen Morris Princeton University. July Economics.

Puri cation 1. Stephen Morris Princeton University. July Economics. Puri cation 1 Stephen Morris Princeton University July 2006 1 This survey was prepared as an entry for the second edition of the New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. In a mixed strategy equilibrium of

More information

Spence s labor market signaling model

Spence s labor market signaling model Spence s labor market signaling model Felix Munoz-Garcia EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II - Washington State University Readings MWG 13.C (You can also read 13.B) Macho-Stadler and Perez-Castrillo,

More information